+ All Categories
Home > Documents > 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING...

5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING...

Date post: 27-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
37
5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING OF THE POOR
Transcript
Page 1: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING OF

THE POOR

Page 2: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

5. OUTREACH OF MICROFINANCE PROGRAMMES AND

TARGETING OF THE POOR

5.1 INTRODUCTION

A number of anti-poverty policies and programmes have been launched in India

during the 1970s and 1980s, including those of credit delivery programmes, targeting

the poor. Various methodologies have been devised and nation wide surveys have

been conducted in identifying the poor for the successful delivery of the programmes.

Unfortunately, such programmes have always been under criticism for mistargeting

either due to lackluster implementation or elite capture at the ground level. For

example, Gaiha eta!. (2001a) argued that benefit to the rural poor of two major anti­

poverty programmes (Rural Public Works and Integrated Rural Development

Programme) are likely to be limited, given their gross mistargeting. Larger sections

among the poor were not covered and moreover, the non-poor were the majority

among the participants. Similar outcomes were also reported by Dreze (1990) in his

study on IRDP in the state of Uttar Pradesh. Such mediocre targeting and performance

of the public programmes on poverty alleviation during the 1980s questioned the

poverty alleviation strategies, particularly identifying poor households/individuals,

besides other bottlenecks in governance and appropriateness. During this period,

many developing countries of Asia, Africa and Latin America reported success of a

new form of targeting the poor which was pioneered by Grameen Bank in Bangladesh.

Inspired by popularity of Grameen's group-based targeting mechanism, and

recognising credit as the main instrument in attacking poverty, microfinance

programmes in India are promoted primarily as a substitute of anti-poverty

programmes through delivering credit for expanding production and employment

choices of poor.

The country-wide spread of microfinance programmes in recent years is

overwhelming and it has generated concern among researchers and policymakers in

scrutinizing the outcomes of such large outlay, most particularly the issue of targeting.

Indeed, the concern arises while one looks at the people in the lower strata of income

distribution -the very poor category. They may be too poorly informed, educated or

nourished to take advantage of the programme, they may not possess required

Page 3: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

documents such as caste certificates or proofs of residence, they may be socially

ostracized or they may even face agency problems that lead bureaucrats and local

politicians to divert resources to the non-target sections of population. Further, there is

empirical evidence from a variety of social programmes in both developed and

developing countries that information sets differ, even among those eligible, and that

participation rates vary widely and are sensitive to programme design. In Bangladesh,

programmes with clear eligibility conditions have often been violated them due to

expectation of higher returns from wealthy borrowers (Morduch, 1998; Rahman,

1999). In the case oflndia, many ofthe group-based microfinance programmes do not

have any clear cut guidelines in targeting and therefore, the possible bias against the

very poor cannot be ruled out. One of the leading microfinance institutions (MFis) in

India believes that MFis are designed to serve the poor and, as a trickle down effect in

the rural economy, the poor will take care of the very poor (Mahajan, BASIX

webpage). Although there has been a plethora of research in assessing the impact of

these programmes on a variety of outcomes 1, in developing as well as developed

countries, there has been little research on how well targeted these group-based

microcredit programmes actually are. Besides, researchers also widely differ in

methodology of identifying poor. In the case of India, both the issues are still under

scrutiny and there is little empirical research from academia in identifying the

targeting of microfinance programmes.

The chapter, thus, examines the extent to which these new institutional arrangements

have been successful in delivering financial services to the poor or the very poor. In

view of unavailability of published data for measurement of targeting, the present

study employs household level data collected from field work in Madhya Pradesh.

The first section of the chapter briefly discusses the review of literature pertaining to

the issue of targeting of microfinance programme. The second section discusses the

data and methodology of the study. The third section analyses the estimation results.

5.2 LITERATURE REVIEW

Microfinance programmes have been under scrutiny, since their inception,

particularly on the issue of targeting. Basically targeting has been debated as a

1 See Hulme and Mosley, 1996a; 1996b; Pitt and Khandker, 1996; 1998; Morduch, 1998; Zaman, 2000; Puhazhedi and Satyasai, 2000; Puhazhedi and Badatya, 2002, Khandker, 2003.

[i44]

Page 4: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

methodological problem. Measuring poverty outreach of clients of microfinance

programmes by using any particular methodology is also difficult because the profile

of clients and concept of poverty varies across regions and population groups. So

poverty measured in a purist fashion (e.g. those living below x number of rupees) may

not be a very good indicator for targeting, because measuring income of household is

itself difficult and importantly, poverty has been looked at through the window of

capability of the household rather than simple income (Henry et al., 2000). Further,

unavailability of income data and questions on its reliability have very often

motivated the practitioners of microfincance programmes to use alternate indicators of

targeting, such as SEF's Participatory Wealth Ranking, Cashpor House Index and

CGAP's proposed poverty assessment tool which help in deriving relative poverty

instead of absolute income poverty. Navajas, et al. (2000) argued that unless there is

an appropriate targeting tool, the poorest will either be missed or they will tend to

exclude themselves because they do not see the programmes as being for them.

Besides methodological problems, there are design issues of microfinance

programmes which also affect targeting. For instance, if the designed products of the

microfinance programme do not suit the need of the poor, then their proportion

diminishes over time (Wright, 2000).

Many empirical studies have attempted measuring targeting of microfinance

programmes by employing different methodologies of measuring poverty 2 .

Constructing an index of fulfillment of basic needs, Navajas et al. (2000) found that

most of the poor households reached by the microfinance organizations were near the

poverty line. They were the richest of the poor. Amin et a!. (2003) used distribution

functions of consumption expenditure between members and non-members to

examine stochastic dominance of one distribution over the other. Further, they

attempted to measure vulnerability in a risk sharing framework of Townsend (1994)

and conclude that microcredit is successful at reaching the poor but it is unsuccessful

in reaching the vulnerable. Some studies have attempted measuring targeting of

microfinance programmes by estimating the differences between the share of

participants and non-participants in some pre-determined intervals of the income

distribution, say income quartiles, quintiles or deciles. This is especially common in

studies concerned with the incidence of public spending on infrastructural facilities

2 See Navajas eta!., 2000; Am in eta/., 2003; Diagne and Zeller, 2001.

Page 5: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

(van de Walle and Nead, 1995; Castro-Leal et al., 1999). With no targeting, the share

of an income group in the benefits of public spending would be equal to its population

share and in well targeted programmes the share of benefits to the poor is high

relative to their population share. Diagne and Zeller (2001) have examined targeting

by using probability regressions which estimates probability that a household

participates in the programme as a function of income and other household

characteristics. The use of probability regression takes into account the nonlinearities

in the marginal effects of income on participation. However, the method has been

subject to criticism as it assumes that the probability of participation is monotonic in

each of the explanatory variables. So some studies have preferred non-parametric

estimates. For example, if the set of households with low participation rates is small

relative to the population, they may also remain undetected when examining the

proportion of programme participants in arbitrarily chosen intervals of the income

distribution, especially ifthey are in income groups where other households have high

participation rates. In a study of microfinance programme in India, Somanathan and

Dewan (2003) used empirical distribution functions to show that there is possibility of

the very poor to get excluded from the programme. Ravall ion ( 1991) had used

empirical distribution functions to evaluate targeting in the Employment Guarantee

Scheme in Maharashtra and, similarly, Gaiha (2001b) used the distribution functions

to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes in India.

However, there is increasing acceptance that traditional Microfinance programmes are

not reaching the poorest of the poor-indeed they are rarely reaching the bottom 10-

15 percent of the population. This is largely driven by the nature of the financial

services provided by the MFis which force the poor members of the community to

choose not to join, and those who are required to guarantee or follow-up their loans to

chose to exclude the poorest. An MFI's ability to attract the poorest depends on the

financial services it offers and whether they have been designed to be appropriate for

the needs of the poor members ofthe community. Rutherford (1995) and Wright eta/.

(1997) argued that the exclusion of the poorest is also driven by the emphasis on

credit delivery by many organizations. For the poorest households the opportunities

for productive use of loans are limited and the risk of taking loans that are repayable

on a weekly basis are unacceptably high. Similarly, Gaiha (2001 b) reviewed the

Maharashtra Rural Credit Project (MRCP), a microcredit scheme in India, and draws

Page 6: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

attention to the deficiencies in the design and implementation ofthis scheme that limit

the participation of the poorest and the benefits accruing to them. In a study of SEWA

Bank in Ahmedabad, it has been found about 40 percent of borrower households live

in poverti. Further, the sensitivity ofthe poverty headcount suggests that households

in the sample cluster around the poverty line while most ofthem are either just above

it or just below it. So, clearly it does not include the poorest (Chen and Snodgrass,

1999).

An interesting study of ASA ( 1997), surveying 626 respondents, revealed various

reasons for which the poorest do not prefer to join the group. Lack of minimum

clothing to attend meetings, infl uence of the local elite (moneylenders, religious

leaders, union chairman etc.) to not to join the programme, the screening procedure of

the programme to exclude the risky clients and the obligation of weekly savings were

some of the reasons which excluded the poorest from the programme.

In view of the above we propose to analyse targeting by use of different

methodologies, including means tests, non-parametric tests, probability regressions

and non-parametric tests using distribution functions of income as also level of living

index which is constructed by multivariate analysis. The use of different

methodologies will help us to arrive at a conclusion which may be more credible and

acceptable to the larger audience.

5.3 DATA AND METHODOLOGY

5.3.1 Data

As mentioned in chapter 3, published data sources are insufficient to measure

targeting of microfinance programmes. So, we collected household level data from

the fieldwork carried out in two different districts of Madhya Pradesh. The study was

focused on three most popular microfinance programmes in India, as they are

implemented. The detail description of the study area, microfinance programmes,

survey methodology and sample selection is provided in chapter 4. However, our total

sample consists of 270 households, with participants and non-participants sample

being in the ratio of 2: 1.

3 The study uses poverty line specified by the World Bank and adjusts it for purchasing power parity (PPP) and prices.

Page 7: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

5.3.2 Methodology

5.3.2.1 Difference between Population Groups- Parametric Approach

A general method of observing absolute differences in participant and non-participant

households is to compare the average value of various indicators from the two

samples by using an appropriate test statistic. For example, we apply t-test to test·

whether the mean for per capita income is the same for participants and non­

participants. It may be noted that the t-test assumes that the samples are drawn

randomly from two normal populations with the same unknown variance. In case the

population distributions are not normal, but the sample size is fairly large, one can

still apply t-test by invoking central limit theorem which treats the distribution to be

asymptotic normal. If the number of groups exceeds two, we apply ANOVA test to

measure whether the mean indicator is same across the groups.

A number of indicators are compared for participants and non-participants by using t­

test procedure. It has been noted earlier that the participant sample is drawn from

three different programmes. It is, therefore, a matter of interest to know if the mean

indicators across the different groups are same. Treating the participant sample into

three different groups, we apply ANOV A to test the null hypothesis that the mean

indicator across the different groups, including non-participants, is same. A rejection

oft-test would imply that the sample means are different for different groups. Further,

the tests are also supported by graphical representation of the distribution functions

across participants and non-participants and also across different categories of

population.

5.3.2.2 Difference between Population Groups - Non-parametric Approach

We apply the non-parametric tests to the null hypothesis of equality of distributions

between population groups, pertaining to various indicators. For example, we denote

the population distribution of the level of living index of the members in the

microcredit programme by F(X) and the distribution for the non-members byG(X).

Let the two samples are denoted by X,, X 2 , ••• , X11

andY,, Y2 ••• , Ym respectively.

We begin with commonly used tests for the equality of two distributions. The

Kolmogorov-Smirnov (KS) is used to test the null hypothesis of equal distributions

Page 8: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

against the very general alternative that the distributions are unequal. KS test statistic

measures the maximum difference between the two empirical distribution functions.

Large values of the statistic are evidence against equal distributions and lead to the

rejection of null hypothesis. The exact null probability distribution is available in

tabulated form for small samples. We use critical values based on the asymptotic

distribution, as our sample size of members and nonmembers are both sufficiently

large.

KS test is often used for preliminary studies of data since the alternatives involved are

very general. To test the null hypothesis against the more specific alternative of

stochastic dominance of the non-member distribution, F(X) ~ G(X) for all X ,

F(X) > G(X) for some X, we use the more powerful Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney

(MW) test. The MW statistic is defined as the number of times an X precedes a Y in

the combined ordered arrangement of the two independent random samples X1

,

X 2 , ••• , X n and Y1 , Y2 ••• , Ym into a single sequence of m + n = N observations,

in ascending order of magnitude. We use critical values based on the asymptotic

distribution of MW under the null hypothesis. This has been shown to be normal with

mean and variance. The null hypothesis is rejected for large values of the statistic. The

test performs particularly well as a test for equality of means (or medians).

5.3.2.3 Examining Targeting by Probability Regression

We employ probit probability regression to estimate the probability of joining

microfinance programme by analysing a number of household and village level

characteristics. Use of probit or logit regression is on the basis of the assumption

regarding the distribution of sample variance. We have a fairly large sample and every

household was free to join the programme. Whether the household joins or not is,

therefore, a case of self selection issue. The latent threshold limits of joining or not­

joining the programme are unobserved for any particular household. In this context,

we assume sample variance to be normally distributed and therefore, we employ

probit regression. When & is normal E(& 1 x) = 0 and var(& 1 x) =I , the pdf is

&2 r I 12 ¢(&)= ,1.-exp(--) andcdfis <D(&)= ~exp(-)dt (Long, 1997).

"2" 2 "'-v2rr 2

Page 9: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Using the probit regression, we estimated the predicted marginal effects and the

predicted probabilities of participation, given X variables. Plotting the predicted

probabilities across per capita income will give us idea about the probability of

participation of households at different points of the income distribution. Therefore,

we can estimate the probability of participation for the households below a threshold

level of living. If the probability of participation below this threshold level is higher

than those above the threshold level, then the programme is well targeted. Therefore,

we can examine the depth of outreach of the programme by using probability

regression.

5.3.2.4 Examining Targeting by "Level of Living" Index

In view of the growing realization that income poverty only partly explains household

vulnerability, researchers have suggested a number of indicators combining economic

as well as social indicators which enhance household capacity to realize a subsistence

level of living. The emphasis on a variety of indicators stems from a realization that

poverty is multidimensional and that any one indicator would not be capable of

capturing poverty levels across different regions and different population groups. A

combination of such socio-economic indicators may help construction of an index that

may be able to explain the relative levels of poverty across households (Henry eta!.,

2000). In the framework of CGAP poverty assessment in microfinance programmes, a

level of living index is constructed using principal component analysis. The index is

constructed using the following variables: type of roof of house, type of wall of house,

type of floor of house, workforce participation rate, any salaried person in the

household, own land, value of productive assets such as livestock, farming assets and

transport assets, annual per capita income, monthly per capita expenditure on clothing

and footwear, education of principal earning member, adult literacy ratio and level of

food security of household during the year. The choice of variables used in the

analysis was based on CGAP proposed indicators 4 and on the basis of field

observation of what captures poverty in this region and on the share of total variance

in the set which was accounted for by the first principal component, which we used as

our index5. To be comprehensive, at least one variable was chosen from each section

4 See Henry et a!., 2000. 5 The level of living index provides a tool to calibrate relative poverty-the extent to which a household is worse off or better off compared to other households. It does not by itself provide

Page 10: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

of the survey to ensure that all aspects of the households' economic condition were

considered.

The construction of "level of living" index uses the method of principal component

analysis (PCA) for obtaining the first principal component to be used as the composite

index. PCA enables construction of a composite index (first principal component) as a

linear combination of standardised indicators with weights obtained from the eigen

vector corresponding to the largest eigen value. It may be pointed out that all the

components are orthogonal, and the first principal component accounts for the largest

amount of variance in the data matrix. The present study uses only the first principal

component as the composite index, as it has the largest possible explanatory power.

Use of more than one principal component would bring in the problem of aggregation

of orthogonal components which should be avoided due to its dubious theoretical

validity.

We also apply the t-tests and the non-parametric tests to "level of living" index score,

which is used as a proxy for household standard of living, in our analysis. We test for

differences in the mean value of this index across participants and non-participants

and also across the four groups. The fairly strong distributional assumptions, under

which these tests are valid, may not be appropriate in the present study since there

may be differences in the distributions of participants and non-participants, or within

different groups among participants, which are reflected, not in their means, but rather

in the tails of these distributions. The wealthier might be ineligible for rural anti­

poverty programmes and the poor might be excluded from them for a variety of social

and economic reasons.

Further, we draw the non-parametric distribution functions of the index scores by

applying k-density estimates for the participants and non-participants. For example, if

the k-density distribution of index scores belonging to participants sample shifts to

right of the non-participants it implies that the later group is worse off than the former.

The exercise is conducted across different member groups as well to understand if

there is any difference across participants belonging to different programmes.

information on the absolute level of poverty, the actual level of depravation of the lowest category of households or the level of affluence of the higher group.

Page 11: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

5.4 ESTIMATION RESULTS

5.4.1 Differences in Household Characteristics

Table 5.1 maps average values of different indicators pertaining to participant and

non-participant households. The exercise has been carried on for the aggregative

sample and also for the samples pertaining to the two districts separately. Further, we

also look at the differences in sample means of participants belonging to different

microfinance programmes, as given in Table 5.2. Tests are applied for the indicators

including demographic structure such as household size and number of children of

age upto 6 yrs; economic status captured by number of usual workers in the

household, agricultural landowned and percent of households reporting self­

employment in off-farm business; value of productive assets such as livestock,

farming and transportation; consumption expenditure per capita on food, clothing and

footwear and total monthly consumption per capita; and monthly income per capita. It

can be seen from the Table 5.1 that average household size of the participant

households is significantly higher than non-participants in total sample as well as in

district samples separately. The difference among average number of children upto

age of 6 years is not significant either in Betul or in Sehore. The average number of

usual workers is significantly higher for the member households than the non­

members in Betul whereas there does not seem to be much difference across the

groups in Sehore. However, the work participation ratio (workers/household size)

turns out to be high among the non-member households than their counterparts, in

each of the districts as also in aggregate sample. One would, therefore, infer that high

work participation ratio tend to be negatively correlated with programme

participation. Nevertheless, the direction of relationship between programme

participation and work participation rate is a proposition to be examined.

One of the most crucial indicators of economic well-being of rural household IS

agricultural land. This does not seem to be different across the population groups. The

test statistics are not significant for any of the categories. However, percent

households reporting self-employment in off-farm activities (excluding livestock) is

much higher for the participant households than their counterpart in Betul. Indeed,

intervention of PRADAN in promoting poultry, mushroom cultivation and sericulture

among the participating households has helped diversifying their economic portfolio,

Page 12: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

whereas undertaking off-farm activities is a distant possibility for the non-participant

households. However, the sample from Sehore indicates that the overall percent of

households reporting self-employment is higher than that of Betul. Understandably,

the locational factors contribute to creation of opportunities for diversifying

production and employment choices and thus, Sehore being situated near a town has

greater opportunities for undertaking off-farm activities. But there does not seem to be

much difference among the participants and non-participants in terms of off-farm

activities undertaken. It was also observed in the study that there was not much extra

effort by the microfinance programmes in promoting off-farm activities among the

participant households in Sehore. The activities of the participants were mostly self­

induced which might have been indirectly supported by access to finance or market

exposure training provided by the self-help group promoting institution (SHPI). One

would, however, observe higher incidence of off-farm activities by member

households than the non-member households in both the regions and also at the

aggregate level.

One of the direct gains from participating in micro finance programmes in rural areas

seem to be increase in livestock holding which is significantly different for the

participants than the non-participants. Most of the Bank finances provided to the

participants are for livestock and the household's demand for livestock, particularly

buffaloes, is not only for its net contribution to household earning but also for the

purpose of consumption needs. The difference in value of livestock assets across the

groups is well noticeable in both Betul and Sehore. Value of transportation assets is

also higher for the participant households than the non-participants in all the regions

and also at the aggregate level. But the pattern is not similar in accumulation of

farming assets. Overall, the non-participants have higher values of farming assets than

the participants and the difference is mainly due to the high difference observed in

Sehore.

Indicators on consumption items, particularly clothing and footwear, seem to obtain

high average values for the participant households than the non-participants. Many of

the respondents reported that increase in sociability in the recent years (which may be

attributed to the effect of television, increasing schooling of children, interacting with

officials through participating in group-based activities etc.) has led to higher

Page 13: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

spending on clothing and footwear. Noticeably, in Betul many households have

reported expenditure on footwear, which they were not doing before their

participation in self-help groups (SHGs). Similar is the case for clothing of children,

particularly those who are going to school. Attending meetings of SHGs has

positively influenced many households to invest in such necessities of social life.

However, overall monthly consumption per capita is higher for the non-participants

than those of the participants. Similarly, at the aggregate level, average monthly per

capita income of the non-members is higher than that of the members. In Betul,

average income is significantly higher for the non-participants than the participants.

But, the difference is not statistically significant in Sehore, although the average

income is higher for the non-participants than the participants. Indeed, both the

regions report higher monthly per capita income (MPCINC) for the non-participants

than those of the participants. However, the aggregative sample shows that the

difference rarely becomes significant at only 10 percent level. Table 5 .la reports the

non-parametric tests for the two indicators, MPCE and MPCINC, which may reflect

that the difference in population groups may not lie in average but it may be there in

the tails of these distributions. Both K-S test and M-W test reveal that the difference

of MPCE between the participants and non-participants is not statistically significant.

In contrast to that significant difference is noted in MPCINC for the aggregative

sample and also for Betul. Sehore does not report any significant difference in

MPCINC between the two groups. However, the average MPCINC is higher for the

sample population in Sehore than that ofBetul.

One may look at the empirical distribution functions drawn for the two indicators,

MPCE and MPCINC, to understand their behaviour across population groups and

regions. Figure 5 .I reveals that the two distributions cross at a point which implies

that at the lower end of the distribution, members' average consumption is higher than

that of the non-members. But later on the non-members dominate over the members.

Similar patterns are observed for the two regions as well, as given in Figure 5.1a and

5 .I b. Figure 5 .I c shows the distribution functions across non-members and members

belonging to different programmes. It reveals that the members in SWASHAKTI

programme dominate over all groups upto a certain point, but later non-members

dominate over all the member groups. The relatively poorest are the PRADAN

Page 14: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

members as revealed from the figure that the distribution function is way behind all

other groups. Similar exercise is made for mapping MPCINC. Figure 5.2 shows that

the non-members have clearly an edge over the members. At all points along the

distributions, the non-members' curve lie to the right ofthat ofthe members'. Similar

pattern is observed for the regional sample as well (Figure 5.2a and 5.2b). However,

Figure 5.2c represents a criss-cross of distribution curves across members belonging

to different programmes and those of non-members. The distribution of the

SWASHAKTI members' is at the extreme right in most ofthe points while that of the

PRADAN members' is at the extreme left.

Noticeably, the behaviours of multiple indicators indicate that the distribution of

economic well-being for the two groups differs across different indicators and we

cannot come to any conclusion about targeting from examining these indicators

differently. One way is to look at probability of participation with per capita income,

while controlling for other covariates of household (Diagne and Zeller, 2001 ). The

other way is to construct a level of living index by aggregating the multi-dimensional

indicators and measure the relative poverty between members and non-members

(Henry et al., 2000). Both the methods are attempted in the following sections.

Figure 5.1 Distribution Functions of Monthly Per Capita Consumption Expenditure (MPCE) By Membership -All Households

--tr-- Non-member ------Member

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 500 1000 1500 MPCE

Page 15: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

'§' 0. E "(:' 0.

Chapter 5

Figure S.la Distribution Functions of Monthly Per Capita Consumption Expenditure (MPCE) By Membership in Betul

--t:s-- Non-member -~-Member

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 500 1000 1500 MPCE

Figure 5.1b Distribution Functions of Monthly Per Capita Consumption Expenditure (MPCE) By Membership in Sehore

--t:s-- Non-member -~-Member

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 500 1000 MPCE

Page 16: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Figure S.lc Distribution Functions of Monthly Per Capita Consumption Expenditure (MPCE) By SHG Type -All Households

--- Non-member --e---SGSY --6----- Pradan --><--- Swashakti

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 500 1000 1500 MPCE

Figure 5.2 Distribution Functions of Annual Per Capita Income (PCINC) by Membership

--6----- Non-member _...,___ Member

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 5 10 15 20 Annual pcinc (Rs. 000)

r-·----, ! 157 J

Page 17: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

u c: '(3 .e, a.

Chapter 5

Figure 5.2a Distribution Functions of Annual Per Capita Income (PCINC) by Membership in Betul

--ts--- Non-member --<>--- Member

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 5 10 15 20 Annual pcinc (Rs. 000)

Figure 5.2b Distribution Functions of Annual Per Capita Income (PCINC) by Membership in Sehore

--b--- Non-member --<>-- Member

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

0 5 10 15 20 Annual pcinc (Rs. 000)

Page 18: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Figure 5.2c Distribution Functions of Annual Per Capita Income (PCINC) by SHG Type

u c '(3 a.

15:

.8

.6

.4

.2

0

--- Non-member --6--- Pradan

0

--<>--- SGSY _ _,______ Swashakti

5 10 15 Annual pcinc (Rs. 000)

5.4.2 Determinants of Participation: Pro bit Regression Model

5.4.2.1 Data and Variables

20

The pro bit regression 6 is applied to estimate the probability of participation as a

function of level of per capita consumption ofhousehold (as a proxy for income), off­

farm activity, work participation rate, years of schooling of principal earner of

household, adult literacy ratio, productive assets, agricultural land (acres), distance

index7, regional dummy and years of operation of different microfinance programmes

in the villages. The level of monthly per capita consumption is divided into five

quintile groups. For the five quintiles we introduced four dummies in the model,

keeping the dummy of the bottom quintile as the default category. Understandably, if

the programme is appropriately targeted towards the poor then the dummies of the

higher categories should be having negative coefficients, as compared to the default

category.

6 The model assumes normality in distribution of sample variance. 7 See Appendix for details about construction of distance index.

,----, I 159! L_____,

Page 19: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

We have observed from the descriptive statistics that the percentage of households

reporting self employment in non-agricultural activities is higher for the participating

households than the non-participants. However, the variable is introduced as a dummy

to capture the unobserved quality of the household for taking risk in non-farm

activities or the entrepreneurial attitude of any member in the household, which may

induce a person in the household to become a member of the group. Becoming a

member might have helped her/him in getting access to resources for which she/he

could have been able to realize her/his expected earnings. If the expected probability

coefficient is positive and significant then it would confirm that the households with

strong motivation for non-farm activities have higher probability of participation in

the programme.

Work participation ratio (ratio of workers to total household size) captures the stock

of labour in the household. Higher the work participation ratio, lower will be the

dependency ratio and therefore, average per capita earnings will be higher.

Households with higher work participation ratio tend to be in the upper quintile of

income distribution. So the probability coefficient of participation is expected to be

negative with increase in work participation rate in case the programmes are targeted

to the poor.

Education, captured by the indicator years of schooling of principal earning member,

helps enhancing opportunities and economic prospects of the person. Importantly, it

also increases access and participation in different institutions in the village. Literacy

ratio8 (ratio of literate adults to total household members) reflects the capacity of the

household in terms of getting access to the village institutions as well as being aware

about the anti-poverty programmes and policies meant for upliftment of the rural

households. One would, therefore, expect a positive coefficient of probability of

participation for both the educational indicators.

Value of productive assets including farming, livestock and transportation represent

household non-liquid wealth and in the model they are used as control variables.

Owning of agricultural land is another non-liquid wealth which is also used as a

control variable. Distance is a major factor in accessing information and also

8 We have excluded the literacy rate of children (age below 15 years) because the participating decisions in village institutions is taken by the adults.

Page 20: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

accessing village institutions for a rural household. Inaccessibility to outside village

institutions, say local agricultural mandi 9 , local hat 10 or nearest town makes a

household vulnerable to local middleman. More importantly, remoteness restricts

flow of information about different programmes and schemes to the targeted sections.

But capturing distance effect by using a particular distance variable brings biasness in

regression equation as it may overestimate the effect while there are other points

which also influence the household or the households in the entire village. So we

construct a distance index by considering multi-point distances from the village,

measured in kilometers, such as distance of village from block office, nearest town,

bus stop, agricultural mandi and local hat. The hypothesis is that with increase in

score of the distance index household's probability of participation in programme

declines.

Our sample represents two regions and we include a dummy for the region Sehore

which has been selected to represent agriculturally prosperous region and it is also

different because of its better access to state level institutions and better infrastructure

facilities, as compared to Betul. The hypothesis to be examined is whether there exists

any regional effect in participation of programme which will account for the

unobserved effects that the region is representing for.

Finally, we have included three variables for three programme effects which are

introduced as number of years of operation of the programme in the village. For

example, a positive and significant coefficient will imply that with increase in

operation of the programme the rate of participation in the village will increase.

5.4.2.2 Regression Results

The regression coefficients and predicted marginal probability of participation in

group-based credit programmes is presented in Table 5.4. The coefficient of dummy

for the 2nd quintile is positive but insignificant. The coefficients of dummies for the

3rd and 4th quintiles are positive and highly significant. Importantly, the values of the

coefficients are increasing, the figures being 0.476 and 0.571. One would, therefore,

see increase in the marginal effects of probability of participation with increase in

9 A1andi is a government administered trading centre. 10 Hat is the local weekly or monthly regular market place.

Page 21: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

level of living upto a certain point, i.e., fourth quintile of population distribution and

then it declines. Noticeably, the marginal effect of the dummy for the fifth quintile is

negative, although not significant.

A household's probability of participation increases if any person from the household

is having entrepreneurial attitude, which is confirmed from the positive direction of

the indicator on self employment in off-farm business. The coefficient is also

statistically significant at 5 percent level. One might say that this is post facto

situation. Indeed, we do not have baseline data in which we have information about

the participant; whether he/she was interested to join the group for undertaking off­

farm business. It is generally observed that the households with some inclination to

start business or other non-farm enterprises are incapable of doing so because of

restricted knowledge of product or factor markets, procedures of starting business or,

most importantly, shortage of capital. Propaganda of microcredit programmes

motivated these households to join the programme and then they took the initial step

in starting off-farm business by borrowing from the group. For example, one

participant reported that she wanted to support her son to start a business (selling

items by moving from place to place in a bicycle), but she had no capital. At that time

Swashakti SHGs were formed in the village and she joined a group with the hope that

she can borrow from the group at a later date. Indeed, after some time she borrowed

from the group for the purpose of business support to her son, and now their earnings

from business has grown significantly. Nevertheless, many households reported that

main purpose of joining the group was to avail credit for income generation purposes,

besides fulfilling consumption needs. So the dummy for self employment activities

represents that with motivations for non-farm work the probability of participation

increases.

Work participation is inversely related with probability of programme participation,

the coefficient being significant at I 0 percent level. This indicates that higher the ratio

of workers in the household lower is the probability of participation in programme.

As work participation rate is higher among the better off households, it implies that

participation rate of such households in the programme is low.

The coefficient of education of earning member turns out to be negative and

significant which implies that higher the level of education lower will be the incentive

Page 22: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

to join the programme. Although this contradicts our hypothesis of positive influence

of education on programme participation, it may be explained by the fact that

education increases economic opportunities of a person and if the returns are higher in

alternative occupation then he/she will not prefer to join the programme, because the

opportunity costs of joining the programme may be higher for him/her. In our context,

higher level of education has been observed for the persons with higher level of

household income or wealth and the participation rate of these households is low as

compared to others. On the other hand, educational attainments are very low among

the poor or the population belonging to the lower strata of income distribution. With

the population highly skewed in terms of educational attainment (high concentration

of persons with higher schooling years in higher income strata) the probability of

participation, therefore, declines with increase in level of educational attainment.

However, this may not be seen as a consequence of higher schooling years, rather an

interaction effect of higher schooling years and higher income. It may be noted that

the effect of literacy ratio on probability of programme participation is positive

although it is not statistically significant.

Distance index has negative effects on probability of participation in the programme.

For instance, if the index has higher values for a particular village then the households

in that village have lower probability of participation. This is primarily due to the fact

that with increase in distance in accessing the village, the cost of communication for

the programme agents increases and the level of intervention decreases. So

penetration of the programme is restricted to few households in the village.

The coefficient of the dummy for district Sehore is negative and significant at 10

percent level. We found that penetration rate is higher in Betul than Sehore, although

the later has geographical advantages over the former. However, the region effect

should not be seen in isolation. We must take into account the interaction of

programme effect with the region effect. One would notice that the higher penetration

in Betul villages is due to greater amounts of efforts of PRADAN, whose processes of

SHG formation and management is much more rigorous and professional than the

agents of programme promotion in Sehore. Another factor is that the density of

households in Betul is much less than Sehore. However, probability of participation

differs across the regions, which can mostly be attributed to the nature of institutions

Page 23: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

supporting the programme. Longevity of operation of programme in the village has a

positive influence on probability of participation in the programme, particularly for

the households in the villages where the PRADAN programmes are in operation.

Unfortunately, the same effect is not seen in case of the SGSY programmes or the

SW ASHAKTI programmes.

The predicted probabilities, estimated from the above regression model, are shown in

Figure 5.3 across consumption quintile groups, for the regions of Sehore and Betul

separately. Further, we also estimated probabilities across annual monthly per capita

income which is plotted in Figure 5.4. Using either consumption or income as an

indicator of economic well-being one would observe that the predicted probabilities

are low for the households belonging to the lower section of population distribution.

The probability of participation increases with increase in economic well-being upto

the fourth quintile in both Betul and Sehore. Of course, the probabilities decline at the

top most quintile but that may not be a concern since many households in the upper

section will never participate in the programme and also they are discouraged to

participate in the programme by the programme agents.

Figure 5.3 Probability of Participation of Household in SHG Programme by Consumption Expenditure Quintiles

0.90

0.80

c ~ 0.70 .9-~ 0.60-

"' a. 0 0.50

i 0.40

"' .0 £ 0.30

0.20

0.10 .

------------··---------- Sehore -Betul

0.00 L------~-------------------~ 2 3 4 5

MPCE Qunitile (District wise)

----- ---·- --- ------- ------------------------- -- --

Page 24: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Figure 5.4 Probability ofParticipatiou ofHousehold iu SHG Programme by Annual Per Capita Income (Rs. 000)

.8

E' .6 Q)

E Ol

..r:. (/)

'c-a.. .4

.2

0

0

0 0

oO

2.5

0 0

0

0 0 0

0

0

5

0

0

0

0

0

0

0 0

0 0

00

7.5

oo

0

0 0

0 0 0

0

0 0 0

0 0 0 0

0 0

0 0

0

10 12.5 15 17.5 pcinc1

In Figure 5.4 we have added three lines, representing the minimum expenditures

required for different levels of living for the rural population, along with the predicted

probabilities. These three vertical lines represent national level estimates from the

latest NSS quinquennial round of consumption expenditure, pertaining to the year

2004-05 (NSS, 2006). This is also the survey year of this research and therefore, the

estimates do not require adjustment for prices. The first line represents Rs. 3240 per

capita per annum, which is calculated as a benchmark for extreme low levels of I iving

(Rs. 9 per day); the second line is the bench mark for subsistence level ofliving ofRs.

4380 per capita per annum (Rs. 12 per day); and the third line represents Rs. 8040 per

capita per annum (which belongs to the 801h percentile of the all-India distribution of

per capita consumption of the rural population) 11• NSS uses consumption as proxy for

income. In our context, we have the income figures and therefore, the lines are drawn

on incomes rather than consumption 12•

11 The NSS consumption expenditure figures are given as per capita per month, such as Rs. 270, Rs. 365 and Rs. 690 respectively. 12 See appendix for discussion on reliability and consistency of household income estimation and its correlates with other household indicators.

Page 25: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Noticeably, much of the sample concentrates below Rs. 12 per day. However, it is a

matter of concern that probability of participation is very low below this level of

income and the probability line is rising with rise in income. One would also see that

below the income level of Rs. 9 per day there are many households whose probability

of participation in near to zero. These are the section of population who are very poor

and they are excluded from the programme. So, this raises a question on use of

microfinance programmes as a substitute for poverty alleviation programmes.

However, many would not accept this result because of the use of income as the only

indicator of economic well-being. So the following section uses an index, constructed

by combining multi-dimensional indicators, for measurement of targeting.

5.4.3 Level of Living Index

The level of living index is constructed using principal component analysis. We use a

wide number of indicators pertaining to different aspects of household level of living

and the final set of indicators are retained, for the first component, on the basis of the

significance of the factor loadings and the eigen values. This has been discussed in

section 5.3.2.4. The variance of the first component, pertaining to the largest eigen

value, accounts for 34 per cent of the total variation in these variables. The factor

loadings pertaining to the first component are given in Table 5.6 and the variance of

each component and associated eigen values are in Table 5 .5. We use the first

principal component as our index of level of living13. In fact, the factor loadings are

weightages assigned to individual indicators which reflect the correlation between the

indicator and the composite index. Higher positive correlations imply better

appropriateness of the indicators. It may be seen from the table that all the indicators

are having factor loadings greater than 0.3 (which is showing the high correlation of

the indicator with the component) except for the indicator on work participation ratio.

However, the indicator is retained in the analysis because of the importance of the

indicator for enhancing household earnings, although it is not statistically significant.

13 We find that estimated distribution functions for the annual household expenditure on clothing and footwear behave very much like the index as a whole. The index also behaves very much like the per capita income. Both are highly correlated. This is consistent with other studies that have used this methodology to measure standards ofliving (Henry et at., 2000).

[i66]

Page 26: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

The distribution of level of living index for members and non-members were

compared using a variety of parametric and non-parametric statistical tests. Mean

values of the index by region and by group membership is given in Table 5. 7. It also

presents the results of t-test of difference of group means of the index. The null

hypothesis of equal means cannot be rejected for the entire sample as a whole, while

we find the difference to be statistically significant at .06 level in one region (Betul).

It is worthwhile to examine whether the microcredit programme targets households in

the middle of the distribution and excludes both tails. Then we need to estimate the

entire population distribution for members and non-members in order to identify the

nature of targeting in the programme. Figure 5.5 represents the distribution functions

of the index for members and non-members. Noticeably, the two functions cross each

other at a point near to the mean value of the index, with the curve of the members

lying to the right of the non-members, and after the crossing the distribution of non­

members shift to the right of the members. This implies that the bottom sections of

population distribution are not well targeted in the programmes. This is also

confirmed from the region-wise distribution functions of the index as shown in Figure

5.5a and Figure 5.5b.

We conducted the non-parametric tests by applying K-S test and also M-W test, the p­

values are shown in Table 5.8. Noticeably, the tests reject the null hypothesis of equal

distribution of members and non-members for the whole sample. Both the tests are

statistically significant at .05 level. Across the regions, we obtained similar results in

Betul, but the hypothesis of equality of distributions of members and non-members

cannot be rejected in Sehore.

We also examined the difference in means of the index and also the difference in

distribution functions of the index across programmes by applying ANOV A as well

as non-parametric tests respectively. Table 5.9 gives the results of both the tests. One

would simply derive the conclusion that the null hypothesis of equality of

distributions of the level of living index is rejected, as both ANOVA and K-W tests

are significant at .05 level. This is also reflected in the distribution functions, as

shown in Figure 5.5c.

Page 27: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

.8

Q) .6 0

()

"' X Q) "0 c ~ .4 a.

.2

0

.8

~ .6 0 ()

"' X Q) "0 c

;::.. .4 0..

.2

0

Figure 5.5 Distribution Functions of Level of Living Index by Membership Status- All

--f!s--- Non-member --<>---Member

-1.000 0.000 1.000 2.000 3.000 4.000 index score

Figure 5.5a Distribution Functions of Level of Living Index by Group Membership- Betul

--f!s--- Non-member _....,___Member

-1.000 0.000 1.000 2.000 3.000 4.000 index score

Chapter 5

5.000

5.000

Page 28: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

.8

Q) .6 ....

0 0 (/)

X Q) "0 r:: ~ .4 a.

.2

0

.8

Q) .6 ....

0 0 (/)

X Q) "0 r:: '=- .4 c.

.2

0

Figure S.Sb Distribution Functions of Level of Living Index by Group Membership- Sehore

--es-- Non-member --+-- Member

-1.000 0.000 1.000 2.000 3.000 4.000 index score

Figure S.Sc Distribution Functions of Level of Living by Group Membership- All

--- Non-member ----SGSY --es-- Pradan --><-- Swashakti

-1.000 0.000 1.000 2.000 3.000 4.000 index score

Chapter 5

5.000

5.000

Page 29: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Estimated kernel densities for the level of living index can be used to get a better idea

of the set of households that are relatively neglected by the programme, and those that

gain the most from it. Estimated densities for the whole sample as well as for regions

are shown in Figures 5.6 to 5.7. For the whole sample, when both densities are rising

the crossing point is less than zero while when both densities are falling the crossing

point is at the tails (near 2). Therefore, the households between these two crossing

points are those selected by the programme14. One can also see the crossing points of

the densities across the different programmes and that of the non-members (Figure

5.8).

~ 'iii c: <I> a

0

-2

Figure 5.6 Kernel Density Estimates Level of Living Index by Membership Status - All

/\ I \ I \

\ \ \ \ \

0

\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \

' ' \ \

\.

' ~ :,..

2 Index score

---4

--- Non-member ----- Member I

14 Similar results were obtained by Somanathan and Dewan (2003).

6

Page 30: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Figure 5.7 Kernel Density Estimates by Membership Status- District-wise

>­:"!:V (/) . c: Q)

0

Betul Sehore

,., ' \. " ' \

\ \ \

' \

-2 0 2 4 -2 0 2 4

1-- Non-member ---- Member I 1-- Non-member ---- Member I Index score

Graphs by district

z. ·u; C:...r Q) •

0

0

-2

Figure 5.8 Kernel Density Estimates Level of Living Index by Group Membership- All

I \

0 2 Index score

4

--- Non-member ----- SGSY

ere

-···- Pradan Swashakti

6

Page 31: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Henry et a/. (2000) suggested measurement of targeting by looking at the relative

poverty of members and non-members, from the index score. First, quartiles of the

index score are calculated for the non-member households. Second, the cut-off scores

of the quartiles for the non-members are applied as cut-off scores for grouping

member households. Ideally with no difference in distribution among member and

non-member households, the quartile groups will be exactly equal. Evidently, the ratio

of members to non-members in the lowest quartile turns out to be 0.13/0.25, while the

ratio is greater than I in 2"d and 3rd quartiles (Figure 5.9). One would, therefore,

conclude that the poorest households are excluded from the programme, as the ratio of

non-members to members is less than I in the bottom quintiles, while it is greater than

one in upper quintiles.

Figure 5.9 Percent of Participant Households Corresponding to Quartiles of Non­Participant Households Classified by Level of Living Index

35 o Non-member

30

25 0. ::)

e (.!)

20 <: 0

N ::) 0.

15 0 Cl.

0 ~ 0

10

5

0 01 Q2 03 04

Poverty Group

Note: First, quartiles are calculated for the non-member households using the household level of living index scores. Second, the cut-off scores of the quartiles for the non-members are applied as cut-off scores for grouping member households. Ideally with no difference in distribution among member and non-member households, the quartile groups will be exactly equal.

Page 32: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

5.5 CONCLUSION

Our results indicate that probability of participation is low at lower end of income

distribution and it increases with increase in per capita income of the household. Of

course, it declines with very high level of per capita income of household. But these

households may as well never participate in the programme. Since microfinance

programmes aim at meeting the credit needs of low income clientele, or supporting

micro enterprises, they may not be attractive for the high income clients. They will

only participate if the returns from joining the programme will be higher than their

present occupation. Some rich households do not join because they are discouraged by

the programme agents to join the programme. Besides, it is below the status, in the

village, for the women from rich households to join the group and save a small

amount.

Probability of participation is high in Betul than Sehore. But the region effect cannot

be explained in isolation. The interaction of programme characteristics has to be

examined before drawing any conclusion about the region effect. We found

programme effect (PRADAN) to be a significant determinant in increasing probability

of participation. In other words, the design and process variables of the programme do

determine the household participation in the group. However, we have no conclusive

evidence on whether peer selection affects the exclusion of very poor from the

programme.

Page 33: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Table 5.1 Mean of Selected Indicators by Membership Status of Household

t-test Nonmembers Members (p-value)

Total Sample

Household size 5.3 6.5 0.000

No. of children of age upto 6 yrs. 1.3 1.3

No. usual workers 3.0 3.4 0.053

Own land (acre) 2.2 2.4

Value of livestock (Rs. 000) 4.3 7.2 0.036

Value of farming assets (Rs. 000) 10.9 8.7

Value of transport vehicles (Rs. 000) 1.4 3.5 0.065

Monthly expenditure on food per capita (Rs.) 178.0 177.6 Monthly expenditure on clothing and footwear per capita (Rs.) 13.7 16.9 0.063

Monthly consumption expenditure per capita (Rs.) 319.2 298.1

Monthly income per capita (Rs.) 414.6 356.3 0.092

%households self-employed in off-farm business 11.4 19.5

Betu1

Household size 4.4 6.2 0.000

No. of children of age up to 6 yrs. 1.1 1.4

No. usual workers 2.6 3.4 0.008

Own land (acre) 2.1 2.6

Value of livestock (Rs. 000) 3.2 5.2 0.007

Value of farming assets (Rs. 000) 0.8 1.9

Value of transport vehicles (Rs. 000) 0.5 1.0

Monthly expenditure on food per capita (Rs.) 149.5 137.8 Monthly expenditure on clothing and footwear per capita (Rs.) 8.9 12.0 0.024

Monthly consumption expenditure per capita (Rs.) 243.6 212.3

Monthly income per capita (Rs.) 350.4 276.6 0.014

%households self-employed in off-farm business 2.6 18.2

Sehore

Household size 5.9 6.7 0.083

No. of children of age upto 6 yrs. 1.4 1.2

No. usual workers 3.2 3.4

Own land (acre) 2.2 2.3

Value of livestock (Rs. 000) 5.1 8.8

Value offarming assets (Rs. 000) 18.6 14.1

Value of transport vehicles (Rs. 000) 2.2 5.4 0.079

Monthly expenditure on food per capita (Rs.) 199.7 209.3 Monthly expenditure on clothing and footwear per capita (Rs.) 17.4 20.7

Monthly consumption expenditure per capita (Rs.) 376.7 366.2

Monthly income per capita (Rs.) 463.3 419.4

%households self-employed in off-farm business 18.0 20.6 Source: Computed from Survey data

~-----....,

Ll2iJ

Page 34: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Table 5.1a Non-Parametric Tests of Equality of Distributions of MPCE and PCINC H h ld b M b h" St t across ouse o s >Y em ers 1p a us

Kolmogorov-Smirnov Mann-Whitney Re11:ion (p-value) (p-value)

MPCE Betul 0.201 0.241

Sehore 0.113 0.270

Total 0.240 0.688

PC INC Betul 0.048 0.014

Sehore 0.640 0.524

Total 0.049 0.053 Source: Same as Table 5.1

T bl 52 S I a e e ecte d I d" b T n tcators >Y Lypeo fSHGM b h" fH em ers tp o h ld ouse o

Members Non- An ova

member SGSY PRADAN SWASHAKTI (p-value)

Average Household size 5.3 6.5 6.3 6.7 0.001 Average No. of children of age upto 6 yrs. 1.3 1.1 1.4 1.3

Average No. usual workers 3.0 3.4 3.5 3.3 Average Own land (acre) 2.2 2.2 2.6 2.5

Average Value of livestock (Rs. 000) 4.3 11.3 4.6 5.5 0.000 Average Value offarming assets (Rs. 000) 10.9 16.2 1.8 7.8 Average Value of transport vehicles (Rs. 000) 1.4 4.4 1.1 4.8 0.016 Average Monthly expenditure on food per capita (Rs.) 178.0 184.3 144.8 203.2 0.006 Average Monthly expenditure on clothing and footwear per capita 13.7 18.4 11.6 20.5 0.000 Average Monthly consumption expenditure per capita (Rs.) 319.2 312.5 218.1 362.0 0.000 Average Monthly income per capita (Rs.) 414.6 359.2 280.0 428.2 0.007 %households food insecured in past 12 months 48.9 38.3 35.0 35.0

% head of households ill iterate 57.8 56.7 45.0 48.3 %head of households >=primary education 32.2 31.7 28.3 36.7 %head of households >=secondary education 5.6 6.7 1.7 8.3 % households with any adult >=primary education 55.6 65.0 61.7 71.7 % households with any adult>=secondary education 11.1 16.7 10.0 21.7

%households with Katcha roof 86.7 81.7 85.0 86.7

%households with Katcha walls 73.3 61.7 80.0 70.0

%households with Katcha floor 88.9 91.7 90.0 91.7

% ST households 44.4 33.3 96.7 0.0

% SC households 12.2 15.0 1.7 38.3 %households with self employment in off-farm business 11.1 18.3 18.3 23.3 Source: Same as Table 5.1

Page 35: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

Table 5.3 Share of Sources oflncome by District and Membership Status

Betul Sehore Sources of Income Non- Non-(Net) member Member Total member Member Total Agriculture 14.6 14.1 14.4 18.8 18.6 18.8 Home produce 1.8 3.7 2.7 2.8 2.2 2.6 Agriculture labour 21.3 27.9 24.5 14.2 7.2 12.3 Non-agriculture labour 27.8 24.6 26.3 20.8 27.3 22.6 Salaried income 5.4 3.5 4.5 15.3 15.9 15.4 Livestock 9.6 3.8 6.8 12.0 15.0 12.8

Other Off-farm business 1.3 9.2 5.0 11.1 7.9 10.2 Other income 18.2 13.3 15.9 5.1 5.9 5.3 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 Source: Same as Table 5.1

Table 5.4 Pro bit Regression: Determinants of Participation and Marginal Effects

Dependent Variable: Participation of Household in SHG Programme (l=Yes, O=No)

Coefficient estimates Robust

Mean Std. Err. P>z HH in mpce quintile 2nd (I ,0) 0.256 0.284 0.369 HH in mpce quintile 3rd (1,0) 0.476 0.282 0.091 HH in mpce quintile 4th (1,0) 0.571 0.291 0.050 HH in top mpce quintile (I ,0) -0.265 0.288 0.358 Self employment in off-farm business (1,0) 0.614 0.276 0.026 Ratio of workers to hhsize (Ratio) -0.814 0.468 0.082 Log of years of schooling of principal earner -0.314 0.150 0.037 Ratio ofliterate adults to hhsize (Ratio) 0.638 0.425 0.134 Value of farming assets (Rs. 000) -0.002 0.003 0.504 Value oflivestock assets (Rs. 000) 0.037 0.011 0.001 Value of transport assets (Rs.OOO) 0.042 0.019 0.025 Own land (acres) -0.023 0.032 0.473 Years ofSGSY operation in the village -0.016 0.062 0.801 Years ofPRADAN operation in the village 0.161 0.069 0.019 Years ofSWASHAKTI operation in the village 0.092 0.082 0.263 Distance index -0.570 0.316 0.071 Dummy for district Sehore -0.695 0.416 0.095 Constant -0.005 0.629 0.993

Log pseudolikelihood -131.73 N Wald chi2 Prob > chi2 McFadden's R2

Cragg & Uhler's R2 (*)Discrete change of dummy vanable from 0 to I Source: Same as Table 5.1

[i76'l

262

66.59 0.000

0.19

0.29

Predicted marginal

effect

dF/dx

0.089 0.170 0.207

-0.085 0.227

-0.273 -0.105 0.213

-0.001 0.012 0.014

-0.008 -0.005 0.054 0.031

-0.191 -0.242

Page 36: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

T bl 55 E. a e 12en VI a ues an dV ar1ances o fP. rlnCipa IC t omponen s Cumulative variance

Components Eig_en value explained I 4.801 0.343

2 1.559 0.454

3 1.327 0.549 4 1.130 0.630

5 1.018 0.703 Source: Same as Table 5.1

T bl 56 F a e . actor L d. ~ th F. t P . oa m2s or e IrS r1nc1pa IC omponen t Indicators Factor loadings Roof type 0.453 Wall type 0.588 Floor type 0.636 Ratio of workers to household size 0.223 Any person salaried in HH (I ,0) 0.408 Own land (acres) 0.605 Value of livestock assets (Rs. 000) 0.506 Value of transport assets (Rs.OOO) 0.663 Value of farming assets (Rs. 000) 0.633 Annual per capita income (Rs. 000) 0.738 Monthly expenditure on clothing and footwear per capita (Rs) 0.763 Education of principal earning member of household 0.611 Ratio of literate adults to household size 0.627 Level of food security during last 12 months 0.525 Source: Same as Table 5.1

Table 5.7 District-wise Mean Values of Level of Living Index for Members and Non-Members Region Non-members Members t-test (p-value)

Betul -0.493 -0.232 0.067 Sehore 0.210 0.221 0.530 Total 0.001 -0.002 0.253 Source: Same as Table 5.1

Table 5.8 Nonparametric Tests of Equality of Distributions of Level of Living 1 d H h ld b M b h. St t n ex across ouse o s >y em ers 1p a us Reeion KS (p-value) MWJp-valu~

Betul 0.026 0.104

Sehore 0.209 0.306 Total 0.027 0.042 Source: Same as Table 5.1

Table 5.9 Mean Values of Level oj_Livinf( Index B, SHG type A nova Kruskal-Wallis

SHG Type Mean (p-value) (p-value) Non-member 0.001 SGSY 0.128

0.044 0.036 PRADAN -0.222 SWASHAKTI 0.155 All members (SGSY, PRADAN, SWASHAKTI) -0.002 Source: Same as Table 5.1

Page 37: 5. OUTREACH OF MICRO FINANCE PROGRAMMES AND TARGETING …shodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/17649/13/13... · 2018-07-09 · to evaluate the targeting of anti-poverty programmes

Chapter 5

APPENDIX

Calculation ofDistance Index

The steps involved in the construction of distance index for the five indicators are appended below: Step 1: Making the indicators scale free

i. Computation of the mean for each indicator. For the /''indicator, the

mean x; would be LX ij IN where X ij is the value of the i'" village for

j'" indicator and i = 1,2, .... .N. N is the number of villages, which is 18 in the present case for each indicator.

ii. Division of each observation of the indicator (X ij) by respective mean

ex;). We thus obtainXij I x;. These may be called the scale free values

of the indicators. Step 2: Adding up the scale free values of the j'" indicators for each village.

D, = I(xijlx;), J=I,2, ..... 5.

Finally, the distance index is D* = D jk, where k is the total number of indicators, .I .I

which is 5, as noted above.

The index shows that higher the value for a village the higher the village will be in a disadvantageous position. The lower the values the more connected the village to the important destinations. Distance of Village from Important Destinations (Km.) and Distance Index

Indicators of Important Destinations

Nearest Local Distance No. Village Block Town Bus Stop Mandi Haat Index I Pola Patthar 14 3.0 0.1 38 3 0.7 2 Mansinghpura 18 7.0 4.0 42 3 1.2 3 Chirmatekri II 6.0 3.0 41 6 1.1 4 Tetar 27.0 16 1.0 62 16 1.9 5 Kuppa 25.0 14 0.1 60 14 1.7 6 Handipani 20.0 8.0 0.1 55 8 1.2 7 Sonadeh 18.0 7.0 0.1 60 7 1.2 8 Phooti Baudi 3.0 6.0 0.1 3 4 0.3 9 Bijora 6.0 6.0 6.0 6 6 0.9 10 Kaudia Chittu 7.0 8.0 8.0 7 8 1.2 II Semli 6.0 5.0 3.0 6 10 0.8 12 Raj_ukhedi 10.0 12.0 5.0 12 12 1.3 13 Manpura 9.0 11.0 1.0 9 11 0.9 14 Rola 12.0 13.0 3.0 12 13 1.2 15 Jahangirpura 5.0 4.0 4.0 5 4 0.6 16 Sekdakhedi 4.0 3.0 2.0 4 3 0.4 17 Takipura 6.0 5.0 5.0 6 5 0.8 18 Konajhir 8.0 7.0 0.1 8 7 0.6

Mean 11.6 7.8 2.5 24.2 7.8 1.0

c.v. 62.3 48.8 95.5 95.2 52.1 40.4


Recommended