+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally...

1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally...

Date post: 17-Dec-2015
Category:
Upload: crystal-edwards
View: 220 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
50
1 Chapter 11 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: Binomial Option Pricing: II II
Transcript
Page 1: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

1

Chapter 11Chapter 11Binomial Option Pricing: IIBinomial Option Pricing: II

Page 2: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

2

Understanding Early Exercise

Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration.

By exercising a Call option, the option holder

receives the stock and thus receives dividends,

pays the strike price prior to expiration (this has an interest cost),

loses the insurance/flexibility implicit in the call.

Page 3: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

3

Understanding Early Exercise

By exercising a Put option, the option holder

receives the strike price and thus collects interest on it going forward,

gives the stock away and thus stops receiving dividends

loses the insurance/flexibility implicit in the put.

Page 4: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

4

Call Option Without Dividends

Put-Call Parity says: C=P+S-Ke-rT

Since P>0, C>S-Ke-rT

And since K>Ke-rT , we have C>S-K Therefore the Call price C is always

greater than the intrinsic value S-K (which is what you would get if you exercised).

Thus it is never optimal to exercise an American Call option on a non-dividend paying stock!!!

Page 5: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

5

Call Option With Dividends

Put-Call Parity says: C=P+S-Ke-rT-D (where D is the present value of all future dividends to be

received) So C = S-K + P + K-Ke-rT – D Thus C = S-K + P + K(1-e-rT) – D

Therefore, when S is high and thus P close to zero, the Call price C can be greater or lower than the intrinsic value S-K (which is what you would get if you exercised) depending on whether K(1-e-rT) is greater or lower than D, i.e. whether the interest saved by delaying the payment K is greater or lower than the lost dividends.

Thus it can be optimal to exercise an American Call option on a dividend-paying stock.

Page 6: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

6

Put Option Without Dividends

Put-Call Parity says: P=C+Ke-rT-S Thus P = K-S + C-K(1-e-rT) Therefore the Put price P can be greater

or lower than the intrinsic value K-S depending on whether C is greater or lower than K(1-e-rT).

Thus even on a non-dividend paying stock, it may be optimal to exercise a Put option ! (It usually happens for low values of S, when C is very small)

Page 7: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

7

Understanding Risk-Neutral Pricing A risk-neutral investor is indifferent between a sure thing and a

risky bet with an expected payoff equal to the value of the sure thing.

p* is the risk-neutral probability that the stock price will go up.

The option pricing formula can be said to price options as if investors are risk-neutral. Note that we are not assuming that investors are actually

risk-neutral, and that risky assets are actually expected to earn the risk-free rate of return.

Page 8: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

8

Pricing an option using risk-neutral probabilities

Consider a world populated by risk-neutral investors.

Investors would only be concerned with expected returns, and not about the level of risk.

Hence investors would not “charge” or require a premium for risky securities.

Therefore risky securities would have the same expected rate of return as riskless securities. In other words, every security is returning the risk-free rate.

Page 9: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

9

Fine point to think about:

Now consider the following scenario: suppose a risky security is expected to achieve great growth and great future profits. (You can even assume that the security actually delivers on its promises later, if you wish.)

Even though risk-neutral investors might only usually require the risk-free rate of return, doesn’t this mean that the expected rate of return on this security will be much higher than the risk-free rate? And if yes, doesn’t that invalidate what we’ve just discussed?

WHAT IS GOING ON HERE ? ANY POSSIBLE RECONCILIATION OF THE TWO IDEAS?

Page 10: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

10

Pricing an option using risk-neutral probabilities

If the stock is thus expected to earn the risk-free rate r and pays out a continuous dividend yield , then the risk-neutral probability p* that the stock will go up must satisfy:

p*u ehS + (1 – p*)d ehS = erhS

Solving for p* gives us

( )he dp*

u d

r

Page 11: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

11

Pricing an option using real probabilities

Is option pricing consistent with standard discounted cash flow calculations?

Yes. However, discounted cash flow is not used in practice to price options. This is because it is necessary to compute the option price

in order to compute the correct discount rate.

Page 12: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

12

Pricing an option using real probabilities

Suppose that the continuously compounded expected return on the stock is and that the stock does not pay dividends.

If p is the true probability of the stock going up, p must be consistent with u, d, and :

puS + (1 – p)dS = ehS (11.3)

Solving for p gives us

(11.4)p

e d

u d

h

Page 13: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

13

Pricing an option using real probabilities Using p, the actual expected payoff to the option one

period hence is

(11.5)

At what rate do we discount this expected payoff?

It is not correct to discount the option at the expected return on the stock, , because the option is equivalent to a leveraged investment in the stock and hence is riskier than the stock.

pC p Ce d

u dC

u e

u dCu d

h

u

h

d

( )1

Page 14: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

14

Pricing an option using real probabilities Let us denote the appropriate per-period discount

rate for the option as .

Since an option is equivalent to holding a portfolio consisting of shares of stock and B bonds, the expected return on this portfolio is

(11.6)

And since an option is equivalent to holding a portfolio consisting of shares of stock and B bonds, the denominator is indeed the option price. This confirms that in order to compute the discount rate , one needs to have the price of the option first.

eS

S Be

B

S Beh h rh

Page 15: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

15

Pricing an option using real probabilities

We can nevertheless now compute the option price as the expected option payoff, discounted at the appropriate discount rate, given by equation (11.6).

We thus need to compute: (11.7)

It turns out that this gives us the same option price as performing the risk-neutral calculation.

C ee d

u dC

u e

u dCh

h

u

h

d

Page 16: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

16

Application: one-period example

Assume the following information: =15%, S=$41, K=$40, S=0.30, r=8%, T=1,

h=1, and =0. The “up-price” for the stock is $59.954 and the “down-price” is $32.903.

Compute the price of a European call option by using:

• True probabilities

• Risk-neutral probabilities

Are the results identical?

Page 17: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

17

Application: one-period example

The true up probability is (with u = 59.954 / 41 = 1.4623 and d = 32.903 / 41 = 0.8025):

p = [e0.15-0.8025] / [1.4623-0.8025] = 0.5446. The expected option payoff therefore is: 0.5446($19.954) + (1-0.5446)($0) = $10.867

We now need to compute the discount rate in order to get the option price today.

Page 18: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

18

Application: one-period example

For , we need the values of and B. = (19.954-0)/(59.954-32.903) = 0.738 B is the present value of loan needed to match cash

flows of S and option (pick the case where stock goes down, since easier – but works for both):

B = -e-0.08[(0.738)(32.903)-0] = - $ 22.405 We thus have:

Or = ln(1.386) = 32.64%

h 0.15 0.08(41)0.738 (-22.405)e e e

(41)0.738 (-22.405) (41)0.738 (-22.405)

Page 19: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

19

Application: one-period example

Finally, armed with , we can compute the discounted expected option value as:

C = e-.3264(10.867) = $ 7.839

Page 20: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

20

Application: one-period example

The risk-neutral probability of the stock going up is:

p* = [e0.08-0.8025] / [1.4623-0.8025] = 0.4256.

The call option price therefore is:

C = e-0.08[(0.4256)(19.954)+(1- 0.4256)(0)] = $ 7.839

This is exactly the price we obtained before.

Page 21: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

21

The Binomial Tree and Lognormality

The usefulness of the binomial pricing model hinges on the binomial tree providing a reasonable representation of the stock price distribution.

The binomial tree approximates a lognormal distribution.

Page 22: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

22

The random walk model

It is often said that stock prices follow a random walk.

Imagine that we flip a coin repeatedly. Let the random variable Y denote the outcome of the flip. If the coin lands displaying a head, Y = 1; otherwise, Y = –

1. If the probability of a head is 50%, we say the coin is fair. After n flips, with the ith flip denoted Yi, the cumulative total,

Zn, is

(11.8)

It turns out that the more times we flip, on average the farther we will move from where we started.

Z Yn iin 1

Page 23: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

23

The random walk model

We can represent the process followed by Zn in term of the change in Zn:

Zn – Zn-1 = Yn

or

Heads: Zn – Zn-1 = +1

Tails: Zn – Zn-1 = –1

Page 24: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

24

The random walk model

A random walk, where with heads, the change in Z is 1, and with tails, the change in Z is – 1:

Page 25: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

25

The random walk model

The idea that asset prices should follow a random walk was articulated in Samuelson (1965).

In efficient markets, an asset price should reflect all available information. In response to new information the price is equally likely to move up or down, as with the coin flip.

The price after a period of time is the initial price plus the cumulative up and down movements due to new information.

Page 26: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

26

Modeling prices as a random walk.

The above description of a random walk is not a satisfactory description of stock price movements. There are at least three problems with this model:

1. If by chance we get enough cumulative down movements, the stock price will become negative.

2. The magnitude of the move ($1) should depend upon how quickly the coin flips occur and the level of the stock price.

3. The stock, on average, should have a positive return. However, the random walk model taken literally does not permit this.

The binomial model is a variant of the random walk model that solves all of these problems.

Page 27: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

27

Continuously compounded returns

The binomial model assumes that continuously compounded returns are a random walk.

Some important properties of continuously compounded returns:

The logarithmic function computes returns from prices. The exponential function computes prices from returns. Continuously compounded returns are additive. Continuously compounded returns can be less than –100%.

Page 28: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

28

The standard deviation of returns

Suppose the continuously compounded return over month i is rmonthly,i. The annual return is

The variance of the annual return is

(11.14)

r rannual monthly ii ,112

Var r Var rannual monthly,ii( ) 112

Page 29: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

29

The standard deviation of returns Suppose that returns are uncorrelated over time and that each

month has the same variance of returns. Then from equation (11.14) we have

2 = 12 2monthly ,

where 2 is the annual variance.

The annual standard deviation is

If we split the year into n periods of length h (so that h = 1/n), the standard deviation over the period of length h is

(11.15)

monthly

12

h h

Page 30: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

30

The binomial model

The binomial model is

Taking logs, we obtain

(11.16)

Since ln (St+h/St) is the continuously compounded return from t to t+h, the binomial model is simply a particular way to model the continuously compounded return.

That return has two parts, one of which is certain, (r–)h, and the other of which is uncertain, h.

S S et h tr h h

( )

ln S S r h ht h t( / ) ( )

Page 31: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

31

The binomial model

Equation (11.6) solves the three problems in the random walk:

1. The stock price cannot become negative.

2. As h gets smaller, up and down moves get smaller.

3. There is a (r – )h term, and we can choose the probability of an up move, so we can guarantee that the expected change in the stock price is positive.

Page 32: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

32

Lognormality and the binomial model The binomial tree approximates a lognormal distribution, which

is commonly used to model stock prices.

The lognormal distribution is the probability distribution that arises from the assumption that continuously compounded returns on the stock are normally distributed.

With the lognormal distribution, the stock price is positive, and the distribution is skewed to the right, that is, there is a chance of extremely high stock prices.

Page 33: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

33

Lognormality and the binomial model

The binomial model implicitly assigns probabilities to the various nodes.

Page 34: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

34

Lognormality and the binomial model

The following information is used to draw the graphs on the next slides: initial stock price S = 100, volatility=30%, E(RS)=10%, T=1year, and we divide the 1-year period into 25 periods (h=1/25). Note that n=25.

The probability of the stock going up from one period to the next is p=[eRh-d]/[u-d]

Use u=esqrt(h) and d=esqrt(h) .

Proba of reaching ith node =(number of ways to reach ith node) pn-i(1-p)i

where number of ways to reach ith node = n!/[(n-i)!i!]

Page 35: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

35

Lognormality and the binomial model

The following graph compares the probability distribution for a 25-period binomial tree with the corresponding lognormal distribution:

Page 36: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

36

Lognormality and the binomial model

0 1 448.168907 0.00%1 25 397.4901627 0.00% u= 1.0618372 300 352.5421487 0.00% d= 0.9417653 2300 312.6768365 0.01%4 12650 277.3194764 0.07%5 53130 245.9603111 0.27%6 177100 218.1472265 0.84%7 480700 193.4792334 2.11%8 1081575 171.6006862 4.41%9 2042975 152.1961556 7.74%10 3268760 134.9858808 11.51%11 4457400 119.7217363 14.59%12 5200300 106.1836547 15.81%13 5200300 94.17645336 14.69%14 4457400 83.52702114 11.70%15 3268760 74.08182207 7.97%16 2042975 65.70468198 4.63%17 1081575 58.27482524 2.28%18 480700 51.68513345 0.94%19 177100 45.84060113 0.32%20 53130 40.65696597 0.09%21 12650 36.05949402 0.02%22 2300 31.98190218 0.00%23 300 28.36540265 0.00%24 25 25.15785531 0.00%25 1 22.31301601 0.00%

node number of ways to reach ith node terminal stock price probability to reach ith node

p*0.518384556

0.00%

2.00%

4.00%

6.00%

8.00%

10.00%

12.00%

14.00%

16.00%

18.00%

0 100 200 300 400 500

Page 37: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

37

Lognormality and the binomial model: Exercise

Use the following information to draw a probability distribution graph: initial stock price S = 100, volatility=30%, E(RS)=10%, T=1year, and we divide the 1-year period into 3 periods (h=1/3). Note that n=3.

The probability of the stock going up from one period to the next is p=[eRh-d]/[u-d]

Use u=esqrt(h) and d=esqrt(h) .

Proba of reaching ith node =(number of ways to reach ith node) x pn-i(1-p)i

where number of ways to reach ith node = n!/[(n-i)!i!]

Page 38: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

38

Lognormality and the binomial model: Solution

1 A B C D E F G H2 0 1 168.1380601 17.02%3 1 3 118.9109944 41.07% u= 1.18911 ==>EXP(0.3*SQRT(1/3))4 2 3 84.09651314 33.05% d= 0.840965 ==>EXP(-0.3*SQRT(1/3))5 3 1 59.47493384 8.86%6 node number of ways terminal stock price probability to reach ith node7 to reach ith node8 p*9 0.5541659 =A$9^(3-A3)*(1-A$9)^A3*B3

1011 =FACT(3)/(FACT(3-A3)*FACT(A3))1213 =(G$3^(3-A5)*(G$4)^A5)*100

=(EXP(0.1/3)-G3)/(G2-G3)

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

25.00%

30.00%

35.00%

40.00%

45.00%

0 50 100 150 200

Page 39: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

39

Alternative binomial trees

There are other ways besides equation (11.6) to construct a binomial tree that approximates a lognormal distribution. An acceptable tree must match the standard deviation of

the continuously compounded return on the asset and must generate an appropriate distribution as h 0.

Different methods of constructing the binomial tree will result in different u and d stock movements.

No matter how we construct the tree, to determine the risk-neutral probability, we use

and to determine the option value, we use

C = e–rh [p* Cu + (1 – p*) Cd]

pe d

u d

r h

*

( )

Page 40: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

40

Alternative binomial trees

The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein binomial tree: The tree is constructed as

(11.18)

A problem with this approach is that if h is large or is small, it is possible that erh > eh. In this case, the binomial tree violates the restriction of u > e(r–)h > d.

In practice, h is usually small, so the above problem does not occur.

u e h

d e h

Page 41: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

41

Alternative binomial trees

The lognormal tree: The tree is constructed as

(11.19)

Although the three different binomial models give different option prices for finite n, as n all three binomial trees approach the same price.

u e r h h ( . ) 0 5 2

d e r h h ( . ) 0 5 2

Page 42: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

42

Is the binomial model realistic?

The binomial model is a form of the random walk model, adapted to modeling stock prices. The lognormal random walk model here assumes that volatility is constant, “large” stock price movements do not occur, returns are independent over time.

All of these assumptions appear to be violated in the data.

Page 43: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

43

Estimated Volatility

We need to decide what value to assign to , which we cannot observe directly.

One possibility is to measure by computing the standard deviation of continuously compounded historical returns.

Volatility computed from historical stock returns is historical volatility.

This is a reasonable way to estimate volatility when continuously compounded returns are independent and identically distributed.

If returns are not independent—as with some commodities— volatility estimation becomes more complicated.

Page 44: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

44

Stock Paying Discrete Dividends

Suppose that a dividend will be paid between times t and t+h and that its future value at time t+h is D.

The time t forward price for delivery at t+h is

Ft,t+h = St erh – D

Since the stock price at time t+h will be ex-dividend, we create the up and down moves based on the ex-dividend stock price:

(11.20)S S e D et

ut

rh h ( )

S S e D etd

trh h ( )

Page 45: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

45

Stock Paying Discrete Dividends

When a dividend is paid, we have to account for the fact that the stock earns the dividend.

(Sut + D) + erh B = Cu

(Sdt + D) + erh B = Cd

The solution is

Because the dividend is known, we decrease the bond position by the PV of the certain dividend.

C C

S Su d

tu

td

B eS C S C

S SDerh t

ud t

du

tu

td

rh

Page 46: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

46

Problems with the discrete dividend tree

1. The conceptual problem with equation (11.20) is that the stock price could in principle become negative if there have been large downward moves in the stock prior to the dividend.

2. The practical problem is that the tree does not completely recombine after a discrete dividend.

The following tree, where a $5 dividend is paid between periods 1 and 2, demonstrates that with a discrete dividend, the order of up and down movements affects the price.

In the third binomial period, there are six rather than four possible stock prices.

Page 47: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

47

Problems with the discrete dividend tree

Page 48: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

48

A binomial tree using the prepaid forward Hull (1997) presents a method of constructing a tree for a

dividend-paying stock that solves both problems.

If we know for certain that a stock will pay a fixed dividend, then we can view the stock price as being the sum of two components:

1. the dividend, which is like a zero-coupon bond with zero volatility, and

2. the PV of the ex-dividend value of the stock, i.e., the prepaid forward price.

Page 49: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

49

A binomial tree using the prepaid forward

Suppose we know that a stock will pay a dividend D at time

TD < T, where T is the expiration date of the option.

We base stock price movements on the prepaid forward price

The one-period forward price for the prepaid forward is

This gives us up and down movements of

However, the actual stock price at each node is given by

u erh h

d erh h

F S Det TP

tr T tD

, ( )

F F et t h t TP rh

. ,

S = F Det t TP r T tD

, ( )

Page 50: 1 Chapter 11 Binomial Option Pricing: II. 2 Understanding Early Exercise Options may be rationally exercised prior to expiration. By exercising a Call.

50

A binomial tree using the prepaid forward

A binomial tree constructed using the prepaid-forward method:


Recommended