+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option...

4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option...

Date post: 13-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
77
4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of a call option – hedges his exposure by holding certain units of the underlying asset in order to create a riskless portfolio. In an efficient market with no riskless arbitrage opportunity, a riskless portfolio must earn rate of return equals the riskless interest rate. 1
Transcript
Page 1: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework

Riskless hedging principle

Writer of a call option – hedges his exposure by holding certain units

of the underlying asset in order to create a riskless portfolio.

In an efficient market with no riskless arbitrage opportunity, a riskless

portfolio must earn rate of return equals the riskless interest rate.

1

Page 2: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Dynamic replication strategy

How to replicate an option dynamically by a portfolio of the riskless

asset in the form of money market account and the risky underlying

asset?

The cost of constructing the replicating portfolio gives the fair price

of an option.

Risk neutrality argument

The two tradeable securities, option and asset, are hedgeable with

each other. Hedgeable securities should have the same market price

of risk.

2

Page 3: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Black-Scholes’ assumptions on the financial market

(i) Trading takes place continuously in time.

(ii) The riskless interest rate r is known and constant over time.

(iii) The asset pays no dividend.

(iv) There are no transaction costs in buying or selling the asset or

the option, and no taxes.

(v) The assets are perfectly divisible.

(vi) There are no penalties to short selling and the full use of pro-

ceeds is permitted.

(vii) There are no arbitrage opportunities.

3

Page 4: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

The stochastic process of the asset price S is assumed to follow the

Geometric Brownian motion

dS

S= ρ dt+ σ dZ.

Consider a portfolio which involves short selling of one unit of a

European call option and long holding of ∆ units of the underlying

asset. The value of the portfolio Π is given by

Π = −c+ ∆S,

where c = c(S, t) denotes the call price.

Since both c and Π are random variables, we apply the Ito lemma

to compute their stochastic differentials as follows:

dc =∂c

∂tdt+

∂c

∂SdS +

σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2dt

4

Page 5: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

dΠ = −dc+ ∆ dS

=

(−∂c∂t

− σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2

)dt+

(∆ − ∂c

∂S

)dS

=

[−∂c∂t

− σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2+

(∆ − ∂c

∂S

)ρS

]dt+

(∆ − ∂c

∂S

)σS dZ.

Why the differential Sd∆ does not enter into dΠ? By virtue of

the assumption of following a self-financing trading strategy, the

contribution to dΠ due to Sd∆ is offset by the accompanying pur-

chase/sale of units of options.

5

Page 6: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

If we choose ∆ =∂c

∂S, then the portfolio becomes a riskless hedge in-

stantaneously

(since

∂c

∂Schanges continuously with time

). By virtue

of “no arbitrage”, the hedged portfolio should earn the riskless in-

terest rate.

By setting dΠ = rΠ dt

dΠ =

(−∂c∂t

− σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2

)dt = rΠ dt = r

(−c+ S

∂c

∂S

)dt.

Black-Scholes equation:∂c

∂t+σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2+ rS

∂c

∂S− rc = 0.

Terminal payoff: c(S, T) = max(S −X,0).

The parameter ρ (expected rate of return) does not appear in the

governing equation and the auxiliary condition.

6

Page 7: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• 5 parameters in the option model: S, T,X, r and σ; only σ is

unobservable.

Deficiencies in the model

1. Geometric Brownian motion assumption? Actual asset price

dynamics is much more complicated.

2. Continuous hedging at all times

— trading usually involves transaction costs.

3. Interest rate should be stochastic instead of deterministic.

7

Page 8: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Dynamic replication strategy (Merton’s approach)

QS(t) = number of units of asset

QV (t) = number of units of option

MS(t) = dollar value of QS(t) units of asset

MV (t) = dollar value of QV (t) units of option

M(t) = value of riskless asset invested in money market account

• Construction of a self-financing and dynamically hedged portfo-

lio containing risky asset, option and riskless asset.

8

Page 9: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• Dynamic replication: Composition is allowed to change at all

times in the replication process.

• The self-financing portfolio is set up with zero initial net invest-

ment cost and no additional funds added or withdrawn after-

wards.

The zero net investment condition at time t is

Π(t) = MS(t) +MV (t) +M(t)

= QS(t)S +QV (t)V +M(t) = 0.

Differential of option value V :

dV =∂V

∂tdt+

∂V

∂SdS +

σ2

2S2∂

2V

∂S2dt

=

(∂V

∂t+ ρS

∂V

∂S+σ2

2S2∂

2V

∂S2

)dt+ σS

∂V

∂SdZ.

9

Page 10: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Formally, we write

dV

V= ρV dt+ σV dZ

where

ρV =

∂V∂t + ρS∂V∂S + σ2

2 S2∂2V∂S2

Vand σV =

σS∂V∂SV

.

dΠ(t) = [QS(t) dS +QV (t) dV + rM(t) dt]

+ [SdQS(t) + V dQS(t) + dM(t)]︸ ︷︷ ︸zero due to self-financing trading strategy

10

Page 11: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

The instantaneous portfolio return dΠ(t) can be expressed in terms

of MS(t) and MV (t) as follows:

dΠ(t) = QS(t) dS +QV (t) dV + rM(t) dt

= MS(t)dS

S+MV (t)

dV

V+ rM(t) dt

= [(ρ− r)MS(t) + (ρV − r)MV (t)] dt

+ [σMS(t) + σVMV (t)] dZ.

We then choose MS(t) and MV (t) such that the stochastic term

becomes zero.

From the relation:

σMS(t) + σVMV (t) = σSQS(t) +σS∂V∂SV

V QV (t) = 0,

we obtain

QS(t)

QV (t)= −∂V

∂S.

11

Page 12: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Taking the choice of QV (t) = −1, and knowing

0 = Π(t) = −V + ∆S +M(t)

we obtain

V = ∆S +M(t), where ∆ =∂V

∂S.

Since the replicating portfolio is self-financing and replicates the

terminal payoff, by virtue of no-arbitrage argument, the initial cost

of setting up this replicating portfolio of risky asset and riskless asset

must be equal to the value of the option being replicated.

12

Page 13: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

The dynamic replicating portfolio is riskless and requires no net

investment, so dΠ(t) = 0.

0 = [(ρ− r)MS(t) + (ρV − r)MV (t)] dt.

PuttingQS(t)

QV (T)= −∂V

∂S, we obtain

(ρ− r)S∂V

∂S= (ρV − r)V.

Replacing ρV by

[∂V

∂t+ ρS

∂V

∂S+σ2

2S2∂

2V

∂S2

]/V , we obtain the Black-

Scholes equation

∂V

∂t+σ2

2S2∂

2V

∂S2+ rS

∂V

∂S− rV = 0.

13

Page 14: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Alternative perspective on risk neutral valuation

From ρV =

∂V∂t + ρS∂V∂S + σ2

2 S2∂2V∂S2

V, we obtain

∂V

∂t+σ2

2S2∂

2V

∂S2+ ρS

∂V

∂S− ρV V = 0.

We need to calibrate the parameters ρ and ρV , or find some other

means to avoid such nuisance.

Combining σV =σS∂V∂SV

and (ρ− r)S∂V

∂S= (ρV − r)V , we obtain

ρV − r

σV︸ ︷︷ ︸λV

=ρ− r

σ︸ ︷︷ ︸λS

⇒ Black-Scholes equation.

14

Page 15: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• The market price of risk is the rate of extra return above r per

unit risk.

• Two hedgeable securities should have the same market price of

risk.

• The Black-Scholes equation can be obtained by setting ρ =

ρV = r (implying zero market price of risk).

• In the world of zero market price of risk, investors are said to be

risk neutral since they do not demand extra returns on holding

risky assets.

• Option valuation can be performed in the risk neutral world by

artificially taking the expected rate of returns of the asset and

option to be r.

15

Page 16: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Arguments of risk neutrality

• We find the price of a derivative relative to that of the underlying

asset ⇒ mathematical relationship between the prices is invariant

to the risk preference.

• Be careful that the actual rate of return of the underlying as-

set would affect the asset price and thus indirectly affects the

absolute derivative price.

• We simply use the convenience of risk neutrality to arrive at the

mathematical relationship but actual risk neutrality behaviors of

the investors are not necessary in the derivation of option prices.

16

Page 17: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

“How we came up with the option formula?” — Black (1989)

⋆ It started with tinkering and ended with delayed recognition.

⋆ The expected return on a warrant should depend on the risk of

the warrant in the same way that a common stock’s expected

return depends on its risk.

⋆ I spent many, many days trying to find the solution to that (dif-

ferential) equation. I have a PhD in applied mathematics, but

had never spent much time on differential equations, so I didn’t

know the standard methods used to solve problems like that. I

have an A.B. in physics, but I didn’t recognize the equation as

a version of the heat equation, which has well-known solutions.

17

Page 18: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Continuous time securities model

• Uncertainty in the financial market is modeled by the filtered

probability space (Ω,F , (Ft)0≤t≤T , P), where Ω is a sample space,

F is a σ-algebra on Ω, P is a probability measure on (Ω,F),Ftis the filtration and FT = F.

• There are M + 1 securities whose price processes are modeled

by adapted stochastic processes Sm(t), m = 0,1, · · · ,M .

• We define hm(t) to be the number of units of the mth security

held in the portfolio.

• The trading strategy H(t) is the vector stochastic process (h0(t)

h1(t) · · ·hM(t))T , where H(t) is a (M+1)-dimensional predictable

process since the portfolio composition is determined by the in-

vestor based on the information available before time t.

18

Page 19: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• The value process associated with a trading strategy H(t) is

defined by

V (t) =M∑

m=0

hm(t)Sm(t), 0 ≤ t ≤ T,

and the gain process G(t) is given by

G(t) =M∑

m=0

∫ t

0hm(u) dSm(u), 0 ≤ t ≤ T.

• Similar to that in discrete models, H(t) is self-financing if and

only if

V (t) = V (0) +G(t).

19

Page 20: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• We use S0(t) to denote the money market account process that

grows at the riskless interest rate r(t), that is,

dS0(t) = r(t)S0(t) dt.

• The discounted security price process S∗m(t) is defined as

S∗m(t) = Sm(t)/S0(t), m = 1,2, · · · ,M.

• The discounted value process V ∗(t) is defined by dividing V (t)

by S0(t). The discounted gain process G∗(t) is defined by

G∗(t) = V ∗(t) − V ∗(0).

20

Page 21: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

No-arbitrage principle and equivalent martingale measure

• A self-financing trading strategy H represents an arbitrage op-

portunity if and only if (i) G∗(T) ≥ 0 and (ii) EPG∗(T) > 0 where

P is the actual probability measure of the states of occurrence

associated with the securities model.

• A probability measure Q on the space (Ω,F) is said to be an

equivalent martingale measure if it satisfies

(i) Q is equivalent to P , that is, both P and Q have the same

null set;(ii) the discounted security price processes S∗

m(t),m = 1,2, · · · ,Mare martingales under Q, that is,

EQ[S∗m(u)|Ft] = S∗

m(t), for all 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T.

21

Page 22: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Theorem

Let Y be an attainable contingent claim generated by some trading

strategy H and assume that an equivalent martingale measure Q

exists, then for each time t,0 ≤ t ≤ T , the arbitrage price of Y is

given by

V (t;H) = S0(t)EQ

[Y

S0(T)

∣∣∣∣∣Ft].

The validity of the Theorem is readily seen if we consider the dis-

counted value process V ∗(t;H) to be a martingale under Q. This

leads to

V (t;H) = S0(t)V∗(t;H) = S0(t)EQ[V ∗(T ;H)|Ft].

Furthermore, by observing that V ∗(T ;H) = Y/S0(T), so the risk

neutral valuation formula follows.

22

Page 23: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Change of numeraire

• The choice of S0(t) as the numeraire is not unique in order that

the risk neutral valuation formula holds.

• Let N(t) be a numeraire whereby we have the existence of an

equivalent probability measure QN such that all security prices

discounted with respect to N(t) are QN-martingale. In addition,

if a contingent claim Y is attainable under (S0(t), Q), then it is

also attainable under (N(t), QN).

23

Page 24: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

The arbitrage price of any security given by the risk neutral valuation

formula under both measures should agree. We then have

S0(t)EQ

[Y

S0(T)

∣∣∣∣∣Ft]= N(t)EQN

[Y

N(T)

∣∣∣∣∣Ft].

To effect the change of measure from QN to Q, we multiplyY

N(T)by the Radon-Nikodym derivative so that

S0(t)EQ

[Y

S0(T)

∣∣∣∣∣Ft]= N(t)EQ

[Y

N(T)

dQNdQ

∣∣∣∣∣Ft].

By comparing like terms, we obtain

dQNdQ

=N(T)

N(t)

/S0(T)

S0(t).

24

Page 25: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Black-Scholes model revisited

The price processes of S(t) and M(t) are governed by

dS(t)

S(t)= ρ dt+ σ dZ

dM(t) = rM(t) dt.

The price process of S∗(t) = S(t)/M(t) becomes

dS∗(t)S∗(t)

= (ρ− r)dt+ σ dZ.

We would like to find the equivalent martingale measure Q such

that the discounted asset price S∗ is Q-martingale. By the Girsanov

Theorem, suppose we choose γ(t) in the Radon-Nikodym derivative

such that

γ(t) =ρ− r

σ,

then Z is a Brownian motion under the probability measure Q and

dZ = dZ +ρ− r

σdt.

25

Page 26: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Under the Q-measure, the process of S∗(t) now becomes

dS∗(t)S∗(t)

= σ dZ,

hence S∗(t) is Q-martingale. The asset price S(t) under the Q-

measure is governed by

dS(t)

S(t)= r dt+ σ dZ.

When the money market account is used as the numeraire, the cor-

responding equivalent martingale measure is called the risk neutral

measure and the drift rate of S under the Q-measure is called the

risk neutral drift rate.

26

Page 27: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

The arbitrage price of a derivative is given by

V (S, t) = e−r(T−t)Et,SQ [h(ST )]

where Et,SQ is the expectation under the risk neutral measure Q

conditional on the filtration Ft and St = S. By the Feynman-Kac

representation formula, the governing equation of V (S, t) is given

by

∂V

∂t+σ2

2S2∂

2V

∂S2+ rS

∂V

∂S− rV = 0.

Consider the European call option whose terminal payoff is max(ST−X,0). The call price c(S, t) is given by

c(S, t) = e−r(T−t)EQ[max(ST −X,0)]

= e−r(T−t)EQ[ST1ST≥X] −XEQ[1ST≥X].

27

Page 28: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Exchange rate process under domestic risk neutral measure

• Consider a foreign currency option whose payoff function de-

pends on the exchange rate F , which is defined to be the do-

mestic currency price of one unit of foreign currency.

• Let Md and Mf denote the money market account process in

the domestic market and foreign market, respectively. The pro-

cesses of Md(t),Mf(t) and F(t) are governed by

dMd(t) = rMd(t) dt, dMf(t) = rfMf(t) dt,dF(t)

F(t)= µdt+σ dZF ,

where r and rf denote the riskless domestic and foreign interest

rates, respectively.

28

Page 29: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• We may treat the domestic money market account and the for-

eign money market account in domestic dollars (whose value

is given by FMf) as traded securities in the domestic currency

world.

• With reference to the domestic equivalent martingale measure,

Md is used as the numeraire.

• By Ito’s lemma, the relative price process X(t) = F(t)Mf(t)/Md(t)

is governed by

dX(t)

X(t)= (rf − r+ µ) dt+ σ dZF .

29

Page 30: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• With the choice of γ = (rf − r+µ)/σ in the Girsanov Theorem,

we define

dZd = dZF + γ dt,

where Zd is a Brownian process under Qd.

• Under the domestic equivalent martingale measure Qd, the pro-

cess of X now becomes

dX(t)

X(t)= σ dZd

so that X is Qd-martingale.

• The exchange rate process F under the Qd-measure is given by

dF(t)

F(t)= (r − rf) dt+ σ dZd.

• The risk neutral drift rate of F under Qd is found to be r − rf .

30

Page 31: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Recall that the Black-Scholes equation for a European vanilla call

option takes the form

∂c

∂τ=σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2+ rS

∂c

∂S− rc, 0 < S <∞, τ > 0, τ = T − t.

Initial condition (payoff at expiry)

c(S,0) = max(S −X,0), X is the strike price.

Using the transformation: y = lnS and c(y, τ) = e−rτw(y, τ), the

Black-Scholes equation is transformed into

∂w

∂τ=σ2

2

∂2w

∂y2+

(r − σ2

2

)∂w

∂y, −∞ < y <∞, τ > 0.

The initial condition for the model now becomes

w(y,0) = max(ey −X,0).

31

Page 32: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Green function approach

The infinite domain Green function is known to be

φ(y, τ) =1

σ√

2πτexp

[y+ (r − σ2

2 )τ ]2

2σ2τ

.

Here, φ(y, τ) satisfies the initial condition:

limτ→0+

φ(y, τ) = δ(y),

where δ(y) is the Dirac function representing a unit impulse at the

origin.

The initial condition can be expressed as

w(y,0) =

∫ ∞

−∞w(ξ, 0)δ(y − ξ) dξ,

so that w(y,0) can be considered as the superposition of impulses

with varying magnitude w(ξ, 0) ranging from ξ → −∞ to ξ → ∞.

32

Page 33: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• Since the Black-Scholes equation is linear, the response in po-

sition y and at time to expiry τ due to an impulse of magnitude

w(ξ, 0) in position ξ at τ = 0 is given by w(ξ,0)φ(y − ξ, τ).

• From the principle of superposition for a linear differential equa-

tion, the solution is obtained by summing up the responses due

to these impulses.

c(y, τ) = e−rτw(y, τ)

= e−rτ∫ ∞

−∞w(ξ, 0) φ(y − ξ, τ) dξ

= e−rτ∫ ∞

lnX(eξ −X)

1

σ√

2πτ

exp

[y+ (r − σ2

2 )τ − ξ]2

2σ2τ

dξ.

33

Page 34: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Note that

∫ ∞

lnXeξ

1

σ√

2πτexp

[y+ (r − σ2

2 )τ − ξ]2

2σ2τ

= exp(y+ rτ)∫ ∞

lnX

1

σ√

2πτexp

[y+

(r+ σ2

2

)τ − ξ

]2

2σ2τ

= erτSN

ln S

X + (r+ σ2

2 )τ

σ√τ

, y = lnS;

∫ ∞

lnX

1

σ√

2πτexp

[y+ (r − σ2

2 )τ − ξ]2

2σ2τ

= N

y+ (r − σ2

2 )τ − lnX

σ√τ

= N

ln S

X + (r − σ2

2 )τ

σ√τ

, y = lnS.

34

Page 35: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Hence, the price formula of the European call option is found to be

c(S, τ) = SN(d1) −Xe−rτN(d2),

where

d1 =ln SX + (r+ σ2

2 )τ

σ√τ

, d2 = d1 − σ√τ .

The call value lies within the bounds

max(S −Xe−rτ ,0) ≤ c(S, τ) ≤ S, S ≥ 0, τ ≥ 0,

35

Page 36: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

36

Page 37: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

c(S, τ) = e−rτEQ[(ST −X)1ST≥X]

= e−rτ∫ ∞

0max(ST −X,0)ψ(ST , T ;S, t) dST .

• Under the risk neutral measure,

lnSTS

=

(r − σ2

2

)τ + σZ(τ)

so that lnSTS

is normally distributed with mean

(r − σ2

2

)τ and

variance σ2τ, τ = T − t.

• From the density function of a normal random variable, the

transition density function is given by

ψ(ST , T ;S, t) =1

STσ√

2πτexp

[lnSTS −

(r − σ2

2

]2

2σ2τ

.

37

Page 38: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

If we compare the price formula with the expectation representation

we deduce that

N(d2) = EQ[1ST≥X] = Q[ST ≥ X]

SN(d1) = e−rτEQ[ST1ST≥X].

• N(d2) is recognized as the probability under the risk neutral

measure Q that the call expires in-the-money, so Xe−rτN(d2)

represents the present value of the risk neutral expectation of

payment paid by the option holder at expiry.

• SN(d1) is the discounted risk neutral expectation of the terminal

asset price conditional on the call being in-the-money at expiry.

38

Page 39: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Delta - derivative with respect to asset price

c =∂c

∂S= N(d1) + S

1√2π

e−d212∂d1∂S

−Xe−rτ1√2π

e−d222∂d2∂S

= N(d1) +1

σ√

2πτ[e−

d212 − e−(rτ+ln S

X)e−d222 ]

= N(d1) > 0.

Knowing that a European call can be replicated by ∆ units of asset

and riskless asset in the form of money market account, the factor

N(d1) in front of S in the call price formula thus gives the hedge

ratio ∆.

39

Page 40: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• c is an increasing function of S since∂

∂SN(d1) is always posi-

tive. Also, the value of c is bounded between 0 and 1.

• The curve of c against S changes concavity at

Sc = X exp

(−(r+

3σ2

2

)

so that the curve is concave upward for 0 ≤ S < Sc and concave

downward for Sc < S <∞.

limτ→∞

∂c

∂S= 1 for all values of S,

while

limτ→0+

∂c

∂S=

1 if S > X12 if S = X0 if S < X

.

40

Page 41: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Variation of the delta of the European call value with respect to the

asset price S. The curve changes concavity at S = Xe−(r+3σ2

2

)τ.

41

Page 42: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Variation of the delta of the European call value with respect to

time to expiry τ . The delta value always tends to one from below

when the time to expiry tends to infinity. The delta value tends to

different asymptotic limits as time comes close to expiry, depending

on the moneyness of the option.

42

Page 43: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Continuous dividend yield models

Let q denote the constant continuous dividend yield, that is, the

holder receives dividend of amount equal to qS dt within the interval

dt. The asset price dynamics is assumed to follow the Geometric

Brownian MotiondS

S= ρ dt+ σ dZ.

We form a riskless hedging portfolio by short selling one unit of the

European call and long holding units of the underlying asset. The

differential of the portfolio value Π is given by

43

Page 44: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

dΠ = −dc+ dS + qS dt

=

(−∂c∂t

− σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2+ qS

)dt+

(− ∂c

∂S

)dS.

The last term qS dt is the wealth added to the portfolio due to

the dividend payment received. By choosing =∂c

∂S, we obtain a

riskless hedge for the portfolio. The hedged portfolio should earn

the riskless interest rate.

We then have

dΠ =

(−∂c∂t

− σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2+ qS

∂c

∂S

)dt = r

(−c+ S

∂c

∂S

)dt,

which leads to

∂c

∂τ=σ2

2S2 ∂

2c

∂S2+(r− q)S

∂c

∂S− rc, τ = T − t, 0 < S < ∞, τ > 0.

44

Page 45: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Martingale pricing approach

Suppose all the dividend yields received are used to purchase addi-

tional units of asset, then the wealth process of holding one unit of

asset initially is given by

St = eqtSt,

where eqt represents the growth factor in the number of units. The

wealth process St follows

dSt

St= (ρ+ q) dt+ σ dZ.

We would like to find the equivalent risk neutral measure Q under

which the discounted wealth process S∗t is Q-martingale. We choose

γ(t) in the Radon-Nikodym derivative to be

γ(t) =ρ+ q − r

σ.

45

Page 46: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Now Z is Brownian process under Q and

dZ = dZ +ρ+ q − r

σdt.

Also, S∗t becomes Q-martingale since

dS∗t

S∗t

= σ dZ.

The asset price St under the equivalent risk neutral measure Q be-

comesdSt

St= (r − q) dt+ σ dZ.

Hence, the risk neutral drift rate of St is r − q.

Analogy with foreign currency options

The continuous yield model is also applicable to options on foreign

currencies where the continuous dividend yield can be considered as

the yield due to the interest earned by the foreign currency at the

foreign interest rate rf .

46

Page 47: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Call and put price formulas

The price of a European call option on a continuous dividend paying

asset can be obtained by changing S to Se−qτ in the price formula.

This rule of transformation is justified since the drift rate of the

dividend yield paying asset under the risk neutral measure is r − q.

Now, the European call price formula with continuous dividend yield

q is found to be

c = Se−qτN(d1) −Xe−rτN(d2),

where

d1 =ln SX + (r − q+ σ2

2 )τ

σ√τ

, d2 = d1 − σ√τ .

47

Page 48: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Similarly, the European put formula with continuous dividend yield

q can be deduced from the Black-Scholes put price formula to be

p = Xe−rτN(−d2) − Se−qτN(−d1).

The new put and call prices satisfy the put-call parity relation

p = c− Se−qτ +Xe−rτ .

Furthermore, the following put-call symmetry relation can also be

deduced from the above call and put price formulas

c(S, τ ;X, r, q) = p(X, τ ;S, q, r),

48

Page 49: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• The put price formula can be obtained from the corresponding

call price formula by interchanging S with X and r with q in the

formula. Recall that a call option entitles its holder the right to

exchange the riskless asset for the risky asset, and vice versa for

a put option. The dividend yield earned from the risky asset is

q while that from the riskless asset is r.

• If we interchange the roles of the riskless asset and risky asset

in a call option, the call becomes a put option, thus giving the

justification for the put-call symmetry relation.

49

Page 50: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Time dependent parameters

Suppose the model parameters become deterministic functions of

time, the Black-Scholes equation has to be modified as follows

∂V

∂τ=σ2(τ)

2S2 ∂

2V

∂S2+[r(τ)−q(τ)] S ∂V

∂S−r(τ)V, 0 < S < ∞, τ > 0,

where V is the price of the derivative security.

When we apply the following transformations: y = lnS and w =

e∫ τ0 r(u) duV , then

∂w

∂τ=σ2(τ)

2

∂2w

∂y2+

[r(τ) − q(τ) − σ2(τ)

2

]∂w

∂y.

Consider the following form of the fundamental solution

f(y, τ) =1√

2πs(τ)exp

(−[y+ e(τ)]2

2s(τ)

),

50

Page 51: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

it can be shown that f(y, τ) satisfies the parabolic equation

∂f

∂τ=

1

2s′(τ)

∂2f

∂y2+ e′(τ)

∂f

∂y.

Suppose we let

s(τ) =

∫ τ

0σ2(u) du

e(τ) =∫ τ

0[r(u) − q(u)] du− s(τ)

2,

one can deduce that the fundamental solution is given by

φ(y, τ) =1√

2π∫ τ0 σ

2(u) duexp

y+∫ τ0 [r(u) − q(u) − σ2(u)

2 ] du22∫ τ0 σ

2(u) du

.

Given the initial condition w(y,0), the solution can be expressed as

w(y, τ) =

∫ ∞

−∞w(ξ,0) φ(y − ξ, τ) dξ.

51

Page 52: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Note that the time dependency of the coefficients r(τ), q(τ) and

σ2(τ) will not affect the spatial integration with respect to ξ. We

make the following substitutions in the option price formulas

r is replaced by1

τ

∫ τ

0r(u) du

q is replaced by1

τ

∫ τ

0q(u) du

σ2 is replaced by1

τ

∫ τ

0σ2(u) du.

For example, the European call price formula is modified as follows:

c = Se−∫ τ0 q(u) du N(d1) −Xe−

∫ τ0 r(u) duN(d2)

where

d1 =ln SX +

∫ τ0 [r(u) − q(u) + σ2(u)

2 ] du√∫ τ

0 σ2(u) du

, d2 = d1 −√∫ τ

0σ2(u) du.

52

Page 53: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Implied volatilities

The only unobservable parameter in the Black-Scholes formulas is

the volatility value, σ. By inputting an estimated volatility value, we

obtain the option price. Conversely, given the market price of an

option, we can back out the corresponding Black-Scholes implied

volatiltiy .

• Several implied volatility values obtained simultaneously from

different options (varying strikes and maturities) on the same

underlying asset provide the market view about the volatility of

the stochastic movement of the asset price.

• Given the market prices of European call options with different

maturities (all have the strike prices of 105, current asset price

is 106.25 and short-term interest rate over the period is flat at

5.6%).

maturity 1-month 3-month 7-monthValue 3.50 5.76 7.97

Implied volatility 21.2% 30.5% 19.4%

53

Page 54: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Time dependent volatility

The Black-Scholes formulas remain valid for time dependent volatil-

ity except that

√1

T − t

∫ T

tσ(τ)2 dτ is used to replace σ.

How to obtain σ(t) given the implied volatility measured at time t∗

of a European option expiring at time t. Now

σimp(t∗, t) =

√1

t− t∗

∫ t

t∗σ(τ)2 dτ

so that∫ t

t∗σ(τ)2 dτ = σ2

imp(t∗, t)(t− t∗).

Differentiate with respect to t, we obtain

σ(t) =

σimp(t∗, t)2 + 2(t− t∗)σimp(t∗, t)

∂σimp(t∗, t)

∂t.

54

Page 55: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Practically, we do not have a continuous differentiable implied volatil-

ity function σimp(t∗, t), but rather implied volatilities are available at

discrete instants ti. Suppose we assume σ(t) to be piecewise con-

stant over (ti−1, ti), then

(ti − t∗)σ2imp(t

∗, ti) − (ti−1 − t∗)σ2imp(t

∗, ti−1)

=

∫ titi−1

σ2(τ) dτ = σ2(t)(ti − ti−1), ti−1 < t < ti,

σ(t) =

√√√√(ti − t∗)σ2imp(t

∗, ti−1) − (ti−1 − t∗)σ2imp(t

∗, ti−1)

ti − ti−1, ti−1 < t < ti.

55

Page 56: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Quanto-prewashing techniques

1. Consider two assets whose dynamics follow the lognormal pro-

cesses

df

f= µf dt+ σf dZf

dg

g= µg dt+ σg dZg.

By the Ito Lemma

d(fg)

fg= (µf + µg + ρσfσg) dt+ σ dZ

where σ2 = σ2f + σ2

g + 2ρσfσg;

d(f/g)

f/g= (µf − µg − ρσfσg + σ2

g ) dt+ σ dZ

where σ2 = σ2f + σ2

g − 2ρσfσg.

56

Page 57: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Proof

d(fg) = f dg+ g df + ρσfσgfg dt︸ ︷︷ ︸arising from dfdg and

observing dZfdZg = ρ dt

d(fg)

fg=

dg

g+df

f+ ρσfσg dt

= (µf + µg+ ρσfσg) dt+ σf dZf + σg dZg. (1)

Observe that the sum of two Brownian processes remains to be

Brownian. Recall the formula

VAR(X + Y ) = VAR(X) + VAR(Y ) + 2COV(X, Y ).

Hence, the sum of σf dZf + σg dZg can be expressed as σ dZ, where

σ2 = σ2f + σ2

g + 2ρσfσg.

57

Page 58: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

d

(1

g

)= −dg

g2+

2

g3dg2

2; (2)

d(1g

)

1g

= −µg dt+ σ2g dt− σg dZg. (3)

Replacing g by 1/g in formula (1), we obtain

d(f/g)

f/g= (µf − µg − ρσfσg + σ2

g ) dt+ σf dZf − σg dZg. (4)

Recall the formula: VAR(X−Y ) = VAR(X)+VAR(Y )−2COV(X, Y ).

The sum of σf dZf − σg dZy can be expressed as σ dZ, where

σ2 = σ2f + σ2

g − 2ρσfσg.

58

Page 59: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

2. S = foreign asset price in foreign currency

F = exchange rate

= domestic currency price of one unit of foreign currency

S∗ = FS = foreign asset price in domestic currency

q = dividend yield of the asset.

Under the domestic risk neutral measure Qd, the risk neutral

drift rate of S∗ and F are

δdS∗ = rd − q and δdF = rd − rf .

Under the foreign Qf , the risk neutral drift rate for S and 1/F

are

δfS = rf − q and δ

f1/F

= rf − rd.

59

Page 60: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Quanto prewashing is to find δdS, that is, the risk neutral drift rate

of the price of the asset in foreign currency under Qd.

Recall the formula:

δdS∗ = δdFS = δdF + δdS + ρσFσS

where the dynamics of S and F under Qd are

dS

S= δdS dt+ σS dZ

dS

dF

F= δdF dt+ σF dZ

dF ,

where ZdS and ZdF are Qd-Brownian process.

60

Page 61: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

We obtain

δdS = δdS∗ − δdF − ρσFσS

= (rd − q) − (rd − rf) − ρσFσS

= (rf − q) − ρσFσS.

Comparing with δfS = rf − q and δdS, there is an extra term −ρσFσS.

The risk neutral drift rate of the asset is changed by the amount

−ρσFσS when the risk neutral measure is changed from the foreign

currency world to the domestic currency world.

61

Page 62: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Siegel’s paradox

Given that the price dynamics of F under Qd is

dF

F= (rd − rf) dt+ σF dZd,

then the process for 1/F is

d(1/F)

1/F= (rf − rd + σ2

F ) dt− σF dZd.

This is seen as a puzzle to many people since the risk neutral drift

rate for 1/F should be rf − rd instead of rf − rd + σ2F .

We observe directly from the above SDE’s that

σF = σ1/F and ρF,1/F = −1.

62

Page 63: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

An interesting application of Siegel’s paradox

Suppose the terminal payoff of an exchange rate option is FT1FT>K.Let V d(F, t) denote the value of the option in the domestic currency

world. Define

V f(Ft, t) = V d(Ft, t)/Ft,

so that the terminal payoff of the exchange rate option in foreign

currency world is 1FT>K. Now

V f(F, t) = e−rf(T−t)EQft [1FT>K|Ft = F ].

63

Page 64: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

From δd1/F = δ

f1/F

+ σ2F and observing σF = σ1/F , we deduce that

δfF = δdF + σ2

F .

This is easily seen if we interchange the foreign and domestic cur-

rency worlds. We obtain

V d(F, t) = FV f(F, t) = e−rf(T−t)FN(d)

where

d =ln FK +

(δfF − σ2

F2

σ√τ

=ln FK +

(rd − rf +

σ2F2

σ√τ

.

64

Page 65: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Foreign exchange options

Under the domestic risk neutral measure Qd, the exchange rate

process follows

dF

F= (rd − rf) dt+ σF dZF .

Suppose the terminal payoff is max(FT − Xd,0), then the price of

the exchange rate call option is

V (F, τ) = Fe−rfτN(d1) −Xde−rdτN(d2),

where

d1 =ln FXd

+

(rd − rf +

σ2F2

σF√τ

, d2 = d1 − σF√τ .

65

Page 66: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Equity options with exchange rate risk exposure

Quanto options are contingent claims whose payoff is determined

by a financial price or index in one currency but the actual payout

is done in another currency.

1. Foreign equity call struck in foreign currency

c1(ST , F,0) = FT max(ST −Xf ,0).

2. Foreign equity call struck in domestic currency

c2(ST , F,0) = max(FTST −Xd,0).

3. Foreign exchange rate foreign equity call

c3(ST , F,0) = F0 max(ST −Xf ,0).

66

Page 67: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Under the domestic risk neutral measure Qd

dS

S= δdS dt+ σS dZS

dF

F= δdF dt+ σF dZF

S∗ = FS = asset price in domestic currency

dS∗

S∗ = δdS∗ dt+ σS∗ dZS∗.

where ZS, ZF , and ZS∗ are all Qd-Brownian processes.

By Ito’s lemma,

δdS∗ = δdS + δdF + ρSFσSσF

σ2S∗ = σ2

S + σ2F + 2ρSFσSσF .

Under the risk neutral measures,

δdS∗ = rd − q, δdF = rd − rf , δfS = rf − q,

δdS = δdS∗ − δdF − ρSFσSσF = rf − q − ρSFσSσF = δfS − ρSFσSσF .

67

Page 68: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

1. Define

c1(S, F, τ)/F = c1(S, τ) so that c1(S,0) = max(S −Xf ,0).

This call option behaves like the usual vanilla call option in the

foreign currency world so that

c1(S,0) = Se−qτN(d(1)1 ) −Xfe

−rfτN(d(1)2 )

where

d(1)1 =

ln SXf

+

(δfS +

σ2S2

σS√τ

, d(1)2 = d

(1)1 − σS

√τ .

68

Page 69: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

2. c2(S, F,0) = max(S∗T −Xd,0)

c2(S, F, τ) = S∗e−qτN(d(2)1 ) −Xde

−rdτN(d(2)2 )

where

d(2)1 =

ln S∗Xd

+

(δdS∗ +

σ2S∗2

σ∗S√τ

, d(2)2 = d

(2)1 − σ∗S

√τ ,

σ2S∗ = σ2

S + σ2F + 2ρSFσSσF .

69

Page 70: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

3. For c3(S,0) = F0 max(ST −Xf ,0), the payoff is denominated in

the domestic currency world, so the risk neutral drift rate is of

the stock price δdS. The call price is

c3(S, τ) = F0e−rdτ [Seδ

dSτN(d

(3)1 ) −XfN(d

(3)2 )]

where

d(3)1 =

ln SXf

+

(δdS +

σ2S2

σS√τ

, d(3)2 = d

(3)1 − σS

√τ .

• The price formula does not depend on the exchange rate F since

the exchange rate has been chosen to be the fixed value F0.

• The currency exposure is reflected through the dependence on

σF and correlation coefficient ρSF .

70

Page 71: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Digital quanto option relating 3 currency worlds

FS\U = SGD currency price of one unit of USD currency

FH\S = HKD currency price of one unit of SGD currency

• Digital quanto option payoff: pay one HKD if FS\U is above

some strike level K.

• We may interest FS\U as the price process of a tradeable asset

in SGD. The dynamics is governed by

dFS\UFS\U

= (rSGD − rUSD) dt+ σFS\U dZSFS\U

.

71

Page 72: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

• Given δSFS\U= rSGD − rUSD, how to find δHFS\U

, which is the risk

neutral drift rate of the SGD asset denominated in Hong Kong

dollar?

• By the quanto-prewashing technique

δHFS\U= δSFS\U

− ρσFS\UσFH\S .

• Digital option value = EQH

t

[1FS\U>K

]= N(d)

where

d =

lnFS\UK +

δHFS\U −

σ2FS\U2

τ

σFS\U√τ

.

72

Page 73: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Exchange options

Exchange asset 2 for asset 1 so that the terminal payoff is

V (S1, S2,0) = max(S1 − S2,0).

Assume

dS1

S1= δS1

dt+ σ1 dZ1, δS1= r − q1,

dS2

S2= δS2

dt+ σ2 dZ2, δS2= r − q2.

Define S =S1

S2, σ2S = σ2

1−2ρ12σ1σ2+σ22. Write

V (S1, S2,0)

S2= max

(S1

S2− 1,0

).

V (S1, S2, τ) = e−rτ[S1e

δS1τN(d1) − S2eδS2τN(d2)

], where

d1 =ln S1S2

+

[(δS1

− δS2

)+

σ2S2

σS√τ

, d2 = d1 − σS√τ .

73

Page 74: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Hints on the proof of the price formula

Under the risk neutral measure

dS

S= (δS1

− δS2− ρ12σ1σ2 + σ2

2) dt+ σ1 dZ1 − σ2 dZ2.

It is convenient to use S2(t)eq2t as numeraire, where

S2(t) = S2(0)e

(δS2−

σ222

)t+σ2Z2(t)

or

S2(t)eq2t

S2(0)e−rt = e−

σ222 t+σ2Z2(t).

We can take γ = −σ2 in Girsanov Theorem so that

S2(t)eq2t

S2(0)e−rt = e−

12σ

22t+σ2Z2(t) =

dQ∗

dQ.

74

Page 75: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

We then have dZ2 = dZ2 − σ2 dt where dZ2 is under Q∗. In a similar

manner, we obtain

dZ1 = dZ1 − ρ12σ2 dt.

Putting everything together,

dS

S= (δS1

− δS2) dt+ (σ1 dZ1 − σ2 dZ2)

and

σ1 dZ1 − σ2 dZ2 = σ dZ

where

σ2 = σ21 + σ2

2 − 2ρ12σ1σ2.

75

Page 76: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

Use of the exchange option formula to price quanto options

Consider

C2(S, F,0) = F max(S −X,0) = max(S∗ −XF,0)

C4(S, F,0) = Smax(F −X,0) = max(S∗ −XS,0)

where S∗ = FS. Both can be considered as exchange options.

Though an exchange option appears to be a two-state option, it

can be reduced to an one-state pricing model when the similarity

variable S =S1

S2is defined. Similarly, the two-state quanto options

can be reduced to one-state pricing models.

76

Page 77: 4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes …maykwok/courses/ma571/06_07/...4. Option pricing models under the Black-Scholes framework Riskless hedging principle Writer of

For valuation of C4(S, F, τ), we consider the similarity variableS∗

S=

F . Note that

δdS∗ = δdS + δdF + ρSFσSσF , σ = σF ,

and the corresponding difference in the risk neutral drift rates in Qdis

δdS∗ − δdS = δdF + ρSFσSσF = rd − rf + ρSFσSσF .

77


Recommended