+ All Categories
Home > Documents > thesis.eur.nl · Web viewMandatory audit partner rotation, actual audit quality and perceived audit...

thesis.eur.nl · Web viewMandatory audit partner rotation, actual audit quality and perceived audit...

Date post: 15-Jul-2018
Category:
Upload: duongdung
View: 216 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
261
Mandatory audit partner rotation, actual audit quality and perceived audit quality: Evidence from China Erasmus School of Economics Master: Accounting, Auditing & Control Master’s Thesis Accounting and
Transcript

Mandatory audit partner rotation, actual

audit quality and perceived audit quality:

Evidence from China

Erasmus School of Economics

Master: Accounting, Auditing & Control

Master’s Thesis Accounting and Auditing

Name: Cheng Liu

Student Number: 366954

Subject: Master’s Thesis Accounting and Auditing

Supervisor Erasmus University: Dr. C.D. Knoops

Co-reader Erasmus University: Drs. R. van der Wal RA

Date: 13 August 2014

Abstract

Mandatory audit partner rotation is required by many countries (for example

Australia, China, Taiwan, Germany, The Netherlands and the United States) based on

the assumption that mandatory audit partner rotation enhances actual and

perceived audit quality. This study investigates the association between mandatory

audit partner rotation and actual and perceived audit quality using the data from

China. I also investigate the association between audit firm tenure and actual and

perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner rotation. Most previous

studies investigate the effects of audit partner rotation through the length of audit

partner tenure. However, this study directly examines the effects of mandatory audit

partner rotation. I use performance-adjusted accruals as the proxy for actual audit

quality and Earnings Response Coefficients as the proxy for perceived audit quality. I

find that there is no significant relation between mandatory audit partner rotation

and actual and perceived audit quality. And there is no significant relation between

audit firm tenure and actual and perceived audit quality after controlling for audit

partner rotation. This suggests that mandatory audit partner rotation cannot

enhance actual and perceived audit quality as expected by regulators and requiring

mandatory audit partner rotation for audit profession might be unnecessary.

Moreover, there is no need to require mandatory audit firm rotation in addition to

audit partner rotation since long audit firm tenure does not deteriorate actual and

perceived audit quality.

Keywords: mandatory audit partner rotation, audit firm tenure, actual audit quality,

perceived audit quality.

1

Table of Contents

Abstract.............................................................................................................................................1Foreword and Acknowledgements:..................................................................................................4Chapter 1: Introduction....................................................................................................................6

1.1 Introduction to main theme................................................................................................61.2 Difference between actual audit quality and perceived audit quality................................71.3 Motivation...........................................................................................................................81.4 Research question.............................................................................................................111.5 Structure of the paper......................................................................................................121.6 Summary...........................................................................................................................12

Chapter 2: Background...................................................................................................................142.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................142.2 Institutional settings in the world.....................................................................................142.3 Institutional settings in China............................................................................................162.4 Summary...........................................................................................................................17

Chapter 3: Theoretical Concepts.....................................................................................................193.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................193.2 Difference between audit partner tenure and audit partner rotation..............................193.3 Audit quality and earnings quality....................................................................................203.4 Actual earnings quality and discretionary accruals...........................................................213.5 Actual audit quality and discretionary accruals................................................................223.6 Perceived earnings quality and earnings response coefficient.........................................223.7 Summary...........................................................................................................................23

Chapter 4: Literature Review..........................................................................................................244.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................244.2 Audit partner rotation/tenure and audit quality..............................................................24

4.2.1 Audit partner rotation/tenure and actual audit quality.........................................244.2.2 Audit partner rotation/tenure and perceived audit quality...................................28

4.3 Audit firm rotation/tenure and audit quality....................................................................304.3.1 Audit firm rotation/tenure and actual audit quality..............................................304.3.2 Audit firm rotation/tenure and perceived audit quality........................................32

4.4 Literature used for hypotheses.........................................................................................334.5 Summary...........................................................................................................................35

Chapter 5: Hypotheses...................................................................................................................365.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................365.2 Hypotheses development.................................................................................................36

5.2.1 Hypothesis for actual audit quality........................................................................365.2.2 Hypothesis for perceived audit quality..................................................................375.2.3 Additional hypothesis............................................................................................37

5.3 Summary...........................................................................................................................38Chapter 6: Research Design............................................................................................................39

2

6.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................396.2 Research method..............................................................................................................39

6.2.1 Measurement of audit partner rotation and audit firm tenure.............................396.2.2 Measurement of actual earnings quality...............................................................406.2.3 Measurement of perceived earnings quality.........................................................43

6.3 Regression model..............................................................................................................456.3.1 Regression model for actual earnings quality........................................................456.3.2 Regression model for perceived earnings quality..................................................46

6.4 Libby boxes........................................................................................................................486.4.1 Libby boxes for actual earnings quality..................................................................486.4.2 Libby box for perceived earnings quality...............................................................48

6.5 Sample selection and data................................................................................................496.6 Summary...........................................................................................................................50

Chapter 7: Results...........................................................................................................................517.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................517.2 Descriptive statistics..........................................................................................................51

7.2.1 Descriptive statistics for actual audit quality.........................................................517.2.2 Descriptive statistics for perceived audit quality...................................................53

7.3 Empirical findings based on performance-adjusted abnormal accruals...........................557.4 Empirical findings based on earnings response coefficients.............................................597.5 Summary...........................................................................................................................63

Chapter 8: Analysis.........................................................................................................................648.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................648.2 The effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on actual audit quality.........................648.3 The effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on perceived audit quality...................678.4 The effects of audit firm tenure on actual and perceived audit quality............................698.5 Summary...........................................................................................................................71

Chapter 9: Conclusion.....................................................................................................................729.1 Introduction......................................................................................................................729.2 Main conclusions and implications of findings.................................................................729.3 Limitations and recommendations for future research....................................................739.4 Summary...........................................................................................................................74

Bibliography....................................................................................................................................75Appendix.........................................................................................................................................81

3

Foreword and Acknowledgements:

This thesis is written in order to complete the Master Accounting and Auditing, at

Erasmus University Rotterdam. And this thesis is partly based on my course paper for

Seminar Financial Accounting Research. I have chosen the topic of audit partner

rotation, which falls within the scope of auditing theory. The main reason for

choosing this topic is that there are many debates about whether mandatory audit

partner rotation is able to enhance auditor independence and audit quality. Previous

studies have no consistent conclusion for the association between mandatory audit

partner rotation and audit quality. Besides, the data for audit partner rotation is not

publicly available in most of the countries. However, in China, audit partners are

required to sign the audit reports. Therefore, I contribute to the debate by providing

the empirical evidence using the data from China.

Since May of this year, I have been conducting research on this topic. I have

experienced an intensive, but interesting time when writing my master’s thesis. At

the beginning, I had little knowledge about the data collection and statistical tests.

But I learned a lot afterwards. In addition, the Chinese database only shows the

names of audit partner and audit firm for each audit report. The data for audit

partner rotation and audit firm tenure are not directly available in the database.

Therefore, I have to hand collect the data for audit partner rotation and audit firm

tenure based on those names. I am satisfied with all the results I have achieved.

However, I didn’t write my master’s thesis completely by my own. I would not finish

my master’s thesis without several people’s help. I would like to thank my thesis

supervisor from the University, Dr C.D. Knoops. He always gave me directions when I

have doubts for my research design. He provided me guidance for the structure of

my thesis. Besides, he gave me many valuable comments, which helped me a lot to

keep a critical mind. After several discussions with Dr C.D. Knoops, I have a better

understanding for the theoretical concepts part in my master’s thesis.

4

Lastly, I would like to thank my mom and friends for their supports during the period

of writing my master’s thesis. My mom helped me a lot in hand collecting the data of

audit partner rotation and audit firm tenure. My friends taught me a lot for statistics.

I would like to thank all the people who have supported me in this period.

Rotterdam, August 2014

5

Chapter 1: Introduction

1.1 Introduction to main theme

Recently, a great number of financial scandals throughout the world (Enron,

WorldCom, Xerox and Sunbeam) have drawn public attention on audit quality.

Auditor independence is a determining factor of audit quality. Therefore, investors

start to doubt the auditor independence as the auditors fail to inform them the

threats of financial scandals in time.

Previous studies (Benston & Hartgraves, 2002; Lyke & Jickling, 2002; Seipp, Kinsella,

& Lindberg, 2011) find that the common characteristic of companies involved in

financial scandals is that the companies all maintain a very long relationship with the

same audit firms. Enron has been audited by Arthur Andersen since the company

was founded in 1985 (Benston & Hartgraves, 2002). Moreover, Arthur Andersen has

audited WorldCom since the company was founded in 1989 (Lyke & Jickling, 2002).

Until the end of 2002, KPMG has maintained the relationship with Xerox for 40 years

(Seipp et al., 2011). Many studies (Dies & Giroux, 1992; Beck, Frecka, & Solomon,

1988) have suggested that excessive length of auditor-client tenure may damage

auditor independence and audit quality. Auditor independence is believed to be one

of the cornerstones of the audit profession. The development of the audit profession

has to face a big challenge nowadays as auditor’s “societal usefulness” becomes in

question. Later in 2002, Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) is issued aimed to maintain auditor

independence and restore the confidence of investors. In Section 203 of SOX, the

requirement of mandatory audit partner rotation is restricted from every 7 years to

every 5 years for all American public company audits. Regulators in USA stated that

mandatory audit partner rotation may avoid the “too familiarity” between auditors

and clients, thereby enhancing auditor independence and audit quality (General

Accounting Office [GAO], 2003). However, the relation between audit partner

rotation and audit quality has not been widely investigated by previous studies due

6

to the lack of information on audit partners in the United States.

After the issuance of SOX in 2002, the Chinese Institute of Certified Public

Accountants (CICPA) issues the Code of Ethics for Chinese Certified Public

Accountants in the same year. In this Code of Ethics, for the first time, the concept of

mandatory partner rotation is introduced in China by CICPA to maintain auditor

independence. Since 2003, China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) officially

requires mandatory audit partner rotation for every 5 years for all the listed

companies in China, which is consistent with the requirement in the United States.

However, unlike in the United States, audit reports in China are required to be signed

by two audit partners. Since the information on audit partners is publicly available in

China, it enables us to identify companies that are subject to mandatory audit

partner rotation and companies that are not subject to partner rotation. In China,

mandatory audit partner rotation takes effect since 2003. Thus, mandatory partner

rotation can be observed in the 2003 annual audit reports for the first time in China.

By focusing on the mandatory partner rotation in 2003, this study will investigate

whether mandatory audit partner rotation enhances audit quality as expected by

regulators using data from China.

In addition, the economy in China is growing rapidly nowadays. Therefore the

international investors are now paying more and more attention on Chinese stock

market. My research results will have important implications on Chinese regulators,

auditors, audit quality and users of financial reports.

1.2 Difference between actual audit quality and perceived audit

quality

Investors are willing to rely on auditor’s opinion because they expect an unbiased

viewpoint from auditors. Several studies (Sinnett, 2004; Moore, Tetlock, Tanlu, &

Bazerman, 2006; Raiborn, Schorg, & Massoud, 2006) argue that the potentially

impaired auditor independence due to long auditor-client relationship is the major

threat in audit quality. However, the American Institute of Certified Public

7

Accountants (AICPA) Code of Professional Conduct and the International Ethics

Standards Board for Accountants (IESBA) Code of Ethics for Professional Conduct

define two types of independence: independence of mind and independence in

appearance. “Independence of mind reflects the auditor’s state of mind that permits

the audit to be performed with an unbiased attitude. Independence in appearance is

the result of others’ interpretations of this independence (Arens, Elder, & Beasley,

2014)”. Therefore, audit quality can also be viewed from two perspectives: actual

audit quality and perceived audit quality (Taylor, 2005). Actual audit quality is

affected by independence of mind, while perceived audit quality is affected by

independence in appearance. Actual audit quality is the extent to which auditors fail

to discover and disclose a breach in the client’s financial reports. Perceived audit

quality is the extent to which investors believe there is no material mistakes in the

client’s audited financial reports.

The Commission on Public Trust and Private Enterprise (2003) outlines in its report

that mandatory audit partner rotation not only enhances auditor independence, but

also restores investor’s confidence in the capital market. Only when investors have

more confidence in auditor’s work, the perceived audit quality could be high. Elliott

(2000), a former chairman of the AICPA, highlights the importance of independence

in appearance. AICPA believes the smooth operation of capital markets is based on

the investor’s confidence in audited financial reports. And the confidence of investors

is heavily determined by auditor independence in appearance. Thus, it is necessary

for this study to evaluate audit quality from both actual and perceived viewpoints.

1.3 Motivation

DeAngelo (1981) defines audit quality from two perspectives. First, auditors should

have enough competence to discover a breach in annual reports of clients. Second,

auditors should be an independent third party and therefore willing to disclose the

breach they have found earlier to the public. Long auditor-client relationship is

believed to be a threat to both auditor independence and auditor competence. To

solve this problem, many countries, for example the United States, the United

8

Kingdom, the Netherlands, Brazil and China, have proposed mandatory auditor

rotation at the partner level or firm level. The purpose of mandatory audit

partner/firm rotation is to limit the allowed audit partner/firm tenure and thereby

enhance audit quality from both independence and competence perspectives.

Mandatory auditor rotation could be at the partner level or the firm level. But the

rationales behind the cost-benefit analysis about mandatory rotation are the same.

Therefore, I will explain the arguments for and against mandatory auditor rotation

together, which means both audit partner rotation and audit firm rotation.

James R. Doty, the Chairman of the five-member Public Company Accounting

Oversight Board (PCAOB), highlights the benefits of mandatory auditor rotation – a

means of enhancing auditor independence, objectivity and professional skepticism

(Bates, Waldrup, Jaeger, & Shea, 2012). This shows us again that one of the major

concerns driving mandatory auditor rotation is the notion that an excessive long and

too close auditor-client relationship negatively affects the independence and

objectivity of auditors. If auditors get too familiar with their clients, audit partners

will feel they are on the same side with clients and audit firms will turn to be a

business partner or subsidiary of their clients (Herrick & Barrionuevo, 2002). Then,

audit partners or audit firms will have difficulty acting as an isolated independent

examiner. Implementing mandatory auditor rotation could enhance auditor

independence by avoiding this too familiar relationship. Besides, mandatory auditor

rotation could also provide a “fresh viewpoint” by new auditors (Cadbury Committee,

1992). Auditors always treat the same clients with the same way of analysis every

year. If auditors have served the same clients for a long time, it will be difficult for

them to discover any new problem as auditors simply repeat their analysis in the old

way. However, new auditors with caution will invest more time and efforts to analyze

clients’ reports in a more thorough way. This “fresh viewpoint” by new auditors could

enhance auditor’s competence to find the potential breach in the client’s audit

reports.

On the contrary, many studies (Geiger & Raghunandan, 2002; Carcello & Nagy, 2004;

9

Daugherty, Dickens, & Higgs, 2010) argue that mandatory auditor rotation initiates

costs from unexperienced audit successor as well. First, new auditors lack of client

specific knowledge and therefore are more likely to result in audit failure. Geiger and

Raghunandan (2002) find a higher rate of Type 2 error (auditors fail to detect

companies that are unable to continue as a going concern) for auditors who are in

the early phase of auditor tenure. More specifically, those new auditors fail to issue a

qualified going concern opinion immediately before the client firms are filed for

bankruptcy. The results by Geiger and Raghunandan (2002) show that new auditors

tend to make unintentional mistakes due to lack of experience. Second, mandatory

auditor rotation costs new auditors more time and efforts to understand the

background information and operation process of client companies. Client specific

knowledge is a crucial element for new auditors to detect material mistakes in

financial reports. And there exists a learning curve for new auditors to gain this

knowledge (Knapp, 1991). Besides, more audit hours mean more audit fees paid by

client companies. Johnson (2012) reports that: “in 2003, it was estimated that a

change in auditors can add 20 percent to the initial cost of an audit”. In sum, on the

one hand, client companies have to suffer more audit fees from mandatory auditor

rotation. On the other hand, investors need to bear the risk of potentially deceased

auditor competence due to lack of client specific knowledge.

The adoption of mandatory audit partner/firm rotation by many countries suggests

that the regulators believe the benefits outweigh the costs of mandatory rotation.

But not all politicians agree on that. In the United States, Representative Michael

Fitzpatrick introduced a legislation in 2012 that would prohibit the implementing of

mandatory audit partner rotation or mandatory audit firm rotation (Bates et al.,

2012).

Besides regulators, previous researches (Dopuch, King, & Schwartz, 2001; Gietzmann

& Sen, 2002; Carey & Simnett, 2006) have no consistent conclusion about the cost-

benefit efficiency of mandatory auditor rotation as well. Through a between-subjects

experiment with auditors, Dopuch et al. (2001) find that auditors are less likely to

10

issue a biased audit report with the imposition of mandatory auditor rotation.

Dopuch et al. (2001) argue that without the pressure from legal requirements,

auditors feel free to cooperate with client management in order to maintain a good

business relationship and gain economic benefits. This leads to a win-win situation

for both clients and auditors in the short term. Gietzmann and Sen (2002) find that

mandatory auditor rotation has a positive net benefit in certain situations where few

large client companies are available in the market. When certain client companies

contribute a large element of auditor’s income, auditors will have stronger incentives

to cooperate with client management in such a thin market.

However, several empirical studies (Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen, Lin, & Lin, 2008;

Myers, Myers, & Omer, 2008; Chi, Huang, Liao, & Xie, 2009) find the opposite

conclusion. Carey and Simnett (2006) and Chen et al. (2008) find no significant

association between audit partner tenure and audit quality measured by accruals.

Myers et al. (2003) find longer audit firm tenure significantly increases audit quality.

Chi et al. (2009) directly examine the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation

instead of audit partner tenure and they find both the actual and perceived audit

quality are not significantly increased by mandatory rotation.

Many regulation setters (Bates et al., 2012) and researches (Carey & Simnett, 2006;

Chen et al., 2008; Myers et al., 2008; Chi et al., 2009) doubt the cost-benefit

efficiency of mandatory auditor rotation. The relation between auditor rotation and

audit quality is still not clear. Mandatory audit partner rotation has been widely

accepted by many countries already, while mandatory audit firm rotation in addition

to partner rotation is still being discussed in most places. In China, only mandatory

audit partner rotation is required for all listed companies. Therefore, in this study, I

will focus on the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation. I investigate whether

the belief is true that mandatory audit partner rotation will enhance actual or

perceived audit quality and whether audit firm tenure will still have effects on audit

quality after controlling for audit partner rotation.

11

1.4 Research question

Based on the discussion above, my research question is as follows:

What is the association between mandatory audit partner rotation and audit

quality?

To investigate the research question further, two sub research questions are designed

as follows:

1. What is the association between mandatory audit partner rotation and actual

audit quality?

2. What is the association between mandatory audit partner rotation and perceived

audit quality?

The additional research question is as follows:

1. What is the association between audit firm tenure and actual audit quality after

controlling for audit partner rotation?

2. What is the association between audit firm tenure and perceived audit quality

after controlling for audit partner rotation?

1.5 Structure of the paper

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The next chapter introduces the

institutional background of mandatory audit partner rotation and audit firm rotation.

Chapter 3 explains several important concepts that will be used in this study. Chapter

4 reviews previous literature related to my research question. Chapter 5 develops the

hypotheses based on my expectation on research question. Chapter 6 describes the

research design and sample selection, which are used to test the hypotheses.

Chapter 7 presents the main empirical results from the regression model in Chapter

6. Chapter 8 answers the research question based on the empirical results. Chapter 9

summarizes the main findings, discusses the research limitations, and recommends

for future studies.

1.6 Summary

Mandatory audit partner rotation has been adopted by many countries, while

12

mandatory audit firm rotation is still being discussed in many places. Mandatory

audit partner rotation is believed as a means to enhance auditor independence and

audit quality. However, the cost-benefit efficiency of mandatory audit partner

rotation is doubted by many previous literatures. It is still an empirical question of

whether mandatory rotation is positively associated with audit quality. Both actual

and perceived audit quality are important. If auditors are independent in fact but

investors don’t believe it, most of the value of the audit function is lost. In this study,

I investigate the relation between mandatory audit partner rotation and audit quality

and examine audit quality from both actual and perceived perspectives. The

association between audit firm tenure and audit quality will be examined as well.

13

Chapter 2: Background

2.1 Introduction

In this chapter, background information and institutional settings about mandatory

auditor rotation will be provided. Auditor rotation could be audit partner rotation or

audit firm rotation. Audit partner rotation requires the audit partners to be rotated

after certain years, while audit firm rotation requires rotation in the firm level. This

chapter will elaborate on the regulation and discussion for both partner rotation and

firm rotation. I will first describe the emergence and development of mandatory

audit partner/firm rotation across the world. Then I will elaborate the mandatory

audit partner/firm rotation in China since the statistical test is based on the Chinese

database in this study.

2.2 Institutional settings in the world

Many countries in the world have implemented mandatory audit partner rotation for

the listed companies to enhance auditor independence. In the United States,

mandatory audit partner rotation has been required by the American Institute of

Certified Public Accountants (AICPA) since 1970s. For all companies registered at

Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the audit partners in charge should be

rotated in every 7 years. In 2002, mandatory audit partner rotation is emphasized

again by SOX, and the allowed audit partner tenure is restricted from 7 years to 5

years in the United States. Although mandatory auditor rotation in the United States

is required at the partner level instead of firm level, audit reports of listed companies

are not required to be signed with the name of audit partner. In the United States,

only the name of audit firm is available in the audit reports. This explains why most

studies (Geiger & Raghunandan, 2002; Johnson, Khurana, & Reynolds, 2002; Myers

et al., 2003) based on American database only investigate the effects of audit firm

rotation/tenure on audit quality, instead of audit partner rotation/tenure.

In Australia, legal requirement for audit partner rotation takes effect since 2001. In

14

2001, the Australian profession’s independence standard mandates audit partner

rotation for every 7 years. After that, the predetermined partner tenure is then

reduced to 5 years in 2004 in Australia. Regulations in Taiwan require mandatory

audit partner rotation for every 5 years since 2003. Before 2003, no legal or

professional audit partner rotation is required in Taiwan. In both Australia and

Taiwan, the audit partner’s name should be disclosed in the audit reports, together

with the name of audit firms (Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen et al., 2008). Similar with

the United States, the partner rotation period has been reduced from 7 years to 5

years in United Kingdom as well. In 2003, the Department of Trade and Industry and

the UK Treasury recommend the tenure of audit partner should be limited within 5

years. Internationally, mandatory audit partner rotation has also been adopted in

Singapore, Japan, France, the Netherlands and Germany.

Regulators from different countries have different opinions about the various forms

of auditor rotation. Some countries (for example United States, United Kingdom,

Australia, Taiwan and the Netherlands) require mandatory audit partner rotation,

while some (for example Brazil, Italy, India and South Korea) choose to require

mandatory rotation at the firm level.

In the United States, the Congress considered audit firm rotation before, but they

choose to mandate audit partner rotation in SOX in the end. Mandatory audit firm

rotation was given up at that time because the Congress believe more time is needed

to analyze the costs and benefits of mandatory audit firm rotation before it is

included into the legislation (Bates et al., 2012). Recently, Arthur Levitt, former SEC

head, emphasizes the benefits of audit firm rotation by suggesting in a recent Wall

Street Journal interview that audit firm should be rotated in every ten years (Chasan,

2011). Besides, the European Commission (2010) underlines mandatory audit firm

rotation and states that “the mandatory rotation of audit firms, not just of audit

partners, should be considered…with a view to instilling and maintaining objectivity

and dynamism in the audit market.” Although audit firm rotation is not required,

many regulators are still considering it. More researches and discussions are needed

15

on audit firm rotation or audit firm tenure. Therefore, the impact of audit firm tenure

will be examined in this study as well.

2.3 Institutional settings in China

In China, the audit profession is regulated by both the Chinese Securities Regulatory

Commission (CSRC) and the Ministry of Finance (MOF). Inspired by SOX, the Chinese

Institute of Certified Public Accountants (CICPA), in the Code of Ethics for Chinese

Certified Public Accountant in 2002, suggests audit partner rotation aimed to

maintain auditor independence. This is the first time when audit partner rotation is

introduced in China. However, the Code of Ethics has no legal effects and audit

partner rotation is not required as a mandatory rule in 2002. After that, CSRC and

MOF jointly adopted a set of rules in October of 2003 and officially require

mandatory audit partner rotation for Chinese listed companies. In China, audit

partners responsible for listed company audits should be rotated at least every five

years. Besides, the policy issued by CSRC and MOF requires that “signing auditors

must not provide audit services for the same initial public offering (IPO) entity for

more than two consecutive years after the IPO (Firth, Rui, & Wu, 2010)”. These rules

became fully effective since the end of 2003 for all annual audit reports of Chinese

listed companies. Before 2003, audit partner rotation in China was entirely voluntary.

Thus, 2003 year-end audit reports are where the information about mandatory audit

partner rotation can be identified for the first time in China. I will investigate the

effects of mandatory audit partner rotation in China based on 2003 annual audit

reports.

Unlike in the United States, audit reports in China are required to be signed by two

certified public accountants. One of the two signing audit partners is responsible for

the related audit work as a leader. The other audit partner is responsible for

reviewing the audit work that the lead audit partner has done. The engagement

audit partner has stronger effects on audit quality than the reviewing audit partner.

Unfortunately, I cannot distinguish these two audit partners from China Stock Market

and Accounting Research (CSMAR) Database as two names are shown equally in the

16

database. However, both of the two audit partners undertake the same legal

liabilities according to the policy issued by CSRC and MOF.

In China, there are some companies funded by the Chinese government. They are

called State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs). SOEs usually have a more powerful position

than auditors in their auditor-client relationship. Auditor independence is more likely

to be impaired due to the threat of being dismissed by issuing qualified audit

opinions to SOEs (Ye, Xu, & Han, 2013). Thus, the State-owned Assets Supervision

and Administration Commission of the State Council (SASAC) of China established

more strict rules for SOEs. In 2005, mandatory audit firm rotation in addition to

mandatory audit partner rotation is required by SASAC for all SOEs under its

jurisdiction. Since 2005, SOEs must rotate both audit partners and audit firms after

the service of 5 consecutive years. For other listed companies except SOEs, only

mandatory audit partner rotation is required in every five years.

According to the official comments by CSRC, Chinese regulators believe auditor’s

incompetence is not the major reason for corporate scandals. The excessive long

auditor-client relationship is the major threat to auditor independence and audit

quality. Mandatory audit partner rotation can not only enhance auditor

independence by restricting the length of audit partner tenure, but also provide a

fresh perspective by new auditors to discover new problems (Firth et al., 2010). CSRC

has considered audit firm rotation as well. However, the regulators think audit firm

rotation will increase the probability of audit failure due to the lack of client specific

knowledge by new auditors (Firth et al., 2010). And the benefit, if there is any, of

mandatory audit firm rotation is still not clear.

2.4 Summary

Internationally, audit partner rotation has been implemented in many countries, for

example in the United States, the United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Australia,

Taiwan and Germany. Audit firm rotation in addition to audit partner rotation is

called for more discussion in both the United States and Europe. In Australia and

Taiwan, information on audit partner rotation or tenure is publicly available, while

17

most other countries do not require disclosure of audit partner’s name in the audit

reports. So far, mandatory audit firm rotation is only required for SOEs in China. For

ordinary Chinese listed companies, only mandatory audit partner rotation is

required. Similar to Australia and Taiwan, Chinese audit partners are also required to

sign in the audit reports. Thus, this study will mainly focus on the effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation on both actual and perceived audit quality based

on data from China.

18

Chapter 3: Theoretical Concepts

3.1 Introduction

In this chapter, theoretical constructs are firstly explained before the literature

review in the following chapter. Discretionary accruals and earnings response

coefficient are widely accepted by previous studies (Myers et al., 2003; Chi & Huang,

2005; Chen & Xia, 2006; Ghosh & Moon, 2005) as the measures for actual audit

quality and perceived audit quality respectively. But it is not clear to what extent

those proxies can capture the concept of audit quality. Thus, the rationales behind

those measurements are explained in this chapter.

3.2 Difference between audit partner tenure and audit partner

rotation

Some studies (Chi & Huang, 2005; Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen et al., 2008) examine

the effects of audit partner tenure on audit quality, while some studies (Chi et al.,

2009; Firth et al., 2010) directly examine the effects of mandatory audit partner

rotation on audit quality.

In fact, audit partner tenure and audit partner rotation are two closely related

concepts. If audit partners have maintained a very long relationship with the same

clients, audit partners are more likely to ignore the problems in their client’s financial

statements because of “too familiarity”. Or audit partners are more reluctant to issue

a qualified audit opinion to an “old friend”. This implies that the audit quality might

be impaired by long audit partner tenure. To solve this potential problem, mandatory

audit partner rotation is required in certain years. Therefore, the purpose of

mandatory audit partner rotation is to enhance the audit quality by limiting the audit

partner tenure within a short term. In sum, audit partner tenure is a time period,

while audit partner rotation is an action to limit the length of this period. Mandatory

audit partner rotation is based on the assumption that long audit partner tenure

19

deteriorates audit quality. Both of them can be used to investigate the relation with

audit quality.

3.3 Audit quality and earnings quality

Earnings quality is used as a proxy for audit quality in this study. Traditionally, high

audit quality means completely compliance with Generally Accepted Auditing

Standards (GAAS). In this study, audit quality is measured by the outcome of

auditor’s work – audited financial statements. Based on the agency theory, client

management is not the owner of the company, but they have superior information

about the company’s performance than the owners. Because of this information

asymmetry, auditors are needed to examine the quality of financial statements as an

independent third party. Therefore, client management and auditors have a joint

responsibility for the quality of financial statements (Antle & Nalebuff, 1991).

Managers of client companies are responsible for the ultimate quality of reported

financial statements. Auditor’s work is to assure the true and fair representation of

client company’s operating performance in the financial statements. Earnings are

stated by managers as the most important financial measure reported to outsiders

(Graham, Harvey, & Rajgopal, 2005). When the quality of financial statements is poor,

earnings reported in the financial statements might be artificially managed upward

or downward to meet (beat) the targets or conserve for the future targets.

In sum, the quality of financial statements can be determined by audit quality since

client management and auditors have a joint responsibility for the quality of financial

statements (Antle & Nalebuff, 1991). At the same time, earnings quality can be

determined by the quality of financial statements since earnings are stated by

managers as the most important financial measure reported to outsiders (Graham et

al., 2005). Therefore, earnings quality can be used as a proxy for audit quality.

However, there is limitation in this study as I use proxy for proxy in the research

design. The internal validity of this study is largely dependent on the ability of

earnings quality to capture the concept of financial statement quality and the ability

of financial statement quality to capture the concept of audit quality. For example,

20

earnings restatement could also be a proxy for audit quality. However, this will result

in a very small sample size in my study considering the limited sample size of

companies that are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation in year 2003. I will

explain more on the research limitations in Chapter 9.

3.4 Actual earnings quality and discretionary accruals

Actual earnings quality is a measure for actual audit quality. And discretionary

accruals are a measure of actual earnings quality in this study. There are two ways to

present the operational performance of a company in accounting: cash based

accounting versus accrual based accounting. Under cash based accounting,

companies record the revenues or costs when cash is received or paid. Cash flow is

deemed to be a more reliable line item to reflect business performance of client

companies. But cash flow has significant timing and matching problems. Accruals-

based accounting can perfectly solve these two problems and thereby is widely

adopted by both Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) and International

Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS). Accruals based accounting records the revenues

and costs when the transaction occurs. Sometimes, managers’ prediction about

future cash flows is needed to estimate accruals. This flexibility provides the ability

for client management to communicate inside information to outsiders, but also

gives them opportunity to manipulate earnings in order to achieve some specific

objectives. Richardson, Tuna and Wu (2002) find that companies with large amount

of accruals are more likely to restate their reported earnings in the financial

statements. Earnings are the sum of accruals and cash flows. Accruals are the sum of

discretionary accruals and non-discretionary accruals. The part of earnings that is

manipulated by client management through accruals to achieve any specific

objective is called discretionary accruals. Client management has more flexibility in

overstating or understating earnings through accruals. Thus, higher level of

discretionary accruals indicates lower level of earnings quality or audit quality.

There are several forms of earnings management: accruals earnings management

and real earnings management. I recognize that both real activities manipulation and

21

accruals manipulation could affect the earnings management. Real activities

manipulation, for example cutting R&D expense and advertising expense, will

negatively affect the client firms’ long-term profits. But this will not affect the quality

of auditors’ work. Auditors only care about the true and fair disclosure of client

company’s performance. Thus it is sufficient for this study to only focus on the

accruals manipulation part.

3.5 Actual audit quality and discretionary accruals

According to section 3.3, actual earnings quality is a proxy for actual audit quality.

Section 3.4 introduces that discretionary accruals are used to measure actual

earnings quality. Thus, discretionary accruals can be used as a proxy for actual audit

quality. Several studies (Geiger & Raghunandan, 2002; Bartov, Gul, & Tsui, 2000) have

examined the association between discretionary accruals and audit quality. Geiger

and Raghunandan (2002) find that higher level of accruals is an indicator for audit

failure. Bartov et al. (2000) find that auditors issue a qualified audit opinion when

accruals level is high. Thus, a higher level of discretionary accruals implies a lower

level of actual audit quality. Besides, performance-adjusted accruals based on the

model by Kothari, Leone and Wasley (2005) has been widely accepted by many

studies (Myers et al., 2003; Chen et al., 2008; Chi et al., 2009) as the proxy for actual

earnings quality or actual audit quality.

3.6 Perceived earnings quality and earnings response coefficient

Perceived earnings quality can reflect perceived audit quality. Earnings Response

Coefficient (ERC) is used by many studies (Ghosh & Moon, 2005; Chi et al., 2009) to

measure perceived earnings quality. ERC is measured by Scott (2012) as follows:

“An earnings response coefficient measures the extent of a security’s abnormal

market return in response to the unexpected component of reported earnings of the

firm issuing that security.”

ERC measures the extent to which investors react to the earnings information.

Investors only react to the information when they perceive the information is

22

credible. Higher perceived earnings quality or audit quality facilitates investors to

invest more in specific client companies as the investors trust the credibility of

earnings information. Previous studies (Schipper & Vincent, 2003; Teoh & Wong,

1993) find that investors are willing to pay a premium for client companies with high-

quality earnings because the earnings are more persistent in the future. Thus, the

effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on perceived earnings quality can be

examined through the price of earnings that investors are willing to pay, which is ERC.

3.7 Summary

Audited financial statement is a joint outcome of both client management and

auditors. The quality of reported earnings in the audited financial statement is

therefore able to reflect audit quality. Audit quality can be divided into actual audit

quality and perceived audit quality. Actual earnings quality reflects actual audit

quality, while perceived earnings quality reflects perceived audit quality. Manages

are more likely to manipulate earnings to achieve any specific objectives through

accruals. Thus, the level of discretionary accruals can be a proxy for actual earnings

quality. ERC reflect the investor’s reaction to earnings information and therefore can

be used to measure the investor’s perception about earnings quality.

23

Chapter 4: Literature Review

4.1 Introduction

In this chapter, previous studies about mandatory audit partner or firm rotation are

introduced. The effectiveness of mandatory rotation is sometimes investigated

through partner tenure or firm tenure. The regulation of mandatory audit

partner/firm rotation is proposed based on the common cognition that excessive

long audit partner/firm tenure deteriorates audit quality as auditor independence is

undermined. In addition, audit quality affected by mandatory audit partner/firm

rotation is examined from two aspects: actual audit quality and perceived audit

quality. Thus, I am going to summarize the previous findings through 4 aspects: audit

partner rotation/tenure and actual audit quality; audit partner rotation/tenure and

perceived audit quality; audit firm rotation/tenure and actual audit quality; audit

firm rotation/tenure and perceived audit quality. A list of previous studies discussed

in this chapter will be provided later in Table 1 and Table 2 under Appendix.

4.2 Audit partner rotation/tenure and audit quality

Although most of the countries around the world require mandatory partner rotation

instead of mandatory firm rotation, few studies have directly investigated the

relation between audit partner tenure and audit quality. Chen et al. (2008)

mentioned that this might be caused by lack of data on audit partner tenure. Many

countries do not require disclosing the audit partner’s name when issuing an audit

report. Thus, the data on audit partner tenure is not publicly available for academic

research in most of the countries. The previous literatures about audit partner

rotation/ tenure discussed below are all listed in Table 1 under Appendix.

4.2.1 Audit partner rotation/tenure and actual audit quality

Chen et al. (2008) examine the relation between audit partner tenure and earnings

quality based on a sample from 1990 to 2001, which is selected from a Taiwanese

24

database. In Taiwan, all the audit reports for the listed companies need to be signed

by two audit partners from the same audit firm. Therefore, the audit partner’s name

can be accessed through the audit reports. This special regulation enables them to

count the audit partner tenure by hand. Chen et al. (2008) use performance-adjusted

discretionary accruals based on the model by Kothari et al. (2005) as the proxy for

earnings quality in their research. However, several proxies are used to measure the

audit partner tenure. Since there are two names in each audit report every year, it is

almost impossible to know which of the two has greater influence on maintaining

auditor-client relationship. In the primary analysis, the tenure of the partner with the

longest tenure is used based on the assumption that the longest-tenure partner is

more likely to determine the relationship with clients. When absolute or positive

values of discretionary accruals are used as dependent variables, the results show

that earnings quality increases significantly with longer audit partner tenure. When

raw or negative values of discretionary accruals are used, no significant results are

found in the test. Besides, Chen et al. (2008) also examine whether this relation is

conditional on the length of audit partner tenure. Since many countries, for example

Taiwan, China, United States and United Kingdom, require mandatory audit partner

rotation for every five years, the relation between partner tenure and earnings

quality might be different when the partner tenure is less than or in excess of 5 years.

However, the results show that the absolute values of discretionary accruals

decrease significantly both before and after the tenure exceeds 5 years. And long

partner tenure (PT > 10) doesn’t indicate higher discretionary accruals, neither. Thus,

there is no evidence which supports the argument that longer audit partner tenure

deteriorates audit quality based on Taiwanese market.

Contrary to the findings by Chen et al. (2008), Chi and Huang (2005) find that

earnings quality first increase with longer audit partner tenure and then decreases

after a turning point. This turning point is around 5 years of partner tenure. Chi and

Huang (2005) investigate the relation between audit partner tenure and the level of

discretionary accruals through a non-linear regression model, which is based on the

25

sample from 1990 to 2001 of a Taiwanese database. Chi and Huang (2005) measure

the discretionary accruals based on the model proposed by Dechow, Richardson and

Tuna (2003). And the sample size used in Chi and Huang (2005) is smaller than that in

Chen et al. (2008).

Later on, Chi et al. (2009) investigate the relation between mandatory audit partner

rotation and audit quality using Taiwanese database again. Different with Chi and

Huang (2005) and Chen et al. (2008), Chi et al. (2009) directly investigate the effects

of mandatory audit partner rotation instead of audit partner tenure. They only focus

on the data in year 2004, when the Taiwanese government requires mandatory

partner rotation for the first time. Chi et al. (2009) first identify a group of companies

whose audit partners were rotated in 2004 due to the requirements of mandatory

audit partner rotation. This group is called mandatory rotation sample (MROTA).

Then, MROTA is compared with three other benchmark groups: 1) non-mandatory

rotation sample (NROTA): all the other companies except MROTA; 2) mandatory

rotation sample itself in the prior year (MBEFR): same companies with MROTA, but in

different year; 3) voluntary rotation (VROTA): companies whose audit partners were

rotated before 2003 voluntarily. Similar with Chen et al. (2008), Chi et al. (2009) also

use both absolute and signed values of discretionary accruals based on the model by

Kothari et al. (2005) as the proxies for audit quality. When compared to MBEFR, they

find the level of performance-adjusted abnormal accruals is higher in MROTA.

Nevertheless, the level of abnormal accruals in MROTA is not significantly different

from that in NROTA or VROTA. Thus, there is no evidence that supports that

implementation of mandatory audit partner rotation enhances the earnings quality

or audit quality. And the earnings quality of companies in the mandatory rotation

sample group is even impaired compared to the prior year, which is consistent with

the main finding in Chen et al. (2008) that earnings quality increases with longer

audit partner tenure.

Similar to Taiwan, audit reports are also required to be signed with both the name of

audit partner and the name of audit firm in Australia. Carey and Simnett (2006)

26

investigate the relation between audit partner tenure and audit quality by focusing

on the data of year 1995 in Australia. The policy for mandatory audit partner rotation

takes into effect from year 2001 in Australia. But, the Big 6 firms in Australia start

discussing and voluntarily implementing audit partner rotation since year 1997. Thus,

1995 is the most recent year when there is enough data for long audit partner

tenure. Carey and Simnett (2006) define long audit partner tenure as the tenure

which is more than 7 years and define short audit partner tenure as the tenure which

is up to 2 years. And they use 3 proxies to measure audit quality: 1) the auditor’s

propensity to issue a going-concern opinion; 2) absolute and signed values of

abnormal working capital accruals; 3) the extent of earnings management. Following

the approach of DeFond, Raghunandan and Subramanyam (2002), Carey and Simnett

(2006) use the audit opinion received by client companies (dummy variable) to stand

for auditor’s propensity to issue a going-concern opinion and regress it to dummy

variables of short and long audit partner tenure. The coefficient of long audit partner

tenure is significantly negative, which means that audit partners with a long tenure

are less likely to issue a going-concern opinion (lower audit quality). Abnormal

working capital accruals (AWCA) is defined as “the difference between realized

working capital and an expected level of working capital needed to support a current

sales level” by DeFond and Park (2001). For both absolute and signed values of

AWCA, the coefficient of long audit partner tenure is not significant in the regression

analysis. Thus, audit quality measured by AWCA is not associated with long audit

partner tenure. Lastly, Carey and Simnett (2006) use two benchmarks to define the

extent of earnings management. They classify a company as engaging in earnings

management if its profit or loss is less than 2 percent of its total assets or the

company’s increase/decrease in profit/loss over last year is less than 2 percent of

total assets. The main reason for using these two benchmarks is that companies with

reported earnings around the targets are regarded as suspects of engaging in

earnings management. Carey and Simnett (2006) only find significant results when

using the breakeven performance as the benchmark, suggesting the client company

27

with long audit partner tenure has a high probability to artificially beat targets (lower

audit quality). In general, Carey and Simnett (2006) provide some evidence which

supports mandatory audit partner rotation as long audit partner tenure deteriorates

audit quality in Australia.

Firth et al. (2010) examine the effects of various forms of auditor rotation on audit

quality based on a Chinese database. All the observations in the sample from 1997 to

2005 are classified into five groups: mandatory partner rotation, mandatory firm

rotation, voluntary partner rotation, voluntary firm rotation and non-rotation.

Modified audit opinion is used as a manifestation of high audit quality. Firth et al.

(2010) find that companies in mandatory partner rotation group have a higher

probability to receive a modified audit opinion compared to the companies in the

non-rotation group. This suggests that mandatory audit partner rotation has effects

on enhancing auditor independence and therefore audit quality.

4.2.2 Audit partner rotation/tenure and perceived audit quality

As is stated before, perceived audit quality is as important as actual audit quality

when evaluating the effects on audit quality (Taylor, 2005). Limperg’s Theory of

Inspired Confidence confirms the importance of perceived audit quality. According to

Limperg’s Theory, the appearance of auditors is based on the needs of the

community. The responsibility of the auditors is therefore to meet the needs of

society. Thus, the existence of auditors relies heavily on the confidence through

assurance work. If society loses its confidence in auditor’s work and the issued audit

opinion, the social usefulness of auditors will be lost. Of course, investors’ confidence

is not only dependent on the actual audit quality, but also largely determined by

what the investors think about the quality of auditor’s work.

Due to the difficulty in measuring an individual’s interpretation about audit quality,

many previous studies (Teoh & Lim, 1996; Goodwin & Seow, 2002; Gates, Lowe, &

Reckers, 2007; Kaplan & Mauldin, 2008; Daniels & Booker, 2011; Dart, 2011) conduct

experiments to examine the association between audit partner rotation/tenure and

perceived audit quality. Gates et al. (2007) and Kaplan and Mauldin (2008) both

28

invite MBA students to act as the real-world investors in their experiments. Gates et

al. (2007) examine the investor’s confidence in company’s reported earnings under

three different conditions (audit firm rotation; audit partner rotation; non-audit

rotation). Based on the responses from MBA students, Gates et al. (2007) find that

requiring audit firm rotation significantly increases investor’s confidence in

company’s reported earnings, while audit partner rotation has little help in restoring

investor’s confidence. In addition, Gates et al. (2007) also invite law students to

conduct the same experiment. Law students stand in the supervisory role. And the

responses by law students show that they are more likely to trust in the companies

under the condition of audit firm rotation than audit partner rotation, which is

consistent with the responses by MBA students. Kaplan and Mauldin (2008) conduct

two experiments and ask MBA students to estimate the income-decreasing audit

difference for each experiment. The first experiment is set under the condition of 5

years auditor-client relationship, while the second is set as 26 years. On the contrary,

Kaplan and Mauldin (2008) find that investors do not perceive any difference

between the condition of audit firm or partner rotation when evaluating credibility of

reported earnings and auditor independence. The appropriateness of using MBA

students to represent investors is questionable itself. MBA students may simply

respond in a way that they learn in business schools. The results extracted from

experiments relying on MBA students can only show us what the business students

believe instead of what the real-world investors will judge.

Very few empirical studies (Ghosh & Moon, 2005; Chi et al., 2009) investigate the

relation between audit firm or partner rotation and perceived audit quality. Ghosh

and Moon (2005) focus on audit firm tenure, while Chi et al. (2009) focus on audit

partner rotation. I will discuss Ghosh and Moon (2005) later in section 4.3.2. Next to

actual audit quality, Chi et al. (2009) also examine the effects of mandatory partner

rotation on perceived audit quality measured by Earnings Response Coefficient (ERC).

As I have explained in section 4.2.1, Chi et al. (2009) compare the mandatory rotation

sample with three other benchmark groups. Following the regression model used in

29

Ghosh and Moon (2005), Chi et al. (2009) find that ERC is not significantly different

between two compared samples, which are mandatory rotation sample versus non-

rotation sample and mandatory rotation sample versus mandatory rotation sample in

prior year. But the ERC in mandatory rotation sample is significantly larger than that

in voluntary rotation sample. Thus, two of the three comparison samples fail to

provide any evidence on that mandatory audit partner rotation could improve

investor’s perception about auditor independence or audit quality.

4.3 Audit firm rotation/tenure and audit quality

When the audit firm is switched, the audit partner will be changed too. Even if most

governments require mandatory partner rotation, data on audit firm rotation can still

reflect the situation in audit partner rotation in some extent. Besides, some

countries, for example USA, Australia and China, are calling for discussion about

whether to require mandatory audit firm rotation in addition to mandatory partner

rotation. Thus, it is still interesting to examine the effects of audit firm

rotation/tenure on audit quality. The previous literatures about audit firm rotation/

tenure discussed below are all listed in Table 2 under Appendix.

4.3.1 Audit firm rotation/tenure and actual audit quality

To examine the potential association between audit firm tenure and audit reporting

failure, Geiger and Raghunandan (2002) select a sample which only contains the

companies that are filed for bankruptcy during 1996-1998 in America. A going

concern modified audit opinion received immediately prior to bankruptcy is regarded

as an indicator of high audit quality. Geiger and Raghunandan (2002) find that long

audit firm tenure may not be the major cause of audit failures, while auditors are

more likely to involve in audit failures at the early stage of audit firm tenure. The

result suggests that auditor’s learning curve matters as the new auditors lack specific

knowledge or experience for their new client companies in the earlier years of audit

engagement.

Besides the propensity to issue a going concern opinion, earnings quality is also used

quite often by previous studies to represent audit quality. Johnson et al. (2002) use

30

absolute values of unexpected accruals and accruals persistence as proxies for audit

quality to examine the effects of audit firm tenure. Expected accruals are estimated

based on a cross-sectional version of modified Jones 1991 model. The results by

Johnson et al. (2002) show that short audit firm tenure (2-3 years) is significantly

associated with a higher level of discretionary accruals and lower level of accruals

persistence. However, no significant results are found for medium (4-8 years) or long

audit firm tenure (more than 9 years). This means the requirement of mandatory

audit firm rotation for every 5 or 7 years may have limited benefits on improving

audit quality. Similarly, Myers et al. (2003) examine the relation between audit firm

tenure and earnings quality as well. Instead of focusing on short or long tenure by

Johnson et al. (2002), Myers et al. (2003) investigate the effects of the magnitude of

audit firm tenure on earnings quality. And they use absolute, raw and signed values

of both discretionary accruals based on Jones model and current accruals as proxies

for earnings quality. In general, the regression analysis by Myers et al. (2003) shows

that longer audit firm tenure significantly decreases the level of both discretionary

accruals and current accruals for both income-increasing and income-decreasing

accruals. This finding again doubts the necessity of requiring mandatory audit firm

rotation.

Jackson, Moldrich and Roebuck (2008) combine the methods from previous studies

(Geiger & Raghunandan, 2002; Johnson et al., 2002; Myers et al., 2003) and test the

effects of audit firm tenure on both the propensity to issue a going concern opinion

and the level of discretionary accruals using a sample of listed companies in

Australia. If a qualified audit opinion is issued, we consider it as a positive signal of

high audit quality. And lower level of performance-adjusted discretionary accruals

based on Kothari et al. (2005) indicates higher level of audit quality as well. The

results by Jackson et al. (2008) find that client firms with longer audit firm-client

relationship are more likely to receive a qualified audit opinion. And the actual audit

quality measured by discretionary accruals is not significantly affected by audit firm

tenure. Considering the potential high firm switching costs, it is hard to conclude any

31

benefits of mandatory audit firm rotation on enhancing audit quality in Australia.

Together with the effects of audit partner tenure, Chi and Huang (2005) and Chen et

al. (2008) examine the effects of audit firm tenure on earning quality in Taiwan as

well. By replacing the audit partner tenure with audit firm tenure in the non-linear

regression model introduced in section 4.2.1, Chi and Huang (2005) find a “U” shape

in the relation between audit firm tenure and discretionary accruals, which means

the earnings quality first increases with longer audit firm tenure, and then goes down

with excessive long tenure. The cut-off point is 5 years which is consistent with the

findings for audit partner tenure. Moreover, Chi and Huang (2005) find audit firm

tenure has stronger effects on earnings quality when including both partner and firm

tenure in the regression model. Chen et al. (2008) add audit firm tenure to the

existing regression model designed for audit partner tenure and examine the effects

of firm tenure on earnings quality after controlling for audit partner tenure. It is

found by Chen et al. (2008) that longer audit firm tenure lowers the level of

discretionary accruals and therefore improves audit quality. And requiring mandatory

firm rotation in addition to partner rotation is not able to further benefit the earnings

quality or audit quality.

Following the method by Chi and Huang (2005), Chen and Xia (2006) conduct the

quadratic regression analysis to examine the non-linear relation between audit firm

tenure and earnings quality based on the data of Chinese listed companies. Chen and

Xia (2006) exclude all the firm year observations with qualified audit opinion. They

only investigate the discretionary accruals in companies which receive unqualified

audit opinion. By this way, Chen and Xia (2006) believe that the level of discretionary

accruals can better reflect the actual audit quality since auditors have confirmed that

there are no material misstatements in those financial reports. The result found by

Chen and Xia (2006) is similar with that by Chi and Huang (2005). In China, longer

audit firm tenure first improves and then deteriorates the earnings quality measured

by discretionary accruals from the Jones model. But the cut-off point found by Chen

and Xia (2006) based on Chinese database is around 6 years instead of 5 years.

32

4.3.2 Audit firm rotation/tenure and perceived audit quality

To mitigate the limitation of using MBA students in the experiment as I have

discussed before in section 4.2.2, Dart (2011) directly sends questionnaires to real

institutional and private investors in UK to get a more targeted response. Dart (2011)

examines the effects of audit firm tenure alone rather than the comparison with

audit partner tenure. It is found that the investors in UK do not consider long audit

firm-client relationship as a major threat that will damage auditor independence or

audit quality based on the results from the survey (Dart, 2011).

Investors could be shareholders, but also debt-holders. Daniels and Booker (2011)

explore loan officer’s perception about auditor independence and audit quality

affected by audit firm rotation or audit firm tenure. In their experiment, the

questions about perceived auditor independence and perceived audit quality are

asked separately. After a case experiment, Daniels and Booker (2011) find that audit

firm rotation can significantly improve loan officer’s perception about auditor

independence, but cannot affect the perceived audit quality. In addition, loan officers

do not perceive any significant difference in auditor independence or audit quality

under different length of audit firm tenure (Daniels and Booker, 2011).

Ghosh and Moon (2005) classify financial statement users into three categories:

investors, independent rating agencies and financial analysts, and examine the

perceived audit quality in each group. Ghosh and Moon (2005) mainly focus on the

research in investors because investors are the principal users. Investors respond

differently to various firms’ earnings information depending on different earnings

quality. In the capital market, investors tend to buy or sell more stocks when the

issued earnings information is perceived to be of high quality. Thus, Ghosh and Moon

(2005) use earnings response coefficient (ERC) from return-earnings regression as the

measure of investor’s perception of auditor independence and audit quality. The

results show that all financial statement users view longer audit firm-client

relationship as favorable for perceived earnings quality and audit quality (Ghosh &

Moon, 2005). All the evidences unanimously approve that mandatory audit firm

33

rotation cannot help in improving both investors’ and information intermediaries’

perception about audit quality.

4.4 Literature used for hypotheses

First, this study will focus on audit partner rotation instead of audit firm rotation.

Many studies (Geiger & Raghunandan, 2002; Johnson et al., 2002; Myers et al., 2003;

Chi & Huang, 2005; Chen & Xia, 2006; Jackson et al., 2008) investigate the association

between audit firm tenure and actual audit quality. Previous studies (Geiger &

Raghunandan, 2002; Johnson et al., 2002; Myers et al., 2003) find that short audit

firm tenure is associated with lower audit quality based on data from the United

States. The explanation of this finding is the lack of client specific knowledge by new

auditors. Therefore, previous studies (Geiger & Raghunandan, 2002; Johnson et al.,

2002; Myers et al., 2003) conclude that there is limited benefit, if there is any, of

mandatory auditor rotation. However, in the United States, mandatory audit partner

rotation is implemented instead of mandatory audit firm rotation. The loss of client

specific knowledge might not take place when audit partners are rotated within the

same audit firm. The information on audit partner rotation is not publicly available in

the United States. However, the audit partner information is available in the Chinese

database. Audit reports in China are required to be signed by both audit partners’

name and audit firm’s name. It is possible to identify the audit partner tenure or

audit partner rotation in the Chinese database. Moreover, only mandatory audit

partner rotation is required for all the listed companies in China. Thus, the effects of

audit partner rotation will be investigated in this study instead of audit firm rotation.

Second, this study will directly examine the effect of audit partner rotation instead of

audit partner tenure. Some studies (Chi & Huang, 2005; Carey & Simnett, 2006;

Chen, et al., 2008) have investigated the association between audit partner tenure

and audit quality. To ensure the variation in audit partner tenure for the test,

previous studies (Chi & Huang, 2005; Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen, et al., 2008) use

the data before the mandatory audit partner rotation is required in the legislation.

However, the data selected from the period when audit partner rotation is voluntary

34

cannot directly reflect the change in audit quality when audit partner rotation is

mandatorily required. Thus, in this study, 2003 annual audit reports are selected to

directly examine the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation as this is the first

year when mandatory audit partner rotation takes effect in China.

Third, this study investigates the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on both

actual audit quality and perceived audit quality. Most studies (Chi & Huang, 2005;

Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen, et al., 2008) only explore actual audit quality. As is

explained before, mandatory audit partner rotation is implemented to enhance

auditor independence and restore investor’s confidence. Higher auditor

independence improves actual audit quality, while investor’s confidence can only be

restored when the perceived credibility of reported earnings is high. Very few studies

(Gates et al., 2007; Kaplan & Mauldin, 2008; Chi et al., 2009) have explored the

informational role of mandatory audit partner rotation. Thus, this study will

supplement the research on perceived audit quality by using the data from China.

Following the method by Ghosh and Moon (2005), ERC is used as the proxy for

perceived audit quality. Following the method by Chen et al. (2008), performance-

adjusted discretionary accruals is used to measure actual audit quality.

4.5 Summary

The results about the effects of audit firm/partner rotation are mixed. Some studies

(Myers et al., 2003; Chen et al., 2008) are against of mandatory audit firm/partner

rotation as longer audit firm/partner tenure significantly deteriorates actual earnings

quality. Some (Chi & Huang, 2005; Chen & Xia, 2006; Firth et al., 2010) are in support

of mandatory audit firm/partner rotation as they find a cut-off point in the relation

between audit firm/partner tenure and actual earnings quality. Other studies

(Johnson et al., 2002; Jackson et al., 2008) find there is no harm, but also no benefit,

of mandatory audit firm/partner rotation as no significant association is found in the

test. Most previous studies (Gates et al., 2007; Kaplan & Mauldin, 2008; Dart, 2011;

Daniels & Booker, 2011) on perceived audit quality are examined by experiments or

surveys, because it is hard to measure investor’s interpretation about audit quality

35

with numbers. To my knowledge, only two archival researches (Ghosh & Moon, 2005;

Chi et al., 2009) are found on perceived audit quality and both of them use ERC to

represent investor’s perception. Results are again mixed on perceived audit quality

measured by different proxies.

36

Chapter 5: Hypotheses

5.1 Introduction

In this chapter, hypotheses for both actual audit quality and perceived audit quality

are developed based on the literature review discussed in previous chapter.

5.2 Hypotheses development

5.2.1 Hypothesis for actual audit quality

When the propensity to issue a going concern opinion is used as the proxy for actual

audit quality, previous studies (Carey & Simnett, 2006; Firth et al., 2010) find positive

impacts of mandatory audit partner rotation. The results by Carey and Simnett

(2006) show that longer audit partner tenure is significantly associated with lower

actual audit quality. Firth et al. (2010) concludes that mandatory audit partner

rotation significantly enhances actual audit quality. The ability of the propensity to

issue a going concern opinion to capture actual audit quality is based on the

assumption that an unqualified audit opinion issued by audit partners stands for

lower actual audit quality. This will result in greater type I error, which means the

true null hypothesis of no earnings management is rejected. Issuing an unqualified

audit opinion might be simply because of the fair representation of financial

statements. When investigating the actual audit quality measured by discretionary

accruals, conflict evidences are provided by previous studies (Chi & Huang, 2005;

Chen et al., 2008; Chi et al., 2009). Chi and Huang (2005) supports mandatory audit

partner rotation based on the finding that longer audit partner tenure strengthens

actual audit quality, but excessive long partner tenure deteriorates actual audit

quality. On the contrary, Chen et al. (2008) find actual audit quality continuously

increases with longer auditor tenure and thereby oppose mandatory audit partner

rotation. Chi et al. (2009) believe there is no harm, but also no benefit, in

implementing mandatory audit partner rotation. As is explained before, most studies

37

(Chi & Huang, 2005; Carey & Simnett, 2006; Chen et al., 2008) focus on audit partner

tenure instead of mandatory audit partner rotation using the data from the period

when the audit partner rotation is still voluntary. This study directly explores the

effects of mandatory audit partner rotation by using the data from 2003 annual audit

reports in China, when the audit partner rotation is mandatorily required. Auditor’s

incentives and behavior might be significantly changed when mandatory audit

partner rotation is included in the legislation.

Previous studies (Chi & Huang, 2005; Chen et al., 2008; Chi et al., 2009) have no

consistent conclusion about the cost-benefit efficiency of mandatory audit partner

rotation. However, the adoption of mandatory audit partner rotation in China implies

that Chinese regulators believe mandatory audit partner rotation can enhance actual

audit quality. Thus, the hypothesis for actual audit quality is expected as follows:

H1: Companies that have mandatorily rotated audit partners have higher actual

audit quality than companies that have not mandatorily rotated audit partners.

5.2.2 Hypothesis for perceived audit quality

Even if the previous studies show no positive association between mandatory audit

partner rotation and actual audit quality, partner rotation may nevertheless improve

investors’ perceived audit quality. Although Chi et al. (2009) find there is no

significant difference in perceived audit quality between mandatory audit partner

rotation sample and non-rotation sample based on the data from Taiwan. This might

not be the case in Chinese capital market. Since very few empirical studies have

investigated the relation between audit partner rotation and perceived audit quality,

I will still expect positive effects on perceived audit quality. The hypothesis for

perceived audit quality is expected as follows:

H2: Companies that have mandatorily rotated audit partners have higher perceived

audit quality than companies that have not mandatorily rotated audit partners.

5.2.3 Additional hypothesis

First, many regulators believe mandatory audit firm rotation can further strengthen

actual audit quality. In both the United States and Europe, regulators have suggested

38

mandatory audit firm rotation in addition to partner rotation (Bates et al., 2012;

European Commission, 2010). Audit firm rotation is also being discussed in China

(Firth et al., 2010). Second, mandatory audit firm rotation might be more visible for

investors than partner rotation. Gates et al. (2007) find investor’s perception about

audit quality is significantly improved by audit firm rotation, but not audit partner

rotation. These two beliefs are both based on the assumption that long audit firm

tenure deteriorates actual or perceived audit quality. In 2003, mandatory audit firm

rotation is not required by legislation in China. Therefore, I can only investigate the

effects of audit firm tenure instead of mandatory audit firm rotation on audit quality.

The additional hypothesis about the effects of audit firm tenure is as follows:

H3a: Longer audit firm tenure is negatively related to actual audit quality after

controlling for audit partner rotation.

H3b: Longer audit firm tenure is negatively related to perceived audit quality after

controlling for audit partner rotation.

5.3 Summary

Based on the literature review and background information discussed above, three

hypotheses are developed as the initial answers for my main research question and

additional research question. I expect mandatory audit partner rotation will enhance

both actual audit quality and perceived audit quality. And I expect longer audit firm

tenure will deteriorate actual and perceived audit quality even after controlling for

audit partner rotation.

39

Chapter 6: Research Design

6.1 Introduction

In this chapter, measurement of audit partner rotation, firm tenure, actual earnings

quality and perceived audit quality are respectively explained. The regression models

for examining the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on both actual and

perceived audit quality are elaborated. Libby boxes are provided after the

explanation of regression models. In the end, the sample selection process and the

selected data will be explained.

6.2 Research method

6.2.1 Measurement of audit partner rotation and audit firm tenure

To examine the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation in China, I firstly identify

a group of companies which are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation in year

2003 – mandatory partner rotation group (MPR). Then, MPR group is compared with

other three benchmark groups. In this study, I use the same benchmarks defined by

Chi et al. (2009). The first benchmark group contains companies that are not subject

to audit partner rotation in year 2003 – non-rotation group (NPR). The second

benchmark group contains companies that are subject to voluntary audit partner

rotation in year 2003 – voluntary rotation group (VPR). The third benchmark group

contains the same companies with MPR, but earnings quality in year 2002 is

investigated in this group – mandatory partner rotation in prior year (MPRPY). In this

study, I separate the non-rotation sample from voluntary rotation sample. The main

reason is that voluntary rotation might be related to “opinion shopping”. Therefore,

voluntary rotation sample might have lower audit quality compared to non-rotation

sample. The first two benchmarks are used to compare the audit quality between

different companies. The third benchmark is used to compare the audit quality

within the same companies over time.

40

According to the policy in China, the requirement of mandatory audit partner

rotation takes effect since 2003. Besides, two audit partners need to sign the audit

reports and the names of partners are publicly available in China Stock Market

Accounting Research (CSMAR) database. One of the two audit partner is the leader

of the audit work. The other audit partner is the reviewer. Unfortunately, there is no

way to distinguish these two audit partners in CSMAR database. I will assume both of

them have the same level of influence on audit quality. For each company, if the

audit partners in year 2003 are not the same with partners in year 2002 and at least

one of them has consecutively served this company for more than 5 years till 2002,

then this company is classified into MPR group. If the company has changed its audit

partners in 2003, but none of them have maintained the relationship with this

company for more than 5 years, then this company is classified into VPR group. If the

company has the same two audit partners in year 2003 with that in year 2002, then

the company is classified into NPR group. In the CSMAR database, it only shows

names of audit partners and audit firms. Thus, I classify all the companies by hand. In

addition, I also count the firm tenure for each company in year 2003. The amount of

firm tenure is simply judged by how many consecutive years the same audit firm has

served the company till year 2003.

6.2.2 Measurement of actual earnings quality

As is explained before in Chapter 3, earnings quality is a proxy for audit quality and

discretionary accruals is a proxy for actual earnings quality. However, discretionary

accruals are unobservable and can only be estimated. There are various models

designed for estimating discretionary accruals according to Ronen and Yaari (2008).

To estimate discretionary accruals, most of the models firstly use several

independent variables to estimate the amount of non-discretionary accruals. Then

the discretionary accruals part can be calculated based on the residual in the

regression models. The key point in each model is which independent variables

should be included in the regression model to estimate non-discretionary accruals.

Dechow, Sloan and Sweeney (1995) compare the rate of Type II errors (companies

41

that have engaged in earnings management are not detected by the model) in 5

different models, and then find the modified Jones model exhibits the most power in

detecting earnings management.

The original Jones model of non-discretionary accruals is developed by Jones (1991).

Jones (1991) creates a model in which she uses three variables to estimate non-

discretionary accruals in a company. All the independent variables she uses in the

model can be easily found from financial statements. The first step is to estimate the

coefficients using the time series model or cross sectional model. Then the non-

discretionary accruals for each company and each year can be calculated from the

estimated coefficients and items from financial statements. The original Jones model

is as below:

NDAT=α1(1/ At−1)+α 2(∆ REV t)+α3 ¿)

Where

NDAT= Non-discretionary accruals in year t;

∆ REV t= Revenues in year t less revenues in year t-1 scaled by total assets at t-1;

PPEt= Gross property plant and equipment in year t scaled by total assets at t-1;

At−1= Total assets at t-1;

α 1α2α3= Firm-specific parameters.

In this model, changes in revenue and property, plant and equipment (PPE) are used

to estimate the normal accruals. Changes in revenue stand for changes in working

capital accruals, while PPE stands for depreciation expense. The final objective of

Jones model is to estimate discretionary accruals, not non-discretionary accruals.

However, the estimated discretionary accruals can be calculated by subtracting non-

discretionary accruals part from total accruals. Here is the regression model for total

accruals:

TAt=α 1(1

A t−1)+α 2(∆ REV t)+α3(PPE t)+v t

Where

TAt= Total accruals scaled by lagged total assets.

Total accruals are publicly available in the financial statements. The residual part in

42

this regression model stands for discretionary accruals.

Nevertheless, there is an obvious problem in the original model. Jones (1991)

assumes that all the amounts of changes in revenue as non-discretionary accruals.

Non-discretionary accruals are overstated in the original Jones model as client

management may boost earnings by booking credit sales in advance. Thus, the cross-

sectional modified Jones model by Dechow et al. (1995) makes the following

adjustment:

TAt=α 1(1

A t−1)+α 2(∆ REV t−∆ ARt)+α3(PPE t)+v t

Where

∆ ARt= Accounts receivable in year t less account receivable in year t-1 scaled by

total assets at t-1.

In this model (Dechow et al., 1995), change in total sales is replaced by change in

cash sales when estimating the part of non-discretionary accruals. Dechow et al.

(1995) believe the managed credit sales will bias the estimate of non-discretionary

accruals part.

Following the method by previous studies (Myers et al., 2003; Chi & Huang, 2005;

Chen et al., 2008; Carey & Simnett, 2006), both signed and absolute values of

performance-adjusted discretionary accruals based on Kothari et al. (2005) are used

to measure the actual earnings quality in this study. This model (Kothari et al., 2005)

makes another two adjustments based on the modified Jones model (Dechow et al.,

1995). The performance-matching model is as follows:

TA¿

A ¿−1=α 1+ β1( 1

A¿−1 )+β2( ∆REV ¿−∆ AR¿

A ¿−1)+β3(

PPE¿

A ¿−1)+β4(ROA¿−1)+DAC¿

Where

ROA¿−1= Net income/ total assets (return on assets for firm i in year t-1);

DAC¿=The residual which is used as a proxy for discretionary accruals.

Kothari et al., (2005) add two independent variables to modified Jones model by

Dechow et al. (1995), which are an intercept and the lagged rate of return on assets.

43

The intercept solves the problem of heteroskedasticity, while the lagged rate of

return on assets includes a performance factor in estimating accruals (Kothari et al.,

2005). Sometimes the estimated discretionary accruals are high simply because the

performance of client company is superior. Both of these two modifications enhance

the power of test for type I error (Ronen & Yaari, 2008). Type I error means the

innocent company is judged as having involved in earnings management.

In this study, I firstly estimate the coefficients in the performance-adjusted Jones

model for each industry in China using cross sectional model. Then I calculate the

raw discretionary accruals for each company in 2003 using the industry based

coefficients. Earnings could be managed upward to meet or beat the financial

analyst’s earnings targets when the performance of client company is poor, but

earnings could also be managed downward to be reserved for the following year

when the client is outperformed. So, the higher absolute value of discretionary

accruals implies poor earnings quality or audit quality. I investigate the signed values

of discretionary accruals as well. Some investors may have more interests in

overstated earnings which are manipulated by income-increasing discretionary

accruals. Auditors are more likely to require adjustments for overstated earnings

rather than understated earnings due to conservatism (Nelson, Elliott, & Tarpley,

2002). Moreover, a large amount of income-decreasing discretionary accruals could

simply be the result of severe conservative accounting policy required for the client

company. Thus, both absolute and signed valued of discretionary accruals should be

analyzed to examine the relation between mandatory audit partner rotation and

actual earnings quality or actual audit quality.

6.2.3 Measurement of perceived earnings quality

As is explained before in Chapter 3, reported earnings with less noise have higher

Earnings Response Coefficients (ERC) (Teoh & Wong, 1993). Following the method by

Ghosh and Moon (2005) and Chi et al. (2009), ERC is used to measure the perceived

earnings quality in this study as follows:

CAR=α+β1E+β2∆ E+ε

44

Where

CAR= Cumulative abnormal return over one year during April – March in the

following year;

E= Reported earnings before extraordinary items, scaled by market value of equity in

the end of previous year;

∆ E= Changes in reported earnings before extraordinary items, scaled by market

value of equity in the end of previous year.

Previous studies (Easton & Harris, 1991; Ali & Zarowin, 1992) find that including both

earnings and changes in earnings can increase the explanatory power of ERC when

there is transitory part in earnings. I estimate β1 and β2 in the above mentioned

equation and then ERC can be estimated based on these two estimated coefficients:

ERC=β1+β2

To estimate ERC, the first step is to calculate abnormal return. In this study, I define

the abnormal return as the difference between daily actual and expected return of a

company’s stock. The daily actual return (Ri) and expected return (Rm) are defined

respectively as follows:

Ri=Closing Stock Pricet−Closing Stock Pricet−1

Closing Stock Pricet−1

Rm=Market Indext−Market Index t−1

Market Indext−1

The Closing Stock Price is the daily stock price for each company. The Market Index

here is the weighted average stock price of Chinese stock market, where the

distinction is made between Shanghai Stock Exchange (SSE) index and Shenzhen

Stock Exchange (SZSE) index, dependent on which index the company is listed on. In

this study, I cumulate the daily difference between actual and expected stock return

for 12 months, which start from April in the first year and end up in March in the

following year. The sum of the daily difference is called Cumulative Abnormal Return

(CAR), which is defined as follows:

45

CAR=∑ (Ri ,t−Rm, t)

Where

Ri , t= The actual return of company i at day t;

Rm, t= The value-weighted market-adjusted return of the index of stock i at day t.

6.3 Regression model

6.3.1 Regression model for actual earnings quality

Following the method by Myers et al. (2003) and Chi et al. (2009), the regression

model used for examining the relation between mandatory audit partner rotation

and actual audit quality is built as follows:

DiscAccr=α+β1BMK+β2 Age+ β3 ¿ β¿4 IndGrowth+β5CFO+ β6Big4+β7FTenure+ε

Where

DiscAccr= Performance-adjusted discretionary accruals;

BMK= A dummy variable equal to 1 if observations are subject to any benchmark

samples (NPR, VPR or MPRPY), and equal to 0 otherwise;

Age= The number of years that the firm has been publicly traded;

¿¿= Logarithmic transformation of previous year-end book value of total assets;

IndGrowth= Industry growth rate of net sales over the previous year;

CFO= Cash flow from operations, scaled by last year’s total assets;

Big4= A dummy variable equal to 1 if the company is audited by Big 4, and equal to

0 otherwise; and

FTenure= Audit firm tenure.

The key independent variable in this regression model is BMK . My first hypothesis

predicts a positive relation between mandatory audit partner rotation and actual

audit quality. Actual audit quality is high when the level of discretionary accruals is

low. Thus, I expect the discretionary accruals in the benchmark sample should be

higher than that in the MPR sample. When the absolute value of discretionary

accruals is used, a positive β1 is expected. When the positive (negative) value of

discretionary accruals is used, a positive (negative) β1 is expected.

46

Following the previous studies (Myers et al., 2003; Chen et al., 2008), several control

variables are included in the regression model. First, Age is included as the level of

discretionary accruals varies with different years in the company’s life cycle (Anthony

& Ramesh, 1992). A negative β2 is expected as the discretionary accruals decrease

with longer company’s age. Second, a negative coefficient of ¿¿ is expected as larger

companies tend to disclose more stable accruals (Dechow & Dichev, 2002). Third, a

positive β4 is expected. The level of discretionary accruals increases with the level of

sales growth within the industry (Myers et al., 2003). Fourth, CFO is included to

predict negative effects on accruals. Accruals and cash flows are negatively related to

each other (Dechow, 1994). More cash flow from operations implies less

discretionary accruals. Thus, a negative β5 is expected. Fifth, a dummy variable of

Big4 is included. Previous studies (Becker, DeFond, Jiambalvo, & Subramanyam,

1998; Francis & Krishnan, 1999) find the large audit firms are more conservative and

are less likely to allow extreme accruals. Therefore, a negative β6 is expected as big 4

audit firms provide higher audit quality. Finally, FTenure is included to examine the

effects of audit firm tenure on actual audit quality after controlling for audit partner

rotation. Longer audit firm tenure might deteriorate auditor independence and is

therefore related to higher level of discretionary accruals (Chi & Huang, 2005). A

positive coefficient of firm tenure is expected.

6.3.2 Regression model for perceived earnings quality

Based on the research method used by Ghosh and Moon (2005), I use the following

regression model to examine the relation between mandatory audit partner rotation

and perceived audit quality in this study:

CAR=α+β1E+β2∆ E+β3BMK+β4 E×BMK+β5∆ E×BMK+∑j=1

9

β6+2 ( j−1)E×Controlvariable j+∑j=1

9

β7+2( j−1)∆ E×Control variable j+∑j=1

9

β23+ jControl variable j+ε

Where

BMK= A dummy variable equal to 1 if observations are subject to any benchmark

samples (NPR, VPR or MPRPY), and equal to 0 otherwise;

FTenure= Audit firm tenure.

47

The most important coefficients are the sum of β4 and β5 (β4+β5). My second

hypothesis predicts a positive relation between mandatory audit partner rotation

and perceived audit quality. Thus, the benchmark sample should have lower ERC

than MPR sample. The sum of coefficients (β4+β5) represents the incremental ERC

for benchmark sample compared to the MPR sample. I predict a negative

incremental ERC and the sum of coefficients (β4+β5) should be smaller than zero.

All the nine control variables are interacted with earnings and changes in earnings.

Following the previous studies (Ghosh & Moon, 2005; Chi et al., 2009), I include 9

control variables in the regression model. The nine control variables are shown as

follows:

1. Age: The number of years that the firm has been publicly traded (discussed

above);

2. Big4: A dummy variable equal to 1 if the company is audited by Big 4, and equal

to 0 otherwise (discussed above);

3. Growth: (Market value of equity + Book value of debt)/Book value of total assets

at the end of year t;

4. Persist : First-order autocorrelation of earnings per share for the past 16 quarters;

5. Volatility: Standard deviation of earnings per share for the past 16 quarters;

6. Beta: Systematic risk calculated with 60 months stock returns;

7. ¿¿: Logarithmic transformation of market value of equity at the end of year t;

8. Leverage: Total debt/total assets at the end of year t;

9. FTenure: Audit firm tenure (discussed above).

Growth, Persist , Volatility and Beta are included as the control variables for the

considerations of valuation (Warfield, Wild, & Wild, 1995). ¿¿ is included based on

the political cost theory (Ghosh & Moon, 2005). Managers of large companies have

incentives to manage earnings in order to reduce the political costs. Leverage is

included based on contracting considerations. Companies with higher leverage are

more likely to manipulate earnings in order to avoid debt-covenant violations

(DeFond & Jiambalvo, 1994).

48

6.4 Libby boxes

6.4.1 Libby boxes for actual earnings quality

The Libby boxes for the regression model on the relation between mandatory audit

partner rotation and actual audit quality are as follows:

Figure 1: Libby boxes for actual earnings quality

6.4.2 Libby box for perceived earnings quality

The Libby boxes for the regression model on the relation between mandatory audit

partner rotation and perceived audit quality are as follows:

Figure 2: Libby boxes for perceived earnings quality

49

6.5 Sample selection and data

In China, mandatory audit partner rotation is required since 2003. Thus, the first

mandatory audit partner rotation can be observed through the 2003 annual audit

reports. I investigate the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation when the

regulation takes effects for the first year. Therefore, I will focus on Chinese listed

companies in year 2003. To identify the companies that changed their audit partners

due to mandatory requirement in 2003, I need to judge if the company has

consecutively maintained the relationship with the same audit partners for 5 years

till 2002. Therefore, I need data for audit partners from year 1998 to year 2003 for

each listed company.

Data for this study are collected from CSMAR database for all the companied listed

on SSE or SZSE. First, my original sample contains all the companies listed on Chinese

stock market, which are 1290 companies. I delete 43 companies which belong to

financial industry and 232 companies which have incomplete data for audit partners.

By focusing on the 2003 data, I obtain a preliminary sample of 1015 companies in

total.

Second, I classify these 1015 companies into three groups. 111 companies (MPR) are

found to have mandatorily rotated their audit partner in year 2003. 426 companies

(VPR) voluntarily rotated their audit partners in year 2003. And the other 478

companies (NPR) did not change their audit partners in year 2003. After that, I delete

64 companies that are delisted in or before 2003. In the end, I obtain a final sample

of 951 companies, which are 109 companies for MPR sample, 439 companies for NPR

sample and 403 companies for VPR sample. The selection process for MPR, NPR and

VPR is summarized in Table 3 under Appendix.

The actual and perceived audit quality in MPR is compared with other three

benchmark groups: VPR, NPR and MPRPY. MPRPY contains the same companies with

MPR, but with different years. Thus, I collect all the data again for those 109

companies, but in year 2002, for example audit firm tenure in 2002 and discretionary

accruals in 2002.

50

To estimate the discretionary accruals, I use the cross-sectional industry model by

Kothari et al. (2005). China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) defined 17

industries in China in 2012. I obtained all the companies for each industry except

financial industry. The coefficients for each industry in the model by Kothari et al.

(2005) are estimated by 8 years data from 2000 to 2007. I start from year 2000

because most of the data for cash flow from operations are missing before 2000.

Data for daily stock return are obtained from WIND database. I obtained both daily

closing stock price and daily market index from 1st of April in 2003 till 31st of March in

2004 for those 951 companies. Due the missing data for daily stock price, I delete

one company for my second regression analysis for NPR sample. Thus, when using

ERC as the measure for perceived audit quality, I obtain 109 companies for MPR

sample, 403 companies for VPR sample and 438 companies for NPR sample.

6.6 Summary

In this chapter, research method for this study is discussed. I hand-collect the data

for audit partner rotation and audit firm tenure. I use discretionary accruals

estimated by Kothari et al. (2005) model to measure the actual audit quality. And I

use ERC as the proxy for perceived audit quality. To examine the relation between

audit partner rotation and discretionary accruals, another 6 control variables are

included in the regression model. To examine the relation between audit partner

rotation and ERC, another 9 control variables are included in the second regression

model. Data are collected from both CSMAR and WIND database. In the end, I

obtained 109 companies for MPR, 403 companies for VPR and 439 (438) companies

for NPR.

51

Chapter 7: Results

7.1 Introduction

In this chapter, I will present the statistical results for regression analyses on both

actual and perceived audit quality. Before the regression analyses, I will first provide

the descriptive statistics and comparisons of means. The results for univariate test

will be presented in section 7.2, while the results for multivariate test will be briefly

discussed in section 7.3 and 7.4. Section 7.3 presents the results based on both

absolute and signed values of discretionary accruals. Section 7.4 presents the results

for perceived audit quality. And I will explain the results for three comparisons

separately, which are MPR vs. NPR, MPR vs. VPR and MPR vs. MPRPY.

7.2 Descriptive statistics

7.2.1 Descriptive statistics for actual audit quality

Descriptive statistics for variables in the regression model of actual audit quality are

shown in Table 4 under Appendix. Firstly, I compare the level of discretionary

accruals between MPR sample and NPR sample. Based on Panel A and Panel B of

Table 4, the mean of │DA│ is 0.064 in MPR sample, while the mean is 0.055 in NPR

sample. Before checking whether the difference in │DA│ is significant between these

two groups, I first examine whether │DA│ is normally distributed in my sample.

Based on the results from Panel A of Table 5 under Appendix, the dependent

variable is not normally distributed. Thus, I will run both parametric and

nonparametric test to examine the mean difference. Table 6 shows the results of

two-tailed t-tests. The results in Panel A of Table 6 suggest that the mean difference

between MPR sample and NPR sample is not significantly different from zero. In

addition, Table 7 shows the results of two-tailed nonparametric Wilcoxon z-tests.

The results in Panel A of Table 7 suggest that the mean of │DA│ in MPR sample is not

significantly different from that in NPR sample. Therefore, the univariate

52

comparisons of mean of │DA│ between MPR sample and NPR sample shows that

there is no significant difference in earnings quality or actual audit quality between

the companies that are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation and companies

that retain the same audit partners, which fails to support Hypothesis 1. Turning to

other 6 control variables, all the mean differences are insignificant between MPR

and NPR samples except for AGE and FTenure. The mean of AGE is 7.321 in MPR

sample, while the mean of AGE is 6.337 in NPR sample based on the results in Table

4. Both the two-tailed t-test and two-tailed nonparametric Wilcoxon z-test show the

mean difference of AGE is significantly different in MPR and NPR samples. The mean

of FTenure in MPR sample is 4.183, while the mean of FTenure in NPR sample is

3.597. The results from both the two-tailed t-test and two-tailed nonparametric

Wilcoxon z-test suggest that the mean of FTenure in MPR sample is significantly

larger than that in NPR sample.

Secondly, I compare the earning quality or actual audit quality between MPR sample

and VPR sample. The mean for │DA│ in MPR sample is 0.064, while the mean for

│DA│ in VPR sample is 0.055. The results of two-tailed t-test in Panel B of Table 6

show that the mean of │DA│ in MPR sample is not significantly different from that in

VPR sample. The two-tailed nonparametric Wilcoxon z-test in Panel B of Table 7

shows that the difference of │DA│ between MPR and VPR samples is not significant

as well. The findings suggest that the actual audit quality in MPR sample is not

significantly different from that in VPR sample. Turning to the mean difference of

control variables, all the mean differences are insignificant except for AGE and

FTenure. The mean of AGE in MPR sample is 7.321, and the mean of AGE in VPR

sample is 6.092. The difference of 1.229 is significant based on the results from both

parametric and nonparametric tests. The mean of FTenure in MPR sample is 4.183,

while the mean of FTenure in VPR sample is 3.295. According to both two-tailed t-

test and two-tailed nonparametric Wilcoxon z-test, the mean of FTenure in MPR

sample is significantly larger than that in VPR sample.

Thirdly, I compare the actual audit quality in companies that are subject to

53

mandatory audit partner rotation in year 2003 with the audit quality in the same

companies, but in year 2002. By this way of comparison, I test whether the

mandatory audit partner rotation is able to increase the actual audit quality in the

same company over time. Based on Panel A and Panel D of Table 4, the mean of

│DA│ in MPRPY sample is 0.055, which is different from the mean of │DA│ in MPR

sample. This mean difference is insignificant according to the results from Panel C of

Table 6 and Table 7. Both two-tailed t-test and two-tailed nonparametric Wilcoxon z-

test show that the actual audit quality is not significantly increased after the

implementation of mandatory audit partner rotation for the same company over

time. All the mean differences in control variables are insignificant except for AGE.

The mean of AGE in MPRPY sample is 6.321, which is significantly from 7.321 in MPR

sample based on both parametric and nonparametric tests.

7.2.2 Descriptive statistics for perceived audit quality

Additional variables are needed for the second regression model to examine the

effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on perceived audit quality. Due to the

missing data for CAR, the sample size is reduced. For the regression analysis on

perceived audit quality, I obtain 109 companies for MPR sample, 403 companies for

VPR sample and 438 companies for NPR sample respectively.

Table 8 under Appendix shows the results for descriptive statistics for perceived audit

quality. Similar with the analysis on actual audit quality, I compare the stock reaction

in MPR sample with the stock reaction in three other benchmark samples.

Firstly, I compare mandatory partner rotation sample with non-rotation sample.

From Panel A and Panel B of Table 8, I find the mean of CAR in MPR sample is -0.395

and the mean of CAR in NPR sample is -0.420. The results in Panel A of Table 9 show

that CAR is not normally distributed under the comparison of “MPR vs. NPR”. A two-

tailed t-test shown in Panel A of Table 10 suggests the difference in CAR means is not

significant. And the two-tailed nonparametric Wilcoxon z-test from Panel A of Table

11 also suggests an insignificant difference in CAR means. Therefore, the univariate

tests show there is no significant difference in CAR between MPR sample and NPR

54

sample. Turning to control variables, all the mean differences are insignificant except

for AGE, Beta and FTenure when comparing MPR sample with NPR sample. The mean

of AGE in MPR sample is 7.321, while the mean of AGE in NPR sample is 6.345. Both

two-tailed t-test and nonparametric Wilcoxon z-test show this mean difference is

significant, which suggests that mandatory audit partner rotation sample include

more old companies. The two tailed t-test shows NPR sample has larger Beta than

MPR sample, which means companies in NPR sample are more risky. I will discuss

FTenure later in this section.

Secondly, I compare MPR sample with VPR sample. The mean of CAR in VPR sample

is -0.414, which is different from -0.395 in MPR sample. Both parametric and

nonparametric tests show that this mean difference is not significant, which means

the CAR in MPR sample is indifferent from the CAR in VPR sample generally. The

control variable of AGE shows a significant difference in mean between MPR and VPR

samples. This finding suggests that companies that are subject to mandatory audit

partner rotation are generally older than companies that are subject to voluntary

audit partner rotation.

Thirdly, I compare CAR in mandatory partner rotation sample with CAR in the same

sample, but in prior year. Based on the two-tailed t-test in Panel C of Table 10 and the

nonparametric test in Panel C of Table 11, the mean difference of 0.248 in CAR is

significant between mandatory audit partner rotation sample and mandatory

rotation sample in prior year. Both parametric and nonparametric tests show that

companies that are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation sample have

significant larger CAR than the same companies in prior year. The two-tailed t-tests

show that the mean differences in AGE and Growth are significant, while the

nonparametric tests show that the mean differences in AGE, Growth, Size and

FTenure are all significant. The nonparametric Wilcoxon z-tests find the mean

differences in FTenure are all significant for all the three comparisons (MPR vs. NPR,

MPR vs. VPR and MPR vs. MPRPY). In general, companies that are subject to

mandatory audit partner rotation have longer audit firm tenure than other

55

benchmark companies.

7.3 Empirical findings based on performance-adjusted abnormal

accruals

All the findings based on univariate tests are inconsistent with the expectation in

Hypothesis 1. Next to univariate tests, I examine the effects of mandatory audit

partner rotation on actual audit quality again with multivariate tests. Table 12 shows

the results of the regression analysis for actual audit quality. Panel A of Table 12

reports the findings using absolute values of performance-adjusted discretionary

accruals as the dependent variable. Firstly, I find that the coefficient of BMK is

insignificant (-0.009, t = -1.390) under the column of “MPR vs. NPR”. This suggests

that │DA│ in MPR sample is not significantly different from that in NPR sample even

after controlling for other 6 common determinants of discretionary accruals based

on the regression model explained in section 6.3.1. Secondly, the coefficient of BMK

is insignificant (-0.008, t = -1.154) under column “MPR vs. VPR”, which means the

difference of │DA│ between MPR and VPR samples is insignificant. Thirdly, the

coefficient of BMK is insignificant (-0.007, t = -0.769) when comparing the MPR

sample with MPRPY sample. This result suggests that the level of │DA│ in companies

that are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation in year 2003 is indifferent with

the level of │DA│ in the same companies one year earlier with old audit partners.

Table 12: Performance-adjusted discretionary accruals and mandatory audit partner rotation

Panel A: Absolute performance-adjusted discretionary accruals (│DA│) resultsVariable Exp.sign MPR vs. NPR MPR vs. VPR MPR vs. MPRPY(Constant) ? 0.362* 0.141* 0.316*   (5.583) (2.204) (2.666) BMK +¿ -0.009 -0.008 -0.007   (-1.390) (-1.154) (-0.769) AGE −¿ 0.001 0.002 0.000   (1.140) (1.423) (0.042) SIZE −¿ -0.034* -0.010 -0.030*   (-4.798) (-1.394) (-2.342) IndGrowth +¿ -0.007 0.004 -0.002   (-1.197) (0.675) (-0.664)

56

CFO −¿ 0.054 -0.044 0.110*   (1.857) (-1.456) (2.316) Big4 −¿ -0.001 0.003 -0.001   (-0.131) (0.276) (-0.061) FTenure +¿ 0.000 0.000 0.004   (0.250) (0.087) (1.381) Adj.R2 0.045 0.005 0.034 n 548 512 218 (The table is continued.)

Following the method by previous studies (Myers et al., 2003; Chi & Huang, 2005;

Chen et al., 2008; Carey & Simnett, 2006), both signed and absolute values of

performance-adjusted discretionary accruals based on Kothari et al. (2005) are used

to measure the actual earnings quality in this study. The results using signed values

of performance-adjusted discretionary accruals as dependent variable are reported

in Panel B and Panel C of Table 12. Firstly, the coefficients of BMK are all insignificant

(-0.005, t = -1.408; -0.002, t = -0.462; -0.007, t = -1.669) for income-increasing

accruals in Panel B. These findings suggest that the level of income-increasing

accruals in MPR is indifferent with that in other three benchmark samples (NPR, VPR

and MPRPY). Secondly, the coefficients of BMK are all insignificant (0.002, t = 0.534;

0.005, t = 0.976; -0.007, t = -0.973) for income-decreasing accruals in Panel C. These

findings suggest that the levels of income-decreasing accruals are not significantly

different between MPR and benchmark samples (NPR, VPR and MPRPY).

In sum, the coefficients of BMK are all insignificant when using absolute value or

signed value of performance-adjusted discretionary accruals as the dependent

variable. All the findings suggest that the actual audit quality in mandatory audit

partner rotation sample is indifferent with the actual audit quality in non-rotation

sample, voluntary audit partner rotation sample or mandatory audit partner rotation

sample in prior year. In addition, when the absolute value of accruals or positive

discretionary accruals is used, the coefficient of BMK is negative (Panel A and Panel B

of Table 12), which is contrary to my expectation of a positive relationship in

Hypothesis 1. When negative discretionary accruals are used, the coefficient of BMK

is insignificantly negative under the column “MPR vs. MPRPY”, which is consistent

57

with the expectation of a negative relationship. But for comparisons of “MPR vs.

NPR” and “MPR vs. VPR”, the coefficients of BMK are positive. A negative relationship

between BMK and absolute value of positive value of discretionary accruals means

that the actual audit quality in mandatory audit partner rotation sample is lower

than the actual audit quality in other benchmark samples (NPR, VPR or MPRPY). A

positive relationship between BMK and income-decreasing accruals suggests that the

actual audit quality is lower in mandatory audit partner rotation sample than other

benchmark samples (NPR or VPR).

Table 12: (Continued)Panel B: Positive performance-adjusted discretionary accruals (DA+¿ ¿) resultsVariable Exp.sign MPR vs. NPR MPR vs. VPR MPR vs. MPRPY(Constant) ? 0.049 0.056 0.132*   (1.409) (1.353) (2.031) BMK +¿ -0.005 -0.002 -0.007  (-1.408) (-0.462) (-1.669) AGE −¿ -0.001 -0.001 -0.002*  (-1.865) (-1.485) (-2.135) SIZE −¿ 0.002 -4.221E-5 -0.008   (0.544) (-0.009) (-1.105) IndGrowth +¿ -0.001 0.003 0.001  (-0.277) (0.934) (0.636) CFO −¿ -0.782* -0.831* -0.783*  (-37.823) (-34.540) (-24.981) Big4 −¿ 0.002 0.005 0.008   (0.341) (0.689) (1.128) FTenure +¿ -0.001 0.001 0.002*  (-1.069) (1.430) (1.983) Adj.R2 0.827 0.830 0.863n 314 256 113 (The table is continued.)

Table 12: (Continued)Panel C: Negative performance-adjusted discretionary accruals (DA−¿ ¿) resultsVariable Exp.sign MPR vs. NPR MPR vs. VPR MPR vs. MPRPY(Constant) ? -0.173* -0.065 -0.057   (-3.719) (-1.469) (-0.762) BMK −¿ 0.002 0.005 -0.007  (0.534) (0.976) (-0.973)

58

AGE +¿ -0.002* -0.002* -0.002  (-2.836) (-2.741) (-1.081) SIZE +¿ 0.023* 0.009 0.010   (4.749) (1.945) (1.265) IndGrowth −¿ 0.010* 0.007 0.002  (2.183) (1.534) (0.847) CFO −¿ -0.815* -0.730* -0.812*  (-32.331) (-25.071) (-20.930) Big4 +¿ -0.003 0.011 0.019   (-0.365) (1.687) (1.059) FTenure −¿ -0.001 0.002* 0.001  (-0.502) (2.136) (0.482) Adj.R2 0.831 0.717 0.811n 234 256 105

Notes:

BMK is a dummy variable equal to 1 if observations are belong to any benchmark

samples (NPR, VPR or MPRPY), and equal to 0 otherwise.

* Significant at the 0.05 level based on a two-tailed t-test (in parentheses).

Turning to control variables, the results in Panel A of Table 12 show that SIZE is

significantly negatively (-0.034, t = -4.798) related to the absolute value of

discretionary accruals when comparing the mandatory audit partner rotation sample

with non-rotation sample. Under column “MPR vs. VPR” of Panel A in Table 12, all

the coefficients of control variables are insignificant when using the absolute value of

discretionary accruals as the dependent variable. Under column “MPR vs. MPRPY” of

Panel A in Table 12, the coefficient of SIZE is significantly negative (-0.030, t = -2.342)

when using absolute value of discretionary accruals in the regression analysis. These

findings are consistent with my expectations and suggest that companies with larger

size have less discretionary accruals, therefore are related to higher actual audit

quality. When income-increasing accruals are used as the dependent variable, the

coefficients of CFO are found to be significantly negative (-0.782, t = -37. 823; -0.831,

t = -34.540; -0.783, t = -24.981) when comparing the MPR sample with three other

benchmark samples (NPR, VPR or MPRPY). This is consistent with the expectation

59

that companies with more cash flow from operations have less income-increasing

accruals and thereby higher actual audit quality. In Panel B of Table 12, the results

show that AGE is significantly negatively (-0.002, t = -2.135) related to income-

increasing discretionary accruals when comparing the mandatory audit partner

rotation sample with mandatory rotation sample in prior year. This means older

companies generally have less income-increasing accruals and thereby have higher

actual audit quality. When the negative value of performance-adjusted discretionary

accruals are used as the dependent variable, the results from Panel C of Table 12

show that the coefficients of CFO are significantly negative (-0.815, t = -32.331; -

0.731, t = -25.071; -0.812, t = -20.930) under all the three columns. The results for

CFO suggest that companies with large amount of cash flow from operations have

more income-decreasing accruals. Under both the columns of “MPR vs. NPR” and

“MPR vs. VPR”, AGE is found to be significantly negatively (-0.002, t = -2.836; -0.002, t

= -2.741) related to the negative values of discretionary accruals based on Panel C of

Table 12. This means older companies generally have more income-decreasing

accruals. This might be caused by the more conservative accounting rules in older

companies. When comparing MPR sample with NPR sample using negative value of

discretionary accruals, the coefficients of SIZE (0.023, t = 4.749) and IndGrowth

(0.010, t = 2.183) are both significantly positive. Based on the results shown in Panel

C of Table 12, it is found that companies with larger size or larger industry growth

have less income-decreasing accruals.

Besides the relation between mandatory audit partner rotation and actual audit

quality, Table 12 also provides some evidence for the effects of audit firm tenure. In

Panel B of Table 12, FTenure is significantly positively (0.002, t = 1.983) related to

income-increasing accruals under the column of “MPR vs. MPRPY”. In Panel C of

Table 12, FTenure is significantly positively (0.002, t = 2.136) related to income-

decreasing accruals under the column of “MPR vs. VPR”. The findings for FTenure

suggest that companies with longer firm tenure have more income-increasing

accruals, but less income-decreasing accruals.

60

7.4 Empirical findings based on earnings response coefficients

The univariate tests presented in section 7.2.2 show that there is no significant

difference in mean of CAR when comparing the mandatory audit partner rotation

sample with other two benchmark samples, which are non-rotation sample and

voluntary audit partner rotation sample. However, I find that CAR in companies that

are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation sample is significantly larger than

CAR in prior year within the same companies. The findings provide some evidence to

support Hypothesis 2 as mandatory audit partner rotation has positive effects on

perceived audit quality. In this part, I will conduct the multivariate test to obtain

more evidence for the relation between mandatory audit partner rotation and

perceived audit quality. Table 13 shows the regression analysis for perceived audit

quality measured by ERC.

Table 13: Earnings response coefficients and mandatory audit partner rotation

Variable

Coefficient (Exp.sign)

MPR vs. NPR

MPR vs. VPR

MPR vs. MPRPY

(Constant) α -3.632* -2.889*  -2.014*  (-9.649) (-8.474) (-3.358)E β1 20.760* 9.632 -33.919  (2.409) (1.253) (-1.937)ΔE β2 -17.484 -4.910  -15.741

  (-1.726) (-0.673) (-

1.684)

 ERC β1+ β2 3.276 4.722 -

49.660*

  (1.298) (1.305) (-

2.331)BMK β3 -0.012 -0.017  -0.196*

  (-0.482) (-0.655) (-

6.066)E*BMK β4 0.470 -0.367  -3.258*

  (−¿) (0.748) (-0.583) (-

3.320)ΔE*BMK β5 -0.686 -0.430  1.244  (−¿) (-0.950) (-0.722)  (1.333) ERC BMK β4+β5 -0.216 -0.797*  -2.013  (−¿) (0.014) (-2.166)  (-

61

0.378)Control variables:E*FTenure(β6)/ΔE*FTenure(β7) β6+β7 -0.141 -0.035  -0.480

  (−¿) (0.155) (0.729) (-

0.034)E*Age(β8)/ΔE*Age(β9) β8+β9 -0.356* -0.051*  -0.442*

  (+¿) (-3.159) (-2.609) (-

1.970)E*Big4(β10)/ΔE*Big4(β11) β10+ β11 2.945 2.113  5.501  (+¿) (0.421) (1.921)  (1.949)E*Growth(β12)/ΔE*Growth(β13) β12+β13 0.701 0.136  0.148  (+¿) (1.341) (0.906)  (0.678)E*Persist(β14)/ΔE*Persist(β15) β14+β15 -0.747 -1.151  6.288  (+¿) (-1.168) (-0.860)  (0.274)E*Volatility(β16)/ΔE*Volatility(β17) β16+ β17 -2.025 -1.172*  -4.916

  (−¿) (-0.932) (-1.989) (-

1.757)E*Beta(β18)/ΔE*Beta(β19) β18+ β19 -1.461 -1.256  -1.467

  (−¿) (-0.873) (-1.510) (-

0.781)E*Size(β20)/ΔE*Size(β21) β20+ β21 0.365 -0.032  4.725*  (+¿) (-0.673) (-0.509)  (2.749)E*Leverage(β22)/ΔE*Leverage(β23) β22+β23 -0.511 -0.433  2.572  (−¿) (-1.098) (-0.541)  (0.193)FTenure β24 0.002 0.006  0.019*  (−¿) (0.358) (0.938)  (2.342)Age β25 0.005 -0.006  -0.005

  (+¿) (1.033) (-1.389) (-

0.653)Big4 β26 0.036 0.041  -0.047

  (+¿) (0.692) (0.785) (-

0.409)Growth β27 -0.016 -0.001  0.014  (+¿) (-1.690) (-0.153)  (0.954)Persist β28 0.086 0.084  -0.207

  (+¿) (1.249) (1.239) (-

1.450)Volatility β29 -0.041 -0.021  0.203  (−¿) (-0.328) (-0.167)  (0.876)Beta β30 0.066 0.026  0.037  (−¿) (1.321) (0.588)  (0.707)Size β31 0.334* 0.268*  0.143*

62

  (+¿) (8.202) (7.073)  (2.151)Leverage β32 0.083 0.000  0.186*  (−¿) (1.538) (0.012)  (2.232)Adj.R2 0.367 0.341  0.470n    547  512  218

Notes:

ERC is calculated by taking the sum of the individual coefficients of E and ΔE.

* Significant at the 0.05 level based on a two-tailed t-test (in parentheses).

I find that the sum of the individual coefficients of E and ΔE is not significant when

comparing the MPR sample with NPR or VPR samples. But ERC (β1+ β2) is significantly

negative (-49.660, t = -2.331) under the column of “MPR vs. MPRPY”. The coefficient

of interest in this study is the incremental ERC (β4+β5) for benchmark samples. I find

that the incremental ERC is indifferent from zero under the column of “MPR vs. NPR”

and “MPR vs. MPRPY”. This means ERC in mandatory audit partner rotation sample is

not significantly different from the ERC in Non-rotation sample or mandatory

rotation sample in prior year, which fails to support my expectation in Hypothesis 2.

However, the incremental ERC for voluntary audit partner rotation sample is

significantly negative (-0.797, t = -2.166). This finding suggests that ERC in mandatory

audit partner rotation sample is significantly larger than ERC in voluntary audit

partner rotation sample, which provides some evidence to support Hypothesis 2.

When using VPR as the benchmark sample, investors’ perception about audit quality

is increased in mandatory audit partner rotation sample.

Following the method by Ghosh and Moon (2005), I present the sum of the two

interaction coefficients for each control variable in Table 13, instead of the individual

coefficient on each control variable. Based on the results shown in Table 13, I find

consistent evidence under all the three comparisons that Age is significantly negative

(-0.356, t = -3.159; -0.051, t = -2.609; -0.442, t = -1.970), which suggests that older

companies have lower perceived audit quality. This finding about Age is consistent

with the findings by Chi et al. (2009) using the data from Taiwan. The results also

63

provide some evidence on Volatility and Size. ERC increases with company size, while

decreases with Volatility. Unfortunately, I do not find any significant results for audit

firm tenure after controlling for audit partner rotation and other factors which could

affect the ERC. This means investors’ perception about audit quality is not

significantly decreased by longer audit firm tenure after controlling for the audit

partner rotation, which is again consistent with the findings by Chi et al. (2009)

based on the Taiwanese database.

In sum, under three comparisons, only one of them shows significant result that is in

support of Hypothesis 2. Therefore, I find no consistent evidence to support my

expectation that mandatory audit partner rotation enhances perceived audit quality

by investors. All the sums of interaction coefficients are insignificant except for Age,

Volatility and Size. Based on the regression analysis in Table 13, I fail to find any

evidence to support Hypothesis 3, which expects longer firm tenure deteriorates

perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner rotation. The sums of

coefficients (β6+β7) are negative, but not significant under all the three comparisons

shown in Table 13.

7.5 Summary

In this chapter, I examine the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on actual

and perceived audit quality through both univariate and multivariate tests. Firstly, for

actual audit quality, all the findings based on univariate tests are inconsistent with

my expectation in Hypothesis 1. The regression analysis on actual audit quality finds

no significant results using both absolute and signed values of discretionary accruals

as the dependent variable. I conclude that no evidence is found to support the

expectation in Hypothesis 1 that mandatory audit partner rotation enhances actual

audit quality. Secondly, for perceived audit quality, the univariate tests find some

evidence that supports Hypothesis 2. I find that CAR in companies that are subject to

mandatory audit partner rotation sample is significantly larger than CAR in prior year

within the same companies. The multivariate tests find that only one (MPR vs. VPR)

of the three comparisons has significant result that is in support of Hypothesis 2.

64

Thus, I conclude that there is no consistent evidence to support the expectation in

Hypothesis 2 that mandatory audit partner rotation enhances perceived audit

quality. In addition, I do not find consistent evidence that supports Hypothesis 3,

which suggests that audit firm tenure has no significant effects on actual and

perceived audit quality after controlling for other determinants of discretionary

accruals or ERC.

65

Chapter 8: Analysis

8.1 Introduction

In this chapter, I will elaborate the results from my regression analyses shown in my

previous chapter. Both main research questions and additional research question

issued in Chapter 1 will be answered. The corresponding 3 hypotheses will be

discussed as well. Based on the findings from my empirical results, I will explain why

the outcomes differ from my expectation before and from prior literatures.

8.2 The effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on actual

audit quality

In this section, I will try to answer one of the main research questions stated in

Chapter 1, which is whether the mandatory audit partner rotation has effects on

earnings quality or actual audit quality. Previous studies (Chi & Huang, 2005; Chen et

al., 2008; Chi et al., 2009) find conflicting results when investigating the effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation or audit partner tenure on earnings quality

measured by discretionary accruals. Most studies (Chi & Huang, 2005; Carey &

Simnett, 2006; Chen et al., 2008) focus on audit partner tenure instead of mandatory

audit partner rotation using the data from the period when the audit partner

rotation is still voluntary. However, this study directly explores the effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation. Auditor’s incentives and behavior might be

significantly changed when mandatory audit partner rotation is included in the

legislation. In addition, the adoption of mandatory audit partner rotation in China

implies that Chinese regulators believe mandatory audit partner rotation can

enhance actual audit quality. Thus, I hypothesized that companies that have

mandatorily rotated audit partners have higher actual audit quality than companies

that haven’t mandatorily rotated audit partners.

To examine the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on earnings quality or

66

actual audit quality based on the sample in China, I compare the level of

performance-adjusted discretionary accruals in mandatory audit partner rotation

sample with other three benchmark samples, which are non-rotation sample,

voluntary audit partner rotation sample and mandatory rotation sample in prior year.

The results for regression analysis shown in Table 12 suggest that mandatory audit

partner rotation has no significant effects on earnings quality or actual audit quality.

From panel A of Table 12, it is found that mandatory audit partner rotation has no

significant effects on absolute values of performance-adjusted discretionary accruals.

Moreover, from Panel B and Panel C of Table 12, it is found that mandatory audit

partner rotation has no effects on either positive or negative values of discretionary

accruals. Thus, all the findings provide no evidence to support Hypothesis 1. My

empirical results suggest that there is no association between mandatory audit

partner rotation and earnings quality or actual audit quality.

There could be several reasons that result in these insignificant effects of mandatory

audit partner rotation on earnings quality. As I have explained before in Chapter 1,

the introduction of mandatory audit partner rotation may solve the problem of long

audit partner tenure. Mandatory audit partner rotation not only enhances auditor

independence, but also provides a “fresh viewpoint” which could enhance auditor’s

competence to find the potential breach in the client’s audit reports. At the same

time, mandatory audit partner rotation could also bring a negative effect on actual

audit quality. Mandatory audit partner rotation initiates costs from unexperienced

audit successor. Based on the regression analysis for actual audit quality, the

insignificant results suggest that the costs of mandatory audit partner rotation have

offset most parts of the benefits from increased auditor independence and “fresh

viewpoints”. The adoption of mandatory audit partner rotation by many countries

suggests that the regulators believe the benefits outweigh costs of mandatory

rotation. However, the main findings in this study suggest that the actual effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation on earnings quality might be overestimated by

those regulators or prior studies.

67

In addition, many other factors could affect the actual audit quality besides

mandatory audit partner rotation. These factors might reduce the effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation. Firstly, audit partners are not the only ones who

can affect the quality of audit work. Although the audit partners have the final

responsibility for audit quality, it is the whole audit team who is doing the audit work

and preparing the audit files. Mandatory audit partner rotation only requires the

rotation of audit partners, not the whole audit team. Thus, it is possible that the

same audit team members are doing the actual audit work even after the partners

are changed, which could still deteriorate audit quality after a long time.

Secondly, client management and auditors have a joint responsibility for the quality

of financial statements (Antle & Nalebuff, 1991). Managers of client companies are

responsible for the ultimate quality of reported financial statements. This means

earnings quality is not only determined by auditors, but also the client management.

For example, managers could affect the quality of reported earnings through internal

control or accounting systems designed for the company. Companies with good

internal control environment or well-designed accounting systems are less likely to

get involved in earnings management. And the client management might have

stronger influence on earnings quality than audit partners. This explains why auditor

partner rotation has no significant effects on earnings quality.

Thirdly, auditors also concern about the litigation risk and audit firm’s reputation.

Even under a long client-auditor relationship, auditors still have strong motivation to

maintain auditor independence due to the potential litigation costs for audit failure.

Auditors add credibility to financial reports, so that their reputation is also a key

factor in assurance work. These two concerns about litigation costs and reputation

could increase the actual audit quality, therefore limiting the influence by mandatory

audit partner rotation. This could also explain the reason for the insignificant results

regarding the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation.

In sum, based on the data from China, my empirical results suggest no association

between mandatory audit partner rotation and earnings quality. However, these

68

insignificant results could also be caused by the missing control variables in the

regression model, which might have some important effects on earnings quality as

well. Firstly, the other members in the audit team might have more influences on

audit quality than audit partners. Secondly, managers in the client companies are

jointly responsible for earnings quality together with audit partners. At last, audit

partners’ concerns about the potential litigation costs and their reputation also

encourage them to maintain the auditor independence and audit quality. Not

including these factors into the regression model may reduce the effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation, which might explain the insignificant results in my

empirical analyses in some extent.

8.3 The effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on perceived

audit quality

In this section, I will try to answer the other main research question stated in the first

chapter, which is whether the mandatory audit partner rotation has effects on ERC or

perceived audit quality. Very few empirical studies have investigated the relation

between audit partner rotation and perceived audit quality. Chi et al. (2009) find

there is no significant difference in perceived audit quality between mandatory audit

partner rotation sample and non-rotation sample based on the data from Taiwan.

However, this might not be the case in Chinese capital market. Therefore, I still

hypothesized that companies that have mandatorily rotated audit partners have

higher perceived audit quality than companies that haven’t mandatorily rotated

audit partners.

To examine the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation on perceived audit

quality, I compare ERC in mandatory audit partner rotation sample with other three

benchmark samples, which are non-rotation sample, voluntary audit partner rotation

sample and mandatory rotation sample in prior year. The regression analysis shown

in Table 13 suggests that the incremental ERC in voluntary audit partner rotation

sample is significantly negative compared to ERC in mandatory audit partner rotation

69

sample. However, the sum of the two interaction coefficients is insignificant under

the column “MPR vs. NPR” or “MPR vs. MPRPY”. This means ERC in mandatory audit

partner rotation sample is not significantly different from ERC in non-rotation sample

or mandatory audit partner rotation sample in prior year, which is inconsistent with

the expectation in Hypothesis 2. In the end, I conclude that there is no consistent

evidence which supports that mandatory audit partner rotation enhances perceived

audit quality. My empirical results suggest there is no association between

mandatory audit partner rotation and perceived audit quality.

There could be several reasons which explain the insignificant results on perceived

audit quality. Firstly, most investors may not notice the rotation of audit partners in

the audit report. Even if the investors notice the audit partner rotation, there are still

several other factors they will take into consider when assessing the earnings quality.

The efficiency of internal control process, corporate governance and accounting

systems are all crucial factors which will determine the investor’s perception about

earnings quality or audit quality. And these factors might be more important than

audit partner rotation in investor’s mind when assessing the earnings quality.

Therefore, the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation become insignificant due

to those more important determinants on earnings quality or audit quality.

Secondly, it is possible that investors do not perceive the mandatory audit partner

rotation as a signal of higher audit quality at all. And the benefits of restoring

investor’s confidence through mandatory audit partner rotation might be

overestimated by government and prior literatures. As I have explained before in

section 8.2, the audit work is finished by the whole audit team instead of only two

audit partners. Investors may also notice this fact and they do not believe the change

of one or two audit partners will materially affect the earnings quality or audit

quality. Therefore, investors will not take mandatory audit partner rotation as a

determinant for the estimation of earnings quality or audit quality.

At last, I do find a significant larger ERC in mandatory audit partner rotation sample

than ERC in voluntary audit partner rotation sample. This suggests that investors may

70

view voluntary audit partner rotation as a way of “audit opinion shopping” by

companies. Therefore, investors perceive lower earnings quality for companies that

voluntarily rotate their audit partners and react less in the stock market to those

companies’ stocks.

In sum, my empirical results find no association between mandatory audit partner

rotation and perceived audit quality using the Chinese database. There could be

several reasons for these insignificant results. Firstly, there are many other factors

which may determine investors’ assessment of earnings quality or audit quality.

These other factors might be more important than mandatory audit partner rotation

to investors, which reduce the effects of audit partner rotation. Secondly, investors

may not believe the change of audit partners will materially affect the earnings

quality or audit quality.

8.4 The effects of audit firm tenure on actual and perceived audit

quality

In this section, additional research question about the effects of audit firm tenure

will be answered. And the corresponding Hypothesis 3 will be analyzed. In the first

chapter, an additional research question is issued to examine the effects of audit firm

tenure on actual and perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner

rotation. First, many regulators believe mandatory audit firm rotation can further

strengthen actual audit quality (Bates et al., 2012; European Commission, 2010).

Second, mandatory audit firm rotation might be more visible to investors compared

to mandatory audit partner rotation (Gates et al., 2007). These two beliefs are both

based on the assumption that long audit firm tenure deteriorates actual or perceived

audit quality. Therefore, I hypothesized that longer audit firm tenure is negatively

related to actual and perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner

rotation.

When using discretionary accruals as the dependent variable, Table 12 shows the

results for the effects of audit firm tenure on actual audit quality after controlling for

71

audit partner rotation. Panel A of Table 12 finds no significant results for the effects

of audit firm tenure on the absolute value of discretionary accruals. Panel B of Table

12 suggests that the income-increasing discretionary accruals in mandatory audit

partner rotation sample is significantly lower than that in prior year. Panel C of Table

12 finds that companies that are subject to mandatory audit partner rotation have

more income-decreasing accruals than companies that are subject to voluntary audit

partner rotation sample. The findings for the effects of audit firm tenure on actual

audit quality are mixed in my empirical results. Therefore, I conclude that there is no

association between audit firm tenure and actual audit quality after controlling for

audit partner tenure.

When using ERC as the dependent variable, Table 13 shows the results for the effects

of audit firm tenure on perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner

rotation. I focus on the sum of the two interaction coefficients for audit firm tenure

instead of individual coefficients in this part. Table 13 finds that the coefficients (

β6+β7) are all insignificantly negative under three comparisons. These findings

suggest that longer audit firm tenure does not significantly affect ERC after

controlling for audit partner rotation. Therefore, I conclude that there is no

association between audit firm tenure and perceived audit quality after controlling

for audit partner rotation.

There are several reasons for these insignificant findings. Firstly, audit firm tenure

may not materially affect actual and perceived audit quality. This is consistent with

the findings by Johnson et al. (2003) that long audit firm tenure is not associated

with accruals quality. The benefits of mandatory audit firm rotation are

overestimated by regulators and previous studies. Besides, investors may not notice

the length of audit firm tenure. And there are always several more important factors

than audit firm tenure that investors will take into consider when assessing the

earnings quality or audit quality. Those factors might reduce the effects of audit firm

tenure.

Secondly, litigation and reputation concerns by audit firms could also motivate the

72

auditors to maintain their audit quality. Audit firms, for example big 4, heavily rely on

their reputation for business. Therefore, audit firms will not sacrifice the audit quality

even under a long client-auditor relationship.

Thirdly, audit service provided by the same audit firm does not mean the service

provided by the same audit team. Sometimes, it is possible that audit members or

audit partners are rotated within the same audit firm. In this case, audit partner

rotation is already enough to maintain auditor independence and audit quality. At

the same time, different audit partners could also share the knowledge and

experience with the previous audit partners within the same audit firm. Investors

may also believe the rotation of audit partners is already enough to maintain auditor

independence. And investors will not perceive long audit firm tenure as a negative

effect on audit quality. Therefore, actual or perceived audit quality is not significantly

affected by audit firm tenure if audit partners are rotated within the audit firm. After

controlling for audit partner rotation, the effects of audit firm tenure are thereby

reduced.

In sum, the empirical results show no association between audit firm tenure and

actual and perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner rotation. On the

one hand, the reason for these insignificant results could be that audit firm tenure

has no effects on actual and perceived audit quality due to investor’s ignorance,

auditor’s litigation and reputation concerns. On the other hand, the effects of audit

firm tenure might be reduced by audit partner rotation or other determinants for

audit quality in investors’ mind.

8.5 Summary

In this chapter, I have answered all the main research question and additional

research question. I find there is no association between mandatory audit partner

rotation and actual and perceived audit quality. And there is also no association

between audit firm tenure and actual and perceived audit quality after controlling for

audit partner rotation. For actual audit quality, there might be some missing control

variables that have stronger influence on discretionary accruals other than audit

73

partner rotation or audit firm tenure. And it is the whole audit engagement team,

instead of audit partner or audit firm, that will determine the actual audit quality. For

perceived audit quality, investors may not notice the audit partner rotation or audit

firm tenure and thereby do not adjust their assessment of audit quality. Besides,

there are several other factors that investors will consider when assessing the audit

quality, which thereby reduce the effects of mandatory audit partner rotation or

audit firm tenure on perceived audit quality.

Chapter 9: Conclusion

9.1 Introduction

In this chapter, the main findings in this study will be summarized and the

implications of the findings on both literature and audit profession will be discussed.

After the conclusions, limitations in this study will be analyzed and I will also

recommend some corresponding solutions for future researches on the topic of audit

partner rotation.

9.2 Main conclusions and implications of findings

The empirical results in this study show that there is no relation between mandatory

audit partner rotation and actual and perceived audit quality. When using

performance-adjusted discretionary accruals as the proxy for actual audit quality, I

find that there is no significant relation between mandatory audit partner rotation

and actual audit quality. When using ERC as the proxy for perceived audit quality, I

find that the perceived audit quality in mandatory audit partner rotation sample is

significantly higher than that in voluntary audit partner rotation sample. However, no

significant results are found for perceived audit quality when using the other two

benchmarks (NPR and MPRPY). In the end, I conclude that there is no consistent

evidence which supports that mandatory audit partner rotation enhances actual and

perceived audit quality.

The main findings in this study have several implications. Firstly, I contribute to the

74

literature on audit partner rotation and audit quality. Mandatory audit partner

rotation has been restricted from every 7 years to every 5 years by SOX in 2002.

Besides the United States, many other countries (for example Australia, Germany,

Japan, Singapore and China) also require mandatory audit partner rotation. The

requirement is based on the assumption that mandatory audit partner rotation

enhances actual and perceived audit quality. However, many previous studies only

investigate the relation between audit partner tenure and actual and perceived audit

quality. Only the study by Chi et al. (2009) directly investigates the effects of

mandatory audit partner rotation using the data from Taiwan. This study follows the

method by Chi et al. (2009), but using the data from China. By examining the relation

between mandatory audit partner rotation and actual and perceived audit quality, I

find that there is limited evidence which supports mandatory audit partner rotation.

The main findings in this study are inconsistent with the assumption that mandatory

audit partner rotation enhances actual and perceived audit quality.

Secondly, I contribute to the literature on audit firm tenure and audit quality. In my

additional research question, I test the relation between audit firm tenure and actual

and perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner rotation. In many

countries, regulators are still considering the requirement of audit firm rotation in

addition to audit partner rotation. The main reason for requiring audit firm rotation

is that long audit firm tenure deteriorates actual and perceived audit quality.

Previous studies have no consistent conclusion about the effects of audit firm tenure.

This study finds that longer audit firm tenure is not related to lower actual and

perceived audit quality after controlling for audit partner rotation.

Lastly, this study has an implication on audit profession as well. The implementation

of mandatory audit partner/firm rotation is costly based on the analysis in Chapter 1.

And this study fails to find any benefits from mandatory audit partner/firm rotation.

Therefore, the requirement of mandatory audit partner/firm rotation might be

unnecessary for audit profession based on the findings in this study.

75

9.3 Limitations and recommendations for future research

The external validity of this study is relatively high since the sample size is large.

However, the internal validity of this study is relatively low. The effectiveness of the

main findings in this study is largely dependent on the ability of performance-

adjusted discretionary accruals and ERC to capture the concepts of actual and

perceived audit quality respectively. As is explained in Chapter 3, discretionary

accruals are the proxy for actual earnings quality, while ERC is the proxy for perceived

earnings quality in this study. And earnings quality is a proxy for audit quality.

Therefore, I am using proxy for proxy in my research design. Although those proxies

are widely used in previous studies as discussed in Chapter 4, they are still noisy. The

audit quality is a wider concept than earnings quality. For example, Audit opinion

issued in the audit reports can also be an indicator of audit quality. Besides the level

of discretionary accruals, earnings quality can also be reflected by earnings

persistence, earnings volatility. Moreover, investors could be stockholders, as well as

debt-holders. Earning Response Coefficients can only measure the reaction by

stockholders, but not debt-holders. Therefore, cost of debts can also be used to

measure the perceived audit quality. There are many other proxies that could be

used to measure the actual and perceived audit quality. The future research could

use those alternative proxies for actual and perceived audit quality to investigate the

association between mandatory audit partner rotation and actual and perceived

audit quality.

9.4 Summary

Based on the results in this study, I find limited evidence which supports that

mandatory audit partner rotation enhances actual and perceived audit quality. And

there is no significant relation between audit firm tenure and actual and perceived

audit quality after controlling for audit partner rotation. The main findings in this

study contribute to the literature on both audit partner rotation and audit firm

tenure. The requirement of mandatory audit partner/firm rotation for audit

76

profession might not be necessary. However, there are some limitations in this study.

The internal validity of this study is relatively low since the proxies I use in this study

cannot fully capture the concepts of actual and perceived audit quality. More

alternative proxies for actual and perceived audit quality are suggested for future

researches.

77

Bibliography

Ali, A., & Zarowin, P. (1992). The role of earnings levels in annual earnings-returns studies. Journal of Accounting Research, 30(2), 286-296.

Anthony, J., & Ramesh, K. (1992). Association between accounting performance measures and stock prices: A test of the life cycle hypothesis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 15(2-3), 203-227.

Antle, R., & Nalebuff, B. (1991). Conservatism and auditor-client negotiations. Journal of Accounting Research, 29(Supplement), 31-54.

Arens, A.A., Elder, R.J., & Beasley, M.S. (2014). Auditing and assurance services: An integrated approach. London, England: Pearson Education Publishing.

Bartov, E., Gui, F.A., & Tsui, J.S.L. (2000). Discretionary-accruals models and audit qualifications. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30(3), 421-452.

Bates, H.L., Waldrup, B.E., Jaeger, D.G., & Shea, V. (2012). Issues with mandatory audit firm rotation. Journal of Business and Accounting, 5(1), 70-75.

Becker, C.L., Defond, M.L., Jiambalvo, J.J., & Subramanyam, K.R. (1998). The effect of audit quality on earnings management. Contemporary Accounting Research, 15(1), 1-24.

Beck, P.J., Frecka, T.J., & Solomon, I. (1988). An empirical analysis of the relationship between MAS involvement and auditor tenure: Implications for auditor independence. Journal of Accounting Literature, 7(1), 65-84.

Benston, G.J., & Hartgraves, A.L. (2002). Enron: What happened and what we can learn from it. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 21(2), 105-127.

Carcello, J.V., & Nagy, A.L. (2004). Audit firm tenure and fraudulent financial reporting. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, 23(2), 55-69.

Carey, P., & Simnett, R. (2006). Audit partner tenure and audit quality. The Accounting Review, 81(3), 653-676.

Chasan, E. (2011). Arthur Levitt backs auditor term limits. The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved from http://mobile.blogs.wsj.com/cfo/2011/10/19/arthur-levitt-backs-auditor-term-limits/

78

Chen, X., & Xia, L. (2006). Auditor tenure and audit quality: Empirical evidence from the Chinese securities market. Accounting Research, 2006(1), 44-53.

Chen, C., Lin, C., & Lin, Y. (2008). Audit partner tenure, audit firm tenure, and discretionary accruals: Does long auditor tenure impair earnings quality? Contemporary Accounting Research, 25(2), 415-445.

Chi, W., & Huang, H. (2005). Discretionary accruals, audit-firm tenure and audit-partner tenure: Empirical evidence from Taiwan. Journal of Contemporary Accounting and Economics, 1(1), 65-92.

Chi, W., Huang, H., Liao, Y., & Xie, H. (2009). Mandatory audit partner rotation, audit quality, and market perception: Evidence from Taiwan. Contemporary Accounting Research, 26(2), 359-391.

Daniels, B.W., & Booker, Q. (2011). The effects of audit firm rotation on perceived auditor independence and audit quality. Research in Accounting Regulation, 23(1), 78-82.

Dart, E. (2011). UK investors’ perceptions of auditor independence. The British Accounting Review, 43(3), 173-185.

Daugherty, B., Dickins, D., & Higgs, J. (2010). Audit partner rotation: An analysis of benefits and costs (University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee Working Paper). Retrieved from https://aaahq.org/meetings/AUD2010/AuditPartnerRotation.pdf

DeAngelo, L.E. (1981). Auditor size and audit quality. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 3(3), 183-199.

Dechow, P.M., Richardson, S.A., & Tuna, I. (2003). Why are earnings kinky? An examination of the earnings management explanation. Review of Accounting Studies, 8(2-3), 355-384.

Dechow, P.M., & Dichev, I.D. (2002). The quality of accruals and earnings: The role of accrual estimation errors. The Accounting Review, 77(Supplement), 35-59.

Dechow, P.M., Sloan, R.G., & Sweeney, A.P. (1995). Detecting earnings management. The Accounting Review, 70(2), 193-225.

Dechow, P.M. (1994). Accounting earnings and cash flows as measures of firm performance: The role of accounting accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 18(7), 3-42.

79

DeFond, M.L., Raghunandan, K., & Subramanyam, K.R. (2002). Do non-audit service fees impair auditor independence? Evidence from going concern audit opinions. Journal of Accounting Research, 40(4), 1247-1274.

DeFond, M.L., & Park, C.W. (2001). The reversal of abnormal accruals and the market valuation of earnings surprises. The Accounting Review, 76(3), 375-404.

DeFond, M.L., & Jiambalvo, J. (1994). Debt covenant violation and manipulation of accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 17(1-2), 145-176.

Dies, D., & Giroux, G. (1992). Determinants of audit quality in the public sector. The Accounting Review, 67(3), 462-479.

Dopuch, N., King, R.R., & Schwartz, R. (2001). An experimental investigation of retention and rotation requirements. Journal of Accounting Research, 39(1), 93-117.

Easton, P.D., & Harris, T.S. (1991). Earnings as an explanatory variable for returns. Journal of Accounting Research, 29(1), 19-36.

Elliott, R.K. (2000). Testimony on auditor independence before the securities and exchange commission. Retrieved from http://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/s71300/testimony/elliott1.htm

European Commission. (2010). Audit policy: Lessons from the crisis. Retrieved from http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2010:0561:FIN:EN:PDF

Firth, M., Rui, O.M., & Wu, X. (2012). How do various forms of auditor rotation affect audit quality? Evidence from China. The International Journal of Accounting, 47(1), 109-138.

Francis, J.R., & Krishnan, J. (1999). Accounting accruals and auditor reporting conservatism. Contemporary Accounting Research, 16(1), 135-165.

Gates, S.K., Lowe, D.J., & Reckers, P.M.J. (2007). Restoring public confidence in capital markets through auditor rotation. Managerial Auditing Journal, 22(1), 5-17.

Geiger, M.A., & Raghunandan, K. (2002). Auditor tenure and audit reporting failures. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 21(1), 67-78.

General Accounting Office (GAO). (2003). Public accounting firms: Required study on the potential effects of mandatory audit firm rotation. Retrieved from http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d04216.pdf

Ghosh, A., & Moon, D. (2005). Auditor tenure and perceptions of audit quality. The 80

Accounting Review, 80(2), 585-612.

Gietzmann, M.B., & Sen, P.K. (2002). Improving auditor independence through selective mandatory rotation. International Journal of Auditing, 6(2), 183-210.

Goodwin, J., & Seow, J. (2002). The influence of corporate governance mechanisms on the quality of financial reporting and auditing: Perceptions of auditors and directors in Singapore. Accounting and Finance, 42(3), 195-223.

Graham, J.R., Harvey, C.R., & Rajgopal, S. (2005). The economic implications of corporate financial reporting. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 40(1-3), 3-73.

Herrick, T., & Barrionuevo, A. (2002). Were Enron, Anderson too close to allow auditor to do its job? The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved from http://online.wsj.com/article/0,,SB1011565452932132000,00.html

Jackson, A.B., Moldrich, M., & Roebuck, P. (2008). Mandatory audit firm rotation and audit quality. Managerial Auditing Journal, 23(5), 420-437.

Johnson, S. (2012). CFOs shout down idea of mandatory auditor rotation. CFO.com. Retrieved from: http://ww2.cfo.com/auditing/2012/03/cfos-shout-down-idea-of-mandatory-auditor-rotation/

Johnson, V.E., Khurana, I.K., & Reynolds, J. (2002). Audit-firm tenure and the quality of financial reports. Contemporary Accounting Research, 19(4), 637-660.

Jones, J.J. (1991). Earnings management during import relief investigations. Journal of Accounting Research, 29(2), 193-228.

Kaplan, S.E., & Mauldin, E.G. (2008). Auditor rotation and the appearance of independence: Evidence from non-professional investors. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 27(2), 177-192.

Knapp, M. (1991). Factors that audit committees use as surrogates for audit quality. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory, 10(1), 35-52.

Kothari, S. P., Leone, A. J., & Wasley, C. E. (2005). Performance Matched Discretionary Accrual Measures. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39(1), 163-197.

Lyke, B., & Jickling, M. (2002). WorldCom: The accounting scandal. Retrieved from http://wew.iwar.org.uk/news-archive/crs/13384.pdf

Moore, D.A., Tetlock, P.E., Tanlu, L., & Bazerman, M.H. (2006). Conflict of interest and the case of auditor independence: Moral seduction and strategic issue cycling.

81

Academy of Management Review, 31(1), 10-29.

Myers, J.N., Myers, L.A., & Omer, T.C. (2003). Exploring the term of the auditor-client relationship and the quality of earnings: A case for mandatory auditor rotation? The Accounting Review, 78(3), 779-799.

Nelson, M.W., Elliot, J.A., & Tarpley, R.L. (2002). Evidence from auditors about managers’ and auditors’ earnings management decisions. The Accounting Review, 77(Supplement), 175-202.

Raiborn, C., Schorg, C.A., & Massoud, M. (2006). Should auditor rotation be mandatory? The Journal of Corporate Accounting and Finance, 17(4), 37-49.

Richardson, S., Tuna, I., & Wu, M. (2002). Predicting earnings management: The case of earnings restatements. (University of Pennsylvania Working Paper). Retrieved from http://homepages.rpi.edu/home/17/wuq2/public_html/restatement%20reference/richardson%20tuna%20and%20wu%202003.pdf

Ronen, J., & Yaari, V. (2008). Earnings management: Emerging insights in theory, practice and research. New York, USA: Springer Science Publishing.

Schipper, K., & Vincent, L. (2003). Earnings quality. Accounting Horizons, 17(Supplement), 97-110.

Scott, W.R. (2012). Financial accounting theory. Toronto, Canada: Pearson Prentice Hall Publications.

Seipp, E., Kinsella, S., & Lindberg, D.L. (2011). Xerox, Inc. Issues in Accounting Education, 26(1), 219-240.

Sinnett, W.M. (2004). Are there good reasons for auditor rotation? Financial Executive, 20(7), 29-32.

Taylor, S.D. (2005). The role of the auditor partner in audit fee determination. (Australian National University Working Paper). Retrieved from http://trove.nla.gov.au/work/35655759?selectedversion=NBD43067225

Teoh, S.H., & Lim, C.C. (1996). An empirical study of the effects of audit committees, disclosure of nonaudit fees, and other issues on audit independence: Malaysian evidence. Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 5(2), 231-248.

Teoh, S.H., & Wong, T.J. (1993). Perceived auditor quality and the earnings response coefficient. The Accounting Review, 68(2), 346-366.

82

The Committee on the Financial Aspects of Corporate Governance. (1992). Report of the committee on the financial aspects of corporate governance. Retrieved from http://www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/cadbury.pdf

The Conference Board. (2003). Commission on public trust and private enterprise: Findings and recommendations. Retrieved from http://www.conference-board.org/pdf_free/SR-03-04-ES.pdf

Warfield, T.D., Wild, J.J., & Wild, K.L. (1995). Managerial ownership, accounting choices, and informativeness of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 20(1), 61-91.

Ye, C., Xu, W., & Han, Y. (2013). The effects of different forms of auditor rotation on audit quality: Empirical evidence form Chinese securities market. Auditing and Assurance, 2013(4), 90-96.

83

Appendix

Table 1: Literature review on audit partner rotation/tenure and audit quality

Authors Object of

study

Sample Method Outcome

Actual audit quality:

Chi and Huang (2005)

X: audit partner tenure

Y: earnings quality

1337 firm year observations from 1998 to

2001 in Taiwan

Archival: non-linear regression analysis between audit partner tenure and discretionary accruals.

Longer audit partner tenure helps to produce higher earnings quality, but

extreme long audit partner tenure results in lower earnings quality. The cut-off

point of audit partner tenure is nearly 5 years.

Carey and Simnett (2006)

X: audit partner tenureY: audit quality

1021 companies in 1995 in Australia

Archival: regression analysis between audit partner tenure and three measures of audit quality (the auditor’s propensity to issue a

going-concern opinion; absolute and signed values of abnormal working capital accruals; the

extent of earnings management).

Audit partners with a long tenure are less likely to issue a going-concern opinion. Audit quality measured by AWCA is not significantly associated with long audit

partner tenure. Client company with long audit partner tenure has a high

probability to artificially beat targets

84

Chen, Lin and Lin (2008)

X: audit partner tenure

Y: earnings quality

5213 firm year observations from 1990 to

2001 in Taiwan

Archival: regression analysis between audit partner tenure and performance adjusted

discretionary accruals.

When absolute or positive values of discretionary accruals are used, the results show that earnings quality

increases significantly with longer audit partner tenure. When raw or negative

values of discretionary accruals are used, results are not significant.

Chi, Huang, Liao and

Xie (2009)

X: audit partner rotationY: audit quality

1131 firm year observations in 2004 in Taiwan

Archival: Compare performance matched abnormal accruals in mandatory audit partner

rotation group with three other benchmark groups

There is no significant difference in audit quality between mandatory rotation

group and non-mandatory rotation group or voluntary rotation group. The audit quality in mandatory rotation group is

significantly lower than itself in prior year.

Firth, Rui and Wu (2010)

X: different forms of auditor rotationY: audit quality

8560 firm year observations from 1997 to 2005 in China

Archival: Compare auditors’ propensity to issue a modified audit opinion among various forms

of auditor rotation (mandatory/voluntary partner rotation, mandatory/voluntary firm

rotation, non-rotation).

Companies in mandatory partner rotation group have a higher probability to receive a modified audit opinion compared to the

companies in non-rotation group.

85

Perceived audit quality:

Gates, Lowe and Reckers (2007)

X: audit firm rotation and audit partner rotation

Y: public confidence in earnings quality

79 MBA students and 92 law

students in USA

Experiment: two separate behavioral studies on MBA

and Law students: a between-subjects design with one-way analysis of variance for each

study.

Audit firm rotation significantly increases investor’s confidence in company’s reported

earnings, while audit partner rotation has little help in restoring investor’s confidence

Kaplan and Mauldin (2008)

X: audit firm rotation and audit partner rotation

Y: non-professional investors’ perceived

auditor independence

236 MBA students in USA

Experiment: two experiments on MBA students: a 2×2

between-subjects design that manipulates auditor rotation

and audit committee strength.

With audit partner rotation in place, audit firm rotation does not further strengthen perceived

auditor independence. And investors value strong audit committee.

Chi, Huang, Liao and

Xie (2009)

X: audit partner rotation

Y: perceived audit quality

1634 firm year comparison

observations in 2004 in Taiwan

Archival: Compare ERC in mandatory audit partner rotation group with three other benchmark groups

ERC is not significantly different between 2 comparison samples, which are mandatory

rotation sample versus non-rotation sample or mandatory rotation sample in prior year. But the ERC in mandatory rotation sample is significantly

larger than that in voluntary rotation sample.

86

Table 2: Literature review on audit firm rotation/tenure and audit quality

Authors Object of

study

Sample Method Outcome

Actual audit quality:

Geiger and Raghunandan

(2002)

X: audit firm tenure

Y: audit reporting

failure

117 companies entering into bankruptcy during 1996-1998

in USA

Archival: regression analysis between audit opinions (dummy

variable) issued before bankruptcy and audit firm

tenure.

There are more audit reporting failures in the earlier years of audit firm tenure.

Johnson, Khurana and

Reynolds (2002)

X: audit firm tenureY: earnings

quality

2463 (2280) firm year observations for the unexpected accruals

(persistence) test from Big 6 clients during 1986-1995 in

USA

Archival: regression analysis between audit firm tenure and absolute values of unexpected

accruals or persistence of accruals.

Short audit firm tenure results in decreased accruals quality, while

medium or long auditor tenure is not associated with accruals quality.

Myers, Myers and Omer (2003)

X: audit firm tenureY: earnings

quality

42302 firm year observations during 1988-2000 in USA

Archival: regression analysis between audit firm tenure and absolute, signed and raw values of both discretionary accruals

and current accruals.

Longer audit firm tenure significantly decreases the level of both

discretionary accruals and current accruals.

87

Chi and Huang (2005)

X: audit firm tenureY: earnings

quality

1337 firm year observations during 1998-2001 in Taiwan

Archival: non-linear regression analysis between audit firm

tenure and discretionary accruals.

Longer audit firm tenure helps to produce higher earnings quality, but

extreme long audit firm tenure results in lower earnings quality. The cut-off point of audit firm tenure is nearly 5

years.Chen and Xia

(2006)X: audit

firm tenureY: earnings

quality

2667 firm year observations during 2000-2002 in China

Archival: non-linear regression analysis between audit firm

tenure and discretionary accruals.

Longer audit firm tenure helps to produce higher earnings quality, but

extreme long audit firm tenure results in lower earnings quality. The cut-off point of audit firm tenure is nearly 6

years.Jackson,

Moldrich and Roebuck (2008)

X: audit firm tenure

Y: audit quality

1750 firm year observations during 1995-2003 in Australia

Archival: regression analysis between audit firm tenure and

propensity to issue a going-concern opinion or discretionary

accruals.

Longer auditor tenure will increase auditors’ propensity to issue a going-

concern opinion, but has no significant effects on accruals quality.

Chen, Lin and Lin (2008)

X: audit firm tenureY: earnings

quality

5213 firm year observations from 1990 to 2001 in Taiwan

Archival: regression analysis between audit firm tenure and

performance adjusted discretionary accruals after

controlling for partner tenure.

Longer audit firm tenure increases the earnings quality. Adding mandatory firm rotation to mandatory partner

rotation has no positive effects on audit quality.

88

Perceived audit quality:

Ghosh and

Moon (2005)

X: audit firm tenureY: public confidence in earnings quality

38794 firm-year observations

during 1990-2000 in USA

Archival: regression analysis between audit firm tenure and

ERC (stock/debt rankings or analyst’s earnings forecast).

Both investors’ and information intermediaries’ perception about earnings

quality is positively associated with audit firm tenure.

Dart (2011)

X: audit firm tenureY: investor’s

perception about auditor

independence

113 institutional investors and 254

private investors in UK

Experiment: a questionnaire-based study.

Investors in UK are relatively unconcerned about the threat of long audit firm tenure compared to other threats in the survey.

Daniels and

Booker (2011)

X: audit firm rotation and audit firm tenure

Y: loan officer’s perception of auditor

independence and audit quality

207 bank loan officers in USA

Experiment: a between-subject design. The versions of the case are different only as it relates to the rotation policy and length of tenure within the rotation policy.

Audit firm rotation improves loan officer’s perception about auditor independence, but does not affect perceived audit quality. Audit firm tenure is not significantly associated with

both perceived auditor independence and perceived audit quality.

89

Table 3: Sample selection

MPR, NPR and VPR sample selection

Companies listed on SSE or SZSE in 2003 from CSMAR database

1290

Less Companies with missing audit partner information (232) Companies belong to financial industry (43)Preliminary sample 1015Sample label MPR NPR VPRPreliminary sample

111 478 426

LessCompanies delisted in or before 2003

(2) (39) (23)

Final sample for the first regression

109 439 403

Less Companies with missing daily stock price information

(0) (1) (0)

Final sample for the second regression

109 438 403

90

Table 4: Descriptive statistics for actual audit quality

Panel A: Mandatory partner rotation sample (MPR, n=109)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation│DA│ 0.000 0.395 0.064 0.070 AGE 3.000 13.000 7.321 2.063 SIZE 8.023 9.992 9.174 0.371 IndGrowth -1.094 0.966 0.592 0.462 CFO -0.256 0.457 0.058 0.101 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.055 0.229 FTenure 1.000 11.000 4.183 2.065          Panel B: Non-rotation sample (NPR, n=439)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation│DA│ 0.000 0.482 0.055 0.058 AGE 1.000 13.000 6.337 2.594 SIZE 7.849 10.271 9.125 0.372 IndGrowth -1.094 0.966 0.606 0.448 CFO -0.290 0.486 0.047 0.084 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.062 0.241 FTenure 1.000 11.000 3.597 1.398        Panel C: Voluntary partner rotation sample (VPR, n=403)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation│DA│ 0.000 0.382 0.055 0.055 AGE 2.000 13.000 6.092 2.552 SIZE 7.770 10.789 9.154 0.402 IndGrowth -3.865 0.966 0.596 0.492 CFO -0.314 0.362 0.050 0.083 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.099 0.299 FTenure 1.000 11.000 3.295 1.657  Panel D: Mandatory partner rotation in prior year (MPRPY, n=109)

  Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation│DA│ 0.000 0.385 0.055 0.066 AGE 2.000 12.000 6.321 2.063 SIZE 8.179 9.939 9.137 0.353 IndGrowth -0.393 14.095 0.479 2.058

91

CFO -0.356 0.436 0.049 0.090 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.092 0.290 FTenure 1.000 10.000 3.706 1.553          

92

Table 5: Tests of Normality for actual audit quality

Panel A: MPR vs. NPR

  Kolmogorov-Smirnova Shapiro-WilkStatistic df Sig. Statistic df Sig.

│DA│ .175 548 .000 .743 548 .000a. Lilliefors Significance Correction

Panel B: MPR vs. VPR

  Kolmogorov-Smirnova Shapiro-WilkStatistic df Sig. Statistic df Sig.

│DA│ .165 512 .000 .760 512 .000a. Lilliefors Significance Correction

Panel C: MPR vs. MPRPY

  Kolmogorov-Smirnova Shapiro-WilkStatistic df Sig. Statistic df Sig.

│DA│ .192 218 .000 .725 218 .000a. Lilliefors Significance Correction

93

Table 6: Independent samples test for actual audit quality

Panel A: MPR vs. NPR

 

Levene's Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means

F Sig. t dfSig. (2-tailed)

Mean Differenc

e

Std. Error Differenc

e

95% Confidence Interval of the

DifferenceLower Upper

│DA│ Equal variances assumed

2.072 0.151 -1.470 546 0.142 -0.009 0.006 -0.022 0.003

Equal variances not assumed

    -1.307 146.249 0.193 -0.009 0.007 -0.024 0.005

Panel B: MPR vs. VPR

  Levene's Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means

F Sig. t df Sig. (2-tailed)

Mean Differenc

e

Std. Error Differenc

e

95% Confidence Interval of the

Difference

94

Lower Upper│DA│ Equal

variances assumed

2.607 0.107 -1.411 510 0.159 -0.009 0.006 -0.021 0.003

Equal variances not assumed

    -1.228 145.705 0.221 -0.009 0.007 -0.023 0.005

Panel C: MPR vs. MPRPY

 

Levene's Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means

F Sig. t dfSig. (2-tailed)

Mean Differenc

e

Std. Error Differenc

e

95% Confidence Interval of the

DifferenceLower Upper

│DA│ Equal variances assumed

0.023 0.880 -0.958 216 0.339 -0.009 0.009 -0.027 0.009

Equal variances not assumed

    -0.958 215.220 0.339 -0.009 0.009 -0.027 0.009

95

Table 7: Test statistics for actual audit quality

Panel A: MPR vs. NPR

  │DA│Mann-Whitney U

21965.000

Wilcoxon W

118545.000

Z -1.325Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

.185

a. Grouping Variable: BMK

Panel B: MPR vs. VPR

  │DA│Mann-Whitney U

20558.500

Wilcoxon W

101964.500

Z -1.025Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

.305

a. Grouping Variable: BMK

Panel C: MPR vs. MPRPY

  │DA│Mann-Whitney U

5163.000

Wilcoxon W

11158.000

Z -1.670Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

.095

a. Grouping Variable: BMK

96

97

Table 8: Descriptive statistics for perceived audit quality

Panel A: Mandatory partner rotation sample (MPR, n=109)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. DeviationCAR -1.218 0.698 -0.395 0.273 E -0.222 0.189 0.015 0.051 ΔE -0.243 1.198 0.020 0.133 AGE 3.000 13.000 7.321 2.063 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.055 0.229 Growth 1.056 6.536 1.903 0.874 Persist -0.683 0.247 -0.267 0.218 Volatility 0.009 2.751 0.159 0.273 Beta 0.000 1.368 0.941 0.306 Size 8.528 10.217 9.289 0.334 Leverage 0.073 4.343 0.547 0.427 FTenure 1.000 11.000 4.183 2.065

Panel B: Non-rotation sample (NPR, n=438)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. DeviationCAR -1.589 0.561 -0.420 0.264 E -0.376 0.288 0.017 0.049 ΔE -0.168 0.381 0.007 0.046 AGE 1.000 13.000 6.345 2.592 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.059 0.237 Growth 0.989 15.163 1.957 1.156 Persist -0.814 0.339 -0.277 0.190 Volatility 0.008 0.962 0.132 0.105 Beta 0.000 2.235 1.007 0.212 Size 8.508 10.540 9.257 0.325 Leverage 0.011 4.883 0.512 0.301 FTenure 1.000 11.000 3.600 1.397  Panle C: Voluntary partner rotation sample (VPR, n=403)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. DeviationCAR -1.134 0.594 -0.414 0.265 E -0.569 0.165 0.013 0.066 ΔE -0.531 1.000 0.006 0.085 AGE 2.000 13.000 6.092 2.552 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.099 0.299 Growth 0.911 24.719 2.054 1.489

98

Persist -0.677 0.838 -0.265 0.202 Volatility 0.008 0.928 0.141 0.121 Beta -0.126 1.408 0.967 0.236 Size 8.542 10.947 9.310 0.378 Leverage 0.027 4.229 0.510 0.334 FTenure 1.000 11.000 3.295 1.657  Panel D: Mandatory partner rotation in prior year (MPRPY, n=109)

Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Std. DeviationCAR -1.281 0.020 -0.643 0.192 E -0.675 0.101 0.002 0.075 ΔE -0.654 0.132 -0.008 0.074 AGE 2.000 12.000 6.321 2.063 Big4 0.000 1.000 0.092 0.290 Growth 1.087 11.262 2.408 1.488 Persist -0.527 0.084 -0.252 0.160 Volatility 0.006 2.748 0.157 0.263 Beta 0.000 1.369 0.951 0.293 Size 8.748 9.992 9.362 0.273 Leverage 0.083 5.948 0.540 0.561 FTenure 1.000 10.000 3.706 1.553      

99

Table 9: Tests of Normality for perceived audit quality

Panel A: MPR vs. NPR

 Kolmogorov-Smirnova Shapiro-Wilk

Statistic df Sig. Statistic df Sig.

CAR .048 547 .004 .980 547 .000

a. Lilliefors Significance Correction

Panel B: MPR vs. VPR

 Kolmogorov-Smirnova Shapiro-Wilk

Statistic df Sig. Statistic df Sig.

CAR .046 512 .011 .988 512 .000

a. Lilliefors Significance Correction

Panel C: MPR vs. MPRPY

 Kolmogorov-Smirnova Shapiro-Wilk

Statistic df Sig. Statistic df Sig.

CAR .071 218 .010 .969 218 .000

a. Lilliefors Significance Correction

100

Table 10: Independent samples test for perceived audit quality

Panel A: MPR vs. NPR

 

Levene's Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means

F Sig. t dfSig. (2-tailed)

Mean Differenc

e

Std. Error Differenc

e

95% Confidence Interval of the

DifferenceLower Upper

CAR Equal variances assumed

0.018 0.893 -0.885 545 0.376 -0.025 0.028 -0.081 0.031

Equal variances not assumed

    -0.868 161.953 0.387 -0.025 0.029 -0.082 0.032

Panel B: MPR vs. VPR

  Levene's Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means

F Sig. t df Sig. (2-tailed)

Mean Differenc

e

Std. Error Differenc

e

95% Confidence Interval of the

Difference

101

Lower UpperCAR Equal

variances assumed

0.071 0.790 -0.664 510 0.507 -0.019 0.029 -0.076 0.037

Equal variances not assumed

    -0.653 167.289 0.515 -0.019 0.029 -0.077 0.039

Panel C: MPR vs. MPRPY

 

Levene's Test for Equality of Variances t-test for Equality of Means

F Sig. t dfSig. (2-tailed)

Mean Differenc

e

Std. Error Differenc

e

95% Confidence Interval of the

DifferenceLower Upper

CAR Equal variances assumed

9.038 0.003 -7.751 216 0.000 -0.248 0.032 -0.310 -0.185

Equal variances not assumed

    -7.751 193.763 0.000 -0.248 0.032 -0.311 -0.185

102

Table 11: Test statistics for perceived audit quality

Panel A: MPR vs. NPR

  CARMann-Whitney U

22473.000

Wilcoxon W

118614.000

Z -.947Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

.344

a. Grouping Variable: BMK

Panel B: MPR vs. VPR

  CARMann-Whitney U

20928.000

Wilcoxon W

102334.000

Z -.756Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

.450

a. Grouping Variable: BMK

Panel C: MPR vs. MPRPY

  CARMann-Whitney U

2438.000

Wilcoxon W

8433.000

Z -7.522Asymp. Sig. (2-tailed)

.000

a. Grouping Variable: BMK

103

104


Recommended