Global climate change: Economics and public action.

Post on 22-Dec-2015

218 views 2 download

Tags:

transcript

Global climate change: Economics and public action

The experiment

Source: Stiglitz, 2006

The Big Picture

Agenda

• A (very) rapid look at the science of climate change

• The economics of climate change– Externalities and public goods– Cost benefit analysis– Policy choices– The collective action problem

The science of global climate change

• The mechanism of global climate change– Greenhouse gases affect temperature– GHGs include carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxides, CFCs etc– Some GHG’s (e.g. CO2, methane) are integral to the earth’s carbon cycle;

others (e.g. CFC) are human products

• The central views from scientists:– Temperatures are rising; GHG levels have a causal influence– Human influence is increasing GHG concentration– If GHG concentrations double, global temperatures will rise of the order of 2-4

degrees– There is still some controversy, but we’ll take the science as given for today

Note: CFCs are greenhouse gases, but the big issue around them was on effects on the ozone layer and so on skin cancer (etc). More on the (successful) Montreal Protocol below

Long-term increases in temperature

Climate models indicate these temperature increases are related to human action…

...due to a variety of sources of GHGs affected by human behavior

Predicted temperature effect of various levels of stabilization of GHGs by 2100…

..and significant variation in predicted effects even for same level of CO2 change…

…with a wide range of effects on water availability…

...and possibilities of severe effects and tipping points

Changes in stocks require large cuts in emissions, given long lives of GHGs

Rich countries account for most of the stock, but developing countries for much of the projected

growth in emissions

So future developing country emissions are part of the problem under these scenarios

The development and distribution issue

Carbon emissions given by:C = C/E x E/Y x Y/P x P

C/E = carbon emissions per unit of energyE/Y = energy use per unit of GDPY/P = GDP per capitaP = population growthIllustrative number: US E/Y is 50% more than for Europe, 100%

more than Japan; many times than for developing countries

Different proposals focus on different variables: C; E/Y or C/Y; C/P

The economics of climate change

• Emission creates a negative externality

Costs to everyone else

Net benefits to polluter

Who is the emitter? Depends on level of aggregation:(a) A firm, or(b) A country, if externalities are internalized within the border

Source: Nolan Miller lecture notes

So abatement is a public good

• Non-rivalrous• Non-excludable…and will be under

produced

Source: Nolan Miller lecture notes

Benefits of abatement to the world

Benefits of abatement to country x

Costs of abatement to country x

Uncertainty prevails; over…

• Size of temperature changes• Impacts on precipitation and sea-level effects• Probabilities of “large” adverse effects• Economic impacts on growth processes and so

benefits of action• Costs of adaptation—but little work on socially

contingent responses e.g. migration and conflict• Costs of mitigation/abatement

Irreversibilities matter..

• “Mega” irreversibilities may exist around climatic conditions, creating option value of preventing large climate change

• Economic irreversibilities matter, and these cut both ways– Changing the economic life of existing capital

stock – Changing to greener capital stock (if prove

unnecessary)

EvaluationHow to evaluate the benefits and

costs of climate change?

Economic issues(i) Valuation of benefits and costs (ii) Inter-temporal equity and the

discount rate(iii) Marginal utility of

consumption• Will future generations be

richer?• Who is hurt by climate

change?(iv) Uncertainty

Where W is social welfare, c is consumption and δ is the social rate of time preference

0

)( tt ecuW

The debate on discount rates

The discount rate (ρ) is a function of the social rate of time preference (δ) the rate of growth of consumption (g) and the elasticity of the marginal utility of consumption (η) [in a simplified account]

Stern review argues for a δ close to zero, and a low value of η (around 1), giving an overall discount rate close to 1.4%

Most economists argue for a higher discount rate, either with a higher δ or a higher η.

This has a huge impact on the benefit cost ratio and the implications for optimal action

g

Costs and benefits of action: large uncertainties and still significant debate

Nordhaus circa 2000: optimal policy is for modest tax; stabilization has negative benefit cost ratio

Now central estimates are shifting to a more favorable benefit cost ratiofor action: Nordhaus circa 2006 has increased estimate of global output cost of 2.5 degrees from 2 to 3% of GDP. This still implies a ramping upscenarioStern Report argues for very favorable benefit cost ratio for strong early actionSome of this comes from estimates of higher estimates of costs, and lowerestimates of benefits; most revolves around the choice of the discount rate

Policy issuesPolicy responses

Adaptation Mitigation

Choice of instruments

Effort distributionacross countries

The collective action problem

Distribution of adaptation costs

Finance/supportfor poor country

adaptation

A side payment

Largelynational

Intrinsically international

Instruments for mitigationType of instrument Advantage Disadvantage

Property rights/Coase Infeasible in international context

Carbon tax Optimal to guide efficient decisions

Uncertain effects

Hard to get cross-country consistency

Cap and trade Politicians and citizens understand caps

Trading can lead to efficient choices

Hard to get agreement on distribution of caps

Thin market; uncertain price

Regulation Clear and understandable

Can be highly inefficient

Subsidies to technological research

Good economics for a public good

Finance

Private sector will be central to research

Rich country bias on adaptation

Policy: taxation (i) taxing emission

Technical problems: (i) finding the Pigovian tax rate, (ii) finding a tax base stronglycorrelated with carbon emissions; in principle past estimates, trial and error can be usedAlso large political and coordination problems

Source: Nolan Miller lecture notes

Polluter now producersuntil marginal net benefitequals the tax rate

Policy: taxation (ii) subsidizing carbon sinks

• Deforestation is a source of increased emisions, so either reforestation or slowing deforestation has a positive externality, warranting a subsidy

• Concept underlying the Rainforest Initiative

Policy: cap and trade

• A cap is a quota, negotiated at country and then industry level

• But can lead to highly inefficient results, since marginal costs of meeting the quota highly unlikely to be equalized

• Creating a market for firms to buy and sell emission rights allows this marginal cost to be equalized (amongst participants)

Policy: regulationExample: the Governator

• Ambitious targets plus regulation for California

• California can be a standards-setter

• Is it credible?

The collective action problem: underlying structure of the game is PD; polluting is a dominant strategy

Player Y

Player X

Abate Pollute

Abate 2, 2 -1, 3

Pollute 3,-1 0, 0

Пa

Пp

0Number of other countries playing abate

Many countries: Payoffs to any country of playing abate (Пa) and pollute (Пb)

The collective action problemWhy the Montreal Protocol worked

• Benefit cost ratios in rich countries were highly favorable to action and supported unilateral action by US

• So US could lead, including in technological change

Payoffs to US (1985 $bln)

No controls

Montreal protocol

Unilateral action of Montreal

Benefits 0 3575 1373

Costs 0 21 21

Net benefits

0 3554 1352

So the US problem is transformed to this…

• Its dominant strategy is abate

• With incentives for US business to innovate, creating strategic complementarities with CFC-substitutes (via standards and reduced cost of abatement)

Пa

Пp

0Number of other countries playing abate

Payoffs to US of playing abate (Пa) and pollute (Пb)

Solving cooperation with Europe was relatively easy

• High benefits, low costs• Internal coordination (partially) solved in

Europe; citizen attitudes underpinned an “abate” domestic political equilibrium

• Two-thirds ratification for treaty to come in force (a 90% threshold would have increased leverage of Japan and USSR)

Trade sanctions were effective in changing the equilibrium on signing for resisting countries

Restrictions on trade in CFCs between signatories and non-signatories was part of the agreement.

There is a tipping point and the interaction becomes a coordination game

Пa

Пp

0

Payoffs to other countries of playing signatory (Пs) and non-signatory (Пn) with trade sanctions

Number of other signatories

And why climate change is a lot harder

• Benefit cost ratios are less favorable• Given higher costs concerns over competitiveness matter

– E.g. European carbon tax made conditional in 1992 on US and Japan adopting the same. They didn’t

– US concerns over developing country competition

Kyoto Protocol

• Cap and trade• Only sought to solve collective action across

rich countries, with negotiated “equitable” caps only for rich countries

• Incentives for mitigation investments in developing countries via inclusion in trading of carbon allowances

Cap and trade

• Business preferred cap and trade to carbon tax

• Business persuaded governments that carbon allowances be given, not auctioned

• Trading with developing countries is taking off, especially for green investments (abatement) in China—a form of side payment

The position of business

• Big concerns over cost effects and competitiveness. Latter is a function of the extent to which collective action problem is resolved

• Different views but most firms have “green” departments e.g. Dupont again

• Pressures from investors

Takeaways and outstanding issues• The Stern Review has done a huge service in bringing the economics of

global climate change to the center of the debate. Core public economics principles pervade the report. But there is still controversy over choices

• Evaluating the economic case for action– What discount rate(s) make sense?– How to value the (catastrophic) tail?– How to value net benefits to poorer groups?

• The domestic political equilibrium– How do citizens value inter-generational equity? – What is the dynamic between business and government policy?– What drives overall political payoffs to government?

• The global strategic interaction– Is there a self-enforcing equilibrium with US, Europe-Japan and China-India at

the core?– Are trade sanctions credible? Against the US? Against “the rest”?– Will rich countries want to use trading to subsidize Chinese industries?– Do aid givers have a contingent liability to hard-hit poor countries?

• How to analyze strategic interactions and feasible, as opposed socially optimal, outcomes is at the center of microeconomics II