+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 14 Consumer Surplus

14 Consumer Surplus

Date post: 30-May-2018
Category:
Upload: leep123
View: 223 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 44

Transcript
  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    1/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 1

    Lecture notes for Intermediate Microeconomics

    Part 1: Consumer Theory

    Contents

    1. Introduction: Microeconomics and the History of Economics

    2. The economic agent: Assumptions of the model2.1 Preferences and Axioms of rational choice

    2.2 Utility functions

    2.3 The Marginal rate of Substitution

    3. Utility maximization: Two methods

    3.1 Substitution method*

    3.2 Lagrangian multiplier method

    3.1 Substituting the constraint into the objective function

    3.3 Marshallian Demand functions

    3.4. Mathematical issues*

    3.5 The meaning of the multiplier*

    4. Comparative statics

    4.1 Change of income

    4.2 Change of prices

    4.3 Indirect Utility Function

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 2

    5. Expenditure minimization and Hicksian demand

    5.1 Derivation of the minimum expenditure function

    5.2 Hicksian/Compensated Demand Curve

    6. Income and Substitution effects

    6.1 Graphical analysis

    6.2 The Slutsky decomposition*6.3 Computing IE and SE for a discrete price change

    7. Labor supply decision of the consumer

    7.1 Introduction: Assumptions of the model

    7.2 Optimal labor supply decision

    7.3 Comparative Statics (for the CD-case)

    7.3.1 Change in non-labor income

    7.3.2 Change of Labor supply when wage rate changes

    7.4 Income and Substitution effects

    7. 4 Appendix: analytical derivation of the Slutsky equation*

    8. Labor supply and taxes

    8.1 A (linear) Income tax

    8.2 Per capita tax

    8.3 Taxes and Efficiency

    Chapters marked with a * do not belong to the core topics and we will deal with them

    only if time permits.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    2/44

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    3/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 5

    2. The economic agent as a consumer: Assumptions of the

    model

    We will start with neoclassical Consumer Theory, which almost

    coincides with the marginalist idea of economics.

    In modern economics, especially microeconomics, theory begins

    with a set of behavioral assumptions, which are formalized in a

    mathematical way. This requires reducing the real world to amodel, in which only (some of) the relevant economic aspects of

    behavior are included. The gain is the possibility of building a

    formal framework, from which rigorous conclusions can be drawn.

    2.1 Preferences and Axioms of rational choice

    Indifference Curves and Preferences

    In 1101 we modeled a consumer, or his/her taste for goods by so-

    called indifference curves (see below for a definition). The

    indifference curves represent what a consumer is (for economic

    theory). Finding the highest indifference curve subject to a budget

    constraint then is a way of describing what a consumerdoes.

    As we will shortly see, indifference curves are derived from a

    concept that describes the objective of a consumer (maximizing

    happiness/utility) by the use of a so-called utility function. Before

    we define the idea of utility functions and indifference curves, we

    will take a glimpse at a more fundamental (and more general) way

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 6

    of defining a consumer. This concept is based on mathematical set

    theory; however, their meaning is very intuitive.

    Preference orderings:

    Consumption set C:

    Defines the space of all possible consumption goods and their

    combinations for a specific consumer.

    Example 1:

    C={2 apples, 1 DVD, 1 car, 3 weeks of vacation in Florida}

    Example 2:

    C={any goods I can buy in the market, given the amount is greater

    or equal to zero, 24 hours of time per day,}

    Preference relation >

    A relation can be any definition of how two objects are related

    (e.g. the symbol > relates numbers according to their value).

    A preference relation defines how a consumer orders goods or

    combinations of goods in terms of utility/benefit.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    4/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 7

    Example 1:

    1 DVD > 1 apple

    This says that the consumer thinks that 1 DVD is as least as good

    as 1 apple. It implies, that he or she is either indifferent between 1

    DVD and 1 apple or she/he likes 1 DVD more than 1 apple (thats

    why people call this is a weak preference ordering)

    Axioms of rational choice

    To go from the underlying preference orderings to the more

    convenient utility functions (which imply indifference curves, see

    next section), economists make the following assumptions on how

    people choose goods from their consumption sets. Since we are not

    claiming that this behavior can be always observed empirically, we

    call them axioms.

    (Axiom 1) Completeness: The agent is able to compare any two

    bundles, i.e. he or she can always say whether bundle A is better,

    equal or worse than another bundle B.

    Examples: Usually, people know what they like more, or at

    least they know that they are indifferent. However, in some

    situations, it might not be so easy.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 8

    1. Consider another type of ordering (i.e. this is not a

    preference ordering), namely the ordering of cities on the

    planet by the relationship: City A is west of city B.

    Knowing that the earth is a sphere, it is not clear whether

    L.A. is west of NYC or the other way round (although

    common sense would say it is clear, which comes from the

    custom, to draw LA and NYC on a map so that L.A. is inthe west).

    2. A more economic problem would be the example of

    someone looking for a job, but given a couple of job offers,

    which superficially look equally good (say same wage,

    location etc.), but the applicant does not know how the

    working atmosphere in the prospective company will be and

    therefore it might be impossible to say which option is better.

    This is a problem of incomplete information that we will rule

    out in the models we consider in this class (although it is

    important problem that has been analyzed by many

    economists) .

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    5/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 9

    (Axiom 2) Transitivity: If bundle A is better than B and B better

    than C then it must be the case that A is better than C. (remember

    that this corresponds to the fact that indifference curves must not

    cross)

    Example: Consider the ordering (not a preference ordering)

    of the natural numbers: 1,2,3,Here it is obvious, that the ordering (greater or equal) is

    transitive. If 3 1 and 5 3 than 5 1.

    (Axiom 3) Continuity: Given that I can assume that all goods are

    divisible (i.e. we assume it makes sense, to talk for example about

    half of a car, a quarter of an apple etc.), we say preference ordering

    is continuous ,

    if A > B then for A very similar to A, we have A > B.

    REMARK: This last assumption is an important assumption

    but purely technical in its nature, so we will ignore it in this

    course.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 10

    From Preferences to Utility functions

    With the above assumptions one can show (the famous economist

    Gerard Debreu showed this first) that we can represent the above

    defined preference orderings of an agent by a utility function.

    2.2 Utility functions

    The relationship between indifference curves and Utilityfunctions

    In your introductory micro class you have already seen something

    that implied the use of utility functions: the indifference curves.

    Def: An indifference curve (IC) gives all combinations of goods

    for which the consumer is indifferent (given a fixed Utility level,

    i.e. U(x,y)=constant, whereas x and y vary).

    In other words, the indifference curves are the level sets (or level

    curve) of the utility function, i.e. the locus of all combinations of

    goods (x and y) that yield the same utility level (see the following

    graph for an example).

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    6/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 11

    Example of a utility function:

    First define: N= minutes of taking a nap

    T= minutes of watching TV soaps

    Then there might be an agent who orders his or her preferences

    according to the following Utility function:

    U(N,T)=2N+T

    Note, that we just made up a utility function forsome consumer;

    the form of a utility function for another agent (e.g. you) might

    look different. In particular, it depends on the underlying

    preference ordering.

    Now, take a look at the above mentioned utility function and

    observe the following properties:

    - The more of either N or T the agent consumes the higher is

    the level of utility (i.e. utility is increasing in both goods).

    - Consuming one unit of N gives me twice as much utility than

    consuming one unit of T. In other words, to achieve the same

    level of utility or happiness, the agent needs less N (half)

    than T (with this information try to draw an indifference

    curve of this agent).

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 12

    - To achieve the same level of utility it does not matter

    whether the agent consumes both goods, or only one of them

    (besides the problem that consuming T is relatively more

    costly, but this is another issue, namely that of the time

    budget constraint). That means, the agent can (almost

    perfectly) substitute one good for the other to get the same

    level of utility.

    Ordinality of Utility functions

    Example: Given the number of minutes sleeping is constant (e.g. =

    10), the utility of watching 1 minute TV is:

    U=2*10+1=21

    And of watching 5 min TV:

    U=2*10+5=25

    What does the difference in utility (25-21=4) tell us? - Nothing

    besides the fact, that the consumer likes watching 5 minutes more

    than just watching 1 minute. It does not say, however, by how

    much he or she prefers 5 to 1 minute of T, the difference 4 has no

    meaning except for its sign (i.e. being bigger or less than zero).

    Thats why we call the utility functions we use ordinal. If the

    difference of utility would carry information about how much

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    7/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 13

    better I like some bundle of goods compared to some other bundle,

    the utility function would be called cardinal.

    Non-Uniqueness of Utility functions

    Since Utility functions just represent the orderof preferences (i.e.

    they are ordinal as explained above), every preference ordering can

    be represented by several (indeed infinitely many) utility functions.

    Example:

    xyyxyxU

    U

    ==

    +5.05.0

    2

    ),(

    ,:

    Now, the utility function xyyxUyxG == 2)],([),( represents the same

    preference ordering. In fact, all monotone transformations of a

    utility function preserve the preference ordering.

    Def.: A monotone transformation of a function U(x,y) is a function

    f(U) that is (strictly) increasing.

    Examples:

    1. f(U) = U

    2

    2. f(U) = U

    3. f(U) = logU

    4. f(U)=2U+1

    where U is always the original Utility function.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 14

    A special Utility function: The Cobb-Douglas Utility function:

    Def.(Cobb-Douglas Utility function): = 1),( yxyxU with

    10

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    8/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 15

    Ad 1.: Marginal Utility (MU) is positive:

    05.0

    05.0

    5.05.0

    5.05.0

    >=

    >=

    yxy

    UMU

    yxx

    UMU

    y

    x

    Ad 2.: Marginal Utility is decreasing, i.e. the second derivative is

    negative

    ( )

    ( )05.0)5.0(

    05.0)5.0(

    5.15.0

    2

    2

    5.05.1

    2

    2

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    9/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 17

    dyyUdx

    xUyxdU

    +

    =),(

    Assuming that Utility stays constant, i.e. 0),( =xdU , we have:

    dyy

    Udx

    x

    U

    +

    =0 .

    Now, solving for the expressiondx

    dy , we obtain the formula for

    the MRS:

    y

    U

    x

    U

    dx

    dyMRS

    = .

    Now we have developed the concept of the MRS and we can come

    back to our initial question how the MRS relates to the property of

    preferring average bundles.Consider some representative ICs of a CD utility function (which

    has the property of decreasing MU as shown above). What fact can

    we infer about the MRS? It is always decreasing (the absolute

    value of the slope goes down, as x, which is on the horizontal axis,

    increases). Intuitively speaking, this means, if I have little x and

    many of y, the MRS is relative high, so I am willing to give upmany y for one additional (marginal) unit of x. If on the other

    hand, I have already a lot of x, the MRS is low, and therefore, I

    would be willing to exchange only little y for one more x (or to put

    it differently: I would be willing to exchange a lot of x to receive

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 18

    one more unit of y), given that utility stays the same (i.e. moving

    on the same IC).

    Having understood what is going on in economic terms, we will

    now formally show, how to prove that the MRS is decreasing

    given that MU for both goods is strictly negative (I will use the

    short hand notation xU for xU

    ):

    ( )

    ( )

    ( )

    }}

    }}} }}

    ( ){

    02

    3

    0

    0

    2

    00000

    2

    0

    3

    22

    2

    2

    >>>>0 are constant coefficients)

    2. Linear preferences (perfect substitutes):

    U(x,y)=ax+by

    x

    yIC 1

    IC 2

    IC 3

    x

    y

    IC 1

    IC 2

    IC 3

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    11/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 21

    3. Utility Maximization

    In neoclassical theory, we assume that all agents are maximizing.

    In particular, consumers are maximizing utility subject to a budget

    constraint and firms are maximizing profits given technological

    possibilities (in more advanced macro models, there may be also a

    government, which could be maximizing aggregated utility of all

    agents).Why maximization? Are you doing calculations when you go to

    the grocery store?

    Economics makes an idealization when considering consumers as

    maximizing agents.

    A way to justify this idealization was proposed by Paul Samuelson:

    He introduced the concept of revealed preferences. That is

    economics assumes agents to behave as if they were maximizing.

    If an economist analyses demand data, he or she can check whether

    these data are coherent with maximizing behavior.

    We assume not only the consumer to be maximizing but

    furthermore maximizing only her or his own utility, .i.e. the

    consumer is supposed to be selfish. The consumer in our models

    cares only about himself or herself. However, this needs not to be

    the case in general. In the theory of externalities the possibility of

    some form of altruism is introduced.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 22

    Utility Maximization Problem

    Mathematical Tools: Lagrangian Optimization

    Graphical analysis:

    Quantity of y

    Quantity of x

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    12/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 23

    Solving for the OCB analytically

    Two methods: I. Substituting the constraint into the

    objective function

    II. Lagrangian multiplier method

    3.1 Substituting the constraint into the objective function

    Consider the following example:

    The objective function is:

    5.05.02 ),(,: yxyxUU +=+

    The budget constraint (BC) is: Mypxp yx =+

    Solving the BC for x yields:x

    y

    x p

    yp

    p

    Mx =

    Substituting this into the objective function gives:

    5.0

    5.0

    ),( yp

    yp

    p

    MyxU

    x

    y

    x

    +

    =

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 24

    Now, to find a maximum, set up the FOC:

    0=

    y

    U,

    which is in our example:

    05.05.0 5.05.0

    5.0

    5.0

    =+

    =

    +

    yp

    yppM

    ppy

    pyp

    pM

    y x

    y

    xx

    y

    x

    y

    x

    or

    )1(

    1

    22

    x

    y

    yx

    y

    y

    x

    xx

    y

    p

    pp

    M

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    M

    p

    py

    +

    =

    +

    =

    To find x, substitute the last expression into the expression for x

    (from BC):

    )1()1(

    ))1(

    )1()1(

    y

    xx

    y

    xyx

    x

    y

    xy

    y

    xy

    x

    x

    y

    y

    x

    y

    xx

    y

    x

    p

    pp

    M

    p

    ppp

    pp

    ppM

    p

    pp

    M

    p

    M

    p

    pp

    M

    p

    p

    p

    My

    p

    p

    p

    Mx

    +

    =

    +

    +

    =

    +

    =

    +

    ==

    .

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    13/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 25

    If our calculations are correct, the quantities of x and y , multipliedby their prices should add up to M:

    M

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    M

    p

    p

    M

    p

    p

    M

    p

    pp

    Mp

    p

    pp

    Mpypxp

    y

    x

    x

    y

    y

    x

    x

    y

    x

    y

    y

    x

    x

    y

    y

    y

    y

    xx

    xyx

    =

    ++

    +++

    =

    +

    +

    +

    =

    +

    +

    +

    =+

    )1)(1(

    )1()1(

    )1()1()1()1(

    3.2 Lagrangian multiplier method

    We start with the same example as above:

    The objective function is:

    5.05.02 ),(,: yxyxUU += +

    The budget constraint (BC) is: Mypxp yx =+

    We now define a new function, which incorporates the constraint,

    multiplied by a factor, which is called the Lagrangian multiplier:

    ))((),(),,( ypxpMyxUyxL yx ++=

    or ))((),,( 5.05.0 ypxpMyxyxL yx +++=

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 26

    To find a maximum, we take FOCs of the Lagrangian function:

    0

    0

    0

    =

    =

    =

    L

    y

    L

    x

    L

    0)(

    05.0

    05.0

    ..

    5.0

    5.0

    =+=

    ==

    =

    ==

    =

    ypxpML

    pypy

    U

    y

    L

    pxpx

    U

    x

    L

    ei

    yx

    yy

    xx

    or

    )(

    5.0

    5.0

    5.0

    5.0

    ypxpM

    py

    px

    yx

    y

    x

    +=

    =

    =

    The first two of the last set of equations can be written as:

    y

    x

    y

    x

    p

    p

    p

    p

    x

    y

    y

    x===

    5.0

    5.0

    5.0

    5.0

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    14/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 27

    You are already familiar with the expressionx

    y. It is the MRS of

    an indifference curve at the point (x, y):x

    y

    MU

    MUMRS

    y

    x = .

    To finish, we can find optimal consumption of x and y by using the

    last equation (the one from the FOC) and the BC which is the same

    as the third FOC of the Lagrangian problem. Luckily, we get the

    same result as we obtained by the first method).

    From the BC:

    x

    y

    x p

    yp

    p

    Mx =

    From the FOC:

    xp

    py

    y

    x

    2

    =

    Combining:

    =

    x

    y

    xy

    x

    p

    yp

    p

    M

    p

    py

    2

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 28

    )1(

    *

    x

    y

    yp

    pp

    My

    +=

    Using the relationship between x and y given by the FOC, we can

    solve for x:

    )1()1(

    )1()1(

    * 2

    22

    y

    xx

    y

    xy

    y

    x

    x

    yy

    y

    x

    x

    yy

    y

    x

    y

    x

    p

    pp

    M

    p

    pp

    p

    p

    M

    p

    pp

    p

    pM

    p

    pp

    Mppy

    ppx

    +

    =

    +

    =

    +

    =

    +

    =

    =

    3.3 Marshallian Demand functions

    We call the optimal values for x and y, the demands of the

    consumer. Furthermore, we define the expressions

    ),,( Mppx yx and ),,( Mppy yx to be the demand functions,

    which give the relationship between optimal consumption of a

    good and its price and the income (which is for now a given value,

    a parameter). Sometimes, these demand functions are also called

    Marshallian demand functions. In our example above the demand

    function for x is (similar for y):

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    15/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 29

    )1(

    ),,(

    y

    xx

    yx

    p

    pp

    MMppx

    +=

    Note, that the demands for both goods each depend on both prices

    (in the general case at least).

    3.4. Mathematical issues

    Two additional things have to be checked for our solution to be

    complete:

    Firstwe note, that this result only holds if we have what is called

    an interior solution, i.e. all variables are strictly greater than 0.

    To explain this problem, look at the following graph:

    The maximum is at the lower right corner of the budget set (i.e.

    only x is consumed). In this case, it might be that the MRS, i.e. the

    slope of the IC in the optimum is not equal to the price ratio (i.e.

    the slope of the budget line). Thus, the condition, given by the

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 30

    FOCs as in our example above does not apply although we have amaximum.

    In this course, however, we will not deal with these non-interior

    cases. They can be solved by a method which is called Kuhn-

    Tucker Nonlinear programming. It is a generalization of the

    Lagrange method, where inequalities ( ), are involved.

    Secondly, in every case we have to make sure, whether secondorder conditions are satisfied. FOCs are only necessary but not

    sufficient conditions for a maximum. That is, we need to find out if

    our solution to the FOC is a minimum or a maximum. The

    theoretical way to find out whether the obtained values

    constitute a maximum or not, is to consider the so called bordered

    Hessian matrix to find out whether the function is positive definite

    or negative definite. Pos./neg. def. is a generalization of the

    concept of concavity and convexity respectively to the multi-

    variable case.

    The applied way to insure that the critical value is a maximum is

    to change the value of the variable near the critical point and check

    if it increases or decreases the value of the objective function. In

    this course, I expect you to have an idea about the meaning and

    relevance of this problem, but I am not requiring you to actually

    check whether second order conditions hold or not.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    16/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 31

    Non-convexity of the Preferred SetA more subtle problem might occur, if ICs have weird shapes

    (remember, that in general, we are not assuming that every

    consumer has the same nice behaved preferences, so anything

    could be possible depending on the actual consumer). One

    particular freakiness of ICs is called non-convexity. As I

    mentioned when I introduced the Cobb Douglas function, if the

    preferred set is not strictly convex, several solutions for the OCB,

    given income and prices, are possible.

    y

    x

    IC

    BL

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 32

    3.5 Meaning of the multiplier:Going one step back, we can rewrite our FOCs as:

    =

    =

    ==

    yx

    y

    y

    x

    x

    p

    y

    U

    p

    x

    U

    p

    MU

    p

    MU

    What does this mean? In an optimum all the marginal utilities per

    dollar spent are the same, i.e. I cannot gain additional utility by

    increasing the amount of the value of one good without decreasing

    any other good by the same (marginal) amount.

    The multiplier represents the additional value in utility of

    loosening the budget constraint (remember, is the factor for the

    BC in the Lagrangian problem). Analytically, this can be shown as

    follows:

    Remember the Lagrangian function for a general consumer

    problem: ((),(),,( ypxpMyxUyxL yx ++=

    Now, assume that that we are evaluating L at the optimal

    (maximizing) values for x and y and also at the optimal value for, all denoted by a *:

    *))*((**)*,(*)*,*,(),,( ypxpMyxUyxLMppV yxyx ++=

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    17/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 33

    Take first derivative with respect to M:

    **)*,(*)*,(

    ))(1(*

    *)*,(*)*,(),,(

    FOCby0FOCby0

    +

    +

    =

    +

    +

    +

    +

    =

    ==44444 344444 2144444 344444 21M

    yp

    y

    yxU

    M

    y

    M

    xp

    x

    yxU

    M

    x

    M

    yp

    M

    xp

    y

    yxU

    M

    y

    x

    yxU

    M

    x

    M

    MppV

    yx

    yx

    yx

    Hence: *),,(

    =

    MppV yx

    If income would go up by one unit, the Value of the Lagrangian

    objective function evaluated at the optimum would increase by .

    Sometimes is called theshadow price (of a constraint). Indeed,

    there are economic problems, where you can directly interpret the

    multiplier(s) as price(s).

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 34

    4. Comparative statics:4.1 Change of income

    1. Graphical analysis

    2. Mathematical analysis

    Remember the example from last time. The expression for the

    OCB for the x good is:

    )1(y

    xx

    p

    pp

    Mx

    +

    =

    Taking the first derivative with respect to (w.r.t.) M, we get:

    0

    )1(

    1

    )1(

    >

    +

    =

    +

    =

    y

    xx

    y

    xx

    p

    pp

    p

    pp

    M

    MM

    x

    A similar result is true for the y-good.

    This means, increasing income, the optimal amount for this good is

    higher. We call goods with this property normal goods.If the demand goes down when income increases, we call these

    goods inferior goods. (graphical example). Analytically speaking,

    a good is inferior if the first derivative w.r.t. M of the optimal

    demand is negative (or non-positive).

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    18/44

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    19/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 37

    )1(*

    y

    xx

    p

    pp

    Mx

    +=

    )1(

    *

    x

    yy

    p

    pp

    My

    +

    =

    Substituting the optimal demands into the utility function:

    ),,(

    )1()1(

    ***)*,(

    5.05.0

    5.05.0

    MppV

    p

    pp

    M

    p

    pp

    M

    yxyxU

    yx

    x

    yy

    y

    xx

    +

    +

    +

    =

    +=

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 38

    5. Expenditure minimization and Hicksian demand

    [Graphical Analysis]

    Why is this useful?

    - for analyzing price changes (Slutsky decomposition)

    - empirical work: expenditures are observable, utility is hard to

    determine directly

    (Remark: In mathematical language, the expenditure minimization

    problem is the dual problem to utility maximization. The two

    problems are closely related.).

    The problem of minimizing expenditure looks as follows:

    UyxU

    ts

    ypxpE yx

    =

    +=

    ),(

    ..

    min

    In our example:

    Uyx

    ts

    ypxpE yx

    =+

    +=

    5.05.0

    ..

    min

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    20/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 39

    5.1 Derivation of the minimum expenditure functionThere are two ways of solving the problem for the expenditure

    function. The first way starts from the previous result of the

    Marshallian demand functions and uses the indirect utility

    function. Although more intuitive it requires more work in terms of

    computations. The second approach is just using the Lagrangian

    procedure to solve the above minimization problem.

    First Approach (via demand functions):

    In this approach we use the fact that we know the demand

    functions for the given utility function from the Utility

    maximization problem.

    )1(

    *

    y

    xx

    p

    pp

    Mx

    +

    =

    )1(

    *

    x

    yy

    p

    pp

    My

    +

    =

    In contrast to the utility maximization problem, M is now treated

    as a variable instead of a given parameter. We indicate this writing

    E (for expenditure) instead of M:

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 40

    )1(

    *

    )1(*

    x

    yy

    E

    y

    xx

    E

    p

    pp

    Ey

    p

    pp

    Ex

    +

    =

    +=

    The problem is now, that we dont know what the optimal E (givenprices and fixed utility level) will be.

    One way to derive the minimum expenditure function ),,( yx ppUE

    is to substitute the optimal demands (given the unknown E), i.e.

    x*E

    and y*E

    into the constraint 5.05.0 yxU += .

    So we get:

    5.05.0

    )1()1(

    +

    +

    +

    =

    x

    yy

    y

    xx

    p

    pp

    E

    p

    pp

    EU

    Solving for E gives:

    ++

    +

    = 5.05.0

    )1()1(x

    yy

    y

    xx

    p

    pp

    p

    pp

    UE

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    21/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 41

    Now we have an expression of E in terms of the parameters ofthisproblem. Substituting E into the expressions for Ex * and Ey * gives

    the optimal, i.e. expenditure minimizing bundle, given prices and a

    fixed level of Utility:

    =

    +

    +

    +

    =

    +

    =2

    2

    )1(

    )1(

    1

    )1(

    *

    x

    yy

    y

    xxy

    xx

    E

    p

    pp

    p

    pp

    U

    p

    pp

    Ex

    2

    2

    2

    2

    2

    2

    1

    )1(

    )1(

    1

    *

    ++

    ++

    =

    +

    +

    +

    =

    yxy

    xyx

    y

    x

    x

    y

    y

    x

    y

    x

    E

    ppp

    ppp

    p

    p

    U

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    p

    Ux

    [cont.]

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 42

    2

    2

    2

    2

    1

    *

    similarlyand

    1)(

    )(1

    *

    +

    =

    +

    =

    +

    ++

    =

    x

    y

    E

    y

    x

    xyy

    xyx

    y

    x

    E

    p

    p

    Uy

    p

    p

    U

    ppp

    ppp

    p

    p

    Ux

    Second Approach (via Lagrangian)

    I introduced the above solution approach because it gives you

    some idea of the relationship between M and E. This, however,

    was very complicated in terms of computations (in fact we were

    moving back and forth between different expressions). Next we

    will use our Lagrangian recipe which turns out to be much easier.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    22/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 43

    1. Step: The Lagrangian is:Take the objective function (not the same as in the Utility max

    problem!) and add (RHS of the constraint minus LHS of

    constraint) times the Lagrangian multiplier ( in this case):

    ))(()y,L(x, 5.05.0 yxUypxp yx +++= ,

    2. Step: Taking FOCs:

    0)(

    0)5.0(

    0)5.0(

    5.05.0

    5.0

    5.0

    =+=

    =+=

    =+=

    yxUL

    ypy

    L

    xpx

    L

    y

    x

    3. Step: Solve the first two FOCs for y (or x):

    y

    x

    p

    p

    x

    y

    y

    x

    ==

    5.0

    5.0

    5.0

    5.0

    Which gives the same condition (surprise!?) for the MRS as the

    utility maximization problem, we discussed before.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 44

    xp

    p

    p

    p

    x

    y

    y

    x

    y

    x

    2

    yor

    ==

    4. Step: Solve the third FOC (the constraint) for y (or x):

    ( )25.0

    5.05.0

    5.05.0

    x

    or

    or

    0)(

    yU

    xyU

    yxU

    =

    =

    =+

    5. Step: Substitute the first of the last two results in the second (or

    vice versa):

    ( )2

    5.0

    25.0225.0

    x

    x

    =

    ==

    xp

    pU

    xp

    p

    UyU

    y

    x

    y

    x

    [cont. next page]

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    23/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 45

    2

    E

    5.0

    5.0

    5.05.0

    1

    *x

    1

    x

    )1(x

    x

    +

    =

    +

    =

    =+

    =

    y

    x

    y

    x

    y

    x

    y

    x

    p

    p

    U

    p

    p

    U

    Up

    p

    xppU

    Notice, this is the same result as above.

    Final Result: the minimum expenditure functionWe are not done yet. We know the expenditure minimizing

    bundles, but we have to combine them to obtain the minimum

    expenditure function:

    22

    11

    **),,(

    +

    +

    +

    =

    +

    x

    yy

    y

    x

    x

    Ey

    Exyx

    p

    p

    Up

    p

    p

    Up

    ypxpUppE

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 46

    5.2 Hicksian/Compensated Demand CurveThe so called Hicksian or compensated demand

    x*=hx(px,py,U)

    considers demand behavior for changing price but constant utility.

    Graphical analysis of the Hicksian demand for good x:

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    24/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 47

    Example CD Utility:

    5.05.02

    ),(,: yxyxUU=

    + By solving the Lagrangian problem (max U s.t. BC), the optimal

    demands are:

    y

    x

    p

    My

    p

    Mx

    2*

    2*

    =

    =

    Then the Indirect Utility function is:

    ),,(2

    22***)*,(

    5.05.05.05.0

    MppVpp

    M

    p

    M

    p

    MyxyxU

    yxyx

    yx

    =

    ==

    To get the compensated demand, i.e. the bundle which is

    demanded if we could compensate the Income such that Utility is

    not affected by the variation of the prices, we take the indirect

    utility function and solve for the income M

    yx

    yxyx

    ppVM

    MppVpp

    M

    2

    ),,(2

    =

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 48

    and substitute the expression for M into the solutions for the

    optimal consumption for the original optimum problem:

    y

    x

    y

    yx

    yyxy

    x

    y

    x

    yx

    xyxx

    p

    pU

    p

    ppV

    p

    VMppUh

    p

    pU

    p

    ppV

    p

    VMppUh

    ===

    ===

    2

    2

    2

    )(),,(

    2

    2

    2

    )(),,(

    Compare this with the other demand, which we first developed, the

    so called Marshallian demand (the ones we already know):

    yy

    xx

    pMyd

    p

    Mxd

    2*

    2*

    =

    =

    The difference is that now with the Hicksian or compensated

    demand the price of the other good is in the argument of the

    function (which is a specific feature of the CD utility function),

    and more important, instead of income M, demand depends on the

    level of U (which is a general property of the Hicksian demand).In ),,( yxx ppUh only substitution effects appear (i.e. no income

    effects), that is why it is steeper than the Marshallian demand

    ),,( yxx ppMd (cf. next chapter).

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    25/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 49

    6. Income effect (IE) and Substitution effect (SE)

    So far we have developed different demand concepts and talked

    about comparative statics. We analyzed how demand reacts, when

    prices change. Usually, if price goes up one expects demand to

    decrease. But why is this so? It turns out that two effects contribute

    to the total effect of a change in demand: One is called Substitution

    effect (SE) and is concerned with the change of demand when

    relative prices change but utility (or alternatively: income) is kept

    constant. There is however, a second effect: If one good becomes

    more expensive, the overall purchasing power to buy any good

    decreases. This is called the income effect. A priori, it is not clear

    in which direction the income effect goes. The IE depends on what

    kind of good we are analyzing (normal or inferior good). The

    overall effect depends therefore both on the sign (direction) and the

    relative magnitude of the two effects in combination.

    We will see an interesting application of IE and SE when we will

    talk about the labor supply decision later in the course.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 50

    6.1 Graphical analysis: Effects of a decrease in pY:

    Definitions:1

    Substitution effect: Geometrically, the SE is the movement from A

    (initial OCB) to B [the dotted line is a parallel of BC2, which is

    tangent to the initial optimal IC (I1)].]. Economically, it is the

    amount of y I would substitute for x if prices change, given that the

    level of utility is kept constant.

    Income effect: Geometrically, the IE is the movement from B to C

    (OCB after price change). Economically, it is the change in

    demand due to a change in purchasing power (income) keeping

    prices constant. Note, that a price increase for one good implies

    that there is less money left to buy any of the other goods

    (provided I want to buy at least some of the good with the

    increased price).

    1Remark: There are two different concepts of IE and SE which are called Slutsky and

    Hicks decomposition respectively. We will focus only on the Slutsky version.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    26/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 51

    6.2 The Slutsky decomposition

    In the following, we want to describe IE and SE in analytical

    terms. To do this, we will use all of the concepts we have learned

    so far: Marshallian demand, Hicksian demand, the indirect Utility

    function and Minimum expenditure function. In general, there are

    two approaches to obtain the formulas for IE and Se: A direct and

    an indirect (dual) approach. We will only cover the latter one (For

    a direct approach, i.e. solving the system of the derivatives of the

    FOCs of the utility maximization problem: see Eugene Silberberg,

    The Structure of Economics (3rd Ed.), p. 276 ff).

    First Step: To start with, we state a relation between the Hicksian

    demand yxx ppUh ,, and the Marshallian demand

    yxx pMd ,, :2

    yxyxxyxx ppppUEdppUh ,),,,(,, =

    Why can we set them equal that way? Because we set the income

    M in the Marshallian demand equal to the amount which is needed

    to obtain the utility level U. Remember that the minimumexpenditure function gives the optimal spending subject to a fixed

    level of utility (show this in the graph of the two demand curves).

    2 Rmk: To avoid confusion, I will not use the shorthand for derivatives by using subscripts anymore. Herethe subscribt x denotes the demand for x

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 52

    This last equation is very useful to analyze the income and

    substitution effect.

    Second Step: Partially differentiating this equation w.r.t. px, gives:

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    x

    p

    E

    E

    d

    p

    d

    p

    h

    +

    =

    Rearranging:

    { { 43421ctIncomeEffe

    x

    x

    onEffectSubstituti

    x

    x

    x

    x

    p

    E

    E

    d

    p

    h

    p

    d

    =

    changeTotal

    Where the substitution effectx

    x

    p

    h

    could be written as

    constant =

    Uxp

    x, which says we are looking at the change of the

    optimal x w.r.t. a price change, when the level of utility is kept

    constant. To get what is called the Slutsky equation or Slutsky

    decomposition one further step is needed.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    27/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 53

    Third Step: We want to determine the termxp

    E

    .

    To find the derivative of the expenditure function w.r.t. to xp , we

    go back to the well known expenditure minimization problem to

    get the minimum expenditure function:

    UyxU

    tsypxpE yx

    =

    +=

    ),(

    ..min

    Set up the Lagrangian:

    )),(()y,L(x, yxUUypxp yx ++=

    The FOCs are:

    3)(FOC0)),((

    2)(FOC0)),(

    (

    1)(FOC0)),(

    (

    ==

    =

    +=

    =

    +=

    yxUUL

    y

    yxUp

    y

    L

    x

    yxUp

    x

    L

    y

    x

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 54

    The trouble is, without specifying a utility function we cannot go

    on solving for the expenditure function. However, we can use a

    little trick, - we use the Lagrangian function and evaluate it at the

    optimal points for x and y, which then becomes:

    ),,())*,*((**

    ),*,*L(

    3FOCbyOptimumin0

    UppEyxUUypxp

    yx

    yxEEE

    yE

    x

    EE

    ++=

    =

    =444 3444 21

    Notice that we have shown that the expenditure function can be

    expressed as the Lagrangian function evaluated at the expenditure

    minimizing values of x and y.

    :w.r.t.E()ofderivativefirstthecomputecanweNow, xp

    ( )

    x

    EEEy

    Ex

    x

    EE

    x

    yx

    p

    yxUUypxp

    p

    yx

    p

    UppE

    ++=

    =

    =

    ))*,*((**

    ),*,*L(

    ),,(

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    28/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 55

    ),,(*),*(

    ),,(*),*(

    ),,(*

    ),,(*),,(*

    x

    yxEE

    x

    yxEE

    x

    yxE

    y

    x

    yxE

    xyxE

    p

    Uppx

    x

    yxU

    p

    Uppy

    y

    yxU

    p

    Uppyp

    p

    UppxpUppx

    +

    +=

    ),,(*

    )*,*(),,(*

    )*,*(),,(*

    ),,(*

    2FOCby0

    1FOCby0

    Uppx

    y

    yxUp

    p

    Uppy

    x

    yxU

    pp

    Uppx

    Uppx

    yxE

    EE

    xx

    yxE

    EE

    xx

    yxE

    yx

    E

    =

    +

    +=

    =

    =

    4444 34444 21

    4444 34444 21

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 56

    For the derivation two things were used:

    First at the optimum values for x and y, i.e. *Ex and Ey * , the

    Lagrangian function equals the minimum expenditure function

    E(.).

    Second, at the optimum values, we can use the FOC of the

    expenditure minimum problem. From this, the result follows. The

    procedure we used is also called Envelope Theorem (see

    Nicholson p 46 f).

    Final Step: With our results we can now express the demand

    effect of changing prices as:

    {32144 344 2143421

    IE

    x

    SE

    Ux

    ctIncomeEffe

    x

    x

    onEffectSubstituti

    x

    x

    x

    x xMd

    px

    pE

    Ed

    ph

    pd

    =

    =

    = constant

    This says, that a marginalincrease in the price of good x can be

    decomposed into a change of demand due to a movement along the

    IC (the SE), which is the change of the Hicksian demand minus the

    change due to an income change multiplied with the initial amount

    of x. Note that the Slutsky decomposition only tells us something

    about marginal IE and SE. In the second example below, I will

    show how to compute IE and SE as a response to a discrete price

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    29/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 57

    change (i.e. how to compute the actual IE and SE we have

    observed in the 2-goods diagram). We will use the concept of the

    Slutsky decomposition again when we will talk about the labor

    supply decision of the consumer.

    Example The Slutsky decomposition for a CD Utility function

    Assume the Utility function has the form:

    xyyxU =),(

    As we have shown the Marshallian and Hicksian demands, are,

    respectively (we do the analysis for the x-good, for y the procedure

    is similar):

    xx

    p

    Mxd

    2* =

    x

    yyxx

    p

    pUppUh =),,(

    Substitution effect:

    5.05.1

    2

    1yx

    x

    x

    y

    x

    x pUpp

    p

    pU

    p

    hSE

    =

    =

    We can eliminate U by using the indirect utility function:

    ( ) 5.05.05.0

    222),,(

    yxyxyx

    pp

    M

    p

    M

    p

    MMppV =

    =

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 58

    ( )

    2

    5.05.15.05.05.1

    4

    1

    22

    1

    2

    1

    x

    yx

    yx

    yx

    p

    M

    pppp

    MpUpSE

    =

    ==

    As expected, the SE is negative, i.e. if the price of good increases,

    the other becomes relatively cheaper, and I want to buy more of

    the other good.

    Income effect:

    xp

    xM

    p

    M

    xM

    dIE

    x

    xx

    2

    12=

    =

    Since, by the Marshallian demand function: xp

    M

    x 2= , the

    previous expression becomes:

    2422

    1

    2

    1

    xxxx p

    M

    p

    M

    px

    pIE ===

    Now we can combine the two effects to obtain the Slutsky

    equation:

    222 2

    1

    44

    1

    x

    ctIncomeEffe

    x

    onEffectSubstituti

    xx

    x

    p

    M

    p

    M

    p

    M

    p

    d==

    32143421

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    30/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 59

    First, observe that in this example both IE and SE are negative and

    of the same magnitude (this is due to the special form of the utility

    function).

    Second, compare the total effect to the direct comparative statics

    result, i.e. how demand changes, when the price changes:

    22

    12

    xx

    x

    x

    x

    p

    M

    p

    p

    M

    p

    d=

    =

    .

    They are the same, as it should be. However, the Slutsky

    decomposition includes more information, it says how much of the

    demand change can be accounted for by a change of relative prices

    (SE) and how much is due to a change in purchasing power (IE).

    6.3 Computing IE and SE for a discrete price change

    We will now analyse the compution of a positive, i.e. non marginal

    price change (the Slutsky decomposition above only deals with

    marginal effects, thats why there are only derivatives in the

    equation). We will explain the computation of discrete IE and SE

    by the use of an example. Consider again the Utility function

    xyyxU =),( . Assume that income is $ 100 and that the price of x

    is 1=xp and 1=yp and that price of x increases to 2=new

    xp .

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 60

    Before you read the following calculations, you may draw a sketch

    of the IE and SE and compare each step of the computations to

    points in the graph.

    Substitution effect:

    1. We want to get the initial bundle first (i.e. the OCB with prices

    all equal to 1). The first step is to compute the Marshallian

    demands from the Utility maximization problem. By our familiar

    procedure (using the Lagrangian), we get:

    501*2

    100

    2*

    501$*2

    100$

    2*

    ===

    ===

    yy

    xx

    p

    Myd

    p

    Mxd

    2. To get the bundle, where the SE leads to, we have to compute

    the Hicksian demand, using the old Utility level (IC) but changing

    the price of x to $2 (Remember that the Hicksian demand keeps U

    constant when price changes, that is, we move along an IC).

    First we need the Indirect Utility function:

    ( ) 5.0

    5.05.0

    222),,(*)*,(

    yxyxyx

    ppM

    pM

    pMMppVyxU =

    ==

    Solving for M as a function of U gives:

    yxppUUM 2)( =

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    31/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 61

    Taking the Marshallian demand and using the relation between M

    and U gives the Compensated or Hicksian demands:

    y

    x

    y

    yx

    yyxy

    x

    y

    x

    yx

    xyxx

    p

    p

    Up

    ppU

    p

    UM

    ppUh

    p

    pU

    p

    ppU

    p

    UMppUh

    ===

    ===

    2

    2

    2

    )(

    ),,(

    2

    2

    2

    )(),,(

    3. To calculate the actual values of the Hicksian demands, we need

    to know the Utility level of the original IC:

    Take the Utility function and plug in the values for the original

    demands (where the prices are all=1):

    ( )50

    112

    100*)*,(

    5.0=

    =yxU

    This is the Utility level of the original demanded bundle for the

    price for x of $1.

    The Hicksian demands for the new price of x, which is $2 are then:

    7.701

    250*)*,(),,(

    4.352

    150*)*,(),,(

    ==

    ==

    y

    newx

    ynew

    xSE

    y

    newx

    yy

    newx

    SEx

    p

    pyxUppUh

    p

    pyxUppUh

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 62

    Thus, the Substitution effect for x is 014.6-50-35.4*x-==SEyh .

    Income effect:

    4. The easiest way to compute the IE is to first compute the new

    optimal consumption bundle, given by the Marshallian demand for

    the new prices:

    501*2

    100

    2**),,(

    252*2

    100

    2**),,(

    ===

    ===

    yy

    newxy

    newx

    ynew

    xx

    p

    MyppMd

    p

    MxppMd

    Then the IE is just the difference of the new bundle and the bundle

    reached by the SE, i.e. 04.104.3525-**x

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    32/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 63

    7. Labor supply decision of the consumer

    7.1 Introduction: Assumptions of the model

    The basic trade-off for the labor supply decision is whether to have

    more free time and fewer earnings and therefore less consumption

    or more consumption, but also more time to spend on working (i.e.

    less leisure time).

    Similarly as in the 2-goods problem, the consumers decision

    problem is based on his or her preferences (utility function) and a

    budget constraint.

    Let utility be given by: U(c, F), where c symbolizes consumption

    (i.e. a basket of consumption goods), and F is the symbol for

    leisure (Free time). We assume that F is less or equal to 24 hours:

    240 F . The remaining time (24-F) is used for earning money

    (which is spent on c), called labor time L. Thus we have F+ L = 24

    or L =24 F.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 64

    Assumptions on preferences

    For our analysis we assume that an increase in either of the goods

    (leisure or consumption) yields an increase in utility, or formally:

    0),(

    0),(

    >

    >

    F

    FcU

    c

    FcU

    Further, we assume that the marginal utilities are decreasing:

    ( )

    ( )0

    ),(

    0),(

    2

    2

    2

    2

    =

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    38/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 75

    Three cases:

    1. IESE: In this case the Income effect outweighs the increase of

    the relative price of leisure, we will supply less labor although the

    wage is increasing.

    Illustration of case 3:

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 76

    If this last case applies for some range of the labor supply, we

    might obtain the following backward bending (aggregated) labor

    supply function:

    Empirical studies claim that for men, the labor supply is slightly

    backward bending and for women it is always increasing. The

    latter is the case, so it is argued, because if household production(as part of leisure time) is taken into account, then the

    substitution effect will always outweigh the income effect.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    39/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 77

    Discussion:

    Certainly people are not changing their labor leisure choice day by

    day. (why?) So the concept we just developed has more appeal for

    long term decisions (if I choose a high earning job which usually

    implies a long working day, may be I plan to retire earlier.)

    Other issues:

    Hours of work versus Participation

    Unemployment Insurance/Protection

    Search for a job

    Bargaining for wages

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 78

    7. 4 Appendix: analytical derivation of the Slutsky equation

    The problem with the analytical solution is that income wT+

    does itself depend on one of the prices, namely w. This implies that

    there are two income effects.

    Marshallian demand for leisure is ),wwTdF +43421(M)incomefull

    (

    Differentiating w.r.t to w:

    constM

    effectincomefull

    w

    dT

    M

    d

    w

    d FFF+

    =

    321

    Where the last expression now can be decomposed into the usual

    income and substitution effects. Using the relation:

    ( ) ( )wwUEdwUh FF ),,(, =

    Taking first derivative w.r.t. w and rearranging:

    { 434214342143421IE

    F

    SE

    U

    IE

    F

    SE

    FF FM

    d

    w

    F

    w

    E

    M

    d

    w

    h

    w

    d

    =

    =

    ==

    const

    constM

    Combining with the first result gives the Slutsky equation::

    44 344 2144 344 21

    IEcombinedSE

    constant

    FM

    dT

    M

    d

    w

    F

    w

    d FF

    U

    F

    +

    =

    =

    LM

    d

    w

    FFT

    M

    d

    w

    F F

    U

    F

    U

    +

    =

    +

    =

    == constantconstant )(

    Note, that we wrote everything in terms of leisure demand. We could transform this into

    a statement in terms of labor supply using the relationship: L=T-F.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    40/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 79

    8. Labor supply and taxes

    There are two stylized types of taxes concerning the labor supply:

    per capita tax and (linear) income tax. We will first look at the

    general set-up of the tax models and then later compute demand

    functions given taxes for a specific example.

    8.1 A (linear) Income tax

    The framework:

    Utility: U(c, F)

    Budget constraint: +w)F-24(=c

    Assume = 0, then: w)F-24(=c

    Now introduce a tax t:

    wt)-)(1F-24(=c

    Budget constraint pivots downward if t is introduced (1>t>0).

    What is the revenue the state will get?

    From the BC:{ {

    nconsumptiotaxbeforeincomerevenueTax

    c-wLtwLor

    wt)-L(1c

    wt)-)(1F-24(=c

    =

    =

    321

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 80

    8.2 Per capita tax

    Lets compare this tax scheme with a so called lump sum tax, a per

    capita tax.

    The Budget constraint is in this case:

    F)w(c = 24

    or

    Lwc =

    where denotes the amount of tax everyone (regardless of

    income) has to pay.

    Budget constraint shift down for 0> .

    Question: How could someone come up with such an idea?

    The advantage of this kind of tax is that it is more efficient.

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    41/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 81

    8.3 Taxes and Efficiency

    The concept of efficiency4

    The official definition of (economic) efficiency, is the so called

    Pareto Efficiency (for an economy with N agents and L goods):

    An allocation of goods among N individuals:

    X={( )x,...x,(x),..,..x,...x,(x),x,...x,(x NLN2

    N1

    2L

    22

    21

    1L

    12

    11 }

    is called efficient, if

    1. the allocation X isfeasible, i.e. the allocation is available (either

    by endowment or in the sense that they can be produced by the

    firms given the resources of the economy),

    and if

    2. there is no otherfeasible allocation

    Y={ ),...y,(y),..,..,...y,(y),,...,(y NLN2

    N1

    2L

    22

    21

    1L

    12

    11 yyyy }

    such that Y is preferred by all consumers, i.e.

    forall consumers i=1,2.N,

    )x,...x,U(x)y,...y,U(y iLi2

    i1

    iL

    i2

    i1

    and for at least one consumer j :

    4 We will discuss this issue more in detail later in the course, the following is for those who are curious toknow.

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 82

    )x,...x,U(x)y,...y,U(y j

    L

    j

    2

    j

    1

    j

    L

    j

    2

    j

    1>

    In words: an allocation is Pareto Optimal (PO) if no consumer

    can be made better of without making at least one other

    consumer worse of.Note that this concept doesnt imply anything

    about fairness: efficient does not mean good.

    This definition will be of interest when we will talk about generalequilibrium analysis later in the course.

    In our single consumer model with taxes, the concept of efficiency

    boils down to the statement, that, given the tax revenue the

    government wants to raise, the consumer is maximizing (why?).

    Lets look at the model for the per capita tax:

    [Graphical analysis]

    What can you say concerning the MRS at the new optimal bundle?

    With the lump sum tax , the MRS will be the same since the

    relative prices do not change (like a pure IE).

    In comparison with the income tax, discussed above, the choices

    are not distorted between the two goods (c and F). The purchasing

    power decreases, though. But the ratio of the consumed goods

    remains constant. This is implicitly the reason why the per capita

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    42/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 83

    tax (assuming standard preferences) is more efficient: it does not

    distort choices.

    To see the difference in efficiency, let us consider a specific

    example.

    We will assume that in both tax scenarios, the total amount of the

    tax incidence (government revenue) is the same, and we will

    compare the level of utility the consumer has under both tax

    regimes.

    Example:

    We will now compute utilities ex post for the two tax regimes,

    assuming that the lump sum tax will be equal to the tax revenue of

    the income tax problem. That is we compare the tax systems in

    terms of the achieved utility by the consumer, given that the

    government gets the same absolute value of tax revenues.

    I. Linear Income tax

    The objective function is (note, the U fcn is not CD):

    5.05.02 ),(,: cFFcUU += +

    The budget constraint:

    )24()1( Fwty = The Lagrangian:

    ))24()1((),,( 5.05.0 cFwtcFFc ++= L

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 84

    FOCs of the Lagrangian function:

    0)24()1(

    05.0

    0)1(5.0

    5.0

    5.0

    ==

    ==

    ==

    cFwt

    cc

    wtFF

    L

    L

    L

    From the first two FOCs:

    ( ) Fwtc

    or

    wtF

    c

    2)1(

    )1(

    =

    =

    Combining with the BC (3rd

    FOC) yields:

    ( )

    wtF

    wt

    wtc

    t

    t

    )1(1

    24

    )1(1

    )1(24

    *

    2*

    +=

    +

    =

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    43/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 85

    Now we compute the tax revenue. For convenience we set

    w = 0.5 and t = 0.5:

    2.1)1(1

    )1(24

    )1(1

    2424)

    2* =

    +

    =

    +==

    wt

    wt

    wttwFtwTR t-(24

    II. Per capita tax

    We use, of course, the same utility fcn:

    5.05.0),( cFFcU +=

    However, the budget constraint now looks like:

    = )24( Fwc

    Lagrangian:

    ))24((),,(L 5.05.0 cFwcFFc ++=

    FOCs:

    0)24(L

    05.0L

    05.0L

    5.0

    5.0

    ==

    ==

    ==

    cFw

    cc

    wFF

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 86

    The first two FOCs give:

    ( ) Fwc

    or

    wF

    c

    2=

    =

    Again, combining with the BC:

    ww

    wF

    w

    wwc

    t

    +

    =

    +

    =

    2

    2*

    24

    1

    24

    Now set equal to TR, so that we can compare the efficiency of

    the two tax regimes by computing the Utilities in both cases (note

    that we set w = 0.5 and t = 0.5):

    Utility in the first case:

    ( )48.5

    )1(1

    )1(24

    )1(1

    24),(

    2**

    +

    +

    +=

    wt

    wt

    wtcFU tt

    And Utility in case of the per capita tax:

  • 8/9/2019 14 Consumer Surplus

    44/44

    3101 Spring 2005 Edgar Preugschat Lecture notes Part 1 page 87

    2.1)-(24where

    70.51

    2424),(

    *

    2

    2

    **

    ==

    +

    +

    +

    =

    tFtw

    w

    ww

    ww

    wcFU

    This says that raising the same revenue, the per capita tax is more

    efficient (b/c it implies a higher Utility for the consumer):

    ),(48.570.5),( **** tt cFUcFU =>= .

    Hence, the utility is higher if the same amount of revenue is raised

    by a per-capita tax, than with a linear income tax. Economically,

    this means that a per-capita tax is more efficient. In terms of

    equality, on the other hand, a per-capita tax would be very unfair.

    Everyone has to pay the same, be he/she a factory worker or a

    CEO of a big company. Neoclassical Economics as a positive

    science tries to provide tools to evaluate the efficiency costs of

    equality (or inequality some research suggests that under some

    specified conditions, a high degree of inequality might be

    inefficient). Neoclassical Economics does not, however, analyze or

    give reasons for or against equality/inequality per se. That is both a

    philosophical and political question.


Recommended