+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

Date post: 07-Jul-2018
Category:
Upload: ngurahwardana
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 15

Transcript
  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    1/15

    International Journal of Information Management 32 (2012) 35–49

    Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

    International Journal of Information Management

     journal homepage: www.elsevier .com/ locate / i j infomgt

    Knowledge complementarity and knowledge exchange in supply channel

    relationships

    Kyung Kyu Kim a,∗, Narayan S. Umanath b,1, Joo Young Kim a, Fred Ahrens c, Beomsoo Kim a,2

    a Yonsei University, Seoul, SouthKoreab University of Cincinnati, 328 Lindner Hall, Cincinnati, OH 45221-0211, United Statesc Department of Information Systems, University of Cincinnati, Cincinnati, OH 45221-0211, UnitedStates

    a r t i c l e i n f o

     Article history:

    Keywords:

    Knowledge exchange

    Knowledge complementarity

    Supply chain management

    a b s t r a c t

    Existing literature on knowledge exchange in inter-organizational relationships (e.g., a supply channel)

    reveals two opposing forces at work: (1) collaborative behavior and (2) opportunistic behavior. A con-

    current assessment of the opposing perspectives and the contingencies under which each is relevant for

    supply channel performance can add valuable insights about the dynamics of knowledge exchange. We

     juxtapose the two behavior patterns using social capital theory and transaction cost economics (TCE)

    respectively as the explicators and employ knowledge complementarity as the contingency to recon-

    cile the opposing behavior patterns. The choice of knowledge complementarity in this role stems from

    ample theoretical and empirical support in prior literature about the criticality of this factor in inter-firm

    knowledge exchange.

    We propose a research model, and use data from a field study of 82 firms in the Electronics Manufactur-

    ing Services (EMS) industry to test our model. Our findings indicate that overall inter-organizationaltrust

    (a surrogate for social capital) and knowledge complementarity promote knowledge exchange behavior

    in a supply channel. The retarding effect of risk of opportunism (a TCE dimension) manifests only when

    knowledge complementarity is low. However, when knowledge complementarity is high, contrary to

    expectations, inter-organizational trust appears to impede knowledge exchange. Our post hoc analysis of 

    this intriguing, counterintuitive result leads us to knowledge interdependence and dependence asym-metry as potentially critical antecedents to knowledge complementarity. Implication of our findings to

    academic research and supply chain scenario is also articulated.

    © 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    1. Introduction

    Although knowledge exchange (KE) in inter-organizational

    relationships has become increasingly important, few companies

    have fully exploited the knowledge resources of their partners.

    Organizations in a supply chain require access to partner firms’

    knowledge (e.g., about markets, products, and raw materials, etc.),

    which they consider essential or useful to their operations, pro-

    viding mutual benefits (Barratt & Oke, 2007; White, Daniel, &

    Mohdzain, 2005). Knowledge from customer and/or supplier orga-nizations may help improve overall supply chain performance and

    their own internal decision making and operating performance

    (Mabert & Venkataramanan, 1998). However, academic scholars

    (e.g., Bowersox, Closs, & Cooper, 2010) predict that it may be a

    ∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +82 2 21234525.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (K.K. Kim), [email protected] (N.S.

    Umanath), [email protected] (J.Y. Kim), [email protected] (F. Ahrens),

    [email protected](B. Kim).1 Tel.: +1 513 5567195.2 Tel.: +822 2123 4527.

    long time before firms cooperate to form a fully collaborative end-

    to-end supply chain. Why can only a few firms benefit from the

    knowledge of their partners? Scholars in both operations manage-

    ment (OM) and strategic management have researched inter-firm

    knowledge exchange, but differences in focus between the various

    approaches have left us with an incomplete understanding of what

    causes knowledge exchange to occur and how it benefits the firms

    throughout a supply chain. In one line of research, scholars have

    focused on organizational social capital perspectives, asserting that

    networks of relationships are valuable resources (i.e., capital) foran organization and conduits for knowledge exchange. The social

    capital view asserts thatrelational rentsare possible when partners

    combine or exchange knowledge and/or when they employ effec-

    tive governance mechanisms that permit the realization of rents

    through a synergistic combination of assets, knowledge, or capa-

    bilities (Dyer & Singh, 1998). On this view, supply chain partners

    are considered the means with which to acquire the complemen-

    taryresourcesand capabilities thatfirms otherwise lack.Thus, from

    the socialcapital view, an effective strategy requires a firmto share

    valuable knowledge systematically with its partners in return for

    access to their knowledge bases.

    0268-4012/$ – see front matter © 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2011.05.002

    http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2011.05.002http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2011.05.002http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/02684012http://www.elsevier.com/locate/ijinfomgtmailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2011.05.002http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2011.05.002mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://www.elsevier.com/locate/ijinfomgthttp://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/02684012http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_5/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2011.05.002

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    2/15

    36   K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of InformationManagement  32 (2012) 35–49

    In another line of research, in contrast, transaction cost eco-

    nomics (TCE) has focused on firms’ concerns with transaction risks

    when they release their knowledge resources outside the firm

    (e.g., Clemons & Hitt, 2004; Madhok & Tallman, 1998). The inter-

    organizational knowledge exchange dilemma is that “(1) being a

    good partner invites exploitation by partners attempting to max-

    imize their individual appropriation of the joint learning, and

    (2) such opportunistic learning strategies undercut the collective

    knowledge development in a collaborative relationship” (Larsson,

    Bengtsson, Henriksson, & Sparks, 1998). An organization’s oppor-

    tunistic behavior may result in gaining more knowledge relative

    to its partners in the short-term, but this exploitation is likely to

     jeopardize supply-chain relationships and/or cause other partners

    to behave opportunistically as well (Park & Ungson, 2001). The

    probable result is that neither organization will contribute to the

    knowledge exchange process. This relative withholding of knowl-

    edge reduces the overall effectiveness of knowledge exchange in

    a supply chain, potentially defeating the purpose of knowledge

    exchange.

    Inter-firmrelationshipsseem necessary for inter-organizational

    knowledge exchange to occur, but knowledge exchange may be

    hindered by concerns with transaction risk. In order to enhance

    our understanding of knowledge exchange among supply chain

    partners, a concurrent assessment of opposing theories based on

    the social capital perspective and transaction risk perspective and

    the contingencies under which each theory is relevant to supply-

    chain performance is crucial. By examining the literature (e.g.,

    Stieglitz & Heine, 2007) and the related theories (Milgrom, Qian,

    & Roberts, 1991), we have identified an important contingency,

    namely, knowledge complementarity (KC), which may help us

    understand behavior patterns in knowledge exchange. This study

    seeks to explore the contingency effect of knowledge comple-

    mentarity on knowledge exchange activity among supply chain

    partners.

    In this paper, we formulate a research model driven by compet-

    ing theories of social capital and transaction risk and develop and

    test appropriate hypotheses, using data collected from purchas-

    ing managers at 82 firms in the Electronics Manufacturing Services(EMS)industry.Specifically, the sample firmsare intermediate pro-

    ducers in the EMS industry that rely on first-tier suppliers for their

    parts and components. These intermediate producers assemble

    low-level parts fromfirst-tiersubcontractors into stable intermedi-

    ate components.The finaloutputs fromthe intermediate producers

    are sold to manufacturers who finally proceed to mount them on

    specific models to be sold to final customers. Intermediate pro-

    ducers do not have access to the final market for electronics. The

    flow of intermediate products in complex industrial activities pro-

    vides a good context within which to study knowledge exchange

    in procurement and supply relationships.

    The next section reviews the relevant literature proposing the-

    ories about inter-firm knowledge exchange. The third section

    discusses the direct effects of social capital and transaction riskperspectives on inter-organizational knowledge exchange. It also

    describes the moderating effects of knowledge complementarity

    on the relationship between forces from the transaction risk/social

    capital perspectives and knowledge exchange. The fourth sec-

    tion describes our research method, and the fifth section presents

    empirical results. We conclude with a discussion of our results and

    their implications.

    2. Inter-firmknowledge exchange

    Pervasive electronic networks enable companies to exchange

    knowledge far more efficiently and effectively than ever before.

    This improvement in the economics of knowledge exchange and

    transaction costs has caused entire industries to reorganize rad-

    ically and dramatically, unbundling the traditional value chain

    (Hagel & Singer, 1999). Firms are relying more on outside part-

    ners to facilitate cost-effective delivery of value to customers,

    since the relevant knowledge is often located outside the firm’s

    particular field (Ye & Agarwal, 2003). Indeed, the proliferation

    of inter-organizational collaborative relationships is considered

    to be driven by the challenge of growing knowledge intensity

    (Adler & Kwon, 2002), which has made knowledge exchange in

    inter-organizational relationships ever more important in today’s

    globalized business environment.

    However, many of the challenges stemming from knowledge

    exchange arise from barriers between source and recipient firms.

    Hsiao, Tsai, and Lee (2003) identify typical barriers to knowledge

    exchange, including unwillingness to share important knowledge

    (e.g., Nahapiet & Ghoshal, 1998), lack of the recipient’s absorptive

    and assimilation capacity (e.g., Lane & Lubatkin, 1998), obstacles to

    effective knowledge search (e.g., Rivikin, 2001), unproven knowl-

    edge content (e.g.,Szulanski,1996), technological incompatibilities

    (e.g., Weill & Vitale, 2002), knowledge-conversion difficulties (e.g.,

    Nonaka, 1994), and socio-political issues (e.g., Hayes & Walsham,

    2001).

    A review of prior studies reveals that these barriers can be

    explained according to one of two opposing theories – namely,

    social capital theory and transaction cost economics – which sug-

    gest that the forces behind the knowledge exchange phenomenon

    may be simultaneously in harmony and at conflict. This study fur-

    ther explains the two opposing theoretical perspectives.

    Transaction risk, a component of transaction costs, is the

    possibility that a trading partner will behave opportunistically

    (Williamson, 1985), leading to uncertainty about the level and

    division of benefits accruing from increased knowledge exchange.

    Among the sources of transaction risk frequently cited in the lit-

    erature (e.g., transaction specific capital, loss of resource control,

    and information asymmetries), loss of resource control is particu-

    larly relevant to inter-firm knowledge exchange. Loss of resource

    control occurs if resources, transferred as part of the relationship,

    cannot be returned or controlled during the relationship (Clemons& Hitt, 2004). Information or know-how is an example of important

    resources subject to loss of control. Once knowledge is transferred

    and assimilated into the recipient’s knowledgebase, it is difficult,if 

    not impossible, for the source firm to control access and the subse-

    quent use of that knowledge. The recipient firm may deliberately

    use knowledge for its own economic benefits at the expense of 

    the source firm and the entire supply chain perhaps by sharing it

    across competing supply channels. In order to manage this trans-

    action risk, supply chain participants may not be willing to share

    important knowledge with each other. For instance, the buyer may

    consider it necessary to maintain a certain level of information

    asymmetrywith the supplier,especiallyregarding the downstream

    supply chain data lest the supplier should use the downstream

    data opportunistically at the expense of the supply chain perfor-mance (i.e., fear of disintermediation) (Bowersox et al., 2010). The

    transaction risk perspective can also explain other challenges to

    knowledge exchange arising from barriers such as lack of motiva-

    tion and unwillingness to share important knowledge (Malhotra,

    Gosain, & Omar, 2005).

    In contrast, social capital theory asserts that networks of rela-

    tionships constitute a valuable resource for the conduct of social

    interactions. Social capital is defined as “the sum of the actual

    and potential resources embedded within, available through, and

    derived from the network of relationships possessed by an indi-

    vidual or social unit” (Nahapiet & Ghoshal, 1998, p. 243). The

    social capital perspective offers a rationale for cooperative behav-

    ior such as knowledge exchange (e.g., Hult, Ketchen, Cavusgil, &

    Calantone, 2006). The primary motivation behind the formation

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    3/15

    K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of Information Management  32 (2012) 35–49 37

    of inter-organizational relationships is to gain access to valu-

    able partner-held resources. Mutual need makes alliances for the

    exchange of resources even more likely. For example, sharing

    knowledgeabout ultimatemarket demand among cooperative sup-

    ply chain participants is known to be effective for dealing with

    the “bullwhip” effect,3 consequently improving the performance

    of the entire supply chain (up/down stream). The “bullwhip” effect

    is said to be a core problem in supply-chain management, because

    it distorts demand information transmitted upstream in the sup-

    ply chain(e.g., Lee,1997). This supposedlyhappens when a supplier

    forecastsdemand patterns on the basis of theorder history from its

    immediate downstream partner (buyer), instead of on the basis of 

    salesinformation fromultimate customers. This lineof research has

    identified barriers to knowledge exchange between the source and

    the recipient as the recipient’s lack of relative absorptive capacity,

    obstacles to effective knowledge search, and unproven knowledge

    content.

    Table 1 summarizes the barriers to knowledge exchange predi-

    cated on social capital theory or transaction risk theory.

    In summary, the existing literature on knowledge exchange

    among supply chain partners suggests two counteracting forces

    underlying knowledge exchange: (1) firms are willing to share

    knowledge with supply-chain partners and trust, a social capital,

    facilitates such an exchange; and (2) firms want to maintain some

    degree of knowledge/information asymmetry to guard against

    channel partners’ opportunistic behaviors.

    3. Theoretical frameworkand researchmodel

     3.1. Theoretical framework

    Efficient and effective transfer of data and information can

    occur via market transactions or through hierarchical governance

    structures (Williamson, 1985). However, inter-organizational phe-

    nomenon such as knowledge sharing in a supply channel often

    requires reciprocal patterns of communication and exchange,

    and may be better served by relational/network forms of orga-

    nizations less guided by a formal structure of authority andmore driven by reciprocity, collaboration, etc. The mold of a

    relational/network structure facilitating long-term interactions,

    complementarity, reciprocity, collaboration, trust, etc. is used here

    to portray exchange behavior in inter-organizational networks.

    Social exchange theory (SET) serves as the theoretical umbrella

    to model the phenomenon. SET here serves as the meta-theory

    providing a robust theoretical base for binding the kernel theories

    of social capital, TCE, and the economic theory of complementar-

    ity where the kernel theories enunciate the three constructs of 

    specific interest to the supply channel context, viz., social capital,

    opportunism, and network complementarity. The domain of the

    theoretical framework is ‘Knowledge’ (Fig. 1).

    Social exchange theory (Kelley & Thibaut, 1978) posits that

    social behavior is the result of an exchange process. The purpose of this exchange is to maximize benefits and minimize costs. Accord-

    ing to SET, actors in a network evaluate the payoff of a relationship

    against the available alternatives; if there are better alternatives or

    the costs outweigh the rewards, one or more members of the net-

    work will prefer to terminate or abandon that relationship (Blau,

    1964). Cost–benefit analysis and comparison of alternative are the

    building blocks of SET (Kelley & Thibaut, 1978).

    While there are many reasons for firms to enter into relation-

    ships (e.g., joint production, product promotion, etc.), we restrict

    3 Th e bullwhip ef fect is w hen “ the var iance o f or der s may be lar ge r th an

    that of sales and the distortion tends to increase as one moves upstream” (Lee,

    Padmanabhan, & Whang, 1997, p. 546).

    our attention to the intellectual property domain – knowledge

    sharing in a supply channel. Thus, our research framework (Fig. 1)

    models exchange behavior in the knowledge domain transpiring in

    the context of inter-organizational networks informed by SET.

    Pursuant to the SET conceptualization, payoff in an inter-

    organizational relationship is essentially value generated less the

    cost incurred in the relationship. At the outset, we posit that the

    social capital of the inter-organizational relationship creates the

    value to promote exchange behavior, while opportunism includ-

    ing the consideration of alternatives constitutes the cost capable of 

    retarding the exchange behavior.

    Risk of opportunistic behavior is an inherent threatin anyinter-

    organizational relationship – e.g., supply channel. To the extent a

    dyadic relationship entails knowledge exchange between partici-

    pating partners thevery exchange process is vulnerable to this risk.

    This is the case in point motivated by self-interest in any dyadic

    exchange scenario –   the self-interest case. TCE (Williamson, 1985,

    1991) tackles the issue along the lines of managing opportunism

    using governance structures – a cost component. Alternatively, the

    very need to work together can spontaneously induce mutual trust

    in the dyad in order to reduce the risk of opportunism simply

    because trust can make knowledge exchange less costly (Zaheer,

    McEvily, & Perrone, 1998) – the risk reduction case.

    While data and information exchange may flourish through

    routine market transactions (Kim & Umanath, 2005), knowl-

    edge complementarity is almost always a necessary condition for

    knowledge exchange (Hamel, Doz, & Prahalad, 1989). Knowledge

    complementarity refers to the characteristic of the knowledge that

    may determine its value as a tradable commodity. It is the effect

    resulting from combining two distinct bodies of knowledge whose

    agglomeration is super-additive – i.e., the combined knowledge set

    has more embedded knowledge than the simple additive values of 

    the parts. This is ratified by the economic theory of complemen-

    tarity which shows that the mathematical relationship between

    a system of complementary variables, and the returns and costs

    are super-modular and sub-modular respectively (Milgrom et al.,

    1991). Here, super-modularity means super-additive value syn-

    ergies, while sub-modularity means sub-additive value synergies(Tanriverdi & Venkatraman, 2005). Knowledge complementarity

    often serves as the compelling reason for the dyad in a supply

    channel to work together and exchange knowledge despite the

    inherent threat of opportunistic behavior by either partner, simply

    because the benefit accrued by the supply channel partners collec-

    tively and/or individually outweighs the expected costdue to riskof 

    opportunism – therisktolerancecase. In essence, where is theincen-

    tive for two parties to enter into a relationship at all to exchange

    knowledge unless they possess complementing knowledge?

    In short, our theoretical framework juxtaposes social capital

    and opportunism as the principal opposing forces – value and cost

    respectively in the payoff structure enunciated in the SET – in the

    exchange scenario. Network complementarity is introduced as the

    common denominator that promotes exchange behavior by accru-ing benefits (contribution to the payoff) that makes it worthwhile

    to tolerate the risk of opportunism – a compensatory mechanism

    even at low levels of social capital. As a consequence, we would

    expecta collective effectof socialcapital andnetwork complemen-

    tarity enhancing exchange behavior, since they mitigate threat of 

    opportunism in different, possibly cumulative ways.

     3.2. Research model

    Our research model (Fig. 2) is predicated on the broader theo-

    retical framework presented in Fig. 1. Here, we juxtapose impact

    of organizational trust and risk of opportunism on knowledge

    exchange in terms of the opposing viewpoints of social capital

    theory and TCE respectively. Social capital theory views inter-

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    4/15

    38   K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of InformationManagement  32 (2012) 35–49

     Table 1

    Barriers to knowledge exchange.

    Social capital related barriers Transaction risk related barriers

    1. Lack of the recipient’s absorptive and assimilation capacity (e.g., Lane &

    Lubatkin, 1998)

    1. Unwillingness to share important knowledge (e.g., Nahapiet & Ghoshal,

    1998)

    2. Knowledge-conversion difficulties (e.g., Nonaka, 1994) 2. Concerns about “Knowledge Poaching” (e.g., Clemons & Hitt, 2004)

    3. Obstacles to effective knowledge search (e.g., Rivikin, 2001) 3. The source firm’s lack of motivation (e.g., Gupta & Govindarajan, 2000)

    4. Unproven knowledge content (e.g., Szulanski, 1996), Technological

    incompatibilities (e.g., Weill & Vitale, 2002)

    4. The source firm’s unfavorableaccess to knowledge(e.g., Hsiao et al., 2003)

    5. Socio-political issues (e.g., Hayes & Walsham, 2001). 6. Loss of resource control (e.g., Williamson, 1985)

    Fig. 1. Research framework based on social exchange theory.

    organizationaltrust as a source of competitive advantagefor supply

    chains, whereas, from the TCE perspective, the intimacy neces-

    sary to realize the potential of the relationship exposes firms to

    risk of opportunism (Madhok & Tallman, 1998). Likewise, resource

    complementarity among the supply channel partners facilitates

    Control Variable

    IT Infrastructure

    Knowledge

    Exchange

    (KE)

    Knowledge

    Complementarities

    (KC)

    Risk of

    Opportunism

    (RO)

    Inter-Organizational

    Trust

    (T)   H1

    H2

    H3

    H4

    H5

    Fig. 2. Research model.

    cooperation for obtaining mutual benefits; and to the extent

    knowledge is an organizational resource, knowledge complemen-

    tarity promotesthe cooperative knowledge exchange behavior.The

    simultaneous impact of inter-organizational trust and knowledge

    complementarity on knowledge exchange is hypothesized as an

    interaction effect. As a contrast, we also examine the collective

    effect of risk of opportunism and knowledge complementarity on

    knowledge exchange.

    IT infrastructure as a research variable may be relevant for data

    and information exchange (e.g., EDI). In a knowledge exchange

    context, IT infrastructure often remains a part of the context (e.g.,

    supply channel). The inclusion of IT infrastructure in our research

    model is more for partialling out any residual effect due to its

    presence (e.g., inadvertent presence of explicit knowledge in the

    exchange). Therefore, our research model portrays IT infrastruc-

    ture as a control variable rather than a hypothesized effect. The

    individual hypothesis development follows.

     3.2.1. Direct effects of social capital and the risk of opportunistic 

    behavior 

    (1)Organizational trust as an enabler of knowledge exchange

    Social capital theorists have focused much attention on the

    structural properties of relationships (Adler & Kwon, 2002), such

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    5/15

    K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of Information Management  32 (2012) 35–49 39

    as tie strength at the dyadic level. While strong ties are impor-

    tant conditions of knowledge exchange, Levin and Cross (2004)

    assert that the relational dimension of social capital, i.e., organi-

    zational trust, mediates the relationship between tie strength and

    knowledge exchange. Tsai and Ghoshal (1998) also find that at the

    department level the structural dimension of social capital stim-

    ulates trust  and perceived trustworthiness, which, in turn, allow

    departments to exchange more resources (including knowledge).

    As described above, the previous literature suggests that organi-

    zational trust mediates between knowledge exchange and other

    dimensionsof social capital (e.g.,relationship structure). Therefore,

    we have chosen to focus on the organizational trust dimension of 

    social capital.

    Moreover, the trust literature (see Mayer, Davis, & Schoorman,

    1995 for reviews) provides considerable evidence that trusting

    relationships lead to greater knowledge exchange. Morgan and

    Hunt(1994) define organizationaltrust as convictionabout the cer-

    tainty and honesty of a trading partner, while Zaheer et al. (1998)

    define trust as the collective trust that every member of an orga-

    nization puts into another trading partner. If supply chain partners

    trust each other, they are more likely to share certain types of 

    knowledge (Modi & Mabert, 2007). For example, tacit and abstract

    knowledge are susceptible to exploitation by partners (Dyer &

    Nobeoka, 2000). Consequently, an organization shares tacit knowl-

    edge only when it really trusts that its partners will use it for the

    benefit of the partnership.

    For the receiving organization, trust makes knowledge trans-

    fer less costly (Zaheer et al., 1998) by reducing conflicts and the

    need to verify information. As a consequence, knowledge-seeking

    organizations in a trusting relationship are readily willing to absorb

    partners’ knowledge (Mayer et al., 1995). Furthermore, knowledge

    seekers are vulnerable to the benevolence of the knowledge source

    (Lee, 1997) and mutual trust tends to facilitate such benevolence.

    Knowledge seekers who trust a source’s competence to make sug-

    gestions and influence their thinking are more likely to heed and

    take action on that knowledge. Trusting a knowledge source to be

    benevolent and competent should increase the likelihood that the

    knowledge receiver will benefit from the interaction.In summary, in high-trust relationships, organizations are apt

    to be more open to the potential for value creation through the

    exchange and combination of resources. Social capital in the form

    of high trust enables supply-chain participants to engage in more

    socialexchangeand to take actionthatwouldusuallybe considered

    risky in such exchanges(Putnam, 1993). From these facts we derive

    the following hypothesis:

    Hypothesis 1. Inter-organizational trust positively influences

    knowledge exchange behavior among supply-channel partners.

    (2) Risk of opportunistic behavior as an inhibitor of knowledge

    exchange

    Inter-organizational relationships are inherently temporal,

    unstable, and disfavored (Williamson, 1991). The stability of  inter-organizational relationships is affected by such factors as

    opportunism, complexity in monitoring behaviors, and difficulty

    in coordination among partners (Park & Ungson, 2001). These

    characteristics are relevant to knowledge exchange between

    supply-chain partners and affect the success of the cooperative

    relationship. Depending on the participants’ private incentives,

    inter-organizational relationships may generate either coopera-

    tive or competitive behaviors between partners (Gulati, 1995).

    Cooperative inter-organizational relationships may fail due to

    opportunistic hazards that arise as each firm pursues its own

    individual interests rather than collective interests. Opportunistic

    behavior may allow for immediate gratification of short-termgoals

    of a partner without the need to face the uncertainty of long-term

    returns. The vulnerability due to a partner’s self-interested behav-

    ior is exacerbated in situations in which the relevant resources and

    behavior are not readily transparent (Park & Ungson, 2001).

    In TCE, opportunism or opportunistic behavior means self-

    interest seeking with guile, involving somekind of deliberatedeceit

    and the absence of moral restraint (Williamson, 1985). It could

    involve deliberately withholding or distorting information, per-

    formance shirking, or failing to fulfill promises and obligations.

    It occurs in business transactions especially where performance

    measures are ambiguous, and where goals of trading partners

    are incongruent (Ouchi, 1980). Because the risk of opportunistic

    behavior is ever present, firms must have recourse to safeguards.

    Mechanisms such as optimal contract structures (e.g., Williamson,

    1991), the alignment of incentives (e.g., Dyer & Singh, 1998), and

    governance structures (e.g., Williamson, 1985) may decrease the

    risk of opportunism. However, a relationship dominated by protec-

    tion against opportunism makes firms reluctant to form unilateral

    and voluntary commitments outside the terms of the contract

    and therefore tend to perceive a greater need to take costly and

    elaborate safeguards (Madhok & Tallman, 1998). This tendency

    diminishesthe level of value created andrealized through the rela-

    tionship.

    In the automobile industry, for example, an automaker’s strate-

    gic knowledge in specific domains may be diffused to competitors

    through shared suppliers. According to Takeishi (2002), some sup-

    pliers intentionally transfer technological knowledge learned from

    one automaker to another, and some automakers try to learn new

    technology and effective practices from others through common

    suppliers. As a result, the strategic knowledge of an automaker

    becomes public knowledge because of its supplier’s opportunistic

    behavior. Concerns about this kind of transaction risk may inhibit

    supply-chain participants from exchanging knowledge. Hence, the

    following hypothesis:

    Hypothesis 2. The risk of opportunistic behavior does not facili-

    tateknowledgeexchangebehavioramong supply channel partners.

     3.2.2. Contingency effect of knowledge complementarity

    When competing theories are available, any behavior patterncan alwaysbe substantiated oneway or theother. Does this require

    acceptance of onetheory andrefutationof theother? Only repeated

    empirical trials with regular and reliable results can support such

    an inference. However, it is likely that two different patterns pre-

    dicted by two competing theories may both be detected under

    different circumstances. In other words, no theory is ever proven

    or rejected, and repeated failure to falsify a theory strengthens a

    theory. Evidence of falsification should be carefully evaluated to

    seek out violations of any assumption(s) behind the theory in the

    study and/or contingencies that may explain the effect. This spirit

    of enquiry guides the following contingency analysis.

    Although a trusting relationship has the potential to positively

    influence knowledge exchange, as predicted by Hypothesis 1, the

    mere presence of a conducive relationship need not necessarilypromote knowledge exchange. Likewise, even when firms discern

    transaction risk in knowledge exchange, they may be willing to

    exchange knowledge if the expected benefits from the exchange

    significantly exceed the expected costs of transaction risk. The

    effect of one or the other of the two conflicting forces may govern

    knowledge exchange contingent on other factors. We posit that

    knowledge complementarity is such a contingent factor. Supply

    chains are often characterized by knowledge complementarity and

    our theoretical framework (Fig. 1) proposes that knowledge com-

    plementarity in a dyad promotes knowledge exchange behavior.

    When knowledgeis exchanged between supply chain partners,the

    knowledge must be useful and effectively integrated into the sup-

    ply chain. We posit that effective integration requires that at least

    some knowledge possessed by the two firms be complementary.

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    6/15

    40   K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of InformationManagement  32 (2012) 35–49

    According to the strategic management literature, complemen-

    taritiesrepresentan enhancementof resource valueand arisewhen

    a resource produces greater returns in the presence of another

    resource than by itself (e.g., Chung, Singh, & Lee, 2000; Milgrom

    et al., 1991). Applying the definition of complementarities to

    knowledge complementarity, it refers to knowledge resources that

    collectively generate greater rents than the sum of those obtained

    from the individual knowledge of each partner (Dyer & Singh,

    1998). Hamel et al. (1989) suggest that mutual gains are possible

    if partners’ individual strengths can complement each other since

    each partner in an alliance should be able to access the comple-

    mentary capabilitiesof itspartner.For instance,in thecontext of an

    inter-organizational relationship in the EMS industry, intermediate

    producers have expert manufacturing knowledge and architec-

    tural knowledge (how to coordinate various components for a

    product). Meanwhile, suppliers have component-specific knowl-

    edge, that is, knowledge about particular components, including

    technology, raw materials, and manufacturing process (Takeishi,

    2002). Firms participating in a supply chain collectively develop

    situation-specific knowledge by creating new combinations of 

    complementary knowledge. For example, intermediate producers

    may devise new ways of manufacturing components by consid-

    ering the strengths and weaknesses of raw materials used by

    suppliers. Productivity gains in the supply chain (e.g., time to

    market, responsiveness to changing environments, overall product

    quality) are possible when participating firmsadjust theiractivities

    according to partnership-specific knowledge.

    Since supply chain partners can create more synergistic knowl-

    edge by combining theircomplementaryknowledge, the likelihood

    of voluntary knowledge exchange will increase. Malhotra et al.

    (2005) find that the value of a partner’s knowledge affects knowl-

    edge exchange in supply chain relationships. Other studies (e.g.,

    Gupta & Govindarajan, 2000) likewise assert that the perceived

    value of a partner’s knowledge is an important antecedent to

    inter-firm knowledge exchange. Hence, we propose the following

    hypothesis:

    Hypothesis3. Knowledge complementarity positively influencesknowledge exchange behavior among supply channel partners.

    Knowledge complementarity refers to knowledge stocks that

    have the capacity to collectively generate synergistic value result-

    ing from the interactions among complementary knowledge

    components (Kim, Shin, & Lee, 2010). The synergistic value is fea-

    sible only when both the partners’ complementary resources are

    present and accessible. Hamel et al.(1989) assert that mutualgains

    are possible if partners can complement (i.e., compensate for) each

    other’s weaknesses since each partner in an alliance can access the

    complementary capabilities of its partner. Thus, the potential gains

    from knowledgecomplementarity will be realized when the acces-

    sibility of partner’s knowledge is allowed through the cooperative

    relationship engendered by mutual trust. Since high knowledge

    complementarity between supply-chain partners offers the poten-tial for significant mutual gains through knowledge exchange,

    mutual trust which fosters exchange presents a win–win situa-

    tion when knowledge complementarity is high. On the other hand,

    opportunistic behavior by either party, when knowledge comple-

    mentarity is high, is detrimental to both parties since the partners

    run the risk of jeopardizing a difficult-to-replace relationship (a

    loose–loose situation) which often outweighs possible short-term

    gains of opportunism. Thus, under high knowledge complemen-

    tarity partners’ self-interests guide them toward mutual trust

    enjoined by the social capital perspective rather than opportunistic

    behavior suggested by the transaction risk perspective. In addi-

    tion,opportunities existfor high-trusting relationships to integrate

    complementaryknowledgecreatively so as to increase valuefor the

    supply chain partners. On the contrary, when the knowledge being

    exchanged is not complementary and thus not expected to cre-

    ate synergistic effects, supply chain partners do not see any value

    of knowledge exchange, even in relationships with a high level of 

    trust. Therefore, we hypothesize:

    Hypothesis 4. The interaction between knowledge comple-

    mentarity and inter-organizational trust influences knowledge

    exchange behavior in the supply channel.

    Hypothesis 4a. When knowledge complementarity in the sup-ply channel is high, increase in inter-organizational trust positively

    influences knowledge exchange behavior among supply channel

    partners.

    Hypothesis 4b. When knowledge complementarity in the sup-

    ply channel is low, increase in inter-organizational trust does not

    influence knowledge exchange behavior among supply channel

    partners.

    When the knowledge possessed by supply chain partners is not

    quite complementary, the collective good of knowledge exchange

    becomes insignificant, no matter the level of trust. The only possi-

    ble motivation for knowledge exchange in this case is to selectively

    aggrandize the partner’s knowledge for one’s own good rather

    than the collective good of the supply chain. Consequently, whencomplementarity in the supply channel is low and therefore not

    expected to create synergistic effects, supply chain partners do not

    see any value in knowledge exchange, and concerns about transac-

    tion risk dominate over the social capital perspective. The effect of 

    concerns about transaction risk on knowledge exchange intensifies,

    as the knowledge to be exchanged becomes less complementary.

    On the contrary, when knowledge complementarity is high,

    opportunistic behavior by either party is detrimental to bothparties

    since the partners run the risk of jeopardizing a difficult-to-replace

    relationship (a loose–loose situation), which often outweighs

    the possible short-term gains of opportunism. Basis resource-

    based view (RBV) and TCE, Conner and Prahalad (1996) assert

    that strategic alliances provide the “more valuable, opportunism-

    independent knowledge” (p. 489). The opportunism-independent

    knowledge encompasses both knowledge substitution and flexibil-

    ity effects. When knowledge complementarity is high, the benefit

    of opportunism-independent knowledge that an alliance provides

    through knowledge exchange ought to outweigh short-term gains

    of opportunism. In other words, gains from opportunistic behavior

    may be too trivial to outweigh the loss of valuable, opportunism-

    independent knowledge. This supports the following hypothesis:

    Hypothesis 5. The interaction between knowledge complemen-

    tarity and the risk of opportunism influences knowledge exchange

    behavior in the supply channel.

    Hypothesis 5a. When knowledge complementarity among sup-

    ply channel partners is low, increase in the risk of opportunistic

    behavior negatively influences knowledge exchange behavior

    among supply channel partners.

    Hypothesis 5b. When knowledge complementarity among sup-

    ply chain partners is high, increase in the risk of opportunistic

    behavior does not influence knowledge exchange behavior among

    supply channel partners.

     3.2.3. Control variable: inter-organizational IT infrastructure

    When organizations are connected through electronic net-

    works, inter-organizational IT infrastructure can facilitate knowl-

    edge exchange. Inter-organizational IT infrastructure encompasses

    the underlying inter-organizational system resources that can be

    harnessed to exploit resources held by supply chain partners. In

    particular, it refers to IT resources such as database, software, and

    networks for an inter-organizational relationship (Weill & Vitale,

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    7/15

    K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of Information Management  32 (2012) 35–49 41

    2002). Compatible infrastructure channels help reduce the costs

    of knowledge exchange and leverage appropriate resources during

    the knowledge exchange process (Colombo & Mosconi, 1995), lead-

    ing to more confidence and receptive attitudes toward knowledge

    exchange.

    Meanwhile, a shortage of system resources has been found to

    inhibit the assimilation of incoming knowledge. Zhu (2004) asserts

    thatfirms with poor IT infrastructure (e.g.,stand-alone, proprietary

    systems) often have difficulties in connecting to their customers,

    suppliers, and business partners, causing delays in collecting and

    exchanging market information among supply chain participants.

    Electronic connectivity creates the potential for developing a

    response-basedbusinessmodel (in contrast to an anticipatory busi-

    ness model),4 which seeks to reduceforecast reliance through joint

    planning and the rapid exchange of knowledge between supply

    chain participants. When all members of the supply chain syn-

    chronize their operations, they can reduce overall inventory and

    eliminatecostly redundancies. Thus,the presence of an appropriate

    inter-organizational IT infrastructure influences supply chain per-

    formance primarily by facilitating knowledge exchange between

    supply chain partners.

    The research model is presented in Fig. 2.

    4. Method

    4.1. Sample

    While this study involves the dyadic exchange relationships of 

    Electronic Manufacturing Services (EMS) companies and their sup-

    pliers, we examine the phenomenon from the buyer’s perspective.

    The data required for this study were collected from managers and

    buyers responsible for supplier relationships in intermediate pro-

    ducers in the EMS industry. The sample frame consisted of the 550

    companies that participated in a national electronics show. Among

    these firms, we asked 400 EMS manufacturers if they were inter-

    ested in participating in ourresearch. If thefirms agreed, they were

    asked to provide contact information about the firm’s purchasing

    managers so thatwe couldcollectdata about the research variables.

    The purchasing managers were asked to respond to the instrument

    in the context of an ongoing relationship through which an impor-

    tantcomponent for theirproduction process was beingsourced.For

    the questions about which the purchasing managers did not have

    enough knowledge, they were encouraged to contact appropriate

    experts inside the firm such as manufacturing, R&D, and informa-

    tion technology. Two follow-up emails were sent five and ten days

    after the initial contact. Participants emailed completed question-

    naires to the researchers. Eighty-five responses (21.3% response

    rate) were received within 14 days. Among those, three were elim-

    inated because they were incomplete, resulting in a final sample

    of 82 EMS firms. With the exception of a few large corporations,

    most firms were small to medium. The annual sales of the sample

    firmsfor the year 2007wereas follows: 76.8% made less than U$10million, 19.5% made between U$10 million and U$100 million, and

    3.7% made over U$100 million.

    To evaluate any systematic differences for non-responses,

    ANOVAs were performed on all independent variables between

    early responses and late responses, i.e., after the follow-up emails.

    No statistically significant differences occurred between the two

    groups at the 0.05 level of significance.

    4 In the response-based business model, the sequence of events is initiated by

    a sale followed by material purchase, custom manufacturing, and direct customer

    delivery. By contrast, the typical stages of the anticipatory business model include

    forecasting, purchasing materials, manufacturing, filling warehouses, selling, and

    then delivering goods.

    4.2. Measures

    We adapted most of the survey items (see Table 2) from preex-

    isting scales in the literature. Main adaptations were made in the

    wording of the measurement items in order to reflect the supply

    chain research context. Though instruments to measure the key

    constructs in our hypotheses are available, a few measures require

    either modification or development.

    Knowledge exchange is the process through which one supply

    chain member is affected by the experience of another (Argote &

    Ingram, 2000). For this construct, we measure the extent to which

    the supply chain partners exchange knowledge in engineering,

    production, raw materials, and new product development. These

    measures were constructed by modifying instruments developed

    by Kotabe, Martin, and Domoto (2003) and Pham (2006).

    Inter-organizational trust was measured on the basis of two

    dimensions, proposed by Bensaou and Venkatraman (1995): (1)the

    degree of mutual trust between the two firms; and (2) the degree

    of comfort in sharing sensitive information with the supplier. For

    opportunistic behavior, respondents were asked to describe the

    potentialof theirpartner’s behaving opportunistically.Opportunis-

    tic behavior was defined to include distorting information, failing

    to fulfill promises or obligations, appropriation of the partner firm’s

    technology, and delivering substandard products (Parkhe, 1993).

    Knowledge complementarity refers to the extent to which the

    knowledge stocks of supply chain partners collectively generate

    greater rents than the sum of those obtained from the individ-

    ual knowledge stock of each partner. In an upstream supply chain,

    buyer–supplier relationships involve ongoing mutual adjustment

    between the buyer’s and the supplier’sdesign and production oper-

    ations (Kotabe et al., 2003). Takeishi (2002) asserts that buyers in

    general have expert knowledge in manufacturing such as a higher

    level of architectural knowledge (how to coordinate various com-

    ponents for a product), while suppliers have component-specific

    knowledge. Specifically, the buyer’s knowledge comprises three

    different areas – production, product design, and component rela-

    tionships – in its products. The supplier’s knowledge also covers

    three domains, namely, raw material characteristics, the technicalstrengths of its products, and technical constraints of its products.

    The authors developed an instrument of nine items to measure

    knowledge complementarity between the three dimensions of 

    buyer’s manufacturing knowledgeand thethree dimensionsof sup-

    plier’s component knowledge.

    InterorganizationalIT infrastructurerefers to shared technology

    and technologyservicesacross supply chainpartners. Followingthe

    work of Weill and Vitale (2002), we adapted six items: hardware

    compatibility, data consistency, common application interface,

    network connectivity, datasecurity, andthe interpretability of elec-

    tronically transferred data.

    4.3. Survey administration

    Preliminary testing of the research instrument involved struc-

    tured interviews. Pretests of theinstrument were performedin two

    companies, and three focus group interviews were conducted with

    respondents to ensure that the target informants understood the

    researchers’ wording. Multiple-structured interviews were con-

    ducted with the managers of purchasing divisions to test the face

    validity of the instrument. The respondents were asked to indicate

    their responses to questions on a seven-point scale with bipolar

    adjectives of the form, Not at all – Very much so. On the basis of 

    responses to these interviews, a few questions were rephrased to

    better reflect industry-specific situations and to improve clarity.

    The twocompanies that participatedin the pretests of the research

    instruments were not a part of the final sample.

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    8/15

    42   K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of InformationManagement  32 (2012) 35–49

     Table 2

    Operationalization of the constructs.

    Construct Assessment References

    Knowledge exchange The extent to which an organization exchanges knowledge

    with its supply chain partners

    Pham (2006) and Kotabe et al. (2003)

    Inter-organizational trust Degree of mutual trust between the two firms and degree of  

    comfort in sharing sensitive information with the supplier

    Bensaou and Venkatraman (1995)

    Risk of o pportunistic b ehavior The p otential f or t he p artner’s b ehaving o pportunistically Parkhe (1993)

    Knowledge complementarity The extent to which knowledge stocks of supply chain

    partners collectively generate greater rents than the sum of those obtained from theindividual knowledgeof each partner

    Developed by the authors

    Inter-organizational ITInfrastructure Shared technology and technologyservices across the supply

    chain partners

    Weill & Vitale(2002)

    5. Results

    5.1. Measurement properties of constructs

    Since we made minor wording changes to theoriginalquestions

    to customize the instrument to a supply chain setting, principal

    component analysis was performed on the data to ascertain the

    integrity of each dimensionality. Table 3 provides standardized

    parameter estimates (factor loadings) of the items for the underly-

    ing dimensions. We used a conservative cut-off value of .60 for the

    factor loadings, in contrast to the often cited rule of thumb for the

    cut off value for factorloadings, which is .50 (Nunnally & Bernstein,

    1994).

    Five factors with eigen-values greater than 1, which accounted

    for 70.63% of the variance in the data set, were extracted. All items

    were loaded together on the intended factors. One item (KE1) was

    discarded from subsequent analyses since it was loaded on two

    factors and its loading was lower than the cut-off value of 0.6.

    The pattern of observed loadings indicates that the multi-item

    scales measure independent constructs, thereby further support-

    ing the unidimensionality and discriminant validity of the scales.

    Each multi-item measure was obtained by computing the average

    score provided by the respondent across the relevant items. We

    assessed multicollinearity among the variables by using variance

    inflation factor (VIF) values from the SPSS regression module. The

    results show that the VIF scores for constructs were well below the

    threshold of 10, indicating that multicollinearity was not a prob-

    lem in this study. Descriptive statistics (e.g., the number of scale

    items in each measure, the mean, the standard deviation, the range

    of values, and reliability coefficients) and the simple correlations

    among the research variables appear in Table 4.

    5.2. Hypotheses testing 

    A multivariate general linear model using SPSS 15.0 was con-

    ducted to assess the hypotheses. If the theoretical interpretation

    suggests that knowledgeexchange is most likely when twofactors,

    such as trust and high knowledge complementarity, are present(or, knowledgeexchangeis least likelywhen both therisk of oppor-

    tunism and low knowledge complementarityare present), then the

    functional form of the interaction is multiplicative (Blalock, 1965).

    Since a product term is a legitimate way to express an interaction

    in the multiple regression procedure, we viewed our problem as a

    multiple regression model, as presented in Table 5, using Type 3

    analysis.5

    The research hypotheses were tested by examining the size and

    significance of the model coefficients. Table 5 shows the unstan-

    dardized coefficients and model statistics for the analyses. While

    5 Type 3 analysiscomputes thesum ofsquaresfor each effectafter partiallingout

    the effects dueto allother variables in theregression model.

    standardized coefficients (beta coefficients) provide an estimate

    of the effect of a variable relative to others in the model, such an

    estimate is not accurate for interaction terms and is therefore not

    interpretable (Frazier, Tix, & Barron, 2004). Consequently, we have

    used unstandardized coefficients to interpret the results.

    The results show that inter-organizational trust significantly

    influences knowledge exchange between supply chain partners,

    thus supporting H1 (t = 1.961,  p=0.054). Knowledge comple-

    mentarity also has a significant direct effect on knowledge

    exchange (H3, t = 2.647, p= 0.010). Further, the interaction between

    knowledge complementarity and inter-organizational trust (H4,

    t =−2.914,  p= 0 .031) turns out to be significant. Also, the risk

    of opportunism does not facilitate knowledge exchange behav-

    ior between supply chain partners (H2, t = 0.519,  p= 0.605). The

    interaction between the risk of opportunism and knowledge com-

    plementarity (H5, t =−0.461,  p=0.646) is not significant either.

    Inter-organizationalIT infrastructure does not show any significant

    associations with knowledge exchange.

    In order to gain deeper insight into the contingency hypothe-

    ses (interaction effects), H4 and H5, sub-sample analyses were

    performed.6 The sub-hypotheses of H4 and H5 essentially indicate

    that when knowledge complementarity is high, the social capi-

    tal perspective will prevail over transaction risk concerns. When

    knowledge complementarityis low, we expectthe opposite.To test

    these drill-down contingency hypotheses, we divided our sample

    into two as follows. Before the sample split, in order to check the

    normality assumption of KC, the Shapiro–Wilk test was performed

    to find that the data came from a normally distributed population.

    Then, sample firms within one standard deviation (1.026) around

    the mean value (4.757) of knowledge complementarity (KC) were

    dropped because they are neutral in terms of KC. Firms with KC

    values higher than one half standard deviation (0.513) from the

    mean were classified as the high KC group (24 firms, mean= 5.92,

    SD = 0.603), whereas firms with KC values lower than onehalf stan-

    dard deviation from the mean were classified as the low KC group

    (25 firms, mean= 3.53, SD=0.528). One way ANOVA test reveals

    that these two groups were significantly different in terms of KC

    (t = 12.947, p= 0.000).Table6 presentstheresultsofthesplitsample

    analysis.The results show that for the group with low knowledge

    complementarity, the risk of opportunism shows a significant neg-

    ative relationship with knowledge exchange, thus supporting H5a

    (t =−2.529,  p=0.020), whereas the impact of trust on knowledge

    exchange (H4b, t = 0.410 p= 0.686) is, as expected, not significant.

    6 Given that the hypothesized interaction (H5), (knowledge complementarity x

    risk of opportunism), is notstatistically significant in themain model (see Table5),

    one may question the appropriateness of sub-sample analysis in evaluating this

    interaction. However, since the two sub-sample analyses are necessary to eval-

    uate the other significant interaction between knowledge complementarity and

    inter-organizational trust, we carried out sub-sample analyses. Nevertheless, inter-

    pretations of H5a and H5b in thesub-sampleanalyses aretentative.

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    9/15

    K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of Information Management  32 (2012) 35–49 43

     Table 3

    Factor analysis results.

    Variables Factors

    1 2 3 4 5

    Opportunism (Oppor)

    Oppor1 .174 −.139 .123 .788 .043

    Oppor2 −.260 .188 .000 .700 .100

    Oppor3   −.070 .111   −.109 .828 .043

    Oppor4   −.085 −.292 −.070 .748 −.129

    Inter-organizational trust 

    Trust1 −.030 −.045 −.117 .067 .838

    Trust2 .062 −.086 .005 −.013 .849

    IT infrastructure (Infra)

    Infra1 .111 .067 .838   −.129 −.029

    Infra2 .178 .029 .853 −.078 −.090

    Infra3 −.019 .048 .837 .005 −.133

    Infra4 .101 −.046 .677 .105 .003

    Infra5 .226 .122 .709 −.059 .227

    Infra6 .132 .067 .730 .165 −.111

    Knowledge complementarity (KC)

    KC1 .822 .045 .104 −.058 −.246

    KC2 .869 .180 .124 −.069 −.160

    KC3 .872 .087 .080 .037 −.175

    KC4 .883 .186 .058 .044 .160

    KC5 .863 .303 .099 .079 .102

    KC6 .851 .270 .100 −.022 −.024

    KC7 .827 .250 .124 −.174 .212KC8 .871 .167 .135 −.141 .150

    KC9 .882 .141 .105 −.086 .096

    Knowledge exchange (KE)

    KE1 .421 .528 .051 .016 −.034

    KE2 .309 .773 −.050 −.045 .039

    KE3 .155 .805 −.027 −.159 −.061

    KE4 .186 .837 .013 −.045 −.099

    KE5 .009 .671 .241   −.054 −.079

    KE6 .115 .731 .330 .041 −.095

    KE7 .301 .651 −.063 .180 −.002

    KE8 .288 .665 .072 .019 .131

    Variance explained (%) 32.846 12.191 10.707 8.758 6.129

    Extraction method: principal components analysis.

    Rotation method: Varimax with Kaiser normalization.

     Table 4Descriptive statistics of the research variables.

    No. of items Mean (SD) Min Max Cronbach’s Alpha Oppor Infra Trust KC

    Opportunism (Oppor) 4 3.234 (1.136) 1.00 6.25 0.775 1

    IT Infrastructure (Infra) 6 4.130 (1.256) 1.00 6.83 0.881 −0.013 1

    Inter-organizational trust (Trust) 2 4.955 (1.228) 1.50 7.00 0.707 0.052 −0.086 1

    Knowledge Complementarity (KC) 9 4.757 (1.026) 2.33 7.00 0.966 −0.036 0.271** 0.015 1

    Knowledge Exchange (KE) 8 4.514 (0.949) 2.13 6.50 0.892 −0.085 0.178 −0.095 0.485***

    N =82.**  p

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    10/15

    44   K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of InformationManagement  32 (2012) 35–49

     Table 6

    Results of regression analyses (the dependent variable is knowledge exchange).

    Model 1: high complementary group+ Model 2: low complementary group++

    Variables Standardized coefficient t P  Standardized coefficient T p

    Opportunism (Oppor) 0.020 0.103 0.919 −0.489 −2.529 0.020

    Trust −0.401 −2.702 0.014 0.079 0.410 0.686

    IT Infrastructure (Infra) 0.164 1.072 0.296 −0.101 −0.538 0.596

    R2 0.368 0.289

    Adj. R2 0.274 0.188

    F  3.890( p= 0.024) 2.850 ( p= 0.062)

    + N = 24++ N =25.

    summary of the findings for the hypothesized effects appears in

    Table 7.

    Finally, we examined the potential for our results to be

    explained by common method variance. Two types of statistical

    analyses were conducted to assess the threat of common meth-

    ods bias: (a) Harman’s one-factor test (Podsakoff, MacKenzie, Lee,

    & Podsakoff, 2003), and (b) Lindell and Whitney’s (2001) marker

    variable test. First, in Harman’s one factor test, the emergence of 

    a single factor that accounts for a large proportion of the vari-

    ance in factoranalysissuggests a commonmethods bias (Podsakoff 

    et al., 2003). No such single factor emerged and the five factorsin Table 3 accounted for 32.8%, 12.2%, 10.7%, 8.7%, and 6.1% of 

    the variance, respectively for the total 70.6% variance. Second, the

    Lindell–Whitney (2001) marker variable test uses a theoretically

    unrelated (marker ) variable to adjust the correlations among the

    model’s principal constructs. Because a marker variable does not

    have a theoretically expected relationship with the study’s princi-

    palconstructs,a high correlation would indicate common methods

    bias (Malhotra et al., 2005). For robustness, the test was performed

    with one otherwise unused variable for which there exists little

    theoretical basis for a relationship (supplier asset specificity). The

    average correlation of the study’s principalconstructs withsupplier

    asset specificity (r = 0.101, t =0.397) was low and not significant,

    providing no evidence of common methods bias.

    6. Discussion and conclusions

    6.1. Discussion

    Our study focuses on the crucial yet long overlooked question

    of why partners sometimes hesitate to share knowledge despite the

    apparentbenefits fromknowledgesharing . This ledus to a concurrent

    assessment of opposing viewpoints – one based on the social cap-

    ital theory and the other informed by transaction risk perspective.

    Since no theory is ever proven or refuted, exploration of contingen-

    cies under which each theory is relevant is a valuable theoretical

    contribution. Our examination of the literature and related theo-

    ries (e.g., Chung et al., 2000; Hamel et al., 1989; Kim et al., 2010;

    Milgrom et al., 1991; Tanriverdi & Venkatraman, 2005) suggests

    that knowledge complementarity is an important factor by which

    to understand the challenges of knowledge exchange in an inter-

    organizational relationship.

    Ratification of H1 (trust promotes knowledge exchange behav-

    ior) and H2 (opportunism impedes knowledge exchange behavior)

    in a supply channel context essentially contributes to the rein-forcement of both the social capital theory and the TCE perspective

    respectively. That is, trusting partners in a supply chain are pre-

    disposed to greater openness to the potential for value creation

    through the exchange and combination of knowledge resources,

    while, in the presence of inter-organizational trust, risk of oppor-

    tunism is irrelevant to knowledge exchange behavior.

    An implication of greater significance though is the ratification

    or refutation of any contingency that clarifies the conditions under

    which the opposing theories become relevant. Since the role of 

    knowledge complementarityin an inter-organizationalcontexthas

    been theorized (Milgrom et al., 1991; Tanriverdi & Venkatraman,

    2005) and empirically tested (Chung et al., 2000; Hamel et al., 1989;

    Kim et al., 2010), examination of knowledge complementarity as a

    possible contingency capable of explaining the opposing concep-tualizations of social capital theory and TCE perspective is in itself 

    a contribution to academic research. Ratification of H3 (knowledge

    complementarity promotes knowledge exchange behavior) bol-

    stersour thesisthat mutual gainsare possible if partners’individual

    strengths can complement each other. Further, it reinforces prior

    research findings in yet another context – i.e., a supply channel.

    Next, our contingency analysis reveals two findings hitherto

    not reported by prior research. First, notwithstanding our broad

    finding that opportunism impedes knowledge exchange behavior

     Table 7

    Results of hypotheses testing.

    Hypothesis Support  p-ValueYes No

    H1 Inter-organizational trust→Knowledge exchange * 0.054

    H2 Risk of opportunism does not facilitate knowledge

    exchange

    * 0.605

    H3 Knowledge complementarity→knowledge exchange * 0.010

    H4 Interaction between knowledge complementarity and

    inter-organizational trust→knowledge exchange

    * 0.031

    H4a Under high KC, inter-organizational trust→Knowledge

    exchange

    * 0.014 (opposite effect)

    H4b Under low KC, inter-organizational trust has no influence

    on knowledge exchange

    * 0.686

    H5 Interaction between knowledge complementarity and risk

    of opportunism→knowledge exchange

    * 0.646

    H5a Under lowKC, risk of opportunism→knowledge exchange * 0.020

    H5b Under high KC, risk o f o pp or tu nism has no influe nce o n

    knowledge exchange

    * 0.919

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    11/15

    K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of Information Management  32 (2012) 35–49 45

    (H1), when knowledge complementarity is low, a stronger effect

    of opportunism on knowledge exchange behavior manifests – a

    statistically significant negative coefficient, implying reduction in

    knowledge exchange behavior as opposed to the irrelevance of 

    opportunism to knowledge exchange behavior when knowledge

    complementarity is high (statistically insignificant positive coeffi-

    cient).

    The contingencyeffect of knowledge complementarityon inter-

    organizational trust (social capital) is thought provoking. When

    knowledge complementarity among supply chain partners is high,

    our result shows that the social capital perspective does indeed

    best explain firms’ behavior. However, this effect is contrary to

    the predicted positive direction (H4a). In other words, in situa-

    tions of high knowledge complementarity, our data indicate that

    inter-organizational trust retards knowledge exchange. This coun-

    terintuitive finding challenges the conventional wisdom that a

    trusting relationship among supply chain partners is a precondi-

    tion for knowledge exchange and opens the doors for investigating

    second order contingencies under which, in a situation of high

    knowledge complementarity, inter-organizational trust may be

    irrelevant to knowledge exchange behavior or even retard knowl-

    edge exchange behavior. The first step, however, in the  post hoc 

    analysis of this unexpected finding is to examine carefully the

    assumptions and controls underlying this study. Such an exami-

    nation follows below.

    Our first suspicion was that while the measure (instrument)

    for knowledge complementarity strictly follows the definition

    based on the resource-based view (Dyer & Singh, 1998), extrane-

    ous factors may have influenced the measurement (e.g., subjects’

    responses). For instance, Kumar, Scheer, and Steenkamp (1995)

    propose that interdependence or mutual dependence in a dyadic

    relationship can enhance trust and thereby performance, and

    dependence asymmetry or the imbalance between the partners’

    dependence as a dysfunctional force that can destabilize trusting

    relationships by creating conflicts.Our study hasnot explicitly con-

    trolled for knowledge interdependence/dependence asymmetry,

    and it is conceivable that our subjects’ response to the mea-

    sure of knowledge complementarity may have been influencedby thoughts about knowledge interdependence/dependenceasym-

    metry. If knowledge interdependenceamong supply chainpartners

    is high, the stakes are high, and inter-organizational trust alone

    may be insufficientto promoteknowledgeexchange.Perhapswhen

    trust is bolstered by behaviors like mutual commitment among

    supplychain partners it may promote knowledge exchange. On the

    contrary, excessive trust with insufficient commitment may also

    trigger the limiting of knowledge exchange as a precaution. This

    condition may be exacerbated if dependence asymmetry among

    supply chain partners plagues knowledge complementarity, that

    is, if one party is more dependent on another party in the sup-

    ply chain for complementary knowledge. Accordingly, given that

    knowledge complementarity promotes knowledge exchange (H3)

    and inter-organizationaltrust promotes knowledge exchange (H1),the only way the interaction among two partners can negatively

    impact knowledge exchange is when such a negative dimension

    (perhaps the knowledge interdependence/dependence asymme-

    try component) exists and manifests in the interaction term. In

    the Type 3 analysis reported in Tables 5 and 6, the interaction

    term represents only the effect not captured by the independent

    effects of the two variables. In other words, in hindsight, we are

    inclined to conclude that after the positive effects of knowledge

    complementarity and inter-organizational trust are partialled out

    through the main effects (H1 and H3), the negative effect triggered

    by perhaps knowledge interdependence/dependence asymmetry

    and trust will manifest in the interaction effect (H4a). To verify

    this inference, we examined a restricted regression model with-

    out the main effect terms of knowledge complementarity and

    inter-organizational trust [Full model: KE= f (Trust, KC, Trust * KC);

    Restricted model: KE= f (Trust*KC)] and, as expected, the inter-

    action term of these two variables yielded a significant positive

    effect (t =1.75,  p= .043)–that is, the relatively mild negative com-

    ponent of the interaction is obscured by the dominant positive

    effect resulting from the additive independent effects of knowl-

    edge complementarity and inter-organizational trust. Clearly,

    these  post hoc explanations are speculative and can be confirmed

    or refuted only by empirical testing –a springboard for future

    research.

    An alternative explanation of this counterintuitive finding is

    predicated on challenging the conventional wisdom that inter-

    organizational trust is always conducive to knowledge exchange-

    even in an environment of high knowledge complementarity. For

    instance, the moderating effect captured by the interaction term

    (knowledge complementarity× inter-organizational trust) is sus-

    ceptible to misperception as a ‘complementing’ effect (H4a) since

    that is thepopularstancein priorwork (Siggelkow,2002). Two vari-

    ablesare saidto interact as complements when themarginalbenefit

    of each variable increases in the level of the other variable. How-

    ever, there is another type of moderation, i.e., substitution. When

    two variables interact as substitutes, the marginal benefit of each

    variable decreases in the level of the other variable (Siggelkow,

    2002). Given a positive baseline effect of organizational trust as

    well as knowledge complementarity on knowledge exchange (H1

    and H3), a substitution effect where the marginal benefit of trust

    decreases when knowledgecomplementarity is highought to entail

    an insignificantpositive ora significant negative interaction (T * KC)

    effect as seen in H4a. In other words, our empirical finding is

    amenable to an interpretation as a substitution effect since the

    main effects of both inter-organizational trust (H1) and knowl-

    edgecomplementarity (H3) are significantly positive,whereas their

    interaction is significantly negative. The theoretical rationale for

    this position again relies on the role of knowledge interdepen-

    dence and dependence asymmetry in this mix (Palmatier, Dant,

    & Grewal, 2007). First, knowledge complementarity is possible

    without any knowledge interdependence. However, knowledge

    interdependence is impossible without the existence of comple-menting knowledge between the supply channel partners. In other

    words, knowledge interdependence is essentially a sub-construct

    of the multi-dimensional construct of knowledge complementarity

    – i.e., knowledge complementarity subsumes knowledge interde-

    pendence (Palmatieret al.,2007). In a supplychain relationship, the

    presence of interdependence in design, production and technical

    knowledge may preclude the need for inter-organizational trust;

    in other words, the partners may have no choice but to exchange

    knowledge because of knowledge interdependency. By not sharing

    knowledge they risk failure, a risk, perhaps higher than trusting an

    untrustworthy or potentially opportunistic partner in the supply

    chain. They may be able to curb opportunistic behavior by institut-

    ing governance mechanisms (Williamson, 1991), though they may

    not succeed without access to complementary knowledge. Orga-nizational trust therefore need not always be a precondition for

    knowledge exchange, and, under certain conditions (e.g., substi-

    tution by knowledge complementarity), may even be irrelevant

    to knowledge exchange (H4). For instance, simply the absence of 

    mistrust may be sufficient when there are other exogenous fac-

    tors motivating knowledge exchange (Bakker, Leenders, Gabbay,

    Kratzer, & Engelen, 2006) – e.g., knowledge complementarity or

    its subconstructs, knowledge interdependence and/or dependence

    asymmetry. In fact, compelling reason to work together can occur

    even in mistrusting relationships (Ahlstrom, Lamond, & Ding,

    2009).

    Another avenue to explore for clarifying the counterintuitive

    finding of H4a is based on the process and content dimensions

    of knowledge (Hass & Hansen, 2007). Process refers to the efforts

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    12/15

    46   K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of InformationManagement  32 (2012) 35–49

    involved in adapting knowledge obtained for a task; while, con-

    tent refers to the quality of knowledge – i.e., the substantiveness

    dimension. It is conceivable that even in situations with high trust

    and high knowledge complementarity, the supply channel partners

    may not share“substantive”knowledgeif, for instance, high depen-

    dence asymmetry punctuates the relationship; a power imbalance

    implicit in dependency asymmetry may be responsible for this

    behavior pattern in the dyad. In other words, one or both part-

    ners may simply go through the motions of knowledge exchange

    by sharing knowledge without much value.7

    Interorganizational IT infrastructure exhibits no significant

    impact on knowledge exchange behavior. A plausible explana-

    tion for this result would be that the nature of knowledge to

    be exchanged in this research context is either inappropriate for

    exchange through the IT infrastructure or actually impossible to

    be exchanged through this medium. Knowledge can be classi-

    fied into two types: (1) explicit knowledge (i.e., know-what) and

    (2) tacit knowledge (i.e., know-how) (Hildreth & Kimble, 2002).

    Explicit knowledge refers to easily codifiable knowledge that can

    be transmitted “without loss of integrity once the syntactical rules

    requiredfor deciphering itare known”(Kogut& Zander, 1992: 386).

    Meanwhile, know-how refers to knowledge that is tacit, situation

    specific, and difficult to codify (Dyer & Singh, 1998). Since know-

    how is tacit and difficult to codify, it is difficult to transfer through

    inter-organizational IT infrastructure. Complementary knowledge

    that is exchanged between supply chain partners is often tacit, sit-

    uation specific, and difficult to codify. For example, they exchange

    professional and expert knowledge about raw materials or manu-

    facturing processes, ideas about new product development, and a

    trial experimentation of new knowledge when they develop a new

    market or new product. These types of knowledge often include

    non-codifiable, tacit components and thus, may not be appropriate

    to exchange through interorganizational IT infrastructure.

    Theunexpected findings in this studynot only open up opportu-

    nities for future research, butalso serveas a precautionaryguidance

    for other researchers trying to study knowledge complementarity.

    From a managerial perspective, one approach to partnership

    management (e.g., McCarter & Northcraft, 2007) holds that man-aging the inherent tension between cooperation and competition

    in inter-firm relationships is essentially a social dilemma. To real-

    ize the potential for joint value creation, partners must exchange

    knowledge and make investments that are specific to the rela-

    tionship (Zeng & Chen, 2003). However, fulfilling these basic

    requirements of alliances renders the valuable investments and

    proprietary knowledge of partners vulnerable to opportunistic

    behavior because each partner may be tempted to use this knowl-

    edge to pursue itsown interests. Recognizing this inherent tension,

    alliance researchers have disagreed as to whether partners should

    pursue “stormy open marriages” (Roehl & Truitt, 1987), or “cooper-

    ativespecialization” (Zeng & Hennart, 2002). Ourfocusin this paper

    has been the exploration of the contingencies under which behav-

    ior patterns triggered by either confident knowledge exchange(the social capital perspective) or cautious knowledge exchange

    (transaction risk perspective) governs knowledge exchange activ-

    ity among supply chain partners. In this regard, the managerial

    prescriptions that emerge from our findings lean toward coop-

    erative specialization – i.e., confident knowledge exchange in a

    trusting relationship because opportunism is subdued to insignif-

    icant levels in the presence of inter-organizational trust (social

    capital). The need for cautious knowledge exchange behavior is

    called for when the knowledge complementarity among partners

    in the supply channel is rather low since this condition tends

    7

    We thank the anonymous reviewer for this specific suggestion.

    to trigger opportunistic behavior patterns. An interesting finding

    of significant value to supply chain managers is that even when

    knowledge complementarity is high one cannot take for granted

    that trusting relationships is always a necessary condition for

    promoting knowledge exchange behavior. Compelling reasons to

    work together can occur even in mistrusting relationships. Like-

    wise, sometimes, simply the absence of mistrust may be sufficient

    when thereare exogenousfactors likeknowledgecomplementarity

    motivating knowledge exchange behavior. Finally, even in a high-

    trust relationship knowledge exchange behavior may sometimes

    be dampened or even retarded subject to the influence of other

    exogenouscontingencies – one oughtto watchfor knowledgeinter-

    dependenceand/or dependenceasymmetriesin the supply channel

    relationships.

    6.2. Future research

    The principal impetus for our future research is the set of unex-

    pected findings reported in this paper. An essential condition for

    knowledgeexchange is the presence of complementaryknowledge,

    which cannot be developed internally in either a timely or a cost-

    effective manner (Park & Ungson, 2001). The more complementary

    knowledgesupplychainpartnershave,the less effortis required for

    the source firm to develop relevant knowledge, as a consequence

    of which more synergistic effects can be realized. For this reason, it

    is important to think about the proportion of the partner’s knowl-

    edge that is synergy-sensitive to the focal firm’s knowledge. An

    important question for the focal firm then is how to evaluate the

    degreeof complementarityof the partner firm’s specializedknowl-

    edge. Our scrutiny of the understudied construct of knowledge

    complementarity sheds light on its richness. Our  post hoc  search

    through the literature led us to a dimensionality of knowledge

    complementarity emerging from the dual constructs of knowledge

    interdependence and dependence asymmetry. Interestingly, most

    research to date accepts as a premise that interdependence, in

    general, positively affects exchange performance in a supply chan-

    nel context because dependence increases both partners’ desire to

    maintain the relationship and the level of adaptation they willfullyundertake (Palmatier et al., 2007). This premise in the knowledge

    exchange scenario, however, has not yet been validated. Likewise,

    dependence asymmetry – that is, the imbalance between partners’

    dependence – has been found to negatively impact exchange per-

    formance. Dependence is the need to maintain a relationship to

    achieve planned goals, and both interdependence and dependence

    asymmetry are crucial to understanding its impact on exchange in

    a dyadic relationship ( Jap & Ganesan, 2000).

    Knowledge complementarity can be of two kinds. The first

    occurs when the bringing together of two knowledge sources

    creates “new” knowledge that neither one of the contributing

    knowledge sources could create or sustain by itself – the idea of 

    the whole is greater than the sum of the parts; the second occurs

    when the knowledge sources provide unidirectional or mutualcat-alyticeffects in enhancing thecapability/potency of each other. It is

    this lattertype of knowledge complementaritythat maybe vulner-

    able to the forces of knowledge interdependence and dependence

    asymmetry. At another level, the properties of “knowledge” should

    be examined to determine to what extent they are conducive to

    complementation. For instance, unlike explicit knowledge, tacit

    knowledge may not be quite amenable to sharing via organized

    mechanisms such as information technology. Tacitknowledge may

    add significant value to supply chain performance and therefore

    cannot simply be ignored because it cannot be easily captured by

    technology.

    Interestingly, both dimensions of dependence, components of 

    or antecedents to knowledge complementation, are shown to

    influence trust. For instance, interdependence, by reducing rela-

  • 8/18/2019 1-s2.0-S0268401211000636-main

    13/15

    K.K. Kimet al./ International Journal of Information Management  32 (2012) 35–49 47

    tionship problems and the convergence of interests, seems to

    have a positive effect on trust (Palmatier et al., 2007). Con-

    versely, trusting relationships tend to increase interdependence

    in a dyad because duplicating relational bonds with a different

    entity entails additional investments of time, effort and other

    tangible and intangible resources (El-Ansary, 1975). Dependence

    asymmetry, on the other hand, can undermine trust as part-

    ners’ interests diverge, resulting in less willingness to compromise

    (Kumar et al., 1995). This behavior pattern, when explored further,

    may shed light on the interactive effect of knowledge complemen-

    tarity and interorganizational trust on knowledge exchange in our

    study.

    In addition to the richer dimensionality of knowledge com-

    plementarity, this ex post literature reminds us of the interactive

    forces binding knowledge complementarity and interorganiza-

    tional trust. It also appears that trust and commitment are

    mutually integrative constructs and that, in the context of  

    knowledge exchange, interorganizational trust with and with-

    out commitment may play different roles (Morgan & Hunt,

    1994) and require further theoretical and empirical investiga-

    tion.

    6.3. Limitations

    The limitations of our study deserve some mention. The data

    for this study were collected from 82 firms, all located in the same

    country. The interpretation of this study’s results is therefore con-

    strained by the particular cultural characteristics of one country.


Recommended