+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 10.1.1.202.5202

10.1.1.202.5202

Date post: 05-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: pushkar-kumar
View: 219 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 42

Transcript
  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    1/42

    Ownership Structure, Managerial Behavior

    and Corporate Value

    J.R. Davies

    David Hillier

    Patrick McColgan

    JEL Classication: G32

    Keywords: Ownership Structure; Capital Expenditure; Corporate Value; Tobin's Q.

    The authors would like to thank John Capsta, Scott Linn, Andrew Marshall, JamesWansley and seminar participants at the Financial Management Association International(2001), European Financial Management Association (2002), Trinity College Dublin andUniversity of Strathclyde for their valuable comments on an earlier version of the paper.The normal caveat applies.

    Department of Accounting & Finance, University of Strathclyde, Glasgow. G4 0LN.Phone: 00 44 141 548 3889. Fax: 00 44 141 552 3547. Corresponding Author e-mail:[email protected].

    October 24, 2002

    1

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    2/42

    Ownership Structure, Managerial Behavior andCorporate Value

    Abstract

    The nonlinear relationship between corporate value (Tobin's Q) and man-

    agerial ownership is well documented. This has commonly been attributed

    to the onset of managerial entrenchment, which results in a decrease of cor-

    porate value for increasing levels of managerial holdings. We propose a more

    complex structure for the corporate value { managerial ownership function,

    which accounts for the eect of conicting managerial incentives and external

    and internal disciplinary monitoring mechanisms. Using this specication as

    the basis for our analysis, we provide evidence that the managerial ownership

    - corporate value relationship is co-deterministic. This nding is at odds with

    recent work by Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al. (1999) who report that

    corporate value determines managerial ownership but not vice-versa.

    2

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    3/42

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    4/42

    1 Introduction

    In a market without agency problems, corporate management will chooseinvestments that maximize the wealth of shareholders. In practice, com-

    peting objectives that are incompatible with the classic shareholder wealth-

    maximizing paradigm may also be pursued. Following Jensen and Meckling

    (1976), a large literature has developed examining the eect of management

    and their behavior on the performance and value of rms they control. A vi-

    brant strand of this literature concerns the relationship between managerial

    ownership levels, the direct investment decisions made by management andthe inherent value of the rm, as proxied by Tobin's Q ratio.

    Morck, Shleifer and Vishny (1988), McConnell and Servaes (1990), and

    Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) provide evidence of a signicant non-linear

    relationship between corporate value and managerial ownership. Specically,

    corporate value increases with management equity holdings to a certain level

    after which entrenchment behavior becomes dominant, leading to decreases

    in rm value. Whereas, Morck et al. (1988) and Hermalin and Weisbach(1991) document a further change in the corporate value-managerial holdings

    relationship at high levels of equity ownership, McConnell and Servaes (1990)

    report no such change.

    Recent work by Cho (1998) and Himmelberg, Hubbard and Palia (1999)

    have shed doubt on these earlier ndings by controlling for the eects of en-

    dogeneity and unobservable (to the econometrician) rm characteristics in

    their analysis. Applying a two-stage least squares methodology, Cho (1998)showed that managerial ownership had no eect on corporate value and in-

    vestment but that corporate value had a signicant impact on managerial

    4

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    5/42

    ownership. Himmelberg et al. (1999) showed that controlling for endogeneity

    eliminated the observed relationship between corporate value and managerial

    ownership but also that a large proportion of the cross-sectional variation in

    managerial holdings was explained by unobserved rm heterogeneity.

    In this paper, we propose an alternative structure to the managerial

    ownership-corporate value relationship which captures a more complex char-

    acterization of the evolving behavior of managers. We argue that at high

    levels of managerial ownership when external market discipline becomes in-

    eective, there will be a resurgence of entrenchment behavior. With equity

    holdings around 50%, managers will have gained implicit control of their

    company, but still do not have objectives completely aligned to external

    shareholders. Only at very high levels of managerial holdings, are incentives

    akin to other shareholders.

    In contrast to Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al. (1999), when this model

    is applied to a large sample of rms incorporated in the UK, managerial

    ownership is shown to have a signicant impact on corporate value. This re-

    lationship is endogenous, and consistent with Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et

    al. (1999), corporate value has a corresponding eect on levels of managerial

    ownership. Surprisingly, we nd that although ownership levels are aected

    by rm level capital expenditures (investment), there is no evidence of the

    reverse occurring.

    We provide a more detailed review of the relevant literature in the next

    section. In section three we justify an examination of this issue using UK

    data and discuss some important features of the UK market. In section

    four we outline a simple model of managerial ownership in which corporate

    5

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    6/42

    value increases non-linearly with management equity holdings. We present

    empirical results in section ve and conclude in section six.

    2 Overview of Relevant Literature

    Since Jensen and Meckling (1976) rst proposed that share ownership would

    provide managers with an incentive to reduce private perquisite consump-

    tion, empirical research has produced conicting results as to the veracity of

    their proposals. An initial attempt to model a linear relationship between

    corporate performance, as measured by accounting prot rate, and owner-

    ship concentration was made unsuccessfully by Demsetz and Lehn (1985).

    However, Morck et al. (1988) documented a signi cant non-linear relation

    between ownership and value in their study of 371 Fortune 500 companies.

    Their ndings point to a positive impact on corporate value for ownership lev-

    els between 0% and 5% managerial ownership and a negative eect between

    5% and 25%. This change in sign is attributed to managerial entrenchment,

    when they gain enough power (with insucient external controls) so as to

    be able to pursue their own objectives at the expense of shareholder value.

    Although managerial interests will converge to that of shareholders as their

    equity stake grows, behavior is still dominated by entrenchment. At levels of

    ownership above 25%, Morck et al. (1988) found that the alignment of ob-

    jectives became prominent and increases in ownership were associated with

    higher levels of corporate value.

    McConnell and Servaes (1990) provide some evidence to support Morck

    et al. (1988). In a larger and more diverse sample, they report a signicant

    6

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    7/42

    quadratic relation between managerial ownership and corporate value. As

    ownership increases, so too does value. However, above equity holdings of

    approximately 50% and 40% in their 1976 and 1986 samples respectively, rm

    value declines. Their interpretation is attributed to initially increased man-

    agerial incentives but with entrenchment prevailing at higher levels of owner-

    ship. Similarly, Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) also report a non-monotonic

    relationship between ownership and corporate value but with dierent turn-

    ing points.1

    More recent work has built upon the ndings of Demsetz and Lehn (1985)

    who argue that levels of managerial ownership will be determined endoge-

    nously in equilibrium. They nd ownership to be a function of the volatility

    of a rm's stock. Managers holding large share stakes in their own rm nd

    it more dicult to diversify their portfolio risk, and thus their incentive to

    hold large shareholdings declines as the risk of their rm's stock increases.

    Cho (1998) extended the argument of Demsetz and Lehn (1985) by exam-

    ining the interdependence of managerial ownership, investment, and corpo-

    rate value. Initially, Cho (1998) reported the same non-monotonic relation

    between ownership and value as found by Morck et al. (1988). Further-

    more, he also found this same relation between levels of ownership and cor-

    porate investment, suggesting that \ownership structure aects investment

    and, therefore corporate value." (p. 114) However, drawing on Demsetz

    1Hermalin and Weisbach use both OLS and instrumental variable regressions, the latterbeing an attempt to control for potential simultaneity between ownership and corporatevalue. However, they argue that such an approach is imperfect. In addition, Himmelberg

    et al. (1999) are critical of an instrumental variables approach, as the instruments formanagerial ownership and corporate value will be similar and determined within the rm'scontracting environment.

    7

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    8/42

    and Lehn (1985), simultaneous regression analysis was utilized to control for

    endogenity and it was found that ownership structure was endogenously de-

    termined by corporate value (as measured by Tobin's Q). It was also reported

    that investment and not managerial ownership signicantly inuenced corpo-

    rate value. Cho (1998) concluded that managers in rms with higher Tobin's

    Q, or with better investment opportunities tend to hold a higher fraction of

    their rm's shares. However, he found no evidence that managerial ownership

    had a causal eect on investment or corporate value.

    Himmelberg et al. (1999) interpret similar ndings of endogeneity in a

    dierent manner. They propose that endogeneity provides evidence of dier-

    ing optimal contracting relationships within various types of rms. In this

    situation, incentives provided by managerial ownership will dier in impor-

    tance depending on both observable and unobservable characteristics of a

    rm's contracting environment. Their ndings point to the importance of

    rm heterogeneity in determining levels of managerial holdings. Moreover,

    when taking these unobserved factors into account, they found no evidence

    of a causal relationship between managerial ownership and corporate value.

    However, Zhou (2001) is heavily critical of the xed eects panel data ap-

    proach employed by Himmelberg et al. (1999). He comments that such a

    methodology will remove any cross-sectional variation in the data, and there-

    fore, reveal no meaningful link between managerial ownership and corporate

    value. Both Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) and Zhou (2001) argue that

    cross-sectional variation is likely to be a signicant factor in any relationship

    between managerial ownership and value.

    With UK companies, Short and Keasey (1999) and Faccio and Las-

    8

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    9/42

    fer (1999) both utilize a cubic specication to model the corporate value-

    managerial holdings relationship and both reported a signicant non-linear

    functional form similar to Morck et al. (1988). Specically, Short and Keasey

    (1999) document turning points of 12.99% and 41.99% and Faccio and Las-

    fer (1999) document breakpoints of 19.68% and 54.12% in their sub-sample

    of above average growth rms. However, neither study fully examines the

    misspecifying impact of endogeneity on their results.2

    3 UK Institutional FeaturesThe UK oers an interesting environment for the conduct of a study of this

    kind in several respects. First, with roughly 2,500 national and multinational

    companies listed on the London Stock Exchange (LSE), the UK is a major

    international nancial market. Furthermore, corporate governance structures

    in the UK are largely similar to those in the US in terms of corporate boards,

    diverse ownership structures and active external markets which in theory

    should contribute to improved managerial monitoring.

    Investment practices in the UK resemble those of the United States, where

    nancial institutions such as pension funds control 80% of UK securities. As

    a consequence, the UK mirrors closely US corporate and nancial practices,

    enabling meaningful comparisons with prior US-based studies.

    Both the UK and US have nancial and regulatory traditions that are

    2Whilst Faccio and Lasfer (1999) ignore this possible eect, Short and Keasey (1999)take ownership as a lagged value as at the end of 1988 and then measure value as theaverage for 1989 to 1992. As an alternative approach they also use xed year dummyvariables within a panel regression framework. However, Himmelberg et al. (1999) contendthat even such an approach doesn't adequately account for endogenity as the contractualnexus of a rm will change only very slowly over time.

    9

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    10/42

    dierent from those of other developed economies such as Japan and Western

    Europe. Evidence of this is provided by Dahya, McConnell and Travlos

    (2002), who document the same statistically signicant relationship between

    outsider dominated corporate boards and performance related management

    turnover as that reported by Weisbach (1988) for US companies. This is in

    contrast to Kang and Shivdasani (1995) who could nd no such relationship

    existing in Japanese companies.

    Any proposed similarity between the UK and US is tempered by the em-

    pirical ndings of a poor disciplinary takeover market in the UK by Franks

    and Mayer (1996) who, in contrast to the ndings of Martin and McConnell

    (1991) for US corporate forms, nd no signicant relation between poor com-

    pany performance, hostile takeovers and top management turnover. These

    ndings point to a similarity between the UK and Germany where Franks

    and Mayer (2000) discuss a lack of takeover market in which to provide man-

    agement with incentives for maximising rm value. In addition, Short and

    Keasey (1999) note that UK companies are substantially less active in their

    use of takeover defences, largely due to opposition from nancial institu-

    tions. Were this to be the case, managerial ownership would take on greater

    signicance in the UK.

    Institutional stakeholders in the UK are also likely to be more active in

    their monitoring capacity than their US counterparts. As Short and Keasey

    (1999) point out, the extreme geographical clustering of large institutions

    within the City of London can lead to an eective but informal monitoring

    mechanism for the management of London Stock Exchange listed companies.

    In addition, Short and Keasey(1999) argue that much of the monitoring

    10

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    11/42

    activity of UK institutions is carried out privately `behind closed doors' and

    unlike many of their US counterparts, UK nancial institutions face no legal

    duty to vote at company AGMs.

    Finally, Franks, Mayer and Renneboog (2001) note the minority protec-

    tion laws in the UK are far more stringent than those applied to US corpora-

    tions. These laws may be vitally important in shielding minority shareholders

    from expropriation by company management or other major shareholders.

    4 Theoretical MotivationIn this section, we propose an alternative structure to the managerial holdings-

    corporate value relationship and argue that the cubic, or simpler representa-

    tions, used in earlier studies (see Morck et al. (1988), McConnell and Servaes

    (1990), Hermalin and Weisbach (1991), Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al.

    (1999) for US companies and Short and Keasey (1999) and Faccio and Las-

    fer (1999) for UK companies) are unnecessarily restrictive and misspecied.

    The model that is presented in this paper captures further nonlinearities

    in this relationship at high levels of managerial holdings and has a quintic

    specication.

    Management are faced with both negative and positive incentives to en-

    sure that they follow objectives that maximize shareholder wealth. The ef-

    fectiveness of incentives is potentially a function of the level of managerial

    ownership in the rm. Since compensation packages such as stock options

    are a transfer of wealth from shareholders to management, the value of these

    incentives will lessen as management ownership increases. External market

    11

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    12/42

    discipline is also a function of managerial ownership. Martin and McConnell

    (1991) argue that the takeover market is an eective means of disciplining

    management for poor performance. However, large shareholdings by top

    management act as a deterrent for takeovers because of the greater ability

    to oppose a hostile bid or drive up premiums to the point where bidders no

    longer view the target company as a positive net present value investment,

    [Stulz (1988)]. Finally, internal controls in the form of monitoring from large

    shareholders and corporate boards should reduce the scope for managers to

    diverge greatly from the interests of shareholders. Again, however, such dis-

    cipline is likely to be inversely related to managerial control.

    We view the propensity of management to maximize shareholder wealth

    to be a function of three unobserved factors: external market discipline (even

    if it is weak), internal controls and convergence of interests. Moreover, the

    strength of each factor can be viewed as a function of the level of managerial

    ownership in the rm.

    4.1 Low levels of managerial ownership

    For low levels of managerial ownership, external discipline and internal con-

    trols or incentives will dominate behavior [see for example Fama (1980), Hart

    (1983) and Jensen and Ruback (1983)] leading towards value maximization.

    Empirically, Morck et al. (1988), McConnell and Servaes (1990), Hermalin

    and Weisbach (1991) and the original analysis of Cho (1998) report results

    consistent with this behavior. However, there is also a possibility that lower

    levels of ownership within this range have endogenously arisen from perfor-

    mance related compensation packages, such as stock options and stock grants

    12

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    13/42

    rather than increased ownership leading to higher Q ratios.

    4.2 Intermediate levels of managerial ownership

    At intermediate levels of managerial ownership, convergence of interests be-

    comes stronger. However, with greater ownership comes greater power in

    the form of voting rights. Managers may be able to maximise their own

    wealth through increasing their perquisites and guaranteeing their employ-

    ment at the expense of corporate value. In addition, whilst ownership in the

    previous range may have arisen through the vesting of compensation plans,

    it is unlikely that such plans will provide management with even a mod-

    erate ownership stake in the rm. Although external market controls are

    still in place, these and the eect of convergence of interests are not strong

    enough to align the behavior of management to shareholders. Managerial

    labour markets operate on the principal that managers can be removed for

    poor performance and appropriately disciplined. Studies by Denis, Denis

    and Sarin (1997) in the US and Dahya et al. (2002) in the UK both nd

    an inverse relation between top-management turnover and managerial own-

    ership. This lack of discipline provides evidence of a deciency in incentives

    for managers to maximise shareholder value at this level of ownership. Em-

    pirically, the management entrenchment hypothesis, as suggested by Fama

    and Jensen (1983), has been veried by Morck et al. (1988), McConnell and

    Servaes (1990), and Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) amongst others.

    13

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    14/42

    4.3 High levels of insider ownership (less than 50%)

    As levels of managerial equity ownership increase, objectives converge furtherto those of shareholders. At ownership levels below 50%, management do not

    have total control of the rm and external discipline still exists. While per-

    haps no longer being subject to any major discipline from external markets,

    it is likely that even at these levels of ownership, managers are still subject

    to discipline from external block shareholders. This is particularly true in

    the UK, where because of strong informal ties between institutions [Short

    and Keasey (1999)], a lax regulatory environment concerning the ownership

    of listed companies [Roe (1990)] and low monitoring costs [Faccio and Lasfer

    (1999)], institutional activism is stronger than in the US.3 This suggests that

    even at high ownership levels, blockholders may still be able to inuence man-

    agerial decision-making. This alignment of interests together with external

    controls that can be applied by blockholders may in eect lead to managers

    reverting to a value maximising strategy, a pattern consistent with Morck et

    al. (1988). This is also consistent with Franks et al.'s (2001) contention of

    strong minority protection laws in the UK, combined with monitoring from

    UK institutions, which may allow external shareholders to impose some form

    of control on management.

    3For a more in-depth discussion of the institutional dierences and similarities betweenthe United Kingdom and United States, see Short and Keasey (1999) and Faccio andLasfer (1999).

    14

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    15/42

    4.4 High levels of managerial ownership (greater than

    50%)

    At levels above 50% managerial ownership, management have complete con-

    trol of their company. Although atomistic shareholders are likely to have

    been unable to inuence managers at far lower levels of ownership than this,

    there is always a possibility that a cartel of blockholders (allied with minority

    shareholder's rights under UK company law) may be able to mount a chal-

    lenge to corporate managers if they fail to make decisions in shareholders'

    best interests. At greater than 50% managerial ownership, this possibilityis no longer likely to be a serious issue to management. Furthermore, at

    levels of 50% managerial ownership the probability of a hostile takeover ef-

    fectively becomes zero. The failure of external discipline at such ownership

    levels combined with a lack of blockholder incentives above 50% may result

    in a decrease in corporate value for a small window of managerial holdings

    above this level. The fall in corporate value at this level can be considered

    similar to that found by McConnell and Servaes (1990).

    4.5 Very high levels of managerial ownership

    Finally, as managerial shareholdings rise to very high levels, management

    eectively become sole owners of the company leading to value maximising

    behavior. Consistent with Morck et al. (1988), Short and Keasey (1999),

    Faccio and Lasfer (1999) and the initial ndings of Cho (1998), above a

    certain level of ownership corporate managers are faced with such severe

    nancial penalties for failing to maximise the value of their companies that

    15

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    16/42

    they are forced to make decisions which will maximise rm value, regardless

    of how this aects their preferences for corporate power.

    4.6 Summary

    Our characterisation of a highly nonlinear relationship between managerial

    equity holdings and corporate value is in contrast to earlier studies [Morck et

    al. (1988), McConnell and Servaes (1990)4, Hermalin and Weisbach (1991),

    Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al. (1999)], which posit fewer breakpoints

    in their analysis. There is little theoretical basis on which the individual

    breakpoints can be determined, and the ndings of Kole (1995) suggest that

    these will be determined by the size of the rms in the sample. However,

    it is expected that the second local maximum will be in the region of 50%

    managerial ownership reecting the stage at which management gain total

    control of the company. In the next section, the main tests of our hypotheses

    will be carried out.

    5 Empirical Results

    5.1 Description of the data

    We use data on managerial and external block ownership for 1995 from the

    Macmillan London Stock Exchange Yearbook for 1996 and 1997. The Year-

    book provides summary accounting data including a consolidated balance

    sheet, information on company directors, legal information on the company's4McConnell and Servaes (1988) modelled the corporate value-managerial ownership

    relationship as a quadratic function, which by construction has only one turning point.

    16

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    17/42

    lawyers, auditors and stockbrokers, principle activities, company history, cap-

    ital and dividend payments and industrial sector for the vast majority of all

    quoted companies and securities.5 The register could be considered similar

    to the Value Line Investment Survey used in comparable US studies by, for

    example, McConnell and Servaes (1990) and Denis et al. (1997).6 We re-

    strict our attention to non-nancial companies only and require that each

    rm have complete managerial and external ownership data for 1995, which

    leaves 802 industrial companies in our sample. Data on capital expenditures,

    total assets employed, after tax prots, depreciation, leverage, equity market

    values and research and development costs are collected from Datastream.

    We estimate Tobin's Q ratio (our proxy for corporate value) using the

    formula below:

    Q =MVEQ + PREF+ DEBT

    BVASSETS(1)

    Where

    MVEQ= the year-end market value of the rm's common stock;

    PREF = the year-end book value of the rm's preference shares (pre-

    ferred stock);

    DEBT = the year-end book value of the rm's total debt; and

    BVASSETS= the total assets employed by the rm, which is measured

    as total assets minus current liabilities.

    Our measure is consistent with the modied version of the formula as

    5Recently listed, merged or acquired rms are not included.6It should be noted that our data includes only the equity stakes of the company's

    directors, whereas McConnell and Servaes (1990) ownership data also includes the hold-ings of company ocers. UK companies are not required to disclose the stakes of suchindividuals.

    17

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    18/42

    used by Chung and Pruitt (1994) who nd that 96.6% of the variability in the

    popular Lindenberg and Ross (1981) algorithm of Tobin's Q is explained by

    their approximation. Our method also avoids the data availability problems

    which arise from using the more rigorous algorithms proposed by Lindenberg

    and Ross (1981) and Lewellen and Badrinath (1997) as both require many

    years data in estimating replacement costs of assets.

    In addition, nancial reporting dierences between the UK and the US

    make Tobin's Q a problematic measure to apply to UK data. Firms in the

    UK have had far more freedom in revaluing their companies' xed assets than

    those in the US and implicit in the more complex Lewellen and Badrinath

    (1997) and Lindenberg and Ross (1981) algorithms is an assumption that

    no revaluations have occurred. Updating previously revalued assets would

    lead to an overestimation of the value of a rm's assets and as such would

    understate the value of Tobin's Q. Furthermore, only including rms that

    report separate pure historical cost accounts would introduce a bias in favour

    of larger rms who would have an incentive to do so for the purpose of

    international exchange listing requirements.

    We use book value of preferred stock and long-term debt, rather than the

    market values proposed by Lindenberg and Ross (1981) and Lewellen and

    Badrinath (1997). In the UK there is a far less active market for the trading

    of corporate debt than that which exists in the US, and as such it is more

    dicult to obtain market values, even through using the relatively simple

    bond rating tables as suggested by these previous studies. Since preference

    shares make up such a minute proportion of traded capital in the UK it is

    unlikely to be necessary to update this for market values. In a nal strati-

    18

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    19/42

    cation of our sample, we mitigate the problem of potential outliers and trim

    twenty-ve rms with the largest and smallest Tobin's Q measure, leaving a

    nal sample of 752 rms.7

    Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for our sample data. The mean

    managerial ownership stake of all board members is 13.02%, which is similar

    to comparable US studies, but slightly lower than Faccio and Lasfer (1999)

    who report mean ownership of 16.7%.

    Tobin's Q is slightly higher than that reported for related US work with

    a mean value of 1.96. The standard deviation of Tobin's Q is 1.21 and is also

    greater than other studies. However, it is substantially less than the mean

    of 2.47 reported by Doukas, McKnight and Pantzalis (2002) and is relatively

    similar to the mean value of 1.86 Short and Keasey (1999) report for their

    market valuation ratio.8 The most likely explanation for this dierence is

    the greater heterogeneity of rms in our sample. UK rms in general also

    tend to be smaller than their US counterparts which would also explain the

    higher average Tobin's Q in our analysis.

    The mean blockholder ownership is 37.34% and is on a par with that

    reported for US rms by McConnell and Servaes (1990) (32.4%) and 34.57%

    reported by Faccio and Lasfer (1999) for UK rms. The average capital ex-

    penditure by rms in the sample is approximately $21 million and the cap-

    ital expenditure to total assets employed ratio is approximately 0.1, which

    7This is a larger sample than that used by Morck et al. (1988) - 371 rms, Cho (1998)- 326 rms and Himmelberg et. al (1999) - maximum 427 rms in any one year.

    8Measured as the market value of equity divided by the book value of equity, minus

    any intangibles. It should also be noted that Doukas et al. (2002) measure Q between1998 and 2000 which was the height of the technological boom on the UK stock market.Faccio and Lasfer (1999) fail to report summary statistics for this variable.

    19

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    20/42

    is again similar to that reported by Cho (1998) for US companies. Debt

    to Asset ratios average 0.14 and is lower than the UK average leverage ra-

    tio for non-nancial rms. The full range of rm sizes are included in the

    sample with the smallest company having an equity market capitalization

    of$680,000 and the largest company's equity valued at approximately $26

    billion. The mean company in the sample has a market capitalization of

    $335 million, which is considerably smaller than the average rm traded on

    NYSE, but is the equivalent of a FTSE 100 company in the UK.

    Table 2 provides the distribution of sample statistics grouped by manager-

    ial ownership. A very large proportion of the sample (62%) have managerial

    ownership levels less than or equal to 10%. However, a large fraction of

    companies (11%) also in the sample had boards which owned at least forty

    percent of all outstanding equity. As would be expected, outside blockholder

    ownership decreases with managerial ownership. At ownership levels of 30%,

    blockholder ownership is slightly less at 24%. It is probable that external

    discipline, as provided by blockholders, would still be strong at these lev-

    els of managerial holdings, particularly where informal coalitions amongst

    blockholders are more prominent [Short and Keasey (1999)]. At higher levels

    of managerial holdings, blockholder ownership decreases sharply leading to

    a collapse in the power of blockholders. For example, between 50% and 60%

    managerial holdings, blockholder ownership falls by approximately half to

    12.4% of the company's outstanding equity. Managerial ownership is a de-

    creasing function of company size indicating that a high level of managerial

    ownership is more prevalent in smaller size companies. Although rm sizes

    in the UK are considerably smaller than US rms, the ratios in table 2 are

    20

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    21/42

    similar to summary statistics provided in Morck et al. (1988), McConnell

    and Servaes (1990), Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al. (1999).

    Table 2 also illustrates the non-linear relationship between Tobin's Q and

    managerial holdings. Visual inspection points to two maximum points in

    the region of 10% to 20% and 50% to 60% respectively. The convergence of

    interests eect at very high levels of managerial ownership is not apparent at

    this stage because of the large managerial ownership grouping for holdings

    above 70%. However, the statistics for all other groupings are consistent with

    our theoretical motivation.

    5.2 Estimation of ownership breakpoints

    In order to model the Tobin's Q - managerial ownership (IO) function as

    having two maximum and two minimum turning points, we specify a quintic

    function.

    Q = 0 + 1IO + 2IO2 + 3IO

    3 + 4IO4 + 5IO

    5 + " (2)

    For the nonlinear relationship discussed in section 4 to be valid, the co-

    ecients in [2] must have the following signs: 0 > 0; 1 > 0; 2 < 0; 3 >

    0;4 < 0; 5 > 0: The estimated values of the coecients in [2] are given in

    table 3. The intercept coecient, which is an estimate of Tobin's Q in rms

    with no managerial holdings, is 1.85. Each slope coecient is of the correct

    sign and statistically signicant at the 5% level. Although the adjusted R2

    is low, it is similar to that found in comparable US studies. The use of this

    model as a basis to estimate managerial ownership breakpoints leads to four

    21

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    22/42

    critical values: 7.01%, 26.0%, 51.4%, 75.7% and is illustrated in gure 1.

    To establish the robustness of our regression model, the spline approach as

    applied by Morck et al. (1988), Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al. (1999) to

    estimate managerial breakpoints was carried out using our generated break-

    points. Table 4 presents the coecients resulting from the piecewise linear

    regression. Similar to table 3, each coecient has the expected sign and all

    but one variable is statistically signicant at the 5% level. The only variable

    that is not signicant, IOover76%, has the correct sign. The probable cause

    for the lack of signicance is the small number of rms in this managerial

    ownership grouping.

    An examination of these results suggests that Tobin's Q increases in rms

    for managerial ownership levels up to 7% and then declines to ownership

    levels of 26%. This is almost exactly the same as the breakpoints in Morck

    et al. (1988) and Himmelberg et al. (1999) (5% and 25% respectively) and

    is comparable to Cho (1998) who use breakpoints of 7% and 38%. However,

    it diers from the UK studies of Short and Keasey (1999) and Faccio and

    Lasfer (1999) who each report two turning points of 12.99% and 41.99% and

    19.68% and 54.12% respectively. Earlier studies limited the turning points

    to two but in our extension it is clear that there are another two turning

    points at much higher levels of managerial ownership. It also appears that

    market discipline has an inuence on managerial objectives up to the point

    where the board takes complete control (51%). Tobin's Q then decreases

    until ownership levels reach 76% after which Q increases.

    Denis and Sarin (1999) argue that cross-sectional studies may be sub-

    ject to bias, whereby they fail to account for events with potentially large

    22

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    23/42

    valuation consequences.9 As a further test of robustness, we carried out the

    quintic analysis for Managerial ownership and Tobin's Q for the same sample

    of available rms in 1997.10 Again, each coecient was signicant with the

    correct signs and the turning points from the estimated model were relatively

    stable at 7.9%, 26.5%, 55.2% and 86.2%.

    5.3 Endogenity of managerial equity ownership, in-

    vestment and corporate value

    To analyse for the eects of endogeneity in the managerial ownership, invest-ment and corporate value relationship we follow Cho (1998) and carry out

    a simultaneous equations analysis using two stage least squares. Cho (1998)

    and Himmelberg et al. (1999) showed that once endogeneity was controlled

    for, the perceived impact of managerial ownership on corporate value dis-

    appeared. Moreover, corporate value was found to positively aect levels of

    managerial ownership.

    It is possible that if the model specication employed by these studies iswrong, what appears to be a lack of statistical signicance in the endoge-

    nous variables in the simultaneous equations analysis may actually be due

    to errors in variables arising from the intermediate regressions. We re-run

    the two-stage least squares analysis of Cho (1998) using our more complex

    specication.11 The control variables in our regression are the same as in

    9Examples of such events may include receiving a takeover bid, top managementturnover, etc.

    10

    Some rms fell out of the sample because of mergers, delisting and being taken over.11Cho (1998) also attempts to control for specication error by re-estimating his si-multaneous regression analysis using managerial ownership as a linear variable and againnds no relationship between managerial ownership and corporate value. However, if in-

    23

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    24/42

    Cho (1998). Namely, managerial ownership, investment and corporate value

    are dened to be endogenously determined by each other as well as some

    additional relevant exogenous variables. That is:

    InsiderOwnership = f(market value of rm's common equity, corporate

    value, investment, volatility of earnings, liquidity, industry)

    CorporateValue = g(insider ownership, investment, nancial leverage,

    asset size, industry, block ownership, largest stakeholder)

    Investment = h(insider ownership, corporate value, volatility of earnings,

    liquidity, industry)

    In addition to the variables used by Cho (1998), we include blockholder

    ownership and largest stakeholder in the corporate value regressions to reect

    the potential impact of blockholder discipline in the UK and the role of a

    founding or dominant individual on corporate value. All accounting and

    market variables are taken at the nancial year-end from Datastream.

    In table 5 we report results from the simultaneous equations analysis.

    Taking the managerial ownership regression rst, all variables with the ex-

    ception of investment have coecients with the expected sign. managerial

    ownership is negatively related to the market value of equity, which reects

    the fact that managerial wealth constraints and risk-aversion will prevent

    them from holding substantial stakes in large rms. Firm level liquidity is

    shown to be positively related to managerial ownership, which is a stronger

    result than Cho (1998) who reported no signicance for this variable. Impor-

    tantly, Tobin's Q is found to be signicant and positively related to the level

    of managerial ownership. This is consistent with Cho (1998) but is opposed

    deed there is a non-linear relationship between ownership and corporate value, such anapproach would fail to capture this

    24

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    25/42

    to Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) who nd the opposite eect. This result

    suggests that managers tend to hold larger stakes in rms that are successful

    or have higher corporate value. This may also be indicative of successful

    managers beneting from equity related compensation policies.

    The investment variable, which has a negative impact on managerial own-

    ership is surprising as theory predicts that rm level investment will be pos-

    itively related to managerial ownership. Himmelberg et al. (1999) contend

    that rms with high investment spending will have high managerial owner-

    ship to alleviate the monitoring problem caused by discretionary managerial

    spending. However, Jensen (1986) argued that rms may over-invest as a

    result of an earnings retention conict, rather than under-invest as Jensen

    and Meckling's (1976) moral hazard theory would predict. When a rm is

    in this situation, managers may be able to maximise their size-related com-

    pensation, but are aware that this may ultimately reduce the value of their

    shareholdings. Although tentative, this could in part explain the negative

    relation between investment and ownership. Cho (1998) also nds a negative

    (but insignicant) coecient on the investment variable using both capital

    and research and development expenditures. In addition, further analysis

    by Cho (1998) provided evidence of investment insignicantly decreasing in

    general with managerial ownership.

    The estimated coecients from the corporate value regression are given

    in the second column of table 5. Corporate value is shown to be positively

    related to investment and leverage. Whilst the investment coecient is as

    expected, the sign of the leverage variable requires more discussion. Morck

    et al. (1988) found that leverage had a negative but insignicant impact on

    25

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    26/42

    corporate value and attributed this to the possibility of managers in highly

    levered rms holding a higher than average level ownership. However con-

    sistent with our results, McConnell and Servaes (1990) reported a positive

    signicant coecient for leverage. Leverage can have various eects on rm

    value. The notion that high debt levels lead to greater corporate value has

    been argued by Modigliani and Miller (1963) with respect to valuable tax

    shields, Ross (1977) and Myers (1977) with respect to a signalling hypothe-

    sis and Jensen's (1986) free cash ow hypothesis. Ultimately, leverage is one

    way of imposing external discipline on management and if it is eective, will

    lead to increased corporate value.

    We view the most important result from the corporate value regression

    as being the signicance of the managerial ownership variables. Our results

    indicate that although managerial ownership levels are determined by corpo-

    rate value, corporate value itself is determined in part by managerial owner-

    ship. This nding is at odds with Cho (1998) and Himmelberg et al. (1999)

    but consistent with the classical view of Jensen and Meckling (1976) and

    empirical work by Morck et al. (1988) and McConnell and Servaes (1990).

    Interestingly, blockholder ownership is shown to negatively impact To-

    bin's Q. This result is consistent with Faccio and Lasfer (1999, 2000). They

    nd that block ownership negatively impacts on corporate value and that

    UK occupational pension funds are associated with poor performance in the

    companies they invest in. McConnell and Servaes (1990) suggest that this

    could be due to a conict of interests, which results from blockholders be-

    ing forced into aligning themselves with managers so as not to jeopardize

    their other dealings with the rm. Alternatively, the negative coecient

    26

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    27/42

    may be explained by the strategic alignment hypothesis, which argues that

    blockholders and managers nd it mutually benecial to cooperate with each

    other, undertaking activity not necessarily value-maximising in nature. Fi-

    nally, such ndings may be consistent with the arguments of Burkart, Gromb

    and Panunzi (1997) in that too much block ownership will overly constrain

    management and reduce their ability to take value maximising investment

    decisions.

    The investment regression coecients presented in column three of table

    5 show a signicant positive eect of corporate value on investment and a

    negative eect of prot volatility on investment. The nding that corporate

    value has a positive eect on investment is consistent with the arguments of

    Cho (1998) that highly valued rms will have large investment opportunities.

    Also, rms with variable earnings will be reluctant to invest if future income

    is uncertain. Managerial ownership is found to have no impact on rm level

    investment. However, this may reect optimality in that investment policy

    may be one way in which managers aect value, but not the only means.

    Ultimately we view our ndings of a causal relation between ownership and

    rm value as being of greater signicance than the lack of a relation between

    ownership and investment. These results are consistent with Cho (1998) but

    slightly stronger, in that volatility of earnings is signicant in our regressions

    but insignicant in Cho (1998).

    27

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    28/42

    6 Conclusions

    Debate as to the relationship between corporate value and managerial own-ership in the US is still unresolved. Studies such as Morck et al. (1988), Mc-

    Connell and Servaes (1990), and Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) document

    a non-linear relation between these two variables. More recent work by Cho

    (1998), Himmelberg et al. (1999), and Demsetz and Villalonga (2001) show

    that when controlling for endogeneity, managerial ownership is determined

    by corporate value but not vice-versa.

    We argue that even accepting corporate value and managerial ownershipto be endogenously related to each other, misspecication of the managerial

    holding-corporate value relationship may lead to spurious conclusions con-

    cerning the direction of causality. Applying a quintic structure, we present

    results which suggest that the correct form of this relationship is a double

    humped curve. This is in contrast to other studies that have assumed a cubic

    or quadratic specication and by construction only one hump.

    The second hump or local maximum is attributed to a collapse in externalmarket discipline at or around the point where managers take overall control

    of their rm. At this point - which is around 50% ownership, the management

    is not suciently akin to owners but has sucient power to disregard any

    form of external monitoring or discipline. This has a detrimental eect on

    corporate value for a short window of managerial holdings. At high levels

    of managerial ownership, managers eectively become owners of their rm

    leading to a convergence of interests with other outside shareholders.Utilizing the quintic specication for managerial ownership, we show that

    even when controlling for endogeneity, not only is corporate value a deter-

    28

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    29/42

    minant of managerial ownership but managerial ownership is also a determi-

    nant of corporate value. This nding is consistent with the classical work of

    Jensen and Meckling (1976) as well as the early empirical work of Morck et al.

    (1988) and McConnell and Servaes (1990) who do not control for endogeneity

    in their analysis of corporate value and managerial ownership.

    We believe our analysis to have several important contributions to the lit-

    erature on corporate value. First, our quintic specication extends previous

    work in this area and successfully captures the complex nonlinear relationship

    between corporate value and managerial ownership. Second, by analysing

    a completely dierent market which is similar in structure to the United

    States, we strengthen the power and insights gained from earlier compara-

    ble US studies. Third, we provide evidence that corporate value, rm level

    investment and managerial holdings are interdependent on each other. This

    has implications for the debate on the eectiveness of compensation policies

    involving stock options for top managers. Moreover, our ndings suggest

    that some levels of managerial ownership may not be benecial to outside

    shareholders even when these levels are high. At the very least, this paper

    has served to add to the debate concerning the importance of managerial

    ownership on corporate value by providing evidence that even controlling for

    endogenous eects, managerial ownership and stock compensation schemes

    do have a signicant inuence on corporate value.

    Our research has provided an initial step towards a more accurate char-

    acterisation of the corporate value-managerial ownership relationship. While

    we do not posit that our specication can be applied to every given data set,

    we argue that previous research may be misspecied where it has failed to

    29

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    30/42

    fully explore alternative specications of the managerial ownership { corpo-

    rate value relationship.

    Future work in this area may focus on other structural forms, which more

    eectively reect the interdependence of managerial ownership and corporate

    prospects. The nonlinear endogenous impact of blockholders on corporate

    value and managerial ownership would also provide interesting insights on

    the external discipline that is faced by rm managers and the role this has

    on corporate value.

    30

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    31/42

    7 References

    1. Burkart, M.; Gromb, D.; and Panunzi, F. 1997. Large shareholders,monitoring, and the value of the rm. Quarterly Journal of Economics

    112, no. 3:693-728.

    2. Cho, M.H. 1998. Ownership structure, investment, and the corporate

    value: an empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 47:103-

    121.

    3. Chung, K.H., and Pruitt S.W. 1994. A simple approximation of tobin'sq. Financial Management 23: 70-74.

    4. Dahya, J.; McConnell, J.J.; and Travlos, N.G. 2002. The Cadbury com-

    mittee, corporate performance and top management turnover. Journal

    of Finance 57, no. 1:461-483.

    5. Demsetz, H., and Lehn, K. 1985. The structure of corporate ownership:

    causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy 93:1155-1177.

    6. Demsetz, H., and Villalonga, B. 2001. Ownership structure and corpo-

    rate performance. Journal of Corporate Finance 7, no. 3:209-233.

    7. Denis, D.J., Denis, D.K.; and Sarin, A. 1997. Ownership structure

    and top executive turnover. Journal of Financial Economics. 45, no.

    2:193-221

    8. Denis, D.J., and Sarin. A. 1999. Ownership and board structures inpublicly traded corporations. Journal of Financial Economics. 52, no.

    2.:187-223

    31

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    32/42

    9. Doukas, J.A., McKnight, P.J.; and Pantzalis, C. 2002. Security analy-

    sis, agency costs and UK rm characteristics. Working Paper.

    10. Faccio, M., and Lasfer, M.A. 1999. Managerial ownership, board struc-

    ture and rm value: the UK evidence. Working Paper.

    11. Faccio, M., and Lasfer, M.A. 2000. Do occupational pension funds

    monitor rms in which they hold large stakes? Journal of Corporate

    Finance 6, no. 1:71-110.

    12. Fama, E.F. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the rm. Journal

    of Political Economy 88, no. 2:288-307.

    13. Fama, E.F., and Jensen, M.C. 1983. Separation of ownership and con-

    trol. Journal of Law and Economics 88 no. 2:301-325.

    14. Franks, J., and Mayer, C. 1996. Hostile takeovers and the correction

    of management failure. Journal of Financial Economics 40:163-181.

    15. Franks, J., and Mayer, C. 2000. Ownership and control in German

    corporations. Working Paper.

    16. Franks, J., Mayer, C.; and Renneboog, L. 2001. Who disciplines man-

    agement in poorly performing companies? Journal of Financial Inter-

    mediation 10, no's. 3/4:209-248.

    17. Hart, O.D. 1983. The market mechanism as an incentive scheme. Bell

    Journal of Economics 14:366-382.

    32

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    33/42

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    34/42

    27. Martin, K.J., and McConnell, J.J. 1991. Corporate performance, cor-

    porate takeovers, and management turnover. Journal of Finance 46,

    no. 2:671-687.

    28. McConnell, J.J., and Servaes, H. 1990. Additional evidence on eq-

    uity ownership and corporate value. Journal of Financial Economics

    27:595-612.

    29. Modigliani, F., and Miller, M.H. 1963. Corporate income taxes and the

    cost of capital: a correction. American Economic Review 53:433-443.

    30. Morck, R.; Shleifer, A.; and Vishny, R.W. 1988. Management owner-

    ship and market valuation: an empirical analysis. Journal of Financial

    Economics 20, no.1-2:293-315.

    31. Myers, S.C. 1977. Determinants of Corporate Borrowing. Journal of

    Financial Economics 5:147-175.

    32. Roe, M.J. 1990. Political and legal restraints on ownership and control

    of public companies. Journal of Financial Economics 27:7-42.

    33. Ross, S.A. 1977. The determination of nancial structure: the incentive-

    signalling approach. Bell Journal of Economics 8:23-40.

    34. Short, H. and Keasey, K. 1999. Managerial ownership and the perfor-

    mance of rms: evidence from the UK. Journal of Corporate Finance

    5:79-101.

    35. Stulz, R.E. 1988. \Managerial control of voting rights: nancing poli-

    cies and the market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Eco-

    34

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    35/42

    nomics 20, no. 1:25-54.

    36. Weisbach, M.S. 1988. Outside directors and CEO turnover. Journal ofFinancial Economics 20, no. 1-2:431-460.

    37. Zhou, X. 2001. Understanding the determinants of managerial own-

    ership and the link between ownership and performance: a comment.

    Journal of Financial Economics 62, no. 3:559-571.

    35

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    36/42

    8 Tables

    Table 1 - Descriptive Statistics

    Insider ownership data measures the total level of holdings held by company managementthat are greater than 0.5% of a company's equity. Blockholder data measures the totallevel of holdings by outside blockholders that are greater than 3% of a company's eq-uity. Largest stakeholder is the largest single outside blockholder that holds at least 3%of company's outstanding equity. Capital expenditure (thousands), total assets employed(thousands), after tax prots, depreciation, leverage, equity market values (millions) andresearch and development costs (thousands)are collected from Datastream. Tobin's Q ismeasured as the ratio of the market value of equity and book values of debt and preferredequity to the book value of assets in the rm minus current liabilities. Shareholdings datais taken from London Stock Exchange Handbook for 1996 and 1997. All data are forindustrial companies quoted on London Stock Exchange in 1995.

    Variable Mean Std. Dev. Minimum MaximumInsider Holdings 13.02% 18.06% 0.00% 79.90%Blockholder Holdings 37.34% 23.57% 0.00% 100.00%Largest Stakeholder 18.82% 21.64% 0.00% 100.00%Capital Expenditures 21,221 75,317 7 1,024,200Total Assets Employed 255,642 1,583,274 268 37,774,000After Tax Prots less de-preciation

    0.1425 0.4763 -10.977 3.4207

    Debt/Assets Employed 0.1411 0.2252 0.0000 4.8358Market Value of Equity 335 1399 0.68 26,224Research and Develop-ment

    2,918 44,108 0 1,198,988

    Tobin's Q 1.9647 1.2092 0.4502 7.0997

    36

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    37/42

    Table 2 - Breakdown of Sample by Insider Ownership

    Insider ownership data measures the total level of holdings held by company management

    that are greater than 0.5% of a company's equity. Blockholder data measures the totallevel of holdings by outside blockholders that are greater than 3% of a company's eq-uity. Largest stakeholder is the largest single outside blockholder that holds at least 3%of company's outstanding equity. Capital expenditure (thousands), total assets employed(thousands), after tax prots, depreciation, leverage, equity market values (millions) andresearch and development costs (thousands) are collected from Datastream. Tobin's Q ismeasured as the ratio of the market value of equity and book values of debt and preferredequity to the book value of assets in the rm minus current liabilities. Shareholdings datais taken from London Stock Exchange Handbook for 1996 and 1997. All data are forindustrial companies quoted on London Stock Exchange in 1995.

    Insider Ownership

    Level

    Number

    ofFirms

    Block-

    holderOwn-ership%

    Tobin's

    Q

    Total

    AssetsEm-ployed

    Capital

    Ex-pendi-tures/AssetsEm-ployed

    Liquidity

    0 I/O 10% 464 43.3 1.952 393,861 0.106 0.13010 I/O 20% 87 34.5 2.033 44,093 0.161 0.12920 I/O 30% 75 34.4 1.736 26,186 0.124 0.15730 I/O 40% 41 24.0 2.109 34,322 0.117 0.19440 I/O 50% 34 22.7 2.113 35,864 0.114 0.19450 I/O 60% 26 13.0 2.257 28,190 0.100 0.17760 I/O 70% 21 12.7 1.933 14,234 0.099 0.169

    70 I/O 100% 4 5.8 1.808 10,127 0.114 0.239

    37

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    38/42

    Table 3 - Regression Results for Tobin's Q on Insider Ownership

    The following equation was estimated using data for 752 rms listed on London Stock

    Exchange during 1995.

    Q = 0 + 1IO + 2IO2 + 3IO

    3 + 4IO4 + 5IO

    5 + "

    where Q is Tobin's Q and IO is insider ownership. Insider ownership data is taken fromLondon Stock Exchange Yearbook and Tobin's Q is calculated from Datastream.

    Variable Intercept IO IO2 IO3 IO4 IO5

    Coecient 1.85 0.12 -0.013 4.63 x 104 -6.73 x 106 3.36 x 108

    t-statistic 28.14 3.23 -3.08 2.82 -2.53 2.24Adj:R2 0:017 F 2:651

    38

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    39/42

    Table 4 - Regression Results for Tobin's Q on Insider Ownership

    The following equation was estimated using data for 752 rms listed on London Stock

    Exchange during 1995.

    Q = 0 + 1IOupto7% + 2IO7%to26% + 3IO26%to51% + 4IO51%to76% + 5IOover76% + "

    where Q is Tobin's Q andIOupto7% =insider ownership if insider ownership < 7%, =7% if insider ownership >

    7%.IO7%to26% = 0 if insider ownership < 7%, = insider ownership minus 7% if 7% 26%.IO26%to51% = 0 if insider ownership < 26%, = insider ownership minus 26% if 26% 51%.IO51%to76% = 0 if insider ownership < 51%, = insider ownership minus 51% if 51% 26%.

    IOover76% = 0 if insider ownership < 76%, = insider ownership minus 76% if insiderownership > 76%.Insider ownership data is taken from London Stock Exchange Yearbook and Tobin's

    Q is calculated from Datastream.

    Variable Intercept IOupto7% IO7%to26% IO26%to51% IO51%to76% IOover76%Coecient 1.854 0.056 -0.020 0.0187 -0.053 0.624t-statistic 28.38 2.93 -2.62 2.57 -1.99 1.12Adj:R2 0.012 F 2.769

    39

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    40/42

    Table 5 - Simultaneous Equations Analysis of Insider Ownership,Corporate Value and Investment

    Results from a simultaneous equations analysis of insider ownership, corporate value andinvestment for 752 rms, using the two stage least squares method to estimate the followingequations:

    InsiderOwnership = f(market value of rm's common equity, corporate value, in-vestment, volatility of earnings, liquidity, industry)

    CorporateV alue = g(insider ownership, investment, nancial leverage, asset size, in-dustry, block ownership, largest stakeholder)

    Investment = h(insider ownership, corporate value, volatility of earnings, liquidity,industry)

    In the above equation, Insider ownership measures the total level of holdings held bycompany management that are greater than 0.5% of a company's equity. Blockholderdata measures the total level of holdings by outside blockholders that are greater than3% of a company's equity. Largest stakeholder is the largest single outside blockholder

    that holds at least 3% of company's outstanding equity. Investment is dened as capitalexpenditure/total assets employed, leverage is the ratio of total debt to total assets andliquidity is measured as cash ow divided by total assets. Capital expenditure, total assetsemployed, after tax prots, depreciation, leverage, equity market values and prot volatili-ties are collected from Datastream. Tobin's Q is measured as the ratio of the market valueof equity and book values of debt and preferred equity to the book value of assets in therm minus current liabilities. Shareholdings data is taken from London Stock ExchangeHandbook for 1996 and 1997. All data are for industrial companies quoted on LondonStock Exchange in 1995. t-statistics are in parenthesis.

    40

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    41/42

    Table 5(cont.) - Simultaneous Equations Analysis of Insider Own-ership, Corporate Value and Investment

    Variable Insider Ownership Corporate Value InvestmentMVEQ -1.8 x 105

    (-3.74)Tobin's Q 0.127

    (4.63)0.073(2.35)

    Volatility -1.0 x 106

    (-0.74)3.89x106

    (-2.86)Liquidity 0.035

    (2.24)0.013(1.01)

    Investment -1.314(-2.67)

    5.136(2.23)

    Leverage 1.088

    (4.36)Asset Size 3.33x108

    (1.17)Largest Stake -0.020

    (-0.06)Blockholder -0.837

    (-2.60)IO 1.588

    (3.07)-0.035(-0.46)

    IO2 -0.395(-2.22)

    0.018(0.72)

    IO3 0.037(1.64)

    -0.003(-0.92)

    IO4

    -0.001(-1.14)

    1.72x104

    (1.03)IO5 1.9x105

    (0.76)-3.12x107

    (-1.07)Industrydummy

    Yes Yes Yes

    Adj. R2 0.045 0.033 0.009F 8.014 3.497 2.497

    41

  • 8/2/2019 10.1.1.202.5202

    42/42

    Figure 1

    Estimated relationship between Tobins Q and Insider Ownership

    Tobins Q was modelled as a quintic function of insider ownership using ordinary least

    squares regression. The estimated regression line is:5846342

    1036.31073.61063.4013.012.085.1 IOxIOxIOxIOIOQ

    +++=

    Estimated Relationship between Tobin's Q and Insider

    Ownership

    1.20

    1.40

    1.60

    1.80

    2.00

    2.20

    2.40

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

    Insider Ownership

    Tobin'sQ