+ All Categories
Home > Documents > A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax...

A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax...

Date post: 14-Mar-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 4 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
46
A Schumpeterian Analysis of Decit-Financed Dividend Tax Cuts Pietro F. Peretto Department of Economics Duke University January 23, 2009 Abstract I propose a Schumpeterian analysis of the e/ects of a decit-nanced cut of the tax rate on distributed dividends. I develop a very tractable model that allows me to study analytically transition dynamics and welfare, and complement the qualitative results with a quantitative assessment of the Job Growth and Taxpayer Relief Reconciliation Act (JGTRRA) of 2003. I nd that the JGTRRA produces lower steady- state growth despite the fact that the economys saving and employ- ment ratios rise. Most importantly, it produces a welfare loss. The mechanism that delivers these results is that the tax rate on distrib- uted dividends distorts the returns to investing in the growth of exist- ing product lines and in the development of new product lines. The quantitative exercise suggests that the JGTRRA will reduce welfare by 19.34% of annual consumption per capita, a substantial e/ect driven by the fact that the steady-state growth rate falls from 2% to 1.08%. Keywords: Endogenous Growth, Market Structure, Dividends, Cor- porate Taxation. JEL Classication Numbers: E10, L16, O31, O40 Address: Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708. Phone: (919) 6601807. Fax: (919) 6848974. E-mail: [email protected] 1
Transcript
Page 1: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

A Schumpeterian Analysis of De�cit-FinancedDividend Tax Cuts

Pietro F. Peretto�

Department of EconomicsDuke University

January 23, 2009

Abstract

I propose a Schumpeterian analysis of the e¤ects of a de�cit-�nancedcut of the tax rate on distributed dividends. I develop a very tractablemodel that allows me to study analytically transition dynamics andwelfare, and complement the qualitative results with a quantitativeassessment of the Job Growth and Taxpayer Relief Reconciliation Act(JGTRRA) of 2003. I �nd that the JGTRRA produces lower steady-state growth despite the fact that the economy�s saving and employ-ment ratios rise. Most importantly, it produces a welfare loss. Themechanism that delivers these results is that the tax rate on distrib-uted dividends distorts the returns to investing in the growth of exist-ing product lines and in the development of new product lines. Thequantitative exercise suggests that the JGTRRA will reduce welfare by19.34% of annual consumption per capita, a substantial e¤ect drivenby the fact that the steady-state growth rate falls from 2% to 1.08%.

Keywords: Endogenous Growth, Market Structure, Dividends, Cor-porate Taxation.JEL Classi�cation Numbers: E10, L16, O31, O40

�Address: Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708. Phone:(919) 6601807. Fax: (919) 6848974. E-mail: [email protected]

1

Page 2: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

1 Introduction

The dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and TaxpayerRelief Reconciliation Act (JGTRRA) has generated a heated public debateand prompted a new wave of research in public and corporate �nance. Sup-porters argue that the Act has reduced the corporate cost of capital andthus raised investment, growth and employment. Critics focus on its dis-tributional implications and on the budget de�cits that it is has generated,given the government�s failure to reduce public spending.

As a large-scale experiment in �scal policy, the JGTRRA provides aunique research opportunity for modern growth economics since one of thecentral ideas � perhaps the central idea � driving the �eld is precisely thatpolicy matters. The theory of endogenous innovation, in particular, hasproduced novel analytical insights that appear well-suited to make a signi�-cant contribution to a debate spurred by a drastic change in the taxation ofcorporate-source income, and heavily loaded on both sides with argumentsthat rely on notions of entrepreneurship, corporate behavior, and their ef-fects on innovation, job creation and growth.

In this paper, I propose a Schumpeterian analysis of the e¤ects of ade�cit-�nanced cut of the tax rate on distributed dividends. I develop a verytractable model that allows me to study analytically transition dynamics andwelfare in response to changes in tax policy. I then calibrate the model andcarry out a quantitative exercise that allows me to assess the magnitudeof the e¤ects. I �nd that the policy produces lower steady-state growthdespite the fact that the economy�s saving and employment ratios rise. Mostimportantly, the policy produces a welfare loss.

The apparently contradictory behavior of saving and growth, and thepivotal role of product variety in determining the sign of the welfare e¤ect,is a quite natural implication of the latest vintage of Schumpeterian modelsthat sterilize the scale e¤ect through a process of product proliferation thatfragments the aggregate market into submarkets whose size does not increasewith the size of the workforce.1 This approach allows one to introduce pop-

1First-generation endogenous growth models feature a positive relation between aggre-gate market size and growth that results in a positive relation, not supported by the data,between the scale of aggregate economic activity and the growth rate of income per capita.Several contributions proposed solutions based on product proliferation: Peretto (1998,1999), Dinopoulos and Thompson (1998), Young (1998), and Howitt (1999). See Aghionand Howitt (1998, 2006), Dinopoulos and Thompson (1999), Jones (1999), Peretto andSmulders (2002) for reviews of the various approaches and of the early empirical evidence.This version of Schumpeterian theory has recently received considerable empirical supportin Ha and Howitt (2006), Laincz and Peretto (2006), Sedgley (2006), Ulku (2007) and,

2

Page 3: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

ulation growth and elastic labor supply without generating counterfactualbehavior of the growth rate. It also implies that fundamentals and policyvariables that work through the size of the aggregate market have no growthe¤ects, whereas fundamentals and policy variables that reallocate resourcesbetween vertical (quality/productivity) and horizontal (variety) innovationdo have long-run growth e¤ects.

The mechanism that delivers my results, then, is that taxes on corporate-source income � in particular distributed dividends � distort the returnsto investing in the growth of existing product lines and in the developmentof new product lines, and thus reallocate resources across activities thathave di¤erent long-run growth opportunity. The feature that drives thisdi¤erence in growth opportunity is a �xed operating cost per product linethat draws a sharp distinction between the two dimensions of technologyspace. Speci�cally, steady-state growth driven by product variety expansioncannot occur independently of population growth because the �xed costper product line implies that at any point in time the size of the workforceconstrains the feasible number of product lines. In the vertical dimension, incontrast, steady-state growth is feasible because improving product qualitydoes not require the replication of �xed costs.2

Given the model�s tractability, I �rst provide analytical results on thegrowth and welfare e¤ects of dividend tax cuts. I then undertake a quantita-tive analysis to assess the magnitude of these e¤ects in a speci�cation of thepolicy change that replicates the JGTRRA. The �rst exercise develops in-sight on the model�s mechanics that helps substantially in the interpretationof the quantitative results.

In the qualitative analysis I posit that the government uses lump-sumtaxes to balance the budget, holds constant the fraction of GDP allocated to(unproductive) public expenditures, and reduces the tax rate on the dividendincome earned by households. The results apply to the case of public debtsince Ricardian equivalence holds so that what matters to agents is thepresent value of the tax liability, not the timing of taxation. The economy�sresponse to the tax cut is as follows.

� The saving ratio jumps up and then converges from above to a per-manently higher value.

� The employment ratio jumps up and then converges from above to apermanently higher value.

especially, Madsen (2008).2See Peretto and Connolly (2007) for a detailed discussion of this property in endoge-

nous growth models.

3

Page 4: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

� The higher investment sustained by the higher saving and employmentratios does not necessarily translate into an acceleration of income percapita growth because the �nancial market reallocates resources fromquality growth to variety expansion. Growth accelerates if the latterproduces su¢ ciently high aggregate productivity gains through spe-cialization that compensate the slowdown of quality growth. This re-allocation, moreover, is in the direction of the low long-run growth op-portunity activity so that growth accelerates, if at all, only temporarilyand the economy converges to a steady state with lower growth.

� The higher saving and employment ratios have a cost in terms of fore-gone consumption and leisure. Similarly, the lower steady-state growthhas a cost. If the contribution of product variety to aggregate outputis small, the expansion of the mass of �rms induced by the tax cutdoes not o¤set these costs and welfare falls. If the contribution issu¢ ciently large, instead, welfare rises.

Why does the dividend tax cut trigger such a reallocation of investmente¤ort? The answer is that the lower tax on dividends implies that �rmscan deliver to stockholders (savers) their reservation after-tax rate of returnwith a lower pre-tax rate of return. The question, then, becomes how themarket generates such lower pre-tax return. The answer turns around twokey relations. One is the relation between the cash �ow of the �rm andthe pre-tax return it generates, which re�ects the fact that since R&D is a�xed, sunk cost there are increasing returns internal to the �rm. The otheris the relation between cash �ow and growth of the �rm, which stems fromthe no-arbitrage requirement that the returns to quality growth and varietyexpansion be equal. The intuition behind this relation is simply that thereturn to the creation of a new product line � with the associated creationof a new �rm bearing its own �xed operating cost � is more sensitive tomarket size than the improvement of quality within an existing product line,which does not require the replication of �xed operating costs. The jointoperation of these relations yields that, in equilibrium, delivering a lowerpre-tax return implies slower quality growth.

In the quantitative analysis I posit that the government reduces the taxrate on the dividend income earned by households from 35% to 15% andthe tax rate on capital gains from 20% to 15% and �nances the revenueshortfall with debt. This replicates the provisions of the JGTRRA andits de facto implementation in 2003. I �nd that the model�s transition lastsabout 30 years. The saving ratio rises on impact from 0.167 to 0.33 and then

4

Page 5: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

falls gradually to 0.202; the employment ratio rises from 0.33 to 0.388 andthen falls gradually to 0.338; the growth rate of income per capita dropson impact from 0.02 to 0.012 and then falls further to 0.0108. Overall,the JGTRRA produces a welfare loss of 19.34% of annual consumption percapita. To check robustness, I do some sensitivity analysis with respectto important parameters of the model. I also compute the welfare changefor a hypothetical, extreme version of the JGTRRA that totally eliminatestaxation of dividends and capital gains and �nd that it would produce awelfare loss of 24.03% of annual consumption per capita. These resultsobtain in the baseline version of the model where social returns to productvariety are zero.

Things do not change much when I allow for positive social returns toproduct variety. A mild degree is su¢ cient for the JGTRRA to deliveran initial growth acceleration but no matter how strong social returns toproduct variety the sign of the welfare change remains negative. Speci�cally,with elasticity of aggregate output with respect to product variety equal tojust 10% of the elasticity with respect to labor, the initial contribution offaster variety expansion cancels out with the slowdown of quality growth sothat the overall growth rate of income per capita does not jump on impact;for values of the product variety elasticity larger than 10% of the laborelasticity, the model produces an initial, temporary acceleration of incomeper capita growth. For example, if the producy variety elasticity is 50% ofthe labor elasticity the growth rate jumps initially from 2% to 2.25%. At16.94% of annual consumption, the welfare e¤ect is smaller in magnitude butstill dominated by the fall of long-run growth and the rise of the long-runemployment and saving ratios.

This paper contributes to the recent literature on the tax policy impli-cations of Schumpeterian growth models. The insight that tax instrumentscan be sorted in two classes according to whether they have or do not havegrowth e¤ects is developed contemporaneously and independently in Zengand Zhang (2002) and Peretto (2003). One limitation of those studies is thatthey consider steady states only and thereby ignore welfare. Peretto (2007a,2007b) extends the analysis to include transitional dynamics and thus al-low for the calculation of the welfare e¤ects of changes in the structure oftaxation. Peretto (2007b), in particular, focuses on corporate taxes and de-velops some of the main ingredients used in the analysis undertaken here.That analysis, however, focuses on revenue-neutral changes in the structureof taxation (in a model with no lump-sum taxes or government debt), afeature that produces interesting insights about hypothetical reforms of thetax code but limits its relevance for the JGTRRA. (Moreover it is only qual-

5

Page 6: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

itative, with no attempt at calibration.) The main innovation of this paperis that I allow the government to �nance the dividend tax cut with debt.Consequently, the analysis applies directly and explicitly to the JGTRRA,an actual, real-world experiment in �scal policy.

I organize the paper as follows. Section 2 sets up the model. Section 3characterizes equilibrium dynamics and the steady state. Section 4 carriesout the qualitative analysis of cuts in the dividend tax rate. Section 5calibrates the model and studies its quantitative implications. Section 6concludes.

2 The model

The economy is closed. To keep things as simple as possible, there is nophysical capital.3 In particular, I construct a model where the household�sportfolio contains securities (shares) issued by �rms and backed up by intan-gible assets accumulated through R&D. Thus, the dividend income earnedby households stems from vertical (quality) and horizontal (variety) productdi¤erentiation.

2.1 Final producers

A competitive representative �rm produces a �nal good Y that can be con-sumed, used to produce intermediate goods, invested in R&D that rises thequality of existing intermediate goods, or invested in the creation of newintermediate goods. The �nal good is the numeraire and I set PY � 1. Theproduction technology is

Y =

Z N

0X�i

�Z�i Z

1��Li�1��

di; 0 < �; � < 1; (1)

where N is the mass of non-durable intermediate goods. These goods arevertically di¤erentiated according to quality: the productivity of Li workersusing Xi units of good i depends on the good�s quality, Zi and on average

3More precisely, there is no capital in the usual neoclassical sense of a homogenous,durable, intermediate good accumulated through foregone consumption. Instead, there aredi¤erentiated, non-durable, intermediate goods produced through foregone consumption.One can think of these goods as capital, albeit with 100% instantaneous depreciation. Inaccordance with the principles of optimal taxation I posit no taxes on purchases or sales ofintermediate goods. Introducing the traditional notion of physical capital in this structurecomplicates the analysis without changing the basic results.

6

Page 7: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

quality Z =R N0

1NZjdj.

4 This formulation posits zero social returns tovariety because they play no essential role in the characterization of thedecentralized equilibrium dynamics. I relax this simplifying assumption inSection 4 where I analyze the growth and welfare e¤ects of the JGTRRA.

The �rst-order conditions for the pro�t maximization problem of the �nalproducer yield that each intermediate producer faces the demand curve

Xi =

��

Pi

� 11��

Z�i Z1��Li; (2)

where Pi is the price of good i. LetW denote the wage rate and L =R N0 Lidi

denote aggregate employment. The �rst-order conditions then yield that the�nal producer pays total compensationZ N

0PiXidi = �Y and WL = (1� �)Y

to intermediate producers and labor, respectively.

2.2 The corporate sector

The typical intermediate �rm operates a technology that requires one unitof �nal output per unit of intermediate good and a �xed operating cost �Z.The �rm can increase quality according to the technology

_Zi = Ri; (3)

where Ri is R&D investment in units of �nal output.To construct the �rm�s objective function, I adapt the formulation in

Turnovsky (1995, Ch. 8 and 11) of a dynamic macro model that incorpo-rates the �New View�in corporate �nance and public economics according

4This speci�cation, borrowed from Peretto (2007b), modi�es the augmented Schum-peterian model without scale e¤ects developed by Aghion and Howitt (1998) to make itbetter suited to my purposes and yet leave the core mechanism essentially unchanged. The�rst is quality spillovers across goods, i.e., � < 1. This allows me to work with symmetricequilibria that feature creative accumulation, whereby all incumbent �rms do R&D, asopposed to creative destruction, whereby outsiders do R&D to replace the current incum-bent. (I discuss reasons why the creative accumulation model is better suited to studythe role of corporate taxation policy in Peretto 2007b.) The second modi�cation is thatquality enters with exponent 1� �, instead of 1, because my intermediate producers facea unitary marginal cost of production in units of the �nal good, instead of a marginal costin units of (physical) capital proportional to their quality level. Both approaches implythat quality enters the reduced-form version of (1) as labor augmenting technical change.Not surprisingly, they produce identical results.

7

Page 8: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

to which �rms �nance investment internally and distribute the residual in-come as dividends.5 Speci�cally, the �rm�s gross cash �ow (revenues minusproduction costs) is

�i = Xi (Pi � 1)� �Z: (4)

I assume that R&D is not expensible.6 The �rm then pays total taxes t��i,where t� is the corporate income tax rate. It follows that

Di = (1� t�)�i �Ri (5)

is the after-tax dividend distributed to the �rm�s stockholders.Next, I de�ne the after-tax rate of return to equity as

r = (1� tD)DiVi+ (1� tV )

_ViVi; (6)

where Vi is the price of �rm i�s shares, tD is the tax on distributed dividendsand tV is the tax on capital gains. In equilibrium r must equal the rate ofreturn to saving obtained from the individual�s maximization problem (seebelow) and thus is the same across �rms. Integrating forward, this equationyields the after-tax value of the �rm

Vi (t) =

Z 1

te� �r(t;s)1�tV

(s�t) 1� tD1� tV

[(1� t�)�i(s)�Ri (s)] ds;

where �r (t; s) � 1s�t

R st r (v) dv is the average interest rate (return to saving)

between t and s.The �rm chooses the time path of its product�s price and R&D in order

to maximize the objective function above subject to (2), (3) and (4). The�rm takes average quality, Z, in (2) and (4) as given. The characterizationof the �rm�s decision is straightforward and in symmetric equilibrium7 yields

5There is an alternative �Old View�that holds that corporations �nance investment byissuing new shares. I work out the results under the New View since there are theoreticaland empirical reasons to think that it is more relevant. (I discussed these reasons in detailin Peretto (2007b).) In an Appendix available on request, I sketch the model under theOld View and show that the mechanism driving growth remains the same.

6This assumption is not realistic since many countries (e.g., the U.S.) grant full ex-pensibility of R&D costs. However, it does not a¤ect the main results while it simpli�esmany of the expressions in the paper and allows me to draw a sharp distinction betweentaxation of corporate pro�ts and distributed dividends. See Peretto (2007b) for a detailedanalysis of what happens under partially or fully expensible R&D in a model of this class.

7See Peretto (1998, 1999) for a discussion of the conditions under which it is reasonableto work with symmetric equilibria in models of this class. These conditions essentially

8

Page 9: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

the rate of return to quality innovation (see the Appendix for the derivation)

r = (1� tV ) (1� t�)���

Z+ �

�: (7)

Observe that this return does not depend on the tax on dividend income.The reason is that the �rm treats dividends as a residual and thus taxation ofthe dividend income received by the stockholder does not a¤ect its internalproduction/investment decisions.

I now characterize the birth of new �rms. Setting up a �rm at time trequires �Z units of �nal output, where � > 1.8 Because of this sunk cost,the new �rm cannot supply an existing good in Bertrand competition withthe incumbent monopolist, but must introduce a new good that expandsproduct variety. Notice that for simplicity I assume that new �rms enter atthe average quality level. To �x terminology, I shall refer to the introductionof new products that expand the variety of intermediate goods and arebrought to market by new �rms as �entry�.

New �rms �nance entry by issuing equity. Entry is positive if the valueof the �rm is equal to its after-tax setup cost, i.e., if the free-entry conditionVi = �Z holds. The post-entry pro�t that accrues to an entrant is given bythe expression derived for the typical incumbent. Hence, the value of the�rm satis�es the arbitrage condition (6). Taking logs and time derivatives ofthe free-entry condition, substituting into (6) and imposing symmetry yields

r =(1� tD)�

�(1� t�)

Z� RZ

�+ (1� tV )

_Z

Z: (8)

Observe that this rate of return decreases with tD.

reduce to the two requirements that: (a) the �rm-speci�c return to quality innovationis decreasing in Zi (see the Appendix); (b) entrants enter at the average level of qualityZ (see below). The �rst implies that if one holds constant the mass of �rms and startsthe model from an asymmetric distribution of �rm sizes, then the model converges toa symmetric distribution. The second requirement simply ensures that entrants do notperturb such symmetric distribution.

8The R&D technology (3) says that achieving quality level Z within an existing productline has a cumulative cost of Z. If we assume that entrepreneurs have access to the sametechnology in the creation of a new �rm, then it is natural to write the cost of creatinga new product line with initial quality level Z as Z. However, entrepreneurs have topay additional setup costs that incumbents have already paid. If these costs are alsoproportional to Z, then it is natural to write the total entry cost as �Z, � > 1.

9

Page 10: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

2.3 Households

The economy is populated by a representative household whose (identical)members supply labor services and purchase �nancial assets (corporate eq-uity) in competitive labor and asset markets. Each member is endowed withone unit of time. The household has preferences

U(t) =

Z 1

te�(���)(s�t) log u (s) ds; � > � � 0; > 0;

where

log u (s) = logC (s)

e�s+ log (1� l (s)) :

� is the individual discount rate. Initial population is normalized to oneso that at time t population size is e�t, where � is the rate of populationgrowth. Instantaneous utility is de�ned over consumption per capita Ce��t

and leisure 1� l, where C is aggregate consumption and l is the fraction oftime allocated to work. measures preference for leisure.

The household faces the �ow budget constraint (I impose symmetryacross �rms to keep the notation simple):

_sNV + s _NV =h(1� tD)D � tV _V

isN + (1� tL)Wle�t � (1 + tC)C � T;

where s and _s are, respectively, the level and change of equity holding ineach �rm, N is the mass of �rms, D is the dividend per share distributedby each �rm, _V is the appreciation of each �rm�s equity. The governmenttaxes labor income at rate tL, dividends at rate tD, capital gains at rate tV ,and consumption at rate tC . It also levies lump-sum taxes T .

The optimal plan for this setup is well known. The household saves andsupplies labor according to:

�� �+_C

C= r = (1� tD)

D

V+ (1� tV )

_V

V; (9)

L = le�t = e�t � (1 + tC) C(1� tL)W

: (10)

The Euler equation (9) de�nes the after-tax, reservation rate of return tosaving that enters the evaluation of corporate equity discussed above.

10

Page 11: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

2.4 The Government

I derive the results for the case of lump-sum taxation and no public debtbecause the notation is simpler. Speci�cally, the government consumes �nalgoods and satis�es the budget constraint9

G = tLWL+ tCC + t��N + tDDN + tV _V N + T:

I characterize �scal policy as

G = gY; g < 1:

The public spending ratio g and the tax rates tL, tC , t�, tD, and tV are�xed. The endogenous instrument is T . In the Appendix I show that theeconomy with public debt generates the same equilibrium dynamics as theeconomy with no debt because Ricardian equivalence holds. Hence, theresults derived below describe the case of a de�cit-�nanced dividend tax cutwhere the government pays back the debt in the future.

3 The economy�s dynamics

In this section I �rst show how the interaction of incumbents and entrants(quality and variety innovators) in the assets market determines the relationbetween growth and the return to stockholding. I then turn to the rest ofthe economy and impose equilibrium of the assets, labor and output marketsto determine dynamics. Finally, I characterize the steady state.

3.1 Equilibrium of the corporate sector

De�ne the growth rate of quality z � Z = RZ . (A hat on top of a variable

denotes a proportional growth rate.) No-arbitrage between quality growthand variety expansion requires that their rates of return be equal. Using (7)and (8) this condition yields

z � R

Z= (1� t�)

����1�tD1�tV

1� � �

��Z

1� 1�tD1�tV

1�

: (11)

Figure 1 illustrates. The �at line is equation (7), which says that the returnto quality is independent of quality growth because the R&D technology (3)

9To simplify thix expression, I impose symmetry across �rms and the normalizationthat each �rm�s stock of shares is s � 1.

11

Page 12: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

features constant returns to scale. The upward sloping line is equation (8),which says that the return to entry (variety expansion) depends positivelyon quality growth.

As one can see from the diagram, an interior equilibrium with both typesof R&D exists and is stable if the entry locus (8) cuts the quality locus (7)from below.10 There are two conditions for this situation to occur.11 The�rst is the intercept condition

1� tD�

Z< � (1� tV )

��

Z+ �

�) �� >

�1� tD1� tV

1

�� �

��

Z; (12)

the second is the slope condition

1� tV �1� tD�

> 0) � >1� tD1� tV

: (13)

In the remainder of the analysis I impose that the slope condition holds.This is not restrictive since � > 1 and in the data tD > tV .

Equations (7) and (11) characterize the instantaneous equilibrium of thecorporate sector given the quality-adjusted cash �ow, �Z , which at any pointin time is determined by the macroeconomic conditions of the economy. Themodel admits two types of interior equilibrium:

� for � > 1�tD1�tV > �� quality growth is decreasing in

�Z ;

� for � > �� > 1�tD1�tV quality growth is increasing in �

Z .

The �rst equilibrium might surprise the reader since the literature has typ-ically produced models with zero �xed operating costs that necessarily pre-dict a positive relation between the growth and pro�tability of a productline. Once �rms bear these costs, however, the return to variety can bemore sensitive to the quality-adjusted cash �ow than the return to qual-ity, in which case an increase in the quality-adjusted cash �ow reallocates

10The equilibrium is stable in the sense that a deviation with, say, higher z yields thatthe return to entry becomes higher than the return to quality growth. The �nancial marketthen reallocates resources from quality growth to variety expansion, thereby reducing therate of quality growth and restoring equilibrium.11The model�s equilibrium is well-de�ned also in the case in which these conditions

fail, but it has the unappealing feature that either only variety expansion or only qualitygrowth takes place. I omit these corner solutions because they add no insight.

12

Page 13: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

resources from investment in existing products to investment in new prod-ucts.12 To �x terminology, I refer to the �rst case as the low-�� regime andthe second as the high-�� regime. Notice how, regardless of the regime,holding constant �

Z a decrease in tD always lowers z. The reason is thatdividend taxation does not distort the return to internal investment, seeequation (7), while it distorts the return to entry, see equation (8).

3.2 General equilibrium

I now construct the general equilibrium of the economy. I de�ne the privateconsumption ratio c � C

Y and the number of �rms per capita n � Ne��t.Rewrite the labor supply equation (10) as

l (c) =1

1 + �c; � � (1 + tC)

(1� tL) (1� �): (14)

The labor market is competitive and clears instantaneously so that l (c) isthe equilibrium employment ratio.

Next, observe that the fact that the �nal producer pays total compensa-tion �Y to intermediate producers yields NX = �2Y . Imposing symmetryin the production function (1) and using this relation allows me to write

Y = l (c) e�tZ; � �2�1�� : (15)

Accordingly, I can write

Z=1� ��

X

Z� � = � (1� �) l (c)

n� �: (16)

This equation shows how, given the mass of �rms per capita n, equilibriumof the labor market determines the �rm�s quality-adjusted cash �ow.

Equations (14)-(15) characterize the supply side of the output market.Equilibrium requires

Y = G+ C +N(X + �Z +R) + �Z _N:

Recall that NX = �2Y and G = gY . Using the employment relation (14),the reduced-form production function (15), the de�nition of n, and dividing

12Fixed operating costs are necessary, not su¢ cient to generate this equilibrium. Mostof the papers referenced in footnote 1 that look at transitional dynamics posit zero �xedoperating costs and thus could not uncover the negative relation between cash �ow andquality growth. Notice, in fact, that � = 0 implies that one must restrict the right handside of (12) to be positive for an equilibrium with z > 0 to exist.

13

Page 14: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

through by Y , I obtain�1� �2 � g � c

n (1 + �c)= �+ z + � (�+ n) : (17)

Notice that c + g is the overall (private plus public) consumption ratio sothat 1� c� g is the economy�s saving ratio.

Equilibrium of the assets market requires that the rate of return to sav-ing be equal to the rate of return to investment generated by �rms. Thede�nition of c, the Euler equation (9), the employment relation (14) and thereduced-form production function (15) allow me to write this condition as

r � z = �+ 1

1 + �cc: (18)

Observe now that (7), (11) and (16) yield that (17)-(18) de�ne a system oftwo di¤erential equations in c and n only. The following proposition andthe phase diagram in Figure 2 characterize the resulting dynamics.

Proposition 1 There exists a unique perfect-foresight general equilibrium.Given initial condition n0, the economy jumps on the saddle path and con-verges to the steady state (n�; c�).

Proof. See the Appendix.

The model�s remarkably simple transition allows me to derive the welfareimplications of dividend tax cuts in a straightforward manner. Before doingthat, however, it is useful to characterize the steady state.

3.3 The steady state

I construct the equilibrium of the assets market as the intersection of therelation

r = �+ z; (19)

describing the reservation interest rate of savers, with the relation

r = (1� tD)D

V+ (1� tV )

_V

V;

which describes the rate of return to stocks delivered by �rms. The insightdriving this paper emerges clearly from how one can use the relations derivedabove to rewrite this equation in (z; r) space.

14

Page 15: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

I begin by using the de�nition of pre-tax dividend (5) and the free-entrycondition V = �Z to write

D

V=D

�Z=1

�(1� t�)

Z� z

�:

I then solve (11) for �Z and substitute the result in this expression to obtain

D

V=�� (1� t�)� (1� �) z

1�tD1�tV � ��

:

Finally, I write

r = (1� tD)�� (1� t�)� (1� �) z

1�tD1�tV � ��

+ (1� tV ) z: (20)

This locus describes the return to investment in quality and variety innova-tion produced by the no-arbitrage condition that the rates of return to thetwo activities be equal.

The model�s solution turns out to be remarkably simple since (9) and(20) yield the closed-form expressions:13

z� =�� (1� t�) (1� tD)� �

�1�tD1�tV � ��

�(1� �) (1� tD) + tV

�1�tD1�tV � ��

� ; (21)

r� = �� (1� t�) (1� tD) + � (1� tV )

�� � 1�tD

1�tV

�(1� �) (1� tD) + tV

�1�tD1�tV � ��

� : (22)

Rather than di¤erentiating these expressions, however, it is more insightfulto investigate the properties of the equilibrium by looking at how the in-vestment locus shifts with the tax rates. The proposition below summarizesthe results, Figure 3 illustrates.

Proposition 2 There are two steady-state equilibrium con�gurations:

� for � > 1�tD1�tV > �� the return to investment is downward sloping in z,

shifts up with tD, and shifts down with t�, tV ;

� for � > �� > 1�tD1�tV the return to investment is upward sloping in z,

shifts down with tD, tV , and shifts up with t�.13Existence conditions are discussed in the proof of Proposition 1.

15

Page 16: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

In both cases, an increase in tD raises z� and r� while an increase in t�lowers them. The e¤ects of tV , in contrast, depend on which case applies:in the former an increase in tV raises z� and r�, in the latter it lowers them.

Proof. See the appendix.

Recall that the analysis of no-arbitrage in the previous section showsthat in the low-�� regime instantaneous quality growth is decreasing in thequality-adjusted cash �ow while in the high-�� regime it is increasing. Theproposition just stated says that this di¤erence has no role in determiningthe sign of the steady-state e¤ects of dividend taxation.

Why does taxation of dividends raise steady-state growth? As the proofof the proposition shows, the partial derivatives of the return to investmentwith respect to z and tD always have opposite sign. Consequently, the locusshifts up with tD when it is downward sloping and intersects the savinglocus from above, while it shifts down with tD when it is upward slopingand intersects the saving locus from below. This is no accident, of course.The reason is that in using (11), the construction of the investment locus (20)incorporates the relation between quality growth and the quality-adjustedcash �ow that results from the partial equilibrium analysis of no-arbitragein Figure 1. That diagram shows that a higher tD does not a¤ect the returnto quality while it shifts down the return to entry. To restore equilibrium,resources �ow from variety expansion to quality growth. The key then isthat accounting for the endogeneity of �Z in steady-state general equilibriumdoes not change this outcome. The reason is that in the low-�� regime thereturn to entry is more sensitive to the cash �ow than the return to qualitywhile the reverse is true in the high-�� regime. It thus follows that in (20)the partial derivatives of r with respect to z and tD always have oppositesign. It is straightforward to see that similar reasoning explains the e¤ectsof taxation of corporate pro�ts.

The rate of return generated by the �rm is related to its scale of activitysince that is the variable that underpins the �rm�s cash �ow. To see this, Inow use (7) and (16) to solve for employment per �rm:�

l

n

��=

�L

N

��=

r�

� (1� �) (1� tV ) (1� t�)�: (23)

Since r� is increasing in tD and decreasing in t� and tV , this measure of �rmsize is increasing in tD while t� and tV have an ambiguous e¤ect. Noticealso that �rm size is independent of tC and tL. Next, I use the free-entry

16

Page 17: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

condition V = �Z, (15) and (23) to compute the wealth (to GDP) ratio�NV

Y

��=�

�nl

��=�� (1� �) (1� tV ) (1� t�)�

r�: (24)

Very intuitively this equation says that for a given interest rate the ratio isdecreasing in t� and tV . If these direct e¤ects dominate the indirect e¤ectsthrough the interest rate, then the ratio is decreasing in t� and tV . Sincethe interest rate is the only channel through which tD enters this expression,the ratio is decreasing in tD because the interest rate is increasing in tD.

Next, I substitute (14), (19) and (23) into (17) to calculate

c� = 1� �2 � g � � (1� �) (1� tV ) (1� t�)���+ �+ z�

�+ z�; (25)

which says that c� is increasing in z�, and thereby increasing in tD, if ��+� > �. This yields the sensible result that taxation of dividends raisesconsumption, that is, reduces the overall saving ratio 1� c� � g.

To solve for the labor market equilibrium, I now use (14) to obtain

l� =1

1 + �c�; � � (1 + tC)

(1� tL) (1� �)

which is decreasing in tD, since c� is increasing in tD, and in tL and tC .Finally, I can rewrite (23) as

n� = � (1� �) (1� tV ) (1� t�)�l�

r�: (26)

With a little bit of tedious algebra, I can show that this expression is de-creasing in tD. I can also show that n� is decreasing in t�, tV , tL, tC andincreasing in g. With these comparative statics results in hand, I am nowready to undertake the main experiment of the paper.

4 A dividend tax cut: Analytical results

In the analysis below, I posit �� + � > � to study the e¤ects of the taxcut under conditions that yield the reasonable result that lower taxation ofdividends raises the saving ratio 1� g� c�. I o¤er three remarks in supportof this choice. First, this response is precisely what most economists wouldexpect. Second, the prediction that the dividend tax cut would raise saving,investment and growth has been o¤ered as one of the strongest argumentsin favor of the policy. Third, it always holds in the calibrated model.

17

Page 18: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

I organize this section in two parts. The �rst deals with the basic modelwith zero social returns to product variety. The second relaxes this sim-plifying assumption and shows that introducing positive social returns toproduct variety yields dynamics consistent with those of the basic model.Working out the two cases separately makes transparent the conditions un-der which social returns to product variety change the sign of the welfaree¤ect of the tax cut.

4.1 The basic model

Figure 2 illustrates the transition in (n; c) space. The following propositionestablishes a central result of the paper.

Proposition 3 Assume ��+� > �, which ensures that the relation betweentaxation of dividends and the economy�s steady-state consumption ratio c�+gis positive. Then, if the economy is in the low-�� regime, � > 1�tD

1�tV > ��, areduction of the tax rate on dividends �nanced with an increase in lump-sumtaxes or public debt is necessarily welfare reducing; if, instead, the economyis in the high-�� regime, � > �� > 1�tD

1�tV , a reduction of the tax rate ondividends �nanced with an increase in lump-sum taxes or public debt is notnecessarily welfare reducing.

Proof. Let 0 be the arbitrary date when the government cuts tD. Referto the phase diagram in Figure 2. The consumption ratio c jumps downand raises thereafter to the value c�� < c�. Accordingly, the employmentratio l jumps up and falls thereafter to the value l�� > l�. The initial jumpup in l produces an initial jump up in the quality-adjusted cash �ow �

Z .According to equation (11), in the low-�� regime this change, together withthe direct e¤ect of the lower tD which is always negative, produces a fallin quality growth z. The economy thereafter experiences a rising rate ofquality growth that converges to the value z�� < z�. To see welfare, use (15)to write output per capita, y � Y e��t, as

log y (t) = log l (t) +

Z t

0z (s) ds+ logZ (0) :

Without loss of generality I normalize Z (0) � 1. Using this expression andthe de�nition of c, I then write �ow utility as

log u (t) = log y (t) + log c (t) + log (1� l (t))

= log +

Z t

0z (s) ds+ log (l (t) c (t)) + log (1� l (t)) :

18

Page 19: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

Flow utility features a tension between work and leisure. However, equa-tion (14) allows me to calculate (I suppress time arguments to simplify thenotation):

log (lc) + log (1� l) = logc

1 + �c+ log

�c

1 + �c

= (1 + ) logc

1 + �c+ log �;

which is increasing in c. The welfare e¤ect of the tax cut then is

� � U0 � U� =Z 1

0e�(���)t log

u (t)

u�dt;

where U� is welfare at (n�; c�) and the change in �ow utility along thistransition is

logu (t)

u�= (1 + ) log

c(t)1+�c(t)

c�1+�c�

+

Z t

0[z (s)� z�] ds:

The �rst term is negative because c (t) � c�� < c�. This re�ects the loss ofutility due to the lower consumption ratio. The second term is also negativebecause z (t) � z�� < z�. Therefore, the welfare change is surely negativebecause the economy experiences a slowdown in quality growth as well asa loss of consumption. In the high-�� regime things di¤er only in that theinitial jump in the quality-adjusted cash �ow due to the expansion of aggre-gate market size produces a jump up in quality growth that could o¤set thedirect e¤ect of the lower tD, and thereby produce a growth acceleration. Ifthis acceleration is strong enough, and the welfare functional puts su¢ cientweight on the early part of the transition, then we can have an overall welfareincrease despite the lower steady-state growth rate. This initial accelerationmust o¤set also the negative e¤ect on �ow utility of the lower consumptionratio (which includes lower leisure).

This result deserves a few comments. The model incorporates the tra-ditional e¤ect that people need to work harder to pay for the anticipatedincrease in lump-sum taxes. In addition, it incorporates the Schumpeterianquality/variety trade-o¤ investigated in the recent literature. Accordingly,the e¤ect of the tax cut depends on two margins. The �rst compares howmuch the economy loses from slower quality growth with how much it gainsfrom the increase in product variety. The second compares how much theeconomy loses from the lower consumption and leisure with how much it

19

Page 20: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

gains from the increase in product variety. With zero social returns to va-riety, the mass of �rms per capita matters only because given aggregatevariables it determines �rm-level variables and thus drives the dynamics ofthe interest rate and growth. It does not, however, contribute directly toproductivity. The next subsection relaxes this assumption.

4.2 The economy with social returns to product variety

I rewrite the production function in (1) as14

Y = n�Z N

0X�i

�Z�i Z

1��Li�1��

di; 0 < �; � < 1; � > 0:

Proceeding as in the previous analysis, this expression yields

Y = n�LZ; � � �

1� � : (27)

These social increasing returns to product variety are external to all agentsso that their behavior does not change with respect to the characterizationabove. The only important di¤erence is that the instantaneous reservationinterest rate of savers now is

r = �+ z +1

1 + �cc+ �n;

where the last term captures the contribution of product variety growth tototal factor productivity growth. The presence of this term complicates thealgebra without altering the basic mechanism.

The expression for the cash �ow now reads

Z= � (1� �) l (c)

n1��� �:

The restriction � < 1 implies that positive social returns to product varietydo not overturn the market share e¤ect so that the quality-adjusted cash�ow remains decreasing in n. This ensures that the basic forces at work inthe model, and therefore the characterization of the equilibrium dynamics,remain qualitatively unchanged. Notice that � < 1 requires � < 1� �, thatis, an elasticity of output with respect to product variety that is less thanthe elasticity of output with respect to labor.

14See Aghion and Howitt (1998, pp. 407-408, in particular footnote 6) for argumentsthat justify introducing social returns to variety in this fashion. See also Peretto (2007a,2007b) for further discussion of social returns to variety in models of this class.

20

Page 21: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

The following proposition shows that the results from Proposition 1above apply virtually unchanged to this case. I use the subscript � to denotethe steady-state values for the case � > 0.

Proposition 4 Assume � < 1 � � so that � < 1. Then, there exists aunique perfect-foresight general equilibrium. Given initial condition n0, theeconomy jumps on the saddle path and converges to the steady state:

c�� = c�;

n�� = (n�)

11�� :

Proof. See the Appendix.

Observe that the solution for c�� (and therefore for l��) is given by the same

expression as in the case � = 0. Also, recall that the characterization of theassets market equilibrium in steady state is independent of �Z . Therefore,the terms n1�� and �n in the expressions above do not a¤ect the solutionsfor the steady-state growth and interest rates, which in this case as well arez� and r� in (21)-(22). Thus, aside from the modi�cations of the transitiondynamics just studied, the only di¤erence due to positive social returnsto product variety is that they deliver a smaller mass of �rms per capita(because n� < 1) without changing any other feature of the steady state.

An important way in which social returns to product variety change themodel�s implications for the dividend tax cut is the aforementioned contribu-tion of product variety growth to total factor productivity growth. Equation(27) and the resources constraint (17) yield

y = z + �n

= z +

��

�1� g � c� �2

� ln� ��� �� z

�=

�1� �

�z +

��1� g � c� �2

� ln� ��� �

�;

where (11) and (16) yield

z = (1� t�)���

�1�tD1�tV

1� � �

� �� (1� �) ln � �

�1� 1�tD

1�tV1�

:

When the tax cut is implemented n does not jump while l jumps up. Con-sequently, the term in brackets jumps up. The previous analysis has shown

21

Page 22: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

that z jumps up with l in the high-�� regime and jumps down in the low-�� regime. Recall also that the direct e¤ect of a reduction of tD is negativeregardless of which regime applies. Hence, an important aspect of allowingfor social returns to product variety is that it introduces an additional forcethat, at least temporarily, works against the negative direct e¤ect of thedividend tax cut and can yield an acceleration of income per capita growthfor a broader range of parameters values. Given that variety expansion isnot an engine of long-run growth, however, the economy exhibits at best aninverted-X time pro�le of productivity growth, whereas the initial accelera-tion is followed by a permanent slowdown with respect to the initial steadystate. As for the case of zero social returns to product variety discussedin Proposition 3, the possibility of an initial growth acceleration makes thetheoretical welfare e¤ect ambiguous.

To check the welfare implications, observe that �ow utility now is

log u (t) = (1 + ) logc (t)

1 + �c (t)+ � log n (t) +

Z t

0z (s) ds. (28)

The new element here is the productivity gain due to product variety, n,that increases in response to a dividend tax cut. The result in Proposition3 generalizes as follows. (I drop the subscript � since I no longer need todi¤erentiate the steady-state values below from those that apply in the case� = 0.)

Proposition 5 Under the assumptions of Propositions 2-4, consider aneconomy in the low-�� regime, � > 1�tD

1�tV > ��. A su¢ cient conditionfor a reduction of the tax rate on dividends �nanced with an increase inlump-sum taxes (or an increase in public debt) to be welfare reducing is thatthe initial (pre-shock) steady state satis�es

l� >1

1 + 1+ �

:

Proof. See the Appendix.

I wish to stress that the proposition establishes a su¢ cient condition forthe tax cut to be welfare reducing. Interestingly, this condition concernsexclusively the labor market. The reason is that the proof splits the roleof the increase of product variety in two components that re�ect two trade-o¤s. The �rst inequality compares how much utility the economy loses fromslower quality growth with how much it gains from the increase in product

22

Page 23: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

variety. This comparison says that the loss dominates the gain regardlessof speci�c parameter values. The second inequality compares how muchutility from consumption and leisure is lost in exchange for the gain due toproduct variety. An important feature of this comparison is that the channellinking the gain from variety to the loss from consumption is the employmentratio because the economy needs to raise employment to support a largermass of �rms. The parameter �, which regulates the response of laborsupply to changes in the consumption ratio, tells us how much consumptionthe economy needs to give up to sustain the increase in product varietygenerated by the tax cut.

How strict is the second condition? Since � < 1 this inequality holds if

l� >1

2 + :

For the period 1960-2000, the total U.S. labor input � the average hoursworked per person times the employment ratio � has ranged between 0.3and 0.36 with a mean value of 0.33.15 The U.S. economy thus satis�es thesu¢ cient condition in the proposition if

>1

0:33� 2 = 1:03:

The business-cycle literature typically works = 2:2. In the quantitativeanalysis below, I obtain the value = 1:439 from the employment equation(14) and data on the consumption ratio and the tax rates. Since either casesatis�es the inequality, we conclude that qualitatively what matters for thesign of the welfare e¤ect of the policy under investigation in the economywith � > 0 is whether the economy is in the low- or high-�� regime, exactlythe conclusion reached in the case � = 0.

5 The JGTRRA: Quantitative analysis

The qualitative analysis above shows that we need to know whether we arein the low or high-�� regime. If the economy is in the low-�� regime thewelfare e¤ect of the dividend tax cut is negative regardless of the degree of

15 If one interprets l more narrowly as the fraction of the individual time endowmentallocated to work, which is what a literal reading of the model suggests, the data saysthat the fraction is clearly larger than 0.33. Similarly, one can reinterpret the model asspecifying l as the fraction of the working age population that is employed and this numbertoo is (much!) larger than 0.33.

23

Page 24: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

social returns to product variety. If, instead, the economy is in the high-�� regime the welfare e¤ect is not necessarily negative. The purpose ofthe quantitative work discussed in this subsection is to provide additionalinformation on the model�s transition and evaluate the welfare change dueto the JGTRRA under a wide range of values of the entry cost.

The estimation of entry costs is still in its infancy. We have drasticallydi¤erent results according to how one thinks about these costs. Djankovet al. (2002) provide estimates of regulatory entry costs. Strictly speak-ing these exclude the technological component that is at the heart of thispaper � recall that I think of � as the cost of developing a new productand its manufacturing process with productivity level Z plus any additionalcost that entrants must pay to start operations. If these extra costs areproportional to Z, we can write � = 1 + �, where 1 is the cost of achievingproductivity level Z starting from scratch and � is the additional cost dueto regulations and other barriers to entry. Djankov et al. (2002) estimatethat in the U.S. economy these costs are about 0.0169 of GDP per capita.We can translate this into an estimate of � as follows. Since we posit thecost as proportional to Z, we can calculate

�Z = 0:0169 � Y e��t ) � = 0:0169 � Y e��t

Z= 0:0169 � � l� = 0:002;

which yields � = 1:002. An alternative approach is to estimate � from stockmarket and employment information (see the Appendix for details). Using(24), we have

� = ��NV

Y

����L

N

��= 6:55:

Given this range of variation, and how important the entry cost is for welfare,it is wise to check the results�robustness over a wide range of values of �.

I calibrate the model as follows; the details are in the Appendix.

Table 1. Fiscal variablesg t� tD tV tL tC

0:143 0:335 0:35 0:2 0:256 0:05

Table 2. Steady state

c� l� r� z�

0:69 0:33 0:04 0:02

Table 3. Parameters� � � � �

0:02 1:439 0:31 0:163 0:068 6:55

24

Page 25: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

It is worth emphasizing that I use equations (14), (22) and (25) to compute , �, � from the data concerning the �scal variables and the steady statevalues of the endogenous variables. Consequently, I have degrees of freedomonly over �, �, �. The �rst two are rather conventional parameters. Inparticular, � plays the role of the traditional capital share and I set its valueaccordingly. As discussed, � requires particular care. I also set the degreeof social return to variety equal to zero, i.e., � = 0, in the baseline case. Ithen do sensitivity analysis over the range � 2 (0; 1� �).

Figure 5 shows the economy�s response to the JGTRRA in the baselinecase. The dynamics are well behaved and the transition lasts about 30 years.The consumption ratio c falls on impact from 0.69 to 0.52 and then risesgradually to 0.655. This dynamics yields that the economy�s overall savingratio 1 � c � g rises on impact from 0.167 to 0.33 and then falls graduallyto 0.202. The employment ratio l rises from 0.33 to 0.388 and then falls to0.338. The growth rate of income per capita z drops on impact from 0.02to 0.012 and then falls further to 0.0108. The last result is interesting. Theeconomy thus calibrated is in the high-�� regime, where the initial rise ofthe quality-adjusted pro�t �Z should produce a jump up in z. Yet, it does notbecause the direct e¤ect of the change in tax rates, in particular the negativee¤ect of the cut in the tax rate on dividends, dominates in equation (11).

The overall result is that welfare falls. In calculations not reported forbrevity, I have experimented with several values of �. The following tablesummarizes the welfare e¤ect of the policy for a few values of � and threevalues of that stand out: = 0 because it corresponds to inelastic laborsupply; = 1:439 because it is what I �estimate� from the data using themodel; = 2:2 because it is common in the literature. The welfare e¤ect isin % of annual consumption per capita; a positive value means a welfare loss,a negative value means a welfare gain. (This re�ects the usual conventionthat we have a welfare loss when we need to raise consumption to make thepolicy acceptable to agents.) The baseline case is in boldface.

Table 4. Welfare cost�= 0 1.439 2.22 23.54 25.90 26.233 19.80 22.02 22.34

6.55 17.29 19.34 19.6410 16.74 18.75 19.05

An important aspect of this analysis is that when � changes the wholetriplet (�; �; �) changes, since �, � are �estimated�from equations (22) and

25

Page 26: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

(25) conditional on the value of �. The following table shows the relationamong these parameters.

Table 5. The triplet (�; �; �)

� � � ��

1.002 -0.0023 0.9013 0.90311.02 -0.0021 0.8882 0.90591.1815 0 0.7859 0.92851.2 0.0002 0.7757 0.93082 0.0104 0.4962 0.99243 0.0231 0.3421 1.02634 0.0358 0.2611 1.04445 0.0485 0.2111 1.0555

6.55 0.0682 0.1627 1.06578 0.0866 0.1340 1.07209 0.0993 0.1195 1.075510 0.1120 0.1078 1.0780

As one can see, very low values of � produce nonsensical results for �.The reason is that when � is too low the existence conditions for an inte-rior equilibrium fail and the model cannot produce the steady-state vector(c�; l�; r�; z�) in Table 2 unless � and � adjust, and the adjustment, of course,does not need to make economic sense. Experimenting with several valuesof � I found that 2 is the lower bound below which we cannot go without de-stroying the key properties of the model. (Speci�cally, this means violatingthe conditions discussed in Section 3.1 and Propositions 1-2.) Notice alsohow multiplying the � column by the � column in the table always yieldsnumbers larger than 1�tD

1�tV = :8125. In other words, to �t the steady-statevector (c�; l�; r�; z�) in Table 2 the model must always be in the high-��regime. This rules out the low-�� regime wherein, as we have seen, thewelfare e¤ect of a dividend tax cut is necessarily negative.

One might be interested in the �pure� comparative dynamics e¤ect ofa change in �. One then might proceed as follows. Select � = 6:55 asthe baseline case; �estimate� �, �; change � without re-estimating �, �.The following table shows the welfare results. I report only values � � 4:5because, given that I am not re-estimating � and �, for � < 4:5 the existence

26

Page 27: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

condition for an interior equilibrium fails and the model breaks down.

Table 6. �Pure�e¤ect of �� Welfare cost %4.5 15.785 16.546 18.26

6.55 19.347 20.318 22.779 25.7310 29.32

According to this analysis the welfare cost rises rapidly with �, whereas inTable 4 it decreases with �. To understand the di¤erence, recall that hereeach row is associated to a di¤erent vector of steady-state values character-izing the economy before the change in tax rates and that except for thebaseline case the steady-state vector does not �t the data. The numbers inTable 4 do not su¤er from this problem because by construction each row isassociated to the steady-state vector (c�; l�; r�; z�) in Table 2, which is data.

I now turn to the more interesting extension that allows for social returnsto product variety. Recall that we are always in the high-�� regime thatpotentially allows for an initial growth acceleration. It is remarkable howeven a mild degree of social returns to product variety is su¢ cient to deliveran initial growth acceleration but no matter how strong social returns toproduct variety the welfare e¤ect remains negative. Figure 6 shows thedynamics for � � �

1�� = 0:1. This value means that the elasticity of outputwith respect to product variety in the reduced-form aggregate productionfunction (27) is � = 10%� (1� �), where 1� � is the elasticity with respectto labor. The initial fall of quality growth due to the tax cut cancels outwith the initial acceleration of variety growth and the rate of growth ofincome per capita does not jump. Figure 7 shows that pushing the value of� up to 0.5 produces a substantial growth acceleration, from 2% to 2.25%on impact, that disappears in about 10 years. (Also, the transition becomeslonger than 30 years.) Figure 8 summarizes the welfare e¤ects. The solidline represents the case in which tD and tV drop to 15%, the dashed linethe case in which tD and tV drop to 0%. In both cases the magnitudeof the loss decreases with �. The reason is that an economy with larger �experiences a larger increase in the steady-state mass of �rms per capita; seeProposition 4 and observe that the percentage change in n�� due to the tax

27

Page 28: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

cut is 11�� times the percentage change in n

�. This larger increase in productvariety compensates more the adverse e¤ects due to the slower steady-stategrowth rate and higher saving and employment ratios. Interestingly, if � issu¢ ciently large the complete elimination of taxes on dividends and capitalgains yields a welfare gain.

6 Conclusion

In this paper, I have proposed a Schumpeterian investigation of the growthand welfare e¤ects of a de�cit-�nanced cut of the tax rate on dividends. Tomy own surprise, I found that under broad and plausible conditions the taxcut reduces long-run growth.

On re�ection, this result rests on a straightforward intuition: the lowerdividend income tax requires �rms to reduce the pre-tax dividend-price ratioand/or the after-tax capital gain components of the return that they deliverto the stockholder in order to match his reservation after-tax rate of return.This, in turn, requires that �rms reduce the growth rate of future earningsby investing less in quality growth. Crucially, �rms are willing to reducethe growth rate of quality within each product line when overall productvariety rises. This is because demand becomes less concentrated and �rmsexploit less e¤ectively the cost-spreading e¤ect associated to (exogenous)�xed operating costs and (endogenous) �xed R&D costs.

The increase in product variety embodies the model�s key insight thatlower taxation of dividends reallocates resources from quality growth toproduct proliferation. But product proliferation is the activity with lowlong-run growth opportunity. The reason is that �xed operating costs implythat the number of products is constrained by the size of the workforce,so that in the horizontal dimension of technology space steady-state growthindependent of (exogenous) population growth is not possible. In the verticaldimension, in contrast, steady-state growth is feasible because improvingproduct quality does not require the replication of �xed costs.

This mechanism has interesting implications for welfare. The e¤ect of thetax cut depends on two margins. The �rst compares how much the economyloses from slower quality growth with how much it gains from the increasein product variety. The second margin compares how much the economyloses from the lower consumption and leisure with how much it gains fromthe increase in product variety. An important feature of this comparison isthat the channel linking the gain from variety to the loss from consumptionis the employment ratio because the economy needs to raise employment to

28

Page 29: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

support a larger mass of �rms. The parameters that regulate the responseof labor supply to changes in the consumption ratio, then, tells us how muchconsumption the economy needs to give up to sustain the increase in productvariety generated by the tax cut.

This analysis is particularly relevant to the current debate on the JobGrowth and Taxpayer Relief reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA). One ar-gument in support of the Act, based on conventional economic wisdom, isthat the reduction of the tax rate on distributed dividends and capital gainsreduces the corporate cost of capital and thereby increases saving and invest-ment. This paper�s analysis suggests that things are not so straightforwardin an environment where market structure matters. The growth e¤ects ofsuch interventions depend on how they a¤ect the �nancial market�s alloca-tion of funds between the vertical (quality) and horizontal (variety) dimen-sions of technological advance. The welfare e¤ects depend on the relativecontribution of the two dimensions to aggregate output. An implication ofthis trade-o¤ is that the JGTRRA will deliver a welfare loss of 19.34% ofannual consumption per capita if social returns to variety are zero. If so-cial returns to variety are positive the magnitude of the loss is smaller. Forexample, with elasticity of aggregate output with respect to product vari-ety equal to 10% of the labor elasticity the welfare loss is 16.94% of annualconsumption.

7 Appendix

7.1 Derivation of the return to quality

The usual method of obtaining �rst-order conditions is to write the Hamil-tonian for the optimal control problem of the �rm. This derivation highlightsthe intuition. The �rm undertakes R&D up to the point where the shadowvalue of the innovation, qi, is equal to its cost,

1� tD1� tV

= qi , Ri > 0: (29)

Since the innovation is implemented in-house, its bene�ts are determined bythe marginal after-tax pro�t it generates. Thus, the return to the innovationmust satisfy the arbitrage condition

r

1� tV=1� tD1� tV

(1� t�)@�i@Zi

1

qi+_qiqi: (30)

To calculate the marginal pro�t, observe that the �rm�s problem is separablein the price and investment decisions. Facing the isoelastic demand (2) and

29

Page 30: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

a marginal cost of production equal to one, the �rm sets Pi = 1� . The �rm�s

cash �ow then is

�i =1� ���

21��LiZ

�i Z

1�� � �Z

and has the convenient property that

@�i@Zi

= ��i + �Z

Zi:

Substituting into (30) and imposing symmetry yields (7).

7.2 The economy with public debt

I now show that the economy with lump-sum taxes yields the same equi-librium path as the economy with public debt. The household budget con-straint reads

_B+ _sNV +s _NV = rB+h(1� tD)D � tV _V

isN+(1� tL)Wle�t�(1 + tC)C;

where B is the stock of government bonds and the remaining notation isunchanged. For simplicity I assume no taxation of the interest income fromgovernment bonds. This setup is standard and yields the same �rst-orderconditions as the case of lump-sum taxes, with the only addition that indif-ference between stocks and bonds requires that they pay the same after-taxrate of return. This is just another way of saying that equilibrium of theassets market requires no-arbitrage.

The introduction of public debt, therefore, does not change the equilib-rium behavior of the household and corporate sectors of the economy. Thebudget constraint for the government is

G+ rB = tLWL+ tCC + t�N (��R) + tDDsN + tV _V sN + _B:

Now recall the normalization s � 1, the de�nition of pre-tax dividendsD = (1� t�) (��R), and substitute the household�s constraint into thegovernment�s constraint to obtain

G+ _NV = N (��R) +WL� C:

Recalling the free-entry condition V = �Z, the de�nition of cash �ow, � =(P � 1)X � �Z, and that the representative �nal producer remunerates itsfactors of production according to WL = (1� �)Y and NPX = �Y , thisbecomes

Y = G+ C +N (X + �Z +R) + �Z _N;

30

Page 31: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

which is the resource constraint used in the text. It follows that replacinglump-sum taxation with public debt leaves the dynamical system unchanged.In other words, Ricardian equivalence holds.

7.3 Proof of Proposition 1

Equations (7), (11) and (16) yield:

z = (1� t�)1�tD1�tV

� � 1�tD1�tV

�� (1� t�)

�1�tD1�tV � ��

�� (1� �)

� � 1�tD1�tV

l (c)

n;

r � z = (1� t�)"(1� tV )�+

1�tD1�tV � ��� � 1�tD

1�tV

#� (1� �) l (c)

n

� (1� t�)1�tD1�tV

� � 1�tD1�tV

�:

Equations (14), (17) and (18) then yield the dynamical system:

n =

�'1 � c

n (1 + �c)� '2

�;

c ='3n� '4 (1 + �c) ;

where I de�ne:

'1 � 1� g � �2 + (1� t�)

�1�tD1�tV � ��

�� (1� �)

� � 1�tD1�tV

> 0;

'2 �1

"��+ �

� � t� 1�tD1�tV� � 1�tD

1�tV

#> 0;

'3 � (1� t�)"(1� tV )�+

1�tD1�tV � ��� � 1�tD

1�tV

#� (1� �) > 0;

'4 � (1� t�)1�tD1�tV

� � 1�tD1�tV

�+ � > 0:

The _n � 0 and _c � 0 loci are, respectively:

'1 � c � '2 (1 + �c)n)'1 � '2n1 + '2�n

� c;

31

Page 32: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

1 � '4'3(1 + �c)n) 1

�'3'4n

� 1�� c;

The steady state is:c� = '1 � '2

'3'4;

n� ='3

'4 + � ('1'4 � '3'2):

The phase diagram is in Figure 2. The existence condition for the steadystate is that the _c = 0 locus cut the horizontal axis to the left of where the_n = 0 locus does:

'1'2>'3'4:

Paths above the saddle path eventually yield zero or negative n and thuscannot be equilibria. Paths below the saddle path eventually yield zero ornegative c and similarly cannot be equilibria.

7.4 Proof of Proposition 2

The sign of the partial derivative of (20) with respect to z is given by

� (1� tD)(1� �)

1�tD1�tV � ��

+ (1� tV ) = �� (1� tV )1� 1�tD

1�tV1�

1�tD1�tV

1� � �

;

the sign of the partial derivative with respect to tD by

�� (1� t�)� (1� �) z� = [�� (1� t�) tV + (1� �) �]�1� tD1� tV

� ���;

and the sign of the partial derivative with respect to t� by

� (1� tD)��

1�tD1�tV � ��

:

The partial derivative with respect to tV is always negative.

7.5 Proof of Proposition 4

I follow the same procedure as in the proof of Proposition 1 to obtain thedynamical system:

n =

�'1 � c

n1�� (1 + �c)� '2

�;

32

Page 33: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

c = (1 + �c)

�'3

n1�� (1 + �c)� '4 � �n

�:

Using the �rst equation, the second becomes

c = (1 + �c)

�'3

n1�� (1 + �c)� '4 � �

'1 � cn1�� (1 + �c)

+ �

�'2

�:

For the purposes of this exercise, it is useful to write the _n � 0 and _c � 0loci, respectively, as follows:

n ��

'1 � c'2 (1 + �c)

� 11��

;

n �

24 '3 � �� ('1 � c)�'4 � ��'2

�(1 + �c)

35 11��

:

The steady state isc�� = '1 � '2

'3'4;

n�� =

�'3

'4 + � ('1'4 � '3'2)

� 11��

:

Figure 4 shows the phase diagram. I have two cases, depending on whetherthe _c = 0 locus is decreasing or increasing, although this feature does nota¤ect the dynamics. As for the case � = 0, the existence condition is thatthe _c = 0 locus cut the horizontal axis to the left of where the _n = 0 locusdoes. Notice that

'1'2>'3'4>'3 � ��'1'4 � ��'2

;

so that existence of the equilibrium with � = 0 implies existence of theequilibrium with 0 < � < 1. As before, paths above the saddle path even-tually yield zero or negative n and thus cannot be equilibria. Paths belowthe saddle path eventually yield zero or negative c and similarly cannot beequilibria.

7.6 Proof of Proposition 5

The transition dynamics in response to the tax cut feature time pro�les of c,l, and z that are qualitatively identical to those discussed in Proposition 2 forthe case � = 0: the consumption ratio c jumps down and raises thereafter,

33

Page 34: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

converging to a value c�� < c�; the employment ratio l jumps up and fallsthereafter, converging to a value l�� > l�; the growth rate of quality jumpsdown and rises thereafter converging to a value z�� < z�. Observe that thegain from product variety is largest at the end of the transition when n islargest, while the loss from lower consumption and the slowdown of qualitygrowth is smallest at the end of the transition when c and z are highest. IfI can show that at the end of the transition the gain from variety is smallerthan the losses from consumption and quality growth, then I have that thechange in utility is surely negative. In other words, if I can show that thepolicy reduces welfare when the transition has in�nite speed, which is whenthe variety gain has the maximal chance of overturning the consumptionand quality growth losses, then the policy surely reduces welfare in the caseof the transition with �nite speed. Speci�cally, I want to show that

� =

Z 1

0e�(���)t log

u (t)

u�dt < �1 =

Z 1

0e�(���)t log

u��

u�dt < 0:

Using (28) and integrating, the inequality I seek to establish is

�1 =1

�� �

"(1 + ) log

c��

1+�c��

c�1+�c�

+ � logn��

n�+z�� � z��� �

#< 0:

Given that � > �, I need to show that the expression inside the bracket ispositive. Upon re�ection, this requires me to show that the expression

(1 + ) logc

1 + �c+ � log n+

z

�� �

is increasing in tD in a neighborhood of c = c��. To accomplish this task,it is useful to recall equation (26), which says that the steady-state mass of�rms per capita is

n =�

r (1 + �c); � � � (1� �) (1� tV ) (1� t�)�:

Therefore, I can use r = �+ z to rewrite the expression above as

(1 + ) logc

1 + �c� � log c� � log (�+ z) + z

�� � + � log�:

The last term is a constant independent of tD. This procedure splits utilityin the sum of two components, one due to consumption c and one due to

34

Page 35: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

quality growth z. A su¢ cient condition for the sum to be increasing is thateach component be increasing. Therefore, I have the two conditions:�

1 + + �

c (1 + �c)� �c

�dc

dtD> 0;�

� �

�+ z+

1

�� �

�dz

dtD> 0:

The characterization of the steady state yields

dc

dtD> 0 and

dz

dtD> 0:

Then, the second inequality is surely satis�ed because

�+ z

�� � > 1 > �:

The �rst inequality holds in a neighborhood of the new steady state if

1 +

�> �c��:

Taking into account that c� > c��, I can rewrite this condition as

1 +

�> �c�;

which concerns the steady state that the economy starts from instead of thatto which it converges after the tax cut. This condition is of course satis�edfor � = 0. It is also satis�ed for = 0, i.e., � = 0, which yields inelasticlabor supply. It is useful to use the employment equation (14) to rewritethe inequality as

l� >1

1 + 1+ �

;

which does not require information on tax rates.

7.7 Calibration

Table A1. Steady states and �scal variables

35

Page 36: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

Variable Description Value Sourcec� consumption

output 0.69 NIPA

l� employmentpopulation 0.33 NIPA

r� interest rate 0.04 NIPAz� growth rate 0.02 NIPAg public spending

output 0.143 NIPAt� corporate 0.335 NIPA T1.10, line 18line 17tD dividend 0.35 JGTRRAtV capital gains 0.2 JGTRRAtL labor 0.256 Daveri and Tabellini (2002)tC consumption 0.05 Mendoza et. al. (1997)

The exact formula for t� is the following:

t� =taxes on corporate income to government

pro�ts with inventory valuation and capital consumption adj.:

The values for tD, tV before and after the policy change are the statutoryrates reported in the JGTRRA.

Table 2. Calibrated parameters

Parameter Value Description Source� 0.31 capital share NIPA� 0.01 population growth U.S. census� 0.02 discount rate conventional 1.439 preference for leisure eq. (14)� 6.55 sunk entry cost eq. (24)� 0.163 appropriable quality eqs. (22), (25) given �� 0.068 �xed operating cost eqs. (22), (25) given �

The procedure is the following. For , I used equation (14) and data onc�, l�, tL, tC from Table 1. For �, I used equation (24) and computedNVY = average 1995-2005 ratio of nonfarm non�nancial corporate businesscorporate equities liability to adjusted income (source: FED Flow of Fundaccounts, L.213, Table: Corporate equities) and L

N = average employmentper �rm (source: Laincz and Peretto (2006)).

36

Page 37: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

References

[1] Aghion P. and Howitt P., 1998, Endogenous Growth Theory, Cam-bridge, MIT University Press.

[2] Aghion P. and Howitt P., 2006, Growth with Quality-Improving Inno-vations: An Integrated Framework, in: Handbook of Economic Growth,Edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, North Holland.

[3] Dinopoulos E. and Thompson P., 1998, Schumpeterian Growth withoutScale E¤ects, Journal of Economic Growth, 3, 313-335.

[4] Dinopoulos E. and Thompson P., 1999, Scale E¤ects in SchumpeterianModels of Economic Growth, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 9,157-187.

[5] Djankov S., La Porta R., Lopez-de-Silanes F., Shleifer A., 2002, TheRegulation of Entry, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1-37.

[6] Howitt P., 1999, Steady Endogenous Growth with Population and R&DInputs Growing, Journal of Political Economy, 107, 715-730.

[7] Jones C.I., 1999, Growth: With or without Scale E¤ects? AEA Papersand Proceedings, 89, 139-144.

[8] Laincz C. and Peretto P.F., 2006, Scale E¤ects in Endogenous GrowthTheory: An Error of Aggregation, not Speci�cation, Journal of Eco-nomic Growth, 11, 263-288.

[9] Madsen J., 2008, Semi-endogenous versus Schumpeterian Growth Mod-els: Testing the Knowledge Production Function Using InternationalData, Journal of Economic Growth, 13, 1-26.

[10] Peretto, P.F., 1998, Technological Change and Population Growth,Journal of Economic Growth, 3, 283-311.

[11] Peretto P.F., 1999, Cost Reduction, Entry, and the Interdependenceof Market Structure and Economic Growth, Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics, 43, 173-195.

[12] Peretto P.F., 2003, Fiscal Policy and Long-Run Growth in R&D-Based Models with Endogenous Market Structure, Journal of EconomicGrowth, 8, 325-347.

37

Page 38: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

[13] Peretto P.F., 2007a, Schumpeterian Growth with Productive PublicSpending and Distortionary Taxation, Review of Development Eco-nomics, 11, 699-722.

[14] Peretto P.F., 2007b, Corporate Taxes, Growth and Welfare in a Schum-peterian Economy, Journal of Economic Theory, 137, 353-382.

[15] Peretto P.F. and Smulders S., 2002, Technological Distance, Growth,and Scale E¤ects, The Economic Journal, 112, 603-624.

[16] Peretto P.F. and Connolly M., 2007, The Manhattan Metaphor, Journalof Economic Growth, 12, 329-350.

[17] Sedgley N., 2006, A Time Series Test of Innovation-Driven EndogenousGrowth, Economic Inquiry, 44, 318-332.

[18] Turnovsky S., 1995,Methods of Macroeconomics Dynamics, Cambridge,MIT University Press.

[19] Ulku H., 2007, R&D, Innovation, adn Growth: Evidence from FourManufacturing Sectors in OECD Countries, Oxford Economic Papers,59, 513-535.

[20] Young A., 1998, Growth Without Scale E¤ects, Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 106, 41-63.

[21] Zeng J. and Zhang J., 2002, Long-Run E¤ects of Taxation in a Non-Scale Growth Model with Innovation, Economics Letters, 75, 391-403.

38

Page 39: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

z

r variety

quality

Dt

Figure 1: Equilibrium of the Corporate Sector with Effects of the Tax Cut

Page 40: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

n

c

c(0) 0=n&

0=c&

n*

c*

c**

n**

Figure 2: General Equilibrium Dynamics with Effects of the Tax Cut

The dashed lines represent the steady-state loci before the tax cut. The Bold line is the transition path in response to the tax cut. For simplicity the diagram represents only arrows of motion for the dynamics after the tax cut.

Page 41: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

z

r saving

investment

Dt

Vtt ,Π

Case βα>−−

V

D

tt

11

z

r saving

investment

VD tt , Πt

Case βα<−−

V

D

tt

11

Figure 3: Steady-State Equilibrium of the Assets Market

Page 42: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

n

c

c(0)

0=n&

0=c&

n(0)

c*

n*

n

c

c(0)

0=n&

0=c&

n(0)

c*

n*

Figure 4: General Equilibrium Dynamics with Social Returns to Variety

Page 43: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

-10 0 10 20 300.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7Consumption (c)

-10 0 10 20 300.05

0.06

0.07

0.08Number of firms (n)

-10 0 10 20 30

0.36

0.4

0.32

Employment (l)

-10 0 10 20 30

0.03

0.035

0.04

0.045

0.05

Rate of return (r)

-10 0 10 20 300.01

0.015

0.02

Growth rate (y)

-10 0 10 20 30

-3.6

-3

-3.3

Log utility (log(u))

Figure 5. Impulse response function η = 0: dividend and capital gains tax rate reduction

Page 44: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

-10 0 10 20 300.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

0.7Consumption (c)

-10 0 10 20 300.03

0.04

0.05

0.06Number of firms (n)

-10 0 10 20 30

0.35

0.4

0.31

Employment (l)

-10 0 10 20 300.03

0.04

0.05

Rate of return (r)

-10 0 10 20 300.01

0.015

0.02

Growth rate (y)

-10 0 10 20 30-4

-3.3

-3.6

Log utility (log(u))

Figure 6. Impulse response function η = 0.1: dividend and capital gains tax rate reduction

Page 45: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

-10 0 10 20 300.62

0.64

0.66

0.68

0.7Consumption (c)

-10 0 10 20 302

3

4

5x 10

-3 Number of firms (n)

-10 0 10 20 300.33

0.34

0.35

0.36Employment (l)

-10 0 10 20 30

0.04

0.045

0.05Rate of return (r)

-10 0 10 20 300.015

0.02

0.025

0.03Growth rate (y)

-10 0 10 20 30

-6.4

-6.2

-6

-5.8

-6.6

Log utility (log(u))

Figure 7. Impulse response function η = 0.5: dividend and capital gains tax rate reduction

Page 46: A Schumpeterian Analysis of De–cit-Financed Dividend Tax …public.econ.duke.edu/~peretto/DeficitFinancedTaxCut.pdfThe dividend tax cut enacted in 2003 with the Job Growth and Taxpayer

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

η

Welfare cost/gain (in %

)

Figure 8. Welfare cost/gain for different values of η

Tax drop

Tax Elimination


Recommended