+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

Date post: 02-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: enzomartin
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 31

Transcript
  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    1/31

    307

    Craft specialization, the reorganization ofproduction relations and state formation

    THOMAS C. PATTERSON

    Department of Anthropology, University of California

    ABSTRACTSince the late 1970s, archaeologists have been concerned with theorigins and development of craft specialization in early civilizations.More recently, some have examined the organization of production,the identities of artisans, the use and consumption of the goods theyproduced, and the cultural and social meanings of those objects. Muchof this literature is rooted in the conceptual framework of societalevolutionism, which was formulated by eighteenth-century theorists,who were attempting to account for the rise of capitalist agriculture

    rather than the development of precapitalist forms of craft produc-tion. This article examines the premises of the conceptual frameworkas well as the political-economic and ideological context in whichsocietal evolutionism was formulated. It suggests that a theoreticalframework derived from Marxs writings after 1857 provides insightsinto the organization of craft production and an alternative expla-nation of the role specialization played in the rise of civilization.

    KEYWORDS

    classical political economy

    craft specialization

    liberal social theory Marxism production relations proto-industrialization societalevolution state formation

    Journal of Social Archaeology A R T I C L E

    Copyright 2005 SAGE Publications (www.sagepublications.com)

    ISSN 1469-6053 Vol 5(3): 307337 DOI: 10.1177/1469605305057570

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    2/31

    308 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    INTRODUCTION

    What roles did craft production and specialization play in the origins of

    civilization? How were they related to the concomitant processes of socialdifferentiation, the increasing division of labor, the formation of villagecommunities and expanded exchange relations typically associated with thistransformation? These questions have long vexed archaeologists. Betweenthe mid-1930s and the mid-1950s, V. Gordon Childe (1936/1983, 1958:16273) theorist of socioeconomic development and life-long socialist was the first archaeologist to attempt a sustained, socioeconomic analysisof the rise of civilization (Wailes, 1996). Childes thesis of uneven andcombined development was historically contingent and composed of three

    elements: (1) agriculture facilitated surplus production over subsistenceneeds and underwrote both technical and social divisions of labor; (2) theruling classes in the Mesopotamian lowlands used part of this surplus tosupport full-time craft specialists, notably metalsmiths who relied on oresobtained from the periphery; and (3) since the initial costs on the periph-ery were underwritten by the lowland elites, development occurred on themargins of civilization without significant local investment, where supplywas met by independent smiths-cum-traders hawking their wares frompetty chief to petty chief, and innovation was unfettered by bureaucratic

    control (Wailes, 1996: 9). It is also noteworthy that Childe (1950/2004)discussed the development of craft specialization in the context of theUrban Revolution (the formation of precapitalist states) and posited asuccession of artisans from those attached to the ruling classes to indepen-dent, itinerant smiths.

    In developing his thesis about the emergence of craft specialization,Childe, the Marxist, engaged the societal evolutionism of liberal theoristsfrom Adam Smith through Herbert Spencer to mile Durkheim and incor-porated their arguments into his own (Patterson, 2003: 3362). From thisperspective, Childe viewed the rise of full-time craft specialists as part ofincreasing social structural differentiation, the emerging interdependencyof food-producers and artisans and the growth of market exchange. Thedifferentiation of production tasks marked the simultaneous witheringaway of the self-sufficiency characteristic of neolithic (agro-pastoral)communities that produced a surplus and the formation of a new kind ofsociety characterized by a division of labor and the production of goods forexchange. The division of labor in the emerging society had three dimen-sions: (1) the distinctions that prevailed among those individuals whoproduced different goods for exchange; (2) the separation of direct pro-

    ducers from those who appropriated their goods and labor power arguably the distinction between manual and mental labor; and (3) thesimultaneous separation of itinerant artisans from their natal communities

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    3/31

    309Patterson Craft specialization

    and formation of a domestic or household mode of production thatreflected their mode of subsistence. Thus, craft specialization was linkedwith production for exchange and with the activities of individuals and

    potentially, by extension, their families or households who were removedat least spatially from the communities to which they belonged. The motordriving this emerging division of labor and ultimately the rise of urbansociety was a technical one, the development of the productive forces (i.e.the Neolithic Revolution).

    From the late 1970s onward as Cathy Costin (1991,1998,2001) and JohnClark (1995) have shown a number of archaeologists following Childeslead have clarified the issues, debated,and refined the notion of craft special-ization. These are some of the more informative and insightful conversationsthat have occurred in archaeology in the last 30 years constructively criticalyet polite and respectful in tone. Some highlights include the distinction thatRobert Evans (1978) drew between part-time and full-time craft production;the distinction that Tim Earle (1981) and Elizabeth Brumfiel and Earle(1987) made between independent artisans and those attached to patrons;Joan Gero and Cristina Scattolins (2002: 169) observation that the opposi-tion posited between domestic and specialized production not only makesit impossible to compare the two but also relegates household divisions oflabor to ongoing background work that varies only in uninteresting ways;and Edward Harriss (2002: 86) question of whether specialized production

    was intended for local consumption or export. In the last decade or so,atten-tion has shifted away from the origins and historical development of craftspecialization toward a series of closely related issues: the organization ofproduction in particular socioeconomic, political and cultural settings; thesocial and cultural identities of artisans; the use or consumption of the goodsthey produced; and even the cultural meanings attached to those goods.These have added significantly to our understanding of craft production andits place in ancient political economies (e.g. Costin, 2004; Schortman andUrban, 2004; Stein, 1998, Stein and Blackman, 1993).

    What has made the conversations so productive is that the participantshave not limited their discussions solely to archaeological data nor claimed,for the most part, that archaeological evidence is superior to that derivedfrom historical or comparative ethnographic accounts. Instead, they haveexamined the interconnections of data and the practice of archaeology. Theparticipants have related both data and methods to their conceptualcategories, and they have examined the conceptual categories themselves.Nonetheless, nagging questions about the historical development of craftspecialization still remain, especially with regard to the dynamics that

    occurred during the transitional phase separating pre-state, neolithicvillages from the various forms of early state-based societies. For example,where and in what contexts did Childes wandering smiths acquire theirknowledge of metallurgy and practical skills in the first place?

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    4/31

    310 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    There are several reasons for the persistence of questions about the riseof craft specialization. The absence of evidence that would confirm or invali-date claims is certainly one reason; however, it is useful to keep in mind that

    Childe formulated his thesis nearly six decades ago when fewer data wereavailable. A more important reason, in my view, is that the language ofsocietal or cultural evolutionism makes it difficult to examine problems ofhistorical development that are of interest to archaeologists. This resultsfrom a set of built-in assumptions about exchange, community, the rural-urban divide, distinctions between manual and mental labor, and evenspecialization itself. The assumptions are a product of the foundational socialtheories we use and of the sociopolitical and ideological contexts in whichthey were developed. In the pages that follow, I want to examine this webof often implicit assumptions that underpin the conceptual categories we useto explain craft specialization and what theorists, both eighteenth-centuryand modern, have said about the organization of production during the earlystages of capitalism, when social life and production were still largely ruralin Western Europe (a region where sociohistorical and economic develop-ment is probably better documented than any of the places or periods typi-cally discussed by archaeologists). I would then like to consider how and inwhat ways Karl Marx broke with the foundational theories of the mid-nine-teenth century. Finally, I would to offer one possible construction, based onwhat Marx wrote after 1857, regarding the interconnections of craft special-

    ization, changing property relations, and the rise of states, including theprecapitalist tributary states of interest to archaeologists.

    SOCIETAL EVOLUTIONISM: ITS POLITICAL-ECONOMIC

    AND IDEOLOGICAL CONTEXTS

    Societal evolutionism arose in the same contexts that facilitated the

    development of liberalism and classical political economy. The ideas andsentiments of liberalism and mercantilism have been intimately linked sincethe seventeenth century. These include laissez-faire (the danger of stateintervention), individualism (the needs of the individual constitute the basicunit of economic policy), utilitarianism (Jeremy Benthams the greatesthappiness of the greatest number), the centrality of commerce or exchange(as the primary building block of community and as a means of obtainingwealth and power), and notions about greedy individuals competing forscarce resources as well as economic rationality (Heckscher, 1955: 469). The

    ideas and sentiments have in turn had a profound shaping effect on boththe conceptual frameworks and languages of economic analysis that AdamSmith, the French Physiocrats and others developed in the eighteenthcentury (e.g. Magnusson, 1994; Meek, 1962). Smith (1776/1976, vol. 1:

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    5/31

    311Patterson Craft specialization

    1718), for example, argued that modern society began with the advent ofproduction for exchange in the market and provided three reasons whypeople engage in market exchange: interdependence increases productiv-

    ity; exchange is a natural human propensity; and greed has become a centralfeature of human nature in commercial society (Gudeman, 2001: 82). Thisweb of assumptions also influenced the naturalistic, evolutionary perspec-tive on human history that various French and Scottish Enlightenmentwriters, including Smith, formulated from the middle to the end of theeighteenth century (Meek, 1976; Patterson, 1997; Trigger,1998: 3041).1 Thisdiscourse was not limited to participants from a single national state orcontinent. In slightly different words, the conceptual elements as well as therhetorical styles of liberalism, political economy and evolutionism havebeen intertwined for more than two centuries. Today, these interconnec-tions are too often unacknowledged or summarily dismissed as trivial,unimportant, or of antiquarian interest. However, they are importantprecisely because they affect the way we think about evidence, draw infer-ences and present arguments.

    The political-economic context in which liberalism, classical politicaleconomy, and societal evolutionism were formulated occurred severalcenturies after the dissolution of feudalism in Western Europe.2 In thesixteenth and seventeenth centuries, as the Americas3 were increasinglyenmeshed in commercial relations, the merchant associations from the

    sovereign states of Western Europe argued with increasing vigor that theyshould not be encumbered with the taxes and tariffs imposed by feudallords. In their view, commerce and the expansion of the market should beunencumbered since it was the source of wealth and power. Here, the senti-ments of the trading companies often coincided with those of would-beabsolutist monarchs who wished to appropriate the revenues obtained bythe nobility in order to use them for their own purposes, most notably tostrengthen their own positions internally and with respect to the monarchsof other national states. The policies advocated and supported by both the

    merchants and monarchs promoted manufactured exports, low wages,cheap raw material imports and favorable balances of trade (surpluses) thatwould yield a net inflow of gold or silver. This was the ideological andconceptual language of mercantilism. It is important to note that commod-ity production and wage labor, two defining elements of the capitalist modeof production, were already realities in the largely rural societies of WesternEurope.

    Other worldviews, besides that of the merchants, were voiced from the1690s onward.4 The most notable, for our purpose here, was that of an

    emerging class of agrarian capitalists farmers and husbandmen whoproduced foodstuffs and raw materials, such as wool or hides, for local,regional and national markets. They emphasized the importance of agri-culture for restructuring and developing the national economy. Their

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    6/31

    312 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    perspectives were championed by John Locke, the French Physiocrats andAdam Smith, among others who argued with different emphases that agri-culture and husbandry were a source of wealth. The circumstances in which

    their perspectives were voiced varied according to place and time. Forexample, when John Locke wrote in the 1690s, landlords controlled 7075percent of all cultivable land in England, and the landlord/tenant/laborerstructure that facilitated investment in and the development of rural capi-talism was already in place (Brenner, 1976/1985: 489; Tribe, 1981: 35100;Wood, 1984: 3171). By contrast, throughout the eighteenth century, 75percent of the French population was composed of peasants who held4550 percent of [the] cultivable land, often in the form of scattered openfields (McNally, 1993: 11; Brenner, 1976/1985: 61). Neverthless, many of theFrench peasants were impoverished tenants burdened with high rents, lowproductivity, low prices on foodstuffs and restrictions on the export of agri-cultural products; they struggled to be self-sufficient in this still largely ruralsociety (Jones, 1988: 130; Nikin, 1975: 84). In the 1760s, the French Physio-crats argued that the development of large-scale capitalist agriculture,which was quite limited at the time, was both part of the natural economicorder (a process guided by natural law) and a means for catching up withEngland;5 they also believed that mercantilist policies, which favoredcommerce and manufacturing, distorted or corrupted the unfolding of thenatural economic order (Meek, 1962). Adam Smith, the Scottish moral

    philosopher whose Wealth of Nations (1776) would later become a foun-dational text of classical political economy, wrote at a time (the third-quarter of the eighteenth century) when a majority of the inhabitants ofScotland, especially in the highlands and the islands, still preferred hunting,fishing, littoral harvesting and subsistence agriculture to wage labor(Whatley, 1997: 917). Like Locke and the Physiocrats, Smith consideredagriculture to be the most productive economic sector, whose developmentwas essential to balanced economic growth (McNally, 1988: 210). He wasalso critical of the merchants and manufacturers whose interests he saw as

    frequently opposed to those of the public; he argued that, because of theirconnection with agriculture, the agrarian capitalists, unlike the merchantsand manufacturers, had a real interest in their country of residence and noparticular reason to obstruct the natural course of economic development(McNally, 1988: 20910, 2205, 263).

    For our purposes, four points are noteworthy. First, the Physiocrats, Smith,and other advocates for agrarian capitalism were among the earliest andmost influential social theorists to deploy societal evolutionist arguments;they maintained that human society had progressed through a steadily

    unfolding sequence of stages, each of which was based on a different modeof subsistence: food-gathering and hunting; pastoralism, agriculture andcommerce (Meek, 1976). As Neal Wood (1984: 51) observed, the motorsdriving this natural progression variously involved [a] small primitive

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    7/31

    313Patterson Craft specialization

    population, movable property, landed property, use production, populationincrease and concentration, barter and money, property differentials, depen-dent labor, exchange production, social conflict, and the eventual emergence

    of the state. Second, both the evolutionist scaffolding of human historyproposed by the early theorists of agrarian capitalism and the language oftheir rhetorical arguments about development influenced contemporarywriters, like Jean-Jacques Rousseau and James Steuart, who did not necess-arily share either their worldview or their political allegiances. Third, thetheorists of agrarian capitalism already assumed that merchants were a forceof progress who extended commerce, and that the market:

    . . . intensified competition between the hitherto protected crafts of thedifferent towns [and] . . . ultimately forced the break-up of the complex,

    unified crafts into the component parts. The rise of manufacture on the ruinsof the crafts thus brought about a new form of specialization, constituted byseparated units carrying out simplified detail production and a new mode ofco-operation based on the manufactory in which merchants controlled thesemi-skilled labour processes. (Brenner, 1989: 278)

    Fourth, the evolutionist/developmentalist discourse came into being at atime when national societies of Western Europe were still largely rural butwhen the rural communities that constituted them and the precapitalistproperty relations that maintained those communities had largely been

    dissolved. Communities of producers and exploiters whose membersformerly had direct access to the means of production and produced forsubsistence were replaced by economically autonomous landlords, tenantsand wage workers who produced commodities for exchange and securedportions if not all of their subsistence needs in the market; in a phrase,community-level property relations and production were replaced by onesthat operated at the level of households or domestic units.

    Evolutionist arguments about the interconnections of surplus foodproduction, specialization and exchange have had profound effects in

    archaeology and anthropology. One legacy is that they were the centerpieceof Childes (1936/1983: 116) thesis that agriculture facilitated the produc-tion of surpluses which were used to underwrite the activities of craftspecialists who did not engage in food production. They were acceptedimplicitly by writers who are usually portrayed as avowedly anti-evolu-tionists, e.g. Franz Boas (1920/1940: 285) who wrote that a surplus of foodsupply is liable to bring about an increase of population and an increase ofleisure, which gives opportunity for occupations that are not absolutelynecessary for the needs of everyday life (quoted by Clark, 1995: 289).

    A second legacy of the evolutionist arguments has been the creation andreification of a set of beliefs concerning the significance of the dichotomybetween city dwellers and their neighbors in the surrounding countryside.However, as we have seen, the chasm separating town and countryside,

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    8/31

    314 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    which has played so prominently in archaeological theories, was less clearor pronounced for eighteenth-century writers, like Smith, than it is for thoseof us writing in the twenty-first century. Intense processes of urbanization

    occurred after the end of the Second World War, and half to two-thirds ormore of the total populations of countries, like the USA or Peru that werepredominantly rural not so long ago, now reside in towns or cities. Theseprocesses have not only obscured or obliterated conditions that prevailedas recently as 20 or 30 years ago, but also diminished our understanding andeven our ability to appreciate them and their significance.

    A third legacy of the linkages between mercantilism, liberalism andevolutionism (both in and beyond the academy) is the positive valuationplaced on the urban way of life. Esteem is typically granted to commerce,industry and city life, while agriculture, animal husbandry and the cultureof rural laborers is denigrated or held in disdain. Another aspect of thislegacy is that rural industry was simultaneously more highly regarded thanagriculture and held in less esteem than urban industry. This resonates withpositive valuation placed on mental rather than physical or manual labor.Phrased differently, towns and cities have been seen as centers of innova-tion whose new ideas and goods are subsequently adopted by their ruralneighbors (Redfield, 1942/1962). Empirically, much of the manufacturingthat occurred in seventeenth- and eighteenth-century Europe seems tohave taken place in the countryside. This requires us to consider, at least

    for a moment, the organization of rural production and industries and theirrelations to the town-country divide that was forming at the time.

    PRODUCTION RELATIONS AN D THE TOWN-COUNTRY

    DIVIDE

    It is worth reiterating that the theorists of agrarian capitalism wrote at a

    time (1) when land constituted the principal base of economic productiv-ity (Fox-Genovese, 1976: 219) and (2) when the operation of the marketwas widening from more or less separate and isolated corners of theeconomy, or in individual spheres of activity like international trade . . . [to]the whole area of the economy and the whole range of economic activities(Meek, 1962: 371). Their explanations typically involved the production ofcommodities, i.e. items that were produced for exchange in the marketrather than for use or consumption by the individuals who produced them.The commodities derived from agriculture and husbandry were foodstuffs

    and secondary products, like hides or wool, that could be either consumedby the individuals who purchased them or further transformed into othercommodities, like shoes or fabrics. Two issues are important. First, was thepurpose of exchange to make a profit (i.e. merchant capital)? Second, who

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    9/31

    315Patterson Craft specialization

    controlled production? In medieval Europe, merchants were mainlyconcerned with controlling access to markets and to the items that wereproduced rather than influencing how production units (households, work-

    shops,or even whole communities) were organized or how workers actuallyproduced the goods (Hilton, 1992: 18).In a discussion of the historical development of the division of labor in

    agriculture, Smith (1776/1976, vol. 1: 79) noted the existence of a paradox.On the one hand, he suggested that the separation of the different branchesof labor in subsistence agriculture and stock-raising was much less developedor clear cut than it was in industry; in his words, the nature of [subsistence]agriculture, indeed, does not admit of so many subdivisions of labour, nor socomplete a separation of one business from another, as manufactures(Smith, 1776/1976, vol. 1: 9). He concluded that the lack of specializationprevented agriculture and stock-raising from developing as rapidly asindustry. On the other hand, he remarked that in every improved society,the farmer is generally nothing but a farmer; the manufacturer, nothing buta manufacturer (Smith, 1776/1976, vol. 1: 9, emphasis added). In thisimproved (developed) society, the division of labor is sharply defined. In thisdevelopmental stage, the activities of the farmer and the manufacturer wereclearly demarcated, and the two types of specialists were inextricably linkedto one another by exchange. In historical-developmental terms, Smith wasarguing that farming became a more specialized activity than it had been

    previously after or in conjunction with the emergence of a division of laborand exchange (i.e. commodity production). The picture of subsistencefarming that emerges from Smiths discussion of the division of labor is onemarked by seasonality. The high demand for agricultural labor at harvesttimes alternated with periods when the demand for labor was lower andwhen other material needs could be produced by members of the householdand be used or shared with kinfolk and neighbors. Thus, the householdsengaged in subsistence agriculture did not limit themselves exclusively toagricultural production, because their members also produced handicrafts

    and the other necessities of everyday life (Duby, 1968: 1535).6 Each indi-vidual engage[d] in a variety of tasks, and [there was] no significant dispar-ity between mental and physical labor (Diamond, 2004: 23).

    In the late 1970s, Peter Kriedte, Hans Medick, and Jrgen Schlumbohm(1977/1981) took a related but slightly different tack in Industrializationbefore Industrialization. They attempted to theorize the rural roots of indus-trial production during the transformation from feudalism to capitalism inWestern and Central Europe. Earlier, Smith (1776/1976, vol. 1: 42931) hadremarked that European export industries developed in two distinct ways:

    as the offspring of foreign commerce, when merchants imitated foreigncrafts using imported raw materials, like mulberry trees and silkworms, andas the offspring of agriculture, when household manufactures based onlocally available raw materials were refined. The implication of Smiths

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    10/31

    316 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    remarks, from the perspective of Kriedte and his associates, was that at leastsome of the early industry in Europe, besides mining and iron work, tookplace in the countryside rather than in urban areas as well as contexts where

    feudal social relations were in decline and capitalist ones had not yet crys-tallized. They referred to this phase as proto-industrialization. In theirview, rural industries developed in those parts of the countryside wherethere was already a socially differentiated peasantry; where at least somepeasant families could not support themselves on the amount and qualityof land available to them even if they could intensify production; wherethere was an elastic labor supply (seasonal unemployment); and where thepowers of local lords or village communities had weakened to the pointwhere earlier forms of socioeconomic cohesion and homogeneity could notbe maintained. The new social relations driving socioeconomic develop-ment in these rural regions were capitalist ones based on commodityproduction, market exchange and wage labor; they were not based on thelaws of the family economy [which had] functioned as the engine of proto-industrial growth (Kriedte et al., 1977/1981: 136).7

    Kriedte and his associates pointed out that proto-industrialization inrural areas had a number of consequences. It promoted the developmentof skilled artisans. In those industries where the putting-out systemprevailed, notably textiles, merchants came to be more closely connectedwith production than their predecessors had been.8 It underwrote the

    formation of symbiotic relations between agriculture and industry and thecreation of networks of local, regional and national markets. It alsowitnessed the emergence of a group of individuals: merchants, middlemenand artisans, who, with an infusion of capital,would become agents of indus-trialization. At the same time, proto-industrialization, which they saw asgeared to quantitative changes in production rather than qualitativechanges in the mode of production, generated a series of contradictions thatbecame particularly evident during harvest seasons when high demands forlabor outside the factory conflicted with production schedules and priori-

    ties of the factory. There were other difficulties as well, particularly with aputting-out system, in which merchants or middlemen provided rawmaterials, like cotton, to households for spinning or weaving. It was diffi-cult to supervise the work, to control the quality of the thread, to preventpilferage of the raw materials, or to coordinate the activities of the spinnerswith the needs of the weavers. These and other contradictions, notably theone between the growth dynamics of the family economy and the overallsystem forged by proto-industrialization, were resolved, at least temporar-ily, through mechanization and the centralization of production in factories

    located increasingly in towns and cities (Kriedte et al., 1977/1981: 13642).This unleashed a new set of contradictions.In the course of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, proto-

    industrialization and early industrialization witnessed growing concerns

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    11/31

    317Patterson Craft specialization

    about work and factory discipline that involved increased supervision, regu-larization of work schedules and standardization of the workday(Thompson, 1967/1991). From the owners perspective, it was important to

    increase his control over his employees schedules, activities, intelligenceand skills in ways that increased the efficiency of production.9 From theworkers perspective, it was essential to maintain their own schedules inorder to deal with subsistence and the production of use values outside thefactory. Time and work discipline increasingly became arenas of conflictbetween factory owners and workers. The struggles that ensued involvedboth arson and the increasing use of brick and stone in factory construc-tion (Russell Handsman, 1990, personal communication). In New England,it also involved new forms of discourse. In the early nineteenth century,factory owners used the rhetoric of republicanism to emphasize their sharedcommunity of interests with their employees. A few decades later, the sameowners dropped this pretense and began to employ arguments and rhetori-cal forms based on liberalism, which emphasized supply and demand,contracts and obligations to stockholders (Siskind, 1991; Wilentz, 1984).

    MARXS ALTERNATIVES

    Karl Marx launched his critique of classical political economy in the early1840s (Oakley, 19845). He drew inspiration from a number of writers,notably Adam Smith and the Physiocrats; however, he also acknowledgedimportant intellectual debts to Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Georg W.F. Hegeland the French socialists. He simultaneously built on their writings,critiqued them and ultimately elaborated an original synthesis that incor-porated and combined elements of their views with his own (Patterson,2003: 732). While there were important continuities in Marxs writings,there were also points where he did not choose between alternative expla-

    nations as well as where he simply changed his mind. During the process,as historian Robert Brenner (1989: 272) observed, Marx developed two ulti-mately incompatible theories of the transition from feudalism to capital-ism. His observation clarifies a lot. For our purposes, it is noteworthy,because the role of craft specialization and production is conceptualizeddifferently in the two theories. More broadly, the existence of the twotheories accounts has fueled a debate about whether or not Marx was asocietal evolutionist, the answer to which depends, of course, on whichtheory contemporary authors prefer to emphasize and on which one they

    choose to downplay or ignore altogether.Marxs earlier,societal evolutionary account of the transition from feudal-ism to capitalism appeared in works that were written in the 1840s, notablyThe Poverty of Philosophy, The German Ideology and The Communist

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    12/31

    318 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    Manifesto, the latter two written with Frederick Engels (Marx, 1847/1963;Marx and Engels, 18445/1974, 1848/1998). In this theory of transition, Marxsaw the structural differentiation of roles within the labor process cooper-

    ation within the production unit and the increasing distinction betweenmental and manual labor as the motor driving the evolution of class andproperty relations. This motor was set in motion by the growth of trade andcompetition. As Brenner (1989: 282) noted, this theory depends heavily onAdam Smiths theory of history. He writes that

    The central explanatory notion at the core of this theory is theself-developing division of labour. The division of labour directly expressesthe level of development of the productive forces; it evolves in response tothe expanding market; and it determines, in turn, the social relations of class

    and property. The theorys basic image of transition from feudal tocapitalism encompasses the maturation of the development of bourgeoissociety, nourished by constantly-growing world trade, within the womb of theold feudal society. (Brenner, 1989: 272)

    Marxs later theory of the transition from feudalism to capitalism appearedin works written after 1857, especially the Grundrisse, Capital, The Ethno-logical Notebooks and the drafts of correspondence with Vera Zasulich(Marx, 18578/1973, 18637/1977, 18802/1974, 1881/1983). Here, heprovided an alternative to the societal evolutionism of the Enlightenment

    theorists of agrarian capitalism as well as of his own earlier work. Hefocused on the historicity of the individual and of social relations ratherthan the unfolding of some potential inherent in groups or in a humannature that could reduce largely or exclusively to its biological or psycho-logical dimensions. This involved a shift away from a natural law to adialectical and historical conception of human nature. Thus, the distinctivefeatures of humankind creative intelligence realized through and mani-fested in labor, sociality, language, culture, the production of use-values(items that satisfy human needs) and the creation of new needs were

    neither timeless nor persistent but rather were constituted, reproduced andtransformed in particular sociohistorical contexts. In his view, human indi-viduals were social beings and human sociality was simultaneouslycommunal in character as well as socially and historically determined.Moreover, the division of labor and the production of use-values wereenduring features of human society from its inception rather than ones thatemerged at a particular stage in its development as Smith and others hadsuggested.

    Marx (18578/1973: 83100) began his analysis of how societies produced

    the material conditions for their own reproduction not with exchange,supply and demand, or the allocation of scarce resources (the starting pointsfor classical political economists), but rather with production itself. He wasquite emphatic about this point and wrote that:

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    13/31

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    14/31

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    15/31

    321Patterson Craft specialization

    (2) everyone engaged in a variety of tasks, some involving physical laborand others mental activity; and (3) the absence of exploitation where themembers of one group permanently appropriated the labor power or goods

    produced by the members of other groups that occupied different places inthe total system of production. Eleanor Leacock (1982: 159) has argued thatthe absence of exploitation, in the sense just described, results from theunity of the production process and the direct participation of all adults inthe production, distribution, circulation, and consumption of the goods thatare produced. This meant that each individual was dependent on the groupas a whole rather than on its constituent households or domestic units. Italso meant that there were no structural differences between producers andnon-producers; such a distinction would exist only from the perspective ofa single labor process and would disappear when that process is viewed inthe context of other activities where the direct producer in one cyclebecomes a consumer in another.11

    Historical and ethnographic accounts show that the interconnections ofproduction, distribution,exchange and consumption vary in significant waysfrom one communal society to another (Testart, 1986, 1987). For instance,among the San of the Kalahari, the right to distribute game belongs to theindividual who made the arrow that first struck the animal; among thePintubi and Tiwi of Australia, the elders of the community traditionally holdthat right; among the Eskimos of the Arctic, it belongs to the hunter who

    first sighted the animal. Moreover, historical and ethnographic accountswritten from the eighteenth century to the present report that these kin-organized communities often had quite elaborate divisions of labor basedon age, gender, status, or life experience. Different individuals workingepisodically or seasonally produced diverse arrays of goods, or use values,for the members of the community and beyond. The activities performedrange from healing to woodcarving. In a phrase, these accounts indicate thatcraft specialization and production do exist, to some extent, in primitivecommunal societies, regardless of whether their subsistence economies are

    rooted in agriculture, stock-raising, or some combination of foraging,hunting and fishing.Let us briefly consider some of the contrasts between Marxs later

    alternative and the perspective formulated by the advocates of agrariancapitalism. First, some degree of craft production and specialization basedon age, gender and experience already existed in primitive communalsocieties where everyone had access to the means of production. Second,the social property relations that existed in the precapitalist tributary states(civilizations) studied by archaeologists allowed both the producers and the

    exploiting classes direct access to the means of production; this freed bothfrom the need to produce for exchange. Third, there were societies in whichmarket exchange was not well developed. Fourth, while Marx worked outthe laws of motion that drove capitalist development, he only hinted at

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    16/31

    322 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    the laws of motion which underpinned the formation of societies manifest-ing the feudal, ancient, or Asiatic modes of production. The hints heprovided, however, suggest that the underlying dynamics differed from one

    mode of production to another (e.g. Brenner, 1986). Fifth, it is clear fromthe archaeological and historical record that production for exchange co-existed with subsistence production, which included non-food items, inmany but not all precapitalist states. This raises a number of questions. Forexample, under what sociohistorically constituted and contingent circum-stances did social property relations develop which facilitated the expan-sion of commodity production, the market and specialization? What werethose social property relations? How are they related to the developmentof the divide between town and countryside, urban and rural? How andunder what circumstances were artisans removed from community-basedproduction? How and under what circumstances did households becomesignificant production units? Such questions focus attention not only on therelations of production but also on the ways in which these relations werereproduced or transformed.

    WHAT DOES THIS MEAN FO R ARCHAEOLOGISTS?

    In some instances, archaeological and historical evidence rules out certaintheory-laden interpretations. For example, it is doubtful that aliensconstructed the Nazca Lines of coastal Peru as landing strips for their space-ships, or that the site of Tiwanaku on the shores of Lake Titicaca in Boliviawas built 10,000 years ago. In other instances, the evidence can sustain twoor more theoretically-informed interpretations. For example, while Smithand Marx relied on much of the same evidence to construct alternativetheories of the development of capitalism, they placed different emphaseson the data they used and connected them in different ways. While some

    may view this as an interpretive dilemma, I am not arguing, as a radical rela-tivist might, that one theory is as good as another, for I happen to believethat some theories provide better answers or signposts for action thanothers. I also believe that knowledge is created in dialogues that ultimatelyinvolve close examinations and interrogations of the interconnections oftheory, practice and evidence.

    For the theorists of capitalism discussed above, the transition from theproduction and circulation of use-values to commodity production andmarket exchange was still taking place; however, the social relations of

    commodity production were already dominant and driving socioeconomicdevelopment when they wrote. They were, in a sense, describing what theeconomy would become in the future. Fortunately, we have archaeologicalevidence as well as historical and ethnographic accounts from other partsof the world that document processes of development. These data afford

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    17/31

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    18/31

    324 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    These practices had three immediate effects. First, the nobility had no localpower bases, since their landholdings were scattered and worked by themembers of communities with diverse local origins and loyalties; as a result,

    their well-being was dependent on that of the Aztec state. Second, the localmarkets were broken up. Third, this underwrote the growing importance ofthe market in the Aztec capital, which the ruler divided among his noblesin the late fifteenth century; this provided the nobles with a tribute in kindfrom the sellers on the market (Hicks 1987: 94, 96).

    Skilled artisans smiths, woodcarvers, feather workers, painters, and lapi-daries to name only a few were commoners who were brought by theAztec state from their natal communities to the capital in order to ply theircrafts full-time in the city. They were installed along with other practitionersof their craft in wards (calpulli), which were also corporate landholdinggroups. The state not only brought them by coercion to the city but alsodetermined whether they would produce items for the palace, the treasury,or the market. Many (most) of the artisans were attached to the palace,while others worked through the market. Their clientele consisted of pettybureaucrats, ritual specialists, military professionals and merchants whotrafficked in raw materials and luxury goods, as well as other artisans. Whilethe artisan wards undoubtedly grew some of their food in garden plots, theirmembers likely acquired many subsistence items as well as raw materialsfor their work through the market. Most of the food items found in the

    market of the Aztec capital were probably grown on the large estates seizedearlier and made their way to the market as tribute to one or another noblehousehold. The estates were the economic base of a market system thateffectively by-passed the local rulers subordinated by the Aztecs and theirallies (Hicks, 1986: 53, 1987: 97101, 1999: 41316).

    Case 2: The intersection of state and communal economies in

    the Inca state

    Market exchange was not well developed in the Inca state. Thus, Inca Peruprovides, for our purposes, a marked and significant contrast with AztecMexico. Many Andean scholars were aware of the contrast by the 1960s, ifnot earlier. The Andean case provides a counter example to often repeatedclaims that the rise of craft specialization and the development of marketsare interconnected. In this instance, the rise of merchant capital along thenorthern frontier of the empire was an aspect of Inca state formation.Commerce in the frontier area was the prerogative of certain client statesin the empire, where merchants from those polities, notably Chincha,

    bartered with a socially differentiated group of merchant Indians fromfrontier societies during the early stages of their encapsulation and incor-poration into the imperial state. The Chincha merchants acquired objects forconspicuous consumption, e.g. emeralds, rather than subsistence. That these

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    19/31

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    20/31

    326 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    It appears that local Andean communities retained significant control oversubsistence production and the production of use-values even during theperiod of Inca rule. The state economy, which appropriated land and labor

    power, was grafted onto those of the subject communities. The imperialstate did not alter social property relations within the communities; itstribute demands were placed on the community rather than individualhouseholds. The communities were not dissolved into a number of inde-pendent, autonomous households. In a phrase, the practices and policies ofthe Incas did not lead to the formation of a peasantry; efforts to do soduring the Colonial Period were resisted strenuously, often with force.Moreover, the fact that the local communities retained control of theproduction, circulation, distribution and consumption of its goods meantthat merchants were unable to detach exchange from their production andto create an autonomous circulation sphere, which is a necessary conditionfor the emergence and continued viability of merchant capitalists. The self-sufficient economies of the local communities inhibited the development oflocal mass markets for inexpensive goods.

    DISCUSSION

    State formation, which involves the simultaneous dissolution of kin-communal societies and the crystallization of class structures and state insti-tutions, creates conditions in which social property relations and craftproduction are typically reorganized. In these new circumstances, part of thetraditional work that underwrote the consumption and reproduction of kincommunities is now subsumed by the state. It is transformed into labor, theproducts of which are drained off to support dominant classes and the state.This reorganization involves labor processes, technical divisions of labor, thespatial organization and even consumption. For instance, in Aztec Mexico,

    the domestic production in communities that pursued intensive agriculturewas reorganized and a portion of the surplus foodstuffs was appropriated astribute by the state. The women in these tributary communities who hadpreviously cooked stews now prepared tortillas, which could be carried easilyto workplaces in the fields, and they also spent less time spinning andweaving, even though the demand for clothing remained constant. Clothingand other necessities they no longer produced were acquired in one of thelocal or regional markets (Brumfiel, 1991). In the Andes, the Inca stateappropriated land and labor service which had differential effects on produc-

    tion and social reproduction in the various local communities under its rule;it also restricted the use of certain goods and reorganized the consumptionof certain foodstuffs at the local level. In sum, the organization of work isdistorted and transformed in the process of state formation. This forces us

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    21/31

    327Patterson Craft specialization

    to consider how state-based societies organized the production, distribution,circulation and consumption of goods. It compels us to examine how theorganization of tributary communities in which the production of goods,

    knowledge, and human beings took place was itself distorted and trans-formed and reproduced under new circumstances.A related issue involves the origins of the kinds of goods or services

    demanded by the state and its associated ruling classes and where struc-turally they intervene in the production relations to extract them. In thecase of Inca Peru, the state intervened in the distribution of land, laborpower, and the goods produced by subject communities; it required anadministrative organization of census takers and tax collectors to ensurethat tribute was received from communities spread over a vast landscape.In Aztec Mexico, the state and its ruling class appropriated land, laborpower and established markets that were ultimately controlled by thenobility. In this case,part of the tribute was acquired from commerce,whichrequired a slightly different kind of administration one that wasconcerned with controlling trade routes and the markets where goods werebartered or sold; as a result, the Aztec state which intervened at the momentof production itself was also more concerned with the circulation of goodsthan were the Incas (Thapar, 1981: 41011). Both cases stand in markedcontrast to early modern England and France, where merchants wereattempting to rest control of the markets from local lords.

    The exchange activities of tributary states based on commerce andmerchant capital must be distinguished from the exchange relations thatexist among kin-organized communities, where surplus raw materials andgoods are transferred from one to another. These intercommunity exchangerelations are unintegrated and unintegrating, since they do not produce thegoods, conditions, or social relations that communally organized societiesneed to sustain and reproduce themselves. They allow the members ofdifferent communities to engage their opposites without abandoning theirplaces in their own societies. Those states whose revenues were derived

    from controlling trade or taxing merchants often flourished on the marginsof states that extracted tribute in the form of labor and goods from theirsubjects; the Maghreb and Egypt provide an example of this relationship(Amin, 1978: 1223). These mercantile states resembled islands based onmerchant capital, money and petty commodity production for the marketin a vast sea of subsistence production i.e. the production of use-valuesfor consumption by the community members. Since only a small portion ofsocial production was geared to the market, merchant capital could developonly to the extent that there was an active commodity sector.

    Traditions of continual technological and scientific innovation are notcharacteristic of precapitalist state-based societies. Their internal logics andlaws of motion are based on the appropriation of labor power and goodsfrom direct producers and on the reproduction of the conditions, social

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    22/31

    328 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    relations and practices that facilitate continued exploitation. Thus, in tribu-tary states, the means of production tools, processes, technical knowledgeand labor power reside with the members of the subject communities.

    Since artisans and producers are members of communities that exertvarying degrees of control over the means of production and theirconditions of work, the states and their associated classes strive to protectand reproduce those institutions that provide them with the labor powerand knowledge of the direct producers (Brenner, 1986: 489).

    In these circumstances, artisans are typically engaged in the productionof use-values rather than commodities for the market. Consequently, thereis no economic imperative to increase the efficiency of artisan productionthrough increased specialization or technical innovation. This does notmean that the technologies of early civilizations were simple or that newobjects or processes were never invented. Those Andean weavers who wovedouble-cloths that resembled much more easily produced tapestries seem-ingly took great delight in displaying their skills, and the metalworkers andjewelers of the area had discovered processes of alloying and producingpure metals that were known nowhere else. However, it does suggest thatartisans were not compelled to use observations made under one set ofconditions to establish scientific and technological principles which couldbe generalized and applied in other circumstances or technical processes.For example, Andean peoples under Inca rule used tweezers to remove

    facial hair; however, they did not generalize the principle of the lever andapply it to mechanically identical operations such as using tongs to movecrucibles of molten metal.

    At the juridical level, patent law is poorly developed in early tributarystates, even though commercial law, involving contracts and usury, was welldeveloped in regions, like Assyria. Since the state provided little protectionto the rights of communities claiming ownership of technical processes andknowledge, these were the trade secrets and lore of the community thatwere passed from one generation of artisans to the next. The absence of

    patent law suggests that possession of such esoteric knowledge still residedin the kin-organized communities encapsulated by these precapitalist states.Patent law, protecting rights of ownership to scientific and technologicalknowledge, is well-developed in societies based on the production ofcommodities, like the city-states of northern Italy during the Renaissance.Patronage of intellectual creation in the arts and sciences by the state and/orby members of the ruling class is also common in societies where artisanshave been separated from the subsistence production of their natal com-munities (Antal, 1947; Berger, 1972; Davis, 1983; Wallace-Hadrill, 1990).

    Traditions of continuous scientific and technological innovation are anessential feature of societies manifesting the industrial capitalist mode ofproduction. Continuous innovation reflects a tradition in which scientificprinciples derived from observations made in one set of conditions or

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    23/31

    329Patterson Craft specialization

    practices are generalized and extended to new applications and circum-stances; it is also a tradition in which knowledge is cumulative and techno-logical progress can be discerned (Zilsel, 1942, 1945/1957). These traditions

    underwrite the production of commodities for competitive markets, theincreased productivity of artisans and machines, changes in the organiccomposition of labor, the creation of new commodities and markets and theaccumulation of capital. The tendency toward greater efficiency and percapita output also involves cost-cutting through specialization, innovation,and the accumulation of the capital necessary for investment in new waysof producing commodities. It too is a motor of economic growth anddevelopment in industrial capitalist societies but not in precapitalist tribu-tary states (Brenner, 1986: 24). Such scientific and technological traditionsare found in state-based societies, where artisans are increasingly removedfrom their natal communities and forced to sell their skills, knowledge andproducts in a labor market.

    Robert Brenner (1986: 51) maintains that modern economic growthrequires the break-up of pre-capitalist property relations characterized bythe producers possession and the exploiters surplus extraction by extra-economic coercion. He sees this break-up as the unintended consequenceof the relations of reproduction of individual actors and the conflicts thatexist between classes. He argues that such transformations are most likelyto occur in those precapitalist societies in which the direct producers

    possess the means of production individually and that state and its associ-ated classes extract goods and labor power directly from the individualproduction units rather than from the community as a whole. He concludesthat capitalist economic development of this sort has not occurred veryoften in human history.

    CONCLUDING REMARKS

    In sum, the theory of societal evolutionism has a shared heritage withmercantilism and liberalism; it was developed in France, Scotland andEngland at a time when those societies were still largely rural. It was elab-orated initially by theorists of agrarian capitalism who advocated thedevelopment of commercial agriculture and stock-raising as well as expan-sion of the domestic markets for those goods. In their view, this would bothcreate wealth and increase the division of labor. While keen observers ofhow production relations were being reorganized, they were less concerned

    with the particulars involved in the development of capitalist manufacturesand industry.Contemporary proponents of societal evolutionism share a vocabulary,

    a set of assumptions, and a form of argumentation that derive from a

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    24/31

    330 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    particular socioeconomic and ideological context, one that was specificallyconcerned with the rise of agrarian capitalism. Here, I have argued that theframework of analytical categories, assumptions and rhetorical forms inher-

    ited from this discourse makes it difficult to examine the development ofcraft and industrial production in the kinds of precapitalist societies typi-cally studied by archaeologists. I suggest rethinking analytical categories,which are so broadly conceived that they miss fundamental differences andobscure essential features of the precapitalist societies we study. As AnnePyburn (2004: xi) recently remarked in a quite different context, thereasoning of cultural [societal] evolutionary explanations predeterminesand drastically limits what we can know about the past. I agree with hersentiments.

    I have tried to show that historians, social theorists and other scholarsbesides archaeologists are concerned with questions about the processesinvolved in the rise of civilization, the origins of states and the appearanceof specialization. The problems are the same, only the kinds of data and themethods they use to interrogate them differ. It is beneficial, I believe, tobegin to look at their arguments more closely, to incorporate them into ourdiscussions and to insert ourselves into theirs. I have also argued that it isimportant to look at the social theoretical frameworks we use to explainthe past in order to see more clearly the relative advantages and limitations.In this article, I attempted to develop in a preliminary manner a framework

    rooted in Marxist social thought that would allow us to look at questionsabout craft specialization, the reorganization of production relations andstate formation from a different vantage point.

    Acknowledgements

    An earlier version of this article was prepared and presented at a pre-congressmeeting of the International Congress of Anthropological and EthnologicalSciences on Artisanal Production throughout the Ages in Africa,Asia, Europe, andthe Americas, organized by June Nash, Jane Schneider and John Clark, 2023 July,1993 in San Cristbal de las Casas, Chiapas, Mexico. This much revised version hasprofited over the years from the work, constructive criticism and thoughtfulcomments of Wendy Ashmore, Elizabeth Brumfiel, Edward Calnek, Cathy Costin,Tim Earle, John Gledhill, Christina Halperin, Russell Handsman, Frederic Hicks,Lynn Meskell, Robert Paynter, Karen Spalding and, more recently, the observationsof three anonymous reviewers.

    Notes

    1 In the eighteenth century, sociocultural evolutionism was based on a notion ofdevelopment, i.e. change was normal and resulted in general betterment(Trigger, 1998: 30). As William Outhwaite (1994: 59) noted, this unfoldingmodel of evolution differed from some subsequent versions that

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    25/31

    331Patterson Craft specialization

    emphasize[d] the Darwinian theme of the adaptations of systems to theirenvironments.

    2 During the transition from feudalism to capitalism, feudal lords who, inpractice if not in theory, supported the ideal of a self-sufficient natural

    economy were pitted against serfs, peasants and artisans, on the one hand,and merchant capitalists who sought increasing control of local and regionalmarkets, on the other. Marx (18637/1977: 87795) outlined the dialectics ofclass struggle in England during the transition. The serfs succeeded in breakingthe bonds of servitude by the end of the fourteenth century, becoming a classof free peasant proprietors. The lesser feudal lords no longer able toappropriate goods and services from their former serfs dissolved by the end ofthe fifteenth century, and their former retainers, who never had direct access tothe means of production and who lacked the ability to appropriate surplusfrom the direct producers, were recast as a proletariat. In the sixteenth century,

    the great feudal lords used coercion, laws and taxes to expropriate theresources they held in common and to force the peasants, formerly inpossession of their means of subsistence and production, into growingdependence on the market and on production for exchange. This wasaccompanied by social differentiation in the rural communities, thesimultaneous appearance of capitalist farmers who produced for the marketand a rural proletariat whose members lacked the means of subsistence andwere forced to hire themselves out as agricultural laborers.

    3 The discovery of the Americas, its peoples, and the wealth of its resourcesplayed a fundamental role in the development of the discourse that yielded

    liberalism, political economy and evolutionism. In what is viewed as one of thefoundational documents of liberal social thought, Second Treatise onGovernment, John Locke (1690/1980: 29, 58) moved quickly from a biblicalaccount of human history rooted in Genesis to a developmental accountrooted in human nature and the world, when he interpreted the availableethnographic literature to indicate that in the beginning all the world wasAmerica (49) and that the kings of theIndians inAmerica . . . [are] still apattern of the first ages inAsia and Europe (108). The individuals who wroteand used this literature typically had axes to grind and, as many scholars havenoted, their writings had important intellectual and political consequences (e.g.

    Meek, 1976).4 Other worldviews were clearly articulated by the latter half of the eighteenth

    century. For example, Jean-Jacques Rousseau, a critic of the commercialculture crystallizing in France, gave voice both to the sentiments of the urban,middling classes composed of artisans, small shopkeepers, and the like whosestandards of living had been declining steadily for several generations and tothe political ideal of popular sovereignty (Lwy and Sayre, 2001; Wood, 1988).Thomas Malthuss views on the interrelations of food supply, population,child-bearing and poverty and support for the Corn Laws gave solace to thelanded gentry who were the primary beneficiaries of this protective tariff on

    imported grains (Rubin, 1929/1979: 291300). The Encyclopedia of DenisDiderot and Jean dAlembert with its emphasis on scientific and technologicalprogress, on the one hand, and on rationality and progressive social thought,on the other, gave hope to the largely urban, educated middle classes of the

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    26/31

    332 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    day. Spokesmen or apologists for industrial capitalism like Jeremy Bentham,Jean-Baptiste Say, or David Ricardo, for example began to articulate theirviews in the first-quarter of the nineteenth century (McNally, 1988: 266; Tribe,1978: 11061, 1981: 10120). Critics of industrialization and the impoverishment

    of wage workers such as Henri Saint-Simon, Robert Owen, or CharlesFourier began to offer alternative perspectives in the 1820s and 1830s.

    5 The Physiocrats, as Ronald Meek (1962: 24) notes, recognized that theprevalence of small-scale, capital-starved, subsistence farming hindered thefurther development of agriculture.

    6 Whether these family farm production units were capitalist or precapitalistdepends not on the form of the work their members performed or whether ornot they were involved with wider socioeconomic structures but rather on thenature of their involvement with those structures. By contrast, AlexanderChayanov (1924/1986), who focused on the organization and nature of peasant

    production processes, viewed peasant family farms as autonomous,transhistorical economic units that were independent of those wider structures.He placed a great deal of emphasis on the relations between family size andproductivity and, hence, on the demographic aspects of domestic production.Numerous writers have pointed out that Chayanov did not adequatelytheorize the transformation from precapitalist to capitalist forms of productionand involvements in wider structures (e.g. Kriedte et al., 1977/1981: 423, 235).

    7 The weaknesses of the proto-industrialization thesis, according to critics, were(1) that its concentration on an organizational form of production obscuredboth the diversity and complexity of the form itself as well as the social

    property relations that underwrote domestic and workshop industries in thecountryside and (2) that its emphasis on an essentially linear and stageistmodel of economic development concealed the dynamics underlying theformation of pre-factory industry in rural areas (Berg et al., 1983).

    8 Putting-out systems are forms of sub-contracting in which owners ormiddlemen distributed raw materials to workers for manufacture in theirhomes or even in factories. The workers typically employed family membersand friends in the production process. An example of the former involved thedistribution of raw cotton to spinners who produced thread; the thread wasthen collected and given to weavers to produce woven fabrics. An example of

    the latter occurred in early cotton mills, where skilled spinners were put incharge of machinery and engaged their own help, usually child assistants fromamong their families and acquaintances. Foremen sometimes added to theirdirect supervisory function the practice of taking a few machines on their ownaccount and hiring labor to operate them (Braverman, 1974: 61).

    9 Charles Babbage (1835/1963), an early theorist of capitalist manufacture,observed that it was men rather than machines that produced profits. Thus,unlike many of his contemporaries who were concerned with machines, hefocused on the organization of the workplace. He advocated technicaldivisions of labor (specialization) and segmenting the labor process, so that no

    single individual had to possess all of the skills required to complete theproduction of a particular commodity.

    10 The fact that Marx never fully developed a theory of transition or fullydescribed the modes of production he mentioned, except for the capitalism,

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    27/31

    333Patterson Craft specialization

    generated an enormous literature, especially from the 1970s onward, partly inresponse to of Eric Hobsbawms (1964) introduction to Marxs comments onprecapitalist forms and partly as an elaboration of what both wrote aboutthem.

    11 This contrasts with some advocates of the domestic economy, who build onChayanov or Marshall Sahlinss (1972) discussion of the domestic mode ofproduction and who tend to view the household rather than the community asthe primary economic unit.

    References

    Amin, S. (1978) The Arab Nation: Nationalism and Class Struggles. London: ZedPress.

    Antal, F. (1947) Florentine Painting and Its Social Background: The BourgeoisRepublic before Cosimo de Medicis Advent to Power: XIV and Early XV

    Centuries. London: Kegan Paul.Babbage, C. (1835/1963) On the Economy of Machinery and Manufacturers, 4th edn.

    New York: A.M. Kelley.Berg, M., P. Hudson and M. Sonenscher, eds (1983) Manufacture in Town and

    Country before the Factory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Berger, J. (1972) Ways of Seeing. London: Penguin Books.Boas, F. (1920/1940) The Method of Ethnology, in F. Boas (ed.) Race, Language,

    and Culture, pp. 2819. New York: Macmillan.

    Braverman, H. (1974) Labor and Monopoly Capital: The Degradation of Work inthe Twentieth Century. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Brenner, R. (1976/1985) Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development inPre-Industrial Europe, in T.H. Aston and C.H.E. Philpin (eds) The BrennerDebate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial

    Europe, pp. 1063. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Brenner, R. (1986) The Social Basis of Economic Development, in J. Roemer (ed.)

    Analytical Marxism, pp. 2353. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Brenner, R. (1989) Bourgeois Revolution and Transition to Capitalism, in A.L.

    Beier, D. Cannadine and J.M. Rosenheim (eds) The First Modern Society: Essays

    in English History in Honour of Lawrence Stone, pp. 271304. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

    Brumfiel, E.M. (1991) Weaving and Cooking: Womens Production in AztecMexico, in J.M. Gero and M.W. Conkey (eds) Engendering Archaeology: Womenand Prehistory, pp. 22451. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Brumfiel, E.M. and T.K. Earle (1987) Specialization, Exchange, and ComplexSocieties: An Introduction, in E.M. Brumfiel and T.K. Earle (eds) Specializa-tion, Exchange, and Complex Societies, pp. 19. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

    Chayanov, A. (1924/1986) On the Theory of Non-Capitalist Economic Systems, in

    D. Thorner, B. Kerblay, and R.E.F. Smith (eds) The Theory of Peasant Economy,pp. 128. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Childe, V.G. (1936/1983) Man Makes Himself. New York: The New American

    Library.

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    28/31

    334 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    Childe, V.G. (1950/2004) The Urban Revolution, in T.C. Patterson and C.E. Orser,Jr (eds) Foundations of Social Archaeology: Selected Writings of V. GordonChilde, pp. 10716. Walnut Creek: Altamira Press.

    Childe, V.G. (1958) The Prehistory of European Society. Harmondsworth: Penguin

    Books.Clark, J.E. (1995) Craft Specialization as an Archaeological Category, Research in

    Economic Anthropology 16: 26794.Costin, C.L. (1991) Craft Specialization: Issues in Defining, Documenting, and

    Explaining the Organization of Production, in M.B. Schiffer (ed.) Archaeo-logical Method and Theory, Vol. 3, pp. 156. Tucson: The University of ArizonaPress.

    Costin, C.L. (1998) Introduction: Craft and Social Identity, in C.L. Costin and R.P.Wright (eds) Craft and Social Identity, pp. 316. Arlington: American Anthro-pological Association.

    Costin, C.L. (2001) Craft Production Systems, in G.M. Feinman and T.D. Price(eds) Archaeology at the Millennium: A Sourcebook, pp. 273327. New York:Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.

    Costin, C.L. (2004) Craft Economies in Ancient Andean States, in G.M. Feinmanand L.M. Nicholas (eds) Archaeological Perspectives on Political Economies,pp. 189221. Salt Lake City: The University of Utah Press.

    Davis, W. (1983) Artists and Patrons in Predynastic and Early Dynastic Egypt,Studien zur altergyptischen Kultur10: 11939.

    Diamond, S. (2004) Anthropology in Question, Dialectical Anthropology 28(1):1132.

    Duby, G. (1968) Rural Economy and Country Life in the Medieval West. Columbia:University of South Carolina Press.

    Earle, T.K. (1981) Comment on Evolution of Specialized Pottery Production: ATrial Model by Prudence M. Rice, Current Anthropology 22(2): 2301.

    Ebert, V. and T.C. Patterson (forthcoming) Gender in South American Archaeol-ogy, in S.M. Nelson (ed.) The Handbook of Gender in Archaeology. WalnutCreek, CA: Altamira Press.

    Evans, R.K. (1978) Early Craft Specialization: An Example from the BalkanNeolithic, in C.L. Redman, M.J. Berman, E.V. Curtin, W.T. Langhorne, Jr, N.M.Versaggi and J.C. Wanser (eds) Social Archeology: Beyond Subsistence and

    Dating, pp. 11329. New York: Academic Press.Fox-Genovese, E. (1976) The Origins of Physiocracy: Economic Revolution and

    Social Order in Eighteenth-Century France. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Gailey,C.W. and T.C. Patterson (1988) State Formation and Uneven Development,

    in J. Gledhill, B. Bender and M.T. Larsen (eds) State and Society: The Emergenceand Development of Social Hierarchy and Political Centralization, pp. 7790.London: Unwin Hyman.

    Gero, J.M. and M.C. Scattolin (2002) Beyond Complementarity and Hierarchy:New Definitions for Archaeological Gender Relations, in S.M. Nelson and M.Rosen-Ayalon (eds) In Pursuit of Gender: Worldwide Archaeological

    Approaches, pp. 15572. Walnut Creek: Altamira Press.Gudeman, S. (2001) The Anthropology of Economy. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.Harris, E.M. (2002) Workshop, Marketplace, and Household: The Nature of Tech-

    nical Specialization in Classical Athens and its Influence on Economy and

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    29/31

    335Patterson Craft specialization

    Society, in P. Cartledge, E.E. Cohen and L. Foxhall (eds) Money, Labour, andLand: Approaches to the Economies of Ancient Greece, pp. 6799. London:Routledge.

    Hastorf, C. (1991) Gender, Space, and Food in Prehistory, in J.M. Gero and M.W.

    Conkey (eds) Engendering Archaeology: Women and Prehistory, pp. 13262.Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Heckscher, E.F. (1955) Mercantilism, Vol. 1. London: George Allen and Unwin.Hicks, F. (1986) Prehispanic Background of Colonial Political and Economic

    Organization in Central Mexico, in Victoria Bricker (ed.) Supplement to theHandbook of Middle American Indians, Vol. 4, pp. 3554. Austin, TX: Universityof Texas Press.

    Hicks,F. (1987) First Steps Toward a Market-Integrated Economy in Aztec Mexico,in H.J.M. Claessen and P. van de Velde (eds) Early State Dynamics, pp. 91107.Leiden: E.J. Brill.

    Hicks, F. (1999) The Middle Class in Ancient Central Mexico,Journal of Anthro-pological Research 55(3): 40928.

    Hilton, R. (1992) English and French Towns in Feudal Society: A Comparative Study.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Hobsbawm, E.J., ed. (1964) Introduction, in K. Marx: Pre-Capitalist EconomicFormations, pp. 965. London: Lawrence and Wishart.

    Jones, P.M. (1988) The Peasantry in the French Revolution. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

    Kriedte, P., H. Medick and J. Schlumbohm (1977/1981) Industrialization beforeIndustrialization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Leacock, E.B. (1982) Relations of Production in Band Societies, in E. Leacock andR. Lee (eds) Politics and History in Band Societies, pp. 15970. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

    Locke, J. (1690/1980) Second Treatise on Government. Indianapolis: HackettPublishing.

    Lwy, M. and R. Sayre (2001) Romanticism Against the Tide of Modernity. Durham:Duke University Press.

    McNally, D. (1988) Political Economy and the Rise of Capitalism: A Reinterpretation.Berkeley: University of California Press.

    McNally, D. (1993)Against the Market: Political Economy, Market Socialism and the

    Marxist Critique. London: Verso.Magnusson, L. (1994) Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language.

    London: Routledge.Marx, K. (1847/1963) The Poverty of Philosophy: Answer to the Philosophy of

    Poverty, Written by M. Proudhon. New York: International Publishers.Marx, K. (18578/1973) Grundrisse: Introduction to the Critique of Political

    Economy. New York: Vintage Books.Marx, K. (1859/1970) A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy. New

    York: International Publishers.Marx, K. (18637/1977) Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1. New York:

    Vintage Books.Marx, K. (18802/1974) The Ethnological Notebooks of Karl Marx. Assen: Van

    Gorcum and Company.Marx, K. (1881/1983) Marx-Zasulich Correspondence: Letters and Drafts, in

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    30/31

    336 Journal of Social Archaeology 5(3)

    T. Shanin (ed.) Late Marx and the Russian Road: Marx and The Peripheries ofCapitalism, pp. 97126. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Marx, K. and F. Engels (18445/1974) The German Ideology. New York: Inter-national Publishers.

    Marx, K. and F. Engels (1848/1998) The Manifesto of the Communist Party, in E.J.Hobsbawm (ed.) The Communist Manifesto: A Modern Edition, pp. 3177.London: Verso.

    Meek,R.L. (1962) The Economics of Physiocracy: Essays and Translations. London:George Allen and Unwin.

    Meek, R.L. (1976) Social Science and the Ignoble Savage. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

    Murra, J.V. (1980) The Economic Organization of the Inka State. Greenwich: JAIPress.

    Nikin, A.A. (1975) A Science in its Youth (Pre-Marxian Political Economy).

    Moscow: Progress Publishers.Oakley, A. (19845) Marxs Critique of Political Economy: Intellectual Sources and

    Evolution, 2 vols. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Outhwaite, W. (1994) Habermas: A Critical Introduction. Stanford: Stanford

    University Press.Patterson, T.C. (1987) Merchant Capital and the Formation of the Inca State,

    Dialectical Anthropology 12(2): 21728.Patterson,T.C. (1992) The Inca Empire: The Formation and Disintegration of a Pre-

    Capitalist State. Oxford: Berg Publishers.Patterson, T.C. (1997) Inventing Western Civilization. New York: Monthly Review

    Press.Patterson, T.C. (2003) Marxs Ghost: Conversations with Archaeologists. Oxford:

    Berg Publishers.Pyburn, K.A. (2004) Preface, in K.A. Pyburn (ed.) Ungendering Civilization,

    pp. xixiii. London: Routledge.Redfield, R. (1942/1962) The Folk Society, in M.P. Redfield (ed.) Papers of Robert

    Redfield, Vol. 1, pp. 23153. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Rubin, I.I. (1929/1979)A History of Economic Thought. London: Ink Links.Sahlins, M.D. (1972) Stone Age Economics. Chicago: Aldine Publishers.Schortman, E.M. and P.A. Urban (2004) Modeling the Roles of Craft Production in

    Ancient Political Economies,Journal of Archaeological Research 12(2): 185226.Siskind, J. (1991) Class Discourse in an Early 19th-Century New England Factory,

    Dialectical Anthropology 16(1): 3550.Smith, A. (1776/1976) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of

    Nations, 2 vols. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Stein, G.J. (1998) Heterogeneity, Power, and Political Economy: Some Current

    Research Issues in the Archaeology of Old World Complex Societies, Journalof Archaeological Research 6(1): 144.

    Stein, G.J. and M.J. Blackman (1993) The Organizational Context of SpecializedCraft Production in Early Mesopotamian States, Research in Economic Anthro-

    pology 14: 2959.Testart, A. (1986) Le communisme primitif, tome 1, Economie et idologie. Paris:

    Editions de la Maison des Sciences de lHomme.

  • 8/10/2019 01 Patterson 2005 Craft Specialization

    31/31

    337Patterson Craft specialization

    Testart,A. (1987) Appropriation of the Social Product and Production Relations inHunter-gatherer Societies, Dialectical Anthropology 12(2): 14764.

    Thapar, R. (1981) The State as Empire, in H.J.M. Claessen and P. Skalnk (eds)The Study of the State, pp. 40626. The Hague: Mouton Publishers.

    Thompson, E.P. (1967/1991) Time, Work-Discipline and Industrial Capitalism, inE.P. Thompson (ed.) Customs in Common: Studies in Traditional PopularCulture, pp. 352403. New York: The New Press.

    Tribe, K. (1978) Land, Labour and Economic Discourse. London: Routledge andKegan Paul.

    Tribe, K. (1981) Genealogies of Capitalism. Atlantic Highlands: Humanities Press.Trigger, B.G. (1998) Sociocultural Evolution. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.Wailes, B. (1996) V. Gordon Childe and the Relations of Production, in B. Wailes

    (ed.) Craft Specialization and Social Evolution: In Memory of V. Gordon Childe,University Museum Monograph 93, pp. 314. Philadelphia: The University of

    Pennsylvania Museum.Wallace-Hadrill, A., ed. (1990) Patronage in Ancient Society. London: Routledge.Whatley, C.A. (1997) The Industrial Revolution in Scotland. Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press.Wilentz, S. (1984) Chants Democratic: New York City and the Rise of the American

    Working Class. New York: Oxford University Press.Wood, E.M. (1988) The State and Popular Sovereignty in French Political Thought:

    A Genealogy of Rousseaus General Will, in F. Krantz (ed.) History fromBelow, pp. 83112. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Wood, N. (1984)John Locke and Agrarian Capitalism. Berkeley: University of Cali-

    fornia Press.Zilsel, E. (1942) The Sociological Roots of Science,American Journal of Sociol-

    ogy 47: 54462.Zilsel, E. (1945/1957) The Genesis of the Concept of Scientific Progress, in P.J.

    Wiener and A. Noland (eds) Roots of Scientific Thought: A Cultural Perspective,pp. 25175. New York: Basic Books.

    THOMAS C. PATTERSON is Distinguished Professor and Chair of

    Anthropology, University of California,Riverside. Besides his works on the

    history of anthropology and archaeology, his books include Marxs Ghost:

    Conversations with Archaeologists and Foundations of Social Archaeology:Selected Writings of V. Gordon Childe (edited with Charles E. Orser, Jr.).

    [email: [email protected]]


Recommended