+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

Date post: 17-Jan-2016
Category:
Upload: lynn-lynch
View: 234 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
72
1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1- 5.2b
Transcript
Page 1: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

1

Technology

Beattie, Taylor, and WattsSections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b

Page 2: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

2

Agenda The Production Function with One

Input Understand APP and MPP Diminishing Marginal Returns and

the Stages of Production The Production Function with Two

Input Isoquants

Page 3: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

3

Agenda Cont. Marginal Rate of Technical

Substitution Returns to Scale Production Possibility Frontier Marginal Rate of Product

Transformation

Page 4: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

4

Production Function A production function maps a set of

inputs into a set of outputs. The production function tells you how to

achieve the highest level of outputs given a certain set of inputs.

Inputs to the production function are also called the factors of production.

The general production function can be represented as y = f(x1, x2, …, xn).

Page 5: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

5

Production Function Cont. The general production function

can be represented as y = f(x1, x2, …, xn). Where y is the output produced and is

a positive number. Where xi is the quantity of input i for i

= 1, 2, …, n and each is a positive number.

Page 6: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

6

Production Function with One Input In many situations, we want to

examine what happens to output when we only change one input. This is equivalent to investigating the

general production function previously given holding all but one of the variables constant.

Page 7: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

7

Production Function with One Input Cont. Mathematically we can represent

the production function with one input as the following: y = f(x) = f(x1) = f(x1|x2,x3,…,xn) Suppose y = f(x1, x2, x3) = x1*x2*x3 Suppose that x2 = 3 and x3 = 4, which

are fixed inputs, then y = f(x) = f(x1) = f(x1|3,4) = 12x1 =12x

Page 8: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

8

Example of Production Function y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

Production Function

0

5000

10000

15000

20000

25000

30000

35000

0 10 20 30 40 50 60

y

Page 9: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

9

APP and MPP There are two major tools for

examining a production function: Average Physical Product (APP) Marginal Physical Product (MPP)

Page 10: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

10

APP The average physical product tells

you the average amount of output you are getting for an input.

We define APP as output (y) divided by input (x). APP = y/x = f(x)/x

Page 11: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

11

Example of Finding APP Assume you have the following

production function: y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

)60(

60

60

2

23

xxAPP

xxAPP

x

xx

x

yAPP

Page 12: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

12

Example of Finding Maximum APP To find the maximum APP, you take the

derivative of APP and solve for the x that gives you zero.

From the previous example: APP = -x2 + 60x

30

0602

60max 2

x

xdx

dAPP

xxdx

d

dx

dAPPAPP

Page 13: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

13

MPP The marginal physical product tells you

what effect a change of the input will do to the output. In essence, it is the change in the output

divided by the change in the input. MPP is defined as:

)(' xfdx

dyMPP

Page 14: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

14

Example of Finding MPP Assume you have the following

production function: y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

)40(3

1203

60

2

23

xxMPP

xxMPP

xxdx

d

dx

dyMPP

Page 15: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

15

Interpreting MPP When MPP > 0, then the production

function is said to have positive returns to the use of the input. This occurs on the convex and the

beginning of the concave portion of the production function.

In the previous example, this implies that MPP > 0 when input is less than 40 (x<40).

Page 16: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

16

Interpreting MPP Cont. When MPP = 0, then we know that

the production function is at a maximum. Setting MPP = 0 is just the first order

condition to find the maximum of the production function.

In the example above, MPP = 0 when the input was at 40.

Page 17: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

17

Interpreting MPP Cont. When MPP < 0, then the production

function is said to have decreasing returns to the use of the input. This occurs on the concave portion of

the production function. In the previous example, this implies

that MPP < 0 when input is greater than 40 (x>40).

Page 18: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

18

Example of APP and MPP y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

APP and MPP

-2000

-1500

-1000

-500

0

500

1000

1500

0 10 20 30 40 50 60APP

MPP

Page 19: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

19

Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns (LDMR) The Law of Diminishing Marginal

Returns states that as you add successive units of an input while holding all other inputs constant, then the marginal physical product must eventually decrease. This is equivalent to saying that the

derivative of MPP is negative.

Page 20: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

20

Finding Where LDMR Exists Suppose y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

To find where the LDMR exists is equivalent to finding what input levels give a second order condition that is negative.

20

0)20(0)20(60

negative termabove set the exists LDMR wherefind To

)20(61206

1203

2

2

2

x

xxdx

dMPP

xxdx

yd

dx

dMPP

xxdx

dyMPP

Page 21: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

21

Relationship of APP and MPP When MPP > APP, then APP is

rising When MPP = APP, then APP is at a

maximum When MPP < APP, then APP is

declining

Page 22: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

22

Relationship of APP and MPP Cont.

APPMPPdx

dAPPx

xfxf

dx

dAPP

xfxxfdx

dAPP

xxfxxfdx

dAPP

x

xfxxf

dx

dAPP

x

xfxxf

dx

dAPP

x

xf

dx

d

dx

dAPPx

xfAPP

when 0

)()(' when 0

)()(' when 0

*0)()(' when 0

0)()('

when 0

)()('

)(

)(

2

2

2

Page 23: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

23

Stages of Production Stage I of production is where the

MPP is above the APP, i.e., it starts where the input level is 0 and goes all the way up to the input level where MPP=APP. To find the transition point from stage I

to Stage II you need to set the APP function equal to the MPP function and solve for x.

Page 24: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

24

Stages of Production Cont. Stage II of production is where MPP is

less than APP but greater than zero, i.e., it starts at the input level where MPP=APP and ends at the input level where MPP=0. To find the transition point from Stage II to

Stage III, you want to set MPP = 0 and solve for x.

Stage III is where the MPP<0, i.e., it starts at the input level where MPP=0.

Page 25: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

25

Graphical View of the Production Stages

Stage II

Stage I

Stage III

TPP

Y

xMPP APP

xMPP

APP

Page 26: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

26

Finding the Transition From Stage I to Stage II Suppose y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

30or 0

0)30(2

0602

120360

for x solve and APP MPPset point n transitio thefind To

601203

1203

2

22

22

2

xx

xx

xx

xxxx

MPPAPP

xxx

xx

x

yAPP

xxdx

dyMPP

Page 27: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

27

Finding the Transition From Stage II to Stage III Suppose y = f(x) = -x3 + 60x2

40or 0

0)40(3

01203

0

for x solve and 0 MPPset point n transitio thefind To

1203

2

2

xx

xx

xx

MPP

xxdx

dyMPP

Page 28: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

28

Production Function with Two Inputs While one input production

functions provide much intuitive information about production, there are times when we want to examine what is the relationship of output to two inputs. This is equivalent to investigating the

general production function holding all but two of the variables constant.

Page 29: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

29

Production Function with Two Inputs Cont. Mathematically we can represent

the production function with one input as the following: y = f(x1,x2) = f(x1, x2|x3,…,xn)

Page 30: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

30

Example of a Production Function with Two Variables: y=f(x1,x2)=-x1

3+25x12-

x23+25x2

2

0 2 4 6 8

10 12 14 16 18 20 22 240

6

12

18

24

0.00

500.00

1000.00

1500.00

2000.00

2500.00

3000.00

3500.00

4000.00

4500.00

5000.00

4500.00-5000.00

4000.00-4500.00

3500.00-4000.00

3000.00-3500.00

2500.00-3000.00

2000.00-2500.00

1500.00-2000.00

1000.00-1500.00

500.00-1000.00

0.00-500.00

Page 31: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

31

Example 2 of a Production Function with Two Variables: y=f(x1,x2)=8x1

1/4x23/4

0

2

4

6

8 10

012345678910

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

70-80

60-70

50-60

40-50

30-40

20-30

10-20

0-10

Page 32: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

32

Three Important Concepts for Examining Production Function with Two Inputs

There are three important concepts to understand with a production function with two or more inputs. Marginal Physical Product (MPP) Isoquant Marginal Rate Of Technical

Substitution (MRTS)

Page 33: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

33

MPP for Two Input Production Function MPP for a production function with

multiple inputs can be viewed much like MPP for a production function with one input. The only difference is that the MPP for the

multiple input production function must be calculated while holding all other inputs constant, i.e., instead of taking the derivative of the function, you take the partial derivative.

Page 34: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

34

MPP for Two Input Production Function Cont. Hence, with two inputs, you need to

calculate the MPP for both inputs. MPP for input xi is defined

mathematically as the following:

22

11

2

21

1

21

21

),(

),(

),(

xx

xx

xi

x

fx

xxfMPP

fx

xxfMPP

fx

xxfMPP

ii

Page 35: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

35

Example of Calculating MPP Suppose y = f(x1,x2) = -x1

3+25x12-x2

3+25x22

222

2

21

121

1

21

22

32

21

3121

503),(

503),(

2525),(

2

1

xxx

xxfMPP

xxx

xxfMPP

xxxxxxfy

x

x

Page 36: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

36

Example 2 of Calculating MPP Suppose y = f(x1,x2) = 8x1

1/4 x23/4

4

1

2

1

4

1

2

4

1

14

1

24

1

14

1

24

1

12

21

4

3

1

2

4

3

1

4

3

24

3

24

3

14

3

24

3

11

21

4

3

24

1

121

66684

3),(

22284

1),(

8),(

2

1

x

x

x

xxxxx

x

xxfMPP

x

x

x

xxxxx

x

xxfMPP

xxxxfy

x

x

Page 37: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

37

Note on MPP for Multiple Inputs When the MPP for a particular

input is zero, you have found a relative extrema point for the production function.

In general, the MPP w.r.t. input 1 does not have to equal MPP w.r.t. input 2.

Page 38: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

38

The Isoquant An isoquant is the set of inputs that

give you the same level of output. To find the isoquant, you need to

set the dependent variable y equal to some number and examine all the combinations of inputs that give you that level of output. An isoquant map shows you all the

isoquants for a given set of inputs.

Page 39: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

39

Example of An Isoquant Map: y = -x1

2+24x1-x2

2+26x2

0 4 8

12

16

20

24 0

3

6

9

12

15

18

21

24

300.00-350.00

250.00-300.00

200.00-250.00

150.00-200.00

100.00-150.00

50.00-100.00

0.00-50.00

-50.00-0.00

Page 40: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

40

Example 2 of An Isoquant Map: y = 8x1

1/4 x23/4

0 2 4 6 8 10

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

60-80

40-60

20-40

0-20

Page 41: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

41

Finding the Set of Inputs for a General Output Given y = -x1

2+24x1-x2

2+26x2

Suppose y = -x12+24x1-x2

2+26x2

We can solve the above equation for x2 in terms of y and x1.

yxx

yxx

yxx

a

acbb

yxx

yxxxx

xxxxy

1212

121

2

121

2

2

2

2

121

1212

22

2221

21

2416913x

2

496467626x

)1(2

)24)(1(4)26(26x

2

4x

24c and 26,b 1,a define weIf

02426

2624

Page 42: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

42

Question From the previous example, does it

make economic sense to have both the positive and negative sign in front of the radical? No, only one makes economic sense; but

which one. You should expect that you will have an

inverse relationship between x1 and x2. This implies that for this particular function, you

would prefer to use the negative sign.

Page 43: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

43

Finding the Set of Inputs for a General Output Given y = 8x1

1/4

x23/4

Suppose y = 8x11/4 x2

3/4

We can solve the above equation for x2 in terms of y and x1.

3/11

3/4

2

4

1

1

4

3

2

4

3

24

1

121

16

8

8),(

x

yx

x

yx

xxxxfy

Page 44: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

44

Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS) The Marginal Rate of Technical

Substitution tells you the trade-off of one input for another that will leave you with the same level of output. In essence, it is the slope of the

isoquant.

Page 45: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

45

Finding the MRTS There are two methods you can

find MRTS. The first method is to derive the

isoquant from the production function and then calculate the slope of the isoquant.

The second method is to derive the MPP for each input and then take the negative of the ratio of these MPP.

Page 46: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

46

Equivalency Between Slope of the Isoquant and the Ratio of MPP’s

MRTSdx

dx

dxdydxdy

dx

dy

dx

dx

i

1

2

x

x

2

1

x

x

x

1

2

2

1

2

1

i

MPP

MPP

equal is MPPeach for y in change heisoquant t on the are weSince

MPP

MPP

MPP that know We

isoquant theof Slope MRTS

Page 47: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

47

Finding the MRTS Using the ratio of the MPP’s Given y = -x1

2+24x1-x22+26x2

Suppose y = -x12+24x1-x2

2+26x2

262

242

262

242

2624

2

1

22

11

2221

21

2

1

2

1

x

x

MPP

MPPMRTS

xx

yMPP

xx

yMPP

xxxxy

x

x

x

x

Page 48: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

48

Finding the MRTS Using the Slope of the Isoquant Given y = -x1

2+24x1-x2

2+26x2

Suppose y = -x12+24x1-x2

2+26x2

2

1

121

1

1

2

12

1

121

1

2

2

1

121

11

2

2

1

1212

121

2

24169

12

x

x

242241692

1

x

x

2416913xx

x

2416913x

2

496467626x

asfunction w above for theisoquant that thefound wepreviously From

yxx

x

xyxx

yxx

yxx

yxx

Page 49: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

49

Finding the MRTS Using the Slope of the Isoquant Given y = -x1

2+24x1-x22+26x2

Cont.

13

12

x

x

13

12

x

x

26169

12

x

x

262424169

12

x

x

262424169

12

x

x

2624y know we

24169

12

x

x

2

1

1

2

2

12

2

1

1

2

2

1

222

1

1

2

2

1

2221

211

21

1

1

2

2

1

2221

211

21

1

1

2

2221

21

2

1

121

1

1

2

x

x

x

x

xx

x

xxxxxx

x

xxxxxx

x

xxxx

yxx

x

Page 50: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

50

Finding the MRTS Using the ratio of the MPP’s Given y = Kx1

x2

Suppose y = Kx1x2

1

212

11

12

11

121

21

1

121

2

21

11

21

2

1

2

1

x

xxxxxMRTS

xKx

xKx

MPP

MPPMRTS

xKxx

yMPP

xKxx

yMPP

xKxy

x

x

x

x

Page 51: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

51

Finding the MRTS Using the Slope of the Isoquant Given y = Kx1

x2

Suppose y = Kx1x2

1

1

1

2

1

1

1

1

2

1

1

11

2

1

11

12

12

21

x

x

x

x

xx

x

xK

y

xK

y

xK

y

xK

y

Kx

yx

Kx

yx

xKxy

Page 52: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

52

Finding the MRTS Using the Slope of the Isoquant Given y = Kx1

x2 Cont.

1

2112

1

2

121

2

1211

2

1

1

21

1

2

1

1

21

1

2

21

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

x

that know But we

x

xxx

xx

xxx

xK

xKx

xK

xKx

xKxy

Page 53: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

53

Returns to Scale Returns to Scale examines what

happens to output when you change all inputs by the same proportion, i.e., f(tx1,tx2). There are three types of Returns to

Scale: Increasing Constant Decreasing

Page 54: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

54

Increasing Returns to Scale Increasing Returns to Scale are said to

exist when f(tx1,tx2)>tf(x1,x2) for t > 1. This implies that as output is increasing,

the isoquants are getting closer together. Suppose y = f(x1,x2) = x1x2

This implies that f(tx1,tx2) = tx1tx2 =t2x1x2

Comparing f(tx1,tx2) and tf(x1,x2) implies f(tx1,tx2) = t2x1x2 >t f(x1,x2) = tx1x2, because when t >1, t2 > t.

Page 55: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

55

Example Increasing Returns to Scale: y = 10x1

x2

0 2 4 6 8

100

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

900-1000800-900700-800600-700500-600400-500300-400200-300100-2000-100

Page 56: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

56

Constant Returns to Scale Constant Returns to Scale are said to

exist when f(tx1,tx2)=tf(x1,x2) for t > 1. This implies that as output is increasing, the

isoquants are the same distance apart. Suppose y = f(x1,x2) = x1

½ x2½

This implies that f(tx1,tx2) = (tx1)½ (tx2)½ =tx1x2

Comparing f(tx1,tx2) and tf(x1,x2) implies f(tx1,tx2) = tx1x2 = t f(x1,x2) = tx1x2, because when t >1, t = t.

Page 57: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

57

Example Constant Returns to Scale: y = 10x1

½ x2½

0 2 4 6 8

100

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10 95-10090-9585-9080-8575-8070-7565-7060-6555-6050-5545-5040-4535-4030-35

Page 58: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

58

Return to Scale Cont. Decreasing Returns to Scale are said to

exist when f(tx1,tx2)<tf(x1,x2) for t > 1. This implies that as output is increasing, the

isoquants are getting farther apart. Suppose y = f(x1,x2) = x1

¼ x2¼

This implies that f(tx1,tx2) = (tx1)¼ (tx2)¼

=t½x1¼x2

¼

Comparing f(tx1,tx2) and tf(x1,x2) implies f(tx1,tx2) = t½x1x2 < t f(x1,x2) = tx1

¼x2¼,

because when t >1, t½ < t.

Page 59: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

59

Example Decreasing Returns to Scale: y = 10x1 ¼ x2

¼

0 2 4 6 8

100

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

28-3224-2820-2416-2012-168-124-80-4

Page 60: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

60

The Multiple Product Firm Many producers have a tendency

to produce more than one product. This allows them to minimize risk by

diversifying their production. Personal choice.

The question arises: What type of trade-off exists for enterprises that use the same inputs?

Page 61: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

61

Two Major Types of Multiple Production Multiple products coming from one

production function. E.g., wool and lamb chops

Mathematically: Y1, Y2, …, Yn = f(x1, x2, …, xn) Where Yi is output of good i Where xi is input i

Page 62: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

62

Two Major Types of Multiple Production Cont. Multiple products coming from

multiple production functions where the production functions are competing for the same inputs. E.g., corn and soybeans

Page 63: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

63

Two Major Types of Multiple Production Cont. Mathematically:

Y1= f1(x11, x12, …, x1m) Y2= f2(x21, x22, …, x2m) Yn= fn(xn1, xn2, …, xnm) Where Yi is output of good i Where xij is input j allocated to output Yi

Where Xj x1j + x2j + … + xnj and is the maximum amount of input j available.

Page 64: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

64

Production Possibility Frontier A production possibility frontier (PPF)

tells you the maximum amount of each product that can be produced given a fixed level of inputs. The emphasis of the production

possibility function is on the fixed level of inputs.

These fixed inputs could be labor, capital, land, etc.

Page 65: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

65

PPF Cont. All points along the edge of the

production possibility frontier are the most efficient use of resources that can be achieved given its resource constraints.

Anything inside the PPF is achievable but is not fully utilizing all the resources, while everything outside is not feasible.

Page 66: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

66

Deriving the PPF Mathematically To derive the production possibility

frontier, you want to use the resource constraint on the inputs as a way of solving for one output as a function of the other.

Page 67: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

67

PPF Example Suppose you produce two goods,

corn (Y1) and soybeans (Y2). Also suppose your limiting factor is

land (X1) at 100 acres. For corn you know that you have the

following production relationship: Y1 = x1

½

Page 68: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

68

PPF Example Cont. For corn you know that you have

the following production relationship: Y2 = x2

½

We know that 100 = x1 + x2.

Page 69: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

69

Solving PPF Example Mathematically

2

12

12

21

22

22

21

21

222

2

1

22

211

2

1

11

100

100

100

100

x Y

x

:following theknow We

YY

YY

YY

xx

Yx

YxY

Page 70: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

70

PPF Graphical Example PPF

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

0 2 4 6 8 10 12

PPF

Page 71: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

71

Marginal Rate of Product Transformation (MRPT) MRPT can be defined as the

amount of one product you must give up to get another product. This is equivalent to saying that the

MRPT is equal to the slope of the production possibility frontier.

MRPT = dY2/dY1

Also known as Marginal Rate of Product Substitution.

Page 72: 1 Technology Beattie, Taylor, and Watts Sections: 2.1-2.2, 5.1-5.2b.

72

Find MRPT of the Following PPF: Y2 = (100-Y1

2)½

Suppose Y2 = (100-Y12)½

0100

2*1002

1

100

2

12

111

2

12

12

11

2

2

12

12

YYdY

dYMRPT

YYdY

dYMRPT

YY


Recommended