+ All Categories
Home > Documents > A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework,...

A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework,...

Date post: 05-Apr-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
256
A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes by Toka S. Mostafa Muhammad A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Civil Engineering University of Toronto © Copyright by Toka S. Mostafa 2017
Transcript
Page 1: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes

by

Toka S. Mostafa Muhammad

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements

for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

Department of Civil Engineering

University of Toronto

© Copyright by Toka S. Mostafa 2017

Page 2: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

ii

A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes

Toka S. Mostafa

Doctor of Philosophy

Department of Civil Engineering

University of Toronto

2017

Abstract

Firmography is a fundamental component of urban systems that has not received much

research attention. Firmographic events of entry, exit, growth, and relocation affect economic

growth, labour dynamics, and result in a complex system of goods movements. This dissertation

develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the

framework is to evaluate the implications of policy on firm evolution over time by simulating

and forecasting firm behaviour. The engine is composed of firm generation, market introduction,

performance evaluation, and firm evolution modules. Firm generation simulates entrepreneurial

decisions of firm entry. Market introduction involves the specification and completion of

operational strategies. Performance evaluation assesses the outcomes of the operational

strategies. Firm evolution simulates growth/shrinkage and exit decisions depending on

performance evaluation results.

Three firmographic events are studied in detail: firm start-up size, growth, and survival.

Ordered logit models are estimated for firm start-up size in terms of the firm’s number of

employees and tangible assets. Autoregressive Distributed-Lag models (ARDL) are estimated to

represent firm growth. Parametric and non-parametric analyses for firm survival are presented.

The non-parametric analysis introduces survival and hazard rates characterized by industry class,

province, firm age, and firm size. The parametric analysis includes a discrete-time hazard

duration model of firm failure. The results show that firm start-up size, growth and survival are

influenced by economic growth, industry dynamics, competition, and firm location and

characteristics.

Page 3: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

iii

Models of freight outsourcing decisions by Canadian manufacturers are also presented.

Binary logit and multinomial logit models are estimated. The models show that freight

outsourcing is driven by firm strategies, supplier locations, government incentives, innovation

and technology, industry dynamics, economic conditions, and competition. Models of

international versus local outsourcing are also explored.

Statistics Canada’s T2-LEAP and Survey of Innovation and Business Strategy (SIBS)

databases are utilized for this research. The longitudinal T2-LEAP dataset is used to estimate

models of firm start-up size, firm growth, and firm failure of Canadian firms for the period of

2001 to 2012. The cross-sectional SIBS dataset, for the years of 2009 and 2012, is used to

estimate models of freight outsourcing by Canadian manufacturers.

Page 4: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

iv

Acknowledgments

First and foremost, it is by the grace of Allah (my God), the most merciful and most gracious,

that this thesis has been completed. I am sincerely thankful to His countless blessings in every

stage of my life, and surrounding me with all the supportive and loving people throughout my

journey. My Lord, thank you for enabling me to finish this research and hopefully benefiting

others with it.

After quite a long journey, here comes the time to finish my thesis and finally write the part I

was longing for the most; the part where I acknowledge and thank all the people who have

helped to make this thesis come to light. William Arthur Ward said, “Feeling gratitude and not

expressing it, is like wrapping a present and not giving it”. So, allow me to ‘wrap my present’ to

the transportation discipline with this humble acknowledgment section.

My sincere gratitude is to my advisor, Professor Matthew Roorda. Thank you Matt for

always guiding me to the right directions, especially during the most difficult and challenging

moments throughout my PhD. You always saw the best in this research, never lost hope, and

with your wisdom, vision, intellect, patience, continuous support and encouragement, positive

spirit, and experience, this research is completed with success. You are the best supervisor a

graduate student can ever have. Matt, you are an inspiration and an outstanding role model, and

certainly, I am forever grateful to your influence on reshaping my academic personality. People

like you make the world a better place.

Thanks go to my PhD committee members; Professors Eric Miller, Khandker Nurul Habib,

and Shoshanna Saxe, for their feedback on my first thesis draft. Your feedback has helped

improving the clarity of the final version. Special thanks to Professor Habib for his valued advice

in behavioural modelling. Also, special thanks to Professor Hanna Maoh for serving as the

external thesis reviewer. Hanna, my thesis is largely motivated by your PhD research back in

2005, and I greatly appreciated all your comments and suggestions.

Many thanks for Professors Baher Abdulhai and Amer Shalaby for supervising my

comprehensive examination, and for their continuous support throughout my time at U of T.

Prof. Amer, I deeply appreciate your guidance with career path selection. Prof. Baher, it has been

my honor to work with you as a teaching assistant. Your outstanding teaching has always

impressed me and motivated me to pursue research in transportation engineering from the early

Page 5: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

v

beginning of my master’s degree time. I always look up to you, and wish one day that I become a

great teacher and professor like you.

I want to acknowledge Statistics Canada for approving this research to use their firm micro

databases. This has certainly made this research more valuable to transportation and land use

research in Canada. More specifically, I want to deeply thank Danny Leung, Lydia Couture, and

Douré Grekou for their support to the project, facilitating my time at Statistics Canada, and

accommodating the project requests promptly and cheerfully.

I would also want to acknowledge the financial support I received from the University of

Toronto, Professor Matthew Roorda, Canadian Transportation Research Forum (CTRF), and

Transportation Association of Canada (TAC).

I want to extend my sincere gratitude to my family who have always been the utmost source

of support in every stage of my life. My precious mother, Naida Alrefaie, you are the greatest

gift that is sent to me in this life. Your unconditional love and support has always been the main

driver to any of my achievements. Your faith in my abilities has always given me strength and

lightened the darkest times. This one goes to you and to my late father Sabry Mostafa. My

dearest sisters Tasneem and Takwa, and my dearest brother Tackey El-Deen, you are my pillars

of support, without your unconditional love and encouragement I would have never made it. My

brother-in-law Mohamed, sister-in-law Safaa, my niece Judy, and my lovely nephews Adam,

Eyad, and Omar, your support has always been the brightest side in my PhD life. May we always

be united and never apart.

It has been a long journey, full of ups and downs, challenges, great moments, and most of all;

awesome people. Prophet Muhammad, peace and blessings be upon him, said, "He who does not

thank people, does not thank Allah*”, so, allow me to spend few lines acknowledging everyone I

met inside and outside of U of T who made this journey unique in many dimensions. I would like

to thank my colleagues Wafic El-Assi, Sami Hasnine, Adam Weiss, and Chris Harding for their

help with discrete choice models. Thanks to my lab mates who have made life more fun at U of

T; Islam Kamel, Bryce Sharman, Ahmed Ramadan, Mehdi Nourinejad, Glareh Amirjamshidi,

and Leila Dianat. Thank you, Mohamed Elshenawy, for your support and encouragement during

the thesis writing stage and providing me with excellent tips for efficient writing.

* Authenticated by Ahmed and Timidhi

Page 6: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

vi

My dearest Samah El-Tantawy and Hossam Abdelgawad, I cannot thank the both of you

enough for all the support you have been providing me inside U of T, and being great friends and

family outside U of T. Samah, your ultimate positivity has always been the spark that motivates

people around you, especially me. I still remember how supportive you were in some difficult

times; your patience, excellent advice, and most of all the “never give up” spirit. Hossam, thanks

for always giving me the best advice in my PhD and in my career, and thanks for being a great

brother. May both of you and your kids, Nour and Yussuf, be always blessed and protected.

Most sincerely, I dearly thank you Aya Aboudina for being my great friend, sister, office-

mate, and roommate. Our PhD paths were parallel; we have shared the most moments together,

we travelled together, matured together, laughed a lot, and shared many life changing events. I

cherish this part of the trip greatly. Thank you for being a true friend and being the greatest

support for me over the past six years. My genuine thanks go to my dear friend Nosayba El-

Sayed for all the support and advice that she has been given me. I deeply treasure all the events,

travels, and conversations we shared. I have learned a lot from you and I forever am thankful for

your friendship and being there for me in the most challenging situations.

I am so humbled by the treasured company of my great friends that created the work-life

balance needed to complete my PhD. Nourhan Safwat, Eman Hammad, Somaia Ali, Hoda

Youssef, Sara Alkokhon, Sarah Salem, Mona El-Mosallamy, Rana Morsi, Nagwa El-Ashmawy,

Yasmine Megahed, Lina Elshamy, Mai Hany, Bailasan Khashan, and Sara Anis: you are my

family and I sincerely thank you for everything. A special thank you to my twin ‘non-biological’

sister Aliaa Bassiuoni for her genuine support in levels I cannot count. My family in Ottawa,

Priya and Indu Bakshi, and Basma Elkhateeb: thank you for your great hospitality and support

during my stay in Ottawa. Also, I want to extend my gratitude to Yamen Elbahy for his support.

Page 7: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

vii

To Mom and Dad…

Page 8: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

viii

Copyright Acknowledgment

In this thesis, portions of two chapters (chapters 2 and 7) are published or under review.

These chapters are:

Chapter 2:

Mostafa, T.S and M.J. Roorda (2016). A Review of Firmography in Freight

Microsimulation Modelling. Submitted to Journal of Transport Reviews (Under review).

Chapter 7:

Mostafa, T. and M.J. Roorda (2017). Discrete Choice Modeling of Freight Outsourcing

Decisions of Canadian Manufacturers. Accepted for publication in Transportation Research

Record.

Page 9: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

ix

Table of Contents List of Tables ......................................................................................................................... xiii

List of Figures ........................................................................................................................ xvi

List of Acronyms ................................................................................................................. xviii

CHAPTER 1 Introduction ...................................................................................................... 1

1.1. Introduction .................................................................................................................... 1

1.2. Motivation ...................................................................................................................... 2

1.3. Existing Work ................................................................................................................ 3

1.4. Research Goals, Objectives, and Scope ......................................................................... 4

1.5. Dissertation Structure ..................................................................................................... 6

1.6. Disclaimer ...................................................................................................................... 9

CHAPTER 2 A Review of Firmography in Freight Microsimulation Modelling ............... 10

2.1. Introduction .................................................................................................................. 10

2.2. Firmography and Firm Life Cycle ............................................................................... 10

2.2.1. What influences firmography? ........................................................................ 11

2.2.2. Firm life cycle ................................................................................................. 13

2.2.3. Relationship between firmographic events ..................................................... 14

2.2.4. Firm birth (entry) ............................................................................................. 16

2.2.5. Firm growth ..................................................................................................... 19

2.2.6. Firm exit/survival ............................................................................................ 21

2.2.7. Firm behaviour: and evolutionary perspective ................................................ 23

2.3. Agent-based Models with Firm Microsimulation ........................................................ 24

2.4. Firm Microsimulation and Freight Models .................................................................. 29

2.5. Concluding Remarks and Research Gaps .................................................................... 30

CHAPTER 3 A Framework of Firm Microsimulation: The Firmographic Engine ............. 33

3.1. Introduction .................................................................................................................. 33

3.2. A Conceptual Framework ............................................................................................ 34

3.3. Underlying Modules .................................................................................................... 38

3.3.1. Firm generation ............................................................................................... 38

Page 10: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

x

3.3.2. Market introduction ......................................................................................... 41

3.3.3. Performance evaluation ................................................................................... 42

3.3.4. Firm Evolution ................................................................................................ 44

3.4. Data Sources ................................................................................................................ 45

3.4.1. T2-Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program (T2-LEAP) ....................... 46

3.4.2. Survey of Innovation and Business Strategies (SIBS) .................................... 47

3.5. Relationship to Other Microsimulation Models of Transportation Systems ............... 51

3.5.1. Integration with FREMIS ................................................................................ 51

3.5.2. Integration with ILUTE ................................................................................... 52

3.6. Concluding Remarks and Future Directions ................................................................ 55

CHAPTER 4 Models of Firm Start-up Size of Canadian Firms .......................................... 58

4.1. Introduction .................................................................................................................. 58

4.2. Determinants of Firm Start-up Size ............................................................................. 60

4.3. Data Description and Basic Analysis ........................................................................... 63

4.4. Model Structure: Ordered Logit Model ....................................................................... 65

4.5. Firm Start-up Employment Size .................................................................................. 66

4.5.1. Order logit model estimation results ............................................................... 67

4.5.2. Results interpretations ..................................................................................... 70

4.5.3. Model validation and goodness-of-fit ............................................................. 77

4.6. Firm Start-up Tangible Assets ..................................................................................... 80

4.6.1. Ordered logit model estimation results ........................................................... 80

4.6.2. Results interpretations ..................................................................................... 83

4.6.3. Model validation and goodness-of-fit ............................................................. 88

4.7. Concluding Remarks and Future Directions ................................................................ 89

CHAPTER 5 Models of Firm Growth of Canadian Firms ................................................... 90

5.1. Introduction .................................................................................................................. 90

5.2. Determinants of Firm Growth ...................................................................................... 91

5.3. Data Description and Basic Analysis ........................................................................... 93

Page 11: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xi

5.4. Firm Employment Growth Models .............................................................................. 98

5.4.1. Ordered logit model of employment growth ratio .......................................... 99

5.4.2. Panel logistic regression model with random effects .................................... 102

5.4.3. Multilevel model with random effects .......................................................... 109

5.4.4. Autoregressive Distributed-lag Model (ARDL) ........................................... 115

5.5. Firm Tangible Assets Growth Models ....................................................................... 121

5.5.1. Model estimation and result interpretation.................................................... 122

5.5.2. Model validation and goodness-of-fit ........................................................... 123

5.6. Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SURE) ................................................................. 124

5.6.1. Model estimation results and interpretation .................................................. 125

5.6.2. Model goodness-of-fit and validation ........................................................... 129

5.7. Concluding Remarks and Future Directions .............................................................. 131

CHAPTER 6 Survival Analysis of Canadian Firms .......................................................... 134

6.1. Introduction ................................................................................................................ 134

6.2. Literature Review....................................................................................................... 134

6.2.1. Determinants of firm failure .......................................................................... 136

6.3. Data Description ........................................................................................................ 138

6.3.1. Population of study........................................................................................ 138

6.3.2. Explanatory variables .................................................................................... 139

6.4. Data Analysis and Trends .......................................................................................... 141

6.4.1. Data analysis ................................................................................................. 141

6.4.2. Firm entry and exit rates................................................................................ 145

6.5. Survival Analysis ....................................................................................................... 147

6.5.1. Non-parametric analysis ................................................................................ 147

6.5.2. Parametric analysis ........................................................................................ 153

6.5.2.1. Model structure ............................................................................................. 153

6.6. General Notes............................................................................................................. 165

Page 12: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xii

6.7. Concluding Remarks .................................................................................................. 167

CHAPTER 7 Discrete Choice Models of Freight Outsourcing Decisions of Canadian

Manufacturers 169

7.1. Introduction and Related Literature ........................................................................... 169

7.2. Data Description ........................................................................................................ 171

7.3. Methodology and Model Structure ............................................................................ 174

7.3.1. Binary logit model structure .......................................................................... 175

7.3.2. Multinomial logit (MNL) model structure .................................................... 176

7.4. Model Results ............................................................................................................ 177

7.4.1. Binary logit model results ............................................................................. 177

7.4.2. MNL model results........................................................................................ 183

7.5. Model Validation ....................................................................................................... 187

7.6. Concluding Remarks and Future Research ................................................................ 189

CHAPTER 8 Conclusions .................................................................................................. 192

8.1. Summary of Chapters ................................................................................................ 193

8.2. Main Conclusions and Findings................................................................................. 194

8.3. Research Contributions to the Literature ................................................................... 199

8.4. Future Research ......................................................................................................... 200

References ............................................................................................................................. 208

Appendix A. Additional Tables......................................................................................... 232

Page 13: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xiii

List of Tables

TABLE 2.1 A Summary of Factors Influencing Firmography ..................................................... 12

TABLE 2.2 Summary of Firmographic Microsimulation Research Efforts ................................. 26

TABLE 4.1 Investigated Determinants of Firm Start-up Size ...................................................... 61

TABLE 4.2 Industry Classification 2-digit NAICS Code ............................................................ 62

TABLE 4.3: Start-up Employment Size Ranges for Ordered Logit Model ................................. 68

TABLE 4.4 Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Employment Size: Simple Model ............... 69

TABLE 4.5 Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Employment Size: Detailed Model ............. 70

TABLE 4.6 Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Each Covariate Independently (Simple

Model) ................................................................................................................................... 76

TABLE 4.7 Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Each Covariate Independently (Detailed

Model) ................................................................................................................................... 77

TABLE 4.8 Model Estimation Summary and Model Goodness-of-fit ......................................... 80

TABLE 4.9 Cross-Validation Results of Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Employment

Size ........................................................................................................................................ 80

TABLE 4.10 Start-up Tangible Assets Ranges for Ordered Logit Model ............................................ 81

TABLE 4.11 Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Tangible Assets: Model Estimation ............. 82

TABLE 4.12 Start-up Tangible Assets Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Each Covariate

Independently ................................................................................................................................................ 85

TABLE 4.13 Cross-Validation Results of Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Tangible Assets

........................................................................................................................................................................... 88

TABLE 4.14 Model Estimation Summary and Goodness-of-fit.............................................................. 88

TABLE 5.1 Summary Statistics of Single-Location Small/Medium Sized Firms (less than 100

employee) ....................................................................................................................................................... 95

TABLE 5.2 Correlation Matrix of Firm Attributes ...................................................................................... 97

TABLE 5.3 Correlation Matrix of Industry Characteristics and Economic Indicators ..................... 98

TABLE 5.4. Employment Ratio Classes......................................................................................................... 99

TABLE 5.5 Ordered Logit Model of Employment Growth Ratio - Simple Model ......................... 100

TABLE 5.6 Ordered Logit Model of Employment Growth Ratio - Detailed Model ....................... 101

Page 14: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xiv

TABLE 5.7 Ordered Logit Model of Employment Growth Estimation Summary and Model

Goodness-of-fit ........................................................................................................................................... 102

TABLE 5.8 Random Effects Panel Logistic Regression Model of Employment Size Estimation

Results: Simple Model .............................................................................................................................. 105

TABLE 5.9 Random Effects Panel Logistic Regression Model of Employment Size Estimation

Results: Detailed Model ........................................................................................................................... 106

TABLE 5.10 Estimation Summary and Model Goodness-of-fit of Employment Size ................... 108

TABLE 5.11 Multilevel Random Intercept Only Model of Employment Size: Simple Model

Estimation Results ...................................................................................................................................... 112

TABLE 5.12 Multilevel Random Intercept Only Model of Employment Size: Detailed Model

Estimation Results ...................................................................................................................................... 113

TABLE 5.13 ARDL Model of Employment Size: Estimation Results ................................................ 118

TABLE 5.14 ARDL Model of Employment Size: Estimation Results Summary, Model

Goodness-of-Fit, and Model Validation .............................................................................................. 121

TABLE 5.15 ARDL Model of Tangible Assets: Estimation Results ................................................... 122

TABLE 5.16 ARDL Model of Tangible Assets: Estimation Results Summary, Model Goodness-

of-Fit, and Model Validation .................................................................................................................. 124

TABLE 5.17 SURE Model Estimation Results: Simple Model ............................................................ 126

TABLE 5.18. SURE Model Estimation Results: Detailed Model ......................................................... 128

TABLE 5.19 SURE Model Estimation Summary and Validation Results: Simple Model ........... 130

TABLE 5.20 SURE Model Estimation Summary and Validation Results: Detailed Model ......... 131

TABLE 6.1 Description of Explanatory Variables used in Firm Failure Hazard Duration Model

......................................................................................................................................................................... 140

TABLE 6.2 Survival and Cumulative Hazard Rates of 2001 Firm Population (Period of 2001 to

2012) .............................................................................................................................................................. 148

TABLE 6.3 Survival Rate by Province ......................................................................................................... 151

TABLE 6.4 Survival Rates by Industry ........................................................................................................ 151

TABLE 6.5 Firm Failure Model: Estimation Results ............................................................................... 159

TABLE 6.6 Model Validation and Goodness-of-Fit ................................................................................ 165

TABLE 7.1 Summary of Investigated Explanatory Variables ............................................................... 172

TABLE 7.2 Binary Logit Models for Logistics Outsourcing ................................................................. 179

Page 15: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xv

TABLE 7.3 Binary Logit Models for Goods Production Outsourcing ................................................ 180

TABLE 7.4 Binary Logit Models for International Outsourcing .......................................................... 182

TABLE 7.5 A MNL Model of Outsourcing: A Simple Model .............................................................. 184

TABLE 7.6 A MNL Model of Outsourcing: A Detailed Model ............................................................ 185

TABLE 7.7 A MNL Model of International Outsourcing ....................................................................... 187

TABLE 7.8 Binary logit model validation ................................................................................................... 189

TABLE 7.9 MNL model validation ............................................................................................................... 189

Page 16: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xvi

List of Figures

FIGURE 1.1 Dissertation Structure ................................................................................................ 8

FIGURE 2.1 Schematic of A Typical Product Life Cycle............................................................ 13

FIGURE 2.2 Relationship Between Market Stress and Firmographic Decisions ........................ 16

FIGURE 2.3 Average Cost and Production Relationship ............................................................. 18

FIGURE 3.1 The Firmographic Engine: A Conceptual Framework ............................................ 36

FIGURE 3.2 The Firmographic Engine: Firm Decision Hierarchy .............................................. 37

FIGURE 3.3 The Firmographic Engine: Firm Decision Hierarchy .............................................. 40

FIGURE 3.4 Market Introduction Module ................................................................................... 42

FIGURE 3.5 Market Introduction Module ................................................................................... 43

FIGURE 3.6 Firm Evolution Module ........................................................................................... 45

FIGURE 3.7 Long Term Strategy, Strategic Focus, and Business Activity Dynamics in SIBS .. 50

FIGURE 3.8 Use of Innovation in SIBS ....................................................................................... 51

FIGURE 3.9 Freight Operations Decision Hierarchy ................................................................... 52

FIGURE 3.10 Overall Structure of ILUTE and Potential Interactions with The Firmographic

Engine ................................................................................................................................... 54

FIGURE 4.1 Firm Start-up and Growth Simulation Configuration ............................................. 59

FIGURE 4.2 Average Number of Employees at Firm Start-up by Industry ................................ 64

FIGURE 4.3 Average Firm Employment Size by Industry (For the period of 2001 to 2012) ..... 65

FIGURE 4.4 Ratio of The Odds of Firm Start-up Employment Size for Some Provinces .......... 71

FIGURE 4.5 Probabilities of Firm Start-up Employment Size for Selected Provinces ............. 72

FIGURE 4.6 Ratio of The Odds by Industry for The Firm Start-up Size: Simple and Detailed

Models................................................................................................................................... 73

FIGURE 4.7 Probabilities of Firm Start-up Employment Size by Industry: Detailed Model ... 73

FIGURE 4.8 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Manufacturers in Different

Provinces-Simple Model ....................................................................................................... 74

FIGURE 4.9 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Manufacturers in Different

Provinces-Detailed Model .................................................................................................... 75

FIGURE 4.10 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Construction Firms in Different

Provinces- Simple Model ...................................................................................................... 75

Page 17: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xvii

FIGURE 4.11 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Construction Firms in Different

Provinces- Detailed Model ................................................................................................... 76

FIGURE 4.12 Tangible Assets Ordered Logit Model - Ratio of the Odds for Some Provinces .. 83

FIGURE 4.13 Tangible Assets Ordered Logit Model - Ratio of the Odds by Industry Class...... 84

FIGURE 4.14 Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Some Provinces ....................................... 86

FIGURE 4.15 Start-up Tangible Asset Ordered Logit Model Probabilities by Industry Class .... 87

FIGURE 5.1. Firm Population Classified by Province ................................................................. 96

FIGURE 5.2. Firm Population Classified by Industry .................................................................. 96

FIGURE 5.3. Multilevel Model Schematic ................................................................................ 110

FIGURE 6.1 Average Firm Exit Rates by Industry Class (From 2001 to 2012) ........................ 142

FIGURE 6.2 Average Firm Exit Rates by Province (2001 to 2012) .......................................... 143

FIGURE 6.3 Average Firm Exit Rates of Manufacturers by Province ...................................... 143

FIGURE 6.4 Cumulative Distribution of Firm Age at Exit ........................................................ 144

FIGURE 6.5 Population Distribution of Firm Age at Exit ......................................................... 145

FIGURE 6.6 Firm Entry and Exit Rates, and GDP Growth Rates ............................................. 146

FIGURE 6.7 Canadian Studies of Firm Survival Rates .............................................................. 149

FIGURE 6.8 Survival Function by Firm Size ............................................................................. 150

FIGURE 6.9 Survival Function for Selected Provinces. ............................................................ 150

(c) FIGURE 6.10 Survival Function by Age Group .................................................................. 153

FIGURE 6.11 GDP by Province for The Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction Industry

Class (NAICS 2-Digit Code: 21) ........................................................................................ 156

FIGURE 6.12 GDP by Province for The Manufacturing Industry Class (NAICS 2-digit code:

31-33) a ............................................................................................................................... 157

FIGURE 6.13 Unemployment and GDP Growth Rates for The Province of Ontario ................ 158

FIGURE 6.14 Ratio of The Odds of Failure for Firms Located in Canadian Provinces with

Ontario being the Reference Province ................................................................................ 161

FIGURE 6.15 Ratio of the Odds for Different Industries with Manufacturers being the Base

Industry ............................................................................................................................... 162

FIGURE 7.1 Model structures .................................................................................................... 174

Page 18: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xviii

List of Acronyms

AAE Average Annual Earnings

ACF Autocorrelation Function

ALU Average Labour Unit

APS Adult Population Survey

AR Autocorrelation

ARDL Autoregressive Distributed-lag Model

CMA/CA Census Metropolitan Area/ Census Agglomeration

GEM Global Entrepreneurship Monitor

GDP Gross Domestics Product

GLS Generalized Least Squares

GTHA Greater Toronto and Hamilton Area

HR Human Recourses

i.i.d. Independent and Identically Distributed

IUMs Integrated Urban Models

ILUTE Integrated Land Use, Transportation, Environment

LME Linear Mixed Effects

LR Likelihood Ratio

MAD Median Absolute Deviation

MES Minimum Efficient Scale

MNL Multinomial Logit Model

NAICS North American Industry Classification System

NL Nested Logit

OLS Ordinary Least Squares

SC Supply Chain

SEPH Survey of Employment, Payrolls and Hours

SIBS Survey of Innovation and Business Strategy

Page 19: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

xix

SME Small-Medium Sized Establishments/Firms

SURE Seemingly Unrelated Regression

T2-LEAP T2-Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program

Page 20: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

1

CHAPTER 1

Introduction

1.1. Introduction

Researchers from regional and transportation planning have focused a large body of research

towards Integrated Urban Models (IUMs) and agent-based microsimulation of urban systems

(Miller et al., 2004; Waddell, 2002; Hunt et al., 2005; Wegener, 1995). IUMs represent urban

activity by simulating the behaviour of interacting agents. IUMs can be used to support strategic

planning by forecasting the effects of policies on demographics and land use changes within

regions. Recent IUMs are focused on representing the system agents at the micro level to provide

better accuracy of the urban systems (Waddell, 2002; Salvini and Miller, 2005). Within urban

systems, firms are recognized as one of the interacting agents whose behaviour influence

regional and local development. Firm entry, exit, growth, and relocation affect labour,

transportation demand, demographic change and other aspects of urban systems.

Firmography, or firm demography, is the study of firm creation, growth, relocation, and

failure. Firm demography is important for several research fields such as microeconomics,

regional science, spatial economics, and transportation planning. Microeconomists are interested

in firmography to observe the economic impacts of labour dynamics, production, sales, and stock

and commodity exchange (Basu at al., 1998; Eidson and Ehlen, 2005; Ehlen et al., 2007).

Transportation planners focus on firm evolution (e.g. firm birth, growth, death, and relocation)

because of their impacts on transportation patterns for passenger and freight trips (Salvini and

Miller, 2005; Roorda et al., 2010). Regional scientists and spatial economists study firmography

because it affects labour force dynamics, labour qualifications and wages, local demand,

demographics, agglomeration economies, urban size, and transportation patterns (Acs and

Storey, 2004; Arauzo-Cardo and Teruel-Carrizosa, 2005; Piacentinoet al., 2016). In addition,

firmographic events induce population demographic changes by attracting skilled labour to

regions where firms are located (van Wissen, 2000).

Freight transportation is a key component of any transportation system. Freight demand is

largely affected by, and affects, land use development projects and the spatial/demographic

composition of urban forms. Current IUMs (such as ILUTE presented by Miller and Salvini,

Page 21: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

2

1998) lack the presence of comprehensive micro-level freight models that simulate the behaviour

and interactions of the individual freight agents. In micro-level freight models, firms (including

shippers, carriers, and logistics service providers) are considered the main interacting agents

whose interrelations induce freight demand. The integration of firm micromodels to IUMs is not

only for representing freight demand and studying resulting effects on land use, but also to

provide accurate representation of the job-supply side in the labour market, which is a

fundamental element of IUMs.

Agent-based firmographic models are suitable to simulate firms in freight systems as they

provide a closer representation of the actual interactions of the agents. Such micro-level

modelling can be used to simulate policy effects on firm dynamics and changes in urban form.

This research focuses on studying firm evolution and associated behaviour at the micro level.

Firmographic events of firm entry, growth, exit, and freight outsourcing decisions are the core

firm behaviour investigated in this study. The presented research is to serve for future freight

microsimulation and integration with ILUTE.

This thesis provides three main contributions to the literature:

• Introduction and partial implementation of the first national level firm microsimulation in

Canada using real data. The microsimulation represents firm evolution and models

associated behaviour with impact on freight systems. It incorporates economic growth,

industry dynamics, and firm characteristics and strategic focus in a unified framework.

• Exploration of new sources of firm micro-level databases that are suitable for, but have

not been used before, firm microsimulation.

• Presentation of firm micromodels of firm start-up size, growth, and outsourcing that have

not been introduced earlier in the Canadian literature.

1.2. Motivation

Behavioural freight transportation modelling has recently emerged as an approach to enhance

the quality of freight and logistics decision assessments. Early freight transportation models were

based on the conventional four-stage or commodity-based approaches (Pendyala et al., 2000;

Cambridge Systematics, 1996; Fischer et al., 2000; Cambridge Systematics, 1998). These

approaches are aggregate and were generally developed using the passenger demand modelling

Page 22: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

3

paradigm. They fail to represent interaction among system agents; hence their accuracy for

freight modelling is questioned (Roorda et al., 2010). On the other hand, agent-based

microsimulation allows for tracking individual agent decisions, and explicit modelling of

interrelated behaviour.

Firmography is a new approach in freight microsimulation modelling; it has been introduced

in few recent transportation and land use modelling efforts in North America (Maoh and

Kanaroglou, 2005; Kumar and Kockelman, 2008). These efforts considered firms as primary

agents and focused mainly on modelling firm failure, expansion, contraction, and location choice

for specific business segments in certain regions with some data limitations (as will be discussed

in chapter 2).

The majority of firmographic models in the literature (Maoh, 2005; Maoh and Kanaroglou,

2005; van Wissen, 2000; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006; Moeckel, 2005) address firm growth as the

change in the employment size and considered other assets (e.g. vehicle fleets, and number of

business locations) as exogenous variables. Firm growth can be fiscal (e.g. growth in profits,

sales values, and revenues) or physical (e.g. employment, floor space, and machinery and

equipment) depending on each firm’s performance indicators and long-term strategies. It is

expected that correlation exists between different measures of growth. For instance, a firm with

growing sales values may consider increasing their production capacity, and may hire new

employees and expand their physical form in new locations. Models that address firm growth in

a multi-dimensional fashion are not covered in the literature. Firm start-up size models are also

absent at the micro-level. Furthermore, models of other freight-related decisions such as

outsourcing, and commercial vehicle fleet ownership, are missing in the literature. The purpose

of this thesis is to investigate modelling methods to address these gaps in the literature.

1.3. Existing Work

The research of Maoh and Kanaroglou (2005; 2007a; 2007b;2009;2013) is the first (and so

far, the only) attempt in the Canadian literature that addresses firmography in IUMs using firm

microdata. Their study provides a modelling framework of firmographic events for the purpose

of microsimulation. The study focused on small and medium sized business establishments

located in the city of Hamilton, Ontario, Canada. The microsimulation utilized Statistics

Canada’s longitudinal Business Registry (BR) data set for the time interval of 1996 to 2002. The

Page 23: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

4

microsimulation presents models of firm failure, mobility, and location choice decisions. Firm

entry and growth are not covered in their microsimulation.

Khan (2002) introduced an agent-based microsimulation of business establishments in a

spatial economic system using a synthetic population. Birth, death, growth, and relocation, are

the firmographic events of consideration in addition to location choice decisions. Birth event is

modelled using probabilistic distributions and Monte Carlo simulation. The growths/shrinkage of

firms are represented in terms of spatial (floor space) expansion of establishments, and

production and consumption of other commodities. The microsimulation is then used for policy

testing scenarios. No other studies are found in the Canadian context of firm microsimulation for

IUMs. Chapter 2 reviews other studies of firmography worldwide and discusses research gaps in

detail.

1.4. Research Goals, Objectives, and Scope

The goal of this research is to introduce a framework of firm microsimulation with a focus on

firm behaviour with direct influence on transportation systems. More specifically, this research

focuses on studying firm behaviour of start-up size, growth, failure, and freight outsourcing with

a case study of Canadian firms.

This research introduces a comprehensive firm microsimulation framework that is called the

firmographic engine. The engine is designed to microsimulate the stages of firm evolution

starting at the entrepreneurial phase of firm entry, and covering the basic firmographic events of

firm birth, growth, relocation, and exit. The engine simulates interactions between individual

firms to replicate freight system dynamics. This research also introduces a suite of firm

behavioural models to formulate parts of the underlying modules of the firmographic engine. The

full implementation and operation of the engine has not yet been completed, however parts of its

components are being implemented, by a research team at the University of Toronto, using the

behavioural models introduced in this thesis.

The microsimulation represents the freight system at the individual firm level, and across

industries in different regions. Firmography is mainly driven by market demand and supply,

economic conditions, and firm attributes such as size, age, and location. The engine incorporates

individual firm characteristics, industry attributes, economic conditions, and market competition

to model firm evolution.

Page 24: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

5

This thesis introduces micromodels of firm start-up size, firm growth, firm exit, and freight

outsourcing decisions of Canadian firms. Firmographic events are studied and modelled using

longitudinal micro datasets of Canadian firms in the interval of 2001-2012, with a focus on

single-location, and small and medium sized firms (i.e. 100 employees and less). Small and

medium sized firms account for a large portion of the Canadian GDP. In 2005, small and

medium sized firms accounted for 54.3% of the Canadian GDP (Leung et al., 2012). They also

account for over half of the GDP in all industries except for mining and oil and gas,

manufacturing, transportation and information where large-size firms dominated (Leung et al.,

2012). In 2014, single location firms constituted 93.7% of the entire Canadian firm population,

while single-location and small and medium sized one (i.e. 100 employees and less) constituted

91.7% of the total firm population (Statistics Canada, 2014; 2016c). In 2017, small sized firms

(50 and less employees) contributed with an average of 30% to the Canadian GDP (Statistics

Canada, 2016d).

In this research, firm size is addressed in two aspects; the number of employees and the value

of the tangible assets. Models of firm start-up size and growth consider both aspects of growth

and their potential dependency. For each of the studied firm behaviour, two types of models are

estimated; simple and detailed models. The simple model set utilizes basic firm attributes (e.g.

size, age, industry class, and provincial location), and economic growth indicators (e.g. GDP

growth and provincial unemployment rates). The detailed models use additional firm attributes

(e.g. tangible assets, and sales values) and industry dynamic variables (e.g. entry and exit rates).

The simple models are the foundation of the firmographic engine, while the detailed ones are to

enrich our understanding of firm evolution. Each of the presented models have been validated at

the aggregate level to assess their performance.

The firmographic engine is designed to be integrated with other microsimulation models of

transportation system. Within freight microsimulation, the engine is to be integrated with

FREMIS (Freight Market Interactions Simulation); an agent-based microsimulation of shipper-

carrier interactions in the freight market (Cavalcante and Roorda, 2013). This integration covers

parts of operational strategy formation in the firmographic engine that are related to carrier

selection (discussed in chapter 3).

The firmographic engine provides information on the job supply side (i.e. job creation and

destruction) provided at the firm level in each industry (NAICS 2-digit code). This micro-level

Page 25: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

6

information is needed to simulate labour dynamics within IUMs such as ILUTE (Integrated Land

Use, Transportation, Environment) introduced by (Miller et al., 2004). The engine provides

yearly labour dynamics of job creation through firm start-up size and firm growth models, and

job destruction through firm growth and exit models.

Freight outsourcing is a key behaviour in freight systems, and has hardly been covered in the

transport modelling literature. This thesis presents micromodels of freight outsourcing decisions

of Canadian manufacturers. Two aspects of freight activities are considered; logistics and

distribution, and goods production. Models of outsourcing’s geographic location (local vs.

international) are also explored.

Economic growth, firmography, and industry dynamics (i.e. entry and exit rates) are

intertwined. Economic growth induces new opportunities for business ventures which

encourages entrepreneurs to open new firms, and existing firms to grow and expand. Similarly,

new and growing firms, and exiting firms influence the economic growth of a region. On the

industry level, a growing demand generates momentum for firm birth and growth, which boosts

the economy. These two-way relationships between the three entities are entwined and hard to

model. The presented microsimulation represents economic growth and industry dynamics as

external variables to firm evolution processes.

This research explores the use of new data sources for firm microsimulation. Two micro

datasets are utilized to estimate the introduced firm micromodels; the T2-Longitudinal

Employment Analysis Program (T2-LEAP), and Survey of Innovation and Business Strategy

(SIBS) provided by Statistics Canada. T2-LEAP is a micro-level longitudinal dataset of

Canadian firms that was made available for our research for the interval of 2001-2012. SIBS is a

cross-sectional database that collects information about firm strategic focus and use of

innovation and technology.

The long-term goal of the firmographic engine is to be used as a tool to evaluate the effect of

policy change on firm evolution over time. Examples of such policies include trade agreements,

government incentives, and land use and taxation policies.

1.5. Dissertation Structure

This dissertation is composed of eight chapters as summarized in FIGURE 1.1. This chapter

introduces the background, motivation and the gaps this research is aiming to cover. In chapter 2,

Page 26: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

7

a comprehensive literature review of firm microsimulation models with an emphasis on freight

systems is presented. The literature review covers different research fields such as urban

planning, economics, regional science, business management, industrial organization, and

transportation and land use. Research gaps in firm microsimulation are stated in chapter 2, which

are the foundation of the remainder of the thesis.

In chapter 3, a framework of firm microsimulation, called the firmographic engine, is

presented. The chapter discusses the main components of the engine. The used data sources to

implement parts of the engine are also discussed in chapter 3. Potential integration with other

microsimulation models for transportation systems is also explored.

Chapter 4 introduces the first set of micromodels of firm events; firm start-up size, expressed

as the number of employees and tangible assets. The models are for for-profit industries only.

The models utilize the longitudinal T2-LEAP database linked to external data of economic

indicators. The ordered logit approach is adopted for firm start-up size models. A literature

review on determinants of firm start-up size is also presented.

Chapter 5 includes a suite of firm growth models (expressed as the number of employees and

tangible assets) for single-location small-medium sized firms (no. of employees less than 100) of

for-profit industries. Several model structures are explored for firm employment growth

including ordered logit, random effects panel logistic regression, random effects-multilevel

regression, and Autoregressive Distributed Lag-Model (ARDL). Only ARDL model structure is

estimated for tangible assets models. Furthermore, seemingly unrelated regression (SURE) is

explored to study the potential correlation between the two aspects of growth of employment and

tangible assets.

Chapter 6 presents survival analyses of single-location small- and medium-sized firms. It

starts with a brief literature on determinants of firm failure. Non-parametric and parametric

analyses of firm survival are explored. The non-parametric analysis presents survival and hazard

rates estimates using Kaplan and Meier and Nelson–Aalen estimators characterized by firm age,

province, and industry. The parametric survival analysis introduces a discrete-time hazard

duration model of failure. A comparison of our findings to other Canadian studies of firm

survival is also presented.

In chapter 7, the cross-sectional SIBS database is used to estimate discrete choice models of

freight outsourcing decisions of Canadian manufacturers. Two modelling structures are explored:

Page 27: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

8

binary logit and multinomial logit structures. Models that distinguish outsourcing type (local vs.

international) are introduced. The last chapter, chapter 8, presents a summary of the research,

major findings, contribution to the literature, and future directions.

FIGURE 1.1 Dissertation Structure

(1) Introduction

[Background + gaps + objectives]

(2) Literature review of firm

microsimulation models

(3) The Firmographic Engine: A

Modelling Framework

(5) Firm growth

models

(6) Firm survival

analysis and models

(4) Firm start-up size

models

Firmographic events: Longitudinal analysis

(7) Outsourcing models of freight

activities

Behavioural micromodels: Cross-sectional analysis

(8) Conclusions

[Research contribution +future directions]

Page 28: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

9

1.6. Disclaimer

This research utilizes datasets that are owned by Statistics Canada, who has kindly approved

our research team for data access with some restrictions. All statistical information in this

research, which is related to T2-LEAP and SIBS datasets, has been reviewed and approved for

publishing by Statistics Canada. We are only allowed to discuss and publish the analysis, model

estimates, and results that are presented in this thesis. Statistics Canada has their own publicly

available reports and statistics that may overlap with some of the topics discussed in this

research. Any differences between the two sources are because of the nature of the presented

research, the scope, and the used methods and datasets.

Page 29: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

10

CHAPTER 2

A Review of Firmography in Freight Microsimulation

Modelling

2.1. Introduction

Firmography is a multidisciplinary research area that attracts researchers from fields

including economics, transportation/land use modelling, sociology, finance, geography, and

spatial sciences (van Wissen, 2000; Kumar and Kockelman, 2008). Firmography analyzes the

major events of firm formation, growth/decline, death, and location/relocation (Khan, 2002;

Maoh, 2005; de Bok, 2007). Firmography has emerged as an approach to enhance the quality of

freight microsimulation models because it allows for understanding the evolution of firm

structure and behaviour at the micro level (van Wissen, 1996; van Dijk and Pellenbarg, 2000;

Wisetjindawat et al., 2007; Kumar and Kockelman, 2008; Abed et al., 2014). Behavioural

models that have introduced firmography in freight microsimulation are scarce in the literature.

In this chapter, a comprehensive review of the state-of-research in firmography is presented,

as it relates to freight models. The chapter starts by explaining firm life cycle and its association

with the firmographic events of firm birth, growth, and survival, and their determinants. Next, a

review of agent-based models that consider firm microsimulation, in the past fifteen years, is

presented. An in-depth review of firm micro-modelling in the field of freight transportation

follows. Finally, the chapter highlights challenges to firmography with some remarks on gaps

observed in the literature for future research directions.

2.2. Firmography and Firm Life Cycle

Firm formation/entry/birth is defined as the event of new firm entry to the market; firms that

did not previously exist (de Bok, 2007; Khan, 2002). Firm exit/closure/failure/dissolution/death

is the event of firm disappearance from the market in a specific year that was present in the

previous years (Khan, 2002). Market exit can either be in the form of merging with other firms

or a complete market exit (Khan et al., 2002; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2005). A

Migration/relocation event is when an establishment changes its geographic location by either

moving within a specific region (intra-migration), or moving out of the region (out-migration)

Page 30: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

11

(Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007a). Growth/expansion and decline/contraction events are when a

measure of firm size (e.g. employment, and number of business establishments) changes over

time. A firm may operate one or more business establishment. If a firm operates more than one

business establishment it is called a multi-establishment firm, otherwise it is called a single-

establishment firm (Maoh, 2005).

Firms base survival and exit decisions on their performance. Firms evaluate their

performance differently; some may use a single metric to assess their performance, while others

may use multiple metrics depending on their economic sector, long-term strategic focus, and

firm’s life cycle. For example, manufacturers may assess their performance by market growth,

production cost, and sales value, while service providers may focus on service times, and

customer satisfaction. Sometimes performance measures change according to the firm’s life

cycle. New start-ups may focus more on achieving market niches by targeting market share

growth, whereas mature firms may focus on revenues and production cost (Mueller, 1972).

Long-term strategies also influence performance measure selection. For instance, firms with

long-term strategies of market positioning and product leadership may assess their performance

based on customer satisfaction and minimized delivery times, while firms adopting mass market

and low-price long-term strategies may use market share and sales growth rates as performance

indicators.

2.2.1. What influences firmography?

Firm evolution is affected by factors related to firm characteristics and strategies, industry,

economic conditions, location (e.g. proximities to highways), population demographics, and

local policies and government incentives. A summary of such factors found in the literature is

provided in TABLE 2.1 (van Wissen, 2000; Maoh, 2005; Moeckel, 2005; de Bok and Bliemer,

2006; Fritsch et al., 2006; Elgar and Miller, 2006; Hu et al., 2008; Bodenmann and Axhausan,

2010; Baptista and Leitão, 2015). Details of how such factors affect firmographic events are

provided in sections 2.2.4, 2.2.5, and 2.2.6 for firm birth, firm growth, and firm exit.

Page 31: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

12

TABLE 2.1 A Summary of Factors Influencing Firmography

Category Factor

Firm related

• Employment size

• Age

• Number of business locations (e.g. production

facilities and warehouses)

• Freight operation decisions (e.g. outsourcing)

• Sales values

• No. of offered products/services

• Growth rates (measured in number of employees,

sales values, profits, or market shares)

• Product Life Cycle (PLC)

• R&D investments

• Business and operational strategies (e.g. financial,

production, marketing, resources and supply

chain, and innovation and technology strategies)

Industry related

• Age of the industry

• Industry Life Cycle (ILC)

• Market competition

• Industry size

• Technological advancements and innovations

• Technology Life Cycle (TLC)

• Availability of materials

Macroeconomic related

• Economies of scale per industry

• Agglomeration economies

• Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and access to

capital (investment potentials)

• Unemployment rates

Location population

demographics

• Average income levels

• Labour market and labour cost

• Population educational level

Location geographic

characteristics

• Space availability and prices

• Location of business owners

• Target customers

• Proximity to other businesses (e.g. suppliers,

carriers, and distribution centres)

• Freeway access and traffic patterns

Local policies • Government financial incentives

• Tax rates and regulations

Page 32: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

13

2.2.2. Firm life cycle

The terms Product Life Cycle (PLC), Technology Life Cycle (TLC), and Industry Life Cycle

(ILC) are used in the literature to reflect changes over time within industries, but with some key

distinctions. PLCs are usually measured as a function of the product sales cycles (Levitt, 1965).

A typical PLC is composed of four stages: introduction, growth, maturity, and decline (Cohen,

2010). As explained in FIGURE 2.1, during market introduction, production costs are higher with

a slow growing rate of revenues, while in the growth stage, costs are starting to drop with the

increase of production (approaching economies of scale) and hence revenues increase. Maturity

is attained when constant rates of revenue are achieved with declining costs. When revenues are

declining with the increase of incurred costs, the product is then said to be in a decline stage; that

is usually followed by a failure or product cancellation (Polli and Cook, 1969; Tibben-Lembke,

2002).

FIGURE 2.1 Schematic of a Typical; Product Life Cycle1

TLCs are influenced by technology improvement rates, age of the technology, process

innovation, and market acceptance (Foster, 1988). TLCs and ILCs follow similar life cycles to

PLCs (Lumpkin and Dess, 2001; Haupt et al., 2007) with some differences. TLCs are not

1 This is a common graph that explains product life cycle adopted from Polli and Cook (1969) and Tibben-Lembke

(2002)

$ p

er p

erio

d

Time

Cost Revenue Profit

Introduction Growth Maturity Decline Product Cancellation(Failure )

Page 33: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

14

specific to certain products, rather to components or material technologies (Cohen, 2010). On the

other hand, ILCs are addressed differently depending on the field of study. For instance,

economists of the industrial organization address ILCs through entry and exit patterns of firms

(Gort and Klepper, 1982), while in the field of evolutionary economics the scope is shifted to

understand competition within industries (Winter and Nelson, 1982).

In general, firm evolution is affected by all three life cycles (Dinlersoz and MacDonald,

2009). New and technologically thriving industries create opportunities for new products to exist,

and hence higher rates of firm births are expected. Firms shift their focus to production

innovation by introducing new or significantly enhanced products/services to achieve better

market shares (Rainey, 2008). Over time, market stability is achieved, entry rates are decreased,

and firm exits take over, and efforts are shifted to improve the process innovation by improving

production or delivery methods to maintain market shares (Klepper, 1996; Wang, 2006;

Davenport, 2013). Moreover, within industries, new/growing products may result in higher rates

of firm birth and existing firm expansion, while products at the mature and declining stages

increase firm contraction decisions and produce higher exit rates.

Growth of individual firms is a function of the growth of the constituent units of firm

production, i.e. number of products or services (Growiec et al., 2008). Thus, firms follow similar

evolution patterns to product life cycles; starting at market introduction, followed by firm

growth, maturity/market stability, and potential firm exit (decline) (Lewis and Churchill, 1983).

Expansion and contraction decisions of firms are a function of the life cycle stage. Firms

expand during growth stages either geographically by opening new business establishments,

growing their other assets such as their employment and vehicle fleet, or introducing new

products. They may also receive offers from other firms to merge. During decline stages,

shrinkage and exit decisions are likely to occur; shutting down some product lines/services,

relocating to smaller places with employment contraction, or merging/selling to other companies

(Lewis and Churchill, 1983; Nandkeolyar et al., 1993).

2.2.3. Relationship between firmographic events

Firmographic events are interrelated depending on the economic sector, market conditions,

and local policies and regulations. There is a correlation between firm entry and firm exit on the

aggregate level; with higher entry rates, higher exit rates are observed (Geroski, 1991; Mata and

Page 34: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

15

Machado, 1996). Higher firm entry rates induce market competition resulting in some firms with

better market shares, and other failure firms who are unable to compete. Hence, it is hard to

study firm birth or death independently without considering the other. Firm survival/failure is

affected by relocation decisions, and entry and exit rates (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b).

Firmographic events are governed mainly by the market economic conditions (van Wissen,

2000). Across industries, increased demands for production increase the chances of firm birth

and growth. This is referred to as the concept of carrying capacity (Hannan and Carroll, 1992;

Hannan and Freeman, 1989). van Wissen (2000), p.116, defined carrying capacity as “the

maximum size a population can attain under the conditions of the current environment”; it is the

market demand. The difference between market demand (Kt) and supply (Xt) is called ‘market

stress’ or ‘market pressure’. Market stress is used as an economic demographic behaviour

predictor. Within industries, if the demand is higher than the supply (i.e. [Kt – Xt] is a positive

value), chances for market growth are increased (either by introducing new firms or expand

existing ones). Firm expansion can happen by opening new business establishments, expanding

employment and/or floor space, or by merger and acquisitions with other firms (Park and Jang,

2011). Alternatively, when supply is larger than demand, the market is in the state of contraction

where firms consider closure and contraction decisions (see FIGURE 2.2). van Wissen (1996)

presented a detailed representation of market demand (K) using spatial input-output models by

industry.

Page 35: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

16

FIGURE 2.2 Relationship between Market Stress and Firmographic Decisions

2.2.4. Firm birth (entry)

The decision to start a new firm is based on the intentions of entrepreneurs to be self-

employed and become independent (Shane et al., 1991; Reynolds, 1997; Kolvereid and Isaksen,

2006; Koster, 2006). New independent firms are usually founded by experienced individuals

who prefer to work independently (Birley and Westhead, 1994; van Wissen, 2000). Also,

unemployment affects firm birth; creating a new business is one way of becoming employed

(Beesley and Hamilton, 1994). Once an entrepreneur forms an intention of new business entry,

exploring business opportunities begins (Shook et al., 2003). A decision of starting a new

business venture or selling the idea to other operating firms is then followed. Once the decision

of starting a new venture is selected, a series of strategic decisions need to be made (e.g.

resources, capital investments, and logistics decisions). The entry decision and the characteristics

of the new business are mainly influenced by the founders’ demographics such as age, gender,

education, experience, nationality, and location (Shane et al., 1991; Barkham, 1994; Beesley and

Hamilton, 1994; Reynolds, 1997; van Wissen, 2000; Colombo and Grilli, 2005; Elgar et al.,

Market stress

Demand (Kt) – Supply (Xt)

Market growth

Demand > Supply Market contraction

Demand < Supply

New firms Expand existing

New business

establishments

Expand floor

space/employment

or relocate

Firm closure Firm contraction

Close business

establishments Contract employment or

relocate

Merger and acquisition

Page 36: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

17

2009). The social network of entrepreneurs also plays an important role during firm start-up and

influences firm survival (Birley, 1986; Anderson et al., 2005).

Generally, firms tend to start small (in size) to reduce losses in the case of firm failure, and to

minimize sunk costs (Birley, 1986; Mata and Machado, 1996). Also, small new firms are more

flexible in location selection decisions, while larger ones would locate where economies of scale

are present to minimize risks (Mata and Machado, 1996). New start-ups grow gradually when

they start making profit and gain adequate market positions. During the growth stage, firms

might consider expansion either (geographically to target different customers) or in assets and

investments (to enhance the current market status and maintain stability).

It is hard to model the firm entry decision because the non-entry decision is not observed

(Melillo et al., 2013). Therefore, firm entry is mostly addressed on the aggregate level by

estimating the entry rates by considering industry sector, exit rates, and economic conditions

(van Wissen, 2000; Kumar and Kockelman, 2008).

2.2.4.1. Start-up size

One of many decisions new entrants have to determine is their number of employees or, as

commonly referred to in the literature, firm start-up size. Many researchers claim that firm start-

up size is an important determinant of a firm’s subsequent performance and survival (Dunne et

al., 1989; Audretsch and Mahmood, 1994; Mata and Portugal, 1994; Mata et al., 1995; Almus,

2000; Görg et al., 2000). Modelling firm start-up size in a microsimulation context is essential to

understand job creation, because new firms are sources of new employment opportunities. For

example, in the United States, between 1976 and 1984, new firms are found responsible for 74%

of 50.8 million new jobs (Kirchhoff and Philips, 1988). In the United Kingdom, around the same

time, 48% percent of new jobs are the result of new small firms (Gallagher et al., 1991).

Some empirical studies link firm start-up size to founder characteristics, industry size and

growth, location, financing opportunities, market competition, and business strategies (Barkham,

1994; Mata, 1996; Mata and Machado, 1996; Görg et al., 2000; Baum et al., 2001; Görg and

Strobl, 2002; Colombo et al., 2004; Colombo and Grilli, 2005; de Jorge et al., 2010). From an

economic perspective, economies of scale are a major factor influencing firm start-up size (Mata,

1996). Mata and Machado (1996) suggest that firm start-up size increases with economies of

scale and the rate of firm entry and exit per industry. As a result, small firms tend to enter the

market and locate anywhere geographically, while larger ones appear only where agglomeration

Page 37: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

18

economies exist. Moreover, the amount of capital required to operate a minimum efficiently

scaled firm (MES) has a negative relationship with the new firm population size, because higher

start-up costs discourage entrepreneurs (Fonseca et al., 2001; Geroski, 1991; Mata et al., 1995).

New firms tend to enter the market below MES which affects the unit production cost compared

to their larger competitors (due to economies of scale), and hence survival is difficult. To

survive, firms need to reduce the production cost by approaching economies of scale to

maximize profits and continue to grow in the market (See FIGURE 2.3).

FIGURE 2.3 Average Cost and Production Relationship2

Financing means also influence many strategic decisions of new firms (Scherr et al., 1993)

including start-up size. Colombo and Grilli (2005) explored the financing means of firm start-ups

in Italy, and they claim that debt-financed firms are not larger in size compared to firms financed

by personal savings of owners, for technology-based firms in manufacturing and service

industries. Robb and Coleman (2010) concluded, based on a study in the United States, that

larger firms tend to use more business debt while small businesses (especially home-based firms)

rely on personal savings and avoid external debt. It seems that the details of the debt-financing

strategies are different from one country to another subject to regulations and economic factors,

2 This is a common graph in economics that explains Long Run Average Cost (LRAC) adopted from Mukherjee et

al. (2004), Mankiw and Taylor (2006), and Found (2012)

Ave

rag

e p

rod

uctio

n c

ost ($

)

Production Q2Q1

C2

C1

Minimum Efficient Scale(MES)

Long Run Average Cost(LARC)

Diseconomies of ScaleEconomies of Scale

Page 38: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

19

hence the effect of the adopted financing strategies for new firms would differ from one country

to another.

While most of the previously cited literature deals with firm start-up size as an independent

decision, Melillo et al. (2012) argue that start-up size depends on the venture entry type. They

explained that the number of employees at firm start-up is a range that depends on the type of

entrepreneurship, hybrid or self-employed. Hybrid entrepreneurs (those who are still employed

by other firms) benefit their new businesses by their strong ties to the market, and hence they

tend to start in relatively smaller sizes. Self-employed entrepreneurs start their business

independently and may require more experienced personnel to grow their businesses.

2.2.5. Firm growth

Most studies have addressed firm growth as a function of the change in number of

employees, because of the economic importance of job creation. Fewer studies have considered

firm growth from a financial perspective (Williams et al., 1995; Huynh and Petrunia, 2010; Coad

and Broekel, 2012). Previous studies suggest that firm growth is a function of firm-related and

industry-based factors such as firm age, investments in research and development (R&D), wages,

business strategies, innovation and technology, industry structure, and market competition, (van

Wissen, 2000; Maoh, 2005; Moekel, 2005; Bodenmann and Axhausan, 2010; Haltiwanger et al.,

2013). Growth also can be attributed to other behavioural aspects such as CEO’s traits (Baum et

al., 2001).

One common debate between researchers is whether firm growth is independent from

employment size (known as Gibrat’s law, or the rule of proportionate growth). Gibrat’s law

states that firm size and its relative rate of growth are independent (Gibrat, 1931). Recent studies

have rejected Gibrat’s law (Wagner, 1992; Audretsch, 1995b; Reid, 1995; Harhoff et al., 1998;

Weiss, 1998; Almus and Nerlinger, 1999; Audretsch et al., 1999; Calvo, 2006; Haltiwanger et

al., 2013) with a consistent conclusion that small new firms have higher growth rates compared

to larger ones (Segal and Spivak, 1989; Almus, 2000; Haltiwanger et al., 2013). Furthermore,

Gibrat’s law cannot be generalized to all firm types since firm growth is a function of other

factors such as market segmentation, country, and economic conditions. Lotti et al. (2003)

conducted a study on Italian manufacturers and concluded that Gibrat’s law fails for small new

firms in years immediately following their birth, while the law cannot be rejected for subsequent

Page 39: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

20

years for older or large firms. Their conclusion agrees with Segal and Spivak (1989) that Gibrat’s

law holds only for large firms. This can be explained by new entrants trying to grow faster to

reach the economies of scale to reduce their costs and achieve market stability (Cabral, 1995;

Lotti et al., 2003; Park and Jang, 2010).

Some studies (Mansfield, 1962; Evans, 1987b; Das, 1995; Huynh and Petrunia, 2010; Park

and Jang, 2010) argue that employment size has a negative relationship with firm growth while

others state the opposite (Singh and Whittington, 1975). This contradiction might be due to the

differences of the studied firm populations and economic sectors. Firms with previous faster

employment growth are more likely to experience future growth as well, but at a slower rate

(Wagner, 1992; van Wissen, 2000; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006). Similarly, profit impacts

employment growth; profit of prior year positively affects the growth of the current year. At the

same time current and prior growth has impact over profitability (Jang and Park, 2011). In other

words, profit induces growth while growth reduces profitability.

Firm age, and R&D investments are found to have a positive impact on firm growth and

survival (Mueller, 1972; Winter and Nelson, 1982; Geroski, 1991; Das, 1995). Other adopted

business strategies such as production and market strategies influence firm growth. For instance,

manufacturing strategies that focus on product quality and production capacity were found to

have positive influences on firm performance in terms of sales growth (Williams et al., 1995;

Amoako-Gyampah and Acquaah, 2008). Adopting competitive strategies of product low prices,

and product differentiation have a positive effect over firm growth as well (Baum et al., 2001).

Innovation practices positively affect firm growth (Acs and Audretsch, 1988; Soni et al., 1993).

Small new firms are more innovative and perform better than their larger counterparts (Soni et

al., 1993; Tether, 1998).

Market conditions and demand govern firm growth potential; the greater the gap between

demand and market supply, the larger the market growth potential, be it new firms, growth of

existing ones, or merger and acquisition (van Wissen, 2000). Market competition, ILC, and

industry structure (including customer concentration and access to resources) affect firm growth

(Marino and De Noble, 1997; Dinlersoz and MacDonald, 2009). Geroski and Gugler (2004)

modelled the impact of competitor firm growth on the firm employment growth. Their results

indicate that there is no statistical significance between competitor growth and employment

growth except for some specific industries such as manufacturers, where a negative effect is

Page 40: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

21

observed. Also, growth rates vary according to competition type; Park and Jang (2010) conclude

that small international firms have higher decline rates compared to their small domestic

counterparts, while large international ones have slower decline rates than large domestic ones.

This is because small domestic firms are more familiar with their markets and customers, thus

they use their resources more optimally compared to international small firms who have limited

learning capacity and usually take a long time to adjust to foreign markets.

The majority of studies that have investigated firm growth present one dimensional models

(e.g. number of employees, sales, or profits). In a unique study, Coad and Broekel (2012)

consider firm growth as the simultaneous growth of both employment and production (sales).

Their analysis underlines that there is no strong relationship between production growth and

employment growth, but there is an inverse association between employment and production

growth; an increase of 1% in employment growth is associated with a 0.1% decrease in

production growth in the following year.

2.2.6. Firm exit/survival

Firms exit the market either by announcing bankruptcy or by merging with other firms (van

Wissen, 2000). Modelling the exit decision as a discrete choice is challenging. Usually, founders

of firms that completely disappear from the market are hard to track making it difficult to

investigate the reasons for the exit decision. Survival and hazard duration models are commonly

used in studies identified in the literature to model firm exit rather than using discrete choice

models (Mata and Portugal, 1994; Bhattacharjee, 2005; Fritsch et al., 2006; Maoh and

Kanaroglou, 2007b; Strotmann, 2007; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010).

Firm survival is affected mainly by two groups of factors; firm specific and industry specific

attributes (van Wissen, 2000; Strotmann, 2007). Firm specific attributes are age, size, growth

rate, PLC, business strategies, location, R&D investments, and innovation practices (Mata et al.,

1995; Stearn et al., 1995; Reynlods, 1997; van Wissen, 2000; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006; Maoh

and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010; Manzato et al., 2011; Schröder and

Sørensen, 2012). Industry specific factors are the economic sector, ILC, agglomeration

economies, and economies of scale (van Wissen, 2000; Strotmann, 2007; Klapper and

Richmond, 2011). Also, characteristics of business founder (e.g. gender) affect some strategic

Page 41: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

22

decisions such as human and financial resources and affect the decisions of business

discontinuance (Carter et al., 1997).

There appears to be a consensus that large and older firms have higher survival probabilities

than small younger ones (Reynolds, 1987; Stearns et al., 1995; van Wissen, 2000; de Bok and

Bliemer; 2006; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010). Exit potential

decreases with increased growth rates; small new firms that experience faster growth rates are

more likely to survive in the market (Mata and Portugal, 1994; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006; Nunes

and Sarmento, 2010). Similarly, production growth rates positively affect firm survival (Schröder

and Sørensen, 2012). Some studies highlighted that firm initial size has an influence on firm

survival (Strotmann, 2007; Schröder and Sørensen, 2012). Firms with large start-up sizes have

better survival chances (Mata and Portugal, 1994). New firms also tend to be more flexible in

changing their strategies to adapt with changes in the economic conditions, market segmentation,

and cope with technological and innovation advancements. Inert firms (firm with more fixed

strategies) have better survival chances compared to firms with a more dynamic nature (van

Wissen, 2000). Several studies in different countries reported that the median life time of newly

born firms is between year five and six after market introduction (Mata and Portugal, 1994;

Wagner, 1994; Audretsch et al., 1999; Bahttacharjee, 2005; Bartelsman et al., 2005; López-

Garcia and Puente, 2006; Schrör, 2009; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010). Moreover, firm growth and

survival seem to be largely affected by the amount of R&D investment (Fritsch et al., 2006;

Nunes and Sarmento, 2010; Sharapov et al., 2011; Zhang and Mohnen, 2013). While survival

probabilities increase with larger R&D investment (Fritsch et al., 2006; Sharapov et al., 2011),

Zhang and Mohnen (2013) pointed that there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between R&D

and firm survival indicating that over investing on R&D increases the risk of firm failure.

Firm survival is related to firm entry and exit rates within industries (Mata and Portugal,

1994; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006). Firms born in industries with higher entry rates have lower

chances of survival because of increased competition (Mata et al., 1995; Nunes and Sarmento,

2010). Foreign firms have lower hazard rates than domestic ones, while state-owned firms have

higher hazard rates than privately owned ones because they are more susceptible to the local

economic conditions (Zhang and Mohnen, 2013). Gross Domestic Product (GDP) growth was

found to have a positive influence over firm survival (Baldwin et al., 2000; Klapper and

Page 42: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

23

Richmond, 2011). Furthermore, failure probability is high in industries where minimum efficient

scale is high, demand is low, and the market is narrow (Fritsch et al., 2006; Strotmann, 2007).

Firm location, on the other hand, reflects the macro-economic conditions of the region,

agglomeration economies, and access to resources (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b). Strotmann

(2007) argue that firms in highly agglomerated geographic regions have higher risk of death. To

accept or reject this conclusion, other economic conditions must be taken into consideration such

as the industry class and the market stress. Market stress, that reflects the difference between

market demand and supply, has a negative effect on firm exit; the higher chances for new firms

and more productions are, the lower the exit potential is. PLCs and ILCs also influence firm

survival (Agarwal and Gort, 2002). Firms with products at declining stages, or belong to

industries with a saturated market might consider exiting the market. Also, firms in highly

innovative environments have lower survival chances (Audretsch, 1995a).

2.2.7. Firm behaviour: and evolutionary perspective

Most of the studies surveyed in the literature that addresses firm entry have either

investigated the entrepreneurial side of the decision (Beesley and Hamilton, 1994; Praag, 1997;

Kolvereid and Isaksen, 2006), modelled the employment size at the start-up (Barkham, 1994;

Mata, 1996; Baum et al., 2001; Colombo et al., 2004; de Jorge, 2010), linked regional

characteristics to new firms (Storey, 1982; Reynolds et al., 1994), used probabilistic distributions

and Monte Carlo simulation to identify characteristics of new entries (Khan et al., 2002; Kumar

and Kockelman, 2008), or estimated firm formation at the aggregate level (van Wissen, 2000).

No studies are found that estimate characteristics and strategies of new firms at the micro level.

Firms interact in an agent-based complex adaptive system, where agents learn optimal

strategies through their experience and the experiences of their counterparts. New firms usually

choose successful strategies of the current firm population with similar economic activities.

New/existing firms may also consider introducing innovative strategies that are completely new

to the market. That kind of complex adaptive system is difficult to model using ordinary

behavioural discrete choice models.

Within market segments, successful strategies survive over the years while

weaker/unsuccessful ones vanish over time. This knowledge of strategy performance is

transferred between firm generations through experience. The research field called

Page 43: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

24

Organizational Learning is concerned with knowledge creation and transformation within

organizations (Cyert and March, 1963). Evolutionary economics, on the other hand, is a branch

of economics that studies the transformation of the economy by observing the growth behaviour

of economic agents using evolutionary methodologies (Friedman, 1998). Both disciplines use

similar methodologies to model the evolutionary behaviour of firms. Concepts from evolutionary

biology are used to describe the evolution patterns of firms. The firm population follows

Darwin’s natural selection and survival theories in biology. Firms follow the ‘survival of the

fittest’ law; firms with good strategies survive while others with weak strategies do not. These

principles have been employed in evolutionary economics to understand firm evolution and

model firm birth (Johnson et al., 2013). New firms (offspring) adopt a mix of the strategies

employed by the existing firm ‘population’ (mating). They also might launch novel strategies to

compete in the market (mutation). This behaviour can be modelled using Genetic Algorithms to

describe firm birth, and estimate the strategies of the new population of firms (Bruderer and

Singh, 1996). Using the same concepts, evolutionary patterns of firm failure can be captured by

tracking the changes in the strategies of failure firms in a genetic algorithm framework (Chen

and Hsiao, 2008).

2.3. Agent-based Models with Firm Microsimulation

Agent-based microsimulation of firm behaviour is a method that represents interacting agents

within economic markets (Basu et al., 1998; Maoh, 2005; Balmer et al., 2006; Roorda et al.,

2010; Cavalcante and Roorda, 2013). Firm microsimulation differs from one field to another.

Regional scientists and spatial economists focus on firm behaviour that is related to location and

influences the demographics and economic activities within a region (van Wissen, 2000).

Transportation planners focus on firmographic events (e.g. entry, growth, and exit) that induce

changes to transportation patterns, either passenger or freight trips (Salvini and Miller, 2005;

Roorda et al., 2010). The focus of microeconomists is to replicate the economic activities of

individual agents and their effect on the economic market, economic production, and

infrastructure dynamics (e.g. usage of electricity, telecommunications, and transportation) where

production and consumption of economic agents (e.g. households, firms, and government

agencies) are presented. In such models, firms are represented for their economic activities such

Page 44: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

25

as labour dynamics, production and selling activities, and stock and commodity exchanges (Basu

et al., 1998; Eidson and Ehlen, 2005; Ehlen et al., 2007).

Most studies that have addressed firmography have only focused on parts of the behaviour

such as birth (Shane et al., 1991; Birley and Westhead, 1994; shook et al., 2003; Kolvereid and

Isaksen, 2006), death (Strotmann, 2007; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010; Zhang and Mohnen, 2013),

growth (Lotti et al., 2003; Huynh and Petrunia, 2010; Park and Jang, 2010), and relocation

(Fritsch et al., 2006; Elgar et al., 2009; Hu et al., 2008; Bodenmann and Axhausan, 2010). In this

section, a review of firm microsimulation efforts, in the past 16 years, that address aspects of

firmography with a focus on spatial demography, and land use and transportation are presented.

TABLE 2.2 provides a summary of such studies highlighting the scope, firmographic events

investigated, data sources, and methods.

Page 45: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

26

TABLE 2.2 Summary of Firmographic Microsimulation Research Efforts

Study/year Location Data Scope Firmographic event Methods

SIMFIRMS:

van Wissen

(2000) Netherlands

Firm

Longitudinal

data set- LISA

(1990-1991)

Spatial modelling of

economic

demographic

Firm birth Logistic regression

Exit Logistic regression

Growth Regression

Sample size

10,000 Relocation

Binary, and multinomial logit

models

Maoh and

Kanaroglou

(2005)

The City of

Hamilton,

Ontario, Canada

Business

establishment

longitudinal data

set (1996-2002),

Statistics Canada

Business

Register (BR)

Integrated urban and

land use models

Failure

Discrete hazard duration model

of survival

Mobility (relocation)

Multinomial logit models by

economic sector Location choice

Moeckel

(2005) Dortmund,

Germany

Synthetic micro-

data based on

aggregate data

Integrated land use

and transportation

models,

Urban spatial

economy

Birth

Markov transition probabilities Growth/decline

Closure

Location choice and

relocation decisions

A series of Multinomial logit

models

Page 46: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

27

TABLE 2.2 Summary of Firmographic Microsimulation Research Efforts (continued)

Study/year Location Data Scope Firmographic

event

Methods

SMF:

de Bok and

Bliemer

(2006)

South

Holland, the

Netherlands

Firm

Longitudinal

data set- LISA

(1988-1997)

Integrated land use

and transport models

Formation Drawing from distribution at random –

Monte Carlo Simulation

Growth Autoregressive model based on firm and

location attributes

Closure Binary regression model and Monte

Carlo simulation

Migration Joint binary and Multinomial Logit

model

Kumar

and

Kockelman

(2008)

Austin, Texas,

the U.S. A

Firm

longitudinal

data (1998-

2004),

Statistics of

U.S.

Businesses

(SUSB)

• Transportation and

land use interaction

• Commercial vehicle

movement models

Entry Firm birth and death are represented

using 2001-2002 and 2002-2003 rates for

low and high growth respectively. Exit

Growth (expansion/

contraction)

Markov transition probabilities and

Monte Carlo simulation

Relocation Random selection of firm population

with a constant rate of 15%.

Location choice Poisson regression model

Commercial trip

generation Negative binomial regression

Commercial trip

distribution Logit model

Page 47: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

28

The work of van Wissen (2000) is a holistic firm microsimulation that addresses all aspects

of firmography. He introduced SIMFIRMS; a spatial demographic microsimulation of firms in

the Netherlands. SIMFIRMS assumes that firms are the primary agents associated with economic

growth. It microsimulates firm birth, growth, migration, and death. Firm birth is microsimulated

at the aggregate level using the concept of carrying capacity. The death module considers the

closure of individual firms as a function of some firm attributes (e.g. age and size), and factors

derived by the economic sector (e.g. availability of infrastructure, accessibility to other firms,

and local taxation). Firm growth is modelled as a function of firm size, location, economic

sector, and market pressure. Firm relocation is derived by two sets of factors; push and pull

factors. Push factors are negative aspects of the current location that cause the firm to consider

relocation (e.g. market segmentation changes, local policies, and location cost). Pull factors are

positive aspects of the new location (e.g. better market segmentation, local policies, and location

cost). Relocation decisions are influenced by age, firm growth rate, and market conditions. He

concluded that older firms are less likely to consider relocation, growing firms are more likely to

move, and the larger the market capacity, the less likely that a firm would relocate (van Wissen,

2000).

Maoh and Kanaroglou (2005) introduced agent-based microsimulation for small and medium

sized business establishments in the City of Hamilton, Ontario, Canada. Their microsimulation is

based on a longitudinal data set obtained from Statistics Canada for the interval of 1996 to 2002.

The microsimulation addresses firm failure, mobility, and location choice decisions. Failure

behaviour is modelled using a discrete hazard duration model of survival.

Moeckel (2005) produced a firm microsimulation with a focus on firm location decisions.

The microsimulation of businesses is integrated with the Integrated Land-Use Modelling And

Transportation System Simulation (ILUMASS). The firmographic events of firm birth,

growth/decline and exit are presented using Markov transition probabilities to estimate the

overall number of births and deaths, and the growth/decline of a simulated firm population.

de Bok and Bliemer (2006) introduced SMF; a firmographic microsimulation of firms in the

South Holland, in the Netherlands. They simulate firms at the micro level in the interval of 1988-

1997. Firm formation, migration, growth, and dissolution are simulated. The microsimulation is

used for spatial policy assessment of infrastructure investments, and industrial or commercial site

planning. Firm exit and birth are simulated using Monte Carlo simulation based on a binary

Page 48: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

29

regression model for firm exit, and drawing random samples from distributions for firm birth.

Firm growth is modelled as a function of firm size and location. It is evaluated in two stages; a

tentative size is first calculated based on firm employment, and then is corrected based on the

average firm size within the economic sector. An interesting finding for the overall

microsimulation results is that the micro approach is not proven to perform better at the

neighbourhood level compared to the aggregate approach.

Kumar and Kockelman (2008) conduct a behavioural firm microsimulation for Austin,

Texas. They address firm entry, exit, growth (as a function of employment), and firm location

and relocation decisions. Commercial trip generation and distribution models are also included in

this microsimulation. Firm entry and exit rates for the years of 2001-2002 and 2002-2003, for

low and high growth rates respectively, are used to randomly select firm candidates for birth and

failure from a simulated population. Characteristics of new firms are selected at random from the

existing population distribution. Markov transition probabilities of aggregate firm population and

Monte Carlo simulation are used to represent expansion and contraction dynamics.

Other firm microsimulation efforts are found in the literature that simulate firms based on

fictitious data (Brenner 2001; Otter et al., 2001). Brenner (2001) introduced a comprehensive

approach of simulating firm entry, exit, and growth and observing their influence over the

evolution of industrial clusters. This approach is comprehensive as it includes the influence of

local circumstances of firms such as firm productivity, innovation, firm size, and human capital

over the evolution of industrial clusters.

2.4. Firm Microsimulation and Freight Models

A few research studies have considered firm microsimulation as part of freight modelling (de

Jong and Ben-Akiva, 2007; Wisetjindawat et al., 2007; Kumar and Kockelman 2008; Roorda et

al., 2010; Pourabdollahi et al., 2012; Cavalcante and Roorda 2013). However, such studies

focused primarily on specific behaviour of firms such as shipper and carrier market interactions

(Cavalcante and Roorda, 2013), supply chain decisions of firms (Pourabdollahi et al., 2012), and

estimation of firm commercial trips (Kumar and Kockelman, 2008).

In logistics and supply chain contexts, de Jong and Ben-Akiva (2007) introduced a firm

microsimulation model using Sweden and Norway commodity flow data. The model takes

commodity flows from production to consumption as inputs and then disaggregates these flows

Page 49: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

30

to firm-to-firm flows. Next, logistics chains (including choice of consolidation and distribution

centres for transhipment), transportation modes, and shipment size and type are microsimulated.

Similarly, Pourabdollahi et al. (2012) and Samimi et al. (2014) introduced FAME II; a

behavioural freight transportation modelling system that incorporates logistics decisions of

supplier selection, shipment size, and mode choice for the U.S. The goal of this framework is to

simulate freight logistics decisions to estimate freight demand by mode choice and then assign

commodity flows to the traffic network.

For the purpose of microsimulating freight flows, Wisetjindawat et al. (2007) introduced a

firm microsimulation for freight movement decisions considering firm characteristics of location,

employment, and floor space. The decisions of commodity generation, size, and consumption are

modelled at a micro level, to estimate truck flows and traffic assignment. Similarly, Abed et al.

(2014) introduced FALCON; an agent-based freight activities and logistic chains simulator. In

which firm agents are represented either as production, consumption, shippers, or carriers for the

purpose of simulating annual freight flows. Kumar and Kockelman (2008) address firm entry,

exit, survival, and location choice, for Austin, Texas, to estimate commercial trip generation.

Their research is based on aggregate firm birth and exit data. They apply firm entry and exit

rates, estimated for U.S. firms for the years of 2001-2002 and 2002-2003, randomly select exit

firm candidates, and generate firm births. Cavalcante and Roorda (2013) introduced FREMIS; an

agent-based microsimulation for freight market interactions and commodity flow modelling.

FREMIS model shippers and carriers interactions in the formation of contracts, while accounting

for market competition, product differentiation and economies of scale.

At an aggregate level, Gardrat et al. (2014), introduced SIMETAB; an aggregate freight

activity model that simulates the economic structure of an area by simulating the number of

establishments by size and economic sector for a given zone. This tool simulates the urban goods

movement in France using simple data such as population and number of establishments.

2.5. Concluding Remarks and Research Gaps

Firmographic modelling is a promising approach in freight microsimulation; it provides

information about firm behaviour of market entry, exit, expansion/contraction and relocation

decisions, in addition to understanding growth/decline patterns. Firmographic events are affected

by the economic growth, firm characteristics and strategies, industry classification, regulations

Page 50: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

31

and local/regional policies, and the geographic locations of firms. While firmography has been

introduced in transportation modelling (Khan et al., 2002; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2005; Moeckel

2005; Elgar et al., 2009), only a few models are found in the literature that address firmography

with a freight perspective (Kumar and Kockelman, 2008). Evidence from the literature suggest

that there is a need to construct freight models that integrate the individual behaviour of the

freight system agents (i.e. firms) with the changes in the economy, while addressing

heterogeneity between industries.

Current firmographic models have some limitations. They are either designed to address a

specific behaviour, deal with a limited number of firm interactions, target specific firm

populations, or study small-scale geographic regions. Key limitations and research gaps in

firmographic modelling are identified as follows:

• Unavailability of firm micro-data: Data availability, specifically firm micro-data, is

the main constraint to more elaborate firmographic models. The models reviewed in

this chapter use data that are either aggregate, or incomplete. The availability of

longitudinal firm micro-data would facilitate the construction of comprehensive

firmographic models.

• Underrepresentation of large and multi-location firms: While small-medium sized,

and single-location firms may constitute large segments of firm populations in

different areas, large-sized and multi-location firms may have a larger influence over

the economy. The majority of the reviewed firm microsimulation studies focus on

single-location, and/or small-sized firms (e.g. Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2005; Kumar

and Kockelman, 2008), leaving firmographic models of large-sized and multi-

location firms under-researched.

• Lack of firm entry behavioural models: Models of firm entry mostly use probability

distributions and Monte Carlo simulation approaches. This procedure relies on the

collective probabilistic behaviour of the population, hence, the micro-behaviour of

entry decisions is not well captured. Modelling the decision of firm entry requires

data that covers the non-entry behaviour. Micro-models that identify the individual

characteristics of new firms mostly rely on probability distribution and Monte Carlo

simulation, hence their accuracy is questioned. Concepts from evolutionary biology

are probably suitable to model such behaviour, where new firms adopt a combination

Page 51: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

32

of strategies similar to the successful ones employed by firms alike, while potentially

introducing some new strategies.

• Unidimensional construct of firm growth: Models of firm growth represent the

change in employment size only, while it might be the combination of the growth of

other assets as well. A correlation between different growth measurements (e.g.

profit, revenues, and employment) is expected (Bruneel et al., 2009; Jang and Park,

2011). Hence, it is worthwhile to explore simultaneous firm growth models, i.e.

modelling firm growth in a multidimensional form taking into account other aspects

of growth such as labour, vehicle fleet, number of business establishments, floor

space, machinery and equipment, market shares, revenues, and sales values.

• A comprehensive agent-based firmographic microsimulation that simulates individual

firm decisions and evolution stages, and models interrelated behaviour within freight

systems is needed. The microsimulation should incorporate the effect of the economy,

market competition, industrial innovation and technological advances, and

firmography altogether. In this fashion, the microsimulation will enable researchers

and decision makers to observe the two way interrelations between freight systems,

and land use and the economy, which eventually can be used for forecasting and

policy assessment. Since firmography is also affected by local/regional policies and

regulations, future research should be conducted across a wider range of countries to

gain better insights about the determinants of firmography.

Page 52: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

33

CHAPTER 3

A Framework of Firm Microsimulation: The Firmographic

Engine

3.1. Introduction

The limitations of the current firmographic models have been highlighted in chapter 2, and

the need for having freight micro models that represent behaviour and interactions of the

individual agents in the freight system is clear. The integrated freight microsimulation should

incorporate changes in the economy, and industry dynamics while considering heterogeneity of

firms across industries and regions.

In this chapter, a concept for an agent-based firm microsimulation is introduced, called the

firmographic engine that models the evolutionary stages and behaviour of firms including their

strategic decisions of resource acquisition, outsourcing, and asset expansion/contraction

decisions. This microsimulation builds upon recent attempt of (Roorda et al., 2010) of presenting

an agent-based microsimulation framework that explains the role and function of each agent (i.e.

firm) in the freight system and represents the interactions (both long and short-term) between

each agent in the market through contract formation. The firmographic engine simulates firm

entry, exit, growth, relocation, commercial vehicle ownership, freight outsourcing, and shippers-

carriers interactions.

The firmographic engine mainly microsimulates the dynamics in the freight system, and is

designed to be integrated with ILUTE (Integrated Land Use, Transportation, Environment) by

(Miller and Salvini, 2001); an agent-based microsimulation of activities of individual

households, families, persons, and jobs. This combination will present a fully integrated urban

land use model of both passenger and freight activities. The engine is designed to feed ILUTE

with the supply side of job dynamics in the market throughout tracking of firm birth, growth,

relocation, and death.

The goal of the engine is to be used as a tool for evaluating the implications of policy on

freight systems by simulating individual agents and forecasting their behaviour. Such policies

Page 53: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

34

include, for example: infrastructure investment, trade agreements, land use, and taxation policies,

and government incentives.

The chapter first introduces a conceptual framework of the firmographic engine, followed by

details of its underlying modules. In each module, the parts have been implemented using the

behavioural models covered in this research are highlighted. A section about the used data sets

follows. Potential integrations of the engine with other transport models are also discussed. A

summary and future directions are presented at the end of the chapter.

3.2. A Conceptual Framework

The engine is composed of four basic modules: firm generation, market introduction,

performance evaluation, and firm evolution and strategy updates (FIGURE 3.1). Details of each

module are discussed next. The engine is designed to simulate the yearly firm events (e.g. firm

entry, growth, relocation, and exit) for a period of T years. The simulation is executed at the end

of every year, and iterates until the end of the desired time T. For instance, at year t =1, the

simulation starts by running the firm generation module that produces a list of “potential” firms,

Nt, that have their business strategies identified. In this stage, potential entrepreneurs are

identified (using population census and demographic data) and those who are more likely to

establish a new firm are simulated to represent the new firm population. The list of potential new

firms ‘Nt’ is then used as an input to market introduction module that is responsible for

microsimulating the physical entry of firms to the market. In this stage, operational strategies of

resource acquisitions (e.g. hiring employees, establishment of facilities, and contract formation

of other services) are identified. The result of this stage is a list of new physically operating firms

in the market (Nt). In the performance evaluation stage, the list of new operational firms along

with existing firms of previous year (Ot-1), are interacting over the course of the simulation year

(t), and according to some predefined performance indicators of each firm, each have three

decisions: 1) continue existing in the market without changing any of their strategies, 2) continue

existing in the market with changing some of their business strategies, or 3) decide to exit the

market either by declaring bankruptcy or merging with other continuing firms. The result of this

simulation stage is a group of surviving (Ot), and exiting firms (Dt). Firms that decide to continue

existing in the market may wish to revisit their strategies and make some updates depending on

their performance and long-term strategies. Decisions related to strategy updates are simulated in

Page 54: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

35

the final stage of ‘firm evolution and strategy updates’. In this stage, decisions related to

expansion/contraction of physical assets, growth/shrinkage in the number of employees,

relocation, opening/closing facilities, and service contracts are simulated. The microsimulation

then steps into the second simulation time instance (t = t + 1) and repeats the same stages again

until the end of simulation time T. FIGURE 3.2 illustrates the decision process of firms in the

firmographic engine.

Page 55: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

36

FIGURE 3.1 The Firmographic Engine: A Conceptual Framework

Firm Evolution / Strategy updates

t = 1

Firm

Generation

Performance Evaluation

t = t+1

Start

End

Nt (list of new firms)

Ñt + Ot-1

Dt (Exiting firms)

Ot (Surviving firms) = Ñt + Ot-1 - Dt

Yes

No

Market

Introduction

(operational firms) tÑ

Operational

Strategies

Business

Strategies

Ot (surviving firms )

t = T?

Page 56: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

37

FIGURE 3.2 The Firmographic Engine: Firm Decision Hierarchy

Consider

entrepreneurship?

Establish a

firm?

Yes No

Yes No

Continue

existing?

Yes No

(market exit)

Merge/sell to

other firms?

Yes No

(Complete market exit)

Update

strategies?

Yes No

New + continuing firms t+1

t=1

1

2

3

4

t+1

Page 57: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

38

3.3. Underlying Modules

3.3.1. Firm generation

This is the initial stage in which entrepreneurs start looking for investment and market

opportunities and define their business strategies accordingly. The output of this module is a list

of potential firms (Nt) with defined business strategies for the current time interval. The results of

this stage are not operational firms, but rather business initiatives that are ready for physical

implementation and introduction to the market. In other words, this stage mainly simulates the

business entry decision at the entrepreneurial stage, where entrepreneurs formulate a group of

strategies for the anticipated firms. Entrepreneurs rely on economic conditions, market demand,

and competition to make a decision of physical market entry or not. Models of entrepreneurial

decision of firm entry are not within the scope of this research. A very useful data source to

model this decision is the Global Entrepreneurship monitor (GEM) - the Adult Population

Survey data set (APS) that is available for the interval of 1998-2010. The APS is designed to

capture aspects of firm creation and entrepreneurship across countries (Global Entrepreneurship

Monitor, 2016). Demographic variables such as respondent age, gender, employment status, and

education are included. The collected information identifies individuals who become active

nascent entrepreneurs in the firm start-up process, either as owner-managers of new firms, or

owner-managers of already established ones. Those who are identified as the owner-managers of

new firms would formulate the population of study for the firm generation module. The survey

also contains information about whether individuals considered starting a business or not, and

whether they have physically established a firm or not. Such decisions can be formulated as in

FIGURE 3.2, in steps (1) and (2).

In the entrepreneurial decision phase, entrepreneurs formulate the firm’s long-term strategy,

and accordingly choose the business strategies that serve their goals. In light of the SIBS (which

will be discussed later), business strategies can include the following (FIGURE 3.3):

a) Production strategy: in which offered products/services, number of product lines, prices

and production quality are identified.

b) Resource strategy: which includes the specification of tangible assets (e.g. buildings,

machinery, equipment, employment, and vehicle fleet), outsourcing of freight operation

decisions, and facility locations.

Page 58: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

39

c) Supply chain (SC) strategy: in which the role in SC, potential local/international

suppliers and their location, inputs/outputs of SC, and distribution and logistics

operations are specified.

d) Financial strategy: that includes the specification of financially related activities such as

feasibility studies, payroll, accounting and bookkeeping, and capital investment

management.

e) Marketing strategy: which is responsible for planning promotions and discount systems,

package designs, and media and advertisement activities.

f) Advanced technology usage and innovation strategies: in which decisions about

software, hardware, advanced technologies (e.g. green technologies, and automation),

and process, organizational, product and marketing innovations are made. The SIBS

offers details about the use of innovation in four areas and will be discussed later in

section 3.4.2, FIGURE 3.8.

As indicated in FIGURE 3.3, the engine is to be integrated with a future national economic

indicator module that is responsible for forecasting the economic conditions using some

indicators such as the GDP growth and unemployment rates. This module is to utilize the

research of (Bachmann et al., 2014a and 2014b) that models the effects of global trade patterns

on domestic freight operations in Canada. Currently, the engine uses economic indicators as

exogenous variables to the system. An illustration of how SIBS defines the long-term strategy

and strategic focus is presented in section 3.4.2, FIGURE 3.7. Additionally, FIGURE 3.7 explains

what are the business activity dynamics that are measured thorough the SIBS.

Page 59: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

40

FIGURE 3.3 The Firmographic Engine: Firm Decision Hierarchy

Start t = 0

Total market &

investment

potentials (P)

National economic

condition indicator

module

P= P - 1 P = 0 or i = M

Yes

No

1. FIRM GENERATION

Nt: list of firms with strategies (n)

Yes

n =n+1

i = 1

n = 0

i = i + 1 Start firm

?

No

Business strategy

Entrepreneurial phase

Saturation

?

A

Production strategy

• Products lines/ # of

products /provided

services

• Product prices

• Production quality

Supply chain (SC) &

logistics strategy

• Role in SC

• Local/international

suppliers

• SC inputs/outputs

• Distribution and logistics

Resources strategy

• Outsourcing decisions

• Tangible and intangible

assets (e.g. employment,

investments, buildings,

fleet, and machinery)

• Facility locations (local /

international)

• Research and

development activities

• Support services (e.g.

HR, ICT support, and

legal services)

• Sales services

Marketing strategy

• Media and advertisement

• Promotions and discount

systems

• Design packaging of

products

Innovation and

technology strategies

• Software development

• Advanced technology

usages (e.g. green

technologies,

nanotechnologies, and

automation)

• Process, organizational,

product, and marketing

innovations.

Financial strategy

• Capital investments

• Feasibility studies

(expected cost, and

expected revenues)

• Financial services (e.g.

payroll, accounting

services, and

bookkeeping)

Business Strategy Generation / Long-term strategic focus

D

Page 60: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

41

3.3.2. Market introduction

This stage is responsible for simulating the firm’s physical entry to the market (FIGURE 3.4).

It simulates the decisions that are related to the application of the operational strategies. It

involves simulating the decisions of hiring employment and acquiring business facilities

including production, logistics, and business service facilities. Resource acquisition also involves

defining other firm tangible assets such as vehicle fleet, machinery and equipment, warehouses,

and transshipment centres. Furthermore, as suggested by (Roorda et al., 2010), interaction

amongst firms (other agents) are defined through contracts. Firms contract with other firms for

other services that are not carried out by the firm. Examples of such contracts are commodity

contracts (e.g. for raw materials), business service contracts (e.g. technical support), and logistics

service contracts (e.g. 3PLs). Contract formation is simulated after the simulation of resource

acquisition, as firms identifies first what are the core activities to be carried out in-house and the

necessary recourses, and what are the activities/services to be outsourced. The result of this

simulation stage is a group of physically operating firms (Ñt) that are interacting in the market

and periodically monitoring their performance.

This module is designed to be integrated with FREMIS, introduced by (Cavalcante and

Roorda, 2013). FREMIS is an agent-based microsimulation of freight market interactions and

commodity flow. FREMIS models shipper-carrier interactions in the formation of contracts,

while accounting for market competition, product differentiation and economies of scale. This

integration will allow the full representation of firm behaviour in the market upon all other firm-

related decisions are modelled. This module utilizes models of firm start-up size that cover the

resource acquisition of employees and tangible assets, that are presented in chapter 4. While

models of freight outsourcing decisions are introduced, their predictive abilities may not be

credible for new firms as the introduced models (in chapter 7) do not include firm age to explain

outsourcing behaviour.

Page 61: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

42

FIGURE 3.4 Market Introduction Module

3.3.3. Performance evaluation

New firms (Ñt) along with already existing firms from previous year (Ot-1) interact in the

market, and after one year, each firm evaluates their performance according to predefined

performance measures. Performance measures are selected mainly based on the long-term

strategy and strategic focus of the firm. For instance, firms that employ market positioning and

product leadership as a long-term strategy may adopt performance measures of market/customer

share growth, customer satisfaction, and improved delivery time as they relate to market

leadership. The SIBS collects information of firm performance measure choices, and is

considered a good data source to model decisions related to performance measures selection,

which is not the scope of this research.

After performance evaluation, each firm decides whether to continue existing in the market

or not. A firm can choose to exit the market, if they are not meeting their anticipated

performance, in two forms; sell/merge with other existing firms, or completely disappear from

i = 1

i = n

?

2. MARKET INTRODUCTION

i = i + 1 No

Ñt : operational firms (n)

Operational strategy

FREMIS

Contract formation

• Commodities

• Logistics services

• Business services

Resource acquisitions

• Employees

• Facilities

Commodity production

Business services

Logistics

Vehicles Transshipment centres Warehouses

Yes

Nt: list of firms with strategies (n)

A

B

Page 62: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

43

the market by declaring bankruptcy (Khan et al., 2002; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2005). Models of

firm survival and exit decisions are covered in this research and are presented in chapter 6. A

discrete-time hazard duration model is introduced, which does not identify the type of exit.

Models that specify firm exit type (i.e. merge/sell to other firms, or declare bankruptcy) are not

covered as the provided database does not include the type of exit. The result of this simulation

step is a group of exiting firms (Dt) and a group of continuing firms (Ot). Exiting firms are

removed from the microsimulated firm population, and only continuing firms (Ot) are carried

forward to the next simulation stage (FIGURE 3.5).

FIGURE 3.5 Market Introduction Module

Ñt : operational firms

i = 1

Dt = 0

Ot = 0

Ot-1: previous year survivals

Ñt +Ot-1 Performance Indicators

Survival

?

Yes

Ot = Ot + 1

i = Ñt + Ot-1

?

Yes

No

3. PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Sell/merge

?

Yes

Exit market Dt = Dt + 1

i = i + 1

No

No

Ot: survivals

Market/Customer

share growth

Gross/Operating

margin growth Sales/revenues

growth

Shareholder

dividends growth Customer

satisfaction

Increased sales

of new products

Improved

delivery time

D

C

B

Page 63: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

44

3.3.4. Firm Evolution

Firms that decide to continue existing in the market (Ot), may need to revisit their employed

strategies and make some updates to maintain/enhance their market status and achieve their long-

term goals. Firms decide to update their strategies depending on the current economic conditions,

market demand, industry dynamics (e.g. entry and exit rates), and market competition. Firms

may decide to increase/decrease their production size by introducing new products, enhance the

quality of currently offered products, and/or cancel product lines. Firms may consider changing

their suppliers (either locally or internationally). Decisions of physical expansion or contraction

are also potential in this stage, such as hire/fire employees, expand/contract facilities, open new

locations, and/or close exiting ones. Firms may also relocate to other locations, outsource some

of their activities, introduce new innovation techniques, and/or change their marketing strategy to

enhance their performance and achieve higher market growth. Firms may form new contracts

and/or update/extend/terminate existing ones with other firms (FIGURE 3.6). As discussed in the

firm generation module, section 3.3.1, an external economic condition module (that is not the

subject of this research) is to be integrated to the firmographic engine, which will provide

estimates of economic indicators such as GDP growth and unemployment rates. In this research,

firm growth models of employment and tangible assets (chapter 5), and models of freight

outsourcing decisions (chapter 7) are presented as parts of business and operational strategy

updates. When this simulation stage is finished, the engine is ready to proceed to the next time

instance (t = t+1), and the microsimulation process is repeated until t = T and the simulation

stops.

The firmographic engine considers two aspects of firm growth; the change in the number of

employees, and the change in the firm physical forms indicated by the dollar value of the

tangible assets. We hypothesize that firm employment size affects their tangible assets. In

chapter 4, details of the adopted simulation configuration of employment and tangible assets are

introduced.

Page 64: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

45

FIGURE 3.6 Firm Evolution Module

3.4. Data Sources

The major obstacle to fully develop firmographic models is longitudinal firm microdata

availability. Several micro databases of firms in Canada have been investigated, which are

relevant to firmography, but can be used in limited ways due to their confidentiality. Statistics

Canada offers a wide range of firm microdata that is available through the Canadian Centre for

Data Development and Economic Research (CDER). This program offers microdata to support

Operational strategy

4. FIRM EVOLUTION

Business strategy

Production strategy

Resources strategy

SC/logistics strategy

Financial strategy

Innovation and technology

Marketing strategy

Resources

• Expansion

• Contraction

Contracts

• Formations

• Renewals

• Terminations

Strategy updates

Ot: survivals (o)

i = 1

i = Ot

Yes

i = i + 1 No

No

End

Yes

t = T t = t+1 D

National economic

condition indicator

module

C

Page 65: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

46

Canadian researchers to conduct analytical research on businesses and economic development

(Statistics Canada, 2016b). Examples of investigated microdata include Annual Survey of

Manufacturing (ASM), Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program (LEAP), T2-LEAP,

Longitudinal Work File (LWF), Capital and Investment Program (CIP), National Accounts

Longitudinal Microdata (NALMF), Survey of Innovation and Business Strategies (SIBS), and

Workplace Employee Survey (WES). Each of the listed datasets could be utilized to estimate

parts of the underlying modules of the firmographic engine. Some of such data sets study labour

dynamics of turnover and mobility (e.g. LWF and WES), some offer longitudinal data of firms’

financial performance (e.g. CIP) and firms’ overall behaviour (e.g. LEAP, T2-LEAP, and

NALMF), and others focus only on firms in specific industries (e.g. ASM). For details about the

listed datasets refer to (Statistics Canada, 2016b).

These data sets have been studied carefully to select the most suitable ones for the scope of

this research and to implement basic parts of the firmographic engine. The T2-LEAP data set has

been selected to estimate the models of firm start-up size, growth, and failure, and SIBS is

selected to estimate the models of manufacturers’ freight outsourcing decisions.

3.4.1. T2-Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program (T2-LEAP)

T2-LEAP offers longitudinal information of Canadian firms that have records in the tax files

from 1984 until 2012. It is the result of merging the LEAP database to Corporate Tax Statistical

Universal File (T2SUF). The LEAP is compiled from three sources: 1) T4 administrative data

available at Canada Revenue Agency (CRA), 2) data from Statistics Canada’s Business Register

(BR), and 3) data from Statistics Canada’s Survey of Employment, Payroll and Hours (SEPH)

(Statistics Canada, 2012a). Statistics Canada considers the LEAP files as the primary source of

information to study employment dynamics at the firm level. For more information on the LEAP

and T2-LEAP refer to their user guide in (Statistics Canada, 2012a).

The T2-LEAP includes yearly information of firm employment size, province, industry class,

sales values, and tangible assets. The data set is linked to CANSIM data to obtain the Canadian

GDP (National GDP, GDP by industry, GDP by province, and GDP growth rates) (Statistics

Canada, 2015a), and yearly unemployment rates (Statistics Canada, 2015b).

Firm population of the years of 2001 to 2012 are the focus of this research. Only for-profit

industries are included while excluding not-for-profit ones from the analysis. For-profit

Page 66: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

47

industries are mostly privately owned, and are more susceptible to economic growth. Not-for-

profit entities (i.e. educational service, health care and social assistance, and public

administration) mostly offer public services that are indispensable (e.g. education and health

services) which typically are governmental, and their growth/shrinkage are affected mainly by

public policies, and demand and supply. A discussion of the data filtering and manipulation

techniques is provided with each model in the corresponding chapters.

3.4.2. Survey of Innovation and Business Strategies (SIBS)

SIBS is a cross-sectional data set that contains statistical firm information of strategic

decisions, innovation activities, operational tactics, business strategies, relationship to suppliers,

sales activities, competition, international activities, use of advanced technology and innovation,

and use of government support programs to support innovation. This survey was initiated in

2007 for the purpose of understanding market and policy factors that influence innovation-

oriented business strategies (Statistics Canada, 2012b). This survey is launched every three

years, and collects firm data for a three-year interval. Two cross-sectional data sets of the 2009

and 2012 surveys have been used to estimate models of outsourcing decisions of manufacturers,

presented in chapter 7. The 2009 survey covers the interval of 2007 till 2009, while the 2012 one

covers the period of 2010 till 2012. The surveys are conducted on a sample of enterprises that

have at least 20 employees and annual revenue of $250,000 and more. The firm population is

limited also to enterprises in the following 14 sectors defined according to NAICS:

1. Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting

2. Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction

3. Utilities

4. Construction

5. Manufacturing

6. Wholesale Trade

7. Retail Trade

8. Transportation and Warehousing

9. Information and Cultural Industries

10. Finance and Insurance

11. Real Estate and Rental and Leasing

Page 67: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

48

12. Professional, Scientific and Technical Services

13. Management of Companies and Enterprises

14. Administrative and Support, Waste Management and Remediation Services

The 2012 survey targeted a random sample of 7,818 enterprises, and the 2009 targeted 6,233

enterprises across Canada. The manufacturing firm population constitutes 6,233 enterprises

(80%) of the 2012 survey, and 4,599 (74%) of the 2009 survey. In this research, manufacturing

firms are the population under investigation as they account for a large percentage of the

Canadian Domestic Product (GDP) (Richards, Snoddon, and Brown 2014). In addition, the

manufacturing industry involves large freight operations, including outsourcing, locally and

internationally.

Long-term strategy and strategic focus information is collected in detail through the

questionnaire. FIGURE 3.7 presents a schematic of how long-term strategy and strategic focus

are addressed in the SIBS. SIBS assumes that the long-term strategy selection is the core

decision that influences firm’s strategic focus and business activities (Statistics Canada, 2012b).

SIBS summarizes the following areas:

a) Business activities: such as outsourcing, relocation, and expansion/contraction of assets

and facilities of firms. The SIBS includes information that allows estimating models to

describe the behaviour of outsourcing and relocating different business

activities/facilities to other locations in Canada or worldwide. Also, expansion and

contraction of different activities (e.g. new products/services, distribution and logistics

centres, other service facilities) can be captured and modelled using data collected by the

SIBS.

b) Changes to business practices: some firms may wish to change some of their business

practices to accommodate some customer requirements such as implementing specific

cost reduction, improve the quality of some goods/services, or entering new geographic

regions.

c) Use of advanced technology: is addressed in SIBS using nine key technologies of

computerized design and engineering, computerized processing and assembly,

computerized inspection, communication, automated material handling, information

Page 68: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

49

integration and control, biotechnologies/bio-products, and green technologies and

nanotechnologies.

d) Human resources practices: which include promotion strategies, performance

management, employment selection practices, training, and incentive programs (e.g.

employee profit-sharing, stock ownership, and merit bonus)

e) Use of innovation: the SIBS collects information for four aspects of innovation;

production innovation, process innovation, organizational innovation, and marketing

innovation (FIGURE 3.8). Statistics Canada (2009) presents a report that includes a

summary of use of innovation in the four identified aspects for Canadian firms.

In addition, the survey includes a section indicating whether firms are utilizing government

support programs for innovation related activities or not. The questionnaire covers federal,

provincial, and municipal programs. Examples of such programs include government training

programs, grants, tax credits, export incentives, and market information services (Statistics

Canada, 2012b).

Page 69: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

50

FIGURE 3.7 Long Term Strategy, Strategic Focus, and Business Activity Dynamics in SIBS

Long term strategy

Market positioning

(product leadership) Mass market

(low-price)

Goods and

Services

0: No 1: Yes

Marketing

practices Operations and

business activities Organizational and

management practices

0: No 1: Yes 0: No 1: Yes 0: No 1: Yes

Maintain

existing Introduce

new Maintain

existing Introduce

new Optimize

existing Introduce

new

0: No 1: Yes

Introduce

new Optimize

existing

0: No 1: Yes

Strategic Focus

Business activities • Production of goods/provision of services

• Service centres (customer service, marketing,

sales, after sales, financial, R&D, ICT…etc.)

• Distribution and logistics

Changes to business practices to

respond to customer requirements

(Specific cost reduction, enter new

market, extend business hours…etc.)

Use of advanced technology

(Automation, biotechnologies,

nanotechnologies, green

technologies…etc.)

HR practices

0: No 1: Yes

Internationally Within Canada

0: No 1: Yes

Internationally Within Canada

0 1 or more

Off-shelf

(purchased/leased) Licensing/ customizing

advanced technologies

In conjunction

with others

Use of innovation

Business Activity Dynamics

Production performance

management practices

Relocation Outsourcing

Page 70: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

51

FIGURE 3.8 Use of Innovation in SIBS

3.5. Relationship to Other Microsimulation Models of Transportation

Systems

3.5.1. Integration with FREMIS

FREMIS is a microsimulation modelling framework of freight agents to forecast freight

flows. It is focused on shipper decisions of shipment bundling and carrier selection throughout

simulating carrier proposals for contracts (Cavalcante and Roorda., 2013). The potential

integration between FREMIS and the firmographic engine is expected to cover the contract

formation of operational strategies of production, logistics, and/or businesses outsourcing to

other firms. This integration is happening in the two simulation stages of market introduction,

and firm evolution in the firmographic engine. FIGURE 3.9 illustrates the decision tree of

whether a firm chooses to outsource their freight activities, such as logistics and distribution, to

other firms or perform such activities in-house using their own vehicle fleet. Commercial vehicle

ownership decisions have been covered by the authors in a separate research using commercial

Process Innovation

• New/improved method of manufacturing

• New/improved logistics, delivery, or distribution

methods

• New/improved supporting activities (e.g.

maintenance systems, computing…etc.)

Marketing Innovation

• Changes to the design/ packaging of

goods/services

• New media or techniques for goods/services

promotions

• New methods for good/ service placements

• New methods of pricing goods/service

Organizational Innovation

• New business practices for organizing procedure

(SC management, knowledge management,

quality management…etc.)

• New methods of organizing work responsibilities

and decision making

• New methods of organizing external relations

1or more 0

Developed within

enterprise Joint with

others

Developed by

other enterprises

Product Innovation

• New or significantly improved goods

• New or significantly improved services

1, or more 0

Novel to the

market Has some

unique features

Widely available

on the market

Page 71: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

52

vehicle travel survey data (Mostafa and Roorda, 2013), and the outsourcing decisions are

covered in this research in chapter 7. FREMIS is intended to cover the third level of the decision

tree (FIGURE 3.9) of shippers when they outsource part/all of their freight operations to other

carriers through long or short-term contracts.

FIGURE 3.9 Freight Operations Decision Hierarchy

3.5.2. Integration with ILUTE

ILUTE is a comprehensive microsimulation model of urban systems to simulate interacting

agents of individuals, households, and firms (Miller et al., 2004). The purpose of ILUTE is to

substitute the conventional four-stage transportation demand models with activity-based models

that produce origin-destination flows by mode, time of day, and trip purpose. ILUTE is designed

to simulate land development, location choices (e.g. dwellings and firms), and auto ownership

(Miller and Salvini, 1998). Another major emphasis of ILUTE is microsimulation of market

demand-supply interactions such as the ones within residential and commercial real-estate

markets, and the job market.

The current firmographic simulation mechanism within ILUTE is restricted to largely

aggregate inputs (Harmon, 2013). No micro-level presentation of the firm has been yet

Freight operations

(e.g. goods production, and logistics and

distribution)

Private fleet

ownership

Outsourcing

3PLs Couriers Individual carriers/

Freight forwarders

Long Term

Cars

(1, 2, 3...N)

Pickups/vans

(1, 2, 3...N)

Trucks

(1, 2, 3...N)

Others

(1, 2, 3...N)

Fleet composition and size Short

Term FREMIS

Page 72: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

53

implemented in ILUTE, instead, firm attributes are synthesized and linked to the ‘Job’ entity.

ILUTE synthesizes four firm attributes of firm size classification, multiple firm location

indicator, collective bargaining agreement indicator, and firm location, which are used in the

‘Wage’ model introduced by (Hain, 2010). The current job creation process in ILUTE is random

and relies on synthesized firm data that are based on deterministic growth factors (Harmon,

2013).

The firmographic engine provides micro-level estimation of the number of yearly created

jobs resulting from firm entry, growth, and exit microsimulation. The firm start-up and growth

models can represent job creation (e.g. hiring), and job destruction could be presented through

firm growth and failure/exit models. However, since the merge/selling to other firms is not

identified in the firm failure model, it is not complete yet to track mergers and acquisitions.

Currently, the firmographic engine simulates employment through firm start-up size, growth, and

exit models on the industry level (based on 2-digit NAICS code), which does not give

information about the job type/occupation level. A potential integration between the

firmographic engine and ILUTE is explained in FIGURE 3.10 and can be summarized in the

following:

• The individual modelling of Canadian firms, introduced in the firmographic engine,

provides job supply side interactions. Employment dynamics are captured through

simulating firm entry, growth, and exit which are inputs to labour market modules in

ILUTE. Firm birth and death models in the firmographic models are to potentially

replace current regression-based Job Supply Model in ILUTE (Harmon, 2013).

• The firmographic engine is designed to include models of firm location choice and

migration. Such models are essential to provide location information of firms, and

simulate associated demographic and land us changes. This would allow ILUTE to

present a dynamic business location choice model, instead of the current

representation of locations which is based on static set of spatial probabilities which

do not change as the urban topography evolves (Harmon, 2013).

Page 73: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

54

FIGURE 3.10 Overall Structure of ILUTE and Potential Interactions with the Firmographic

Engine - Adapted from (Miller et al., 2010)

Observed Base Year Aggregate

Distribution of Agents & Attributes

(Census, etc.)

Labour Market

Built-Space

Market

Auto Ownership

Activity-Based Daily Travel

(TASHA)

Network Assignment

(MatSim/EMME)

Urban Energy Consumption

Transportation Emissions &

pollution Concentration Dispersion

Demographic

Update

Firmography and

Employment

(The Firmographic Engine)

Commercial Vehicle

Movement

Agent Synthesis

Synthetic Agents @ T

T= T + ΔT

Road & Transit

Network

Evolution

Page 74: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

55

3.6. Concluding Remarks and Future Directions

Firmographic models are useful for freight micro-modelling. They provide essential

information of firm entry, growth, relocation, and exit that influence transportation systems at

large. Such events are the main controllers of the job market. They also induce land use and

demographic changes to the surrounding areas. New/expanding firms may attract labour with

specific skills, education, and experience to the firm geographic zones. Also, businesses of the

same industry class may cluster together geographically to benefit from sharing same resources

and services (e.g. agglomeration economies). Such phenomena eventually impact transportation

demand and traffic patterns.

National micro-level firmographic models are scarce in the Canadian literature. In this

research, we propose our concept for the firmographic engine; a firm microsimulation platform

that accommodates changes in the economy and industry activities, and considers differences

between firms across industries and regions in a unified framework. It simulates firm evolution

stages of the early entrepreneurial stage, market entry, growth, and market exit. Throughout the

evolutionary stages, events of firm birth, growth, relocation, death are simulated, in addition to

other firm freight-related decisions. In this chapter, the modelling framework of the firmographic

engine is presented. A full description of the underlying modules is introduced with highlights of

the implemented parts in this research.

Microdata availability is the main challenge for implementing the firmographic engine.

Several microdata sets have been investigated and two sources have been selected; T2-LEAP and

SIBS datasets that are available through Statistics Canada. T2-LEAP is a longitudinal microdata

of firms that covers the Canadian firms (that have tax records) in the interval of 2001-2012. T2-

LEAP is used to estimate behavioural models of firm start-up employment and tangible assets

(used in market introduction stage), firm employment and tangible assets growth (used in firm

evolution and strategy updates), and firm exit/survival (used in performance evaluation stage).

Two cross-sectional datasets of SIBS are used to estimate freight outsourcing models for

Canadian manufacturers. The estimated models are to cover parts of business strategy updates in

firm evolution module. However, such models have not been tested for their predictive abilities

for simulating outsourcing decisions of new firms as no information about firm age was available

in the SIBS.

Page 75: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

56

Currently, the estimated models are presented at the Canadian provincial level. To make the

models transferable, models should be re-estimated using land use and demographic variables

(e.g. population density, education levels, land use, and firm densities) instead of the provincial

dummy variables to describe the firm location. This way, models can be applied in locations with

similar attributes.

Firm entry decisions have not been covered in this research. Instead, simple forecasts of entry

rates of simple linear regression models using historical data available (Statistics Canada, 2016a)

are potential candidates. Models that cover the first stage of the entrepreneurial decision of firm

entry (to cover firm generation module) is a logical next step to present firm entry on the micro

level. The APS (Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, 2016) is a suitable data source to identify the

potential entrepreneurs using individual population demographics such as age, gender, and

education. Entrepreneurs that establish new firms can also be modelled using the same data set

and inferences about discrete firm entry can be made. The result of this modelling step covers

firm entry behaviour in the firmographic engine.

Decisions related to performance indicator choices that are addressed in the performance

evaluation stage, can be modelled using data from SIBS. This model can provide explanation of

how firms measure their performance depending on their strategic focus and scope.

Economic growth indicators of GDP and unemployment rates are currently being treated

exogenously to the engine. A future step is to provide a national economic indicator module that

provides forecasts of economic growth using models of global trade pattern effects on domestic

freight operations introduced by (Bachmann et al., 2014a and 2014b). Currently, simple models

(e.g. linear regression) can be used to estimate future GDP and unemployment rates using

historical data publicly available at (Statistics Canada, 2015a; Statistics Canada, 2015b). GDP

rates are classified by industry at the provincial level, while unemployment rates are presented at

the provincial level.

Firm exit/survival models are presented in this research to cover the firm exit decision in

performance evaluation stage. However, the introduced models do not define the exit type (i.e.

bankruptcy vs. merge/sell to other firms) as exit type is not possible to identify using the T2-

LEAP dataset. Once such data is available, competing risk models are potential model structures

to represent firm exit type.

Page 76: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

57

Potential integration of the firmographic engine and other transportation microsimulation

models have been discussed. A two-way interaction between the firmographic engine and the

shipper-carrier interactions microsimulation model of FREMIS has been explained to cover other

aspects of firm-to-firm interactions. Furthermore, the engine is a strong candidate to provide

ILUTE with firm-level employment dynamics. Such integrations will provide a fully integrated

urban model of both passenger and freight activities in transportation systems.

Page 77: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

58

CHAPTER 4

Models of Firm Start-up Size of Canadian Firms

4.1. Introduction

Firm start-up size is an important determinant of new firms. Modelling firm start-up size at

the micro level is essential to understand job creation because new firms are an important part of

the supply of employment. Also, some studies suggest that firm start-up size influences the

firm’s subsequent performance and survival (Dunne et al., 1989; Audretsch and Mahmood,

1994; Mata and Portugal, 1994). Determinants of firm start-up size have been addressed largely

for European countries (Arauzo-Carod and Segarra-Blasco, 2005;Audretsch et al., 1999;

Barkham, 1994; Görg et al., 2000; Mata and Machado, 1996). To the best of the author’s

knowledge, research studies in a Canadian context that address determinants of firm start-up size

are absent, both in terms of employment size or tangible assets.

This chapter includes models of firm start-up size in terms of employment and tangible assets

for Canadian firms. The models are the foundation of the firm generation module of the

firmographic engine, presented in chapter 3. The majority of studies surveyed in the literature

address firm start-up in terms of number of employees only (Mata, 1996; Mata and Machado,

1996; Görg et al., 2000; Colombo et al., 2004; Arauzo-Carod and Segarra-Blasco, 2005), while

firm size can be multi-dimensional (e.g. number of business establishments, owned vehicles,

and/or warehouses) (Barkham, 1994; Bruneel et al., 2009; Jang and Park, 2011). In this research,

firm size is addressed in two dimensions; the number of employees and the value of tangible

assets. Tangible assets include physical assets such as buildings, land, and machinery and

equipment (Statistics Canada, 2012a). Tangible assets are selected because they represent the

physical size of the firms, and we hypothesize that employment and tangible assets are correlated

(e.g. larger assets require larger number of employees and vice versa). From a transportation and

land use perspective, spatial attributes of the firm (e.g. floor space, and the number of business

establishments), and the vehicle fleet size are of interest. Since disaggregate data are only

available for the dollar value of the tangible assets, tangible assets are utilized as a proxy for

Page 78: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

59

other physical indicators of firm size such as floor space, number of business establishments and

fleet ownership.

Models of firm start-up size and growth are configured as in FIGURE 4.1. The selected

sequence starts first (at time t =1) by simulating the firm start-up decision of employment size

(step #1) using basic firm information (e.g. province, industry class, and economic indicators).

The estimated number of employees is then passed as input to estimate the start-up tangible

assets (step #2). In the following year (t = 2), the number of employees is estimated (in step #3)

using previous year’s number of employees (t-1), and this information is then used to estimate

the tangible assets (in step #4) along with the previous year’s tangible assets.

FIGURE 4.1 Firm Start-up and Growth Simulation Configuration

This configuration is based on the assumption that employment and tangible assets are

dependent on what the previous year’s values were. It also assumes that the tangible asset growth

is a function of the number of employees of the current year (t), as in Equations (4.1) and (4.2).

𝑒𝑚𝑝𝑡 = 𝑓(𝑒𝑚𝑝𝑡−1, 𝑓𝑖𝑟𝑚 𝑎𝑡𝑡𝑟𝑖𝑏𝑢𝑡𝑒𝑠) (4.1)

𝑻𝑨𝒕 = 𝒇(𝑻𝑨𝒕−𝟏, 𝒆𝒎𝒑𝒕, 𝒇𝒊𝒓𝒎 𝒂𝒕𝒕𝒓𝒊𝒃𝒖𝒕𝒆𝒔) (4.2)

While it is more logical that firms decide first on their tangible assets (i.e. purchase new/sell

equipment, or open/close a new business establishment), and then hire/fire employees

accordingly, the aforementioned configuration is chosen for two reasons. First, information of

the tangible assets ($) for firms is not easily available for microsimulation purposes; no public

sources are available for such information on the micro level. Second, simulating employment

Tangible Assets

(TA)

Employment

t = 1 t = 2 t = N

.....

...........

.....

...........

t = 3

1

2

3

4

5

6

2N-1

2N

Page 79: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

60

growth is more important for transportation and land use models than tangible assets. In some

situations, simulating the employment growth individually would be more essential than

simulating the tangible assets, and hence they are simulated in separated models, and without

necessitating tangible assets as inputs for employment models.

This chapter is organized as follows. It starts with a review of literature on determinants of

firm start-up size. Then the data sources are explained, followed by explanations of ordered logit

models for start-up employment size and tangible assets. Concluding remarks and future work

are discussed at the end of the chapter.

4.2. Determinants of Firm Start-up Size

The decision of firm start-up size is mainly governed by industry characteristics, firm

characteristics, economic conditions, and founder characteristics (Barkham, 1994; Mata, 1996;

Mata and Machado, 1996; Görg et al., 2000; Colombo et al., 2004; Colombo and Grilli, 2005).

Industry characteristics include economies of scale, industry size and growth, and industry

turbulence (e.g. entry and exit rates) (Mata, 1996; Görg at al., 2000; Arauzo-Carod and Segarra-

Blasco, 2005). Economic conditions are reflected in GDP growth by (Reynolds and White,

1997). Finally, founder characteristics (age, gender, education, human capital, and work skills)

are found in several studies to be the major driving factors to firm start-up size (Colombo et al.,

2004; Mata, 1996; Barkham, 1994).

In this research, determinants of firm start-up size, including firm characteristics, economic

conditions, competition, and industry characteristics, are investigated. Founder characteristics are

not included in this research for two reasons: 1) unavailability of suitable data, and 2) the firm

microsimulation context for the model will simulate individual firms and the surrounding

environment, not the firm founders. The studied determinants are summarized in TABLE 4.1

along with their expected effect on firm start-up size.

Page 80: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

61

TABLE 4.1 Investigated Determinants of Firm Start-up Size

Variable Description Expected sign

Industry class A series of dummy variables to represent the 17

classes of the for-profit industries on the 2-digit

NAICS code.

--

Province

A series of dummy variables representing the

province where the firm is located. The

investigated provinces are Ontario, Quebec,

Alberta, British Columbia, Manitoba,

Saskatchewan, Atlantic Canada (including Nova

scotia, New Brunswick, Newfoundland and

Labrador, and Prince Edward Island), and rest of

Canadian provinces and territories (Nunavut,

Yukon, and Northwest Territories)

--

Economic Indicators

Yearly GDP growth rates (%) The percent change in the GDP between year (t)

and year (t-1). Positive

(Log) GDP by industry (2-

digit NAICS code)

The natural logarithmic value of the GDP

classified by the industry for year (t) Positive

Yearly provincial

unemployment rate (%)

The unemployment rate of year (t) on the

province level of where each firm is located Negative

Industry characteristics and competition

Entry rate by industry Yearly firm entry rate on the 2-digit NAICS code Negative Exit rate by industry Yearly firm exit rate on the 2-digit NAICS code Negative

Average firm size (log) The natural logarithmic value of the average firm

size of each 2-digit NAICS code industry Positive

Number of competitors in the

same CMA/CA of the same

NAICS-3 (log)

The natural logarithmic value of the number of

competitors located in the same CMA/CA of

where a firm is located, on the 3-digit NAICS

code.

Negative

We expect that firm start-up size varies across industries in different provinces as highlighted

in similar studies (Audretsch et al., 1999). Therefore, dummy variables of a firm’s industry and

province are considered. The literature indicates that economic growth has an impact on firm

start-up size. A growing economy encourages firms to start large in size, while firms may

choose to start small in size if the economy is declining. Three economic indicators are included

in our models to reflect economic growth: 1) % growth in the GDP, 2) the dollar value of the

GDP by industry (to represent the economic size of the industry), and 3) provincial

unemployment rates.

Mata and Machado (1996) suggest that firm start-up size increases with economies of scale

and the rate of firm entry and exit per industry. Also, the amount of capital required to operate a

Page 81: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

62

minimum efficiently scaled (MES) firm has a negative relationship with the new firm size,

because of the higher start-up costs (Fonseca et al., 2001; Geroski, 1991; Mataet al., 1995). Entry

and exit rates by industry, using the 2-digit NAICS code (TABLE 4.2), are included in firm start-

up size models. Firm start-up size and average firm size across industries vary according to the

technology and innovation usage, and economies of scale in each industry (Mata and Machado,

1996). Since it is hard to quantify the MES by industry, average firm size of each industry is

included as an indicator of the MES in the employment dimension. We hypothesize that the

larger the average size of firm within industries, the larger the start-up size of new firms is.

Most of the studies in the literature used regression approaches to investigate determents of

firm start-up size (Mata and Machado, 1996; Görg et al., 2000; Audretsch et al., 1999; Barkham,

1994). In our study, start-up size is considered to be a decision, and discrete choice model

approaches are used to quantify the effect of each of the investigated determinants on the start-up

size choice.

TABLE 4.2 Industry Classification 2-digit NAICS Code

NAICS 2-digit

code Industry Classification

11 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting

21 Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction

22 Utilities

23 Construction

31-33 Manufacturing

41 Wholesale trade

44-45 Retail trade

48-49 Transportation and warehousing

51 Information and cultural industries

52 Finance and insurance

53 Real estate and rental and leasing

54 Professional, scientific and technical services

55 Management of companies and enterprises

56 Administrative and support, waste management and remediation services

71 Arts, entertainment and recreation

72 Accommodation and food services

81 Other services (except public administration)

Page 82: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

63

4.3. Data Description and Basic Analysis

The T2-Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program (T2-LEAP) database provided by

Statistics Canada is used for model estimation. The data provide longitudinal information of

Canadian firms between the years of 2001 and 2012. Only for-profit industries are included, and

not-for-profit industries are excluded from the analysis (i.e. Educational service, Health care and

social assistance, and Public administration) because for-profit industries are mostly privately

owned, and are more susceptible to economic growth. Not-for-profit entities mostly offer public

services that are indispensable (e.g. education and health services) which are typically

governmental, and their growth/shrinkage are affected mainly by public policies, and demand

and supply.

The T2-LEAP includes yearly information of firm employment size, province, industry

class, sales value, and tangible assets. The data set is linked to CANSIM data to obtain the

Canadian GDP (National GDP, GDP by industry, GDP by province, and GDP growth rates)

(Statistics Canada, 2015a) and yearly unemployment rates (Statistics Canada, 2015b). Data are

filtered to only include new firms that entered the market between 2001 and 2012. A new firm is

marked when the first firm record is observed in year (t) and is not observed in previous years (t-

1, t-2…etc.). The 2001 new firm population is excluded from the analysis as the data is left

censored, and it is not evident whether firms that appear in the year 2001 have been present in

previous years or not.

Average firm start-up employment size (for the period of 2001-2012) is classified by industry

as in FIGURE 4.2. It can be seen that firms that belong to ‘Accommodation and food services’

industry have the highest start-up size (4.2 employees) whereas new firms in ‘Mining,

Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction’ industry have the lowest size (1.6 employees). Firm

employment sizes at entry calculated using the T2-LEAP in this research conform to those

published by (Ciobanu and Wang, 2012) for 2000 to 2008. Check TABLE A.1 in Appendix A for

the yearly values of firm start-up by industry for the 2001 to 2012 interval.

Page 83: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

64

FIGURE 4.2 Average Number of Employees at Firm Start-up by Industry

We hypothesize that firm start-up employment size is positively influenced by the average

size of firms within the industry (the higher the average firm size is, the higher the probability of

larger start-up size is). FIGURE 4.3 shows that average firm size varies from one industry to the

other. Firms that belong to information and cultural industries rank first, with an average of

364.3 employees, while firms belonging to agriculture, forestry, fishing and hunting industries

have the lowest average firm size of 4.6 employees. Check TABLE A.2 in Appendix A for the

yearly values of the average firm size for each industry class.

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

Nu

mb

er o

f em

plo

yees

Page 84: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

65

FIGURE 4.3 Average Firm Employment Size by Industry

(For the period of 2001 to 2012)

4.4. Model Structure: Ordered Logit Model

Several estimation procedures are available when the response (dependent) variable is

qualitative, one of which is the multinomial model (MNL) structure. However, when the

response variable (y) is ordinal and has more than two (ordered) responses, the MNL structure is

not suitable because MNL ignores the ordinal aspect of the outcome. Ordered logit models (also

known as proportional odds models) provide better representation of the ordering information

(StataCorp, 2013). In the ordered model, the response variable (y) takes values i=1 to N that are

ordered, and the probability of 𝑦𝑖 = 𝑖 is calculated using Equation (4.3)

𝑝𝑖𝑗 = Pr(𝑦𝑖 = 𝑖) = Pr(𝑘𝑖−1 < 𝑥𝑗𝛽 + 𝑢 ≤ 𝑘𝑖) (4.3)

= 1

1 + exp(𝑥𝑗𝛽 − 𝑘𝑖 )−

1

1 + exp(𝑥𝑗𝛽 − 𝑘𝑖−1)

0.0

50.0

100.0

150.0

200.0

250.0

300.0

350.0

Ave

rage

nu

mb

er o

f em

plo

yees

Page 85: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

66

where 𝑥𝑗 is a vector of independent variables (covariates), and 𝛽 is a vector of estimated

coefficients of the covariates. The formula indicates that the probability that a specific outcome i

is selected equals to the probability that the utility function (𝑥𝑗𝛽 + 𝑢) is between two

thresholds/cut-points 𝑘𝑖 and 𝑘𝑖−1, given that 𝑘𝑖−1 is always less than 𝑘𝑖. The vector 𝛽 and the

thresholds (ki; i=1 to N-1) are estimated using maximum likelihood estimation. The estimated

model has no constant terms because their effects are captured in the thresholds. A positive sign

of a coefficient indicates that an increase in the associated covariate increases the likelihood of

having higher start up size, and a negative sign indicates the opposite.

The ordered logit model structure is selected for modelling the firm start-up employment

size and firm start-up tangible assets because they can be classified in ranges that are ordinal (as

explained in TABLE 4.3 and TABLE 4.10).

4.5. Firm Start-up Employment Size

Data show that 50% of the firms start with one employee, while 75% of the new firms have

two employees or less. The average start-up size is 2.5 employees with a standard deviation of

4.3. The total number of firms under investigation is 275,517 in for-profit industries. A hold-out

sample of 20% of the records are kept for validation.

Two models are estimated; a simple model (includes basic variables of provincial location,

industry classes, and provincial unemployment rate), and a detailed model that includes

information such as provincial unemployment yearly rates, firm exit rates, average firm size by

industry, and average number of competitors within the same CMA/CA. The simple model is

intended for microsimulation purposes while the detailed one is intended to enhance our

understanding of the behaviour.

First, a simple linear regression model is estimated. The results of the simple and detailed

models are presented in TABLE A.3 and TABLE A.4 in appendix A, along with the model

goodness-of-fit. The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the number of employees at

firm start-up. The estimates are used as guidelines for selecting the statistically significant

explanatory variables and understanding the expected effect of the covariates in the ordered logit

model structure.

Page 86: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

67

4.5.1. Order logit model estimation results

Four classes are identified for the ordered logit model structure for firm start-up employment

size and are shown in TABLE 4.3. The ordered logit model is estimated using the STATA 13

package, and the estimation results of both the simple and detailed models are presented in

TABLE 4.4 and TABLE 4.5. Only variables that are statistically significant at 95% and higher are

included. TABLE 4.4 and TABLE 4.5 include the coefficient estimates, the ratio of the odds, the

P-Values, and the thresholds for each of the identified four employment size classes. A positive

sign of a coefficient indicates that an increase of one unit in the value of the associated covariate

increases the ordered log-odds of being in the higher range for employment size by the

coefficient value, while all other variables are held constant. A negative sign indicates the

opposite. As shown in TABLE 4.5, the log of the odds for firms in Ontario to be in a higher start-

up size category is -0.283 less than firms from other provinces and territories, when other

variables are held constant.

Marginal effects and odds ratios are other statistics that are used to interpret the effect of the

independent variables on the response variable. Marginal effects measure the expected change in

the response variable as a function of the change in the predictors (i.e. explanatory variables) at

specific values (e.g. mean values) of all independent variables (Mood, 2010). It is calculated by

taking the partial derivative of the probability function with respect to the predictor of interest

(Wicksteed, 1910). On the other hand, the odds ratios are obtained by exponentiating the

coefficient estimates (e coef ) (Bland and Altman, 2000). In ordered logit models, odds ratios

indicate that for a one-unit change in a given covariate, the odds for cases in a category greater

than (k) versus being in other categories less than or equal k are the value of the odds ratio

(Brant, 1990; Greenwood and Farewell, 1988; McCullagh, 1980). For example, TABLE 4.5

indicates that the odds for firms located in Quebec to have a start-up employment size in the

higher range (more than five employees) are 0.21 times lower than being in other employment

classes (i.e. five and less employees) compared to other provinces and territories, given that all

other variables are held constant. Likewise, the odds of the response variable to be in the other

combined categories (class 2 to 4; more than one employee) versus being in the first class (start-

up size of one employee) are 0.21 times lower for firms in Quebec compared to firms located

elsewhere, where other variables are held constant. Odds ratios are commonly used with

dichotomous independent variables as they give better interpretations compared to marginal

Page 87: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

68

effects (Armstrong and Sloan, 1989; Haddock et al., 1998). Since the presented ordered logit

models in this chapter are mostly dominated by dummy variables, the odds ratios are used to

interpret the effect of independent variables over the response variable.

The estimation results also report the cut-points (thresholds) that are used to differentiate the

adjacent levels of the response variables. Each cut-point separates response variable categories

when all values of the covariates are evaluated at zero. For instance, k1 value (1.164) in TABLE

4.5 is used to differentiate the response variable’s first class from the rest of the classes. Firms

that have a latent variable value less than 1.164 (when all model variables are evaluated at zero),

are classified with a start-up employment size of one employee (the first class). Similarly, firms

that have a value between k1 and k2 of the latent variable are classified in the second employment

class (two employees), and so on.

TABLE 4.3: Start-up Employment Size Ranges for Ordered Logit Model

Class Range

1 1 employee

2 2 employees

3 3-5 employees

4 Greater than 5 employees

Page 88: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

69

TABLE 4.4 Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Employment Size: Simple Model

Covariates Coef. Odds Ratio P>|z|

Province

Ontario -0.437 0.646 0.000

Quebec -0.357 0.700 0.000

Alberta -0.692 0.500 0.000

British Columbia -0.378 0.685 0.000

Industry class

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.491 0.612 0.000

Construction -0.193 0.824 0.000

Manufacturing 0.324 1.383 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.215 0.806 0.000

Retail trade 0.266 1.305 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.775 0.461 0.000

Information and cultural industries 0.127 1.135 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.159 0.853 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.374 0.688 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.620 0.538 0.000

Accommodation and food services 1.066 2.905 0.000

Economic indicators of previous year’s (t-1)

Provincial unemployment rate -0.013 0.987 0.000

/k1 -0.226

/k2 0.713

/k3 2.033

Page 89: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

70

TABLE 4.5 Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Employment Size: Detailed Model

Covariates Coef. Odds Ratio P>|z|

Province

Ontario -0.283 0.753 0.000

Quebec -0.231 0.794 0.000

Alberta -0.535 0.586 0.000

British Columbia -0.264 0.768 0.000

Industry class

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -1.279 0.278 0.000

Construction -0.277 0.758 0.000

Manufacturing -0.537 0.585 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.524 0.592 0.000

Retail trade -0.538 0.584 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -1.171 0.310 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.792 0.453 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.750 0.472 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.509 0.601 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.726 0.484 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.807 2.241 0.000

Economic indicators of previous year’s (t-1)

(log) GDP by industry (dollars x 10-10) 0.097 1.102 0.001

Industry characteristics and competition of previous year’s (t-1)

Firm exit rate by industry (%) -0.005 0.995 0.060

(log) Number of competitors (CMA/CA and NAICS 3-Digit

code) -0.056 0.946 0.000

(log) Average firm size by industry (2-digit NAICS) 0.254 1.289 0.000

/k1 1.164

/k2 2.113

/k3 3.431

4.5.2. Results interpretations

The results indicate that firm start-up employment size varies across industries and across

provinces. The coefficients of the province variables (in the simple and detailed models) indicate

that firms located in Ontario, Quebec, Alberta, and British Columbia, when all other variables

are held constant, are less likely to have their start-up employment size in higher classes

compared to firms located in the rest of Canada. FIGURE 4.4 shows that firms located in Alberta

are less likely to have larger start-up employment size, whereas firms located in Quebec are more

likely to have higher start-up employment size compared to other provinces and territories.

Page 90: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

71

FIGURE 4.5 shows the ordered logit model probabilities of firms located in the four studied

provinces, when other variables are held constant (calculated based on Equation (4.3), and

TABLE 4.5). These values quantify what the values of the coefficients and odds ratios mean. For

instance, firms located in Alberta have the highest probability (85%) of starting with one

employee, whereas firms in Quebec have a probability of 80% of starting with one employee. On

the other end, firms located in Quebec have a 2.5% chance of starting with five or more

employees while firms located in Alberta have a probability of 1.8% of starting five or more

employees.

FIGURE 4.4 Ratio of the Odds of Firm Start-up Employment Size for Some Provinces

0.000

0.100

0.200

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

0.900

Quebec British Columbia Ontario Alberta

Rat

io o

f th

e o

dd

s

Detailed model Simple model

Page 91: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

72

FIGURE 4.5 Probabilities of Firm Start-up Employment Size for Selected Provinces

(when other variables are held constant)

Industry class influences the start-up size decision. Some industries require larger start-up

sizes compared to other industries as shown in FIGURE 4.2, for instance, firms in

‘Accommodation and food services’ industry have the highest average start-up employment size

(approximately 4.2 employee). On the other side, model results indicate that firms belonging to

‘Accommodation and food services’ industry have higher odds of starting with employment size

greater than five employees compared to other firms in other industries (FIGURE 4.6).

Comparing the values for ‘Accommodation and food services’ in both figures, we can conclude

that the ordered logit model gives a reasonable representation of the industry class effect on firm

start-up size.

Furthermore, the results show that firms belonging to ‘Mining, Quarrying and Oil and Gas’

industries have a probability of 92% of starting with one employee, whereas firms in

‘Accommodation and food services’ have a 58.8% of starting with one employee (FIGURE 4.7).

Firms belonging to ‘Accommodation and food services’ have a 6.8% chance of starting with

more than five employees while firms in ‘Mining, Quarrying and Oil and Gas’ have a 0.9%

probability of starting with greater than five employees.

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1 2 3 4

Ord

ered

lo

git

mo

del

pro

bab

ilit

ies

Start-up Employment Size Classes

Alberta Ontario British Columbia Quebec

Page 92: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

73

FIGURE 4.6 Ratio of the Odds by Industry for the Firm Start-up Size: Simple and Detailed

Models

FIGURE 4.7 Probabilities of Firm Start-up Employment Size by Industry: Detailed Model

(when other variables are held constant)

Manufacturing and construction firms are explored in more detail to assess the effect of

location on start-up probabilities within industries. The probabilities of the start-up employment

0.000

0.500

1.000

1.500

2.000

2.500

3.000

3.500

Rat

io o

f th

e O

dd

s

Simple model Detailed model

0.000

0.100

0.200

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

0.900

1.000

Ord

ered

lo

git

mo

del

pro

bab

ilit

ies 1 employee 2 employees 3-5 employees > 5 employees

Page 93: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

74

size for manufacturers in different provinces are presented in FIGURE 4.8, and FIGURE 4.9 for

the simple and detailed model, respectively. FIGURE 4.10 and FIGURE 4.11 represent the

probabilities of start-up employment size for construction firms using the simple and detailed

models, respectively. The simple model indicates that, generally, when everything else is held

constant, construction firms have higher probabilities to start with one employee compared to

manufacturers, while manufacturers have higher probabilities to start with two employees

compared to construction firms (FIGURE 4.8 and FIGURE 4.10). There is variation in the

estimated probabilities by the simple and detailed models. This is because the detailed model

accounts for the effects of the economic indicators and the industry variables that explains part of

the behaviour, and hence some variation is expected.

FIGURE 4.8 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Manufacturers in Different

Provinces-Simple Model

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

1 2 3 4

Pro

bab

ilty

Employment Classes

Alberta Ontario British Columbia Quebec

Page 94: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

75

FIGURE 4.9 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Manufacturers in Different

Provinces-Detailed Model

FIGURE 4.10 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Construction Firms in Different

Provinces- Simple Model

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1 2 3 4

Pro

bab

ility

Employment Size Class

Alberta Ontario British Columbia Quebec

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

1 2 3 4

Pro

bab

iliti

es

Employment Classes

Alberta Ontario British Columbia Quebec

Page 95: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

76

FIGURE 4.11 Probabilities of Start-up Employment Size for Construction Firms in Different

Provinces- Detailed Model

The probabilities of the ordered logit for each of the covariates, independently while the

effect of the rest of the variables is held constant in the simple and detailed models, are

calculated using Equation (4.3), and summarized in TABLE 4.6 and TABLE 4.7. Such

probabilities are useful to explain the effect of each of the studied variables, independently, on

the firm start-up employment size.

TABLE 4.6 Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Each Covariate Independently (Simple Model)

Start-up Employment Class

Covariates 1 2 3 4

Ontario 60.5% 19.2% 14.0% 6.4%

Quebec 58.6% 19.8% 14.8% 6.9%

Alberta 66.4% 17.1% 11.5% 5.0%

British Columbia 59.1% 19.6% 14.6% 6.7%

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 56.6% 20.3% 15.7% 7.4%

Construction 49.2% 22.1% 19.0% 9.7%

Manufacturing 36.6% 23.0% 25.1% 15.3%

Wholesale trade 49.7% 22.0% 18.8% 9.6%

Retail trade 37.9% 23.1% 24.4% 14.6%

Transportation and warehousing 63.4% 18.2% 12.7% 5.7%

Information and cultural industries 41.3% 23.0% 22.8% 12.9%

Finance and insurance 48.3% 22.2% 19.4% 10.0%

Real estate and rental and leasing 53.7% 21.1% 17.0% 8.3%

Professional, scientific and technical services 59.7% 19.4% 14.3% 6.6%

Accommodation and food services 21.5% 19.7% 31.2% 27.6%

Provincial unemployment rate 44.7% 22.7% 21.2% 11.4%

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1 2 3 4

Pro

bab

iliti

es

Employment Classes

Alberta Ontario British Columbia Quebec

Page 96: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

77

TABLE 4.7 Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Each Covariate Independently (Detailed Model)

Start-up Employment Class

Covariates 1 2 3 4

Ontario 81.0% 10.7% 6.0% 2.4%

Quebec 80.1% 11.1% 6.2% 2.5%

Alberta 84.5% 8.8% 4.8% 1.9%

British Columbia 80.7% 10.8% 6.1% 2.4%

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 92.0% 4.7% 2.4% 0.9%

Construction 80.9% 10.7% 6.0% 2.4%

Manufacturing 84.6% 8.8% 4.7% 1.9%

Wholesale trade 84.4% 8.9% 4.8% 1.9%

Retail trade 84.6% 8.8% 4.7% 1.9%

Transportation and warehousing 91.2% 5.2% 2.6% 1.0%

Information and cultural industries 87.6% 7.2% 3.7% 1.4%

Finance and insurance 87.2% 7.4% 3.9% 1.5%

Real estate and rental and leasing 84.2% 9.0% 4.9% 1.9%

Professional, scientific and technical services 86.9% 7.6% 4.0% 1.5%

Accommodation and food services 58.8% 19.8% 14.6% 6.8%

(log) GDP by industry x 1010 74.4% 13.8% 8.3% 3.4%

Firm exit rate by industry (%) (t-1) 76.3% 13.0% 7.6% 3.1%

(log) Number of competitors (CMA/CA and NAICS 3-Digit

code) 77.2% 12.5% 7.3% 3.0%

(log) Average firm size (2-digit NAICS) 71.3% 15.2% 9.5% 4.0%

Provincial unemployment rates are found to have a negative effect on firms to start large in

size (TABLE 4.4). GDP growth by industry increases the likelihoods of firms to start with larger

employment size classes as indicated in TABLE 4.5. On the other side, higher firm exit rate

reduces the likelihoods of firms to start large in size (TABLE 4.5), which is intuitive as higher

exit rates may indicate an economic decline in the industry growth. Also, competition is found to

negatively influence the decision of firms to start with large number of employees (TABLE 4.7).

Average firm size is found to have a positive effect on firm start-up size. Firms that belong to

industries with higher average firm size are more likely to start relatively lager in size to reach

the average size quickly (TABLE 4.7) as also explained in (Baldwin et al., 2000; Pagano and

Schivardi, 2003).

4.5.3. Model validation and goodness-of-fit

Model validation was conducted to assess the performance of the estimated model. The

appropriate statistic for assessing the goodness-of-fit of binary choice models is the McFadden

Page 97: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

78

pseudo R2 (also known as rho-square). For ordered logit models, maximum likelihood method is

used to estimate the parameters. The R2 reports the variability between the estimated model (full

model) and the null model as follows:

𝑹𝑴𝒄𝑭𝒂𝒅𝒅𝒆𝒏𝟐 = 𝟏 −

𝐥𝐨𝐠(�̂�𝑭𝒖𝒍𝒍)

𝐥𝐨𝐠(�̂�𝑵𝒖𝒍𝒍) (4.4)

where �̂�𝐹𝑢𝑙𝑙 is the maximum likelihood value of the fitted (full) model, and �̂�𝑁𝑢𝑙𝑙is the

likelihood value of the null model (the model with no covariates that includes only intercepts).

In any estimated model (that includes any number of covariates), the reported log-likelihood will

always be higher than the log-likelihood of the null model (a model with no covariates). For a

model that has a very low predictive performance of the outcomes, the ratio between the log-

likelihood of the fitted model and the null model will be close to 1, meaning that the two models

are not much different, and the 𝑅𝑀𝑐𝐹𝑎𝑑𝑑𝑒𝑛2 will be close to zero, indicating a poor predictive

performance of the model (Windmeijer, 1995).

Pseudo R2 increases with the addition of more explanatory variables regardless of their

influence to the dependent variable. This could misleadingly lead to a false interpretation of the

model goodness-of-fit (Theil, 1961). Another measure that considers the number of added

explanatory variables and their effect on the Pseudo R2 is the adjusted-R2 as in:

𝑅𝑎𝑑𝑗2 = 1 − [

(1−𝑅2)(𝑛−1)

𝑛−𝑘−1] (4.5)

where R2 is the pseudo R2 calculated from equation (4.4), n is the total sample size, and k is the

number of explanatory variables. This adjustment indicates that the more explanatory variables

added to the model, the less the adjusted-R2 is unless there is a significant increase in the original

pseudo R2.

Although the pseudo R2 and adjusted-R2 statistics are considered measures of goodness-of-fit

of model estimates, they are not enough to assess the predictive capabilities of the model. Cross-

validation is a common technique that is being widely used in discrete choice model validation

(Roorda et al., 2008; Robin et al., 2009; Habib, 2013). The purpose of cross-validation is to

compare the estimated model outcomes (the dependent variable) for a subset of the data set (a

validation dataset; usually data that are not used in the model estimation), to the actual observed

values of the outcomes in the data. Also, cross-validation limits the problem of model

overfitting. Overfitting occurs when the model ‘memorizes’ the estimation data rather than

Page 98: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

79

providing a generalized relationship of the observed behaviour. This often happens when the

model is excessively complex (e.g. the number of estimated parameters are larger than the

number of observations). As a consequence, the model predictions are unreliable as the model in

this case describes the random error or the noise rather than describing the real behaviour

(Hawkins, 2004).

Cross-validation is used to further validate the predictive performance of firm start-up size

models on the aggregate level. For this purpose, a hold-out sample (a validation set) of 20% of

the firm population of investigation (43,281 records) is extracted, and not used in the estimation

process. According to (McFadden, 1978), the predicted total probabilities (for each observation

in the validation dataset) are calculated first and then divided by the validation sample size to

calculate the predicted shares of the four classes of the ordinal outcome of the start-up

employment size (TABLE 4.3). This number is compared to the observed shares of the start-up

employment classes in the sample. The model goodness-of-fit and validation results are

summarized in TABLE 4.8 and TABLE 4.9.

The pseudo and adjusted R2 statistics indicate a poor fit of the model (McFadden, 1978).

However, pseudo and adjusted R2 should not be the only measures to assess the model goodness-

of-fit. Another measure of assessing the overall model significance is a chi-squared test for

testing the null hypothesis that the model coefficients are not statistically different from zero. Let

Lf and L0 be the log-likelihood values of the full and null models respectively. The Likelihood

Ratio (LR) = - 2 (Lf – L0) is approximately χ2 distributed with df-d0 degrees of freedom if the full

model is true. For instance, in TABLE 4.8, prob> chi2 is the probability of obtaining a chi-square

of (16172.25) if the covariates are with no significant effect on the dependent variable (the null

hypothesis is true). This value is the p-value (with a value of 0.00) that when compared to a

critical value (e.g. 0.05 or 0.01 significance level) indicates that the null hypothesis cannot be

true and the model is statically significant at a 99% and higher confidence (i.e. all the model

coefficients are statistically different from zero) (Greene, 2012).

The cross-validation in TABLE 4.9, on the other hand, shows that the detailed model is

perfectly predicting the aggregate behaviour for the second and fourth employment class (zero

difference in the observed and predicted total probabilities), while it under predicts the

probabilities of the first class with 1.8%, and slightly under predicts with a 0.1% for the third

class. Results of cross-validation of the simple model are not included in this research.

Page 99: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

80

TABLE 4.8 Model Estimation Summary and Model Goodness-of-fit

Simple model Detailed model

Log likelihood (Null) -261084.65 -191880

Log likelihood (Full) -251559.51 -183794

Number of observations 232,303 167,972

LR chi2(16) 19050.28 16172.25

Prob > chi2 0.000 0.000

Pseudo R2 0.0365 0.0421

Adjusted- R2 0.0364 0.0420

TABLE 4.9 Cross-Validation Results of Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Employment

Size

Detailed Model

Class Observed Predicted Difference (%)

1 56.9% 55.0% -1.9%

2 18.9% 18.9% 0.0%

3 15.8% 15.7% -0.1%

4 8.4% 8.4% 0.0%

4.6. Firm Start-up Tangible Assets

4.6.1. Ordered logit model estimation results

The same data set that is used for estimating firm start-up employment size is used to

estimate the start-up tangible assets model. No descriptive analyses of the tangible assets can be

provided, as per the data confidentiality agreement with Statistics Canada. Outlier analysis

indicates that firms with more than $400,000 of tangible assets should be removed. The final

sample size that is used for model estimation is 272,746 records. 20% of the records are reserved

as a hold-out sample for model validation. Six class ranges are identified and selected for the

ordered logit model. TABLE 4.10 shows such ranges and their distribution in the data set.

Page 100: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

81

TABLE 4.10 Start-up Tangible Assets Ranges for Ordered Logit Model

Class number Ranges ($) Frequency

1 0 19.67%

2 0.01 - 4,999.99 19.14%

3 5,000 - 19,999.99 19.26%

4 20,000 - 49,999.99 15.58%

5 50,000 - 99,999.99 10.13%

6 > 99,999.99 16.21%

An ordered logit model is estimated using STATA 13 statistical software package.

Estimation results are summarized in TABLE 4.11. The model of firm start-up tangible assets is

designed to use the estimated number of start-up employees as one of the explanatory variable

(as explained in FIGURE 4.1). Only variables that are significant at a 95% level and higher are

included. For confidentiality reasons, the estimation results for the ‘Utilities’ industry class are

suppressed and only the sign of the coefficient can be included.

Page 101: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

82

TABLE 4.11 Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Tangible Assets: Model Estimation

Covariates Coef. Odds

Ratio P>|z|

Number of Employees (log) 0.601 1.825 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.022 0.979 0.038

Quebec 0.186 1.204 0.000

Alberta 0.067 1.070 0.000

Saskatchewan 0.279 1.322 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.984 2.675 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.117 1.124 0.003

Utilities Negative

Construction -0.447 0.640 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.761 0.467 0.000

Retail trade -0.369 0.691 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.173 0.841 0.000

Information and cultural industries -1.427 0.240 0.000

Finance and insurance -1.220 0.295 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.077 0.926 0.023

Professional, scientific and technical services -1.174 0.309 0.000

Management of companies and enterprises -1.203 0.300 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and remediation

services -0.772 0.462 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation -0.196 0.822 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.561 1.753 0.000

Other services (except public administration) -0.179 0.836 0.000

Economic indicators of year (t)

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) -0.047 0.954 0.000

GDP growth (%) 0.007 1.007 0.007

Industry characteristics and competition of year (t)

Yearly firm entry rate by industry class (NAICS2) (%) -0.062 0.940 0.000

(log) # of competitors in the same CMA/CA of the same NAICS-3 -0.056 0.946 0.000

/k1 -2.704

/k2 -1.651

/k3 -0.735

/k4 0.087

/k5 0.800

Page 102: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

83

4.6.2. Results interpretations

FIGURE 4.12 shows that firms located in Saskatchewan have higher odds of starting at

higher ranges of tangible assets compared to rest of Canada, while firms in Ontario have the

lowest odds of starting at higher tangible asset ranges.

FIGURE 4.12 Tangible Assets Ordered Logit Model - Ratio of the Odds for Some Provinces

Odds ratios by industry are presented in FIGURE 4.13. Firms that belong to ‘Agriculture,

Forestry, Fishing and Hunting’ industry class have higher odds of higher start-up tangible asset

values compared to other industries. This is due to the nature of this industry which requires

land, machinery and equipment as fundamental assets. Other industries are less dependent on

machinery and equipment as core assets (e.g. Information and cultural industries) and therefore

have lower start-up asset values.

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.60

0.80

1.00

1.20

1.40

Saskatchewan Quebec Alberta Ontario

Rat

io o

f th

e o

dd

s

Page 103: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

84

FIGURE 4.13 Tangible Assets Ordered Logit Model - Ratio of the Odds by Industry Class

The ordered logit model probabilities are summarized in TABLE 4.12, using Equation (4.3),

for each variable separately while the rest of the variables are held constant at zero. Employment

size has a positive effect on the start-up tangible assets. An increase of one-unit in the log value

in the number of employees increases the log of the odds by 0.601 (TABLE 4.11). TABLE 4.12,

however, shows that a unit increase in the log number of employees results in a 3.5% chance of

starting the tangible assets in class #1, a 6% chance to be in the second class, a probability of

11.3% to start in the third class, and a 45% chance of starting at value greater than $99,999.99.

0.00

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.00

Rat

io o

f th

e o

dd

s

Page 104: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

85

TABLE 4.12 Start-up Tangible Assets Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Each Covariate

Independently

Start-up Tangible Assets Classes

Covariates 1 2 3 4 5 6

Number of Employees (log) 3.5% 6.0% 11.3% 16.6% 17.5% 45.0%

Ontario 6.4% 10.0% 16.5% 19.8% 16.8% 30.5%

Quebec 5.3% 8.5% 14.7% 19.0% 17.4% 35.1%

Alberta 5.9% 9.3% 15.7% 19.5% 17.1% 32.5%

Saskatchewan 4.8% 7.9% 14.0% 18.6% 17.5% 37.2%

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and

Hunting 2.4% 4.3% 8.5% 13.8% 16.5% 54.6%

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas

Extraction 5.6% 9.0% 15.3% 19.3% 17.2% 33.5%

Construction 9.5% 13.6% 19.8% 20.2% 14.6% 22.3%

Wholesale trade 12.5% 16.6% 21.5% 19.4% 12.6% 17.3%

Retail trade 8.8% 12.9% 19.2% 20.3% 15.1% 23.7%

Transportation and warehousing 7.4% 11.2% 17.7% 20.2% 16.1% 27.4%

Information and cultural industries 21.8% 22.6% 22.2% 15.3% 8.3% 9.7%

Finance and insurance 18.5% 20.9% 22.5% 16.8% 9.6% 11.7%

Real estate and rental and leasing 6.7% 10.4% 17.0% 20.0% 16.5% 29.4%

Professional, scientific and technical

services 17.8% 20.5% 22.5% 17.1% 9.9% 12.2%

Management of companies and

enterprises 18.2% 20.8% 22.5% 16.9% 9.7% 11.9%

Administrative and support, waste

management and remediation services 12.7% 16.7% 21.6% 19.3% 12.6% 17.2%

Arts, entertainment and recreation 7.5% 11.4% 17.9% 20.2% 16.0% 27.0%

Accommodation and food services 3.7% 6.2% 11.6% 16.9% 17.6% 44.0%

Other services (except public

administration) 7.4% 11.3% 17.8% 20.2% 16.1% 27.3%

Yearly provincial unemployment rate

(%) 6.6% 10.2% 16.7% 19.9% 16.7% 30.0%

GDP growth (%) 6.2% 9.8% 16.3% 19.7% 16.9% 31.1%

Yearly firm entry rate by industry class

(NAICS2) (%) 6.6% 10.3% 16.8% 19.9% 16.6% 29.7%

# of competitors in the same CMA/CA

of the same NAICS-3 (log) 6.6% 10.3% 16.8% 19.9% 16.6% 29.8%

FIGURE 4.14 shows that the majority of firms in four provinces are more likely to start at

higher start-up tangible asset ranges. Probabilities for all provinces increase with the increase in

the tangible asset ranges, except for the fifth category, that decreases for all provinces compared

to the fourth category.

Page 105: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

86

FIGURE 4.14 Ordered Logit Model Probabilities for Some Provinces

The ordered logit model probabilities for each industry class (while the rest of the covariates

are held constant) are provided in TABLE 4.13 and plotted in FIGURE 4.15. There is great

variation in the start-up tangible assets across industries. Firms in information and cultural

industries have the lowest tangible asset values. Firms in ‘Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and

Hunting’ industries have the highest tangible asset values, followed by firms in ‘Accommodation

and food services’ and ’Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction’ industries. Such

industries that require larger start-up tangible assets rely on larger investments in land, and

machinery and equipment.

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

25.00%

30.00%

35.00%

40.00%

1 2 3 4 5 6

Ord

ered

lo

git

mo

del

pro

bab

ilit

ies

Start-up tangible assets classes

Saskatchewan Quebec Alberta Ontario

Page 106: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

87

FIGURE 4.15 Start-up Tangible Asset Ordered Logit Model Probabilities by Industry Class

Canadian GDP growth has a positive effect on firm start-up size. A growth of 1% in the

GDP increases the log of the odds of firms to have higher values of start-up size with a

magnitude of 0.007. Provincial unemployment rates have a negative impact on firm start-up

tangible assets indicated by the negative sign of the coefficient (TABLE 4.11). An increase of 1%

in the unemployment rate results in a 6.6% probability of firms to start with no tangible assets

(range #1), and a 30% chance of starting with values greater than $99,999.99. The effect of

Canadian GDP growth and provincial unemployment rates are similar (in terms of the ordered

logit probabilities in TABLE 4.12). Such findings are consistent with outcomes of the start-up

employment size models. Clearly, a thriving economy encourages businesses to grow in size and

decreases the likelihood of failure (van Wissen, 2000).

Firm entry rates by industry have a negative effect on start-up tangible asset values.

TABLE 4.12 indicates that higher entry rates reduce the odds of starting at higher tangible asset

0.00%

10.00%

20.00%

30.00%

40.00%

50.00%

Ord

ered

lo

git

mo

del

pro

bab

ilit

ies

$0 $0.01 - $4,999.99 $5,000 - $19,999.99

$20,000 - $45,999.99 $50,000 - $99,999.99 > $99,999.99

Page 107: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

88

ranges. Higher entry rates indicate higher competition of new firms in the market, which may

increase the likelihood of failure. Moreover, the number of competitors aggregated to the

CMA/CA and the sub-industry class (NAICS 3-digit code levels) has a negative similar effect on

start-up tangible assets. The values of the calculated probabilities are very close to those

calculated for the entry rates indicating similar impacts. Given these two findings, it can be

concluded that firms are inclined to start smaller to minimize potential sunk costs as a result of

higher competition of similar firms (Cabral, 1995).

4.6.3. Model validation and goodness-of-fit

A cross-validation of the overall shares of the observed and predicted probabilities is

conducted to evaluate the aggregate model performance for each class of the response variable.

A hold out sample of 41,547 records that were not used in the model estimation is used. TABLE

4.13 summarizes the comparison between observed and predicted shares. The maximum

difference between observed and predicted shares is 1.3%. Such small prediction variation

indicates an accepted overall performance of the model.

TABLE 4.13 Cross-Validation Results of Ordered Logit Model of Firm Start-up Tangible Assets

Range Observed shares Predicted shares Difference (%)

1 18.7% 17.5% -1.2%

2 19.0% 17.7% -1.3%

3 18.7% 19.1% 0.4%

4 16.2% 15.9% -0.3%

5 10.4% 10.6% 0.2%

6 16.9% 16.9% -0.1%

The reported pseudo and adjusted R2 are low. However, the chi-square test indicates that the

model coefficients are statistically different from zero with 99% confidence (TABLE 4.14)

TABLE 4.14 Model Estimation Summary and Goodness-of-fit

Number of observations 226040

Log likelihood (Null) -400079.06

Log likelihood (Full) -378437.96

LR chi2(25) 43282.21

Prob > chi2 0.000

Pseudo R2 0.0541

Adjusted R2 0.0540

Page 108: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

89

4.7. Concluding Remarks and Future Directions

In this chapter, models of firm start-up size are explored. Start-up size is addressed in two

dimensions: the number of employees and the dollar values of tangible assets. Models of firm

start-up size are not found in the Canadian literature. The presented models fill this gap and

enrich the literature. The models are components of firm start-up in the proposed firmographic

engine. Determinants of firm start-up size are explored and quantified.

Determinants related to firm characteristics, economic conditions, and industry

characteristics are investigated in this research. However, determinants related to the founder

characteristics are not covered. As a future research step, models that simulate the

entrepreneurial decision of the firm start-up could be estimated. A publicly available data source

for this purpose is the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor database (Global Entreprenurship

Monitor, 2015). This database includes information about individual entrepreneurs in different

countries, including Canada. This program conducts yearly surveys on randomly selected

individuals investigating their potential entrepreneurship. The currently published data set covers

the time period from 1998 to 2012. The data includes demographic information of firm founders

such as age, education, gender, and work experience. This data source is considered suitable to

model the firm start-up decision at the entrepreneurial stage, in addition to studying determinants

of firm start-up size related to founder characteristics.

The reported model goodness-of-fit indicates a poor fit. Other model structures that consider

firm start-up size in a continuous fashion is a potential future step. Examples of such models are

Poisson regression that assume that all firms choose their start-up size independently (Kumar and

Kockelman, 2008). Furthermore, the presented ordered logit models ignore the endogeneity

between employment and tangible assets, which induce endogeneity bias. One possibility to

overcome this bias is to explore other model structures that consider the simultaneous decision of

firm start-up size of employment and tangible assets, such as SURE and simultaneous equation

models.

Page 109: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

90

CHAPTER 5

Models of Firm Growth of Canadian Firms

5.1. Introduction

This chapter presents firm growth models measured in two dimensions: 1) the change in the

number of employees, and 2) the change in the tangible asset values. These models are the

foundation of the firm evolution module of the firmographic engine of Canada. Several model

structures that address the growth behaviour of the two growth aspects, both individually and

simultaneously, are explored. Panel regression models, multi-level models, a system of related

regression models, and auto-regressive models are estimated. The details, rationale, and results

of each investigated model structure are presented in this chapter.

Our finally selected model structure for firm microsimulation is the Autoregressive

Distributed-lag model (ARDL) as it fits the designed microsimulation configuration of firm start-

up and firm growth discussed previously in chapter 4, FIGURE 4.1. The configuration is based

on the assumption that employment and tangible assets in year (t) are dependent on what the

previous year’s (t-1) values were. It also assumes that tangible assets are a function of the

number of employees of the current year (t). The configuration quantifies the effects of other

firm attributes such as age, provincial location, and industry classification as in Equation (5.1)

and (5.2).

𝑒𝑚𝑝𝑡 = 𝑓(𝑒𝑚𝑝𝑡−1, 𝑓𝑖𝑟𝑚 𝑎𝑡𝑡𝑟𝑖𝑏𝑢𝑡𝑒𝑠) (5.1)

𝑻𝑨𝒕 = 𝒇(𝑻𝑨𝒕−𝟏, 𝒆𝒎𝒑𝒕, 𝒇𝒊𝒓𝒎 𝒂𝒕𝒕𝒓𝒊𝒃𝒖𝒕𝒆𝒔) (5.2)

The majority of the studies surveyed in the literature address firm growth in terms of number

of employees only (Shanmugam and Bhaduri, 2002; Evans, 1987b; Yasuda, 2005), while firm

size can be multi-dimensional (e.g. profit, revenues, number of business establishments, owned

vehicles, and/or warehouses) (Bruneel et al., 2009; Jang and Park, 2011; Huynh and Petrunia,

2010). In this research, firm size is addressed in two dimensions; the number of employees and

the tangible assets expressed as a dollar value. As explained in chapter 4, tangible assets include

assets with physical form such as buildings, land, and machinery and equipment (Statistics

Canada, 2012a). Tangible assets are selected as they represent the physical size of the firms and

Page 110: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

91

we hypothesize that employment and tangible assets are correlated (e.g. larger assets require

larger number of employees and vice versa).

The presented models of firm growth do not actually model the growth directly, instead, they

estimate the expected size (the number of employees and tangible assets values) at a specific

year (t), and this information can be compared to the previous year’s values (t-1) and determine

whether a firm has grown or contracted in size.

This chapter is organized as follows, it starts by briefly reviewing the literature on

determinants of firm growth that are used in this research, followed by an explanation of the

data. Model structures for firm employment including ordered logit, random effects panel

logistic regression, random effects-multilevel regression, ARDL, and seemingly unrelated

regression (SURE), along with the estimation results are then explained. Next, an ARDL model

of tangible assets is presented. Concluding remarks and future work are discussed at the end of

the chapter.

5.2. Determinants of Firm Growth

There is no general agreement on a single measure of firm growth. Size could be measured in

terms of revenues or profits, or by the human and physical capital a firm employs (Barkham et

al., 2002). The way firm size is addressed depends on the field of study. For instance, in the field

of geography and economics, employment is used as a measure of growth as it is an important

economic indicator that is essential for policy makers and is easy to measure. In the field of

finance, fiscal variables such as profits and sales are used to be consistent with other aspects of

businesses (Barkham et al., 2002). However, there is a distinction that should be noted; firm

growth and financial performance are independent. Firms may be performing financially well but

not physically growing, while a firm may be physically growing but financially is performing

poorly. So, the context is important in determining which aspect of growth should be considered.

Firm growth is affected by factors related to firm characteristics, industry characteristics,

location, market demand and supply, competition, and economic conditions (van Wissen, 2000;

Evans, 1987b; Dinlersoz and MacDonald, 2009; Marino and Noble, 1997; Geroski and Gugler,

2004; Barkham et al., 2002). Founder/owner-manager characteristics can also influence growth

within small firms (Barkham et al., 2002). Examples of such characteristics are gender, age,

Page 111: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

92

education, work experience, social network, and location (Shane et al., 1991; Barkham, 1994;

van Wissen, 2000; Barkham et al., 2002; Colombo and Grilli, 2005; Elgar et al., 2009)

Age of the firm has been recognized as an important determinant of growth in many studies.

Several studies agree that age has a negative effect on firm size and growth (Jovanovic, 1982;

Evans, 1987a; Evans, 1987b; Variyam and Kraybill, 1992). This could be because younger firms

grow faster to reach economies of scale and attain better market stability compared to older ones

(Cabral, 1995; Lotti et al., 2003; Park and Jang, 2010). Yasuda (2005) has attributed this to the

economic growth vitality; the slow growth of older firms encourages small new firms to enter the

market and create new employment opportunities. Other studies have claimed that age has a

positive impact on size and growth such as Shanmugam and Bhaduri (2002) and Das (1995) for

manufacturers in India.

Firm performance and growth are largely affected by location characteristics such as

population density, access to resources, labour market and demand, access to customers, distance

to suppliers, and land price (Mansfield, 1962; Hoogstra and Dijk, 2004; Maoh and Kanaroglou,

2007a; Elgar et al., 2009). Firm growth patterns also differ across industries (Delmar et al.,

2003).

Firm geographic concentration (competition) has an influence on firm growth (Baldwin and

Gorecki, 1998). It can be positive; higher competition leads to better strategic decisions, and

hence better growth when growth is measured in fiscal terms (Hermalin, 1992). When growth is

measured as number of employees, the effect of competition can be negative as firms benefit

from agglomeration economies as they share services and infrastructures, and hence may

contract in size to minimize costs. Furthermore, firm events of entry and exit influence firm’s

growth and turnover (Kehoe et al. , 2016; Baldwin and Gu, 2006).

Since this research targets firm microsimulation, the focus is on basic firm attributes, general

economic indicators, and basic industry variables that are readily available. More specifically,

the focus is on: a) firm characteristics of age, provincial location, and industry classification, b)

economic indicators of GDP growth and provincial unemployment rates, and c) industry

variables of average firm size, firm entry and exit rates, and local competition.

Also, there is a gap in the literature in introducing firm growth in more than one aspect,

except for one unique study by (Coad and Broekel, 2012) who presented growth as a

simultaneous relationship between employment and production size (expressed as sales values).

Page 112: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

93

Their analysis suggests that there is no strong relationship between the two aspects. In this

chapter a potential simultaneity of growth between firm employment size and tangible assets is

investigated by introducing a system of SURE equations.

5.3. Data Description and Basic Analysis

The T2-Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program (T2-LEAP) database, which is provided

by Statistics Canada, is used for model estimation. The data provide longitudinal information of

Canadian firms between the years of 2001 and 2012. We focus on single-location small to

medium sized firms (100 employees and less) as they constitute the largest segment of the firm

population and are more dynamic compared to larger firms (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2005; Kumar

and Kockelman, 2008). As discussed earlier, only for-profit industries are included and not-for-

profit industries are excluded from the analysis (i.e. educational service, health care and social

assistance, and public administration), refer to section 4.3.

According to the firm start-up and growth microsimulation configuration that has been

explained earlier in chapter 4 (FIGURE 4.1), the growth models depend on the previous year’s

firm characteristics. Therefore, only continuing firms (i.e. excluding the new firms) are included

in the model estimation. A continuing firm is identified in year (t), when records of the same

firms are found in year (t-1).

An outlier analysis has been conducted on the firm and panel levels to exclude deviating

observations. Outlier analysis is performed on the continuous variables of interest included in

TABLE 5.1 such as number of employees, tangible assets, and sales values. For instance, assume

a firm has records for 5 consecutive years. The recorded numbers of employees for each year are

10, 10, 80, 12, and 12. It is intuitive that third observation of 80 employees is an outlier. There

are different outlier labeling methods such as standard deviation method, Z-score method,

median rule, and median absolute deviation (MAD) method. Such methods generate an interval

or criterion that identifies boundaries that if an observation falls beyond them is considered an

outlier. For details about such methods refer to (Seo, 2006). Median absolute deviation method is

used on the entire sample level and on the firm level. In this method, the MAD is calculated

using the following formula:

𝑴𝑨𝑫 = 𝟏. 𝟒𝟖𝟑 ×𝒎𝒆𝒅𝒊𝒂𝒏(|𝒙𝒊 − 𝒎𝒆𝒅𝒊𝒂𝒏(𝒙)|), 𝒊 = 𝟏, 𝟐, … … 𝒏 (5.3)

Page 113: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

94

Observations that fall beyond the intervals of Median ± 3 MAD are labeled as outliers and

are excluded from the data set. This technique is performed on the firm level to exclude

deviating observations within the panel.

A preliminary descriptive analysis of the data set is conducted and summarized in TABLE

5.1. The populations of firms classified by province and industry class are presented in FIGURE

5.1 and FIGURE 5.2. It is shown that Ontario contains the majority of firms across Canada with a

share of 34%, followed by Quebec with a share of 22%. Professional, scientific and technical

services, and construction industries are top ranked for the largest share of firms across Canada

with percentages of 14.8% and 14.1% respectively.

Page 114: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

95

TABLE 5.1 Summary Statistics of Single-Location Small/Medium Sized Firms (less than 100

employee)

Variables # of obs. Mean Std. Dev.

Firm attributes (current year t)

No. of Employees 6,700,632 6.49 10.64

Firm age 6,700,596 10.43 7.76

log (emp) 6,700,632 1.19 1.06

log (age) 6,700,596 1.97 0.97

log (tangible assets) × 10-6 6,052,401 -2.33 1.93

log (sales values) × 10-6 6,631,898 -1.03 1.52

log (gross profits) × 10-6 5,654,550 -1.69 1.36

Firm attributes (previous year t-1)

log (emp t-1) 6,516,923 1.21 1.06

log (tangible assets t-1) × 10-6 6,080,227 -2.40 1.94

log (sales values t-1) × 10-6 6,637,759 -1.05 1.48

log (profits t-1) × 10-6 5,680,817 -1.72 1.33

Economic Indicators (current year t)

GDP by industry × 10-6 6,649,023 75460 43970

log (GDP by industry) × 10-6 6,649,023 1.84 0.64

GDP growth rate by industry 6,638,144 2.42 3.19

Provincial unemployment rate 6,682,628 7.01 1.81

Provincial employment rate 6,682,628 62.84 3.88

Economic Indicators previous year (t-1)

GDP by industry (10-6) (t-1) 6,701,093 731925 43930

log (GDP by industry t-1) × 10-6 6,638,605 1.82 0.63

GDP by industry and province (t-1) × 10-6 6,701,093 17880 17910

GDP by province (t-1) 6,701,093 314480 175955

Provincial unemployment rate (t-1) 6,682,628 6.99 1.84

Provincial employment rate (t-1) 6,682,628 62.82 3.91

Industry characteristics (current year t)

Entry rate (%) 6,700,632 3.66 1.25

Exit rate (%) 6,014,157 5.23 1.98

Number of competitors within CMA/CA in the NAICS 3-digit 6,700,632 30552 146725

log (number of competitors) 6,700,632 7.09 2.46

Average firm size (NAICS 2-digit) 6,700,632 57.23 83.14

log (average firm size) - NAICS 2-Digit code 6,700,632 3.31 1.16

Industry characteristics of previous year (t-1)

Entry rate 6,175,584 3.89 1.10

Exit rate 6,175,584 5.22 1.97

Number of competitors within CMA/CA in the NAICS 3-digit 6,518,906 6064 12241

log (number of competitors) 6,518,251 6.90 2.22

Average firm size (NAICS 2-digit) 6,700,632 57.91 84.33

log (average firm size) - NAICS 2-Digit code 6,700,632 3.31 1.17

Page 115: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

96

FIGURE 5.1. Firm Population Classified by Province

FIGURE 5.2. Firm Population Classified by Industry

Correlation analysis is conducted next to understand the potential relationship between

variables. This analysis is used as a guideline to assess the logical interpretation of the coefficient

signs of the explanatory variables in the final models. TABLE 5.2 shows that that there is a weak

positive correlation between firm age and number of employees. Another two sets of correlations

are observed. First, moderate to strong correlations between the log value of the number of

0.0%

5.0%

10.0%

15.0%

20.0%

25.0%

30.0%

35.0%

40.0%

Ontario Quebec Alberta British

Columbia

Atlantic Rest of

Canada

0.00%

2.00%

4.00%

6.00%

8.00%

10.00%

12.00%

14.00%

16.00%

Page 116: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

97

employees and tangible assets, sales values, and gross profits. Second, moderate correlations are

observed between tangible assets, sales values, and gross profits. These two groups of

correlations imply that larger firms (those with more employees and/or tangible assets) are more

profitable and have larger sales values. An expected very strong correlation is observed between

sales values and gross profits; as higher sales values increase gross profits.

TABLE 5.2 Correlation Matrix of Firm Attributes

emp

Ag

e

log

(em

p) t

log

(ag

e)

log

(em

p) t

-1

log

(ta

ng

ible

ass

ets)

t

log

(ta

ng

ible

ass

ets)

t-1

log

(sa

les

val

ues

) t

log

(sa

les

val

ues

) t-

1

log

(g

ross

pro

fits

) t-

1

emp 1.00

Age 0.22* 1.00

log(emp)t 0.81 0.27* 1.00

log(age) 0.20* 0.92†† 0.26* 1.00

log(emp)t-1 0.78† 0.31* 0.93†† 0.33* 1.00

log (tangible assets)t 0.46** 0.35* 0.53** 0.34* 0.53** 1.00

log (tangible assets)t-1 0.45** 0.39* 0.52** 0.39* 0.54** 0.97†† 1.00

log (sales values) t 0.64† 0.24* 0.78† 0.23* 0.75† 0.56** 0.54** 1.00

log (sales values) t-1 0.63† 0.28* 0.76† 0.29* 0.78† 0.56** 0.56** 0.95†† 1.00

log (gross profits) t 0.58** 0.17 0.70† 0.17 0.67† 0.52** 0.49** 0.83†† 0.77† 1.00

log (gross profits) t-1 0.58** 0.22* 0.69† 0.24* 0.70† 0.52** 0.52** 0.78† 0.83†† 0.91††

* Weak correlation ** Moderate correlation † Strong correlation †† Very strong correlation

Correlation of industry dynamic variables and economic indicators are calculated and

summarized in TABLE 5.3. A logical weak positive correlation is observed between entry rate by

industry and GDP growth by industry indicating that higher GDP induces higher entry rates. A

weak positive correlation is observed between entry rate by industry and log values of the

number of competitors, indicating that higher entry rates may exert higher competition. A weak

positive correlation is observed between GDP by industry and average firm size by industry

implying that larger industries have higher average firm sizes. The negative correlation detected

between the GDP values and entry rate by industry indicates that larger industries have lower

entry rates.

Page 117: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

98

TABLE 5.3 Correlation Matrix of Industry Characteristics and Economic Indicators

GD

P b

y i

nd

ust

ry

(x 1

0-6

)

log

(G

DP

by i

ndu

stry

)

x 1

0-6

GD

P g

row

th r

ate

by

ind

ust

ry (

%)

En

try

rat

e (t

)

Ex

it r

ate

(t)

No

. co

mpet

ito

rs (

t)

log

(N

o. co

mp

etit

ors

)

(t)

Entry rate (t) -0.33* -0.24* 0.30* 1.00

Exit rate (t) -0.01 0.01 -0.08 0.00 1.00

No. competitors (t) -0.02 0.05 0.05 0.13 -0.05 1.00

log (No. competitors) t -0.09 -0.02 0.08 0.20* -0.07 0.66 1.00

Ave. firm size (t) 0.17 0.19 -0.09 -0.03 0.25* -0.21* -0.31*

log (avg. firm size) t 0.25* 0.26* -0.16 -0.06 0.37* -0.22* -0.31*

* Weak correlation

5.4. Firm Employment Growth Models

Several model structures have been estimated and statically evaluated before settling on the

ARDL model to be the better representation of the firm growth. Two modelling approaches are

tested; a discrete choice, and a continuous modelling approach. Employment growth can be

formulated in several ways such as the percent growth from one year to the next, or the

ratio/difference between the number of employees in two consecutive years (e.g. emp(t) /emp(t-1)).

Number of employees can also be modelled for each year independently and the growth can then

be calculated by subtracting the number of employees in year (t) from the number of employees

in previous year (t-1). Continuous modelling approaches (e.g. regression models) are deemed

suitable to model the number of employees. Some discrete choice models have been tried (e.g.

ordered logit models) in addition to a group of continuous models (e.g. panel logistic regression,

ARDL, and multilevel regression models). In this section, some of the model structure estimates,

that may be good representations of firm growth, are presented with explanation of their

limitations. The ARDL model is chosen to simulate firm growth in the firmographic engine. The

rationale for this selection is discussed in section 5.4.4.

Page 118: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

99

5.4.1. Ordered logit model of employment growth ratio

The increase or decrease in the number of employees could be perceived as an ordinal

decision where employment is increased or decreased in year (t) as a ratio of employment in year

(t-1). The ratio between the number of employees in year t and year t-1 is first calculated. Then,

an ordinal variable ‘emp_ratio_classes’ is defined to represent the ordinal classes of employment

increase or decrease as in TABLE 5.4.

TABLE 5.4. Employment Ratio Classes

emp_ratio_classes Range Frequency

1 Employment has decreased in year t by more than half of

its value compared to t-1 (emp_ratio < 0.5) 7.45%

2 Employment has decreased by up to half of its value in

year t-1 (0.5≤emp < 1) 16.62%

3 No change (emp_ratio=1) 49.38%

4 Employment has increased by up to 1.5 times its value in

year t-1 (1.5 ≥ emp_ratio>1) 17.22%

5 Employment has increased by more than of 1.5 times its

value in year t-1 (emp_ratio>1.5) 9.32%

Ordered logit model is estimated using ologit function in STATA software to statistically test

and assess the model fitness and logical interpretation. For details about the definition and

mathematical formulation of the ordered logit model, please refer to chapter 4, section 4.4.

Results of the ordered logit model are presented in TABLE 5.5 and TABLE 5.6 for simple and

detailed models respectively.

Page 119: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

100

TABLE 5.5 Ordered Logit Model of Employment Growth Ratio - Simple Model

Covariates Coef. Odds

ratio P>|z|

Firm Attributes

Age (log) -0.285 0.752 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.055 0.947 0.000

Alberta -0.056 0.945 0.000

British Columbia -0.060 0.942 0.000

Atlantic Canada -0.039 0.962 0.000

Industry Class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.070 1.073 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.073 1.076 0.000

Utilities 0.233 1.263 0.000

Construction 0.148 1.159 0.000

Manufacturing 0.106 1.112 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.094 1.099 0.000

Retail trade 0.126 1.135 0.000

Information and cultural industries 0.046 1.047 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.065 1.067 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.016 1.017 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.018 0.982 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and remediation

services 0.091 1.095 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.116 1.123 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.025 1.025 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.114 1.121 0.000

Economic indicators

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.007 1.007 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of t-1 -0.004 0.996 0.000

k1 -3.088

k2 -1.720

k3 0.504

k4 1.783

Page 120: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

101

TABLE 5.6 Ordered Logit Model of Employment Growth Ratio - Detailed Model

Covariates Coef. Odds

ratio P>|z|

Firm Attributes

Age (log) -0.338 0.713 0.000

(log) Tangible assets (t-1) in million dollars 0.029 1.030 0.000

(log) Gross profits (t-1) in million dollars 0.054 1.056 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.062 0.940 0.000

Alberta -0.066 0.936 0.000

British Columbia -0.056 0.946 0.000

Atlantic Canada -0.068 0.934 0.000

Industry Class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting -0.082 0.921 0.000

Utilities 0.170 1.185 0.000

Construction 0.150 1.161 0.000

Manufacturing 0.078 1.081 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.085 1.089 0.000

Retail trade 0.098 1.103 0.000

Information and cultural industries 0.057 1.058 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.099 1.104 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.028 0.972 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services 0.046 1.047 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and remediation services 0.118 1.125 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.044 1.045 0.000

Accommodation and food services -0.029 0.972 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.056 1.057 0.000

Economic indicators, industry characteristics, and competition

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.009 1.009 0.000

Exit rate by industry of year (t-1) -0.006 0.994 0.000

# of competitors in the same CMA/CA of the same NAICS-3 (log) (t-1) -0.010 0.990 0.000

k1 -3.494

k2 -2.013

k3 0.073

k4 1.469

The signs of the coefficient estimates are logical. For instance, GDP growth by industry class

is found to have a positive effect on firm growth (TABLE 5.5 and TABLE 5.6). Age is found to

have a negative effect on firm growth indicating that older firms have slower growth (TABLE 5.5

and TABLE 5.6). Also, unemployment rates have a negative effect on growth (TABLE 5.5), and

exit rates and competition are found to have a negative effect on growth rates rate (TABLE 5.6).

Although the models look logical, the reported goodness-of-fit of the models (TABLE 5.7)

show a very poor model fit, interpreted from the pseudo and adjusted R2 values. This highlights

Page 121: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

102

that ordered logit model structure may not be a good representation of employment growth, and

other model structures should be investigated. MNL structures were also tested, and the reported

goodness-of-fit suggests a very poor model fit as well. The results of the MNL structure has not

been vetted by Statistics Canada, and hence are not included in this research. Results of ordered

logit models are only included as examples of the discrete choice models approach.

TABLE 5.7 Ordered Logit Model of Employment Growth Estimation Summary and Model

Goodness-of-fit

Simple model Detailed model

Number of observations 5,501,728 3,695,280

log likelihood (Null) -7469329.8 -5101586

log likelihood (Full) -7411041.9 -5054397.2

LR chi2 116575.94 94377.7

Prob > chi2 0.000 0.000

Pseudo R2 0.0078 0.0092

Adjusted R2 0.0078 0.0092

5.4.2. Panel logistic regression model with random effects

Another way of modelling the number of employees is to use continuous modelling

approaches, while accounting for the variance that may occur on the firm level. The variance on

the firm level represents the influence of other uncaptured effects related to the firm such as firm

structure and strategic decisions. A panel data set is used, which offers a great source to capture

the individual heterogeneity of firms if appropriate model structures are used (Baltagi, 2008). We

hypothesize that there are differences between firms that have influence on the employment

growth, and which are not captured in the data set. Examples of such effects are the long-term

strategic focus, technologies used, innovation, international activities, and firm structure. There

are several model structures that account for such variance such as panel regression and

multilevel panel regression models. The first model structure that is tested to account for

variance between panel participants is a panel logistic regression with random effects model.

Simply, the model accounts for the variation that could result from one panel participant to

another by estimating a random effects term. The model assumes that variation across panel

participants are random and uncorrelated with the dependent or the independent variables. An

advantage of a random effects model is that it assumes no correlation between error terms and

Page 122: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

103

the explanatory variables. This allows for quantification of the effect of time-invariant variables

(e.g. dummy variables of industry class and provincial location) and their inclusion as

explanatory variables. If no random effects are allowed, the effect of the time-invariant variables

can only be considered as fixed effects in the intercept value, and their individual effects are not

estimated (StataCorp, 2013). The random effects model takes the following formulation:

𝒚𝒊𝒕 = 𝛂 + 𝜷𝒙𝒊𝒕 + 𝝂𝒊 + 𝜺𝒊𝒕 (5.4)

for i = 1,…,n panels, where t = 1,….T, νi represents the unit/panel/firm specific error term (also

known as the between-entity error) that are assumed i.i.d. with N(0,𝜎𝜈2). The variance component

model states that:

𝛽𝑥𝑖𝑡 + 𝜈𝑖 + 휀𝑖𝑡 > 0 (5.5)

where 휀𝑖𝑡 is the typical error term that is assumed to be i.i.d. logistic distributed with mean zero

and variance 𝜎ε2 and is not correlated with itself, independent from xit and 𝜈𝑖, and homoskedastic.

The proportion of the total variance contributed by the panel-level variance (𝜌) is another term

that is calculated and reported in the estimation summary (StataCorp, 2013). This term indicates

whether the panel variance is significant or not. The term is calculated as follows:

𝜌 = 𝜎𝜐

2

𝜎𝜐2+ 𝜎𝜀

2 (5.6)

When the value of 𝜌 is zero, the panel-level variance component is neglected and the random

effects part is not statistically significant (StataCorp, 2013). In our case, the model estimates

suggest that the null hypothesis of 𝜌 not being statistically different from zero is rejected and the

variance between panel participants is significant (TABLE 5.8 and TABLE 5.9). The xtreg

function in STATA 13 software is used to estimate the model, which uses a Generalized Least

Square (GLS) transformation for estimation. In this function, estimates of �̂�ε2 and �̂�𝜐

2 are given to

perform the GSL transformation of a variable z (independent or dependent variable) as follows:

𝑧𝑖𝑡∗ = 𝑧𝑖𝑡 − 𝜃�̂�𝑧�̅� (5.7)

where 𝑧�̅� =1

𝑇𝑖 ∑ 𝑧𝑖𝑡

𝑇𝑖𝑡 , and 𝜃�̂� = 1 − √

𝜎ε2̂

𝑇𝑖𝜎𝜈2̂+ 𝜎ε

2̂. When 𝜎𝜈

2 = 0, 𝜈𝑖 is always zero, and 𝜃 = 0.

Alternatively, when 𝜎ε2 = 0, meaning that 휀𝑖𝑡 = 0, and 𝜃 = 1.

Page 123: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

104

Dependent and independent variables are transformed using an estimate of 𝜃�̂�. Coefficient

estimates and the conventional variance-covariance matrix are then estimated using Ordinary

Least Square (OLS) regression of 𝑦𝑖𝑡∗ on 𝑥𝑖𝑡

∗ and the transformed constant 1-𝜃�̂�. The OLS is

performed to estimate the following:

(𝑦𝑖𝑡 − 𝜃𝑦�̅�) = 𝛼(1 − 𝜃) + 𝛽(𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝜃𝑥�̅�) + {(1 − 𝜃)𝜐𝑖 + (휀𝑖𝑡 − 𝜃휀�̅�)} (5.8)

The model estimation results are shown in TABLE 5.8 and TABLE 5.9 for simple and

detailed models. The reported 𝜌 values of 0.82 and 0.745, in the simple and detailed models

respectively, imply that the panel level variance component is significant and should be

considered in the model.

Page 124: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

105

TABLE 5.8 Random Effects Panel Logistic Regression Model of Employment Size Estimation

Results: Simple Model

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

Firm Attributes

Age (log) 0.044 0.000 123.740 0.000

Provinces

Quebec 0.042 0.002 19.170 0.000

Alberta -0.135 0.002 -59.700 0.000

British Columbia -0.073 0.002 -31.490 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.121 0.004 32.530 0.000

Industry Class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.054 0.008 6.540 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.041 0.011 3.900 0.000

Utilities 0.787 0.032 24.350 0.000

Construction 0.211 0.008 28.150 0.000

Manufacturing 0.748 0.008 93.600 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.376 0.008 47.520 0.000

Retail trade 0.564 0.008 74.360 0.000

Transportation and warehousing 0.033 0.008 4.190 0.000

Information and cultural industries 0.194 0.010 19.880 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.017 0.008 2.000 0.045

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.034 0.008 4.250 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.077 0.007 -10.350 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.395 0.008 48.970 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.375 0.009 39.960 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.992 0.008 127.590 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.294 0.008 37.980 0.000

Economic Indicators

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.003 0.000 42.450 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of (t-1) -0.007 0.000 -40.510 0.000

_cons 0.716 0.007 97.760 0.000

sigma_u (𝝈𝝊𝟐) 0.849

sigma_e (𝝈𝜼𝟐) 0.381

rho (ρ) 0.832 (fraction of variance due to

u_i)

Page 125: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

106

TABLE 5.9 Random Effects Panel Logistic Regression Model of Employment Size Estimation

Results: Detailed Model

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

Firm Attributes

Age (log) -0.027 0.000 -60.170 0.000

(log)Tangible assets (t-1) × 10-6 dollars 0.067 0.000 239.580 0.000

(log)Gross profits (t-1) × 10-6 dollars 0.319 0.000 970.720 0.000

Province

Ontario 0.009 0.003 3.060 0.002

Quebec 0.056 0.003 18.670 0.000

Alberta -0.122 0.003 -40.760 0.000

British Columbia -0.012 0.003 -3.810 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.108 0.004 28.620 0.000

Industry Class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting -0.225 0.008 -29.570 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.291 0.009 -30.720 0.000

Utilities 0.095 0.026 3.590 0.000

Construction 0.055 0.007 8.080 0.000

Manufacturing 0.293 0.008 37.580 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.038 0.007 5.340 0.000

Retail trade 0.067 0.008 8.590 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.138 0.007 -18.970 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.078 0.010 -7.960 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.037 0.008 -4.670 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.147 0.007 -20.130 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services 0.044 0.007 6.440 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.277 0.007 38.310 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.325 0.008 39.400 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.684 0.007 94.840 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.305 0.007 42.350 0.000

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.001 0.000 17.710 0.000

Entry rate by industry (%) (t-1) 0.038 0.000 122.830 0.000

Exit rate by industry (%) (t-1) -0.009 0.000 -78.310 0.000

(log) # of competitors in the same CMA/CA of the same

NAICS-3 (t-1) -0.019 0.000 -50.720 0.000

(log) Average firm size by industry (NAICS-2 digit) (t-1) 0.064 0.002 40.020 0.000

_cons 1.385 0.009 154.080 0.000

sigma_u (𝝈𝝊𝟐) 0.586

sigma_e (𝝈𝜼𝟐) 0.343

rho (ρ) 0.745 (fraction of variance due to

u_i)

Page 126: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

107

5.4.2.1. Result interpretations

Age is found to have a positive effect on the number of employees in the simple model

TABLE 5.8. In the detailed model, when profits and tangible assets variables are included, the

age is observed to have a negative effect (TABLE 5.9). This indicates that growth in the number

of employees is largely affected by the growth in their profits and tangible assets and the effect

of the age alone may not be sufficient (by comparing the Z values in both tables for age, tangible

assets, and gross profits in TABLE 5.8 and TABLE 5.9). In other words, the simple model

suggests that older firms have larger numbers of employees, while the detailed model suggests

that older firms that have growing tangible assets and profits are less likely to have larger

number of employees.

The province variables in both models have the same sign and almost the same magnitude

indicating that the provincial location effect does not vary when other firm characteristics are

considered. GDP growth is found to have a positive effect on firm employment size in both

models. The simple model indicates that higher unemployment rates (reflecting a declining

economy) reduce the employment size. GDP growth and unemployment rates effects confirm the

hypothesis that a thriving economy encourages firms to grow in size.

Firm entry and exit rates are indications of market conditions and demand that are main

drivers to firm growth decisions (van Wissen, 2000). In other words, the greater the gap between

demand and supply, the larger the chance for market growth. Higher entry rates indicate possible

market growth that can take the form of new firm creation (as indicated by the entry rate) and/or

the growth of existing firms. In the detailed model (TABLE 5.9), firm entry rates within the same

2-digit NAICS code are positively influencing employment size of existing firms. On the other

side, the negative sign of the exit rate covariate (TABLE 5.9) suggests that when a market is

shrinking in size, existing firms are more likely to reduce their employment size.

Competition is found to have a logical negative effect on firm employment size; the higher

the number of competitors in the same sub-industry class (NAICS 3-digit code), that are located

in the same CMA/CA area, the lower the number of employees within a firm is (TABLE 5.9).

This could be due to agglomeration economy effects. When firms with similar activities cluster

together in a specific geographic region, they minimize their costs by sharing assets/services

such as logistics operations and warehouses. This could mean that fewer number of employees

that are required to perform the shared activities.

Page 127: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

108

5.4.2.2. Model goodness-of-fit and validation

TABLE 5.10 shows the estimation summary along with the model goodness-of-fit. The

overall R2 of the detailed model indicates a good model fit. A cross-validation technique is

performed to assess the model predictive capabilities. A 20% hold-out sample that has not been

used in the model estimation is used to predict the number of employees using the simple and

detailed models. The number of correct predictions are observed with a 10% marginal error.

Model validation indicates that the detailed model is 63.8% of the time able to correctly predict

the number of employees within a 10% error.

TABLE 5.10 Estimation Summary and Model Goodness-of-fit of Employment Size

Simple Model Detailed Model

Number of observations 5,659,027 4,451,208

Number of groups 1,124,099 914,138

R2

within 0.000 0.119

between 0.133 0.580

overall 0.123 0.579

Adusted-R2

within 0.000 0.119

between 0.133 0.580

overall 0.123 0.579

Wald chi2(23) /(29) 168315.53 1.67E+06

Prob > chi2 0.000 0.000

Validation sample size 945,361

# of correct predictions (within 10% error) 456,650 603,326

% difference 48.3% 63.8%

The reported R2 values do not have all the OLS R2 properties. The OLS mandates that R2 is

equal to the squared correlation between �̂� and y (r is calculated from Equation (5.9)), and also

equals to the fraction of the variation in y explained by �̂� (or the ratio between Var(�̂�) and

Var(y)).

𝑟 = ∑ 𝑦𝑦 ̂−

(∑ 𝑦) (∑ �̂�)

𝑛

√(∑ 𝑦2− (∑ 𝑦)2

𝑛)(∑ �̂�2−

(∑ �̂�)2

𝑛)

(5.9)

Page 128: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

109

The reported R2 values are different from the OLS R2 as it is not necessary that the squared

correlation equals to the ratio of the variances between �̂� and y, and the ratio of the variances do

not have to be less than 1 (StataCorp, Stata: Release 13. Statistical Software, 2013). The reported

R2 values are calculated as correlations squared using equations (5.10), (5.11), and (5.12). The R2-

overall corresponds to calculating the correlation squared using equation (5.10), the R2-between

corresponds to Equation (5.11), and the R2-within corresponds to (5.12).

�̂�𝑖𝑡 = �̂� + �̂� 𝑥𝑖𝑡 (5.10)

�̂̅�𝑖 = �̂� + �̂� �̅�𝑖 (5.11)

�̂̃�𝑖𝑡 = (�̂̃�𝑖𝑡

− �̂̅�𝑖) = �̂� (𝑥𝑖𝑡 − �̅�𝑖) (5.12)

In the estimated random effects model, R2-between is used to interpret the ratio of variations

across panelists, and the R2-overall is used to interpret the overall ratio of variances in the

sample, bearing in mind that the predictions under evaluation are the second-round regressions of

𝛾1�̂�𝑖𝑡 from 𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝛾1�̂�𝑖𝑡, 𝛾2𝑦�̂̅� from 𝑦�̅� = 𝛾2�̅��̂�, and 𝛾3�̂̃�𝑖𝑡 from �̂̃�𝑖𝑡 = 𝛾3�̂̃�𝑖𝑡 (StataCorp, 2013).

5.4.3. Multilevel model with random effects

Not only is there variability in firm decisions that are related to the firm itself, but there are

also other variabilities related to the industry class and to the provincial location. The hierarchy

of the firms clustered by different levels are presented in FIGURE 5.3. A multilevel approach is

suitable to model the random effects of panel data due to higher levels of data clusters.

The major distinction between panel data models (such as random effects panel logistic

regression) and multilevel models (or mixed effects model) is how each model handles the

regressors xij. Multilevel models treat regressors as non-random variables, while in panel models

regressors are assumed to be random.

Page 129: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

110

FIGURE 5.3. Multilevel Model Schematic

The estimation of multilevel models is computationally intensive for large data sets with

lower-level clusters, as the case of the used T2-LEAP data sets. Computation time increases

significantly when the number of estimated parameters increases (StataCorp, 2013). For

example, it took approximately 72 to 96 hours for estimating a random intercept only model that

has twenty-three independent variables using around six million records. Due to time and

hardware limitations, the estimation of the multilevel models with random slopes was not

feasible, and random intercept only models are estimated to demonstrate their statistical

significance.

5.4.3.1. Model description

Linear multilevel models, also known as Linear Mixed-Effects (LME), are a generalization

of the linear regression models that allow for the inclusion of random effects other than those

associated with the overall error term (StataCorp, 2013). The general matrix notation of the

model is represented in Equation (5.13)

𝐘 = 𝛽 𝐗 + 𝑢 𝐙 + 𝜖 (5.13)

where Y is n × 1 vector of responses, X is an n × p covariate matrix for the fixed effects 𝛽 of

the regressors, and Z is n × q covariate matrix for random effects u. The 𝜖 is a vector of errors

that is assumed to be multivariate normal with mean = 0 and variance matrix of 𝜎𝜖2R. Only

random intercept models are estimated in this research for the complexity and computation time

constraints related to other random slope models. A random intercept model takes the form in

Province

Level # 4

Industry

Level # 3

Firm

Level # 2

Observation

Level # 1

Page 130: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

111

Equation (5.14), which contains both level-1 (individual observation) and level-2 (the firm level)

effects, and can be written in separate equations as in (5.15) and (5.16).

𝑦𝑖𝑗 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝑥𝑖𝑗 + 𝑢𝑗 + 𝜖𝑖𝑗 (5.14)

𝑦𝑖𝑗 = 𝛾0𝑗 + 𝛽1𝑥𝑖𝑗 + 𝜖𝑖𝑗 (5.15)

𝛾0𝑗 = 𝛽00 + 𝑢0𝑗 (5.16)

The equation of the intercept (5.16) includes the overall intercept mean of 𝛽00 and a cluster-

specific random intercept 𝑢0𝑗. A level-2 random intercept only model is estimated to quantify the

variation on the firm/panel clusters. The mixed function in STATA 13 is used to estimate LME

for simple and detailed models. Estimates are summarized in TABLE 5.11 and TABLE 5.12.

Details of the maximum likelihood estimation technique of the LME are provided in (StataCorp,

2013).

Page 131: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

112

TABLE 5.11 Multilevel Random Intercept Only Model of Employment Size: Simple Model

Estimation Results

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log) Age 0.037 0.000 111.71 0.000

Province: Quebec 0.042 0.002 19.13 0.000

Alberta -0.130 0.002 -57.46 0.000

British Columbia -0.073 0.002 -31.85 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.117 0.004 31.38 0.000

Industry class: Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.052 0.008 6.26 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.032 0.011 2.95 0.003

Utilities 0.770 0.033 23.44 0.000

Construction 0.203 0.008 26.57 0.000

Manufacturing 0.740 0.008 90.8 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.369 0.008 45.73 0.000

Retail trade 0.555 0.008 71.83 0.000

Transportation and warehousing 0.024 0.008 2.95 0.003

Information and cultural industries 0.185 0.010 18.69 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.016 0.009 1.85 0.064

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.031 0.008 3.71 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.085 0.008 -11.25 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.386 0.008 46.98 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.367 0.010 38.45 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.980 0.008 123.65 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.288 0.008 36.45 0.000

Economic indicators: GDP growth (%) by industry 0.002 0.000 45.64 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of (t-1) -0.007 0.000 -41.31 0.000

_cons 0.723 0.007 97.15 0.000

Random-effects Parameters Estimate Std. Err.

Identity (Firm ID): var(_cons) 0.777 0.001

var(Residual) 0.144 0.000

Number of observations 6,601,802

Number of groups 1,140,557

log likelihood (0) -4815186

log likelihood -4815186

Wald chi2(23) 158908.97

Prob > chi2 0.000

Pseudo R2 0.000

Adjusted R2 0.000

LR test vs. linear regression

chibar2(01) 8.8e+06

Prob >= chibar2 0.0000

Page 132: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

113

TABLE 5.12 Multilevel Random Intercept Only Model of Employment Size: Detailed Model

Estimation Results

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log) Age -0.032 0.000 -70.01 0.000

(log) Tangible assets ($×10-6) 0.065 0.000 228.08 0.000

(log) Sales (t-1) ($×10-6) 0.323 0.000 952.87 0.000

Province: Ontario 0.008 0.003 2.780 0.005

Quebec 0.055 0.003 17.56 0.000

Alberta -0.122 0.003 -39.12 0.000

British Columbia -0.014 0.003 -4.5 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.108 0.004 27.18 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting -0.228 0.008 -28.43 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.291 0.010 -29.33 0.000

Utilities 0.099 0.027 3.62 0.000

Construction 0.050 0.007 6.9 0.000

Manufacturing 0.295 0.008 36.04 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.032 0.008 4.2 0.000

Retail trade 0.069 0.008 8.41 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.138 0.008 -18.06 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.070 0.010 -6.88 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.032 0.008 -3.85 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.145 0.008 -18.87 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services 0.041 0.007 5.66 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.275 0.008 36.05 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.321 0.009 37.02 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.684 0.008 90.2 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.298 0.008 39.39 0.000

Economic indicators, industry characteristics, and competition

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.001 0.000 16.81 0.000

Entry rate by industry (%) t-1 0.038 0.000 118.43 0.000

Exit rate by industry (%) t-1 -0.009 0.000 -78.26 0.000

(log)# of competitors on CMA/CA and NAICS-3 levels (t-1) -0.020 0.000 -50.14 0.000

(log) Average firm size (2-digit NAICS) (t-1) 0.060 0.002 36.99 0.000

_cons 1.417 0.009 151.53 0.000

Random-effects Parameters Estimate Std. Err.

unique_id: Identity (Firm Level)

var(_cons) 0.396 0.001

var(Residual) 0.120 0.000

Page 133: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

114

TABLE 5.12 Multilevel Random Intercept Only Model of Employment Size: Detailed Model

Estimation Results (continued)

Number of observations 4,314,653

Number of groups 910,038

log likelihood (0) -2,739,682

log likelihood -2,739,682

Wald chi2(23) 1.58E+06

Prob > chi2 0.000

Pseudo R2 0.000

Adjusted R2 0.000

LR test vs. linear regression

Chibar2(01) 3.30E+06

Prob >= chibar2 0.000

When no random slope components are included in level-3 and higher, and only random

intercepts are considered, the estimation results will divide the variance of the intercept equally

amongst the indicated random-effects clusters (TABLE A.5 and TABLE A.6 in Appendix A). In

order to have a meaningful LME model with more than two levels, random slopes should be

included and identified.

5.4.3.2. Results interpretation

In the presented random intercept only simple model, age is observed to have a positive

influence on firm employment size. Whereas, in the detailed model TABLE 5.12, when other

firm attributes of tangible assets and sales values are included, the age turns to have a negative

effect. This finding is similar to the panel logistic regression with random effect model results,

and similar conclusions can be made.

GDP growth is found to have a positive effect on employment size, whereas unemployment

rates have a negative effect. Both findings highlight that a growing economy encourages firms to

have larger employment sizes and vice versa. Similar to findings of the panel logistics models

discussed in section 5.4.2.1, entry and exit rates, competition, and average firm size have the

same intuitive effects.

Variability between panels has reduced by almost half when other firm related variables are

included (from 0.777 in the simple model to 0.395), which is intuitive. When other variables

related to the panelists are included in the model, the unobserved variability is reduced. A

likelihood ratio (LR) test is reported to compare the model significance to a linear regression

Page 134: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

115

model. In both models, the LR test indicates that multilevel models have better representation of

the dependent variable compared to linear regression models.

5.4.4. Autoregressive Distributed-lag Model (ARDL)

We hypothesize that firm growth (either in terms of employment size or tangible assets)

depends on their historical values and trends. More specifically, in a certain year (t), a firm may

choose to increase or decrease their employment size with a specific value based on its previous

year’s value (t-1). This means that there is an autocorrelation between the firm’s size in year (t)

and its size in year (t-1) at least. To verify this hypothesis, autoregressive models for firm

employment size and tangible assets are estimated as measures of growth.

Autoregressive models are considered to be dynamic regression models, in which the effect

of a regressor x on y occurs over time rather than all at once in a specific time instance (t) (Hugh

and Box, 1997). This dynamic specification (particularly in time series and panel data) allows for

quantifying the lag effects on future (expected) forecasts of y (Hendry et al., 1984).

In estimating ARDL models, first, it should be determined whether there is an

autocorrelation between longitudinal observations of the same panel participant or not, and

determine the order of the autocorrelation (i.e. AR (1), or AR (2) …etc.). One simple and

common technique is to use autocorrelation function (ACF). ACF is simply a plot of the

coefficients of correlation ρ, Equation (5.17), between a time series variable (xt) and its lags (xt-1,

xt-2, ..., xt-n).

𝜌 =𝐶𝑜𝑣 (𝑦𝑡,𝑦𝑡−1)

𝜎𝑡𝜎𝑡−1=

𝐸 [ (𝑦𝑡− �̅�𝑡)(𝑦𝑡−1− �̅�𝑡−1)]

𝜎𝑡𝜎𝑡−1 (5.17)

where �̅�𝑡 and �̅�𝑡−1 are the mean values of the variables 𝑦𝑡 and it is lag 𝑦𝑡−1, and 𝜎𝑡 and 𝜎𝑡−1 are

their standard deviations. However, ACF can only be used for a single panelist observation,

which is not our case as there are many panel participants in the dataset. For this, a number of

individual time series panelists are randomly selected and ACF is checked to determine the sign

and order of autocorrelation (if any) for each. The corrgram function in STATA software is

used. This is done for both the number of employees and the tangible assets variables. The ACF

indicate that there is no significant autocorrelation beyond the first lag, showing that the effect of

the autocorrelation beyond the first lag is diminished, and that AR (1) is a suitable order for both

variables. The ACF is also checked for the log value of both variables, and it is concluded the

Page 135: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

116

AR (1) is stronger for the log values than the absolute value of the variables. Generally, the AR

(1) values of the log values of both the tangible assets, and the number of employees’ variables,

for the randomly selected panels, are with negative values, indicating a negative effect of the

variable and its lagged value (StataCorp, 2013). The results of the ACF analysis have not been

approved for publication by Statistics Canada, to ensure privacy of the respondents, and

therefore have not been included in the thesis.

A first-order ARDL model structure is used for estimating the yearly number of employees

and tangible assets using a longitudinal panel data. The model accounts for the effect of

autocorrelation between the response variable (at t) and its first lagged value (at t-1). In addition,

the random effects component in the model accounts for explaining the variation on the panel

level as indicated in Equation (5.18).

𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝕏𝑖𝑡 + 𝜐𝑖 + 𝜖𝑖𝑡 (5.18)

where i = 1,….,N and t = 1,…..,Ti, and

𝜖𝑖𝑡 = 𝜌 𝜖𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜂𝑖𝑡 (5.19)

where | 𝜌| <1, and 𝜂𝑖𝑡is independent and i.i.d. with a mean of 0 and variance of 𝜎𝜂2. 𝜐𝑖 is the

part that represents the variation on the panel level and the 𝜖𝑖𝑡 is the component responsible for

addressing the autocorrelation of the first lag (StataCorp, 2013). 𝜐𝑖 is assumed to be realizations

of an i.i.d. process with a mean of 0 and variance 𝜎𝜐2 and is assumed to be independent from the

covariates 𝕏𝑖𝑡.The xtregar function in STATA 13 software package is used to estimate the

ARDL models with random effects for both the number of employees and tangible assets. A

random effects model structure is selected to accommodate time invariant covariates (e.g.

location and industry class dummy variables). The data set for this study can be unbalanced (i.e.

the number of time periods is not the same for every panel) and unequally spaced (i.e. missing

yearly records within the time interval are allowed). The command applies the Prais-Winsten

estimation method, which is explained in detail in (Prais and Winsten, 1954).

5.4.4.1. Model estimation results

The dependent variable is defined as the natural logarithmic value of the number of

employees at time (t) regressed against the variables identified earlier in the data description

section (TABLE 5.1). The estimation results are summarized in TABLE 5.13. The model uses the

first lag of the number of employees as an explanatory variable, and the rest of the covariates

Page 136: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

117

represent the change in the number of employees compared to year (t-1). Only variables that are

statistically significant at 99% and higher are included.

Page 137: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

118

TABLE 5.13 ARDL Model of Employment Size: Estimation Results

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log) Age -0.049 0.000 -209.650 0.000

(log) No. of employees of previous year's (t-1) 0.898 0.000 3962.720 0.000

Province

Quebec 0.011 0.001 17.170 0.000

Alberta -0.021 0.001 -26.630 0.000

British Columbia -0.009 0.001 -14.200 0.000

Manitoba 0.010 0.001 6.910 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.005 0.001 3.820 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting -0.049 0.003 -14.640 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.085 0.002 -35.660 0.000

Construction -0.025 0.002 -10.230 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.015 0.002 -7.880 0.000

Retail trade -0.022 0.001 -18.100 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.074 0.002 -45.140 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.094 0.002 -39.610 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.076 0.002 -48.950 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.068 0.003 -25.770 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.081 0.002 -35.310 0.000

Management of companies and enterprises -0.091 0.003 -33.030 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services -0.025 0.002 -11.700 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation -0.028 0.002 -11.470 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.020 0.002 11.650 0.000

Other services (except public administration) -0.019 0.003 -6.520 0.000

Economic indicators

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.002 0.000 12.570 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of (t-1) -0.002 0.000 -11.350 0.000

Industry characteristics and competition

Entry rate by industry (t-1) 0.006 0.000 21.760 0.000

Exit rate by industry (t-1) -0.002 0.000 -13.040 0.000

(log) # of competitors on CMA/CA on NAICS-3 (t-1) -0.004 0.000 -35.120 0.000

(log) Average firm size (2-digit NAICS) (t-1) 0.009 0.001 10.190 0.000

_cons 0.254 0.005 49.910 0.000

rho_ar (ρ) -0.126 estimated AR coefficient

sigma_u ( 𝝈𝝊𝟐)

0.077

sigma_e ( 𝝈𝜼𝟐) 0.389

rho_fov ( 𝝆𝝊) 0.038 fraction of variance due to u_i

Page 138: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

119

From TABLE 5.13, the estimated autocorrelation coefficient (ρ) indicates that the

autocorrelation of the first variable lag has a negative effect on the number of employees in year

t, conforming to results found by (Coad and Broekel, 2012; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006). This

confirms ACF explained earlier. This means that a firm with relatively significant growth in one

year is more likely witness a slower growth in the next year. The estimated value of 𝜌𝜐,

previously explained in (5.6), which calculates the proportion of the total variance contributed by

the panel-level variance, indicates a diminished effect of the panel variance for the current model

configuration. A discussion on the model goodness-of-fit is provided in section 5.4.4.2.

5.4.4.2. Results interpretation

The first lagged value of the number of employees was found to have a strong positive effect

on the employment size of year (t) (both in terms of the magnitude and the statistical

significance) which agrees to (de Bok and Bliemer, 2006). Age is found to have a negative effect

on employment size when the value of first lag is included in the model. This indicates that older

firms have slower growth rates. Our finding is in agreement to (Yasuda, 2005; Evans, 1987b;

Variyam and Kraybill, 1992). The values of the location and industry classification dummy

variables show that employment growth varies across industries in different locations.

The economic growth is explained by two covariates, the GDP growth and the provincial

unemployment rate. The positive value of the GDP growth and the negative value of the

unemployment rate covariates indicate that a growing economy encourages firms to grow their

number of employees, and vice versa. Entry and exit rates by industry are another aspect of

economic conditions and market demand and supply. The results show that firms increase their

number of employees with higher entry rates, while they contract their employment with higher

exit rates.

Competition on the other hand is found to have a negative effect on firm employment

growth. Competition is represented as the number of firms that are located in the same CMA/CA

that belong to the same sub-industry class (NAICS 3-digit). Higher competition results in lower

employment firm size. Competition is also the other side to agglomeration economies, meaning

that firms located in highly agglomerated areas are less likely to have larger employment size as

they probably share some activities/resources with other neighbouring firms. Furthermore, the

model suggests that firms that belong to industries that have higher average sizes are more likely

Page 139: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

120

to have faster growth rates. Firms tend to grow in size until they reach the average firm size

within the same industry.

5.4.4.3. Model validation and goodness-of-fit

The reported goodness-of-fit of the estimated ARDL model along with a cross-validation

results are summarized in TABLE 5.14. The reported ‘between’ and ’overall’ R2 values imply a

very good model fit compared to the panel regression model with random effects. While the R2

values are important measures of model goodness-of-fit, there are two other parameters whose

statistical significance need be evaluated. The two parameters are the estimated value of ρ, in

Equation (5.19), that specifies whether there is an autocorrelation (AR) of level (1), and the

proportion of the total variance contributed by the panel-level variance 𝜌𝜐 in Equation (5.6). Both

values are reported in TABLE 5.13. For the ρ estimate, a hypothesis testing is conducted to

statistically evaluate the null hypothesis that H0: ρ=0. The modified Durbin-Watson test,

suggested by (Bhargava et al., 1982), is performed and compared to values recommended by

(Verbeek, 2008) to accept or reject the null hypothesis that ρ is not statistically different from

zero. For very large data sets, if the value of Durbin-Watson statistic (dp), calculated using

Equation (5.20), is less than two, then the null hypothesis is rejected, and the value of ρ is

statistically different from zero. The calculated value for the Modified Durbin-Watson (TABLE

5.14) of 1.512 is less than two indicating that the autocorrelation term is significant and should be

included in the model. In other words, the number of employees in one year is significantly

dependent on its value in the previous year.

𝑑𝑝 =∑ ∑ (�̂�𝑖𝑡 −�̂�𝑖,𝑡−1)

2𝑇𝑡=2

𝑁𝑖=1

∑ ∑ �̂�𝑖𝑡 2𝑇

𝑡=1𝑁𝑖=1

(5.20)

Another test statistic that is calculated to evaluate the null hypothesis H0: ρ=0 against H1:

ρ≠0 is the Baltagi-Wu Locally Best Invariant (LBI) test statistics (Baltagi and Wu, 1999)

reported in TABLE 5.14. According to (Baltagi and Wu, 1999), this test statistic accounts for

unequal (missing observations) panel data, and the reported LBI is compared to the critical value

from the upper tail (to test negative autocorrelation) of a N(0,1) distribution. The Baltagi-Wu

LBI value of 2.1 is compared to Z value of a N(0,1) and it can be concluded that the probability

of obtaining a ρ value that is greater than zero is 98%. In other words, the null hypothesis can be

rejected, and it is concluded that ρ is statistically different from zero.

Page 140: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

121

The second term, the panel-variance significance 𝜌𝜐 in Equation (5.6) reported in TABLE

5.13, is of a value 0.038 indicates that the variation due to the panel level is diminished.

However, there are no further statistical tests to verify whether it is statistically different from

zero or not. Therefore, the term is kept in the model.

A cross-validation technique is conducted to assess the predictive performance of the model

for each individual year-record for every panel. A 20% hold-out sample that has not been

included in the model estimation has been evaluated using the model. The model is able to

predict the number of employees correctly 85.44% of the time while allowing for a marginal

error of 10%. This highlights that the model has an acceptable predictive performance on the

individual record.

TABLE 5.14 ARDL Model of Employment Size: Estimation Results Summary, Model Goodness-of-

Fit, and Model Validation

Number of observations 4,884,484

Number of groups 998,690

R2 -within 0.192

R2 -between 0.901

R2 -overall 0.861

Adjusted R2 -within 0.192

Adjusted R2 -between 0.901

Adjusted R2 -overall 0.861

Wald chi2(29) 1.93E+07

Prob > chi2 0.000

Modified Bhargava et al. Durbin-Watson 1.512

Baltagi-Wu LBI 2.101

Validation sample size 945,361

Successful prediction (10% error) 807706

% difference 85.44%

5.5. Firm Tangible Assets Growth Models

Per the microsimulation configuration of firm growth (FIGURE 4.1), models of tangible

assets growth use estimates of employment growth model (for the simulated year), and previous

year’s tangible assets as inputs. The same hypothesis assumed in the employment growth ARDL

model (section 5.4.4) is followed, which states that firm increase/decrease their tangible assets of

the current year (t) based on their previous year’s value (t-1) as explained earlier in FIGURE 4.1,

and Equation (5.2).

Page 141: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

122

5.5.1. Model estimation and result interpretation

The ARDL model estimates are presented in TABLE 5.15. The tangible assets are presented

in their natural logarithmic dollar value ×10-6.

TABLE 5.15 ARDL Model of Tangible Assets: Estimation Results

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log)Tangible assets (t-1) ×10-6 0.926 0.000 2471.390 0.000

(log) number of employees (t) 0.097 0.001 154.860 0.000

(log) age -0.074 0.001 -116.630 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.006 0.002 -3.810 0.000

Quebec 0.013 0.002 7.770 0.000

Alberta 0.027 0.002 14.720 0.000

Saskatchewan 0.029 0.003 8.560 0.000

Industry Class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.109 0.003 35.710 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.054 0.006 9.610 0.000

Manufacturing -0.041 0.003 -14.760 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.060 0.003 -22.340 0.000

Retail trade -0.111 0.002 -47.690 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.029 0.003 -10.300 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.061 0.005 -12.000 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.068 0.004 -19.370 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.028 0.003 9.110 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.063 0.002 -28.820 0.000

Management of companies and enterprises -0.020 0.007 -2.680 0.007

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services -0.060 0.003 -20.430 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation -0.046 0.004 -10.350 0.000

Accommodation and food services -0.116 0.003 -42.190 0.000

Other services (except public administration) -0.047 0.002 -19.060 0.000

Economic indicator, industry characteristics, and competition

Overall GDP growth (%) 0.001 0.000 5.090 0.000

Exit rate by industry (t) -0.001 0.000 -2.700 0.007

# of competitors on CMA/CA and NAICS-3 levels (log) (t) -0.009 0.000 -28.240 0.000

_cons 0.027 0.004 7.220 0.000

rho_ar (ρ) -0.496 estimated AR coefficient

sigma_u ( 𝝈𝝊𝟐) 0.085

sigma_e ( 𝝈𝜼𝟐) 0.417

rho_fov ( 𝝆𝝊) 0.040 fraction of variance due to u_i

Page 142: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

123

The model show that tangible assets (of year t) are greatly dependent on their value in the

previous year (t-1) indicated by the large value of the coefficient (0.926) and large z-value in

TABLE 5.15. Small-medium sized firms (employment less than 100) do not appear to make large

scale expansion of their tangible assets. The mean and standard deviation of the tangible assets

and their first lag values (TABLE 5.1) show a small variation between the two numbers

indicating a small variation which confirms the model results.

The number of employees is found to have a positive effect on the tangible assets. An

increase in the log value of the number of employees by 1 unit (i.e. an increase of 2.72 units in

the number of employees) increases the value of the tangible assets by $1.102×106. Age is found

to have a negative effect on tangible assets. This could have the same analogy followed in ARDL

model of employment size (5.4.2.2) that older firms have slower growth pace.

5.5.2. Model validation and goodness-of-fit

It can be inferred from TABLE 5.16 that the estimated ARDL model has a very goodness-of-

fit indicated by the high values of the R2 (specifically the between and the overall R2). Also, the

values of the Wald Chi2 and prob>chi2 indicate that all model coefficients are statistically

significant from zero. The autocorrelation coefficient ρ=-0.496 reported in TABLE 5.15, implies

that the there is a high negative autocorrelation between the tangible assets and their first lagged

value. Two statistics are reported to assess whether the term ρ is statistically significant from

zero or not; the Modified Bhargava et al. Dubrin-Watson and the Baltagi-Wu LBI in TABLE

5.16. The value of the modified Bargava et al. Dubrin-Watson is less than two rejecting the null

hypothesis that ρ=0 and confirms that it is statistically different from zero. Comparing the

Baltagi-Wu statistics of 2.204 to a standard normal distribution N (0,1), it can be inferred that the

probability of obtaining ρ that is greater than zero is 98.6%. Please refer to section 5.4.4.3 for

details and discussion about these two test statistics. For the panelist-variance significance, the

value of 𝜌𝜐 reported in TABLE 5.15, and calculated from Equation (5.20), imply that variation

due to firm-level variation is small. However, as mentioned earlier, there are no further statistical

tests to reject or accept the hypothesis that it is not statistically different from zero.

A hold-out sample of 20% of the records (that has not been used in the model estimation) has

been used to validate the model. A cross-validation technique is conducted by estimating the

tangible assets values for each individual record in each panel, and compared to their observed

Page 143: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

124

values in the hold-out sample. Model validation indicates that the model can correctly predict the

tangible assets 80.82% of the time while allowing for a 10% margin of error. This implies that

the model has a good predictive capability.

TABLE 5.16 ARDL Model of Tangible Assets: Estimation Results Summary, Model Goodness-of-

Fit, and Model Validation

Number of observations 923,828

Number of groups 540,531

R2

within 0.444

between 0.944

overall 0.938

Adjusted R2

within 0.444

between 0.944

overall 0.938

Wald chi2(26) 1.05E+07

Prob > chi2 0.000

Modified Bhargava et al. Durbin-Watson 1.004

Baltagi-Wu LBI 2.204

Validation sample size 1,046,767

Successful prediction (10% error) 845,974

% difference 80.82%

5.6. Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SURE)

Firm growth can be multidimensional; the growth is happening in more than one aspect at the

same time. We hypothesize that a change in a firm’s tangible assets is associated with a change

in their number of employees and vice versa. To model this simultaneous relationship, a

Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SURE) approach is presented to investigate this hypothesis.

This approach is limited for use in a freight microsimulation model because it doesn’t consider

any variability between the panel participants in the data. A future direction for this step is to

estimate a SURE model for a panel that accounts for the unobserved heterogeneity of the panel

units as explained in (Avery, 1977).

SURE models are deemed suitable when a simultaneous relationship between two dependent

variables is suspected, and the dependent variables are explained by the same set of independent

variables. The regression equations of the employment size and the tangible assets (Equation

Page 144: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

125

(5.21) and (5.22) are hypothesized and the associated error terms (𝑢1 and 𝑢2) may be correlated

(Cameron and Trivedi, 2009).

log _𝑒𝑚𝑝𝑖 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽𝑖𝑿𝑖 + 𝑢1 (5.21)

log _𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑙𝑒_𝑎𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖 = 𝛾0 + 𝛾𝑖𝑿𝑖 + 𝑢2 (5.22)

where 𝑿𝑖 is a vector of independent variables, and 𝑢1 and 𝑢2 are the error terms (the residuals)

that are assumed to be correlated. The sureg function in STATA 13 software package is used to

estimate the explained SURE equations. The sureg uses a generalized least-squares (GLS)

algorithm that is described in details in (Greene, 2003), page 341-343. Two types of models are

estimated, simple and detailed models. The simple model includes basic information of the firm

while the detailed one includes more information such as the sales values, and industry

characteristics. The model estimation results are presented in TABLE 5.17 and TABLE 5.18.

5.6.1. Model estimation results and interpretation

Both the simple and detailed systems of equations imply that firm age has a positive effect on

the studied firm growth aspects. This indicates that older firms have more employees and higher

tangible asset values. Unemployment rates in (TABLE 5.17) have a negative effect on

employment size, while GDP growth has a positive effect (TABLE 5.17 and TABLE 5.18). Both

unemployment and GDP growth rates as economic indicators imply that a growing economy

encourage firms to grow in number of employees as explained earlier. Similarly, the value of the

GDP by industry (TABLE 5.17 and TABLE 5.18) has a positive influence on tangible asset

values, indicating that firms belonging to larger industries have higher tangible asset values.

Furthermore, provincial location and industry class dummy variables show variable effects on

the employment size and tangible assets.

Sales values have a large positive impact on both aspects of growth indicated by the

magnitude and z-value of the corresponding coefficient in TABLE 5.18. This is intuitive, as firms

with higher sales values in a particular year (t-1) may consider to physically grow in the

following year (t) to maintain/increase their achieved sales values. Competition has a negative

effect on both aspects of growth as shown in TABLE 5.18. Entry and exit rates are measures of

industry dynamics and are found to have a positive and a negative influence on employment size,

respectively (TABLE 5.18). This is intuitive; higher entry rates indicate higher demand for new or

growing firms, while exit rates imply the opposite.

Page 145: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

126

TABLE 5.17 SURE Model Estimation Results: Simple Model

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

Equation (1) (log) # of employees

(log) Age 0.244 0.000 523.010 0.000

Province

Quebec 0.005 0.001 4.390 0.000

Alberta -0.196 0.001 -

133.660 0.000

British Columbia -0.081 0.001 -62.350 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.108 0.002 46.960 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting -0.041 0.003 -15.300 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.022 0.005 4.840 0.000

Utilities 0.694 0.015 45.040 0.000

Construction 0.234 0.002 104.640 0.000

Manufacturing 0.770 0.003 293.820 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.424 0.003 167.100 0.000

Retail trade 0.598 0.002 259.920 0.000

Transportation and warehousing 0.140 0.003 53.380 0.000

Information and cultural industries 0.227 0.004 55.120 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.044 0.003 14.140 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.061 0.002 -27.190 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.435 0.003 158.900 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.432 0.004 114.180 0.000

Accommodation and food services 1.092 0.003 430.600 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.316 0.002 128.820 0.000

Economic indicators

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.003 0.000 22.240 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of (t-1) -0.013 0.000 -40.440 0.000

_cons 0.545 0.003 175.710 0.000

Page 146: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

127

TABLE 5.17 SURE Model Estimation Results: Simple Model (Continued)

Equation (2) (log) Tangible assets ($×10-6) Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log) Age 0.594 0.001 737.960 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.304 0.003 -97.110 0.000

Quebec -0.294 0.003 -88.520 0.000

Alberta -0.191 0.003 -55.090 0.000

British Columbia -0.347 0.003 -99.620 0.000

Atlantic Canada -0.208 0.004 -48.330 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 1.343 0.010 131.320 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.392 0.020 -19.800 0.000

Construction -1.063 0.017 -62.530 0.000

Manufacturing -0.654 0.022 -30.360 0.000

Wholesale trade -1.046 0.016 -66.440 0.000

Retail trade -1.058 0.016 -67.660 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.429 0.015 -29.320 0.000

Information and cultural industries -1.026 0.014 -71.260 0.000

Finance and insurance -1.524 0.017 -87.780 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.250 0.021 -11.960 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -1.987 0.016 -

126.950 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services -0.906 0.012 -74.460 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.213 0.010 20.690 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.176 0.011 15.930 0.000

Other services (except public administration) -0.609 0.011 -56.250 0.000

Economic indicators

(log) GDP by industry (dollars x 10-10) 0.489 0.007 66.750 0.000

_cons -3.350 0.009 -

360.690 0.000

Page 147: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

128

TABLE 5.18. SURE Model Estimation Results: Detailed Model

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

Equation (1) (log) # of employees

(log) Age 0.057 0.000 157.06 0.000

(log) Sales (t-1) ($×10-6) 0.540 0.000 2198.09 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.013 0.001 -13.92 0.000

Quebec 0.040 0.001 40.20 0.000

Alberta -0.129 0.001 -121.47 0.000

British Columbia 0.124 0.002 80.11 0.000

Atlantic Canada -0.247 0.004 -61.57 0.000

Industry class

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.216 0.004 -58.00 0.000

Utilities 0.167 0.013 12.91 0.000

Construction -0.032 0.003 -10.82 0.000

Manufacturing 0.293 0.002 124.73 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.160 0.002 -66.74 0.000

Retail trade -0.013 0.003 -5.08 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.055 0.002 -24.25 0.000

Information and cultural industries 0.014 0.004 3.36 0.001

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.097 0.003 -29.96 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services 0.041 0.003 15.02 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.254 0.003 94.10 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.411 0.003 126.80 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.749 0.003 290.73 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.268 0.004 74.87 0.000

Economic indicators, industry characteristics, and competition

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.003 0.000 24.17 0.000

Entry rate by industry (%) t-1 0.049 0.000 102.15 0.000

Exit rate by industry (%) t-1 -0.008 0.000 -36.53 0.000

(log)# of competitors on CMA/CA and NAICS-3 levels

(t-1) -0.015 0.000 -83.76 0.000

(log) Average firm size (2-digit NAICS) (t-1) 0.026 0.001 20.02 0.000

_cons 1.428 0.006 233.74 0.000

Page 148: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

129

TABLE 5.18 SURE Model Estimation Results: Detailed Model (Continued)

Equation (2) (log) Tangible assets ($×10-6)

(log) Age 0.360 0.001 461.85 0.000

(log) Sales (t-1) ($×10-6) 0.635 0.001 1191.81 0.000

Province

Ontario -0.152 0.002 -77.49 0.000

Quebec -0.088 0.002 -41.43 0.000

British Columbia -0.141 0.002 -61.67 0.000

Atlantic Canada -0.146 0.003 -43.35 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 1.366 0.011 121.86 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.451 0.023 19.27 0.000

Utilities 0.336 0.030 11.30 0.000

Construction -0.345 0.021 -16.79 0.000

Manufacturing -0.094 0.026 -3.60 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.970 0.019 -51.25 0.000

Retail trade -0.922 0.019 -48.88 0.000

Transportation and warehousing 0.148 0.017 8.52 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.514 0.016 -31.19 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.600 0.021 -28.83 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.949 0.025 37.24 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.816 0.019 -43.41 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services -0.447 0.014 -31.83 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.189 0.010 18.58 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.375 0.013 29.98 0.000

Other services (except public administration) -0.214 0.012 -17.49 0.000

Economic indicator, and competition

(log) GDP by industry (dollars x 10-10) 0.064 0.009 7.25 0.000

(log)# of competitors on CMA/CA and NAICS-3 levels

(t-1) -0.088 0.000 -222.16 0.000

_cons -1.585 0.010 -165.98 0.000

5.6.2. Model goodness-of-fit and validation

Estimation summary and model validation results of the SURE models are presented in

TABLE 5.19 and TABLE 5.20. The R2 values of the detailed system of equations indicate a

moderate fit, whereas the simple system of equations indicates a poor fit for both the number of

employees and the tangible assets. The reported R2 values are the percent of the variance

explained by the predictors. The R2 may be used for descriptive purposes, but they are not well-

defined when GLS is used (StataCorp, 2013) and therefore should not be solely used to assess

the model goodness-of-fit. The values of the Chi2 test in both the simple and detailed models

indicate that all model coefficients are statistically different from zero. A cross-validation is

Page 149: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

130

performed to further verify the estimation capabilities of the model. The simple system of

equations indicates that it is able to correctly predict the number of employees 50.7% of the time,

and correctly predict the tangible assets 55.8% of the time. The detailed system of equations

imply that the system is 62.1% and 60% of the time is able to correctly predict the number of

employees, and the tangible assets, respectively.

It is noted that the correlation of the residuals is higher in the simple model compared to the

detailed model. The simple model has a correlation of error terms of a value of 0.437 (TABLE

5.19) indicating a moderate correlation between unobserved terms of employment size and

tangible assets models. When more regressors are added to the system of equations, it is noted

that the value of the correlation is reduced to 0.128 (TABLE 5.20). This is intuitive as the more

added explanatory variables that are relevant to both dependent variables, the less the correlation

between the residual terms that accounts for the unobserved effect.

TABLE 5.19 SURE Model Estimation Summary and Validation Results: Simple Model

Equation # (1) log_emp # (2) log_tangible_mill

# of observations 4.90E+06 4.90E+06

Parameters 22 22

RMSE 0.975 1.684

R2 0.158 0.237

Adjusted R2 0.158 0.237

chi2 925861.17 1.54E+06

P 0.000 0.000

Correlation of residuals of Eq. (1) and Eq. (2) 0.437

Validation sample size 1,039,154

# of correct predictions 526484 579415

% of correct predictions 50.66% 55.76%

Page 150: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

131

TABLE 5.20 SURE Model Estimation Summary and Validation Results: Detailed Model

Equation #(1) log_emp # (2) log_tangible_mill

# of observations 4.30E+06 4.30E+06

Parameters 26 24

RMSE 0.672 1.455

R2 0.603 0.430

Adjusted R2 0.603 0.430

chi2 6560000 3.27E+06

P 0.000 0.000

Correlation of residuals of Eq. (1) and Eq. (2) 0.128

Validation sample size 1,039,154

# of correct predictions 645433 624019

% of correct predictions 62.11% 60.05%

5.7. Concluding Remarks and Future Directions

In this chapter a range of firm growth models is presented. Employment growth models of

ordered logit, panel logistic regression with random effects, autoregressive distributed-lag, and

multilevel models with random effects are presented. The rationale and statistical significance of

each are discussed in detail. The ARDL model is selected for the proposed firm microsimulation

because it is a better representation of employment growth that fits the designed microsimulation

configuration. It is intuitive that firms grow relative to their size in previous years. ARDL uses

previous year’s firm attributes, economic conditions, industry characteristics, and market

competition to forecast the next year’s size. On the other hand, the presented panel regression

model with random effects can also be used in microsimulation if more weight to the panelist

level variation is desired while ignoring the autocorrelation of the dependent variable.

Firm tangible assets are information that is hard to obtain, and may not be feasible to include

in a parsimonious model of firm growth in a microsimulation setting. Hence, tangible assets are

not included as explanatory variables in the employment growth model to make the

microsimulation of employment achievable. For this reason, only ARDL models are estimated

for tangible assets in case such information is available and can be included in the

microsimulation.

While firm growth is presented in two dimensions that seem to be correlated, firm growth

could better be presented using a single unit the combines both growth aspects, such as

employment per floor space (Hunt et al., 2005; Badoe and Miller, 2000; Miller and Lerman,

Page 151: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

132

1981). This information is not available in the used data set. If such information becomes

available, the physical form of the firm could be better explained as the employment per floor

space.

Systems of SURE equations that consider correlation between unobserved terms of the

number of employees and the tangible assets are explored. The SURE may not be suitable for

prediction nor microsimulation purposes because it ignores unobserved heterogeneity between

panelists. SURE do not capture actual correlation of dependent variables, but rather a correlation

between error terms. A future step for this approach is to estimate SURE for panels by

considering that both equations are correlated over time and across units as explained in (Avery,

1977). The effect of autoregression can also be considered by estimating a multivariate time-

series regression of each dependent variable on their lags and on the dependent variable lags as

well (StataCorp, 2013;Kmenta and Gilbert, 1970). Furthermore, a system of simultaneous

equations is another future approach to capture correlation between dependent variables; when

the effect of one dependent variable is endogenous to the other. The estimation of a system of

simultaneous equation models requires enough additional exogenous variables to explain

identified endogenous variables (referred to ‘instruments’). The currently used data set is

dominated by dummy variables, with no enough instruments to be used to estimate the

endogenous variables. When dummy variables, such as industry classification, provincial

location, and corporate type (i.e. private vs. public), are used, the estimation of a system of

structure equation results in the same values as SURE. To have an identified system, a number of

exogenous variables to be instruments is needed to satisfy the condition 𝑚𝑖 ≤ (𝐾 − 𝑘𝑖), where

𝑚𝑖 is the number of endogenous variables in an equation i, K is the total number of all exogenous

variables (including instruments) in the system of equations, and 𝑘𝑖 is the number of exogenous

variables in equation i.

Further discrete choice model approaches such as nested logit (NL) can be explored. Also,

discrete choice models that accommodate panel variance are good candidates to represent firm

growth decisions. Examples of such models are multilevel/mixed MNL, multilevel/mixed NL,

and multilevel ordered logit.

The effect of age on firm growth and employment size is a controversial topic in the

literature. Throughout the models presented in this chapter, it is observed that when age is solely

included to explain employment size, age has a positive effect. Whereas when other firm related

Page 152: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

133

attributes that have greater effects on employment size (e.g. tangible assets) are included, the

effect of age is negative. Since other firm attributes of tangible assets and sales values are found

to have higher statistical significance on firm employment size, there are higher confidence that

age has a negative effect on employment size, and it can be concluded that older firms have

smaller growth rates compared to younger ones, agreeing to (Yasuda, 2005; Evans, 1987b;

Variyam & Kraybill, 1992). Young firms grow faster as they need to reach economies of scale to

attain market stability (Cabral 1995, Lotti, Santarelli and Vivarelli 2003, Park and Jang 2010)

Economic growth presented as the GDP and unemployment rate is found to have an

intuitive positive effect on firm size. Firms consider expansion when there is higher demand in

the market. Agglomeration economies (presented as market competition) negatively affect firm

size. When firms geographically cluster together, they are more likely to share common

services/infrastructure, such as warehouses, to minimize cost. As a result, they may consider to

reduce their employment size. There seem to be association between economic growth, firm

entry and exit rates, firm growth, and market competition. In this research, each aspect is treated

exogenously to firm size models. Further models that accounts for such endogeneity are a logical

future step for this research.

Page 153: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

134

CHAPTER 6

Survival Analysis of Canadian Firms

6.1. Introduction

In this chapter, firm survival analysis for for-profit, single-location, small-to-medium sized

Canadian firms (with 100 or less employees) is introduced for an eleven-year interval (2001 to

2012). More specifically, the focus is on studying the effect of firm characteristics (e.g. firm age

and number of employees), firm location, industry dynamics (e.g. firm entry and exit rates),

market competition, and economic growth (e.g. GDP growth rates, and provincial unemployment

rates), on firm failure. The analysis includes two components: parametric and non-parametric

models. The parametric model is intended to form part of a large-scale firmographic

microsimulation for firms in Canada (Mostafa and Roorda, 2015). The chapter starts with a brief

literature review on determinants of firm failure. Next, the longitudinal database is described,

followed by preliminary analysis of the data to understand firm entry and failure trends. Then,

the chapter presents non-parametric and parametric analyses of firm survival, in which failure

events of the 2001 firm population are observed from 2002 to 2012. The non-parametric analysis

presents survival and hazard rates estimates using Kaplan and Meier, and Nelson–Aalen

estimators characterized by firm age, province, and industry. In the parametric survival analysis,

a discrete-time hazard model of failure for the targeted firm population is introduced. Our results

are compared to other Canadian studies of firm survival analysis (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b;

Baldwin et al., 2000). The chapter ends with some concluding remarks and highlights future

directions.

6.2. Literature Review

Firm failure takes one of two forms; firms either disappear from the market or merge with

other firms (van Wissen, 2000). Generally, firms fail due to unsuccessful business strategies.

Baldwin and Gellatly (2003) indicate that firms fail because of internal deficiencies in core areas

such as management, finance, and marketing. Modelling firm failure as a discrete choice by

considering firm strategies is difficult for two reasons. First, causes of failure are hard to

discover because firm founders are hard to track (especially for firms that disappear from the

Page 154: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

135

market). Second, detailed longitudinal data of firm strategies for long periods of time are

necessary to draw sufficient conclusions about failure patterns. Such datasets are rare.

Firm strategies are influenced by external factors such as market dynamics and changes in

the economy. They are the result of competition, changes within the industry, and economic

growth. Since it is difficult to obtain longitudinal data of firm strategies, most studies that

address firm failure use external drivers that influence firm strategy formulation (e.g. firm

characteristics, industry features, location information, and economic indicators) as determinants

of failure (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Baldwin et al., 2000). In these studies, survival and

hazard duration models are used to provide models of firm failure based on firm characteristics,

location demographics, and economic indicators as determinants of failure (Mata and Portugal,

1994; Fritsch et al. 2006; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Strotmann, 2007; Nunes and Sarmento,

2010; Bhattacharjee, 2005).

The majority of studies that have addressed firm failure are for European firms (Audretsch et

al., 2000; Berglund and Brännäs, 2001; Carree et al., 2008; Fotopoulos and Spence, 2001; van

Wissen, 2000; Lopez-Garcia and Puente, 2006; Dunne and Hughes, 1994; Eriksson and Kuhn,

2006; Harhoff et al., 1998; Wagner, 1999; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006). Few studies are found for

North American firms (Kumar and Kockelman, 2008; Dunne et al., 1988; Audretsch, 1991;

Baldwin et al., 2000; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Shapiro and Khemani, 1987). In the

Canadian context, only two studies (Baldwin et al., 2000; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b) have

addressed firm failure from land use and geographic perspectives. Maoh and Kanaroglou (2007)

have addressed firm failure on a local level (i.e. the City of Hamilton in Ontario) while Baldwin

et al. (2000) have presented a study of survival of new firms for Canada.

Firm failure is related to the firm’s performance, productivity and status in the market and

ability to achieve their long-term goals (Agarwal, 1996; Cefis and Marsili, 2006; Siegfried and

Evans, 1994). However, every firm has their own measures of effectiveness depending on

criteria such as the long-term strategy and strategic focus, production capacity, competition, and

industry dynamics. A large body of research has investigated determinants of firm failure using

firm micro-data for the purpose of building fundamental understanding of failure patterns (Acs et

al., 2007; Audretsch et al., 2000; Berglund and Brännäs, 2001; Carree et al., 2008; Fotopoulos

and Spence, 2001; Nyström, 2007; Siegfried and Evans, 1994).

Page 155: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

136

6.2.1. Determinants of firm failure

Determinants of firm failure are related to the firm, industry, location and/or macro-economic

conditions (van Wissen, 2000; Strotmann, 2007; He and Yang, 2015). Firm related factors

include firm age, employment size, location, firm growth rate, offered products and services,

business strategies, research and development (R&D) investment, and innovation (Mata et al.,

1995; Stearns et al., 1995; Reynolds, 1997; van Wissen, 2000; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006; Maoh

and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010). Firm survival patterns vary across

industries depending on the economic growth of the industry, industry size, industry life cycle,

agglomeration economies and economies of scale (van Wissen, 2000; Strotmann, 2007; Klapper

and Richmond, 2011). Below are details of the most common determinants surveyed in the

literature.

6.2.1.1. Type of entry and ownership

Several studies state that firm entry type affects survival (Eriksson and Kuhn, 2006;

Lindholm, 1994; Dietrich and Gibson, 1990;Walsh and Boyland, 1996). Spin-offs (firms that are

formed when a group of persons, who are working in existing firms, decide to open a new firm)

tend to have higher growth and survival rates. Spin-offs benefit from personal networks (that are

transformed by their founders from their previous workplace), and industry-specific knowledge.

Eriksson and Kuhn (2006) investigated growth and survival of Danish private sector spin-offs

during the period of 1981 to 2000. Their results highlight that spin-offs have lower failure risks

compared to other entrants. On the other hand, Zhang and Mohnen (2013) have shown that the

type of ownership affects failure probabilities; they state that domestic firms have lower survival

probability than foreign firms in China. They also show that privately owned firms have higher

survival rates than state-owned firms reflecting the privatization of the Chinese economy and

that privately owned firms are more sensitive to local economic conditions.

6.2.1.2. Age and size

Several studies state that firm size (number of employees) and age affect firm survival;

larger and older firms have higher survival potential (Reynolds, 1987; Stearns et al., 1995; van

Wissen, 2000; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Nunes and Sarmento,

2010). Hannan et al. (1998), Lopez-Garcia et al. (2007) find that age and size effects vary across

firms and industries. Studies that have investigated the effect of firm size only confirm also that

Page 156: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

137

large firms are less likely to fail (Audretsch and Mahmood, 1995; Dunne and Hughes, 1994;

Ericson and Pakes, 1995; Geroski, 1995; Mata and Portugal, 1999). Other studies report that the

effect of size on firm failure is not uniform and could be nonlinear (Mata and Portugal, 1994;

Pérez et al., 2004; Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b). Moreover, firm initial size (also known as

firm start-up size) influences firm survival as highlighted in (Schröder and Sørensen, 2012;

Strotmann, 2007). Mata and Portugal (1994) indicate that firms that start their business with

larger sizes have better survival probabilities. Firm growth rate also affects firm survival. Some

studies find that small new firms that have faster growth rates experience higher survival

probabilities (Mata and Portugal, 1994; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010).

6.2.1.3. Firm strategies

van Wissen (2000) points out that the flexibility of strategy selection influences firm

survival. His study states that firms with more fixed strategies have better survival rates

compared to firms with more dynamic ones. He also finds that older larger firms have reached

the set of strategies that allows them to maintain adequate performance within the market.

6.2.1.4. Research and Development (R&D) investments

The amount of R&D investment also has an influence over firm survival (Fritsch et al.,

2006; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010; Sharapov et al., 2011; Zhang and Mohnen, 2013). Firms that

dedicate more funds for R&D have higher survival chances (Fritsch et al., 2006; Sharapov et al.,

2011). However, Zhang and Mohnen (2013) found that there is an inverted U-shaped

relationship between R&D investments and firm survival indicating that overinvesting in R&D

increases the risk of failure.

6.2.1.5. Industry environment and dynamics

Failure probabilities vary from one industry to another. For instance, survival probabilities

are low in industries where demand is low, the market is narrow, and minimum efficient scale is

high (Fritsch et al., 2006; Strotmann, 2007). Minimum efficient scale is the amount of capital

required for a firm to operate efficiently (Fonseca et al., 2001). Also, firms that belong to highly

innovative industries have higher failure rates (Audretsch, 1995a). Industry dynamics

represented in firm entry and exit rates affect survival of firms within the same industry cohorts

(Mata and Portugal, 1994; de Bok and Bliemer, 2006). New firms that exist in industries with

Page 157: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

138

higher entry rates have lower survival chances because of the increased competition of similar

firms (Mata et al., 1995; Nunes and Sarmento, 2010).

6.2.1.6. Agglomeration economies

Firms tend to locate near similar firms to benefit from agglomeration economies. However,

Strotmann (2007) states that firms that locate in highly agglomerated areas have higher risks of

failure. This could be because, beyond a certain level of agglomeration, further increase in the

density of firm clusters in the same industry could result in higher competition.

6.2.1.7. Economic growth and market demand

Generally, it is found that firm survival is positively affected by Gross Domestic Product

(GDP) growth (Klapper and Richmond, 2011; Baldwin et al., 2000). On a macroeconomic level,

market stress, which reflects the difference between market demand and supply, positively

affects firm survival (van Wissen, 2000). Increased GDP reflects higher potential for more

production, leading to lower failure probability. On the other hand, firms that belong to

industries with saturated market have higher failure rates (Audretsch, 1995a).

6.3. Data Description

This study utilizes the T2-Longitudinal Employment Analysis Program (T2-LEAP), a

longitudinal database of the entire Canadian firm population that have records in the tax files

every year. For more information about the database, refer to chapter 3, section 3.4.1.

6.3.1. Population of study

The T2-LEAP database is used to assess firm failure events from 2001 to 2012. Only single-

location small to medium sized firms (employment 100 or less) are considered for this analysis

as they constitute the largest segment of firm population and are more dynamic compared to

larger firms (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2005; Kumar and Kockelman, 2008). As discussed in

section 4.3, for-profit industries are included and non-for profit ones are excluded from the

analysis.

The T2-LEAP uses the Survey of Employment, Payrolls and Hours (SEPH) to calculate a

measure of employment called Average Labour Unit (ALU). The T4 records do not include

exact information on when and for how long an employee has worked for a firm. Therefore,

Statistics Canada has used the ALU to calculate the average employment an enterprise would

Page 158: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

139

have if it paid its workers the average annual earnings (AAE) of a typical worker in the firm’s

particular 4-digit industry, province, and firm size. AAE are obtained from the SEPH (Statistics

Canada, 2012a). The ALU is calculated as follows:

𝐴𝐿𝑈 = 𝐴𝑛𝑛𝑢𝑎𝑙 𝑡𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑝𝑎𝑦𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑙

𝐴𝐴𝐸

This procedure for calculating the ALU means that some firms result in zero employment for

some years. This could be because the annual total payroll is missing or the firm is inactive (i.e.

the firm is registered in the tax records but not physically in business). Zero employment firms

are excluded from our analysis. The 2001 firm population size is 970,498 firms. These firms are

tracked until 2012 while marking firm failure events during this period. The total number of

observations is 6,184,894 for the entire period (after exclusion of 20% of the records as a

validation data subset).

6.3.2. Explanatory variables

The T2-LEAP includes firm characteristics such as employment size, NAICS code, province,

Census Metropolitan Area/Census Agglomeration (CMA/CA), the first year a firm has appeared

in the records, gross profits, sales, tangible assets, and revenues. The purpose of the parametric

model (the discrete-time hazard duration model) of firm failure is to be used for firm

microsimulation. Therefore, basic firm information is only included in the models (TABLE 6.1).

Other explanatory variables (e.g. firm age, and number of competitors within CMA/CA with the

3-digit NAICS code) are also investigated. The database is also linked to data extracted from

Statistics Canada’s socioeconomic database, (Statistics Canada, 2015b) that includes annual

GDP growth by industry and province for the study period (2001-2012). Entry and exit rates by

2-digit NAICS code are also calculated and included in the analysis. TABLE 6.1 represents all

variables that are considered in the parametric model of firm failure along with the expected

effect of each variable. A positive sign indicates that an increase in the value of the variable

increases the likelihood of failure, and a negative sign indicates the opposite.

Page 159: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

140

TABLE 6.1 Description of Explanatory Variables used in Firm Failure Hazard Duration Model

Variable Description Expected

coef. sign

Firm specific variables

Number of employees

(log)

The natural logarithm of the number of employees in

year (t) Negative

Age of firm

The age of the firm, deduced by subtracting the

current year (t) from the first year the firm has

appeared in the records.

Positive

(Age of firm)2 The square value of the firm age Negative

Employment decrease

A dummy variable indicating whether the firm has

decreased their number of employees in year (t)

compared to its size in year 2001 (the beginning of the

analysis period)

Positive

Employment increase

A dummy variable indicating whether the firm has

increased their number of employees in year (t)

compared to its size in year 2001 (the beginning of the

analysis period)

Negative

Competitors The natural logarithm of competitors in the same

CMA/CA with the same 2-digit NAICS industry Positive

Economic indicators

GDP growth Percent change in GDP by province and industry (2-

digit NAICS) Negative

Unemployment rate Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) Positive

Entry rate by industry Yearly firm entry rate for each industry (2-digit

NAICS level) (%) Positive

Exit rate by industry Yearly firm exit rate for each industry (2-digit NAICS

level) (%) positive

Location specific variables

Ontario 1 if the firm is located in Ontario; 0 otherwise

Quebec 1 if the firm is located in Quebec; 0 otherwise

Alberta 1 if the firm is located in Alberta; 0 otherwise

British Columbia 1 if the firm is located in British Columbia; 0

otherwise

Manitoba 1 if the firm is located in Manitoba; 0 otherwise

Saskatchewan 1 if the firm is located in Saskatchewan; 0 otherwise

Atlantic Canada

1 if the firm is located in Newfoundland and Labrador, New

Brunswick, Prince Edward Island, or Nova Scotia; 0 otherwise

Canadian Territories 1 if firm is located in Yukon, Nunavut, or Northwest Territories; 0

otherwise

Page 160: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

141

TABLE 6.1 (Continued)

Industry specific variables

Agriculture, Forestry,

Fishing and Hunting

1 if the firm belongs to the Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and

Hunting industry; 0 otherwise

Mining, Quarrying, and

Oil and Gas Extraction

1 if the firm belongs to the Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas

Extraction industry; 0 otherwise

Utilities 1 if the firm belongs to the Utilities industry; 0 otherwise

Construction 1 if the firm belongs to the Construction industry; 0 otherwise

Manufacturing 1 if the firm belongs to the Manufacturing industry; 0 otherwise

Wholesale trade 1 if the firm belongs to the Wholesale trade industry; 0 otherwise

Retail trade 1 if the firm belongs to the Retail trade industry; 0 otherwise

Transportation and

warehousing

1 if the firm belongs to the Transportation and warehousing

industry; 0 otherwise

Information and cultural

industries

1 if the firm belongs to the Information and cultural industries; 0

otherwise

Finance and insurance 1 if the firm belongs to the Finance and insurance industry; 0

otherwise

Real estate and rental and

leasing

1 if the firm belongs to the Real estate and rental and leasing

industry; 0 otherwise

Professional, scientific

and technical services

1 if the firm belongs to the Professional, scientific and technical

services industry; 0 otherwise

Management of

companies and enterprises

1 if the firm belongs to the Management of companies and

enterprises industry; 0 otherwise

Administrative and

support, waste

management and

remediation services

1 if the firm belongs to the Administrative and support, waste

management and remediation services industry; 0 otherwise

Arts, entertainment and

recreation

1 if the firm belongs to the Arts, entertainment and recreation

industry; 0 otherwise

Accommodation and food

services

1 if the firm belongs to the Accommodation and food services

industry; 0 otherwise

Other services (except

public administration)

1 if the firm belongs to the Other services (except public

administration) industry; 0 otherwise

6.4. Data Analysis and Trends

6.4.1. Data analysis

Preliminary data analysis for exit firms are conducted to gain better understanding of the firm

exit behaviour. First, firm failure rates by industry and by province are investigated. FIGURE 6.1

shows the average exit rates of firms by industry of the period of (2001-2012). It shows that

‘Accommodation and food services’ and ‘Information and cultural ‘industries have the highest

Page 161: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

142

firm exit rates of ~ 6.5% to 7%. Manufacturing ranks as the 5th highest with a failure rate of ~

5.7%. It is important to highlight that our rates in this study are different from the rates published

by Statistics Canada in (Statistics Canada, 2016a) because the dataset is only for incorporated

firms while their published statistics are for both incorporated and unincorporated firms.

FIGURE 6.1 Average Firm Exit Rates by Industry Class (From 2001 to 2012)

FIGURE 6.2 shows that, on average, Northern Territories have the highest firm exit rates

with a value of 22.6% while Ontario and Quebec have the lowest rates of values of 12.6% and

10.8%, respectively (Statistics Canada, 2016a). For their economic importance, manufacturers

are selected as the reference industry in our analysis to compare the exit propensities of other

industries to it. FIGURE 6.3 focuses on average firm exit rates of manufactures in provinces

across Canada. It is seen that Ontario and Quebec still rank as the two provinces with the lowest

exit rates with a value of ~8.8% (Statistics Canada, 2016a).

0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 7.0 8.0

Accommodation and food services

Information and cultural industries

Retail trade

Wholesale trade

Manufacturing

Mining, quarrying, and oil and gas extraction

Transportation and warehousing

Administrative and support, waste…

Arts, entertainment and recreation

Professional, scientific and technical services

Construction

Finance and insurance

Other services (except public administration)

Real estate and rental and leasing

Agriculture, forestry, fishing and hunting

Firm Exit Rate (%)

Page 162: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

143

FIGURE 6.2 Average Firm Exit Rates by Province (2001 to 2012)

FIGURE 6.3 Average Firm Exit Rates of Manufacturers by Province

As highlighted in the literature review, firm survival is affected by firm age. The data

indicate that around 20% of firm population exit at the age of 3 years or less, 30% fail at the age

of 5 years or less, 50% fail at the age of 9 years or less, and 75% of firm population fail at the

age of 16 years or less (FIGURE 6.4). Also, the average firm size at failure is 6 employees. Our

0.0

5.0

10.0

15.0

20.0

25.0

Exit

Rat

es (

%)

0.0

5.0

10.0

15.0

20.0

25.0

30.0

35.0

Exit

Rat

es (

%)

Page 163: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

144

finding agrees with other similar studies in different countries which report that the median life

time of firms is between five to six years after their establishment (Mata and Portugal, 1994;

Bhattacharjee, 2005; Bartelsman et al., 2005; Lopez-Garcia and Puente, 2006; Schrör, 2009;

Nunes and Sarmento, 2010). FIGURE 6.5 indicates that there is an inverted U-shape relationship

between firm failure and age conforming to similar studies by (He and Yang, 2015; Agarwal et

al., 2004).

FIGURE 6.4 Cumulative Distribution of Firm Age at Exit

0.0%

20.0%

40.0%

60.0%

80.0%

100.0%

120.0%

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

Per

centa

ge

of

Exit

Fir

ms

Firm Age (years)

Page 164: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

145

FIGURE 6.5 Population Distribution of Firm Age at Exit*

Data show that 75% of the firm population exit the market with number of employees of two,

while 50% of firms exit with number of employees of one. The average size at exit is 5.6 with a

standard deviation of 31.9.

6.4.2. Firm entry and exit rates

FIGURE 6.6 shows firm entry and exit rates per year. FIGURE 6.6 shows that, in 2008,

Canada’s firm population witnessed a sudden increase in firm exit rates. This is due to the global

recession (defined as two consecutive quarters of negative economic growth) that was sparked

by the US housing market crisis in 2008. This crisis affected Canada’s economy negatively in

two ways: trade, and credit (OECD, 2008). For trade, approximately three-quarters of Canadian

exports are directed to the United States constituting approximately 25% of the Canadian GDP.

This indicates that any change in the US economy has a large effect on many Canadian exporters

(OECD, 2008). For credit, the recession triggered tighter credit conditions, which created a

challenging financing environment in Canada to finance consumers and businesses (OECD,

2008). As a consequence of this recession, GDP growth and firm entry rates declined in the

following year 2009 (FIGURE 6.6). Also, in 2004, there was a significant increase in the firm

* Percentage of exit firms = No. of exit firms (t)/total no. of firms (t)

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

5.0%

6.0%

7.0%

8.0%

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

Per

centa

ge

of

Exit

Fir

ms

Firm Age (years)

Page 165: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

146

exit rates, and this is related to the decline in the Canadian GDP in 2003. According to (Statistics

Canada, 2004) this economic decline was due to major international events that took place

around the year 2003 such as the SARS outbreak, the mid-August power blackout, the war in

Iraq, and natural disasters such as Hurricane Juan in Nova Scotia. We hypothesize that firm

events of entry and exit along with the growth in the GDP are affecting the exit decision on the

firm micro-level, and hence are included in the firm exit parametric model.

FIGURE 6.6 Firm Entry and Exit Rates, and GDP Growth Rates

Firm entry and exit rates are calculated using the T2-LEAP data set for the years 2001-2012.

The resulting firm entry and exit trends are similar to those produced by (Macdonald, 2014;

Ciobanu and Wang, 2012) with lower values due to some differences in the target population and

the methods used to identify entry and exits. Entry and exit rates in our study are only for-profit

industries (excluding firms belonging to educational, healthcare, and public services), while

those published by Macdonald (2014) and Ciobanu and Wang (2012) are for all industries. Also,

Macdonald (2014) and Ciobanu and Wang (2012) used the three-year observation rule described

in (Baldwin et al., 2013), in which entrants are identified when they are active in year (t) and in

subsequent year (t+1), and are inactive in previous year (t-1). Similarly, firm exit is identified

when the firm is active in year t and year (t-1) and is inactive in (t+1). In our study, the two-year

-4.0%

-3.0%

-2.0%

-1.0%

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

0.00%

1.00%

2.00%

3.00%

4.00%

5.00%

6.00%

7.00%

8.00%

9.00%

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

GD

P G

row

th R

ate

Entr

y a

nd

Exit

Rat

es

YearsFirm entry rates Firm exit rates GDP growth

Page 166: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

147

observation rule is used. Simply, for every panelist in the data (the longitudinal records for an

individual firm), for a given year (t), a new firm is identified when it appears in year (t) and not

in (t-1), while firm exit is marked when a firm appears in year (t) and not in year (t+1). New

firms of the year 2001 are not identified because records for the year 2000 are not available.

Similarly, 2012 exits are not identified because the dataset doesn’t include the 2013 records.

Firm entry and exit rates are then calculated by dividing the total number of entrants/exits by the

total number of firms in each year. Entry and exit rates are also calculated for each industry

based on NAICS 2-digit code and used in firm exit parametric model.

6.5. Survival Analysis

6.5.1. Non-parametric analysis

Survivor and the cumulative hazard rates are calculated to analyze how firm survival is

affected by industry class, province, age, and size independently. Then, our results of firm

survival are compared to other similar Canadian studies. Kaplan and Meier, and Nelson –Aalen

estimators are used to produce survival and cumulative hazard rates because the data is right

censored (i.e. exit event is unknown past year 2012). The non-parametric estimator introduced by

(Kaplan and Meier, 1958) of the survival function (St) described in Equation (6.1) is used.

𝑆(𝑡) = ∏ (1 − 𝑑𝑗

𝑛𝑗)𝑗 | 𝑡𝑗 <𝑡 (6.1)

where nj is the number of firms at risk at time tj, and dj is the number of failures at tj. The

survival function indicates the probability of survival beyond time tj, decreases over time. The

cumulative hazard estimator of Nelson –Aalen is a measure of the risk of failure; the greater the

value, the higher the risk (Cleves, 2008). However, unlike the survival function, cumulative

hazard is not a probability, it is a representation of the risk as follows:

𝑯(𝒕) = ∑𝒅𝒋

𝒏𝒋𝒋 | 𝒕𝒋 <𝒕 (6.2)

Both the survival and hazard functions are related; one can be estimated using the other as

follows:

𝐻(𝑡) = − ln 𝑆(𝑡) (6.3)

Page 167: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

148

Our survival rates (TABLE 6.2) are higher compared to (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b)

(FIGURE 6.7). This could be for several reasons: first their analysis is focused on enterprises

with employment less than 50 employees. Second, not-for-profit industries are excluded from

our database. Third, our study area is the entire Canadian population while their study focuses

only on the City of Hamilton, Ontario. Fourth, the time interval in both studies is different;

(Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b) study the time interval of 1990 to 2002 while our research

studies the interval of 2001 to 2012, however, the rates follow approximately the same trend. On

the other hand, Baldwin et al. (2000) presented a firm survival analysis of new firms in the time

interval of 1984 to 1994. Their survival rates represent the probability that a new firm will live

beyond a certain age. Compared to our analysis (FIGURE 6.7), we can conclude that new firms

have lower survival probabilities compared to the survival of the entire firm population (new and

continuing).

TABLE 6.2 Survival and Cumulative Hazard Rates of 2001 Firm Population

(Period of 2001 to 2012)

Duration (t)

Years

Survival Rate

S(t)

Nelson-Aalen

Cumulative Hazard

1 0.97 0.03

2 0.94 0.06

3 0.88 0.13

4 0.83 0.18

5 0.80 0.22

6 0.76 0.27

7 0.70 0.35

8 0.67 0.39

9 0.64 0.44

10 0.61 0.48

Page 168: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

149

FIGURE 6.7 Canadian Studies of Firm Survival Rates

The survival function is also calculated for firms categorized by firm size (FIGURE 6.8). We

can conclude that larger firms have higher survival rates compared to smaller ones. Survival

functions are also calculated categorized by the provincial location of the firm (TABLE 6.3). For

example, FIGURE 6.9 show that firms located in Ontario have higher survival probability

compared to firms in Quebec and Alberta. However, survival rates for firms in Ontario past the

6th year have lower survival chances compared to firms in Quebec. The figure also shows that

firms in Alberta have higher survival probabilities in the first two years compared to Quebec.

This highlights that firm locations significantly influence firm survival. Survival rates by

industry are also calculated (TABLE 6.4)

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Surv

ival

Rat

e

Time (t) in Years

Survivor Function (2001 to 2012) Maoh and Kanaroglou (2007): 1991- 2002

Baldwin et al. (2000): 1984-1994

Page 169: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

150

FIGURE 6.8 Survival Function by Firm Size

FIGURE 6.9 Survival Function for Selected Provinces.

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Surv

ival

Rat

e

Time in Years (t)

Large: >49 employee Medium 20-49 employee Small: <19 employee

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Surv

ival

Rat

e

Time in Years (t)

Ontario Quebec Alberta

Page 170: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

151

TABLE 6.3 Survival Rate by Province

Time (t) years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Ontario 0.98 0.95 0.90 0.86 0.83 0.77 0.71 0.67 0.64 0.61

Quebec 0.97 0.94 0.83 0.79 0.75 0.72 0.67 0.65 0.62 0.59

Alberta 0.96 0.92 0.87 0.83 0.80 0.77 0.73 0.70 0.66 0.63

British Colombia 0.97 0.94 0.90 0.84 0.79 0.76 0.71 0.68 0.65 0.62

Manitoba 0.97 0.93 0.88 0.85 0.82 0.80 0.75 0.72 0.69 0.66

Saskatchewan 0.97 0.94 0.89 0.85 0.82 0.80 0.76 0.73 0.71 0.68

Atlantic Canada* 0.97 0.94 0.86 0.82 0.79 0.74 0.68 0.64 0.62 0.59

Canadian

territories** 0.98 0.94 0.83 0.65 0.59 0.53 0.46 0.42 0.37 0.33

* New Brunswick, Prince Edward Island, and Nova Scotia

**Yukon, Nunavut, and Northwest Territories

TABLE 6.4 Survival Rates by Industry*

Time (t) years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Agriculture, Forestry,

Fishing and Hunting 0.98 0.97 0.93 0.90 0.88 0.86 0.82 0.80 0.77 0.75

Mining, Quarrying, and

Oil and Gas Extraction 0.96 0.92 0.88 0.83 0.79 0.76 0.72 0.69 0.65 0.62

Construction 0.98 0.95 0.89 0.85 0.81 0.78 0.73 0.70 0.67 0.64

Manufacturing 0.97 0.94 0.87 0.82 0.78 0.73 0.67 0.64 0.61 0.58

Wholesale trade 0.97 0.93 0.86 0.81 0.77 0.73 0.67 0.64 0.61 0.58

Retail trade 0.97 0.94 0.85 0.80 0.76 0.71 0.64 0.60 0.57 0.54

Transportation and

warehousing 0.97 0.94 0.87 0.82 0.79 0.74 0.68 0.65 0.62 0.58

Information and cultural 0.97 0.93 0.86 0.81 0.77 0.72 0.66 0.62 0.59 0.56

Finance and insurance 0.97 0.93 0.89 0.85 0.82 0.79 0.75 0.72 0.69 0.66

Real estate and rental and

leasing 0.98 0.96 0.92 0.89 0.86 0.83 0.78 0.76 0.73 0.70

Professional, scientific

and technical services 0.98 0.95 0.89 0.85 0.81 0.77 0.72 0.68 0.65 0.62

Management of

companies and

enterprises

0.97 0.94 0.90 0.86 0.83 0.79 0.75 0.72 0.69 0.66

Administrative and

support, waste

management and

remediation services

0.97 0.95 0.88 0.84 0.80 0.76 0.70 0.67 0.64 0.61

Arts, entertainment and

recreation 0.98 0.95 0.88 0.84 0.81 0.77 0.72 0.69 0.66 0.63

Accommodation and food

services 0.96 0.92 0.80 0.74 0.69 0.63 0.55 0.52 0.48 0.45

Other services (except

public administration) 0.98 0.95 0.89 0.85 0.82 0.78 0.74 0.71 0.69 0.66

*Survival rates for the utilities industry class are suppressed by Statistics Canada for confidentiality

Page 171: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

152

(a)

(b)

Group 1 (1- 2 years)

Group 2 (3 years)

Group 3 (4-6 years)

Group 4(7-10 years)

Group 5 (11-16 years)

Group 6 (>16)

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Surv

ival

Funct

ion

Time in Years (t)

Survival Function by Age Group

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Surv

ival

Funct

ion

Time in Years (t)

Survival Function by Age Group

Group 1 (1- 2 years) Group 2 (3 years) Group 3 (4-6 years)

Group 4 (7-10 years) Group 5 (11-16 years) Group 6 (>16 years)

Page 172: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

153

(c)

FIGURE 6.10 Survival Function by Age Group

As for firm age, it is noted from FIGURE 6.10-b that firms that are ten years or younger have

the same survival trends; survival rates decrease with the increase in age. For instance, firms that

belong to age group 3 (4-6 years) have lower survival rates compared to firms of age group 2 (2-

3 years). This relationship changes beyond the age of ten years; for instance, firms that belong to

age group 5 (11-16 years) have higher survival rates compared to firms in age group 4 (7-10

years). FIGURE 6.10-c shows that survival rates of firms for a duration of two years or less have

similar patterns while for three years and more have other similar patterns for different age

groups.

6.5.2. Parametric analysis

6.5.2.1. Model structure

In this section, the parametric analysis of the firm failure model is presented. The failure

event occurs in a discrete-time fashion; time is observed in discrete units (years) that take

positive integer values (t = 1, 2, 3….). Therefore, a discrete-time hazard duration model is

estimated, which determines the hazard rate of firm (i) that exits the market at time (t), given it

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1

1 2 3 4 5 6

Surv

ival

Funct

ion

Age Groups

Survival Patterns by Time

1 Year

2 years

3 Years

4 Years

5 Years

6 Years

7 Years

8 Years

9 Years

10 Years

Page 173: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

154

was in operation between 2001 and year Ti=t. Allison (1982) has represented the discrete-time

hazard rate as follows:

𝑷𝒊𝒕 = 𝑷𝒓[𝑻𝒊 = 𝒕 | 𝑻𝒊 ≥ 𝒕, 𝑿𝒊𝒕] (6.4)

where Ti is the discrete random time of the failure event, given it has not occurred before time t,

and Xit is a vector of the observed explanatory variables (that may vary over time) that affect the

failure event. A common formulation for Equation (6.4) is the logistic regression function

presented by (Cox, 1972; Myers et al., 1973) as follows:

𝑃𝑖𝑡 = 1

[1+ 𝑒− (𝛼𝑡+ 𝜷′𝑿𝒊𝒕)] (6.5)

where 𝛼𝑡 is a set of constants, and 𝜷′ is the vector of parameters that quantifies the effect of

the covariates (the explanatory variables) on the failure event. Maximum likelihood estimation

method provides an efficient estimator for the values of 𝛼𝑡 and 𝜷′ . As indicated by (Allison,

1982; Guo, 1993), the log-likelihood function can be presented as follows:

log 𝐿 = ∑ ∑ 𝛿𝑖𝑗𝑡𝑖𝑗=1 log [

𝑃𝑖𝑗

(1−𝑃𝑖𝑗)] + ∑ ∑ log(1 − 𝑃𝑖𝑗)

𝑡𝑖𝑗=1

𝑛𝑖=1

𝑛𝑖=1 (6.6)

where 𝛿𝑖𝑗 =1 if firm i has failed at time j and 0 otherwise. Equation (6.6) represents the log-

likelihood of a logistic regression indicating that discrete-time hazard model can be estimated

using the same routine as the logistic regression model. For this type of setup, and to be able to

estimate equation (6.6), for each panelist (longitudinal firm records) a dependent variable yi = 1 is

coded when the failure event occurs and 0 otherwise. This means that if a firm was present in the

records starting in the year 2001 and has disappeared in 2006, then the variable yi = 0 in the first

5 observations (for the years of 2001 till 2005) and yi =1 in year 2006. However, the data is left

truncated, meaning that the firm population of 2001 includes firms that existed prior to 2001.

This means that some firms have been exposed to risk of failure for some years (r) before it

became under observation for survival analysis. A firm i may have been at risk for r years prior

to 2001 and has failed at time ti corresponding to q years after 2001. This creates q observations

only for firm i in the record set that formulates the log-likelihood function of the hazard model.

A treatment for left truncated data in discrete-time hazard duration models is suggested by

Guo (1993) and Allison (1995) by conditioning the likelihood function in Equation (6.6) on

Page 174: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

155

having survived to tr. By taking the logs, and multiplying over the sample, the conditional log-

likelihood for discrete time models is:

log 𝐿 = ∑ ∑ 𝛿𝑖𝑗𝑡𝑖𝑗=1 log [

𝑃𝑖𝑗

(1−𝑃𝑖𝑗)] + ∑ ∑ log(1 − 𝑃𝑖𝑗)

𝑡𝑖𝑗=𝑟+ 1

𝑛𝑖=1

𝑛𝑖=1 (6.7)

Equation (6.7) can be considered a binominal log-likelihood function as equation (6.6) except

that the second summation in the second term sums from r+1 rather than 1. The hazard rate Pij

for observation i at time j can be linked to the observation covariates (as in Equation (6.4))

through a logistic regression.

6.5.2.2. Model specification and hypotheses

As summarized in TABLE 6.1, firm failure is affected by factors related to the firm, market

competition, economic conditions, location and industry. TABLE 6.1 lists the variables under

investigation in terms of their influence over firm failure, along with their expected effect

(negative or positive). For instance, from the data analysis (FIGURE 6.5) and the non-parametric

analysis (FIGURE 6.10), we hypothesize that firm age has a non-linear relationship with firm

failure (i.e. parabolic function), therefore, both the age and the age2 variables are added in our

model. We also hypothesize that employment size has a negative effect on firm exit. Firm

growth on the other hand is hypothesized to have a negative effect on firm exit decisions;

employment decrease may indicate that a firm is in the failure pattern, whereas employment

increase decisions indicate stability in the market. Hence, three variables that represent

employment size and employment growth are included; a continuous variable for employment

size, and two dummy variables indicating whether employment increased or decreased relative to

2001’s size.

Dummy variables that represent the industry class (based on the 2-digit NAICS code) are

tested, as well as dummy variables for the province where the firm is located. In this way,

location and industry effects on firm exit decisions can be captured. We also hypothesize that

market competition has a negative effect on firm survival; higher competition may lead to higher

probability of firm exit. In our model, competition is defined as the number of competitors (firms

within the same Census Metropolitan Area/Census Agglomeration) that are similar in the

services/products offered by their counterparts (based on the NAICS 3-digit code). Economic

Page 175: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

156

conditions are also hypothesized to have influence on firm survival. Three economic indicators

are included:

1) The GDP growth rate by industry (2-digit NAICS code) and province. This considers

the diversity of firms in different provinces and industries as some provinces may be

leaders in specific industries and are economically developing faster compared to other

provinces and territories. For instance, Alberta ranks first for GDP for the Mining,

Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction industry class, followed by Saskatchewan

(FIGURE 6.11) while Ontario ranks first in Manufacturing industry followed by

Quebec, Alberta, British Columbia, and the rest of Canada (FIGURE 6.12). In the

model of firm failure, the manufacturing industry is chosen as the reference industry

because it significantly contributes to the Canadian GDP according to Statistics Canada

(2015b). Also, Ontario is chosen to be the reference province as it is the province with

the highest economic activity for manufacturing industry (FIGURE 6.12).

FIGURE 6.11 GDP by Province for the Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction

Industry Class (NAICS 2-Digit Code: 21)*

* Source: (Statistics Canada, 2015b)

0

10000

20000

30000

40000

50000

60000

70000

80000

GD

P (

do

llar

s X

1,0

00

,00

0)

2001

2012

Page 176: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

157

FIGURE 6.12 GDP by Province for The Manufacturing Industry Class

(NAICS 2-digit code: 31-33)

2) Yearly unemployment rate by province: unemployment rate is considered a key

economic indicator that reflects the labour market within a country. Some studies that

addressed firm exit have used unemployment rate as an explanatory variable of the exit

decision (e.g. Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b). Unemployment rate aggregated to the

provincial level are used to account for variability amongst provinces in firm failure

behaviour. Unemployment rates are extracted from (Statistics Canada, 2015a) for all

provinces. For example, in the province of Ontario (FIGURE 6.13), there seems to be a

negative relationship between GDP growth and the increase in the unemployment rates

(e.g. check values of year 2009 as a consequence of the 2008 U.S recession as

explained earlier).

0

10000

20000

30000

40000

50000

60000

70000

80000

90000

100000

GD

P (

do

llar

s X

1,0

00

,00

0)

2001

2012

Page 177: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

158

FIGURE 6.13 Unemployment and GDP Growth Rates for the Province of Ontario

3) Yearly entry and exit rates: as explained in section four, firm entries and exits both

affect and are affected by GDP growth. They can be used as economic indicators

reflecting the conditions of the market. Firm entry and exit rates are calculated on the

aggregate level of the 2-digit NAICS code.

6.5.2.3. Model results and interpretations

STATA software is used to estimate the discrete-time hazard duration model for firm failure.

A hold-out sample was extracted as a validation data set before the estimation process. A total of

6,184,894 records for the entire observation period, which are the total number of records for

970,498 firms tracked over 2001-2012, are used to estimate the model. TABLE 6.5 presents the

model coefficient estimates, the odds ratio, and the P-values. All the coefficients are reported at

95% and higher confidence interval. The odds ratio is the ratio of the probability that the event of

interest occurs to the probability that it does not (Bland and Altman, 2000). For example, assume

that the probability of success for a particular event is p = 0.8 and the probability of failure is q =

0.2, then the odds of success = 𝑝/𝑞 = 0.8/0.2 = 4. This means that the odds of success are four

to one. In logistic regression, the logit is defined as the log base e (log) of the odds meaning:

𝐿𝑜𝑔𝑖𝑡 (𝑝) = 𝑎 + 𝑏𝑋 or log (𝑝

𝑞) = 𝑎 + 𝑏𝑋 (6.8)

This means that the coefficients in the logistic regression are represented in terms of the log of

the odds. So, a one-unit change in a specific explanatory variable xi results in a bi change in the

log of the odds (UCLA, 2007). Equation (6.8) can be written as follows:

-4.0%

-3.0%

-2.0%

-1.0%

0.0%

1.0%

2.0%

3.0%

4.0%

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

GD

P G

row

th

Unem

plo

ym

ent

Rat

e

Unemployment rate GDP growth

Page 178: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

159

𝑒(log

𝑝

𝑞)

= 𝑒(𝑎+𝑏𝑋) or 𝑝

𝑞= 𝑒(𝑎+𝑏𝑥) (6.9)

The odds ratio is simply calculated by exponentiation of the coefficient; Odds Ratio (OR) = 𝑒𝑏.

TABLE 6.5 Firm Failure Model: Estimation Results

Variables Coef. Odds ratio P>|z|

_cons -4.385 0.012 0.000

Firm

characteristics

# of employees (log) -1.211 0.298 0.000

Firm age 0.103 1.109 0.000

Firm age ^ 2 -0.003 0.997 0.000

Employment decrease 0.378 1.459 0.000

Employment increase -0.261 0.770 0.000

Province

Ontario Reference province

Quebec 0.144 1.155 0.000

Alberta 0.105 1.111 0.000

British Colombia 0.118 1.126 0.000

Manitoba 0.205 1.228 0.000

Saskatchewan 0.131 1.140 0.000

Atlantic Canada* 0.256 1.292 0.000

Canadian territories** 0.487 1.627 0.006

Industry Class:

2-Digit NAICS

Code

11 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting -0.504 0.604 0.000

21 Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction -0.619 0.538 0.000

22 Utilities -0.131 0.877 0.014

23 Construction -0.470 0.625 0.000

31-33 Manufacturing Reference industry

41 Wholesale trade -0.241 0.786 0.000

44-45 Retail trade -0.194 0.824 0.000

48-49 Transportation and warehousing -0.336 0.714 0.000

51 Information and cultural industries -0.681 0.506 0.000

52 Finance and insurance -0.541 0.582 0.000

53 Real estate and rental and leasing -0.693 0.500 0.000

54 Professional, scientific and technical services -0.736 0.479 0.000

55 Management of companies and enterprises -0.822 0.440 0.000

56 Administrative and support, waste management

and remediation services -0.427 0.652 0.000

71 Arts, entertainment and recreation -0.362 0.696 0.000

72 Accommodation and food services -0.256 0.774 0.000

81 Other services (except public administration) -0.237 0.789 0.000

*Newfoundland and Labrador, New Brunswick, Prince Edward Island, and Nova Scotia

** Yukon, Nunavut, and Northwest Territories

Page 179: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

160

TABLE 6.5 Firm Failure Model: Estimation Results (Continued)

Competition # of competitors in the same CMA/CA of the

same NAICS-3 (log) 0.058 1.059 0.000

Economic

indicators

% GDP growth by province and Industry

(NAICS2) -0.002 0.998 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) 0.022 1.022 0.000

Yearly firm entry rate by industry class (NAICS2)

(%) 0.081 1.084 0.000

Yearly firm exit rate by industry class (NAICS2)

(%) 0.162 1.176 0.000

The model estimates (TABLE 6.5) confirm our previously stated hypotheses regarding the

effect of the explanatory variables on the firm exit (the determinants of failure). Looking at the

signs of the coefficients, when all other variables are held constant, the number of employees has

a negative impact on firm exit; i.e. larger firms are less likely to fail. The odds ratio implies that

an increase in one unit in the log value of the number of employee reduces the likelihood of

failure by 30%. This result conforms to other studies for Canadian firms conducted by (Maoh

and Kanaroglou,2007b; Baldwin et al., 2000). This also confirms the non-parametric analysis

(FIGURE 6.8) that larger firms have better survival chances. Furthermore, employment growth

(increase or decrease) is found to have a statistically significant effect on firm failure, agreeing

with what (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b) have found in their study. If a firm has increased its

employment size compared to its original size in the base year (2001), it is ~77% less likely to

fail. Firms that shrink in size are approximately 46% more likely to fail.

As expected, and as indicated by the non-parametric analysis (FIGURE 6.10-b and FIGURE

6.10-c), firm age is found to have a non-linear relationship with firm exit. When all other

variables are held constant, exit propensity increases with firm age (explained by the positive

sign of the age covariate), until a limit β1/2β2, and then the exit propensity decreases with firm

age (the negative sign of the age2 covariate), where β1 and β2 are the estimated parameters of the

age and age2 covariates. This means that, older firms have better survival probabilities. Our

results confirm those found by (Baldwin et al., 2000) and are in line with the hypothesis of

“liability of newness” introduced by (van Wissen, 2000).

Firm failure behaviour varies depending on the firm location. As demonstrated in the non-

parametric analysis, firms located in different provinces have different survival behaviour

(FIGURE 6.9). The parametric model confirms that all provinces compared to Ontario have

Page 180: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

161

higher risk of failure. This finding complies with the results of (Baldwin et al., 2000). In our

model, for example, compared to Ontario and when all other variables are held constant, firms

located in Alberta are 10% more likely to fail whereas firms located in Quebec have a 14%

greater chance of failure than firms in Ontario. This finding conforms to the results highlighted

in the non-parametric analysis as well (FIGURE 6.9). Generally, exit chances are 11% to 29%

higher for firms located outside of Ontario (except for firms located in Yukon, Nunavut, and

Northwest Territories) compared to firms in Ontario. FIGURE 6.14 ranks the odds of failure for

each province compared to Ontario.

FIGURE 6.14 Ratio of The Odds of Failure for Firms Located in Canadian Provinces with

Ontario being the Reference Province

Our original hypothesis is that failure varies across industries. A group of dummy variables

that indicates the industry class of the firm is included. The results show variability in failure

propensities of firms in different industries illustrated by the odds ratio in FIGURE 6.15. The

manufacturing industry is the reference industry. Compared to manufacturers in Ontario, when

other variables are held constant, all other industries have better survival chances. Firms that

belong to ‘Management of companies and enterprises’ industry class ranks first in firms with

better survival chances. They have an approximately 44% lower chances of failure compared to

manufacturers. Firms that belong to the ‘utilities’ sector are around 88% less likely to fail

compared to manufacturers. This is expected as the data show that Ontario has the highest failure

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8

Other provinces**

Atlantic Canada*

Manitoba

Quebec

Saskatchewan

British Colombia

Alberta

Odds ratio

Page 181: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

162

shares of manufacturers compared to other provinces and territories (see FIGURE 6.2 and

FIGURE 6.3).

FIGURE 6.15 Ratio of the Odds for Different Industries with Manufacturers being the Base

Industry

Competition on the other hand is found to have a negative impact on firm survival. Higher

number of competitors increases the likelihood of failure. An increase of one unit in the log

value of the number of competitors, categorized in the same industry class (to the level of the 3-

digit NAICS code) and located in the same CMA/CA, increases the likelihood of failure by

approximately 6%. Two effects must be distinguished; the effect of the agglomeration

economies, and the effect of competition. These effects are ‘two sides of the same coin’.

Agglomeration economies, in simple terms, are the benefits firms gain when locating near other

competing firms with similar activities. Such benefits are attained through sharing the same

resources (e.g. goods, labor, technologies, and transportation infrastructure) (Ellison et al., 2010).

Agglomeration economies are similar in concept to economies of scale; when firms with similar

activities cluster together in the same area, their cost of production may decline (Glaeser, 2010).

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%

Utilities

Retail trade

Other services (except public administration)

Wholesale trade

Accommodation and food services

Transportation and warehousing

Arts, entertainment and recreation

Administrative and support, waste management and…

Construction

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting

Finance and insurance

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction

Information and cultural industries

Real estate and rental and leasing

Professional, scientific and technical services

Management of companies and enterprises

Odds ratio (%)

Page 182: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

163

A recent example of such agglomeration is the case of Silicon Valley in California, where

several computer-technology related companies have clustered in one area for the purpose of

sharing the same infrastructure and resources. Such clustering has resulted in the concentration

of highly skilled labour in the field of computer-technology in one area, giving new start-ups in

the same area better access to skilled labour (Fallick et al., 2006). This in return gives start-ups

higher chances of survival and growth in addition to benefiting from using the existing

technologically-advanced infrastructure for communication and data sharing, and hence costs are

significantly reduced. Competition on the other hand, is when firms with similar activities locate

near to competitors, and the result of this geographic nearness leads to greater price competition

and results in lower profits (Pasidis, 2013). In other words, when businesses that offer highly

similar (homogenous) products/services (e.g. gas stations) are located near each other, they

compete mainly on the product price, and the benefits of the agglomeration are diminished.

Whereas, businesses that offer similar products with some distinctions (i.e. less homogeneous

such as clothing shops) locate near each other, benefits of agglomeration are stronger because

price competition is less important (Pasidis, 2013). Our findings suggest that benefits of

agglomeration economies are diminished, and competition dominates, indicated by the positive

sign of the coefficient of the number of competitors within the CMA/CA and NAICS 3-digit

code. Our finding is in agreement with the ones stated by (Strotmann, 2007).

The economic conditions of the region where the firm is located is expected to influence firm

survival. Three main economic indicators are used; one that reflects the economic growth of the

region by industry (GDP growth rate by industry and province), one reflects the economic

conditions with respect to labour within the firm’s region (provincial unemployment rate), and

the third reflects the dynamics within the industries (entry and exit rates by industry). As

elaborated earlier; there is a strong association between the overall GDP growth and firm entry

and exit rates and (FIGURE 6.6), the GDP growth and unemployment (FIGURE 6.13). The model

results confirm that there are statistically significant relationships between the used economic

indicators and the firm failure probabilities. The sign of the coefficient covariate confirms our

original hypothesis that GDP growth has a positive impact on survival. The results show that an

increase of 1% in the GDP reduces the likelihood of failure by 99.77% when the rest of the

variables are held constant. Yearly provincial unemployment rates, on the other hand, are found

to have a positive impact on failure. An increase of 1% in unemployment rate per province

Page 183: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

164

increases the chances of failure by 2%, when everything else is held constant. Industries with

higher entry and exit rates have higher failure chances. Higher entry rates increase competition,

which may result in higher exit rates. Higher exit rates may reflect two things; they may be the

result of higher entry rates, or a reflection of the status of the economic growth. Our results show

that exit rates have a higher impact on firm exit; and increase in 1% of exit rate by industry

increases the odds of failure by 17.6%, whereas the increase of 1% in entry rate by industry

increases the likelihood of failure by 8.4% only.

GDP growth rates, unemployment rates, and firm entry and exit need to be forecast. In a

microsimulation environment, there would be modules or scenarios that forecast such economic

indicators. Yearly GDP by province and industry are publicly available online on Statistics

Canada’s CANSIM tables (Statistics Canada, 2015b). Also, entry and exit rates are available

(from this study) and in other statistics published by Statistics Canada (Statistics Canada, 2016a).

Trends and simple linear regression models are famous methods for forecasting using historical

data and are candidates for such forecasting models.

6.5.2.4. Model Validation

Model validation is an essential step that comes after model estimation to assess the

performance of the estimated model. A discussion about model goodness-of-fit is provided in

chapter 4, section 4.5.3. Cross-validation is used to validate the predictive performance of firm

failure model on the aggregate level. For this purpose, a hold-out sample (a validation set) of

20% of the firm population of investigation (1,570,339 records) was extracted, which was not

used in the estimation process. According to (McFadden, 1978), the predicted total probabilities

(for each observation in the validation dataset) are calculated first and then divided by the

validation sample size to calculate the predicted shares of the binary outcome (firm failure). This

number is compared to the actual observed shares of the failure event in the sample (the number

of failure firms divided by the total number of firms). The validation and goodness-of-fit

summary are presented in (TABLE 6.6), showing an accepted overall performance of the model.

The reported pseudo R2 statistics indicates a good fit of the model as suggested in (McFadden,

1978). Another measure of assessing the overall model significance is a chi-squared test for

testing the null hypothesis that the model coefficients are not statistically different from zero. A

discussion about chi2 is provided in chapter 4, section 4.5.3. Prob > chi2 in TABLE 6.6 when

compared to a critical value (e.g. 0.05 or 0.01 significance level) indicates that the null

Page 184: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

165

hypothesis cannot be true and the model is statically significant at a 99% and higher confidence

(i.e. all the model coefficients are statistically different from zero) (Greene, 2012).

TABLE 6.6 Model Validation and Goodness-of-Fit

Total number of observations

(Estimation sample size) 6,184,894

Log likelihood (Null model) -1182090

Log likelihood (Full model) -1018971

Pseudo R2 (rho-square) 0.138

Adjusted R2 0.138

LR of chi2(33)* 326238

Prob > chi2 (p-value) 0.00

Observed total probabilities 4.8%

Predicted total probabilities 4.7%

% Difference (Predicted - observed) -0.1%

The cross-validation results indicate that the model slightly under predicts the total failure

probabilities by 0.1%. This value is very small and indicates a very good predictive performance.

6.6. General Notes

The selection of a pooled regression model for the parametric analysis came after trials of

other model structures. First, a panel logistic regression that considers random effects is tested.

In simple terms, the model accounts for the variation that could results from one panelist to the

other by estimating a random effect term.

Pr(𝑦𝑖𝑡 ≠ 0|𝑥𝑖𝑡) = 𝑃 (𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 + 𝜈𝑖) (6.10)

for i = 1…, n panelists, where t = 1…., ni, νi are i.i.d. with N(0,σ2ν), and the variance

component model states that:

𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 + 𝜈𝑖 + 휀𝑖𝑡 > 0 (6.11)

where 휀𝑖𝑡 are i.id. logistic distributed with mean zero and variance σ2ε and is independent

from 𝜈𝑖. Another term that is estimated to indicate whether the panel regression is significant or

not is the proportion of the total variance contributed by the panel-level variance (𝜌) as:

* Likelihood ratio (LR) chi-square test= -2 x (log(LNull) – log(Lfull))

Page 185: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

166

𝜌 = 𝜎𝜐

2

𝜎𝜐2+ 𝜎𝜀

2 (6.12)

When the value of 𝜌 is zero, the panel-level variance component is neglected and the panel

logistic model is not statistically different from the pooled model (StataCorp, 2013). In our case,

the model estimates suggest that the null hypothesis of 𝜌 being statistically different from zero

cannot be rejected, i.e. a panel logistic regression is not statistically different from a pooled

logistic regression.

A multilevel model structure is also tested to check if the variance between firm clusters (the

panelist level) is statistically significant or not. The result suggests that the multilevel model is

not statistically different from a pooled logistic model as the variance calculated on the cluster

level (the firm level) is not statistically different from zero. For a quick hands-on on the

multilevel logistic regression models visit melogit chapter in (StataCorp, 2013).

Due to Statistics Canada’s requirements for privacy protection, the results of the indicated

models are not available for publication, and only results of the pooled regression model is

approved for publication.

In the parametric analysis of firm failure, and in order to understand the effect of firm size on

failure events, the number of employees was first discretized into different intervals and

statistically evaluated in the logit regression. It was found that the larger the number of

employees, the less likely a firm to fail. In other words, it has a monotonically decreasing

relationship that can be described by a log function (which is the current used format in the

parametric model for the number of employees). However, in the non-parametric analysis, the

relationship is not the same. In FIGURE 6.8, the curves indicate that very small firms have lower

survival probabilities compared to larger ones. The probability of survival is increased with the

increase in the number of employees to a certain threshold (the medium size class), and then

starts to decrease when the size in the large range. This is because the way the survival function

is calculated does not account for the variability in size for the same firm throughout the years.

Firm change in size by time (shrink or grow); small ones become medium, medium become

large, and so on. Falsely, the survival function, Equation (6.1), considers a firm that changes its

size class to have disappeared from the population, and is marked as a failure, which is not the

case, it has changed in size. Therefore, the results of the non-parametric analysis cannot be fully

Page 186: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

167

considered when it comes to employment size to understand the effect of firm size on failure

events, and the results of the parametric model is more trusted in this sense.

6.7. Concluding Remarks

The study of firm demography is essential in regional planning. Firm exit results in changes

in labour dynamics, which may result in labour migration across regions, resulting in major

demographic changes within regions. Such behaviour is important to understand and models that

identify drivers to firm failure are needed. Models of firm failure in Canada are limited; the

models found in the literature are either limited to small geographic regions (Maoh and

Kanaroglou, 2007b) or only addresses survival of new firms (Baldwin et al., 2000), leaving room

for further research to cover firm survival in Canada.

Our study explores the patterns of failure for firms in Canada during the period of 2001-

2012. Both parametric and non-parametric analyses indicate that firm employment size, age,

industry classification, and location are influencing firm failure patterns. Our analysis finds that

larger and older firms have a better survival chances compared to smaller younger firms. Market

competition is found to have a negative effect on firm survival; the higher the number of

competitors is, the higher the risk of failure. Economic indicators are also statistically tested in

the discrete-time hazard model. We conclude that a growing economy increases the likelihood of

firm survival. This is indicated by the negative effect of the GDP growth on firm exit decisions,

and the positive effects of provincial unemployment rates, and firm entry and exit rates on firm

exit decisions. These findings at large show that a thriving economy with stable industry

dynamics reduces the likelihood of firm exits.

Several opportunities exist for future research. In our study, economic growth is treated as

an external driver to firm exit, while in fact the relationship between firm demography and the

economy is two-way. A growing economy increases investment potential which is expected to

reduce firm failure and encourage new business. On the other hand, an increase in the number of

firm exits would result in a decline in the economic growth of a region and an increase in the

unemployment rate, and eventually affects the GDP. Modelling such two-way relationships is

challenging, and is left for future research.

Other determinants of failure, for example those related to firm market strategies, have not

yet been explored due to data unavailability. Since it is challenging to contact representatives of

Page 187: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

168

firms that have already exited the market, a possible technique is stated preference surveys of

firm failure, in which decision makers of firms are interviewed about the main reasons and

conditions that would lead to firm exit.

Our study contributes to the firm demography literature in the Canadian context and is

potentially beneficial to research fields such as regional development, transportation and land

planning. Our conclusions fall in-line with other studies indicating that firm failure patterns are

similar in regions with similar externalities. This research has potential to be incorporated as one

component within a microsimulation model of the urban spatial economy that can be used for

regional development analysis and forecasting.

Page 188: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

169

CHAPTER 7

Discrete Choice Models of Freight Outsourcing Decisions of

Canadian Manufacturers

7.1. Introduction and Related Literature

One of many decisions firms make, which directly impacts freight systems and the economy,

is outsourcing of freight related activities (such as logistics, and intermediate goods production).

Firms can either choose to perform all of their activities in-house, own subsidiaries to perform

activities, or outsource part/all of their activities to other firms (Abdur Razzaque and Chen

Shang, 1998; Deepen, 2007). Outsourcing is defined as the procurement of products/services

from other sources that are external to the firm (Foster and Muller, 1990). Generally, firms

choose to outsource non-core activities to minimize cost and maximize profits, as outsourcing

reduces capital investments in facilities, equipment, information technology, and workforce

(Fantasia, 1993; Lankford and Parsa, 1999; Montemayor, 2014; Quinn and Hilmer, 1994; Rao

and Young, 1994; Richardson, 1992; Sheffi, 1990). Freight outsourcing allows firms to focus on

the core activities that help them gain competitive advantage, to improve customer deliveries,

and expand in new markets (Lankford and Parsa, 1999; Quinn and Hilmer, 1994; Gonzalez et al.,

2009). However, there are some trade-offs associated with outsourcing related to quality

assurance, protection of shared proprietary data (e.g. product designs), and loss of control (e.g.

supply chain control) (Rao and Young, 1994).

Outsourcing of freight logistics (including transportation, distribution, warehousing,

inventory management, and material handling), and intermediate goods production have strategic

importance. They affect the labour market (Senses, 2004), transportation network efficiency

(Abdur Razzaque and Chen Shang, 1998), and growth of economy (Richardson, 1993).

Globalization has allowed firms to choose to outsource intermediate goods production

internationally to low-cost subcontractors (Lommerud et al., 2003; Lommerud et al., 2009).

International outsourcing may have economic disadvantages for the local labour market. As a

consequence of globalization, there has been concern that labour demand is shifting from

economies with high labour costs to economies with lower costs, which affects job stability and

Page 189: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

170

increases unemployment of low-skilled workers in economies with high labour costs (Bachmann

and Braun, 2011). Other researchers suggest that international outsourcing has a positive impact

on organizational performance by allowing a focus on core activities, increasing productivity,

which in return increases the demand for local employment (Alexandrova, 2009; Amiti and Wei,

2006; Egger and Egger, 2006; Görg and Strobl). Given the economic importance of outsourcing

type (local vs. international), it is important to explore the underlying factors related to

outsourcing of goods production and logistics, and whether activities are outsourced

internationally or locally.

Freight outsourcing decisions are mainly driven by whether freight operations are within the

firm’s core competency, liability and control, operating costs, information and communication

systems, and market relationships (Rao and Young, 1994). Freight outsourcing is also affected

by other factors related to the firm (e.g. strategic focus, size, production size, and shipment

frequency), the industry (e.g. the nature of the supply chain, the average size of the industry, and

market competition), the economic conditions, location characteristics (e.g. access to resources,

and proximities to highways), and advances in innovation and technology (Abdur Razzaque and

Chen Shang, 1998; Bienstock and Mentzer, 1999; Rao and Young, 1994). Also, outsourcing of

freight operations, and supplier selection decisions might be intertwined. Supplier selection

decisions depend on the transportation cost and the proper mode of transport (Pourabdollahi et

al., 2016). One form of outsourcing can be seen in the shipper’s choice of whether to outsource

logistics activities to other transportation providers or to explicitly choose the desired mode of

transport (Fridstrom and Madslien, 1994; Fries and Patterson, 2008). Fries and Patterson (2008)

provide a distinction between two types of shippers and their preference to outsourcing. They

highlight that “private” shippers prefer to transport their shipments using their own fleet.

Whereas “end-shippers” prefer to completely outsource their freight activities (Fries and

Patterson, 2008).

Our study focuses on Canadian manufacturers, which account for a large percentage of the

Canadian Gross Domestic Product (GDP) (Snoddon et al., 2014). The manufacturing sector

involves large outsourcing operations both locally and internationally (Baldwin and Gu, 2009).

For its economic importance, it is valuable to understand how firm characteristics and economic

conditions influence outsourcing decisions. In this chapter, discrete choice models of freight

outsourcing for Canadian manufacturers are introduced. In addition to building understanding of

Page 190: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

171

influencing factors contributing to outsourcing, the models are also intended to be integrated

within an agent-based firm microsimulation platform that simulates individual firm decisions and

evolution, and explicitly model interactions between firms (Mostafa and Roorda, 2015). No

previous attempts were found in the literature that introduce discrete choice models to quantify

effects of firm characteristics and the economic environment on freight outsourcing decisions of

manufacturers in a Canadian context. The models consider factors with potential influence over

freight outsourcing such as firm characteristics and strategic focus, market competition, GDP

growth, and international relations. Also, models that examine the outsourcing type (international

vs. local) are introduced. The chapter starts by describing the data and modelling methodology,

and follows with model results and interpretations and model validation.

7.2. Data Description

Two cross-section data sets of the Survey of Innovation and Business Strategy (SIBS),

collected by Statistics Canada, are used. The survey is launched every three years and collects

data for a three-year interval; the 2009 survey covers the period of 2007-2009 and the 2012

survey covers the period of 2010-2012. The surveys were conducted on a sample of enterprises

that have at least 20 employees and annual revenue of at least $250,000. The sample was

stratified according to 14 industry sectors using the North American Industry Classification

System (NAICS). The two data sets include information about 6,233 and 4,559 enterprises in

different industries across Canada for the 2009 and 2012 surveys, respectively (Statistics Canada,

2012b). Approximately 8,000 of these enterprises are manufacturers. The survey collected

information about long-term strategies, outsourcing of business activities, international activities

and relationship with main suppliers, competition, use of advanced technology and innovation,

and use of government support programs for innovation related activities. TABLE 7.1

summarizes all the variables that are considered in this study along with a brief description of

each. All the listed variables have been statistically evaluated in the model estimation, and only

the statistically significant variables are included in the final models discussed in this chapter.

The data are combined with data from Statistics Canada’s socioeconomic database, CANSIM

(Statistics Canada, 2015a), that includes GDP growth for the years investigated in the survey.

Page 191: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

172

TABLE 7.1 Summary of Investigated Explanatory Variables

Variable Description

Number of employees

Three dummy variables indicating the firm size: 1) small, number of employees <100

2) medium, number of employees between 100 and 250

3) large, number of employees >250

Other firm characteristics

Employees with university degrees (%) Percentage of employees with a university degree

The head office location in Canada A dummy indicating that the head office location is in Canada

More than one profit center A dummy indicating that a firm has more than one profit center

Other subsidiaries in Canada A dummy indicating that a firm has other subsidiary locations in Canada

Provincial location variables A set of 5 dummy variables indicating the firm's provincial location (Ontario, Quebec,

Alberta, British Columbia, and the rest of Canada)

Industry classification (NAICS 3-Digit code) A group of 19 dummy variables representing the sub-industry classification of the

manufacturing industry based on the 3-digit NAICS code (e.g. Food manufacturing (311))

Number of products and services The natural logarithm of number of offered products and services

Long-term strategy: Mass market A dummy variable indicating that a firm's long-term strategic focus is on offering

products/services with low-price and cost leadership

Long-term strategy: Goods or services positioning A dummy variable indicating that a firm's long-term strategic focus is on product

leadership, market segmentation, or product diversification

Age of long-term strategy A variable indicating how long the long-term strategy has been implemented within a firm

Long-term strategy’s performance indicators

Gross/margin operating cost

A set of dummy variables representing 7 different performance indicators a firm may select

to evaluate the performance of the selected long-term strategy

Sales/income growth

Shareholder dividends growth

Market/customer share growth

Customer satisfaction

Sales of new products

Delivery times

Strategic focus

New goods/ services A set of dummy variables for four main strategic foci of a firm. A value of 1 indicates that

a firm is seeking to introduce new or significantly improved

practices/service/goods/activities. A value of 0 indicates that a firm is more focused on

maintaining or expanding the chosen strategic focus

Marketing practices/methods

operations and business activities

Organizational and management practices

Economic indicator: GDP growth on naics-3 level Percent growth of the GDP by sub-industry class

Page 192: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

173

TABLE 7.1 (Continued)

Operational strategies

Outsource of goods production Indicates a firm outsources their goods production (locally or internationally)

Outsource of logistics Indicates a firm outsources their logistics activities (locally or internationally)

Outsource of goods production (internationally) Indicates a firm outsources their intermediate goods production internationally

Outsource logistics (internationally) Indicates a firm outsources their logistics activities internationally

Opened a new/expand production facility Indicates a firm opened a new production facility or expanded in capacity

Expand production facility by M&A Indicates a firm obtained production capacity by merger and acquisition

Close or contract capacity of production facilities Indicates a firm has closed/contracted the capacity of existing production facilities

Opened new/expanded logistics facilities Indicates a firm has opened a new or expanded the capacity of logistics facilities

Expand logistics by M&A Indicates a firm has obtained logistics capacity by merger or acquisition

Closed/contract capacity of logistics facilities Indicates a firm has closed/contracted the capacity of existing logistics facilities

Use of innovation and advanced technologies

Use of advanced communication technology

A group of dummy variables indicating which type of innovation/advanced technology a

firm may have utilized

Use of advanced automated material handling

Use of process innovation in logistics

Process innovation in new manufacturing methods

Use of Product innovation

Government tax credit programs A group of dummy variables indicating that a firm has utilized different government

support programs for innovation. The government programs can either be federal,

provincial, or municipal.

Government training programs

Government grants

International activities and involvements

Direct exports Indicates that a firm has direct exports outside of Canada

International subsidiaries Indicates that a firm has subsidiaries outside of Canada

International activities Indicates that a firm has activities outside of Canada

International suppliers Indicates that a firm has suppliers outside of Canada

Canada being the main market Indicates that Canada is a firm’s main market

Competition from multinational firms Indicates that a firm has competition from other multinational firms

Competition and market share

Number of competitors <3

A group of three dummy variables indicating the number of competitors for each firm Number of competitors 3-10

Number of competitors >10

Market share of highest selling goods/services in the

main market (%)

A continuous variable representing the percentage of the market share of the highest selling

goods or services a firm is offering in the main market

Page 193: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

174

7.3. Methodology and Model Structure

We hypothesize that there is correlation between outsourcing of goods production and

outsourcing of logistics and distribution decisions. Therefore, both decisions are considered in a

common modelling framework to capture their interrelation. Outsourcing of goods production,

and outsourcing of logistics and distribution can be formulated as a two independent binary

decisions, while considering the effect of the other decision exogenously (FIGURE 7.1.a), a joint

simultaneous decision (FIGURE 7.1.b), or as a nested structure (FIGURE 7.1.c). It is important to

highlight that nested structures are not sequential models, but rather another representation of a

joint choice model when the choice set is multidimensional and shares observed and unobserved

variables (Ben-Akiva and Lerman , 1985).

FIGURE 7.1 Model structures

Outsource goods

production

Yes No

Outsource logistics

and distribution

Yes No

Outsource

None

Goods production

only

Logistics and

distribution only

Both

Outsource goods

production

Yes No

Yes No

(b) (c)

(a)

Outsource logistics

and distribution

Outsource goods production/logistics

and distribution

Locally Internationally

Page 194: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

175

In this chapter results of the first two model structures (independent binary choice models,

and a multinomial model of the joint simultaneous decision) are presented. The binary logit

model structure is used to represent the decisions of outsourcing of goods production, and

logistics and distribution decisions. The binary choice structure is also used to model the

outsourcing type (local/international) for firms that choose to outsource part or all goods

production and/or logistics and distribution activities. The results for the nested structure

(FIGURE 7.1.c) suggest that a nested logit model is not statistically different from a multinomial

logit (MNL) model of the joint simultaneous decision.

7.3.1. Binary logit model structure

The outsourcing of the two freight activities of goods production and logistics are binary

choices. In our binary logit models, the dependent variable y=1 if a firm outsources an activity,

and y=0 otherwise. Given a vector of explanatory variables xi, the probability of outsourcing

(yi=1) is represented as follows:

𝐏𝐫(𝒚𝒊 = 𝟏 | 𝒙𝒊) = 𝑭(𝒙𝒊, 𝜷) (7.1)

where 𝜷 is a vector of parameter coefficients of the independent variables xi. Representing this

relationship using a logistic model takes the following form as described in (Ben-Akiva and

Lerman , 1985):

𝐏𝐫(𝒚𝒊 = 𝟏 | 𝒙𝒊) = 𝒆𝑽𝒊

𝟏+ 𝒆𝑽𝒊 (7.2)

where 𝑉𝑖 is the systematic utility, which is a linear function of a set of independent variables xi as

follows:

𝑽𝒊 = 𝜷𝟎𝒊 + 𝜷𝟏𝒊𝒙𝟏𝒊 + 𝜷𝟐𝒊𝒙𝟐𝒊 + ⋯ + 𝜷𝒏𝒊𝒙𝒏𝒊 (7.3)

The vector 𝜷 of can be estimated using Maximum Likelihood Estimation (Greene, 2008),

where the log likelihood function (LL) can be formulated as follows:

𝑳𝑳(𝜷) = ∑ [𝒚𝒊𝒍𝒏[𝑭 (𝒙𝒊, 𝜷)] + (𝟏 − 𝒚𝒊) 𝒍𝒏 [𝟏 − 𝑭 (𝒙𝒊, 𝜷)]]𝒊 (7.4)

where 𝐹 (𝑥𝑖, 𝜷) takes the logit form represented in (7.2)

Page 195: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

176

Two groups of independent binary logit models are presented in this chapter. One addresses

outsourcing of goods production, and the other addresses outsourcing of logistics and

distribution. For each outsourcing decision model, the outcome of the other decision is included

as an independent binary variable. For example, in the logistics outsourcing model, the goods

production outsourcing is used as an independent variable to capture its effect and significance

on logistics outsourcing decision. The binary logit model structure is also used to represent the

outsourcing type (local/international) decisions for both goods production and logistics and

distribution.

7.3.2. Multinomial logit (MNL) model structure

Correlation analysis of the data and the results of the binary logit models (as shown in the

results section) reveal a high correlation between the decisions of outsourcing of goods

production and outsourcing of logistics. Therefore, a MNL model structure of the joint

outsourcing decisions is tested. MNL is an appropriate approach when the dependent variable is

categorical (more than two categories) and the categories are unordered (Smithson and Merkle,

2013). In the MNL formulation, the probability of alternative i to be chosen amongst a set of

alternatives J is given by:

𝑷𝒓(𝒊) = 𝒆𝑽𝒊

∑ 𝒆𝑽𝒋𝑱

𝒋=𝟏

(7.5)

The log likelihood function can be formulated as follows:

𝑳𝑳(𝜷) = ∑ ∑ 𝜹𝒋𝒕∀ 𝒋 ∈𝑱 ∀ 𝒕 ∈ 𝑻 ×𝒍𝒏 (𝑷𝒓𝒋𝒕(𝜷)) (7.6)

where 𝛿𝑗𝑡= 1 if alternative j is chosen by individual t and 𝛿𝑗𝑡 = 0 otherwise. In the joint model of

freight outsourcing decisions, four decision alternatives are identified as in FIGURE 7.1c:

• Alt. 0: outsource none (the base alternative)

• Alt. 1: outsource goods production only

• Alt. 2: outsource logistics and distribution only

• Alt. 3: outsource both goods production and logistics and distribution

Page 196: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

177

7.4. Model Results

Three types of models have been estimated for both the binary logit, and MNL model

structures. Results are organized as follows. First, for binary logit model structure, the following

models are presented:

• Logistics outsourcing (simple and detailed models) (TABLE 7.2)

• Goods production outsourcing (simple and detailed models) (TABLE 7.3), and

• International outsourcing (logistics and goods production) (TABLE 7.4)

Then, for the MNL model structure the following models are presented:

• Logistics and goods production outsourcing (simple and detailed models) (TABLE 7.5,

TABLE 7.6)

• International logistics and goods production outsourcing (TABLE 7.7)

The simple models include available generic variables only. These models are intended for use in

a freight microsimulation, in which all inputs must be forecast. The detailed models include more

information about the firm structure, strategic focus, economic growth, market competition, and

use of innovation and advanced technologies. These additional variables would not necessarily

be available within a microsimulation but provide new insights on underlying behaviour.

The models for explaining international outsourcing are based on a subset of the data set that

contains records of all outsourcers. Firms that outsource locally versus internationally are

distinguished. Models for quantifying the effects of firm characteristics and economic

environment on outsourcing type for goods production, and logistics activities are then

estimated.

7.4.1. Binary logit model results

The simple and detailed model estimates for the binary logit model structure are shown in

TABLE 7.2, and TABLE 7.3. TABLE 7.4 provides model estimates for the international

outsourcing models. We hypothesize that outsourcing decisions are different from one industry

to the other. As such, industry effects are represented by dummy variables to identify sub-

industry 3-digit NAICS code. Industries such as wood product, and computer and electronic

Page 197: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

178

product manufacturers are less likely to outsource their logistics compared to beverages and

tobacco product manufacturers.

Firm size (represented as the number of employees) is found to have an influence over

outsourcing of both decisions; the larger the firm, the more likely they are to outsource their

freight related activities. This finding is in agreement with (Kurz, 2006) for U.S. manufacturers,

which states that outsourcers have significantly greater employment compared to non-

outsourcers. When firms outsource intermediate goods production, they hire more highly-skilled

workers (explained by the positive sign of the percentage of university degree employees in

TABLE 7.2) to perform a firm’s core activities.

Strategic focus of the firm is found to have an impact on goods production outsourcing.

When firms are focused on producing significantly improved or new goods, they are less likely

to outsource production activities. Firms whose strategy is to minimize operating cost, expand

market share growth, or increase the sales of their new products are more likely to outsource

some or all of their production activities.

Growth in the GDP has a positive impact on outsourcing of logistics. When the economy is

growing, manufacturers tend to focus on increasing their market share by focusing on the

production side, and hence are more likely to outsource their logistics. Moreover, firms that

outsource part or all of their goods production are more likely to outsource the associated

logistics and vice versa.

The decisions of expansion and contraction of production facilities are found to have almost

the same impact on the logistics outsourcing. Firms that close production facilities may also want

to close some of their logistics facilities as well. On the other hand, firms that expand their

production facilities may want to focus on the production side, and hence would also want to

outsource logistics. Similarly, closing production or logistics and distribution facilities increase

the likelihood of outsourcing goods production.

The use of advanced communication technologies is found to have a positive influence on

logistics outsourcing. Use of advanced technologies in general indicates an interest in enhancing

production quality to gain higher market share. Hence, outsourcing of logistics is more plausible.

When a firm is using process innovation in introducing new or significantly improved logistics

operations, it is logical that they are focused on administrating their own logistics operations as

Page 198: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

179

they are already investing in it, as most likely it is within their goals to enhance their delivery

times (explained by the negative sign of the use of process innovation coefficient in TABLE 7.2).

TABLE 7.2 Binary Logit Models for Logistics Outsourcing*

Simple model Detailed model

Variables Coef. P >|Z| Odds

ratio Coef. P >|Z|

Odds

ratio

_cons -1.090 0.000 0.336 -1.790 0.000 0.167

Industry

Beverage and tobacco products 0.670 0.014 1.960 1.092 0.001 2.980

Textile products -- -- -- -0.340 0.124 0.712

Apparel, leather and allied products -0.348 0.093 0.706 -0.367 0.096 0.690

Wood products -0.440 0.015 0.644 -- -- --

Plastics and rubber products -- -- -- 0.308 0.041 1.360

Non-metallic mineral products -0.548 0.008 0.578 -- -- --

Computer and electronic products -0.467 0.003 0.627 -0.569 0.001 0.567

Furniture and related products -- -- -- 0.330 0.072 1.390

Rest of subindustries Reference

Employment Size

Small-sized firm (less than 100 employees) Reference

Medium-sized firm (100-250 employees) 0.413 0.000 1.511 0.217 0.024 1.242

Large-sized firm (>250 employees) 0.516 0.000 1.675 0.250 0.021 1.280

Location: Ontario 0.242 0.001 1.273 -- -- --

GDP growth on naics-3 level -- -- -- 0.009 0.022 1.009

Other operational strategies

Outsource of goods production -- -- -- 1.415 0.000 4.115

Opened a new/expand production facility -- -- -- 0.467 0.000 1.595

Closed/contracted capacity of production

facility -- -- -- 0.355 0.002 1.426

Use of innovation and advanced technologies

Use of advanced communication tech. -- -- -- 0.245 0.018 1.278

Process innovation in logistics -- -- -- -0.270 0.013 0.764

Use of government tax credit programs -- -- -- 0.140 0.097 1.151

Strategic focus

Gross/margin operating cost -- -- -- 0.181 0.053 1.198

Organizational and management practices -- -- -- -0.130 0.104 0.878

International activities

Direct exports -- -- -- 0.217 0.011 1.242

* All model variables are dummy variables unless otherwise stated

Page 199: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

180

TABLE 7.3 Binary Logit Models for Goods Production Outsourcing

Simple model Detailed model

Variables Coef. P>|Z| Odds

ratio Coef. P>|Z|

Odds

ratio

_cons -0.763 0.000 0.466 -2.978 0.000 0.051

Industry: Food manufacturing -1.435 0.000 0.238 -1.213 0.000 0.297

Beverage and tobacco products -0.940 0.006 0.391 -- -- --

Apparel, leather and allied products -- -- -- 0.668 0.001 1.951

Wood products -1.409 0.000 0.244 -0.773 0.002 0.462

Paper manufacturing -0.689 0.001 0.502 -- -- --

Petroleum and coal products -1.209 0.026 0.298 -- -- --

Chemical manufacturing -0.805 0.000 0.447 -0.835 0.000 0.434

Plastics and rubber products -0.650 0.000 0.522 -0.424 0.017 0.655

Non-metallic mineral products -1.483 0.000 0.227 -1.011 0.000 0.364

Primary metal manufacturing -0.620 0.001 0.538 -- -- --

Fabricated metal products -0.263 0.040 0.769 -- -- --

Transportation equipment manufacturing -0.569 0.000 0.566 -- -- --

Furniture and related products -0.623 0.001 0.536 -- -- --

Rest of subindustries Reference

Size: Small firm (less than 100 employees) Reference

Medium-sized firm (100-250 employees) 0.401 0.000 1.493 -- -- --

Large-sized firm (>250 employees) 0.501 0.000 1.650 -0.306 0.008 0.736

Employees with university degrees (%) -- -- -- 0.007 0.003 1.007

Production size: # of products and

services(log) -- -- -- 0.068 0.000 1.070

Long-term strategy: Mass market strategy -- -- -- -0.310 0.039 0.734

Improved goods/services -- -- -- -0.218 0.017 0.804

Strategic focus: Gross/margin operating cost -- -- -- 0.297 0.005 1.345

Market/customer share growth -- -- -- 0.191 0.034 1.211

Sales of new products -- -- -- 0.208 0.024 1.231

Other operational strategies

Outsource logistics -- -- -- 1.330 0.000 3.780

Close/ contract capacity of goods production

facilities -- -- -- 0.447 0.001 1.564

Close/contract capacity of logistics facilities -- -- -- 0.355 0.086 1.426

Competition: Number of competitors < 3 Reference

Number of competitors 3-10 -- -- -- 0.328 0.007 1.389

Number of competitors >10 -- -- -- 0.341 0.010 1.406

Process innovation of new manufacturing

methods -- -- -- 0.218 0.002 1.243

International activities -- -- -- 0.660 0.000 1.935

International suppliers -- -- -- 0.392 0.023 1.480

Page 200: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

181

Government programs of tax credit are found to have a positive influence over logistics

outsourcing. One example is the Ontario innovation tax credit program. Briefly, this program

allows businesses to claim a 10% of their tax credit for expenditures on scientific research and

experimental development performed in Ontario (Ministry of Finance, 2016). Competition is

found to have a positive impact on goods production outsourcing; the higher the number of the

competitors, the more likely firms would outsource their goods production activities to cope with

the competition and maintain their market share.

TABLE 7.4 presents models for international freight outsourcing. It is found that firms with

international activities/subsidiaries or who have an international market are more likely to

outsource freight activities internationally, as this might be more cost effective.

Page 201: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

182

TABLE 7.4 Binary Logit Models for International Outsourcing*

Logistics outsourcing Goods production

outsourcing

Variables Coef. P >|Z| Odds

ratio Coef. P>|Z|

Odds

ratio

_cons -2.617 0.000 0.073 -0.029 0.937 0.972

Industry: Beverage and tobacco products -- -- -- -1.434 0.114 0.238

Apparel, leather and allied products -- -- -- 3.253 0.003 25.856

Printing and related support activities -- -- -- -1.378 0.039 0.252

Rest of subindustries Reference

Size: Small -medium (≤ 250 employees) Reference

Large-sized firm (>250 employees) 0.443 0.065 1.558 -- -- --

Production size: # of product lines (log) -- -- -- 0.190 0.068 1.209

Other characteristics

The head office location in Canada -- -- -- -1.451 0.000 0.234

Other operational strategies

Expand production facility by M&A -- -- -- 1.052 0.009 2.863

Expand logistics by M&A -- -- -- -2.074 0.000 0.126

Use of product innovation -- -- -- 0.477 0.049 1.611

Long-term strategy: Mass market -0.602 0.128 0.548 -- -- --

International involvement

Outsourcing of goods production(intl.) 2.090 0.000 8.087 -- -- --

Outsourcing of logistics (intl.) -- -- -- 2.164 0.000 8.708

International subsidiaries -- -- -- 0.925 0.001 2.522

International activities 0.841 0.001 1.327 -- -- --

Canada being the main market -0.480 0.029 0.619 -0.496 0.039 0.609

Competition from multinational firms 0.599 0.021 1.821 -- -- --

Direct exports 0.433 0.097 1.541 -- -- --

Also, few industries are found to have a statistical significance on goods production

outsourcing. For instance, apparel, leather and allied product manufacturers are more likely to

outsource part of their goods production internationally compared to the rest of manufacturers.

This could be due to resources availability and manufacturing cost, but more information about

outsourcing cost is needed to support this claim.

* All model variables are dummy variables unless otherwise stated

Page 202: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

183

7.4.2. MNL model results

The main purpose of the MNL models is to explore the effect of the independent variables on

the joint decision of the two freight outsourcing decisions, and whether such effects are

significantly different from the binary logit models or not. TABLE 7.5, TABLE 7.6, and TABLE

7.7 represent the estimates of the three MNL models; the simple model, the detailed, and the

international outsourcing models.

Joint freight outsourcing decisions are different from one industry to the other. For instance,

from the odds ratio in TABLE 7.5 and TABLE 7.6, when all other variables are held constant,

apparel, leather and allied producers are almost 3 times likely to outsource their logistics only,

and are 1.3 times likely to outsource their goods production only than not to outsource any

freight operations, while they are 0.74 ~ 1.1 times likely to outsource both operations than not to

outsource any.

Location of manufacturers also has an effect on outsourcing decisions. Manufacturers in

Ontario are 20% more likely to outsource both freight activities than firms located in Alberta

(calculated from the odds ratio in TABLE 7.5 and TABLE 7.6 This is affected by several groups

of factors related to the location such as the targeted customers, the market, resource availability

and cost of outsourcing. When such information is available, further solid conclusions can be

drawn regarding the effect of firm location on outsourcing decisions.

Professional employment was found to have almost the same effect on outsourcing decisions

(TABLE 7.6). An increase of 1% in the number of employees with university degrees has almost

the same effect across outsourcing decisions compared to the base alternative. Firms that have

other subsidiaries in Canada are generally less likely to outsource freight activities because the

presence of other Canadian subsidiaries may entail expansion in production/logistics operations

and hence are performed within the firm.

Furthermore, firms that target mass markets as their long-term strategy are less likely to

outsource any of their freight operations, which conforms to the results of the binary logit

models. Firms that focus on minimizing operating costs and those whose strategy is to increase

their market share are more likely to outsource goods production only compared to outsourcing

logistics only or outsourcing both goods production and logistics. Firms that aim to increase the

sales of their new products are more likely to outsource logistics compared to the rest of

alternatives. The change in market share of the highest selling goods or services in the main

Page 203: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

184

market is found to have the same effect on different outsourcing decision alternatives (the

coefficients of all alternatives have the same sign and almost the same magnitude in TABLE 7.6).

Growth in the GDP of each industry is found to have almost the same effect on outsourcing

decisions over the base alternative.

Confirming the conclusions drawn from the binary logit models, firms that employ process

innovation in logistics are less likely to outsource their logistics operations. Also, the use of

government programs of tax credits and trainings are found to have a positive influence on all

outsourcing decisions.

TABLE 7.5 A MNL Model of Outsourcing: A Simple Model*

Coef. P >|Z| Odds ratio

Variables Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3

_cons -1.448 -1.540 -1.602 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.235 0.214 0.201

Industry

Food manufacturing -0.940 -1.235 0.236 0.000 0.000 0.147 0.391 0.291 1.266

Apparel, leather and allied

products 0.240 1.078 -0.299 0.359 0.000 0.377 1.271 2.939 0.741

Wood products -0.943 -1.175 -0.066 0.001 0.001 0.765 0.389 0.309 0.936

Chemical manufacturing -0.262 -0.515 0.108 0.182 0.036 0.561 0.769 0.597 1.114

Plastics and rubber products -0.145 -0.328 0.318 0.476 0.187 0.093 0.865 0.720 1.375

Primary metal

manufacturing -0.507 0.102 0.612 0.106 0.721 0.007 0.602 1.108 1.845

Machinery manufacturing 0.372 0.629 0.261 0.036 0.001 0.177 1.450 1.876 1.299

Computer and electronic

products -0.177 0.611 -0.352 0.418 0.002 0.156 0.838 1.843 0.703

Transportation equipment

manufacturing -0.103 -0.055 0.266 0.553 0.778 0.112 0.902 0.947 1.305

Furniture and related

products 0.054 -0.388 0.369 0.817 0.212 0.100 1.055 0.678 1.446

Miscellaneous

manufacturing 0.297 1.022 0.297 0.232 0.000 0.255 1.346 2.780 1.345

Rest of subindustries Reference

Employment size

Small and medium sized

firms (≤ 250 employees) Reference

Large-sized firm (>250

employees) 0.593 0.088 0.266 0.000 0.545 0.026 1.810 1.092 1.305

Location

Ontario 0.174 0.004 0.257 0.097 0.968 0.011 1.190 1.004 1.293

Alberta -0.075 -0.495 0.059 0.661 0.013 0.714 0.928 0.610 1.061

Rest of provinces in Canada Reference

* All model variables are dummy variables unless otherwise stated

Page 204: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

185

TABLE 7.6 A MNL Model of Outsourcing: A Detailed Model

Coef. P >|Z| Odds ratio

Variables Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3

_cons -2.913 -2.698 -2.120 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.054 0.067 0.120

Industry

Food manufacturing -1.218 -1.301 0.413 0.000 0.000 0.012 0.296 0.272 1.511

Apparel, leather and allied

products 0.262 1.136 0.095 0.381 0.000 0.761 1.300 3.115 1.100

Wood products -0.747 -0.652 0.161 0.010 0.043 0.453 0.474 0.521 1.175

Paper manufacturing -0.590 -0.324 -0.171 0.079 0.302 0.541 0.554 0.723 0.843

Chemical manufacturing -0.837 -1.065 -0.002 0.000 0.000 0.993 0.433 0.345 0.998

Plastics and rubber products -0.241 -0.512 0.257 0.261 0.049 0.181 0.786 0.600 1.292

Primary metal products -0.382 -0.013 0.115 0.239 0.968 0.669 0.683 0.988 1.122

Computers and electronics -0.650 -0.293 -0.580 0.006 0.186 0.022 0.522 0.746 0.560

Furniture and related

products 0.290 -0.203 0.412 0.224 0.509 0.070 1.337 0.817 1.510

Miscellaneous

manufacturing 0.248 0.724 0.068 0.322 0.002 0.803 1.281 2.063 1.071

Rest of subindustries Reference

Location: Ontario 0.182 -0.015 0.449 0.114 0.901 0.000 1.200 0.985 1.566

Alberta 0.308 -0.257 0.312 0.095 0.230 0.072 1.361 0.773 1.366

Rest of provinces in Canada Reference

Other firm characteristics

Employees with university

degrees (%) 0.005 0.012 0.001 0.133 0.000 0.733 1.005 1.013 1.001

Other subsidiaries in

Canada -0.021 -0.038 -0.240 0.864 0.770 0.047 0.979 0.962 0.787

More than one profit center 0.130 0.268 0.323 0.293 0.037 0.005 1.138 1.307 1.381

Long-term strategy of

mass market -0.550 -0.107 -0.033 0.006 0.569 0.826 0.577 0.899 0.968

strategic focus

Organizational and

management practices -0.285 -0.366 -0.266 0.009 0.001 0.008 0.752 0.693 0.766

Gross/margin operating cost 0.447 0.153 0.131 0.001 0.242 0.248 1.564 1.165 1.140

Market/customer share

growth 0.206 0.126 0.005 0.063 0.277 0.965 1.229 1.134 1.005

Sales of new products 0.181 0.515 0.023 0.104 0.000 0.827 1.199 1.674 1.023

Other operational strategies

Open new/expand capacity

of production facilities 0.548 0.200 0.489 0.000 0.133 0.000 1.729 1.222 1.631

Close / contract capacity of

production facilities 0.749 0.634 0.505 0.000 0.000 0.001 2.114 1.885 1.657

Open new/expand logistics

facilities -0.137 -0.197 -0.629 0.347 0.223 0.000 0.872 0.821 0.533

Close or contract capacity

of logistics facilities 0.354 -0.058 -0.223 0.104 0.816 0.360 1.425 0.944 0.801

Page 205: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

186

TABLE 7.6 (Continued)

Market share of highest

selling goods/services in

the main market (%)

-0.005 0.000 -0.002 0.013 0.878 0.150 0.995 1.000 0.998

Use of innovation and advanced technologies

Process innovation of new

manufacturing methods 0.290 0.101 0.237 0.013 0.405 0.025 1.337 1.106 1.267

Process innovation in

logistics 0.068 -0.133 -0.485 0.633 0.402 0.001 1.070 0.875 0.615

Use of advanced

automated material

handling

-0.132 -0.401 0.131 0.345 0.013 0.307 0.876 0.670 1.140

Use of government support programs

Gov. training programs 0.249 0.012 0.196 0.038 0.926 0.084 1.283 1.012 1.216

Gov. tax credit programs 0.282 0.014 0.027 0.021 0.908 0.801 1.325 1.014 1.027

International involvement

International suppliers 0.260 0.464 0.290 0.200 0.040 0.069 1.297 1.590 1.337

International activities 0.399 0.642 0.102 0.001 0.000 0.351 1.490 1.901 1.107

Direct exports 0.396 0.037 0.171 0.002 0.778 0.134 1.486 1.037 1.186

GDP growth on NAICS-

3 level 0.016 0.004 0.008 0.005 0.563 0.134 1.016 1.004 1.008

For international outsourcing decisions (TABLE 7.7), larger firms (with number of

employees >250) are 40% more likely to outsource both freight decisions internationally than not

to outsource any. The production scale is also found to have a positive effect on international

outsourcing; an increase of 1 unit in the log value of the number of goods/services of a firm

increases the likelihood of outsourcing goods production by 20%, outsourcing logistics by

approximately 14% and outsourcing both activities by 10%. Moreover, firms that focus on

maintaining or expanding their sales of the existing products/services are less likely to outsource

goods production, and are more likely to outsource logistics, as firms may outsource logistics to

focus on maintaining a specific level of production quality. Firms that use government training

programs are less likely to outsource any of their freight operations internationally. This is

intuitive because such programs allow firms to enhance their local capabilities through training,

and hence firms use this knowledge to improve their performance locally. On the other hand,

firms that use government grants are more likely to outsource freight internationally. Such

programs, like CanExport (Global Affairs Canada, 2016) and Export Market Access (Ontario

Chamber of Commerce, 2015), aim to help small and medium sized Canadian companies to

increase export opportunities by providing direct finance. This explains the positive sign of the

Page 206: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

187

parameter coefficients in the dummy variable of ‘Use of government grants’ in TABLE 7.7. This

finding points to the effectiveness of such programs to help Canadian firms penetrate

international markets. Alternatively, firms that target Canadian markets are approximately

34%~50% less likely to outsource any of their freight activities internationally, unlike firms that

have international subsidiaries, which are approximately 3~3.5 times more likely to outsource

their freight operations internationally than not to outsource any.

TABLE 7.7 A MNL Model of International Outsourcing*

Coef. P >|Z| Odds ratio

Variables Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3

_cons -0.945 -2.004 0.203 0.015 0.000 0.524 0.389 0.135 1.225

Size: Small and medium

firms (≤ 250 employee) Reference

Large-sized firm (>250

employees) 0.192 0.050 0.343 0.609 0.923 0.276 1.212 1.052 1.409

Other firm characteristics

# of products & services (log) 0.178 0.131 0.096 0.001 0.072 0.046 1.194 1.139 1.101

Other subsidiaries in Canada -0.342 -1.113 0.222 0.343 0.038 0.449 0.711 0.329 1.249

Long-term strategy and strategic focus

Age of long-term strategy 0.007 0.027 0.025 0.723 0.201 0.089 1.007 1.027 1.025

Maintaining/expanding sales

of existing goods/services -0.308 0.124 -0.645 0.273 0.747 0.007 0.735 1.132 0.525

Use of advanced automated

material handling -0.531 0.296 0.613 0.193 0.517 0.037 0.588 1.345 1.846

Use of government support programs

Gov. training programs -0.185 -0.349 -0.659 0.544 0.399 0.014 0.831 0.705 0.518

Gov. grants 0.572 0.820 0.220 0.051 0.033 0.391 1.771 2.270 1.246

International involvement

International Subsidiaries 1.122 1.260 1.041 0.002 0.008 0.001 3.071 3.527 2.832

Canada being the main

market -0.699 -0.677 -1.072 0.018 0.083 0.000 0.497 0.508 0.342

7.5. Model Validation

A hold-out sample of 20% of the full sample (for both model structures) was extracted for

model validation. Cross validation techniques are widely used in discrete choice model

validation to evaluate the predictive performance of model estimates by comparing predicted

choice probabilities against observed choice probabilities (Habib, 2013; Robin et al., 2009;

* All model variables are dummy variables unless otherwise stated

Page 207: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

188

Roorda et al., 2008). Model performance is evaluated at the aggregate level by comparing the

predicted shares against the observed shares of each choice in the hold-out sample (TABLE 7.8

and TABLE 7.9). The validation results show an accepted overall predictive performance of the

presented models.

In the binary logit model of outsourcing of logistics decisions, the simplified model over

predicts outsourcing by 3.9%, and the detailed and international outsourcing models slightly

under predict outsourcing by 0.9%, and 0.7% respectively. The binary models for goods

production outsourcing over predict by 0.4% and 1% in the simplified and detailed models

respectively, and under predict by 0.2% in the international model.

For the simple MNL model, the cross validation results indicate that the model slightly

under predicts the choice probabilities of the base alternative (no outsourcing) and Alt.3

(outsourcing both goods production and logistics) by 0.3% and 0.7%, over predicts by 1.1% in

Alt.2 (outsource logistics only), and perfectly predicts Alt.1 (outsource goods production only).

For the detailed MNL model, the model under predicts by 0.6% and 0.7% for Alt.1 and Alt.2,

and over predicts by 0.5% and 0.9% for the base alternative and Alt.3.

The McFadden pseudo-R2 (rho-square) and adjusted-R2 values for some of the presented

models may not seem to be high for transportation behavioural models. We believe that this is

because the available data do not include details of many of the main drivers to outsourcing

decisions (e.g. cost), but rather include firm characteristics and aggregate descriptions of the

economic environment.

By looking only at the model goodness-of-fit (psudo-R2 values) for both the binary logit and

MNL models, one can infer that MNL may not offer a better model fit compared to the binary

structures for all models. However, the MNL offers a potential realistic representation of the

simultaneous decisions of outsourcing. Statistically, it may seem that there is no added value of

the MNL relative to the binary logit structures in terms of the goodness-of-fit. If other data sets

that include more details relevant to outsourcing decisions (e.g. cost) are used, further solid

conclusions can be drawn about MNL versus binary logit structures.

Page 208: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

189

TABLE 7.8 Binary logit model validation

Logistics and distribution outsourcing

McFadden

pseudo R2

(rho-square)

Adjusted

R2

Observed

total

probabilities

Predicted

total

probabilities

%

Difference

Simple model 0.019 0.017 25.4% 29% 3.90%

Detailed model 0.108 0.104 32.0% 31% -0.90%

International outsourcing

model 0.250 0.240 47.7% 47% -0.70%

Goods production outsourcing

Simple model 0.040 0.037 25.1% 25.5% 0.40%

Detailed model 0.170 0.165 26.7% 27.7% 1.00%

International outsourcing

model 0.318 0.303 58.2% 58.0% -0.20%

TABLE 7.9 MNL model validation

Model type pseudo R2 Adj. R2 Cross validation Alt.0 Alt.1 Alt.2 Alt.3

Simple

model 0.0285 0.0248

Observed total

probabilities 57.9% 14.3% 11.7% 16.1%

Predicted total

probabilities 57.5% 14.3% 12.7% 15.4%

% Difference -0.3% 0.0% 1.1% -0.7%

Detailed

model 0.0814 0.0724

Observed total

probabilities 32.1% 41.4% 19.3% 7.1%

Predicted total

probabilities 32.6% 40.9% 18.6% 8.1%

% Difference 0.5% -0.6% -0.7% 0.9%

International

model 0.1069 0.088

Observed total

probabilities 57.0% 15.3% 12.3% 15.5%

Predicted total

probabilities 57.1% 14.1% 12.4% 16.4%

% Difference 0.2% -1.2% 0.1% 0.9%

7.6. Concluding Remarks and Future Research

Freight outsourcing decisions are a key component of the organizational structure of firms,

which in turn affect how they engage in the freight transportation system. This research studies

the effects of some firm characteristics including strategic focus, firm location, industry class,

economic growth, use of innovation and advanced technologies, market competition, and

international involvement on freight outsourcing decisions. Two groups of models of freight

outsourcing activities of goods production and logistics are presented; binary logit and MNL

Page 209: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

190

models. The models generally indicate that when a firm is focused on their core activities they

are more likely to outsource their freight related activities. This can be explained by the positive

sign of the effect of employment size, economic growth, and the use of advanced technologies in

the production process on outsourcing decisions.

Parsimonious models (simple models) are presented that are to be used in a microsimulation

platform for the purpose of agent-based firm micro-modelling. The detailed and international

outsourcing models provide insights on the effect of some policies (such as government

programs), and the use of innovation and advanced technologies on freight outsourcing. They

also provide insights on how the strategic focus and long-term strategies of firms influence their

outsourcing decisions.

The used data set includes only firms with 20 or more employees and annual revenues of at

least $250,000. Small firms (less than 20 employees) are not studied in this research. A potential

direction for this research is to study outsourcing decisions for the small-sized firm and compare

it to outsourcing decisions with medium and large firms and observe variations once suitable

data are available.

Outsourcing decisions may be influenced by other decisions such as relocation of activities,

and/or expansion/contraction of freight facilities (locally/ internationally). Such decisions may

induce some endogeneity to outsourcing decisions. This research offers basic models to

understand outsourcing decisions, some of which are to be used for microsimulation purposes.

Thus, the effect of other decisions is treated exogenously in the presented models. Such

endogeneities can be investigated using other model structures when appropriate data are

available. Other model structures such as mixed logit or probit models could be investigated.

However, the absence of alternative specific variables may result in poor model fitness of mixed

models. Once such data are available, mixed model structures could be explored.

Further improvement to the models of the decision of outsourcing requires detailed data

specific to outsourcing alternatives such as costs and profits, reliability, and delivery times. The

next step of this research is to quantify other key drivers to freight outsourcing. In order to do

that, surveys that are tailored to address outsourcing behaviour would need to be undertaken.

Such surveys would include questions related to the specifics of outsourcing such as operational

costs, delivery times, reliability, liability, resource availability, supplier locations, and target

customer locations. Surveys can either be revealed preferences (RP), stated preferences (SP), or a

Page 210: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

191

combination of both RP/SP surveys. Further efforts are also needed to incorporate outsourcing

models within an agent-based firm microsimulation platform.

Page 211: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

192

CHAPTER 8

Conclusions

This research is motivated by the paradigm shift from aggregate four-stage models of

transportation demand towards disaggregate agent-based models that represent the individual

behaviour of the transportation system agents. Freight systems are fundamental components in

transportation systems. Firms are the key interacting agents in freight systems whose dynamics

of entry, exit, relocation, and growth influence the evolution of urban form, employment, and

economic growth.

Firmography is the research field that studies firm evolution processes of entry, growth,

relocation, and exit, at the individual level. Firmographic models can be used to represent these

firm evolution processes in agent-based transportation modelling systems. Research gaps in

firmographic modelling exist in the Canadian context. This research aims to fill the research gaps

by providing a firmographic microsimulation platform for evaluating policy implications on firm

evolution by forecasting their behaviour. Such policies include trade agreements, land use policy,

government incentives, and taxation policy.

This thesis introduces and implements components of a framework of firm microsimulation,

called the firmographic engine that models evolution of firms and their interactions within

freight systems. The firmographic engine extends the framework presented by (Roorda, et al.

2010) which defines firms as interacting agents in freight systems, whose interrelations result in

goods movements. The engine is designed to be integrated with other freight models such as

FREMIS (Cavalcante and Roorda, 2013). The firmographic engine provides information on job

supply-side dynamics that is needed on the micro-level in IUMs, which makes it suitable for

integration with ILUTE (Miller and Salvini, 1998).

Behavioural models of firm start-up size, firm growth, firm exit, and freight outsourcing are

introduced. The presented models capture the effects of firm attributes, firm strategic focus,

economic changes, industry dynamics, and market competition on firm behaviour. Two types of

models have been presented; simple and detailed models. Simple models use basic firm

attributes, such as age, employment size, provincial location, industry class, and general

economic growth indicators (e.g. GDP growth and provincial unemployment rates). Simple

Page 212: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

193

models are designed to be implemented within the microsimulation platform. Detailed models

are developed for the purpose of gaining a deeper understanding of behaviour using additional

explanatory variables that may not easily be available in a microsimulation model.

8.1. Summary of Chapters

The first chapter highlights the motivation behind this research and states the gaps this

research is trying to cover. Chapter 2 is a comprehensive literature review of firmography and

firm microsimulation in transport modelling with a focus on freight systems. The chapter reviews

studies of firmography, over the past fifteen years, in research areas such as economics,

industrial organization, regional sciences, transportation and land use. This chapter covers basic

principles of firmography, firm life cycle, and relationship between firmographic events, market

dynamics, and economic growth. The summary includes the scope of each study, population of

study, data, the firmographic events under investigation, and the used methods. Firm

microsimulation studies in freight systems are also presented. In addition, the chapter highlights

potential innovative directions for firmographic modelling using concepts of evolutionary

biology and game theoretic approaches. The chapter summarizes major research gaps in

firmographic modelling and potential future research.

Chapter 3 introduces a framework of firm microsimulation that addresses gaps highlighted in

chapter 2. A conceptual framework is presented with underlying modules of firm generation,

market introduction, performance evaluation, and firm evolution and strategy updates. Canadian

sources of firm micro-level data that are used in this research are discussed. Potential integration

of the introduced firm microsimulation and other transportation and land use microsimulations of

FREMIS and ILUTE is illustrated. The chapter explains the firmographic behaviour this research

aims to estimate and implement.

Chapter 4 presents micro-models of firm start-up size. First, determinants of firm start-up

size in the literature are discussed. Data analysis of firm start-up size is introduced. The models

address firm start-up size both in terms of the number of employees and the tangible asset values.

An ordered logit model structure is adopted to represent start-up size decisions. Estimation and

validation results of ordered logit models are discussed.

In chapter 5, several model structures to represent firm growth events are explored. Firm

growth is presented in two dimensions; employment size and tangible assets. Estimation results

Page 213: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

194

of firm employment growth models of ordered logit, panel logistic regression with random

effects, multilevel models with random effects, and autoregressive distributed-lag (ARDL) are

discussed. ARDL model estimation and results for tangible asset growth are also presented. The

chapter provides a comparison between each of the models, and recommends ARDL models to

represent growth events in the firmographic engine. The chapter also presents seemingly

unrelated regression (SURE) as a simultaneous modelling approach of the firm growth aspects of

employment and tangible assets.

Chapter 6 presents survival analyses of Canadian firms. Parametric and non-parametric

analyses are introduced. The parametric analysis introduces a discrete-time hazard duration

model to represent firm exit events. The non-parametric analysis estimates survival and hazard

rates. The chapter includes a comparison of our results to other Canadian studies of firm survival

analysis introduced by (Maoh and Kanaroglou, 2007b; Baldwin et al., 2000). A discussion of

other explored modelling approached is also provided.

Chapter 7 proposes a suite of freight outsourcing models of Canadian manufactures. Discrete

choice models of binary logit and multinomial logit are introduced. The models quantify the

effect of firm attributes, firm strategic focus, market competition, economic growth, and use of

innovation, advanced technologies, and government incentives on outsourcing decisions. The

chapter presents models of freight outsourcing by geographic selection (local vs. international).

8.2. Main Conclusions and Findings

The review of the current firm microsimulation studies (refer to chapter 2) led to the

following conclusions:

• Firmography is important to freight microsimulation.

• National level firmographic microsimulation is not well-covered in the Canadian

literature.

• Firmography is influenced by firm characteristics, industry dynamics, economic

growth, market demand and competition, firm location, innovation and technological

advancements, and use of and local policies. Such factors should be considered when

developing firm micromodels.

Page 214: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

195

• Firmographic events of firm entry, growth, relocation, and exit are intertwined and

have a two-way relationship with economic conditions, and hence, should be studied

together.

Analysis and models of firm start-up size (refer to chapter 4) led to the following

conclusions:

• Firms tend to start small (in size) to reduce losses in the case of firm failure. Around

50% of Canadian firms starts with one employee, while 75% of new firms are two

employees or less, and the average firm start-up size of Canadian firms is 2.5

employee.

• Model results indicate that firm start-up employment size varies across industries and

across provinces. Firms located in Quebec have higher odds of starting relatively

large in size compared to the rest of Canada, while firms located in Alberta have 85%

chances of starting with one employee compared to firms located in Ontario, Quebec,

and British Columbia. Firms in the accommodation and food services industry have

higher odds of starting with larger number of employees compared to other industries.

• Provincial unemployment rate, firm exit rate by industry, and competition are found

to have a negative effect on firm start-up employment size. GDP growth, and average

firm size (in each industry) are found to positively influence firm start-up

employment size.

• Tangible assets models indicate that a larger number of employees increases the

likelihood of starting with larger tangible asset values. Approximately, for every three

employees, there is a 45% probability of tangible assets start-up size to be greater

than $99,999.99.

• Firms located in Saskatchewan have higher odds of starting at higher ranges of

tangible assets compared to rest of Canada, while firms in Ontario have the lowest

odds of starting at higher tangible asset ranges.

• Firms that belong to ‘Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting’ industry class have

higher odds of having higher start-up tangible asset values compared to other

industries.

Page 215: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

196

• Provincial unemployment rates, are found to negatively influence firm start-up

tangible asset values, while GDP growth has a positive effect. Clearly, a thriving

economy encourages businesses to grow in size and decreases the likelihood of

failure.

• Firm entry rates by industry have a negative effect on start-up tangible asset values

• The number of competitors aggregated to the CMA/CA and the sub-industry class

(NAICS 3-digit code levels) has a negative effect on start-up tangible assets.

Generally, it can be concluded that firms are inclined to start smaller to minimize

potential sunk costs as a result of higher competition of similar firms.

The following conclusions are drawn from firm growth models (refer to chapter 5):

• The growth in the number of employees is largely affected by the growth in firm

profits and tangible assets, and the effect of the age alone may not be robust.

• GDP growth is found to have a positive effect on firm employment and tangible asset,

whereas unemployment rates have a negative effect. Both findings highlight that a

growing economy encourages firms to grow in size.

• The results show that firms increase their number of employees with higher entry

rates, while they contract their employment with higher exit rates. Higher entry rates

indicate possible market growth that can take the form of new firm creation (as

indicated by the entry rate) and/or the growth of existing firms. Higher exit rates

suggest that when a market is shrinking in size, existing firms are more likely to

reduce their employment size.

• In employment size models, age has a positive effect on employment size when it is

solely included with basic firm characteristics of provincial location and industry

class. Whereas when other firm related attributes that have greater effects on

employment size (e.g. tangible assets) are included, the effect of age is observed to be

negative. Since other firm attributes of tangible assets and sales values are found to

have higher statistical significance on firm employment size, there is higher

confidence that age has a negative effect on employment size, and older firms have

smaller growth rates compared to younger ones, agreeing with (Evans, 1987b;

Variyam & Kraybill, 1992; Yasuda, 2005).

Page 216: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

197

• Firm employment growth is variable from one firm to the other, across industries in

different regions.

• The first lagged value of the number of employees and tangible assets are found to

have strong positive effects on the employment size and tangible assets of the next

year, respectively.

• The number of employees is found to have a positive effect on the tangible assets. An

increase in the log value of the number of employees by 1 unit (i.e. an increase of

2.72 units in the number of employees) increases the value of the tangible assets by

$1.1 million.

• Competition is found to have a logical negative effect on firm employment and

tangible assets.

Firm survival analysis (refer to chapter 6) led to the following conclusions:

• Larger and older firms have better survival chances compared to smaller younger

firms.

• Market competition is found to have a negative effect on firm survival; the higher the

number of competitors is, the higher the risk of failure.

• A thriving economy with stable industries reduce the likelihood of firm exits.

• Our conclusions fall in-line with other studies indicating that firm failure patterns are

similar in regions with similar externalities.

The following conclusions are drawn from freight outsourcing models (refer to chapter 7):

• Industries such as wood product, and computer and electronic product manufacturers

are less likely to outsource their logistics compared to beverages and tobacco product

manufacturers.

• Firm employment size is found to have an influence over freight outsourcing. The

larger the firm, the more likely they are to outsource their freight related activities.

• Strategic focus of the firm is found to have an impact on goods production

outsourcing. When firms are focused on producing significantly improved or new

goods, they are less likely to outsource production activities. Firms whose strategy is

Page 217: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

198

to minimize operating cost, expand market share growth, or increase the sales of their

new products are more likely to outsource some or all of their production activities.

• Growth in the GDP has a positive impact on outsourcing of logistics. When the

economy is growing, manufacturers tend to focus on increasing their market share by

focusing on the production side, and hence are more likely to outsource their

logistics.

• There is endogeneity between freight outsourcing activities of goods production and

logistics and distribution. Firms that outsource part or all of their goods production

are more likely to outsource the associated logistics and vice versa

• Firms that close production facilities may also want to close some of their logistics as

well. On the other hand, firms that expand their production facilities may want to

focus on the production side, and hence would also want to outsource logistics.

Similarly, closing production or logistics and distribution facilities increase the

likelihood of outsourcing goods production.

• The use of advanced communication technologies is found to have a positive

influence on logistics outsourcing.

• When a firm is using process innovation in introducing new or significantly improved

logistics operations, it is logical that they are focused on administrating their own

logistics operations as they are already investing in it, as most likely it is within their

goals to enhance their delivery times (i.e. they are less likely to outsource their

logistics operations).

• Government programs of tax credit are found to have a positive influence over

logistics outsourcing.

• Competition is found to have a positive impact on goods production outsourcing; the

higher the number of the competitors, the more likely firms would outsource their

goods production activities to cope with the competition and maintain their market

share.

• Larger firms (with number of employees >250) are 40% more likely to outsource

both goods production and logistics and distribution internationally than not to

outsource any.

Page 218: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

199

• Firms that focus on maintaining or expanding their sales of the existing

products/services are less likely to outsource goods production, and are more likely to

outsource logistics, as firms may outsource logistics to focus on maintaining a

specific level of production quality.

• Firms that use government grants are more likely to outsource freight internationally.

Such programs, aim to help small and medium sized Canadian companies to increase

export opportunities by providing direct finance. This finding points to the

effectiveness of such programs to help Canadian firms penetrate international

markets.

8.3. Research Contributions to the Literature

This research contributes to the firmography literature in the Canadian region and is

potentially beneficial to research fields such as regional development, transportation and land use

planning. More specifically, the key contributions of the research can be summarized as follows:

• It offers the first national level firm microsimulation in Canada that utilizes microdata

of firms. The microsimulation tracks evolutionary stages of firms across industries in

Canadian provinces. The presented firm behavioural models in this research

incorporate firm attributes, industry characteristics, market competition, and

economic change to quantify their effect on the studied firmographic events of firm

start-up, growth, exit and freight outsourcing.

• It uses two new firm microdata sources (SIBS and T2-LEAP) that have not been

utilized in firm microsimulation in other Canadian research.

• This is the first attempt recorded in the Canadian literature to provide micromodels of

firm start-up size both in terms of employment and tangible assets.

• Exploring new model structures for firm growth such as ARDL, panel logistic

regression, and multilevel random effects models.

• First attempt in the Canadian literature to explore potential relationship between

growth in the number of employees and the firm’s physical form represented as the

tangible assets.

• Presenting firm survival analysis and failure model on a national level.

Page 219: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

200

• No previous attempts were found in the literature that introduce discrete choice

models of freight outsourcing decisions for Canadian manufacturers. This research

presents models that quantify the effects of the firm attributes, provincial location, use

of advanced technology and innovation, government incentives, and economic

conditions on freight outsourcing decisions. The models distinguish between

domestic and international freight outsourcing.

• The proposed framework is a strong candidate for integration with other

transportation and land use microsimulation of FREMIS (Cavalcante and Roorda.,

2013) and ILUTE (Miller and Salvini, 1998).

8.4. Future Research

This research is still emerging and has many potential significant contributions for further

enhancement and extension. Current research gaps are highlighted with potential future steps in

this section.

1. Endogeneity of firm behaviour, economic growth, and industry dynamics

Economic changes, industry dynamics, and firm evolution are entwined: the change of one

element influences the other. Economic growth encourages firms to grow, and creates

opportunities for new firms to enter the market, which influences competition, and affect entry

and exit rates in each industry. Increased demand and changes in innovation and advanced

technologies, in a specific industry, increase firm entry and growth events, which in turn affects

the economy. New, growing, and exiting firms collectively influence the economic growth

within a region. Currently, the engine considers the effect of economic growth and industry

dynamics exogenously to the firmographic models while the nature of the interactions suggests

endogeneity of the three aspects. The models presented in this research act as first steps to

highlight the determinants of the studied firm behaviour and offer basic models for freight

microsimulation purposes. For this purpose, other decisions are treated exogenously. Also, the

used datasets are not comprehensive enough to model such endogeneity. In a complete system,

these three elements should be modelled simultaneously, which has not been covered yet in any

research area in the literature.

Models that estimate variables of economic growth and industry dynamics are not covered

yet. A simple approach is to estimate simple linear regression models using historical data of

Page 220: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

201

such variables. Data about GDP, unemployment rates, firm entry and exit rates are publically

available through statistics Canada’s website (Statistics Canada 2015a, Statistics Canada 2015b,

Statistics Canada 2016).

2. Model validation on the firm and provincial levels

Due to restrictions in the data usage, a micro-level validation (using the hold-out sample) was

not conducted, especially with discrete choice models. It was not possible to evaluate the model

on the individual firm level for such a relatively small data set (the hold out sample) given that

the used explanatory variables are mostly dummy variables (especially for the case of the SIBS

database). A validation on the provincial level was also not a possibility due to the same data

usage limitations. For instance, for some regions, the count of firms classified by some industry

classes have too few companies, such that it would be easy to identify unique firms in some

regions which breaches the confidentiality of the data. As a result, it was not possible to perform

the validation on the region level, and we had to settle for evaluating the model at the Canadian

aggregate level. Also, simplified models are to be used for microsimulation purposes for all of

Canada, and hence the model performance on the aggregate is important. Once other data

sources (or the same used ones but offered with fewer restrictions) available, validation on both

the firm and the provincial levels is needed to give more confidence on the individual and

regional performance of the introduced discrete choice models. The continuous models of firm

growth do not have the same constraint, as the number of employees and the tangible assets were

predicted using a 10% marginal error. It was possible to perform model validation on the firm

level and then sum the number of successful predictions on the national level. Also, a provincial

level validation was not possible due to the firm count restriction for some industries in some

provinces.

3. Other techniques to test model forecasting capabilities

In this research, cross-validation techniques are used to assess the predictive capabilities of

the presented firm behavioural models. This has been done by using a hold-out sample of 20% of

the entire data set (that has not used in the model estimation procedure) to estimate forecasts of

the addressed response variables. Another potential technique for further model validation is to

use an entire future year data (i.e. another panel for the year 2013 of the T2-LEAP or another

cross-section of the year 2014 of SIBS) and compare model predictions to actual observed data.

Page 221: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

202

This procedure would give more confidence in the predictive capabilities of the behavioural

models in the future.

4. Modelling freight outsourcing of small-sized firms

Freight outsourcing behaviour of small-sized firms (employment <20) is not covered. The

SIBS that was used was collected through a survey that targeted firms with 20 or more

employees that have annual revenues of at least $250,000, for the purpose of studying relatively

stable firms. A potential research direction for studying this is to design a survey for small-sized

firms only, to answer the question of whether outsourcing decisions vary significantly between

medium and large firms or not.

5. Firm entry models

Models of firm entry are not well covered in the literature because the non-entry decision is

hard to observe (Melillo et al., 2013). Currently, the firmographic engine’s framework allows for

modelling the entrepreneurial decision of firm entry. The framework is designed to simulate

potential entrepreneurs and then identify those who will establish a new firm. A potential data

source for modelling the entrepreneurial decision is the Adult Population Survey (APS)

publically offered by (Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, 2015). This step is a logical next step to

addressing the complete firm entry decision in the firmographic engine. Another simpler

approach, although not at the micro-level, is to use linear regression models to estimate firm

entry rate by industry. This can be modelled using historical data of firm entry publically

available at Statistics Canada’s website (Statistics Canada 2016a).

6. Models of location choice and business mobility

Firm location choice and migration (mobility) are essential components for transportation

system microsimulation. Firm location influences many other firm decisions such as supplier

selection, outsourcing, and vehicle ownership. It also causes demographic changes to the

surrounding area by attracting employment with suitable skills or attracting other businesses for

agglomeration purposes. Simulating firm location is important to understand goods movements,

and demographic changes, and to estimate these impacts on transportation demand and traffic

patterns. Location choice models are a fundamental next step in the firmographic engine.

Estimation of such models requires firm location data at a finer geographic scope than the

provincial level. The T2-LEAP offers the firm location at the CMA/CA level, which may be

suitable for modelling firm location choice. Firm migration modelling, on the other hand,

Page 222: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

203

requires longitudinal information of firm locations. The design of the T2-LEAP does not keep

track of historical information of location; it only retains the most recent location information

and updates the entire firm previous records. The Business Registry (BR) database, that is

available through Statistics Canada, is an alternative data source that offers longitudinal firm

location information.

7. Improvements to firm exit/survival models

Firm exit/survival models are presented in this research do not define the exit type (i.e.

bankruptcy vs. merge/sell to other firms) as exit type was not possible to identify using the T2-

LEAP dataset. Once such data is available, competing risk models are potential approaches to

represent firm exit type. Identifying firm exit type is important to simulate employment

dynamics, especially those resulting from merging. When a firm acquires another firm,

potentially their number of employees will increase due to the merger event. In the current

operation of the firmographic engine, this is simulated as employment growth. This may falsely

refer to new employment opportunities (i.e. new jobs in the market) and may lead to partially

misleading representation of job supply-side dynamics.

8. Improvements to freight outsourcing models

Binary and multinomial logit models have been explored and presented in this thesis. Nested

logit models have also been estimated but are not presented in this document because they were

not statistically significant from MNLs. Mixed logit models are potential candidates to represent

outsourcing behaviour. However, mixed and nested logit require data that include information

specific to each alternative (e.g. cost of outsourcing, distance, and delivery times), which is not

part of the SIBS. A potential next step of this part of the research is to quantify other main

drivers to freight outsourcing throughout tailored surveys. Such surveys can be revealed

preference (RP), stated preference (SP), or a combination of both, that include questions related

to the specifics of outsourcing such as operational costs, delivery times, reliability, liability,

resource availability, supplier locations, and target customer locations.

Outsourcing decisions may be influenced by other decisions such as relocation of activities,

and/or expansion/contraction of freight facilities (locally/ internationally). Such decisions may

induce some endogeneity to outsourcing decisions. This research offers basic models to

understand outsourcing decisions, some of which are to be used for microsimulation purposes.

Thus, the effect of other decisions is treated exogenously in the presented models. Such

Page 223: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

204

endogeneities can be investigated using other model structures when appropriate data are

available. Other model structures such as mixed logit or probit models could be investigated.

However, the absence of alternative specific variables may result in poor model fitness of mixed

models. Once such data are available, mixed model structures could be explored.

9. Improvements to firm start-up size models

Ordered logit model approaches have been explored to address firm start-up size in terms of

the number of employees and tangible assets. The reported model goodness-of-fit indicate poor

fit. Further approaches, such as Poisson regression, can be investigated to enhance the model

goodness of fit. Also, firm start-up employment and tangible assets are endogenous and can be

modelled in a simultaneous fashion using other model structures such as SURE and simultaneous

equation models.

10. Integration with FREMIS

The firmographic engine represents the interactions in freight system of their basic agents

(firms). The firmographic engine is to be integrated with FREMIS; agent-based microsimulation

of shipper-carrier interactions. This integration would offer a complete representation the

interactions between shippers and carriers through contracts. Upon integration with the already

finished components of the firmographic engine that are related to shipper and carrier

interactions, (e.g. outsourcing and vehicle ownership models), and FREMIS, a simultaneous

validation of the two systems is necessary.

11. Development and operation of the firmographic engine

Although the underlying behavioural components of the firmographic engine are not fully

estimated, the physical implementation of the framework (i.e. programming the microsimulation

platform) is currently ongoing by a research team at the University of Toronto. The behavioural

models presented in this research are being implemented and upon completion the

microsimulation of firmographic events is to be tested and validated.

12. Under-representation of behavioural models of multi-establishment firms

The models presented in this research focus on single establishment firms as they constitute

the largest portion of firm population in Canada. However, large-sized multi-establishment firms

may have a larger impact on the economy. Models of firmographic events of large multi-

establishment firms are still under-researched in the literature. The T2-LEAP data set that is used

in this research contains information on multi-establishment firms, which makes it a strong

Page 224: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

205

candidate for estimating models to simulate the firmographic events of large multi-establishment

firms.

13. Uni-dimensional construct of firm growth

Models of firm growth represent the change in employment size only, while it might be the

combination of the growth of other assets as well. This research explored a potential statistical

model (SURE) that represents the growth in two aspects simultaneously. However, this approach

may not be suitable for microsimulation as it ignores unobserved heterogeneity between firms. A

future step in this direction to estimate other SURE models that considers correlation of the two

aspects of growth over time and across firms. Examples of such models include multivariate

time-series regression, and a system of simultaneous equations. Also, other aspects of growth can

be investigated such as number of business locations, vehicle fleet, floor space, sales, and

revenues.

14. Representing firm size using a single unit

This research presents firm size in two dimensions that seem to be correlated; employment

size and tangible asset values. However, firm size could better be presented using a single unit

that combines both aspects, such as employment per floor space (Badoe and Miller, 2000; Hunt

et al., 2005; Miller and Lerman, 1981). This information is not available in the T2-LEAP dataset.

If such information becomes available, the physical form of the firm could be better explained as

the employment per floor space. Models of firm start-up size and growth can also be reproduced

to reflect this representation.

15. Refining model spatial resolutions

The current behavioural models of the engine are developed at the provincial level. The

models use dummy variables to indicate the provincial location of the firms. Models can be

refined by introducing land use variables of the firm’s CMA/CA location (e.g. population

density, labour, education, income…etc.) to help the models capture the location effect in a

better resolution. When that is done, such models are reasonably transferable and can be used in

similar geographic regions by using location descriptive variables instead of provincial dummy

variables. Such models need to be re-estimated once appropriate data are available.

16. Integration with ILUTE

The model component representing the job supply side in ILUTE is not yet developed at the

micro-level. Once the previous step is achieved, the models are suitable to provide ILUTE with

Page 225: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

206

suitable labour demand forecasts at the firm micro-level. The engine provides predictions of firm

start-up size by industry class, which can be used to represent the number of jobs created due to

firm entry. It also tracks the change in the number of employees per firm in each industry on

annual basis. It provides firm exit microsimulation to present the job destruction on the micro

level. A further refining extension to the introduced models is to incorporate the job type to

provide accurate information on the job availability once appropriate data are available.

Currently, the next step is to integrate the firmographic engine with ILUTE and provide

employment dynamics using firm start-up size and growth models.

Page 226: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

207

Concepts of evolutionary biology and game theories in firmographic models

There is a separate field in economics, called evolutionary economics, that is based on the

assumption that economic organizations are dynamic involving transformation and the economic

behaviour driven by the decisions and interactions of diverse agents in the economic system

(including firms, individuals, and economic institutions) (Hodgson, 1993). This research stream

is based on concepts from evolutionary biology that are used to describe the evolution patterns of

firms. In this research stream, firm population is theorized to follow Darwin’s natural selection

and survival theories in biology. Firms follow the ‘survival of the fittest’ law; firms with good

strategies survive while others with weak strategies do not. These principles have been employed

in evolutionary economics to understand firm evolution and model firm birth (Johnson, Price and

Vugt, 2013). Genetic Algorithms have been introduced as a concept to describe firm birth, and

estimate the strategies of the new population of firms (Bruderer and Singh, 1996). Using the

same concepts, evolutionary patterns of firm failure can be captured by tracking the changes in

the strategies of failure firms in a genetic algorithm framework (Chen and Hsiao, 2008).

Furthermore, behaviour of individual firms affects other firms’ (within the same industry

and/or geographic region) strategies and evolution patterns. For instance, when a firm is

considering the introduction of a new product, it studies the current /potential offerings of similar

products by other firms, as well as selecting optimal price and quality strategies to gain new

market shares. Concurrently, other similar-neighbouring firms may need to update some of their

strategies to maintain their status in the market. This is a two-way interaction that can be

represented using a game theoretic approach, in which, individual agents are ‘players’ seeking to

optimize their decisions based on their opponent strategies. Agents adopt mixed cooperative and

competitive strategies based on available information on payoffs of joint actions with their

opponents. The goal of this game is to reach an equilibrium that optimizes the joint agent

decisions based on past payoffs rather than selecting strategies that maximize individual agents’

payoffs (Friesz and Holguín-Veras 2005).

Page 227: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

208

References

Abed, O., Janssens, D., Wets, G., & BELLEMANS, T. (2014). An agent based freight activities

and logistic chains optimized network simulator (FALCONS).

Abdur Razzaque, M., & Chen Sheng, C. (1998). Outsourcing of logistics functions: a literature

survey. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management, 28(2),

89-107.

Acs, Z. J., Armington, C., & Zhang, T. (2007). The determinants of new firm survival across

regional economies: The role of human capital stock and knowledge spillover. Papers in

Regional Science 86, no. 3, 367-391.

Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1988). Innovation and firm size in

manufacturing. Technovation, 7(3),197-210.

Acs, Z., & Storey, D. (2004). Introduction: Entrepreneurship and economic development.

Regional Studies, 38:8, 871-877.

Agarwal, R. (1996). Technological activity and survival of firms. Economics Letters 52, no. 1,

101-108.

Agarwal, R., & Gort, M. (2002). Firm and product life cycles and firm survival. The American

Economic Review, 92(2), 184-190.

Agarwal, R., Echambadi, R., Franco, A. M., & Sarkar, M. B. (2004). Knowledge transfer

through inheritance: Spin-out generation, development, and survival. Academy of

Management journal 47, no. 4, 501-522.

Alexandrova, M. (2009). International outsourcing: Incentives, benefits and risks for the

companies in SEE countries.

Allison, P. D. (1982). Discrete-time methods for the analysis of event histories. Sociological

methodology 13, no. 1, 61-9.

Allison, P. D. (1995). Survival analysis using SAS: a practical guide. Cary, NC: SAS Institute.

Almus, M., & Nerlinger, E. A. (1999). Growth of new technology-based firms: which factors

matter?. Small business economics, 13(2), 141-154.

Almus, M. (2000). Testing" Gibrat's Law" for Young Firms–Empirical Results for West

Germany. Small Business Economics, 15(1), 1-12.

Page 228: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

209

Amiti, M., & Wei, S. J. (2006). Service offshoring and productivity: evidence from the United

States (No. w11926). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Amoako-Gyampah, K., & Acquaah, M. (2008). Manufacturing strategy, competitive strategy and

firm performance: An empirical study in a developing economy

environment. International Journal of Production Economics, 111(2), 575-592.

Anderson, A. R., Jack, S. L., & Dodd, S. D. (2005). The role of family members in

entrepreneurial networks: Beyond the boundaries of the family firm. Family Business

Review, 18(2), 135-154.

Arauzo-Cardo, J.-M., & Teruel-Carrizosa, M. (2005). An urban approach to firm entry: The

effect of urban size. Growth and Change 36, no. 4, 508-528.

Arauzo-Carod, J.-M., & Segarra-Blasco, A. (2005). The determinants of entry are not

independent of start-up size: some evidence from Spanish manufacturing. Review of

Industrial Organization 27, no. 2, 147-165.

Armstrong, B., & Sloan, M. (1989). Ordinal regression models for epidemiologic data. American

Journal of Epidemiology, 129(1), 191-204.

Audretsch, D. B. (1991). New-firm survival and the technological regime. The Review of

Economics and Statistics, 441-450.

Audretsch, D. B. (1995a). Innovation, growth and survival. International journal of industrial

organization 13, no. 4 , 441-457.

Audretsch, D. B. (1995b). Innovation and industry evolution. MIT Press.

Audretsch, D. B., & Mahmood, T. (1994). The rate of hazard confronting new firms and plants

in US manufacturing. Review of Industrial organization 9, no. 1, 41-56.

Audretsch, D. B., & Mahmood, T. (1995). New firm survival: new results using a hazard

function. The Review of Economics and Statistics , 97-103.

Audretsch, D. B., Houweling, P., & Thurik, A. R. (2000). Firm survival in the Netherlands.

Review of industrial organization 16, no. 1, 1-11.

Audretsch, D. B., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (1999). Start-up size and industrial dynamics:

some evidence from Italian manufacturing." International Journal of Industrial

Organization 17, no. 7. 965-983.

Avery, R. B. (1977). Error components and seemingly unrelated regressions. Econometrica:

Journal of the Econometric Society, 199-209.

Page 229: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

210

Bachmann, C., Kennedy, C., & Roorda, M. (2014b). A Framework for Analyzing The of Global

Trade Patterns on Domestic Freight Operations. Canadian Transportation Research

Forum Conference. Windsor, Canada.

Bachmann, C., Kennedy, C., & Roorda, M. J. (2014a). Applications of random-utility-based

multi-region input–output models of transport and the spatial economy. Transport

Reviews, 34(4), 418-440.

Bachmann, R., & Braun, S. (2011). The impact of international outsourcing on labour market

dynamics in Germany. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 58(1), 1-28.

Badoe, D. A., & Miller, E. J. (2000). Transportation–land-use interaction: empirical findings in

North America, and their implications for modeling. Transportation Research Part D:

Transport and Environment, 5(4), 235-263.

Baldwin, J. R., Bian, L., Dupuy, R., & Gellatly, G. (2000). Failure rates for new Canadian

firms: New perspectives on entry and exit. Failure Rates for New Canadian Firms: New

Perspectives on Entry and Exit. Statistics Canada.

Baldwin, J. R., & Gellatly, G. (2003). Innovation strategies and performance in small firms.

Edward Elgar Publishing.

Baldwin, J. R., & Gorecki, P. (1998). The dynamics of industrial competition: A North American

perspective. Cambridge University Press.

Baldwin, J. R., & Gu, W. (2006). Competition, firm turnover and productivity growth. Economic

Analysis (EA) Research Paper Series, Available at SSRN 1371593.

Baldwin, J. R., & Gu, W. (2009). Outsourcing and Offshoring in Canada. Available at SSRN

1369254.

Baldwin, J. R., Liu, H., & Wang, W. (2013). Firm Dynamics: Firm Entry and Exit in the

Canadian Provinces, 2000 to 2009. Economic Analysis Division, Statistics Canada.

Balmer, M., Axhausen, K., & Nagel, K. (2006). Agent-based demand-modeling framework for

large-scale microsimulations. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the

Transportation Research Board, (1985), 125-134.

Baltagi, B. (2008). Econometric analysis of panel data. John Wiley & Sons.

Baltagi, B. H., & Wu, P. X. (1999). Unequally spaced panel data regressions with AR (1)

disturbances. Econometric Theory 15, no. 06 , 814-823.

Page 230: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

211

Baptista, R., & Leitão, J. (2015). Entrepreneurship, Human Capital, and Regional

Development (pp. 15-28). Heidelberg: Springer.

Barkham, R. J. (1994). Entrepreneurial characteristics and the size of the new firm: a model and

an econometric test. Small Business Economics 6, no. 2, 117-125.

Barkham, R., Gudgin, G., & Hanvey, E. (2002). Determinants of small firm growth: An inter-

regional study in the United Kingdom 1986-90 (Vol. 12). Psychology Press.

Bartelsman, E., Scarpetta, S., & Schivardi, F. (2005). Comparative analysis of firm

demographics and survival: evidence from micro-level sources in OECD countries.

Industrial and Corporate Change 14, no. 3, 365-391.

Basu, N., Pryor, R. J., & Quint, T. (1998). A microsimulation model of the economy.

Computational Economics, 12(3), 223-241.

Baum, J. R., Locke, E. A., & Smith, K. G. (2001). A multidimensional model of venture

growth. Academy of management journal, 44(2), 292-303.

Beesley, M. E., & Hamilton, R. T. (1994). Entry propensity, the supply of entrants and the

spatial distribution of business units. Regional Studies, 28(3), 233-239.

Ben-Akiva, M. E., & Lerman, S. R. (1985). Discrete choice analysis: theory and application to

travel demand (Vol. 9). MIT press.

Ben-Akiva, M. E., Meersman, H., & Voorde, E. Van de (Eds.), 2013. Freight Transport

Modelling. Emerald Group Publishing.

Berglund, E., & Brännäs, K. (2001). Plants' entry and exit in Swedish municipalities. The Annals

of Regional Science 35, no. 3, 431-448.

Bernard, A. B., & Sjoholm, F. (2003). Foreign owners and plant survival (No. w10039).

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Bhargava, A., Franzini, L., & Narendranathan, W. (1982). Serial correlation and the fixed effects

model. The Review of Economic Studies 49, no. 4 , 533-549.

Bhattacharjee, A. (2005). Models of firm dynamics and the hazard rate of exits: Reconciling

theory and evidence using hazard regression models. St. Salvator's College, School of

Economics and Finance.

Bienstock, C. C., & Mentzer, J. T. (1999). An experimental investigation of the outsourcing

decision for motor carrier transportation. Transportation Journal, 39(1), 42-59.

Page 231: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

212

Birley, S. (1986). The role of networks in the entrepreneurial process. Journal of business

venturing, 1(1), 107-117.

Birley, S., & Westhead, P. (1994). A taxonomy of business start-up reasons and their impact on

firm growth and size. Journal of Business Venturing, 9(1), 7-31.

Bland, J. M., & Altman, D. G. (2000). The odds ratio. Bmj 320, no. 7247: 1468, 1468.

Bodenmann, B. R., & Axhausen, K. W. (2010). Synthesis report on the state of the art on

firmographics. Institute for Transport Planning and Systems, ETH, Zurich.

Brant, R. (1990). Assessing proportionality in the proportional odds model for ordinal logistic

regression. Biometrics, 1171-1178.

Brenner, T. (2001). Simulating the evolution of localised industrial clusters-an identification of

the basic mechanisms. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 4(3), p.4.

Bruderer, E., & Singh, J. V. (1996). Organizational evolution, learning, and selection: A genetic-

algorithm-based model. Academy of management journal, 39(5), 1322-1349.

Bruneel, J., Clarysse, B., & Wright, M. (2009). Linking entrepreneurial strategy and firm

growth. Ghent University, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration.

Cabral, L. (1995). Sunk costs, firm size and firm growth. The Journal of Industrial Economics,

161-172.

Calvo, J. L. (2006). Testing Gibrat’s law for small, young and innovating firms. Small Business

Economics, 26(2), 117-123.

Cambridge Systematics. (1996). Inc. Quick Response Freight Manual. Final Report. Prepared for

the Federal Highway Administration, September.

Cambridge Systematics. (1998). Collection and Analysis of Commodity Flow Information in the

Portland Metropolitan Area: Compendium of Technical Memoranda and Other Key

Documents. Prepared for Portland Metro and the Port of Portland with ICF Kaiser

Consulting Group and Nelson/Nygaard Consulting Associates.

Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2009). Microeconometrics using stata (Vol. Vol. 5). College

Station, Texas: Stata press.

Carree, M., Santarelli, E., & Verheul, I. (2008). Firm entry and exit in Italian provinces and the

relationship with unemployment. International Entrepreneurship and Management

Journal 4, no. 2, 171-186.

Page 232: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

213

Carter, N. M., Williams, M., & Reynolds, P. D. (1997). Discontinuance among new firms in

retail: The influence of initial resources, strategy, and gender. Journal of business

venturing, 12(2), 125-145.

Cavalcante, R. A., & Roorda., M. J. (2013). Freight Market Interactions Simulation (FREMIS):

An Agent-Based Modeling Framework. Procedia Computer Science, 9, 867-873.

Cefis, E., & Marsili, O. (2006). Survivor: The role of innovation in firms’ survival. Research

Policy 35, no. 5, 626-641.

Chen, L.-H., & Hsiao, H.-D. (2008). Feature selection to diagnose a business crisis by using a

real GA-based support vector machine: An empirical study. Expert Systems with

Applications, 35(3), 1145-1155.

Ciobanu, O., & Wang, W. (2012). Firm dynamics: Firm entry and exit in Canada, 2000 to 2008.

Statistics Canada, (022).

Cleves, M. (2008). An introduction to survival analysis using Stata. Stata Press.

Coad, A., & Broekel, T. (2012). Firm growth and productivity growth: evidence from a panel

VAR. Applied Economics, 44(10), 1251-1269.

Cohen, S. K. (2010). Innovation-driven industry life cycles. Encyclopedia of technology and

innovation management, VK Narayanan, Gina Colarelli O'Connor Eds. Wiltshire: John

Wiley&Sons, 69-76.

Colombo, M. G., & Grilli, L. (2005). Founders’ human capital and the growth of new

technology-based firms: A competence-based view. Research policy 34, no. 6, 795-816.

Colombo, M. G., Delmastro, M., & Grilli, L. (2004). Entrepreneurs' human capital and the start-

up size of new technology-based firms. International journal of industrial organization

22, no. 8, 1183-1211.

Cox, D. R. (1972). "Regression models and life tables. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society

34, 187-220.

Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ, 2.

Das, S. (1995). Size, age and firm growth in an infant industry: The computer hardware industry

in India. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13(1), 111-126.

Davenport, T. H. (2013). Process innovation: reengineering work through information

technology. Harvard Business Press.

Page 233: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

214

de Bok, M., & Bliemer, M. (2006). Infrastructure and firm dynamics: Calibration of

microsimulation model for firms in the Netherlands. Transportation Research Record:

Journal of the Transportation Research Board 1977, 132-144.

de Bok, M. A. (2007). Infrastructure and firm dynamics: a micro simulation approach. TU Delft,

Delft University of Technology.

de Jong, G., & Ben-Akiva, M. (2007). A micro-simulation model of shipment size and transport

chain choice. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological, 41(9), 950-965.

de Jorge Moreno, J., Castillo, L. L., & de Zuani Masere, E. (2010). Firm size and entrepreneurial

characteristics: evidence from the SME sector in Argentina. Journal of Business

Economics and Management, 11(2), 259-282.

Deepen, J. M. (2007). Logistics outsourcing relationships: measurement, antecedents, and

effects of logistics outsourcing performance. Springer Science & Business Media.

Delmar, F., Davidsson, P., & Gartner, W. B. (2003). Arriving at the high-growth firm. Journal of

business venturing, 18(2), 189-216.

Dietrich, G. B., & Gibson, D. V. (1990). New business ventures: the spin-off process. In D. G. F.

Williams, Tehcnology Transfer: a communication prespective (pp. 153-171). London:

SAGE Publications.

Dinlersoz, E. M., & MacDonald, G. (2009). The industry life-cycle of the size distribution of

firms. Review of Economic Dynamics, 12(4), 648-667.

Dunne, P., & Hughes, a. A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the 1980s.

The Journal of Industrial Economics, 115-140.

Dunne, T., Roberts, M. J., & Samuelson, L. (1988). Patterns of firm entry and exit in US

manufacturing industries. The RAND journal of Economics, 495-515.

Dunne, T., Roberts, M. J., & Samuelson, L. (1989). The growth and failure of US manufacturing

plants. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 671-698.

Egger, H., & Egger, P. (2006). International Outsourcing and the Productivity of Low-skilled

Labor in the EU. Economic Inquiry, 44(1), 98-108.

Ehlen, M. A., Scholand, A. J., & Stamber, K. L. (2007). The effects of residential real-time

pricing contracts on transco loads, pricing, and profitability: Simulations using the N-

ABLE™ agent-based model. Energy Economics 29, no. 2, 211-227.

Page 234: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

215

Eidson, E. D., & Ehlen, M. A. (2005). NISAC Agent-Based Laboratory for Economics (N-

ABLE™): Overview of Agent and Simulation Architectures. Sandia National Laboratories

Elgar, I., Farooq, B., & Miller, E. (2009). Modeling location decisions of office firms:

Introducing anchor points and constructing choice sets in the model system.

Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, 2133,

56-63.

Elgar, I., & Miller, E. (2006). Conceptual model of location of small office firms. Transportation

Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board, (1977), 190-196.

Ellison, G., Glaeser, E. L., & Kerr., W. R. (2010). What causes industry agglomeration?

Evidence from coagglomeration patterns. The American Economic Review 100, no. 3 ,

1195-1213.

Ericson, R., & Pakes, A. (1995). Markov-perfect industry dynamics: A framework for empirical

work. The Review of Economic Studies 62, no. 1 , 53-82.

Eriksson, T., & Kuhn, J. M. (2006). Firm spin-offs in Denmark 1981–2000—patterns of entry

and exit. International Journal of Industrial Organization 24, no. 5, 1021-1040.

Evans, D. S. (1987a). Tests of alternative theories of firm growth. journal of political economy,

95(4), 657-674.

Evans, D. S. (1987b). The relationship between firm growth, size, and age: Estimates for 100

manufacturing industries. The journal of industrial economics, 567-581.

Fallick, B., Fleischman, C. A., & Rebitzer, J. B. (2006). Job-hopping in Silicon Valley: some

evidence concerning the microfoundations of a high-technology cluster. The Review of

Economics and Statistics 88, no. 3 , 472-481.

Fantasia, J. J. (1993). Are you a candidate for third party logistics?. Transportation &

Distribution, 34(1), 30.

Fischer, M., Ang-Olson, J., & La, A. (2000). External urban truck trips based on commodity

flows: a model. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the Transportation

Research Board, (1707), 73-80.

Fonseca, R., Lopez-Garcia, P., & Pissarides, C. A. (2001). Entrepreneurship, start-up costs and

employment. European Economic Review 45, no. 4 , 692-705.

Foster, R. N. (1988). Innovation: The attacker's advantage. Summit Books.

Page 235: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

216

Foster, T. A., & Muller, E. J. (1990). Third parties: your passport to profits. Distribution, 89(10),

30-32.

Fotopoulos, G., & Spence, N. (2001). Regional variations of firm births, deaths and growth

patterns in the UK, 1980–1991. Growth and Change 32, no. 2, 151-173.

Found, A. (2012). Economies of Scale in Fire and Police Services in Ontario (No. 12).

University of Toronto, Institute on Municipal Finance and Governance.

Fridstrom, L., & Madslien, A. (1994). Own account or hire freight: a stated preference analysis.

In IABTR Conference, Valle Nevado.

Friedman, D. (1998). Evolutionary economics goes mainstream: a review of the theory of

learning in games. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 8(4), 423-432.

Fries, N., & Patterson, Z. (2008, October). Carrier or Mode? The Dilemma of Shippers’ Choice

in Freight Modelling. In 8th Swiss Transport Research Conference, at Ascona,

Switzerland.

Fritsch, M., Brixy, U., & Falck, O. (2006). The effect of industry, region, and time on new

business survival–a multi-dimensional analysis. Review of industrial organization 28, no.

3, 285-306.

Gallagher, C. C., Thomason, J. C., & Daly, M. J. (1991). The growth of UK companies and their

contribution to job generation, 1985–1987. Small Business Economics, 3(4), 269-286.

Gardrat, M., Serouge, M., Toilier, F., & Gonzalez-Feliu, J. (2014). Simulating the Structure and

Localization of Activities for Decision Making and Freight Modelling: The SIMETAB

Model. Procedia-Social and Behavioral Sciences,125, 147-158.

Geroski, P. A. (1991). Market dynamics and entry. Blackwell.

Geroski, P. A. (1995). Innovation and competitive advantage. Wokring paper No. 195.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

Geroski, P., & Gugler, K. (2004). Corporate growth convergence in Europe. Oxford Economic

Papers, 56(4), 597-620.

Gibrat, R. (1931). Les inégalités économiques. Recueil Sirey.

Glaeser, E. L.(Editor). (2010). Agglomeration economics. University of Chicago Press.

Global Affairs Canada. (2016).online: http://international.gc.ca/canexport/index.aspx?lang=eng.

Global Entrepreneurship Monitor. (2016). Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM). Retrieved

2016, from http://www.gemconsortium.org/data/sets

Page 236: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

217

Gonzalez, R., Gasco, J., & Llopis, J. (2009). Information systems outsourcing reasons and risks:

an empirical study. International Journal of Human and Social Sciences, 4(3), 181-192.

Görg, H., Hanley, A., & Strobl, E. (2008). Productivity effects of international outsourcing:

evidence from plant‐level data. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne

d'économique, 41(2), 670-688.

Görg, H., Strobl, E., & Ruane, F. (2000). Determinants of firm start-up size: an application of

quantile regression for Ireland. Small Business Economics 14, no. 3 , 211-222.

Görg, H., & Strobl, E. (2002). Multinational companies and indigenous development: An

empirical analysis. European Economic Review, 46(7), 1305-1322.

Gort, M., & Klepper, S. (1982). Time paths in the diffusion of product innovations. The

economic journal, 92(367), 630-653.

Greene,W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis (Vol. 5th ed). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice

Hall.

Greene,W. H. (2008). Econometric analysis.New Jersey,USA:Prentice Hall,2008.

Greene,W. H. (2012). Econometric analysis. 7th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Greenwood, C., & Farewell, V. (1988). A comparison of regression models for ordinal data in an

analysis of transplanted kidney function. Canadian Journal of Statistics, 16(4), 325-335.

Growiec, J., Pammolli, F., Riccaboni, M., & Stanley, H. E. (2008). On the size distribution of

business firms. Economics Letters, 98(2), 207-212.

Guo, G. (1993). Event-history analysis for left-truncated data. Sociological methodology, 217-

243.

Habib, K. M. (2013). A joint discrete-continuous model considering budget constraint for the

continuous part: application in joint mode and departure time choice modelling.

Transportmetrica A: Transport Science 9, no. 2, 149-177.

Haddock, C. K., Rindskopf, D., & Shadish, W. R. (1998). Using odds ratios as effect sizes for

meta-analysis of dichotomous data: a primer on methods and issues. Psychological

Methods, 3(3), 339.

Hain, M. (2010). Labour Market Model of the Greater Toronto and Hamilton Area for

Integration within the Integrated Land Use, Transportation, Environment Modelling

System. MSc. Thesis, University of Toronto.

Page 237: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

218

Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R. S., & Miranda, J. (2013). Who creates jobs? Small versus large

versus young. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(2), 347-361.

Hannan, M. T., & Carroll, G. (1992). Dynamics of organizational populations: Density,

legitimation, and competition. Oxford University Press on Demand.

Hannan, M. T., Carroll, G. R., Dobrev, S. D., & Han, J. (1998). Organizational mortality in

European and American automobile industries Part I: Revisiting the effects of age and

size. European Sociological Review 14, no. 3, 279-302.

Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. (1989). Organization ecology.

Harhoff, D., Stahl, K., & Woywode, M. (1998). Legal form, growth and exit of West German

firms—empirical results for manufacturing, construction, trade and service industries.

The Journal of industrial economics , 46(4), 453-488.

Harmon, A. (2013). A Microsimulated Industrial and Occupation-Based Labour Market Model

for Use in the Integrated Land Use, Transportation, Environment (ILUTE) Modelling

System. University of Toronto.

Hawkins, D. M. (2004). The problem of overfitting. Journal of chemical information and

computer sciences 44, no. 1, 1-12.

He, C., & Yang, R. (2015). Determinants of firm failure: empirical evidence from China. Growth

Change, 47, 72–92.

Hendry, D. F., Pagan, A. R., & Sargan, J. D. (1984). Dynamic specification. Handbook of

econometrics, 2, 1023-1100.

Hermalin, B. E. (1992). The effects of competition on executive behavior. The RAND Journal of

Economics, 350-365.

Hodgson, G. M. (1993). Economics and evolution: bringing life back into economics. University

of Michigan Press.

Hoogstra, G. J., & Dijk, J. v. (2004). Explaining firm employment growth: does location matter?

Small business economics, 22(3-4), 179-192.

Haugh, L. D., & Box, G. E. (1977). Identification of dynamic regression (distributed lag) models

connecting two time series. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 72(357),

121-130.

Haupt, R., Kloyer, M., & Lange, M. (2007). Patent indicators for the technology life cycle

development. Research Policy, 36(3), 387-398.

Page 238: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

219

Hu, W., Cox, L. J., Wright, J., & Harris, T. R. (2008). Understanding Firms' Relocation and

Expansion Decisions Using Self-Reported Factor Importance Rating. The Review of

Regional Studies, 38(1), 67.

Hunt, J. D., Kriger, D. S., & Miller, E. J. (2005). Current operational urban land‐use–transport

modelling frameworks: A review. Transport Reviews 25, no. 3 , 329-376.

Hunt, J. D., & Stefan, K. J. (2007). Tour-based microsimulation of urban commercial

movements. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological, 41(9), 981-1013.

Huynh, K. P., & Petrunia, R. J. (2010). Age effects, leverage and firm growth. Journal of

Economic Dynamics and Control, 34(5), 1003-1013.

Jang, S. S., & Park, K. (2011). Inter-relationship between firm growth and profitability.

International Journal of Hospitality Management 30, no. 4, 027-1035.

Johnson, D. D., Price, M. E., & Vugt, M. V. (2013). Darwin's invisible hand: Market

competition, evolution and the firm. ournal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 90,

S128-S140.

Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the Evolution of Industry. Econometrica: Journal of the

Econometric Society, 649-670.

Kaplan, E. L., & Meier, P. (1958). Nonparametric estimation from incomplete observations.

Journal of the American statistical association, 53(282), 457-481.

Kehoe, T., Hur, S., Ruhl, K., & Asturias, J. (2016). Firm Entry and Exit and Aggregate Growth.

Meeting Papers, no. 573. Society for Economic Dynamics.

Khan, A. S., Abraham, J. E., & Hunt, J. D. (2002). Agent-based micro-simulation of business

establishments. Congress of the European Regional Science Association (ERSA).

Dortmund.

Khan, A. S. (2002). A system of microsimulating business establishments: analysis, design and

results. PhD Dessertation, University of Calgary.

Kirchhoff, B. A., & Phillips, B. D. (1988). The effect of firm formation and growth on job

creation in the United States. Journal of Business Venturing, 3(4), 261-272.

Klapper, L., & Richmond, C. (2011). Patterns of business creation, survival and growth:

Evidence from Africa. Labour Economics 18, S32-S44.

Klepper, S. (1996). Entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the product life cycle. The American

economic review, 562-583.

Page 239: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

220

Kmenta, J., & Gilbert, R. F. (1970). Estimation of seemingly unrelated regressions with

autoregressive disturbances. Journal of the American Statistical Association 65, no. 329,

186-197.

Kolvereid, L., & Isaksen, E. (2006). New business start-up and subsequent entry into self-

employment. Journal of Business Venturing, 21(6), 866-885.

Koster, S. (2006). Whose child. How existing firms foster new firm formation: individual start-

ups, spin-outs and spin-offs. Ipskamp, Enschede.

Kumar, S., & Kockelman, K. (2008). Tracking size, location, and interactions of businesses:

microsimulation of firm behavior in Austin, Texas. Transportation Research Record:

Journal of the Transportation Research Board 2077, 113-121.

Kurz, C. J. (2006). Outstanding outsourcers: A firm-and plant-level analysis of production

sharing.

Lankford, W. M., & Parsa, F. (1999). Outsourcing: a primer. Management Decision, 37(4), 310-

316.

Leung, D., Rispoli, L., & Chan, R. (2012). Small, medium-sized, and large businesses in the

Canadian economy: Measuring their contribution to gross domestic product from 2001

to 2008. Statistics Canada, Economic Analysis Division.

Levitt, T. (1965). Exploit the product life cycle (Vol. 43). Graduate School of Business

Administration, Harvard University.

Lewis, V. L., & Churchill, N. C. (1983). The five stages of small business growth. Harvard

business review, 61(3), 30-50.

Lindholm, A. (1994). The economics of technology-related ownership changes. Gothenburg,

Sweden: Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Chalmers University of Technology,

Department of Industrial Management and Economics.

Lommerud, K. E., Meland, F., & Sørgard, L. (2003). Unionised oligopoly, trade liberalisation

and location choice. The Economic Journal, 113(490), 782-800.

Lommerud, K. E., Meland, F., & Straume, O. R. (2009). Can deunionization lead to international

outsourcing?. Journal of International Economics, 77(1), 109-119.

Lopez-Garcia, P., & Puente, S. (2006). Business demography in Spain: determinants of firm

survival. Banco de Espana Research Paper No. WP-0608.

Page 240: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

221

Lopez-Garcia, P., Puente, S., & Gómez, Á. L. (2007). Firm productivity dynamics in Spain.

Banco de España.

Lotti, F., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2003). Does Gibrat's Law hold among young, small

firms? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 13(3), 213-235.

Lumpkin, G. T., & Dess, G. G. (2001). Linking two dimensions of entrepreneurial orientation to

firm performance: The moderating role of environment and industry life cycle. Journal of

business venturing, 16(5), 429-451.

Macdonald, R. (2014). Business Entry and Exit Rates in Canada: A 30-year Perspective.

Statistics Canada.

Mankiw, G., & Taylor, M. (2006). Microeconomics. Thomson Learning, chapter 14.

Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat's law, innovation, and the growth of firms. The American

economic review, 52(5), 1023-1051.

Manzato, G., Arentze, T., Timmermans, H., & Ettema, D. (2011). Exploration of Location

Influences on Firm Survival Rates with Parametric Duration Models. Transportation

Research Record: Journal of the Transportation Research Board 2245, 124-1.

Maoh, H. (2005). Modeling Firm Demography in Urban Areas with an Application to Hamilton,

Ontario: Towards an Agent-Based Microsimulation Model. PhD thesis (School of

Geography and Earth Sciences, McMaster University, Hamilton, ON).

Maoh, H. F., & Kanaroglou, P. S. (2005). Agent-based firmographic models: a simulation

framework for the city of Hamilton. Proceedings of PROCESSUS Second International

Colloquium on the Behavioural Foundations of Integrated Land-use and Transportation

Models: Frameworks, Models and Applications. Toronto.

Maoh, H., & Kanaroglou, P. (2007a). Business establishment mobility behavior in urban areas: a

microanalytical model for the City of Hamilton in Ontario, Canada. Journal of

Geographical Systems, 9(3), 229-252.

Maoh, H., & Kanaroglou, P. S. (2007b). Modeling the failure of small and medium size business

establishments in urban areas: an application to Hamilton, Ontario. Hamilton, Ontario:

Centre for Spatial Analysis, McMaster University.

Page 241: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

222

Maoh, H. & Kanaroglou, P. (2009) Intrametropolitan Location of Business Establishments:

Microanalytical Model for Hamilton, Ontario, Canada. Transportation Research Record:

Journal of Transportation Research Board. 2133: 33-45.

Maoh, H. & Kanaroglou, P. (2013). Modelling Firm Failure: Towards Building a Firmographic

Microsimulation Model, Employment Location. Pagliara, F., de Bok, M., Simmonds, D.,

Wilson, A.Employment Location in Cities and Regions. 2013: 243-261.

Marino, K. E., & Noble, A. F. (1997). Growth and early returns in technology-based

manufacturing ventures. The Journal of High Technology Management Research, 8(2),

225-242.

Mata, J. (1996). Markets, entrepreneurs and the size of new firms. Economics Letters 52, no. 1,

89-94.

Mata, J., & Machado, J. A. (1996). Firm start-up size: A conditional quantile approach.

European Economic Review 40, no. 6, 1305-1323.

Mata, J., & Portugal, P. (1994). Life duration of new firms. The Journal of Industrial Economics,

227-245.

Mata, J., Portugal, P., & Guimaraes, P. (1995). The survival of new plants: Start-up conditions

and post-entry evolution. International Journal of Industrial Organization 13, no. 4, 459-

481.

McCullagh, P. (1980). Regression models for ordinal data. Journal of the royal statistical

society. Series B (Methodological), 109-142.

McFadden, D. (1978). Quantitative Methods for Analysing Travel Behaviour of Individuals:

Some Recent Developments. In D. A. Hensher, & P. R. Stopher, Behavioural Travel

Modelling (pp. 306-308). London: Croom Helm.

Melillo, F., Folta, T. B., & Delmar, F. (2013). What determines the initial size of new ventures.

DRUID Celebration Conference, 35th, 2.

Miller, E. J., & Lerman, S. R. (1981). Disaggregate modelling and decisions of retail firms: a

case study of clothing retailers. Environment and Planning, 13(6), 729-746.

Miller, E. J., & Salvini, P. A. (1998). The Integrated Land Use, Transportation, Environment

(ILUTE) Modelling System: A Framework. 77th Annual Meeting of the Transportation

Research Board. Washington, DC.

Page 242: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

223

Miller, E. J., & Salvini, P. A. (2001). The Integrated Land Use, Transportation, Environment

(ILUTE) microsimulation modelling system: description and current status. In D. (.

Hensher, Travel Behaviour Research: The Leading Edge (pp. 711–724). Pergamon,

Amsterdam.

Miller, E. J., Hunt, J. D., Abraham, J. E., & Salvini, P. A. (2004). Microsimulating urban

systems. Computers, environment and urban systems 28, no. 1, 9-44.

Miller, E., Farooq, B., Chingcuanco, F. & Wang, D. (2010). Microsimulating urban spatial

dynamics: historical validation tests using the ILUTE model system. Workshop on Urban

Dynamics. Marbella, Chile.

Ministry of Finance.(2016).Government of Ontario.

http://www.fin.gov.on.ca/en/credit/oitc/index.html.

Moeckel, R. (2005). Microsimulation of firm location decisions. 9th international conference on

computers in Urban Planning and Urban Management, 7, pp. 2005-29. London.

Montemayor, H. M. V. (2014). Outsourcing Transportation Services: Evidence from Mexican

Maquiladora Industry. International Journal of Operations and Logistics

Management, 3(1), 48-57.

Mood, C. (2010). Logistic regression: Why we cannot do what we think we can do, and what we

can do about it. European sociological review, 26(1), 67-82.

Mostafa, T. S., & Roorda, M. J. (2013). A Framework and Analysis of Firm Evolution Processes.

METRANS 2013 International Urban Freight Conference. Long Beach, CA.

Mostafa, T. S., & Roorda, M. J. (2015). A Conceptual Framework for Modelling Firmography.

Canadian Transportation Research Forum 50th Annual Conference. Montreal, Quebec.

Mostafa, T. S., & Roorda, M. J. (2016). A Review of Firmography in Freight Microsimulation

Modelling. Transport Reviews.

Mostafa, T. S., & Roorda, M. J. (2017). Discrete Choice Modeling of Freight Outsourcing

Decisions of Canadian Manufacturers . Transportation Research Record.

Mostafa, T. S., & Roorda, M. J. (2017). Discrete Choice Modeling of Freight Outsourcing

Decisions of Canadian Manufacturers . 96th Annual Meeting og the Transportation

Research Board. Washington, DC.

Page 243: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

224

Mostafa, T., & Roorda, M. (2013). A Structural Equation Model of Commercial Vehicle

Ownership. Paper presented at the hEART Conference - 2nd Symposium of the European

Association for Research in Transportation. Stockholm.

Mueller, D. C. (1972). A life cycle theory of the firm. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 199-

219.

Mukherjee, S., Mukherjee, M., & Ghose, A. (2004). Microeconomics. Pages: 119-148.

Myers, M. H., Hankey, B. F., & Mantel, N. (1973). A logistic-exponential model for use with

response-time data involving regressor variables. Biometrics , 257-269.

Nandkeolyar, U., Rao, S. S., & Rana, K. (1993). Facility life cycles. Omega, 21(2), 245-254.

Nunes, A., & Sarmento, E. (2010). Business survival in portuguese regions. GEMF Working

Papers.

Nyström, K. (2007). An industry disaggregated analysis of the determinants of regional entry and

exit. The Annals of Regional Science 41, no. 4 , 877-896.

OECD. (2008). OECD Economic Surveys: Canada 2008. OECD Publishing.

Ontario Chamber of Commerce.(2015).OCC Funding for Ontario Exporters.Online:

http://www.occ.ca/sme-programs/occ-funding-for-ontario-exporters/.

Otter, H. S., van der Veen, A., & de Vriend, H. J. (2001). ABLOoM: Location behaviour, spatial

patterns, and agent-based modelling. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social

Simulation, 4(4).

Park, K., & Jang, S. S. (2010). Firm growth patterns: examining the associations with firm size

and internationalization. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 29(3), 368-

377.

Pagano, P., & Schivardi, F. (2003). Firm size distribution and growth. The Scandinavian Journal

of Economics, 105(2), 255-274.

Park, K., & Jang, S. S. (2011). Mergers and acquisitions and firm growth: Investigating

restaurant firms. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 30(1), 141-149.

Pasidis, I.-N. (2013, July 16). Why do shops cluster? Spatial competition and collaboration in the

retail sector of f the Netherlands. Amesterdam, Netherlands.

Page 244: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

225

Pendyala, R., Shankar, V., & McCullough, R. (2000). Freight travel demand modeling: synthesis

of approaches and development of a framework. Transportation Research Record:

Journal of the Transportation Research Board, (1725), 9-16.

Pérez, S. E., Llopis, A. S., & Llopis, J. A. (2004). The determinants of survival of Spanish

manufacturing firms. Review of Industrial Organization 25, no. 3, 251-273.

Piacentino, D., Espa, G., Filipponi, D., & Giuliani., D. (2016). Firm Demography and Regional

Development: Evidence from Italy. Growth and Change.

Polli, R., & Cook, V. (1969). Validity of the product life cycle. The Journal of Business, 42(4),

385-400.

Pourabdollahi, Z., Karimi, B., Mohammadian, K., & Kawamura, K. (2016). A Hybrid Agent-

based Computational Economics and Optimization Approach for Supplier Selection

Problem 2. In Transportation Research Board 95th Annual Meeting (No. 16-4865).

Pourabdollahi, Z., Mohammadian, A. K., & Kawamura, K. (2012). A behavioral freight

transportation modeling system: an operational and proposed framework. In Proceedings

of the 14th Annual International Conference on Electronic Commerce (pp. 196-203).

ACM.

Praag, C. M. (1997). Determinants of succesful entrepreneurship. The Tinbergen Institute

Research Series no. 112. Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam

Prais, S. J., & Winsten, C. B. (1954). Trend estimators and serial correlation. Working paper

383, Cowles Commission.

Quinn, J. B., & Hilmer, F. G. (1994). Strategic outsourcing. Sloan management review, 35(4),

43.

Rainey, D. L. (2008). Product innovation: leading change through integrated product

development. Cambridge University Press.

Rao, K., & Young, R. R. (1994). Global supply chains: factors influencing outsourcing of

logistics functions. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics

Management, 24(6), 11-19.

Reid, G. C. (1995). Early life-cycle behaviour of micro-firms in Scotland. Small Business

Economics, 7(2), 89-95.

Reynolds, P. D. (1987). New firms: societal contribution versus survival potential. Journal of

Business Venturing 2, no. 3, 231-246.

Page 245: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

226

Reynolds, P. D. (1997). Who starts new firms?–Preliminary explorations of firms-in-gestation.

Small Business Economics 9, no. 5, 449-462.

Reynolds, P., Storey, D. J., & Westhead, P. (1994). Cross-national comparisons of the variation

in new firm formation rates. Regional Studies, 28(4), 443-456.

Reynolds, P. D., & White, S. B. (1997). The entrepreneurial process: Economic growth, men,

women, and minorities. Praeger Pub Text.

Richards, E., Snoddon, C., & Brown, J. (2014). Manufacturing: The Yea 2014 in Review.

Analytical Paper, Analysis in Brief. Statistics Canada. Issue #:2015097,no.97,2014

Richardson, H. L. (1992). Outsourcing: the power worksource. Transportation & Distribution,

July, 22-4.

Richardson, H. L. (1993). Economy spurs growth in outsourcing. Transportation & Distribution,

45-7.

Robb, A. M., & Coleman, S. (2010). Financing strategies of new technology-based firms: a

comparison of women-and men-owned firms. Journal of technology management &

innovation, 5(1), 30-50.

Robin, T., Antonini, G., Bierlaire, M., & Cruz, J. (2009). Specification, estimation and validation

of a pedestrian walking behavior model. Transportation Research Part B:

Methodological 43, no. 1, 36-56.

Roorda, M. J., Cavalcante, R., McCabe, S., & Kwan, H. (2010). A conceptual framework for

agent-based modelling of logistics services. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics

and Transportation Review 46, no. 1, 18-31.

Roorda, M. J., Miller, E. J., & Habib, K. M. (2008). Validation of TASHA: A 24-h activity

scheduling microsimulation model. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice

42, no. 2, 360-375.

Salvini, P., & Miller, E. J. (2005). ILUTE: An operational prototype of a comprehensive

microsimulation model of urban systems. Networks and Spatial Economics 5, no. 2, 217-

234.

Samimi, A., Mohammadian, A., Kawamura, K., & Pourabdollahi, Z. (2014). An activity-based

freight mode choice microsimulation model. Transportation Letters, 6(3), 142-151.

Scherr, F. C., Sugrue, T. F., & Ward, J. B. (1993). Financing the small firm start-up:

Determinants of debt use. The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance, 3(1), 17.

Page 246: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

227

Schröder, P. J., & Sørensen, A. (2012). Firm exit, technological progress and trade. European

Economic Review 56, no. 3, 579-591.

Schrör, H. (2009). Business Demography: employment and survival. eurostat.

Segal, U., & Spivak, A. (1989). Firm size and optimal growth rates. European Economic

Review, 33(1),159-167.

Senses, M. Z. (2004). The Effects of Outsourcing on the Elasticity of Labor Demand. Available

at SSRN 837744.

Seo, S. (2006). A review and comparison of methods for detecting outliers in univariate data

sets. University of Pittsburgh.

Shane, S., Kolvereid, L., & Westhead, P. (1991). An exploratory examination of the reasons

leading to new firm formation across country and gender. Journal of business venturing,

6(6), 431-446.

Shanmugam, K. R., & Bhaduri, S. N. (2002). Size, age and firm growth in the Indian

manufacturing sector. Applied Economics Letters 9, no. 9, 607-613.

Shapiro, D., & Khemani, R. S. (1987). The determinants of entry and exit reconsidered.

International Journal of Industrial Organization 5, no. 1, 15-26.

Sharapov, D., Kattuman, P., & Sena, V. (2011). Technological Environments, R&D Investment,

and Firm Survival. MICRO-DYN Working Paper 34/10.

Sheffi, Y. (1990). Third party logistics: present and future prospects. Journal of Business

Logistics, 11(2), 27.

Shook, C. L., Priem, R. L., & McGee, J. E. (2003). Venture creation and the enterprising

individual: A review and synthesis. Journal of Management, 29(3), 379-399.

Siegfried, J. J., & Evans, L. B. (1994). Empirical studies of entry and exit: a survey of the

evidence. Review of Industrial Organization 9, no. 2, 121-155.

Singh, A., & Whittington, G. (1975). The size and growth of firms. The Review of Economic

Studies, 42(1), 15-26.

Smithson, M., & Merkle, E. C. (2013). Generalized linear models for categorical and continuous

limited dependent variables. CRC Press.

Soni, P. K., Lilien, G. L., & Wilson, D. T. (1993). Industrial innovation and firm performance: A

re-conceptualization and exploratory structural equation analysis. International Journal

of Research in Marketing, 10(4), 365-380.

Page 247: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

228

StataCorp. (2013). Stata: Release 13. Statistical Software. College Station, TX: StataCorp LP.

Statistics Canada. (2009). Highlights of the Survey of Innovation and Business Strategy (SIBS).

Retrieved from https://www.ic.gc.ca/eic/site/eas-aes.nsf/vwapj/SIBS_summary-

EISE_resume-eng.pdf/$file/SIBS_summary-EISE_resume-eng.pdf

Statistics Canada. (2004). The economy: Year-end review. Retrieved from anadian Economic

Observer, Vol. 17, no. 4: http://www.statcan.gc.ca/daily-quotidien/040414/dq040414b-

eng.htm

Statistics Canada. (2012a). The T2-LEAP User Guide, 1984-2010. Statiscs Canada.

Statistics Canada. (2012b). Survey of Innovation and Business Strategy. Retrieved from

http://www23.statcan.gc.ca/imdb-bmdi/instrument/5171_Q1_V2-eng.pdf

Statistics Canada. (2014). CANSIM: Table 552-001 – Canadian business patterns, location

counts with employees, by employment size and North American Classification System

(NAICS), Canada and provinces, December 2014. Retrieved 2017 from:

http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a26?lang=eng&retrLang=eng&id=5520001&&pattern

=&stByVal=1&p1=1&p2=31&tabMode=dataTable&csid=

Statistics Canada. (2015a). CANSIM: Table 282-0087 - Labour force survey estimates (LFS), by

sex and age group. Retrieved 2015, from

http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a26?lang=eng&retrLang=eng&id=2820087&&pattern

=&stByVal=1&p1=1&p2=37&tabMode=dataTable&csid=

Statistics Canada. (2015b). CANSIM: Table 379-0030 - Gross domestic product (GDP) at basic

prices, by North American Industry Classification System (NAICS), provinces and

territories. Retrieved 2015, from

http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a26?lang=eng&id=3790030

Statistics Canada. (2016a). CANSIM: Table 527-0007 - Business dynamics measures, by North

American Industry Classification System (NAICS), provinces and the territories.

Retrieved September 2016, from http://www5.statcan.gc.ca/cansim/a47

Statistics Canada. (2016b). The Canadian Centre for Data Development an Economic Research

(CDER). Retrieved 12 10, 2016, from http://www.statcan.gc.ca/eng/cder/index

Statistics Canada. (2016c). Canadian Economy (NAICS 11-91): Establishments. Retrieved

January 2017 from:

https://www.ic.gc.ca/app/scr/sbms/sbb/cis/establishments.html?code=11-91&lang=eng

Page 248: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

229

Statistics Canada. (2016d). Key Small Business Statistics - June 2016. Retrieved January 2017

from: https://www.ic.gc.ca/eic/site/061.nsf/eng/03027.html

Stearns, T. M., Carter, N. M., Reynolds, P. D., & Williams, M. L. (1995). New firm survival:

industry, strategy, and location. Journal of business venturing 10, no. 1, 23-42.

Storey, D. J. (1982). Entrepreneurship and the new firm. Taylor & Francis.

Strotmann, H. (2007). Entrepreneurial survival. Small business economics 28, no. 1, 87-104.

Tether, B. S. (1998). Small and large firms: sources of unequal innovations?. Research

Policy, 27(7),725-745.

Theil, H. (1961). Economic forecasts and policy.

Tibben-Lembke, R. S. (2002). Life after death: reverse logistics and the product life

cycle. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management, 32(3),

223-244.

UCLA. (2007). Introduction to SAS. UCLA: Academic Technology Services, Statistical

Consulting Group. Retrieved August 15, 2016, from

http://www.ats.ucla.edu/stat/stata/faq/oratio.htm

van Dijk, J., & Pellenbarg, P. (2000). Demography of firms: progress and problems in empirical

research. In: P.H. Pellenbarg & J. van Dijk (eds) Demography of firms: spatial dynamics

of firm behaviour. Nederlandse Geografische Studies 262. Utrecht/Groningen: Koninklijk

Nederlands Aardrijkskundig Genootschap/faculteit der Ruimtelijke Wetenschappen

Rijksuniversiteit Groningen, p. 325-337.

van Wissen, L. (1996). Demography of the firm: modelling and death of firms using the concept

of carrying capacity. In: Van den Brekel H, Deven F (eds) Population and families in the

low countries 1996/1997. NIDI/CBGS, series. The Hague, Brussels.

van Wissen, L. (2000). A micro-simulation model of firms: applications of concepts of the

demography of the firm. Papers in Regional Science 79, no. 2, 111-134.

Variyam, J. N., & Kraybill, D. S. (1992). Empirical evidence on determinants of firm growth.

Economics Letters, 38(1), 31-36.

Verbeek, M. (2008). A guide to modern econometrics. . John Wiley & Sons.

Waddell, P. (2002). UrbanSim: Modeling urban development for land use, transportation, and

environmental planning. Journal of the American Planning Association 68, no. 3, 297-

314.

Page 249: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

230

Wagner, J. (1992). Firm size, firm growth, and persistence of chance: Testing GIBRAT's law

with establishment data from Lower Saxony, 1978–1989. Small Business

Economics, 4(2), 125-131.

Wagner, J. (1994). The post-entry performance of new small firms in German manufacturing

industries. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 141-154.

Wagner, J. (1999). The life history of cohorts of exits from German manufacturing. Small

Business Economics 13, no. 1, 71-79.

Walsh, S. K., & Boyland, R. (1996). Founer background and entrepreneurial success:

Implications of core competence strategy application to new ventures. In P. Reynolads, S.

Birley, J. Butler, W. Bygrave, P. Davidsson, W. Gartner, & P. McDougall, Frontiers of

Entrepreneurship Research (pp. 146-154). Babson Park, US: Babson College.

Wang, Z. (2006). Learning, diffusion and industry life cycle. manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank

of Kansas City.

Wegener, M. (1995). Current and future land use models. Travel Model Improvement Program

Land Use Model Conference. Dallas , Texas.

Weiss, C. R. (1998). Size, growth, and survival in the upper Austrian farm sector. Small Business

Economics, 10(4), 305-312.

Wicksteed, P. H. (1910). The common sense of political economy.

Williams, F. P., D'Souza, D. E., Rosenfeldt, M. E., & Kassaee, M. (1995). Manufacturing

strategy, business strategy and firm performance in a mature industry. Journal of

Operations Management, 13(1), 19-33.

Windmeijer, F. A. (1995). Goodness-of-fit measures in binary choice models. Econometric

Reviews 14, no. 1, 101-116.

Winter, S. G., & Nelson, R. R. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. University

of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign's Academy for Entrepreneurial Leadership Historical

Research Reference in Entrepreneurship.

Wisetjindawat, W., Sano, K., Matsumoto, S., & Raothanachonkun, P. (2007). Micro-simulation

model for modeling freight agents interactions in urban freight movement. In CD

Proceedings, 86th Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research Board, Washington

DC (pp. 21-25).

Page 250: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

231

Yasuda, T. (2005). Firm growth, size, age and behavior in Japanese manufacturing. Small

Business Economics, no. 1(24), 1-15.

Zhang, M., & Mohnen, P. (2013). Innovation and survival of new firms in Chinese

manufacturing, 2000-2006. United Nations University, Maastrecht Economic and Social

Research Training Centre on Innovation and Technology.

Page 251: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

232

Appendix A. Additional Tables

TABLE A. 1 Firm Start-up Employment Size by Industry Class

Industry Class

NAICS

2-digit

code

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Avg.

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 11 2.5 2.4 2.3 2.4 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.4 2.0 2.0 2.2

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 21 1.7 1.8 1.7 1.7 1.8 1.6 1.7 1.7 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.6

Utilities 22 Suppressed

Construction 23 2.4 2.3 2.1 2.0 2.1 2.1 2.0 2.0 2.0 1.9 1.8 2.1

Manufacturing 31-33 4.0 4.5 3.6 4.1 3.8 3.0 3.5 2.9 2.8 3.2 5.0 3.7

Wholesale trade 41 2.5 2.4 2.2 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.0 2.1 2.4 1.9 1.9 2.1

Retail trade 44-45 3.0 3.0 2.6 2.6 2.5 2.6 2.8 2.5 2.4 2.2 2.8 2.6

Transportation and warehousing 48-49 2.2 2.0 1.9 1.9 2.0 1.9 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.7 1.9

Information and cultural industries 51 3.9 3.8 3.4 3.9 3.8 3.0 3.2 2.8 2.7 2.6 3.8 3.4

Finance and insurance 52 2.6 2.5 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.5 2.8 2.4 2.4 2.1 2.7 2.5

Real estate and rental and leasing 53 2.3 2.2 2.1 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 1.9 1.9 1.8 1.8 2.0

Professional, scientific and technical services 54 1.9 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.8 1.7 1.7 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.6 1.7

Management of companies and enterprises 55 Suppressed

Administrative and support, waste management

and remediation services 56 3.6 3.3 3.2 3.7 3.3 2.7 3.1 2.8 2.6 2.5 3.5 3.1

Arts, entertainment and recreation 71 3.3 3.1 3.1 2.8 2.8 2.7 3.0 2.8 2.6 2.3 3.5 2.9

Accommodation and food services 71 4.8 4.8 4.4 4.2 4.1 3.9 4.0 3.3 3.4 4.0 5.2 4.2

Other services (except public administration) 81 2.2 2.2 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 1.9 1.9 1.8 1.7 2.0

Page 252: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

233

TABLE A. 2 Average Firm Size by Industry Class

Industry Class

NAICS

2-digit

code

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Avg.

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing

and Hunting 11 5.5 4.9 4.6 4.9 4.7 4.5 4.6 5.3 4.6 4.0 3.6 4.0 4.6

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil

and Gas Extraction 21 144.6 131.7 148.0 132.1 130.8 126.5 146.0 162.4 131.9 118.0 126.1 135.4 136.1

Utilities 22 818.0 783.7 682.3 768.5 859.6 913.5 921.1 1116.5 1410.0 1225.8 1359.1 1369.0 1018.9

Construction 23 9.2 9.9 10.4 10.6 11.8 11.6 11.7 12.6 12.5 12.4 13.3 13.6 11.6

Manufacturing 31-33 203.2 186.4 184.3 171.3 177.3 180.3 154.0 143.4 132.4 117.6 109.4 112.1 156.0

Wholesale trade 41 28.0 26.7 25.7 23.2 25.5 26.5 26.2 24.5 24.7 25.2 23.9 23.1 25.3

Retail trade 44-45 142.1 154.1 152.3 152.1 167.5 175.8 168.0 154.0 157.5 156.5 154.4 159.6 157.8

Transportation and

warehousing 48-49 271.7 281.2 240.1 246.3 229.5 242.5 272.4 254.7 242.4 214.3 198.8 211.9 242.1

Information and cultural

industries 51 575.5 535.4 436.1 405.5 369.5 345.3 300.7 345.1 318.5 281.5 240.6 217.9 364.3

Finance and insurance 52 90.0 84.9 80.6 72.5 74.6 75.6 77.8 73.2 80.2 77.0 74.8 79.1 78.4

Real estate and rental and

leasing 53 11.2 11.6 10.6 9.6 9.0 11.2 10.4 9.4 14.8 14.4 13.7 16.6 11.9

Professional, scientific and

technical services 54 17.8 16.1 16.7 15.5 16.0 16.3 15.4 15.7 16.1 14.1 14.4 14.3 15.7

Management of companies and

enterprises 55 9.3 9.0 8.6 9.7 12.2 14.6 17.0 15.0 20.7 20.6 22.9 27.8 15.6

Administrative and support,

waste management and

remediation services

56 27.1 26.3 25.8 24.1 24.3 25.7 24.2 23.5 22.4 21.3 20.9 21.4 23.9

Arts, entertainment and

recreation 71 18.0 18.9 23.6 23.4 25.1 23.8 25.2 26.8 23.5 23.3 22.6 22.1 23.0

Accommodation and food

services 71 48.4 49.2 50.6 46.6 47.2 50.3 48.3 46.2 47.8 49.3 44.6 46.1 47.9

Other services (except public

administration) 81 9.2 7.1 6.2 6.2 7.0 6.6 6.3 6.6 6.6 6.9 6.3 6.7 6.8

Page 253: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

234

TABLE A. 3 Linear Regression Model of Firm Start-up Size: Short Model

Number of observation 232236

F( 19,168569) 948.14

Prob > F 0.000

R-squared 0.086

Adj R-squared 0.086

Root MSE 0.704

Source SS df MS

Model 10853.47 20 542.674

Residual 115184.6 15 0.496

Total 126038.1 35 0.543

Covariates Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t|

Province: Rest of Canada Reference

Ontario -0.087 0.007 -11.62 0.000

Quebec -0.050 0.008 -6.05 0.000

Alberta -0.188 0.007 -25.87 0.000

British Columbia -0.081 0.008 -10.43 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.127 0.011 11.1 0.000

Industry Class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and

Hunting -0.237 0.012 -20.51 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas

Extraction -0.284 0.014 -19.84 0.000

Utilities and Manufacturing Reference

Construction -0.246 0.007 -32.83 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.224 0.010 -22.89 0.000

Retail trade -0.057 0.008 -7.42 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.384 0.009 -44.4 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.030 0.013 -2.26 0.024

Finance and insurance -0.217 0.013 -16.5 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.283 0.011 -25.1 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical

services -0.364 0.007 -48.79 0.000

Management of companies and

enterprises -0.081 0.009 -8.94 0.000

Administrative and support, waste

management and remediation services Reference

Arts, entertainment and recreation -0.107 0.013 -8.06 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.290 0.008 37.5 0.000

Other services (except public

administration) -0.228 0.008 -27.19 0.000

Economic Indicator of previous year’s (t-1)

Provincial unemployment rate -0.012 0.001 -9.91 0.000

_cons 0.836 0.011 75.89 0.000

Page 254: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

235

TABLE A. 4 Linear Regression Model for Firm Start-up Size: Detailed Model

Number of observation 232236

F( 19,168569) 948.14

Prob > F 0.000

R-squared 0.086

Adj R-squared 0.086

Root MSE 0.704

Source SS df MS

Model 10853.47 20 542.674

Residual 115184.6 15 0.496

Total 126038.1 35 0.543

Covariates Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t|

Province: Ontario -0.055 0.009 -6.060 0.000

Quebec -0.021 0.010 -2.080 0.037

Alberta -0.168 0.009 -19.300 0.000

British Columbia -0.064 0.009 -6.930 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.110 0.014 8.120 0.000

Industry Class

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas

Extraction -0.322 0.017 -19.530 0.000

Construction -0.070 0.006 -12.070 0.000

Wholesale trade -0.122 0.010 -12.640 0.000

Retail trade -0.107 0.009 -11.590 0.000

Transportation and warehousing -0.328 0.009 -37.660 0.000

Information and cultural industries -0.129 0.017 -7.660 0.000

Finance and insurance -0.203 0.015 -13.150 0.000

Real estate and rental and leasing -0.111 0.011 -9.800 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical

services -0.208 0.006 -33.740 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.388 0.007 53.570 0.000

Provincial unemployment rate of

previous year -0.013 0.002 -8.540 0.000

Industry dynamics and

competition of previous year’s (t-1)

Firm exit rate by industry (%) -0.004 0.001 -3.840 0.000

(log) Number of competitors

(CMA/CA and NAICS 3-Digit code) -0.014 0.001 -13.880 0.000

(log) Average firm size by industry

(2-digit NAICS) 0.083 0.003 27.480 0.000

_cons 0.571 0.016 36.510 0.000

Page 255: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

236

TABLE A. 5 A Linear 3-level Random Intercept Only Model: Estimation Results

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log) Age 0.037 0.000 111.71 0.000

Province

Quebec 0.042 0.002 19.13 0.000

Alberta -

0.130 0.002 -57.46 0.000

British Columbia -

0.073 0.002 -31.85 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.117 0.004 31.38 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.052 0.008 6.26 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.032 0.011 2.95 0.003

Utilities 0.770 0.033 23.44 0.000

Construction 0.203 0.008 26.57 0.000

Manufacturing 0.740 0.008 90.8 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.369 0.008 45.73 0.000

Retail trade 0.555 0.008 71.83 0.000

trans_48_49 0.024 0.008 2.95 0.003

Information and cultural industries 0.185 0.010 18.69 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.016 0.009 1.85 0.064

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.031 0.008 3.71 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -

0.085 0.008 -11.25 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.386 0.008 46.98 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.367 0.010 38.45 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.980 0.008 123.65 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.288 0.008 36.45 0.000

Economic indicators

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.002 0.000 45.64 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of (t-1) -

0.007 0.000 -41.31 0.000

_cons 0.723 0.007 97.15 0.000

Random-effects Parameters Estimate Std. Err.

unique_id: Identity (Firm Level)

var(_cons) 0.388 0.021

ind_id: Identity (Industry Level)

var(_cons) 0.388 0.021

var(Residual) 0.144 0.000

Page 256: A Microsimulation Platform of Firm Evolution Processes · develops a firm modelling framework, called the firmographic engine. The goal of the framework is to evaluate the implications

237

TABLE A. 6 A Linear 4-level Random Intercept Only Model: Estimation Results

Covariates Coef. Std.

Err. z P>|z|

(log) Age 0.037 0.000 111.71 0.000

Province

Quebec 0.042 0.002 19.13 0.000

Alberta -0.130 0.002 -57.46 0.000

British Columbia -0.073 0.002 -31.85 0.000

Atlantic Canada 0.117 0.004 31.38 0.000

Industry class

Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 0.052 0.008 6.26 0.000

Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 0.032 0.011 2.95 0.003

Utilities 0.770 0.033 23.44 0.000

Construction 0.203 0.008 26.57 0.000

Manufacturing 0.740 0.008 90.8 0.000

Wholesale trade 0.369 0.008 45.73 0.000

Retail trade 0.555 0.008 71.83 0.000

trans_48_49 0.024 0.008 2.95 0.003

Information and cultural industries 0.185 0.010 18.69 0.000

Finance and insurance 0.016 0.009 1.85 0.064

Real estate and rental and leasing 0.031 0.008 3.71 0.000

Professional, scientific and technical services -0.085 0.008 -11.25 0.000

Administrative and support, waste management and

remediation services 0.386 0.008 46.98 0.000

Arts, entertainment and recreation 0.367 0.010 38.45 0.000

Accommodation and food services 0.980 0.008 123.65 0.000

Other services (except public administration) 0.288 0.008 36.45 0.000

Economic indicators

GDP growth (%) by industry 0.002 0.000 45.64 0.000

Yearly provincial unemployment rate (%) of (t-1) -0.007 0.000 -41.31 0.000

_cons 0.723 0.007 97.15 0.000

Random-effects Parameters Estimate Std. Err.

unique_id: Identity (Firm Level)

var(_cons) 0.259 0.041

ind_id: Identity (Industry Level)

var(_cons) 0.259 0.033

ind_id: Identity Province Level)

var(_cons) 0.259 0.040

var(Residual) 0.144 0.000


Recommended