+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Acid Rain, by David Newbery

Acid Rain, by David Newbery

Date post: 10-Oct-2015
Category:
Upload: teodorasimionel
View: 22 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Acid Rain, by David Newbery
Popular Tags:

of 51

Transcript
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    1/51

    Centre for Economic Policy Research

    Center for Economic Studies

    Maison des Sciences de l Homme

    Acid Rain

    Author(s): David M. Newbery, Horst Siebert and John VickersSource: Economic Policy, Vol. 5, No. 11 (Oct., 1990), pp. 297-346Published by: Wileyon behalf of the Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for EconomicStudies, and the Maison des Sciences de l'HommeStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1344480.

    Accessed: 08/09/2014 12:37

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    .

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    .

    Wiley, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies,Maison des Sciences de l'Hommeare collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access toEconomic Policy.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=blackhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ceprhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ceshttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ceshttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=mshhttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1344480?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1344480?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=mshhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ceshttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ceshttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ceprhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=black
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    2/51

    Economic

    olicy

    October 990

    Printed n Great

    Britain

    Acidrain

    David

    Newbery

    Summary

    Acid rain

    is

    not new

    phenomenon,

    ut nvironmental

    wareness

    has

    grown

    apidly

    ver

    he astdecade.

    Much

    data has been ollected

    and the

    ransmission

    rocess

    s

    better

    nderstood.

    olicy-makers

    n

    Europe

    have et hemselveshe

    bjectivef uniform

    0%

    reduction

    in

    national

    missions

    f

    ulphur

    ioxide nd a

    freeze

    n

    emissions

    of

    nitrogen

    xides.

    Whereas

    imple

    conomic

    rinciples

    ave

    nformed

    uch

    f

    the

    policy ebaten theUS, the ame has notbeen rue n Europe.A

    reduction

    f

    emissions

    hich

    s

    uniform

    cross ountriess

    likely

    o

    be

    highly

    nefficient:

    ather,

    articular

    missions

    hould

    e

    curtailed

    until the

    marginal

    ost

    f

    further

    batement

    quals

    the

    marginal

    benefit

    s measured

    y

    he

    marginal amage hereby

    voided.Within

    and across

    countries,

    marginal

    batement osts

    nd,

    a

    fortiori,

    marginaldamagefrom

    cid rain

    varygreatly.

    hus

    an

    efficient

    emission-reduction

    rogramme

    nvolves

    unequal

    reductions

    f

    emissionscross ountriesnd activities. hepaperoffersalcula-

    tions

    f

    the tructure

    f

    an

    efficient

    rogramme,

    nd

    discusses ow

    we can bestmakeuse

    of

    marketsnd

    prices

    odecentralize

    s

    many

    decisions

    s

    possible.

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    3/51

    Acid rain

    David

    M.

    Newbery

    Department

    f

    Applied

    Economics,

    Cambridge

    nd CEPR

    1. Introduction

    Air

    pollution

    is not a new

    phenomenon-Londoners

    in the twelfth

    century omplained

    about the noxious

    fumes

    from

    burning

    sea

    coal,

    and

    the

    corrosive ffects

    f

    sulphur

    dioxide

    (SO2)

    dissolved

    n rain have

    been

    well

    understood

    for

    a

    least a

    century.

    But the focus of concern

    constantly

    hifts. n Britain moke

    AbatementActs date

    from1853-56.

    The landmark Clean

    Air Act of 1956

    was

    primarily

    response

    to the

    health hazards associatedwiththe

    unregulated

    burning

    of coal. An

    estimated

    4,000

    people

    died

    in

    the

    great

    London

    smog

    of

    December

    1952.

    The US

    has also been concerned

    with

    reducing

    coal

    pollution,

    but

    was

    also active

    n

    reducing

    automobile

    pollution

    from

    quite

    early

    on. Here

    the

    impetus

    was

    the

    deteriorating

    ir

    quality

    n

    urban areas

    like Los

    Angeles

    and

    Washington

    DC,

    where

    photochemical

    mog

    led

    to

    high

    levels

    of

    ozone,

    traced

    to

    exhaust

    emissions

    of

    hydrocarbons

    and

    nitrogen

    xides

    NOx).

    California ed

    the

    way

    n

    ntroducing ighter

    emissions controls. n Europe, the impetusforenvironmental olicy

    developed

    because

    acid rain

    from

    the

    SO2

    and

    NOx

    emissions

    from

    the

    burning

    of

    coal

    and

    oil

    -

    is no

    respecter

    of national boundaries.

    Each

    locality

    and

    country

    discovered

    that

    some

    of the

    immediately

    harmful ffects

    f

    burning

    oal

    could be avoided

    by building

    tall chim-

    neys,

    but this

    merelydispersed

    the

    pollutants

    lsewhere,

    often across

    great

    distances

    to other

    countries.

    These countries

    could

    not

    directly

    controlthe

    deposition

    of

    acid

    rain,

    and could

    instead

    only complain

    I I

    Research

    support

    from

    he

    UK Economic

    and Social Research

    Council's

    grant

    Privatisation

    nd

    Reregulation

    f

    he

    Network

    ndustriess

    gratefullycknowledged.

    am indebted

    to

    Margaret

    Clark

    for

    assistance

    with the literature

    earch,

    to Michael Hannaman

    for

    bringing

    o

    my

    notice

    the

    paper

    by

    Maler

    (1989),

    to R.

    G.

    Derwent of Harwell

    for his

    extremely horough

    and

    helpful

    scientific

    omments,

    nd

    to David

    Pearce,

    John

    Vickers nd

    David

    Begg

    for careful comments.

    None

    of these s to

    he

    held

    responsible

    for

    the

    interpretations

    have chosen.

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    4/51

    Acid rain

    299

    and

    negotiate

    for

    ome

    coordinated

    olution

    o

    the

    perceived

    problem.

    Different ountries

    esponded

    to different acets

    f the

    pollutionprob-

    lem. The

    Scandinavian countries

    were

    troubled

    by

    the death and

    disap-

    pearance

    of fishfrom akes and rivers.Germans worried about forest

    die-back.Glasnost evealedthe full

    xtent

    f

    theenvironmental

    isasters

    in Eastern

    Europe,

    and

    provided

    the

    focus

    for

    local

    hostility

    o the

    environmental

    nsensitivity

    f central

    planning.

    Environmental wareness has

    grown rapidly

    over

    the

    past

    decade,

    and with

    t

    the

    growing

    realization hat we live

    on

    a

    rather mall and

    fragileplanet.

    The

    green

    movementhas

    had to work hard

    to

    capture

    the attention nd

    imagination

    f the

    public

    and

    politicians,

    nd has had

    to resort o emotionalarguments o getitsmessageacross.There is no

    doubt

    that the

    hidden

    environmental osts

    of

    current

    echnologymay

    be

    high,

    ven

    life-threatening,

    ut t

    s

    also clear

    from ecent

    xperience

    that

    the costs of

    carelesslydesigned

    environmental

    egulation

    an also

    be

    high.

    As

    economists,

    we

    have a

    duty

    to

    argue

    for

    cost-effective

    environmental

    olicies.

    Inefficient

    olicies

    not

    only

    achieve

    less than

    they

    should,

    but

    they

    also run the

    risk of

    alienating taxpayers

    and

    consumers

    who

    ultimately ay

    for the

    regulation

    nd

    may

    undermine

    the

    aims of

    the

    environmental

    movement.

    conomists,

    with

    honourable

    exceptions,have tended to ignoreenvironmental conomicsbecause it

    seems

    to raise few

    new

    ideas.

    Most of the useful

    techniques

    have been

    the stuff f

    undergraduate

    welfare conomics ince

    Pigou's

    day.

    Though

    each

    generation

    adds to

    the stock of

    knowledge

    and

    techniques,

    the

    subject

    has not been at the theoretical

    utting dge

    for

    ome time.This

    might

    ot

    have mattered

    f

    conomists ad been

    supplied

    with ccessible

    facts

    with

    whichto clothe

    the

    theory

    nd to

    bring

    the

    policy

    ssues nto

    sharp

    perspective.

    But these factsare

    largely

    produced by

    scientists

    unfamiliar

    with

    he economic

    tyle

    f

    argument,

    nd often nconcerned

    with conomic costs nd benefits. here has been too little ommunica-

    tion between the

    disciplines.

    It is

    interesting

    o

    compare

    the situation

    n the US. The

    style

    of

    regulation

    exemplifiedby

    the Environmental rotection

    Agency,

    nd

    the

    separation

    of

    legislative

    nd executive

    power,

    means that

    environ-

    mental

    egislation

    has to be

    argued

    in a

    quasi-judicial

    way

    before

    being

    enacted,

    and

    economistshave

    been

    centrally

    nvolved n the

    ensuing

    debates

    not

    necessarily

    uccessfully.

    s a resultof

    having

    to make a

    quantified

    case in

    public,

    economists have

    investigated

    he

    scientific

    evidence,

    have conducted

    empirical nquiries,

    and have identified

    he

    gaps

    in

    our

    knowledge.

    Environmental conomics

    has received a

    con-

    siderable

    mpetus

    nd a

    solid

    body

    of

    theory

    nd

    evidence on which

    o

    build.

    We in

    Europe lag

    behind,

    though

    there

    are

    signs

    that

    the times

    are

    changing.

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    5/51

    This

    contribution

    eals with

    small

    part

    of the

    environmental

    ebate,

    that

    oncerned

    with

    cid

    rain.

    t

    is

    an

    important

    opic

    not as

    important

    as

    the

    greenhouse

    effect,

    which s

    global

    in

    scale,

    and

    probably

    not

    as

    important

    s traffic

    ongestion,

    which is a domestic matterfor each

    country.

    Nevertheless,

    ubstantial

    ums of

    money

    have been

    spent

    and

    are now

    being

    committed n an

    attempt

    o

    alleviate

    he

    problem

    of

    acid

    rain. The

    thrust

    of this

    paper

    is

    that this

    programme

    as

    currently

    interpreted

    s

    flawed,

    nnecessarily xpensive,

    nd

    if t

    succeeds,

    t

    runs

    the risk

    of

    high political

    cost.

    Relatively imple

    economic

    principles

    applied

    to the

    appropriate

    facts

    ught

    to

    be able to

    achieve

    the

    same

    environmental

    enefits t

    substantially

    ower

    cost,

    nd

    in

    a more

    decen-

    tralized nd less politically roblematicway.

    I

    make no

    apologies

    for

    the

    high

    ratio of

    factsto

    theory

    n

    what

    follows.

    The

    environmental ebate

    has been

    long

    on

    emotional

    argu-

    ment and

    shorton

    substance

    for too

    long.

    I

    am not an

    expert

    n this

    field,

    nd

    have

    had to

    rely

    on

    secondary

    ources for the

    data. On the

    crucial

    ssue of

    quantifying

    he

    benefits f

    reducing

    acid rain

    I have

    not

    been

    able to

    find

    dequate

    evidence

    and so

    cannot

    finally

    uantify

    the

    efficient

    olicy.

    But I

    have

    found

    enough

    evidence to cast

    consider-

    able

    doubt about

    the

    priorities

    or

    abatement,

    nd

    to

    suggest

    where

    research efforthould be concentrated. everal findings urpriseme.

    Fish death

    from

    cid rain

    is

    sad,

    but

    economically

    unimportant.

    ree

    death

    may

    be far

    more

    important,

    hough

    there

    are

    worrying

    ncer-

    tainties

    bout the

    cause and

    cure of

    this

    problem.

    Health

    problems

    associated

    with

    oal

    emissions,

    articularly

    he

    combination

    f

    SO2

    and

    particulates

    smoke

    particles)

    are

    potentially

    f

    the first

    mportance,

    whereas

    those

    associated with

    NOx

    and ozone

    seem

    trivial.

    2. Acid rain and its effects

    In

    order

    to

    understand the

    acid

    rain

    problem

    it

    is

    necessary

    first o

    describe

    the

    causes

    and

    consequences

    of

    acid rain.

    Considerable scien-

    tific

    esearch

    over

    the

    past

    decade has

    illuminated his

    phenomenon,

    though

    uncertainties

    emain.

    The

    next

    step

    is to

    identify

    he

    sources

    and

    measure

    the

    amounts of

    pollutant

    eleased,

    and their

    destination.

    What s it

    that

    causes

    the

    damage,

    where

    does the main

    damage

    occur,

    and what

    are

    economically

    he

    most

    expensive

    consequences

    of

    acid

    rain?

    Finally,

    one

    needs

    to

    determine the

    techniques

    available

    for

    reducing

    emissions, nd the costsof

    abatement,

    n order to

    identify

    cost-effective

    batement

    policies.

    This

    last

    step

    is

    usually ignored

    by

    ecologists

    nd

    politicians,

    who

    are

    content

    once

    they

    have

    found

    ways

    of

    reducing

    acid rain

    to

    press

    for

    the

    maximum

    politically?)

    easible

    degree

    of

    abatement.

    This section

    ddresses

    each

    issue

    in

    turn.

    300

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    6/51

    2.1.

    Defining

    acid

    rain

    Acid

    rain s

    normally

    nderstood o include the

    deposition

    of

    the

    acidic

    combustion

    productssulphurdioxide, SO2,

    various

    nitrogenoxides,

    NOx,

    and

    chloride,

    Cl-,

    either s

    dry

    gases

    or

    particles,

    r

    as

    wet

    deposits

    in

    rain, now,

    sleet,

    hail,

    mistor

    fog.

    These

    pollutants

    sually

    undergo

    a

    seriesof chemical

    ransformationsnto

    sulphuric

    cid,

    nitric cid

    and

    hydrochloric

    cid. These acids

    affect he

    environment,

    oth

    directly

    and

    indirectly

    n

    causing

    the release of further

    armful hemicals uch

    as aluminium.Acid rain can

    be

    measured

    n a

    variety

    f

    ways

    in terms

    of

    tonnesof the

    original

    gases

    released,

    or

    tonnes

    of

    elemental

    ulphur,

    or in terms of the

    acidity

    of the

    rainfall,run-off,

    treams or lakes.

    Aciditys measuredin pH unitson a logarithmiccale.' As thescale is

    logarithmic,

    ainfall

    with a

    pH

    of 5

    is

    10

    times as acid as that with

    pH

    of 6.

    Unpolluted

    rain

    s

    slightly

    cidic

    from

    issolved

    arbon dioxide

    and has a

    pH

    of about 5.6. Sea

    water s

    naturally

    lkaline,

    having pH

    of 8.3.

    Most

    SO2

    comes

    from

    arge

    combustion

    plants-thus

    in

    1987,

    85%

    came

    from

    arge

    combustion

    plants,

    nd

    73%

    from

    power

    stations.Of

    UK emissions

    rom ossil

    uel

    combustion,

    9%

    came

    from

    oal

    combus-

    tion and

    12%

    fromfuel oil.2

    Sulphur

    dioxide

    pollutes

    he environment

    throughtwo different outes.Much of the gas fallsto earthwithin

    300 km of the

    source

    in

    its

    dry

    form,

    nd this

    process

    s described as

    dry

    deposition. Long-range transport

    ccurs

    because

    SO2

    is

    oxidized

    to

    sulphateparticles,

    which re not

    readilydeposited

    n

    dry

    form.

    Their

    main removal s

    by scavenging

    n

    rain-making rocesses

    s wet

    deposi-

    tion,

    which

    may

    occur

    1,000-2,000

    km from he

    source.

    Wet

    deposition

    can be

    reported

    n two

    ways by

    ts

    ntensity

    nd cumulative

    eposition.

    Intensity

    s shown

    by

    the

    maps

    of the

    average acidity

    f

    precipitation

    (in

    pH),

    and

    cumulative

    depositionby

    wet

    deposited acidity

    n

    gramsof

    hydrogen

    ons

    per

    square

    metre

    per year. Deposited

    acidity

    s the

    product

    of the

    acidity

    of the rainfall nd

    the

    amount

    of rain wetter

    areas

    in

    the west

    may

    have more

    acid

    deposited

    even

    though

    the

    precipitation

    s less

    acidic.

    2.2.

    Measuring

    acid

    rain

    The

    European

    Monitoring

    nd Evaluation

    Programme

    EMEP)

    was set

    up

    in 1978 to monitor he movement f

    pollutants,

    nd

    to determine

    I I

    pH

    is defined as the

    negative

    ogarithm

    f

    the

    hydrogen

    on

    (H+)

    concentration,

    aving

    the

    perverse

    effect

    hat lower numbers

    correspond

    to

    higher

    acidity.

    Thus

    0

    is

    most

    acid,

    7 is

    neutral

    and

    14 most alkaline.

    Lemon

    juice

    has a

    pH

    of

    2,

    milk of

    magnesia

    10.5.

    2

    UK data are

    taken from he

    Digest f

    Environmentalrotection

    nd Water

    tatistics,988,

    Depart-

    ment of the

    Environment).

    igures

    after 1970 are based

    on revisedemissionfactors escribed

    therein.

    Acid

    rain

    301

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    7/51

    where the

    deposition

    of

    pollutants

    eleased fromeach source

    occurs.

    Until

    recently

    he

    only

    pollutant

    rackedwas

    SO2,

    though

    now

    NOx

    is

    also

    monitored.The surface

    f

    Europe

    is divided nto

    squares

    with

    gridlines 150 km

    apart.

    There are about

    720

    grid

    ineintersectionsn land

    and

    about

    100

    monitoring

    iteswhich re used in the EMEP model

    and

    these

    are

    termed

    rrival

    points.

    Using

    detailed

    meteorological

    nforma-

    tion,

    the track

    of air

    which

    arrived

    at

    each of the

    820

    or

    so

    points

    s

    followed

    backwards

    n

    time for96

    hours. An air

    parcel

    is then studied

    forwards

    n

    time

    as

    it

    follows

    each back-track

    precisely,

    picking

    up

    pollution

    and

    depositing pollution

    until it

    arrives back at its arrival

    point.

    This whole

    procedure

    for

    each of

    the

    820

    points

    s

    repeated

    at

    six-hourlyntervals 65 daysof theyear.The model alsokeepsa record

    of the

    pollution produced by

    each

    country.

    Not all the

    deposition

    can

    be tracedback

    to an

    identified

    ource,

    s

    meteorological

    ata is accurate

    enough

    to track

    back

    for

    only

    96

    hours. Table

    1

    gives

    a

    subset of the

    basic data

    from

    this

    exercise for

    1987,

    and

    is

    to

    be read

    as

    follows.3

    Looking

    along

    the row

    against

    GB the table showsthat

    Britainreceived

    14,000

    tonnes of

    sulphur4

    i.e.

    about

    27,000

    tonnes

    SO2)

    from

    France,

    11,000

    tonnes

    from

    West

    Germany

    DE)

    and

    571,000

    tonnes from

    domestic

    sources.

    Looking

    down the

    column headed GB the

    Table

    shows that Britain emitted1,271,000 tonnes of sulphurwhose final

    destination

    could be

    established,

    and of this

    43,000

    tonnes fell on

    France.

    45,000

    tonnes on

    Germany

    and

    437,000

    tonnes

    on

    North

    Africa within the

    monitoring

    rea

    (demonstrating ust

    how

    far the

    plume

    can

    travel).

    The

    large

    numberson the

    diagonal

    of Table 1 showshow

    important

    domestic sources of

    pollution

    are. The

    large off-diagonal

    numbers

    indicatewhere the

    major mpacts

    f

    one

    country

    n another

    occur,

    nd

    it

    is

    striking

    hat

    they

    primarily

    ccur in

    East

    Europe,

    confirming

    he

    viewthat central

    planning

    has been an environmental isasterfor ts

    participants.

    Table

    2

    presents

    the

    information rom the

    same

    programme

    n

    a

    different

    ay.

    The first wo

    columns

    give

    totalemissions

    not

    ust

    those

    whose final

    destination an

    be

    identified)

    or the

    base

    year

    1980 and

    the most

    recent

    year

    available,

    n

    order of

    magnitude.

    This allows an

    estimateof the

    extent to

    which

    countries have succeeded in

    moving

    towards

    he

    target

    30%

    reduction

    now

    widely ccepted.

    The next two

    columnsgive depositionswithin he country, nd an estimateof the

    I

    1

    3

    The

    fullertable is

    given

    in

    the

    Appendix

    and is the

    source of

    calculations

    reported

    below.

    Using

    the

    abbreviated able

    leads to considerable

    biases in

    estimating

    otal

    damage,

    and the

    complete

    table should be used for

    all

    calculations.

    4

    To

    convert

    ulphur

    to

    sulphur

    dioxide,

    multiply y

    1.9,

    or

    roughly

    double the numbers.

    302

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    8/51

    Table

    1.

    Origins

    of

    sulphur deposition

    in

    Europe

    (thousand

    tonnes

    a

    year)

    Emitters

    CS

    FR DD DE

    BL HU

    IT PL ES

    SC

    Czechoslovakia

    CS

    France

    FR

    GDR

    DD

    West

    Germany

    DE

    Benelux

    BL

    Hungary

    HU

    Italy

    IT

    Poland

    PL

    Spain

    ES

    Scandinavia

    SC

    USSR*

    SU

    Britain GB

    Other

    Europe

    OE

    N. Africa

    NA

    Sum

    Error

    385

    11

    128

    28

    5

    45 10 95

    1

    19

    332

    41 40 28

    5

    21

    15 65

    84

    14

    725

    61

    11 2

    2

    32

    1

    47

    69 163 330

    44

    3 13 23

    6

    4 32

    15 51

    102

    0 0

    4

    2

    31

    3

    16 6

    1 190

    12

    25

    0

    13

    21

    15

    8 2

    11 353

    14

    10

    145

    15

    310 47 10

    40 10 790

    1

    2

    11 5

    3 1 2 2

    3

    523

    17 5

    48

    18 6

    4

    2

    44 0

    107

    10

    167

    36 8 84

    13

    337

    1

    5 14 15 11 8 0 1 3 2

    95

    40

    97 49 8

    141

    136

    101

    29

    105

    136 253

    131

    71 64 182

    194 210

    1,064

    721

    2,005

    823

    322

    594

    759

    1,685

    856

    5

    8

    7

    4 17

    3 2

    5 5

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    0

    1

    0

    59

    8

    0

    3

    28

    107

    8

    Source:

    Acid

    Magazine,

    Sept.

    1989,

    fromEMEP

    data.

    Notes:

    Sulphur

    dioxide

    figures

    will be

    about

    twice s

    large.

    *

    European part

    of

    USSR within

    EMEP area

    of

    calculation.

    UI

    =

    unattributable

    o

    any

    country, lus

    a small

    amount

    from N. Africa.

    Receivers

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    9/51

    Table 2.

    Sulphur

    emissions

    (thousand

    tonnes

    or

    %)

    Emissions

    Change

    Depositions

    1980

    1987

    %

    1980

    1987

    USSR* 6,400 5,100 -20 5,101 3,584

    GDR

    2,500

    2,500

    0 963

    979

    Poland

    2,050 2,270

    +10

    1,443 1,492

    UK

    2,335

    1,840

    -21

    803

    702

    Spain

    1,625

    1,581

    -3

    670

    674

    Czechoslovakia

    1,550

    1,450

    -6 818

    765

    Italy

    1,900 1,252

    -34

    916 562

    German

    Fed

    Rep

    1,600

    1,022

    -36

    1,083

    821

    France

    1,779

    923

    -48

    1,160

    760

    Hungary

    817

    710

    -13

    416

    337

    Yugoslavia

    588

    588

    0

    662

    497

    Bulgaria

    517

    570

    +9

    293

    235

    Belgium 400 244 -39 162 121

    Greece 200

    180

    -10

    150

    119

    Turkey

    138

    177

    +22

    209

    210

    Finland 292

    162

    -44

    273 210

    Denmark

    219

    155

    -13

    110

    83

    Netherlands

    244

    141

    -42

    175

    139

    Portugal

    133

    116

    -13

    83

    83

    Sweden

    232

    116

    -50

    333

    307

    Romania

    100

    100

    0 405

    330

    Ireland

    110

    84

    -24

    66

    68

    Austria

    177

    75

    -58 282

    207

    Norway 70 50 -29 199 194

    Switzerland

    63

    31

    -51 121

    70

    Total

    26,078

    21,471

    -18

    20,484

    16,695

    Source: Acid

    Magazine,

    Sept.

    1989,

    from

    EMEP data.

    Notes:

    Sulphur

    dioxide

    figures

    will be

    twiceas

    large.

    Countries

    ordered

    by

    1987 emissio

    *

    European

    part

    of USSR

    within

    EMEP

    area

    of

    calculation.

    Figures

    for emissions

    n 1987

    based

    on

    interpolation

    xcept

    for

    USSR,

    UK,

    Czechoslova

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    10/51

    fraction

    f

    depositions

    which can be

    traced

    back

    to

    domestic

    sources

    (using

    Table 1

    data).

    This

    confirms

    he

    importance

    of

    the

    diagonal

    element n

    Table

    1,

    and

    the

    mportance

    f

    domestic

    ourcesofpollution.

    The

    final olumn

    gives

    the

    ratio of

    exports

    of

    SO2

    to

    imports.

    As total

    depositions

    n

    1987

    are

    only

    78%

    of

    total

    emissions,

    his

    ratio can

    be

    expected

    to

    be

    significantly

    bove

    unity

    on

    average.

    The

    smaller t

    is,

    the more

    the

    country

    s

    sinned

    against,

    han

    sinner.

    Britain

    tands out

    as

    the

    greatest

    inneron

    this

    criterion,

    nd the

    Scandinavian

    countries

    as those

    most

    sinned

    against.

    Only part

    of

    total

    SO2

    emissions

    ome from

    man-made

    ources;

    other

    important

    ources

    nclude

    volcanoes,

    biological

    decay

    and

    forest

    fires.

    These natural ourcesmight ccount for80-290 mn.tonnesperannum

    worldwide,

    compared

    to

    total

    man-made

    emissions of

    75-100

    mn.

    tonnes.

    The levels

    and

    mechanisms

    responsible

    for

    natural

    emissions

    are

    imperfectly

    nderstood,

    but

    they

    may play

    an

    important

    ole in

    the

    European

    acid rain

    problem.

    The

    information

    enerated

    by

    EMEP

    is

    remarkably

    seful,

    not

    only

    in

    quantifying

    he level

    of

    pollution,

    but also in

    identifying

    fficient

    and feasible

    batement

    policies.

    The

    information

    n

    deposition

    can

    be

    used to draw

    maps

    showing

    the

    average acidity

    of

    precipitation

    ver

    Europe using contour ines of increasing evels of acidity.Such maps

    show

    that

    n

    1987 most

    of

    Yorkshire

    nd the

    East

    Midlands had

    precipi-

    tation f

    average

    acidity

    elow

    pH

    4.3,

    (i.e.

    five

    imes

    s acid

    as

    'normal'

    rain

    with

    pH

    of

    5.0)

    whereas

    Wales,

    South-west

    ngland

    and the

    west

    coast of

    Scotland

    was

    above

    4.6,

    and so less

    acid.

    Substantial

    reas

    north

    of

    a line

    joining

    the Wash

    and

    Liverpool

    received

    more

    than

    0.05

    gm

    H+

    per

    square

    metre

    y

    wet

    deposition

    i.e.

    0.5

    kg/hectare

    r

    50

    kg/km2),

    with

    Wessex,

    East

    Wales,

    Northern

    reland

    and

    North-east

    cotland

    receiving

    ess

    than

    0.02

    gm.

    Most

    of the

    sulphurdeposition

    n

    the

    UK

    occurs

    through dry

    deposition

    as

    SO2,

    particularly

    n the southand

    eastof

    the

    country.

    n

    the north

    nd

    west

    where

    rainfall s

    more

    frequent

    and

    intense,

    wet

    deposition

    f

    SO2

    and

    sulphate

    particles

    ecomes

    more

    significant.

    In

    a

    European

    context,

    he

    lines of

    equal

    rainfall

    cidity

    how

    the

    highest

    concentrations

    n

    Germany

    and

    Poland,

    with

    pH

    below

    4.1,

    with

    most of

    Southern

    France,

    almost all

    Italy,

    Spain,

    Portugal,

    West

    Yugoslavia

    and

    West

    Greece

    having pH

    greater

    han 4.9

    (i.e.

    less

    acid

    thanany partofthe UK and Ireland).

    The EMEP

    tables can

    also be

    used to throw

    ight

    on

    the

    political

    economy

    of

    pollution

    control.

    Consider first

    he column

    in

    Table

    2

    which

    gives

    the

    fraction f

    total

    deposition

    which can

    be

    attributed o

    domestic

    ources.The

    unweighted verage

    of

    these

    figures

    s

    41%

    (with

    a

    standarddeviation f

    21%).

    The

    weighted

    verage

    heavily

    nfluenced

    Acidrain

    305

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    11/51

    by

    the

    larger

    countries,

    specially

    he

    USSR, which,

    by

    their

    ize,

    have

    higher

    domestic

    absorption)

    s

    52%.

    The

    weighted

    average

    domestic

    absorption

    s a fraction

    f

    total

    production

    s

    33%,

    and

    the

    unweighted

    average

    s 29%

    (with

    standarddeviation f

    only

    5%). What thismeans

    is

    that the

    average

    unilateral

    cost of

    reducing

    a tonne of

    domestic

    deposition

    s

    equal

    to

    the

    cost of

    reducing

    domestic

    missions

    by

    about

    3

    tonnes.

    The ratio of total

    European

    depositions

    to total

    European

    emissions

    s

    66%,

    so that f

    all

    European

    countries

    cted

    in

    concert,

    he

    cost

    of

    reducing depositions

    by

    1 tonne

    would

    be

    only

    half as

    great.

    Put another

    way,

    many

    countries

    ould

    reduce

    depositions

    within heir

    borders

    by

    about

    50%,

    but at twice he cost

    per

    tonne

    reduced as

    if all

    countries cted together.There are thusconsiderablebenefits o coor-

    dinated

    action,

    but these

    should

    not be dramatized

    SO2

    pollution

    s

    farfrom

    pure

    public

    good

    at

    the

    country

    evel,

    nd

    self

    nterest

    ught

    to

    go

    a

    considerable

    way

    towards

    lleviating

    he

    problem.

    The next

    question

    one can ask of

    the EMEP data

    is whether

    here

    are

    significant pportunities

    or

    bilateral

    bargaining

    between

    pairs

    of

    countries ver

    pollution

    evels. One

    way

    to

    identify

    uch

    opportunities

    is to

    ook

    for

    nstanceswhere

    the volume of

    bilateral

    pollution

    xchange

    is

    large

    relative o total

    depositions,

    nd where trade

    is

    bilateralrather

    thanunilateral.The volume can be measuredbyone-half xportsplus

    imports,

    nd bilateralism an be

    measured

    by

    the

    difference

    etween

    exports

    and

    imports.

    Table

    Al of

    the

    Appendix

    gives

    the

    net

    ex-

    ports

    of

    each

    country

    nd can be used to

    identify

    he extentof

    bilater-

    alism.

    The

    following

    ountry

    pairs

    have a difference etween these

    two measures

    of

    5%

    of

    depositions

    or

    less for

    the

    smallerof the

    part-

    ners:

    Czechoslovakia-GDR;

    Czechoslovakia-Hungary;

    zechoslovakia-

    Poland;

    GDR-Poland;

    Poland-Hungary;

    USSR-Czechoslovakia;

    USSR-

    GDR;

    USSR-Hungary;

    USSR-Poland.

    It is

    notable that

    significant

    balanced exchange of pollutionis confined to Eastern Europe, and

    does not affect

    ny

    of the other countries dentified

    n

    Table

    2.

    (It

    may

    be substantial

    for

    smaller countries

    as a

    proportion

    of their

    deposition.)

    Another

    possiblequestion

    to

    ask

    s which

    pairs

    of

    countries

    have

    large

    net

    tradebalances

    n

    pollution

    which

    might

    ead to financial

    egotiations

    over

    pollution

    evels.

    The

    following

    ountrieshave net

    imports

    from

    another

    country

    which re

    greater

    han

    5%

    of total

    depositions:

    Poland

    from

    GDR

    (19%);

    Denmark from

    GDR

    (12%);

    Scandinavia fromGDR

    (10%);

    Scandinavia from Poland

    (9%);

    USSR from Poland

    (9%);

    Czechoslovakia from

    GDR

    (6%);

    Scandinavia from USSR

    (5%).

    Scan-

    dinavia thus contains

    he

    only

    West

    European

    countries

    whichreceive

    large

    net

    mports

    rom

    ingle

    ountries otherwise

    t s the

    Easternbloc

    countries hat stand

    out as

    large

    net

    importers

    rom

    ach other.

    306

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    12/51

    Table 3.

    Emissions

    per

    head

    (kilogramsper

    head

    per year)

    SO2 NO,

    1980 1985 1980 1985

    Austria 47 18

    29

    28

    Czechoslovakia

    202

    203

    78 73

    France 65 31 34

    29

    Germany

    Fed

    Rep

    52

    43 49

    49

    Greece 83 73 13 15

    Ireland

    63

    39

    21

    19

    Netherlands 28

    25

    35

    34

    Poland

    115

    116

    5 18

    Spain

    87 75

    21 24

    Sweden 64 33 38 37

    Switzerland 19 15

    31 33

    UK 85 65

    35 33

    Canada

    193 150

    72 72

    US

    102

    90

    90 83

    Averages:

    All 86 70 39 39

    Europe

    76

    61

    32 32

    West

    Europe

    59

    42

    31 30

    Source:

    UNECE

    (1987)

    abatement.

    National

    trategies

    nd

    policies

    or

    ir

    pollution

    Note:

    Averages

    are

    unweighted.

    Nitrogen

    oxide emissions.

    Nitrogen

    xide,

    or

    NOx,

    emissions re measured

    in

    terms f tonnes

    nitrogen

    dioxide

    equivalent,

    NO2.

    Table 3

    gives per

    capita

    emission

    levels for both

    SO2

    and

    NOx

    for the

    major

    member

    countries f

    the UN Economic Commission

    for

    Europe

    Conventionon

    Long-range Transboundary

    Air Pollution. t shows

    that

    UK levels are

    not

    high

    n

    comparison

    with

    urope

    and

    NorthAmerica

    aken

    ogether,

    but are ratherhigher hanthe WestEuropean countries n thesample.

    The table

    shows that

    whereas

    SO2

    has decreased

    between 1980 and

    1985,

    NOx

    has if

    anything

    ncreased.

    Table

    4

    gives

    further nformation

    bout

    NOx

    for

    1985. The first

    column shows that

    mobile sourcescontribute bout one-half f

    all

    NOx

    emissions

    in

    Western

    Europe

    (actually

    OECD

    Europe),

    though

    the

    range

    is

    from

    28%

    in

    Eire

    to

    84%

    in

    Norway.

    Much

    of

    the rest

    comes

    from

    arge

    combustion

    plants-thus

    in

    Britain

    35%

    of the

    total came

    from

    power

    stations.

    The next

    column shows total emissions

    of

    NOx

    frommobile and

    stationary

    ources n relation ototal

    energy

    use.

    The coefficient

    f

    variation

    CV)

    is

    34%,

    showing

    hat missions

    orrelate

    quite closely

    with

    energy

    consumption,

    but

    there are

    important

    ari-

    ations

    n

    the

    degree

    to which

    energy

    use causes

    NOx

    pollution.

    Britain

    does

    poorly by

    this

    score,

    almost as

    badly

    as

    Portugal

    and

    Greece.

    307

    cid

    rain

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    13/51

    Table

    4.

    NO,

    emissions

    frommobile

    and other

    sources

    Ratio

    of total

    NOx

    to

    Ratioof mobileNOx to

    Mobile

    NOx

    energy

    (%

    of

    total)

    consumption

    GDP car

    use petrol road fuel

    Country

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4) (5)

    (6)

    Austria

    68

    10.1 1.27

    3.76

    61 37

    Belgium

    55 9.0

    0.84

    2.73

    44 22

    Denmark

    34 15.9

    1.04

    2.48

    61 35

    Finland

    58 14.8

    1.80

    7.62

    86 47

    France

    66 13.1 1.29

    2.81

    62

    38

    Germany

    59 14.6

    1.54 3.73

    70

    46

    Greece 63 18.6 3.35 4.36 75 44

    Ireland 28 10.7 1.08

    22

    14

    Italy

    51

    14.8

    1.06

    2.03

    70 34

    Luxembourg

    64 6.9

    2.32

    5.61 45

    28

    Netherlands

    60

    10.5

    1.53

    3.27

    95

    56

    Norway

    84

    12.3 2.27

    9.65

    113 81

    Portugal

    38

    19.6 3.38 4.13

    123

    54

    Spain

    46 18.5

    1.49 4.50

    67 36

    Sweden

    68

    9.2

    1.48 3.26 52

    37

    Switzerland

    74 11.1

    0.92

    3.04

    49 41

    UK

    45 16.4 1.65 2.96

    44

    32

    Europe 49 14.1 1.42 3.15 63 39

    SD

    unweighted

    14

    4.76 0.83

    2.01

    25 14

    CV

    0.29

    0.34

    0.58 0.63

    0.40 0.37

    Sources: UNECE

    (1987)

    and

    OECD

    (1987).

    Data for

    1985-86.

    Notes:

    (2)

    shows

    kg

    of

    NOx

    per

    tonne of

    oil

    equivalent

    of

    energy

    onsumption

    nd

    (3)

    per

    unit

    of GDP.

    (4)

    shows

    gm

    of

    NOx

    per

    km driven

    by

    cars.

    (5)

    and

    (6)

    show

    kg

    of

    NO,

    per

    kg

    of

    petrol

    nd

    kg

    of total road

    transport

    uel. SD is standard

    deviation

    nd

    CV coefficient

    f variation.

    (Figures

    for

    Luxembourg

    seem rather

    ow and

    may

    be

    explained

    by

    some

    energy

    ales,

    especially

    f

    transport

    uel,

    being

    consumed

    abroad.)

    Column

    (3)

    shows

    mobile

    emissions

    f

    NO,

    per

    unit

    of

    GDP

    (which

    has

    a lower CV

    than

    total

    emissions

    per

    unit

    of

    GDP).

    Column

    (4)

    gives

    mobile emissions

    n

    gm

    NO2

    per

    km

    driven

    by

    cars.

    White

    1982,

    Table

    2)

    shows that f there

    were

    no emissions

    regulations,

    hen

    forthe

    US

    64%

    of total

    NOx

    emissions

    would come

    from

    ars,

    and

    the

    balance

    of

    36% from rucks.Uncontrolled missions re 5.44 gm/km orcars, nd

    38.6gm/km

    from

    heavy

    diesel

    trucks.

    The

    expected

    uncontrolled

    emissions

    per

    km driven

    by

    cars

    alone

    might

    herefore

    e

    8.5

    gm/km

    (i.e.

    5.44/0.64)

    f

    the

    proportion

    f car

    km

    n

    total

    vehicle

    km were the

    same as the US.

    The

    European

    average

    is 3.15

    or

    only

    37%

    of

    that

    predicted

    for uncontrolled

    missions.

    Perhaps

    more

    impressive,

    f the

    308

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    14/51

    total emissionsfrom ll mobile sources

    are

    attributed

    ntirely

    o

    cars,

    then

    the

    average

    achieved is about as

    good

    as those achieved

    in

    the US

    by

    cars

    of

    later than 1976 model

    year

    White,

    1982,

    Table

    10).

    The last

    twocolumns relate mobile emissions o two

    transport

    uels.Column

    (5)

    gives

    mobile emissions n

    kg

    per

    tonne of

    gasoline.

    The finalcolumn

    gives

    total

    mobile emissions

    divided

    by

    total fuel consumed

    in

    the

    transport

    ector,

    and thus accounts

    for

    diesel

    emissions,

    which are

    potentially uite

    serious.

    Nitrogen

    xides also come fromnatural

    s well as man-made ources.

    Again

    estimates

    re

    very mprecise,

    but natural sources

    may

    account

    for

    20-90

    mn.

    tonnes

    compared

    to estimated otalman-made

    emissions

    of about 90 mn. tonnes. One might herefore rgue thatperhaps only

    half the

    total

    acid rain

    emissions re

    man-made,

    but

    whereas

    natural

    emissionsare

    worldwide,

    man-made sources are

    concentrated

    n the

    northern

    hemisphere,

    nd

    specifically

    n

    Europe

    and North America.

    2.3.

    Assessing

    the

    damage

    caused

    by

    acid rain

    Acid rain has

    ecological consequences

    in that

    t

    affects he

    soil,

    vegeta-

    tion,

    specially

    orests,

    akes

    and

    hence

    fish).

    t causes

    economic

    damage

    to man-made structuresbuildings,fabrics,metals),and it can affect

    human health.

    The

    ecologicalconsequences

    re

    complex

    nd still

    ubject

    to scientific

    ncertainty

    nd hence

    dispute.

    Soils

    vary widely

    n their

    ability

    o

    buffer

    i.e. neutralize)

    cid

    rain,

    and natural

    processes

    add

    to

    the

    man-made sources of acid rain. Recent work undertaken for the

    UNECE

    Convention on

    Long-range Transboundary

    Air Pollution5

    attempts

    o establish ritical oads for various kinds of

    soils,

    which,

    f

    exceeded,

    would mean that he oilcould no

    longer

    neutralize dditional

    acid rain

    depositions.

    Many

    sensitive reas

    especially

    n

    Scandinavia

    experience

    both

    high

    rates of

    deposition

    and soils for which critical

    loads are

    low.

    The effects f

    acid

    runoff n

    lakes have been

    intensively

    tudied in

    Scandinavia and the UK

    (and

    doubtless

    elsewhere).

    One of the main

    mechanisms

    eading

    to

    the

    decline

    in fish

    stocks is the

    release

    of

    aluminium aused

    by

    acidification,

    ather han the direct

    ffects

    f

    acid

    (see

    e.g.

    Environmental

    Resources,

    Limited,

    1983).

    Palaeoecological

    studies

    of core

    samples

    can traceback

    acidity

    evels nto

    the

    distant

    ast

    and show substantialfalls in pH in many lakes after the industrial

    revolution.

    Thus

    Battarbee

    et

    al.

    (1988)

    analysed

    lake acidification n

    sensitive reas

    in the

    UK and

    found

    thatbefore 1850

    most akes

    studied

    I

    I

    5

    Reported

    n Acid

    News,

    No

    3,

    October 1988.

    Acid rain

    309

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    15/51

    had

    pH

    levels of

    about

    6.0,

    but

    that ince

    then

    pH

    values had declined

    by

    0.5-1.5,

    (i.e.

    acidity

    had

    increased

    by

    between

    3

    and

    30

    times)

    depending

    on

    deposition

    rates and

    bufferingapacities.

    Other

    studies

    show

    similar

    trends,

    and also show

    that

    lake

    acidification

    may

    be

    reversed

    even

    if

    temporarily) y

    the addition of ime either o

    the

    ake

    or the rivers

    n the

    catchment rea.

    This

    is

    expensive,

    s

    about 5

    g/m3

    of

    bicarbonate

    usually

    n the formof

    limestone)

    re

    required

    to raise

    the

    pH

    from

    4.5 to

    6.5,

    and

    it

    does not

    by

    itself estore

    he

    lake

    to

    its

    original

    condition

    restockingmay

    also be

    required.

    (See

    e.g.

    Dudley

    et

    al., 1985; Britt,

    1986.)

    One

    implication

    whichdoes

    not

    eem

    to

    have been

    adequatelyempha-

    sized is thatacid rain is a stockpollutant s well as a flowpollutant.

    That

    is,

    part

    of the final

    damage

    caused

    will

    depend

    on stocksof

    acid

    in

    the

    environment,

    ot

    just

    the rate at which acid rain is

    deposited.

    Even

    if

    the environment

    s

    capable

    of

    neutralizing

    r

    disposing

    of some

    of the

    acid each

    year,

    f inflows

    xceed this

    rate of

    disposal,

    then the

    stockof

    acid will

    ncrease.

    In

    the UK it is

    believed

    that current

    evels

    of soil acidification re a

    legacy

    of

    the

    Industrial

    Revolution,

    nd that

    water

    quality

    will

    not be

    restoreduntilthe soil recovers.This

    recovery

    is a slow

    process

    nd

    relatively

    nsensitive o near-term atesof emission

    reduction, equiring imingforrapid recovery.6 his maygo someway

    to

    explaining

    he

    paradoxical

    relationship

    etween

    decreasing

    evels of

    SO2

    emissions n the one

    hand,

    and

    apparently eteriorating cological

    conditions

    n the other.On

    the other

    hand,

    Battarbee

    et

    l.

    (1988)

    note

    that acid

    deposition

    has been

    declining

    n

    Scotland

    over

    the

    past

    15

    years,

    and that

    the

    uppermost

    sediments are

    already recording

    an

    improvement,

    hich

    uggests possibly

    wift

    mprovement

    f

    deposition

    levelscould be

    further educed. The

    speed

    of

    response

    will

    presumably

    depend

    on the

    ecologicalcircumstances,

    ut

    may implyhigh

    rates of

    'depreciation'

    ofacid stock evels.

    Lake and fish

    damage appears

    quite

    well

    understood

    compared

    to

    the

    damage

    suffered

    y

    trees.The

    problem

    was

    highlighted

    n

    Germany

    in the

    early

    1980s,

    and shown to occur

    elsewhere. Forest

    damage

    has

    been attributed

    o acid

    rain,

    weather

    changes

    and

    droughts,

    he

    age

    of

    trees,

    fragility

    f

    soils at

    high

    altitudes,

    nd

    inappropriate

    forest

    management.

    Ozone

    attack

    appears

    to

    be

    important,

    nd

    may

    have

    synergistic

    nteractions

    with

    acid

    rain

    (Environmental

    Resources

    Limited,1983). Even if theexactproportion fdamage attributableo

    acid rain s not

    known,

    here

    seems

    widespread agreement

    hatreduc-

    tions

    in acid rain would be beneficial o

    forests. imilar

    uncertainty

    pervades

    the

    study

    f

    crop damage, though

    again

    ozone

    appears

    to be

    I

    1

    6

    Personal

    communication

    romProfessorDavid

    Pearce.

    310

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    16/51

    more

    directly

    armful

    han acid rain.

    To the extent hatozone

    plays

    a

    major

    role n

    crop

    and forest.

    amage,

    NOx,

    which

    s a

    major

    contributor

    to ozone

    production,

    s

    more

    damaging

    than

    SO2.

    Damage

    to

    buildings

    and materialsoccurs

    primarily

    n urban areas

    as

    a

    consequence

    of

    relatively igh

    concentrations

    f

    SO2,

    with ittle

    effect etected

    from

    xposure

    to

    NOx.

    The effects

    ave

    been observed

    and

    correctly

    ttributed or

    centuries,

    nd

    the

    estimated

    damage

    costs

    are

    thought

    o be

    high.

    Health effects f intense

    pollution

    an be dramatic-

    as noted

    above,

    it is estimated

    that

    4,000

    people

    died in the

    great

    London

    smog

    of

    December

    1952.

    Similar

    evels

    of

    SO2

    concentration

    were attained

    n

    a

    subsequent episode in London from 3-7 December 1962, after the

    Clean

    Air Act of 1956

    had lead

    to a

    dramatic

    fall

    n

    smoke concentra-

    tions. This time an estimated

    340

    died,

    suggesting

    that the earlier

    episode

    was so

    deadly

    because

    of

    synergistic

    nteractions etween moke

    particles

    nd

    SO2

    (Park,

    1987,

    p.

    127).

    It

    appears

    that

    t is

    the

    gas

    SO2

    that s

    harmful,

    ather

    han

    the

    wet formof acid rain. Acid rain in its

    wet

    form

    an have indirect ffects

    y

    releasing

    toxic

    heavy

    metals

    nto

    water

    upplies.

    ndividuals

    vary onsiderably

    n

    their olerance

    o these

    gases,

    but

    there is some evidence from

    epidemiological

    studies that

    long-term xposureat lower evelsthan thesedramatic pisodes can be

    harmful o

    health

    Park,

    1987,

    p.

    127.

    See also Pearce and

    Markandya,

    1989,

    for

    summary

    f the

    extensive conomics

    iterature

    n

    the health

    impacts

    of

    SO2.)

    If

    SO2

    and

    particulates

    re

    lethal,

    the

    health

    case

    against

    NOx

    is

    at

    best

    unproven,

    for t

    appears

    that

    NOx

    is

    much less active

    biologically.

    There is

    a

    certain

    irony

    in

    the fact that

    the

    impetus

    to

    reducing

    automobile missions

    nitially

    ame from

    California,

    where

    t

    was

    suspec-

    ted,

    nd later stablished

    hat

    photochemical mog

    was caused

    by

    vehicle

    exhaust.The case mounted

    by

    he US Environmental rotection

    gency

    for

    reducing

    missionswas based on the

    supposed

    adverse

    health ffects

    of

    high

    oncentrations

    f

    ozone,

    though ubsequent

    tudies

    Lave,

    1982;

    White,

    1981;

    1982)

    cast considerabledoubt on the evidence. To

    quote

    White

    (1981,

    p.

    59-60):

    '...

    the

    ozone-related health effects

    nder

    discussion

    were

    short

    erm nd

    reversible....

    Thus

    far,

    zone

    exposure

    has not been demonstrated

    o

    have

    ong-term

    ebilitating onsequences

    in

    humans.... The contrast

    with

    other studies of

    pollutants,

    uch as

    particulates nd sulphates,was striking.... Particulates nd sulphates

    probably

    killed;

    ozone

    appeared

    to do

    littlemore than cause

    coughing '

    2.4.

    Measuring

    the costs

    of acid rain

    damage

    Estimates

    orthe

    costs

    of different

    ypes

    f

    damage

    are

    scattered

    n the

    literature,

    nd

    varygreatly

    n their

    reliability.

    earce and

    Markandya

    311

    cid rain

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    17/51

    (1989)

    provide

    a useful

    methodological

    iscussion f

    cost-benefit

    naly-

    sis

    applied

    to

    environmental

    ollution,

    ummarize a

    variety

    f

    these

    estimates,

    nd

    note the

    criticisms o which

    they

    are vulnerable. One

    approach

    familiar o economists s to askwhat

    people

    wouldbe

    willing

    to

    pay

    for

    property

    ocated

    in

    less rather

    than more

    polluted

    air,

    as

    reflected n the

    response

    of

    property

    alues

    to

    pollution

    evels.

    Most of

    the

    estimateshere come

    from he 1960s and

    1970s,

    and

    suggest

    that

    for

    each

    1%

    increase

    in

    SO2

    concentration,

    roperty

    values

    fall

    by

    between

    0.06-0.15 of

    1%

    of their

    value for

    a house of

    average

    value.

    An

    alternative

    pproach

    is to

    look at

    the direct conomiccosts

    aused

    by

    the

    acid

    rain,

    and

    this has

    been done

    by

    for the

    Netherlands

    for

    1986. It was estimated hatcurrent osts wereabout $53-175 mn. per

    annum,7

    but

    f

    the

    costsof

    dealing

    with

    future

    damage

    were

    taken

    nto

    account

    (loss

    of

    timber

    tc.)

    this

    might

    rise to

    $120-380

    mn.

    Looking

    at the current

    costs,

    the

    large

    proportion

    of the

    total comes from

    agricultural damage,

    thus

    extra

    liming

    of the soil to counteract

    acidification

    might

    cost

    $18-60

    mn.,

    and falls n

    crop

    yield

    might

    be

    $36-360

    mn.

    One should

    of

    course be most

    wary

    bout

    estimating

    he

    value of lost

    agriculturaloutput

    given

    the

    distortions f the

    CAP.

    Indeed,

    as an

    aside,

    agriculture

    s

    responsible

    for

    considerable

    ground

    waterpollution notablynitrates,nd possibly lgal blooms).Much of

    this s n

    turn he

    consequence

    of ntensive

    gricultural

    ractices

    nduced

    by

    the

    high agriculturalprices

    enjoyed

    under the

    CAP,

    notablyhigh

    fertilizer

    evels.

    f

    forvarious

    reasons t

    s

    difficulto reform

    gricultural

    output price

    levels,

    then there

    s

    a

    strong

    ase for

    raisingagricultural

    input

    price

    levels to the same ratio

    to

    world

    prices

    as

    output prices

    enjoy.

    This

    would

    improve

    the

    efficiency

    f

    resource use and

    reduce

    the

    deadweight

    osses associated

    with

    the CAP. Thus if

    output

    prices

    are

    twice

    mport

    parity

    evels,

    then fertilizer

    rices

    should be taxed to

    raisetheirpriceto twiceworld market evels.This would

    go

    some

    way

    to

    reducing

    another

    formof

    environmental

    ollution.

    See

    Newbery,

    1990,

    for

    the

    details of the

    arguments

    n

    efficient

    nput

    taxation.)

    Other

    ecological

    damage

    estimates

    are

    given

    in

    Environmental

    Resources

    Limited,

    1983).

    German forest

    amage

    was

    put

    at

    $0.25

    bn.

    p.a.,

    and

    rough

    estimates

    f

    potential

    EC

    wide

    damage

    can be

    deduced

    from he

    annual value of

    spruce

    and

    fir

    orestry roduction

    f

    $6.6

    bn.

    p.a.

    Thus

    if

    20%

    of

    forests re

    adversely

    ffected

    o that heir

    production

    drops by 10%,

    the

    loss is

    $0.13

    mn.

    p.a.8

    OECD

    (1981)

    estimated hat

    I

    I

    7

    Unless

    otherwise

    tated,

    ll cost estimates

    re in mid-1989

    purchasingpower, updating

    from

    the US consumer

    price

    index.

    8

    But

    note that here

    s still

    onsiderable

    disagreement

    s

    to

    how much forest

    amage

    has occurred

    and

    how

    much

    s

    caused

    by

    acid rain.

    312

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    18/51

    the value

    of

    fish oss in

    Scandinavia was

    $38

    mn.

    p.a.

    and

    in

    Scotland

    might

    be

    $0.7

    mn.

    p.a.

    Acid rain causes

    material

    damage,

    whose

    costs,

    excluding

    the

    costs

    of

    restoring

    istoric

    uildings,

    have been estimated

    by

    UNECE

    (1982)

    at between

    $4-17/head

    (i.e.

    $1.0-4.7

    bn. for

    the

    1983

    European

    Com-

    munity

    s a

    whole).

    The

    figures

    n

    the Netherlands

    re somewhat

    higher

    ($10-19/head)

    and in

    Germany

    are estimated at

    $19/head.

    Environ-

    mental

    Resources

    Limited,

    1983)

    gives figures

    romOECD

    (1981)

    for

    the estimated

    otal

    orrosion

    damage

    for

    12

    OECD

    European

    countries

    to

    galvanized

    teel

    nd

    its

    paintcoatings

    n 1974. For the UK the

    figures

    were

    $5.9

    bn.

    p.a.,

    for West

    Germany

    $9.5

    bn.

    p.a.,

    and

    for

    Belgium,

    Luxembourg,Denmark,France and the Netherlands ogether 3.3 bn.,

    or

    in total

    $18.7

    bn. How much of

    this

    can be

    attributed o acid rain is

    stillunder

    study.

    Reducing

    car

    emissions would

    also

    reduce

    photochemical mog

    in

    some areas-

    particularly

    hose which

    experience temperature

    nver-

    sions combined

    with

    strong

    un. Los

    Angeles

    is

    the

    leading example,

    but

    clearly

    Athens suffers

    imilarly.

    here

    is no

    doubt that hose

    iving

    in

    such areas

    would be

    willing

    o

    pay

    for

    reductions

    n

    smog

    evels,

    nd

    Schechter

    t

    al.

    (1989)

    estimate hathouseholds

    in

    metropolitan

    Haifa,

    Israel,would be willing o pay?12 (?1987) per householdper annum

    to

    reduce

    pollution

    levels

    by

    50%.

    It

    is difficulto

    imagine

    that this

    would

    amount to a

    large

    total

    sum

    for

    Europe

    as a whole

    compared

    withthe

    other

    damage

    costs,

    given

    the relative

    nfrequency

    f

    photo-

    chemical

    smog

    in

    more

    Northerly

    limes.

    2.5.

    The costs

    of

    abatement

    The

    Department

    of

    Environment

    stimated

    the

    costs to the UK of

    retrofitting

    GW of coal fired

    plant

    withFlue Gas

    Desulphurization

    (FGD)

    and

    all

    12

    major

    coal fired

    power

    stations

    23 GW)

    with ow

    NOx

    burners at

    over

    ?1 bn. It

    now seems doubtful

    hat more than a small

    part

    of this

    programme

    will

    go

    ahead,

    as the

    liability

    o

    install FGD

    would make the

    privatization

    ale

    of

    the CEGB unattractive.nstead it

    appears

    that the successor

    companies

    to

    the

    CEGB,

    Powergen

    and

    National

    Power,

    will meet the

    emissions tandards

    by

    a combination f

    installing

    igh efficiency

    as

    turbines nd

    importing

    ow

    sulphur

    coal.

    The impact of this on British Coal will be substantial, nd it is in

    interesting

    xample

    of

    how the

    (private) cost-minimizing

    olution

    to

    the emissions standards

    may

    differ rom

    centrally mposed

    solutions.

    The

    Government

    also intends to

    apply

    the EC

    large

    car emission

    standards

    'as soon as

    practical, probably

    in the

    early

    1990s,'

    at

    an

    estimated nnual cost

    of

    ?550

    mn.

    The second

    stage, pplying

    o small

    Acid

    rain

    313

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    19/51

    Table 5. Estimates of

    costs

    of

    reducing

    SO2

    by

    various means

    Cost

    ($1989)

    per

    tonneof SO2

    Source Action removed

    A

    moving

    o

    low

    sulphur gas

    oil

    2,560

    A

    moving

    o

    low

    sulphur

    fuel oil 640

    A Fluidized bed combustors

    FBC):

    new

    boilers 96

    existing

    2,240

    A

    Flue

    gas

    desulphurization

    FGD):

    new

    plant

    256

    existingplant

    640

    B Drax FGD newplant 350

    C

    FGD retrofit

    ,000

    MW

    plant

    400-750

    D

    60%

    reductionfrom

    40

    GW CEGB

    coal

    capacity

    600

    E FGD

    90%

    removal

    600

    E

    FGD

    marginal

    cost

    of

    next

    5%

    removal

    1,600

    F

    US

    coal

    generators,

    oal

    switching,

    v

    cost 400

    F

    US

    coal

    generators,

    no

    coal

    switching,

    v cost 460

    G East

    Germany,

    Wellman-Lord

    FGD,

    net of S sales 300

    H move from

    2.15%

    to

    1%

    sulphur heavy

    fuel oil 380

    H

    move

    from

    1%

    to

    0.7%

    sulphur heavy

    fuel oil

    825

    Sources:A, Environmental esourcesLimited 1983, p. 137,uprated by1.28to$1989).

    B,

    Based

    on

    Layfield

    1987)

    and

    Jeffrey

    1988).

    C,

    Longhurst

    et

    al.

    (1987).

    D,

    Dudley

    et al.

    (1985,

    p.

    121).

    E,

    Brackley

    1987).

    F,

    Congressional Budget

    Office

    1986)

    in

    Dowlatabadi and

    Harrington

    1989).

    These are

    average

    costs.

    Marginal

    cost

    might

    be

    twice

    verage

    cost.

    G,

    Acid

    News,

    No.

    3,

    July

    1989,

    p.

    9.

    H,

    Alfsen

    et

    al.

    (1986).

    cars,

    was estimated o

    add an additional

    ?250

    mn.

    per

    annum,

    a total

    of

    about

    4%

    of

    UK

    motoring

    osts.

    Department

    of

    Environment,

    988,

    7.14-15.)

    This

    sectionexamines various estimates f the

    costs of abate-

    ment n

    somewhatmore detail to see

    if

    mandatingparticular

    olutions

    is

    likely

    to be cost effective,nd to check on the

    consistency

    nd

    plausibility

    f various

    estimates.

    The

    results re summarized n Table

    5 and

    then

    briefly

    xplained.

    The

    sources

    of

    these

    estimates re

    as

    follows. nvironmental

    esour-

    ces

    Limited

    1983)

    gives

    estimates f the

    capital

    cost

    of FGD at

    $175-

    200/kW

    r

    about

    15-20%

    of the

    capital

    cost of

    the

    plant. Retrofitting,

    where

    practical,

    may

    increase

    this

    cost

    by

    a

    further

    30-50%.

    FGD

    reduces thermal

    fficiencyy

    about

    2%

    (e.g.

    from

    36%

    to

    34.1%)

    and

    so can increase the

    operating

    costs

    by 10-20%.

    the

    first

    tation

    which

    the CEGB

    plans

    to

    retrofits Drax A+

    B,

    which has a total

    capacity

    f

    4,000

    MW,

    and

    which burns

    11 mn.

    tonnes of

    coal

    per

    annum with

    sulphur

    content of

    1.7%.

    If

    95%

    of this

    were

    previously

    eleased

    as

    SO2,

    theannual

    emissions

    would

    be

    178,000

    tonnes

    S,

    or

    338,000

    tonnes

    SO2.

    After

    fitting

    GD,

    90%

    of

    the

    SO2

    will be

    removed,

    and the

    314

    David

    Newbery

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    20/51

    reduction n

    SO2

    would be

    287,000

    tonnes.

    The

    Layfieldreport

    gives

    the

    costs

    of FGD

    as

    ?17/kW/year,

    roken down into

    ?5

    capital,

    ?2.5

    operating

    and

    ?9.5

    for

    loss

    of

    thermal

    efficiency.

    his last

    figure

    depends

    on the cost of coal which has since fallenand

    Jeffrey

    1988)

    estimates he

    efficiency

    ost as

    ?6.5.

    Using

    these

    figures

    he annualized

    cost of

    the Drax

    programme

    would be ?56

    mn.,

    or about

    ?200/tonne

    SO2

    reduction.

    Longhurst

    et

    al.

    (1987)

    gives

    the CEGB's

    estimates f

    the

    cost

    of

    retrofitting

    GD for a

    2,000

    MW

    plant

    as

    ?160

    mn.

    plus

    ?35

    mn. in

    lost

    output,

    or

    ?440-740/tonne

    of

    sulphur

    removed from

    the

    gas

    stream

    i.e.

    ?230-390/tonne

    SO2

    removed).

    Dudley

    et

    l.

    (1985,

    p.

    121)

    try

    o cost a

    programme

    o

    achieve a

    60%

    reduction n

    SO2

    in

    UK emissionsfrom ts 40 GW coal-fired apacityusingCEGB data and

    data

    presented

    at the

    Layfield

    enquiry.

    The

    levelized lifetime ost

    of

    sulphur

    bated

    ranges

    from

    442/tonne

    to

    ?738

    with n

    average

    value

    of

    ?550,

    all

    in

    ?1983.

    (The

    average figure

    s thus

    ?745

    in

    ?1989,

    or

    $1,200/tonne

    . The costs

    per

    tonne

    SO2

    removed would

    be abouthalf

    this.)

    Brackley

    1987)

    estimates

    he cost

    of

    SO2

    removal

    using

    FGD

    as

    $1,150/tonne

    removed

    with

    90%

    removal,

    rising

    to

    $3,000/tonne

    forthe next

    5%

    removed

    n

    going

    from

    90-95%

    removal,

    n

    both cases

    using

    coal with

    1

    %

    sulphur

    content. his

    figure

    s

    very

    lose to

    Dudley's

    estimate.

    The

    effect

    n

    the costof

    electricityeneration

    would

    be

    about

    10-15%

    of the cost

    of

    generation

    from oal-fired

    ower

    stations,

    r

    possibly

    %

    of the

    price paid by

    customers.9

    his can

    usefully

    be

    compared

    with

    the

    predicted

    size

    of

    the

    nuclear

    evy'

    of

    11%

    of the

    sales

    price,

    which

    will

    be

    paid by

    consumersof

    fossil-fuel

    enerated electricity

    fter

    he

    privatization

    f

    the CEGB to cover the

    cost of

    supplying

    20%

    of

    total

    electricity

    y

    non-conventional

    mainly

    nuclear)

    means.'0

    Dowlatabadi and

    Harrington

    1989),

    in a rather

    critical ccount of

    US estimates f the costsof argeprogrammes o reduce total missions

    by

    8

    mn. tonnes

    per

    annum from

    he

    current evels of

    25

    mn.

    tonnes,

    cites

    various

    estimates

    of the

    average

    cost

    per

    tonne

    SO2

    reduction.

    Thus the

    Congressional

    Budget

    Office

    1986)

    gives

    he

    eastcostmethod

    of

    making

    his

    reduction

    by

    allowing

    he

    utilities

    o

    choose how best to

    meet

    the

    standards)

    as

    $360/tonne,

    nd

    $400/tonne

    f

    they

    must con-

    tinue o use

    thesame

    coal as

    originally

    nstead

    of

    substituting

    o

    ower

    ul-

    phur

    contentcoal.

    These are

    average

    costs,

    nd

    there s

    considerable

    I I

    9

    Based

    on

    estimated

    capital

    costs of

    100-200/kWe

    capacity,

    5-7%

    discount

    rate,

    30-40

    year

    lifetime,

    0%

    load

    factor,

    nd

    1.7%

    sulphur

    coal content.The

    calculated

    figure

    s

    reassuringly

    close to

    that

    given

    n

    1984

    by

    the

    CEGB in HMSO

    (1984,

    para

    5.93).

    10

    This

    suggests

    he

    cost

    of

    non-conventional

    lternative s

    55%

    of

    the

    final

    price

    11%

    borne

    by

    80%

    of

    the total allocated to the

    20%

    non-conventional)

    which

    seems

    unreasonably

    high.

    But

    detailed estimates f the cost of nuclear

    power

    are not

    yet

    available.

    Acidrain

    315

    This content downloaded from 193.54.67.93 on Mon, 8 Sep 2014 12:37:20 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 5/20/2018 Acid Rain, by David Newbery

    21/51

    agreement

    that the

    marginal

    costsof

    high

    levelsof

    sulphur

    removal

    are

    substantially

    igher

    han

    smallreductions.

    f

    the

    marginal

    ost

    were

    twice the

    average

    cost at

    this

    programme

    evel then the US

    figures

    would be

    close to the CEGB

    figures.

    stimates

    based on

    German data

    applied

    to East

    Germany

    uggest

    hat

    the

    capital

    cost

    per

    kW

    capacity

    is DM

    600

    using

    the Wellman-Lord

    method."

    At

    present

    the

    capacity

    of

    the

    15

    larger

    plants

    is

    13.3 GW which s

    responsible

    for

    1.98 mn.

    tonnes f

    SO2

    p.a.

    The

    capital

    ostwould be DM 8

    bn.,

    and the

    estimated

    annual cost of

    operating

    ess

    the value of the

    sulphur

    sold on world

    markets would

    be

    DM

    1.6bn.,

    or DM

    600/tonne

    SO2

    removed,

    or

    $300/tonne

    O2,

    which

    appears

    rather ow.

    An alternative ptionforreducingSO2 emissions stoswitch olower

    sulphur

    content

    fuels. Thus

    Alfsen

    et al.

    (1986)

    calculate the cost of

    switching

    rom

    high

    to

    low

    sulphurheavy

    fuel oil as

    2,300

    NOK/tonne

    SO2

    removed

    (i.e. $380)

    when

    moving

    from

    2.15%

    to

    1%

    HFO,

    and

    5,000

    NOK/tonne

    removed

    (=$823)

    when

    moving

    from

    1%

    to

    0.7%

    HFO.

    Table

    5

    shows

    similar alculations

    f

    switching

    rom

    high

    to low

    sulphur

    fuels

    for

    the EEC

    given

    n EnvironmentalResources Limited

    (1983,

    p.

    137).

    What

    stands out

    from Table 5 is

    the wide variation n

    the costs

    of

    the most common proposed method of dealing with large power

    stations-flue

    gas desulphurization,

    r FGD. In

    part

    this

    variation

    may

    be

    explained by

    differing

    egrees

    of

    sulphur

    removal estimate shows

    that

    he

    marginal

    ost s

    sharply

    ncreasing.

    The East

    German estimates

    may

    be based on lower construction

    osts or a more

    optimistic

    iew of

    the

    value

    of

    recovered

    sulphur.

    The

    figures

    for

    FGD

    from

    source

    A

    seem

    rather ow when

    compared

    to other stimates.

    Unfortunately

    here

    are no

    European

    estimates or the

    important

    ption

    of

    shifting

    o low

    sulphur

    oal.

    In

    part

    his s

    because,

    unlike

    oil,

    there s no

    clearly

    efined

    worldmarket

    price

    for he two

    grades

    of coal thatwould allow a robust

    estimate o

    be made

    of the differentialost

    of

    shifting

    rom

    high

    to low

    sulphur

    coal.

    The

    study

    by

    Environmental

    Resources Limited

    (1983)

    concludes

    that the

    estimated

    total

    damage

    caused

    by

    acid rain

    might

    be in

    the

    range

    $0.6-4.5

    bn.

    per

    annum,

    of

    which the

    larger part

    is

    damage

    to

    buildings,

    hen to

    forests,

    hen to

    crops,

    withfisheries

    egligible.

    The

    costs f


Recommended