+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Advanced Microeconomic Theoryย ยท Production Sets โ€ข Let us define a production vector (or plan)...

Advanced Microeconomic Theoryย ยท Production Sets โ€ข Let us define a production vector (or plan)...

Date post: 04-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: dotuyen
View: 219 times
Download: 3 times
Share this document with a friend
192
Advanced Microeconomic Theory Chapter 4: Production Theory
Transcript

Advanced Microeconomic Theory

Chapter 4: Production Theory

Outline

โ€ข Production sets and production functionsโ€ข Profit maximization and cost minimizationโ€ข Cost functionsโ€ข Aggregate supplyโ€ข Efficiency (1st and 2nd FTWE)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Production Sets and Production Functions

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 3

Production Sets

โ€ข Let us define a production vector (or plan)๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = (๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐ฟ๐ฟ) โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ

โ€“ If, for instance, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 > 0, then the firm is producing positive units of good 2 (i.e., good 2 is an output).

โ€“ If, instead, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 < 0, then the firms is producing negative units of good 2 (i.e., good 2 is an input).

โ€ข Production plans that are technologically feasible are represented in the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

๐‘Œ๐‘Œ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ: ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) โ‰ค 0where ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) is the transformation function.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 4

Production Setsโ€ข ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) can also be

understood as a production function.

โ€ข Firm uses units of ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 as an input in order to produce units of ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 as an output.

โ€ข Boundary of the production function is any production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆsuch that ๐น๐น ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = 0.โ€“ Also referred to as the

transformation frontier.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 5

Production Sets

โ€ข For any production plan ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ on the production frontier, such that ๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = 0 , we can totally differentiate ๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ as follows

๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜ +๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ = 0

solving

๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

= โˆ’๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™

, where ๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™

= ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ measures how much the (net) output ๐‘˜๐‘˜can increase if the firm decreases the (net) output of good ๐‘™๐‘™ by one marginal unit.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 6

Production Sets

โ€ข What if we denote input and outputs with different letters?

๐‘ž๐‘ž = (๐‘ž๐‘ž1, ๐‘ž๐‘ž2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ž๐‘ž๐‘€๐‘€) โ‰ฅ 0 outputs๐‘ง๐‘ง = (๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐ฟ๐ฟโˆ’๐‘€๐‘€) โ‰ฅ 0 inputs

where ๐ฟ๐ฟ โ‰ฅ ๐‘€๐‘€.

โ€ข In this case, inputs are transformed into outputs by the production function, ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐ฟ๐ฟโˆ’๐‘€๐‘€), i.e., ๐‘“๐‘“: โ„๐ฟ๐ฟโˆ’๐‘€๐‘€ โ†’ โ„๐‘€๐‘€.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 7

Production Sets

โ€ข Example: When ๐‘€๐‘€ = 1 (one single output), the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ can be described as

๐‘Œ๐‘Œ = (โˆ’๐‘ง๐‘ง1, โˆ’๐‘ง๐‘ง2, โ€ฆ , โˆ’๐‘ง๐‘ง๐ฟ๐ฟโˆ’1, ๐‘ž๐‘ž):๐‘ž๐‘ž โ‰ค ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐ฟ๐ฟโˆ’1)

โ€ข Holding the output level fixed, ๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0, totally differentiate production function

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜ +๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™ = 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 8

Production Sets

โ€ข Example (continued): and rearranging

๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

= โˆ’๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™

, where ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™

= ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง

โ€ข ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง measures the additional amount of input ๐‘˜๐‘˜ that must be used when we marginally decrease the amount of input ๐‘™๐‘™, and we want to keep output level at ๏ฟฝ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง .

โ€ข ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง in production theory is analogous to the ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ in consumer theory, where we keep utility constant, ๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘ข๐‘ข = 0.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 9

Production Setsโ€ข Combinations of (๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2)

that produce the same total output ๐‘ž๐‘ž0, i.e., (๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 : ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2) = ๐‘ž๐‘ž0}

is called isoquant.

โ€ข The slope of the isoquant at ( ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2) is ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง .

โ€ข Remember: โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€refers to isoquants

(and production function).

โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ refers to the transformation function.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 10

z2

z1

Isoquant,

Production Sets

โ€ข Example: Find the๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง for the Cobb-Douglas production function ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = ๐‘ง๐‘ง1

๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2๐›ฝ๐›ฝ,

where ๐›ผ๐›ผ, ๐›ฝ๐›ฝ > 0.

โ€ข The marginal product of input 1 is ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง1= ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง1

๐›ผ๐›ผโˆ’1๐‘ง๐‘ง2๐›ฝ๐›ฝ

and that of input 2 is ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง1= ๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง1

๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2๐›ฝ๐›ฝโˆ’1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 11

Production Sets

โ€ข Example (continued): Hence, the๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง is

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง =๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง1

๐›ผ๐›ผโˆ’1๐‘ง๐‘ง2๐›ฝ๐›ฝ

๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง1๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐›ฝ๐›ฝโˆ’1 =๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐›ฝ๐›ฝโˆ’(๐›ฝ๐›ฝโˆ’1)

๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง1๐›ผ๐›ผโˆ’(๐›ผ๐›ผโˆ’1) =

๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง1

โ€ข For instance, for a particular vector ๐‘ง๐‘ง =๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = (2,3), and ๐›ผ๐›ผ = ๐›ฝ๐›ฝ = 1

2, then

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘ง๐‘ง =32

= 1.5

i.e., the slope of the isoquant evaluated at input vector ๐‘ง๐‘ง = ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = (2,3) is โˆ’1.5.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 12

Properties of Production Sets

1) Y is nonempty: We have inputs and/or outputs.

2) Y is closed: The production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œincludes its boundary points.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 13

y2

y1

Y

2 y

Properties of Production Sets

The firm uses amounts of input ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1in order to produce positive amounts of output ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 14

3) No free lunch: No production with no resources.

y2

y1

Y

2y Y R+โˆˆ โˆฉ

Properties of Production Sets

The firm produces positive amounts of good 1 and 2 (๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 > 0and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 > 0) without the use of any inputs.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 15

3) No free lunch: violation

y2

y1

Y

2y Y R+โˆˆ โˆฉ

Properties of Production Sets

The firm produces positive amounts of good 2 (๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 > 0) with zero inputs, i.e., ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 =0 .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 16

3) No free lunch: violation

Properties of Production Sets

Firm can choose to be inactive, using no inputs, and obtaining no output as a result (i.e., 0 โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 17

4) Possibility of inaction

Properties of Production Sets

Inaction is still possible when firms face fixed costs (i.e., 0 โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 18y2

y2

y1

Y 0 YโˆˆSet up non-sunk cost

4) Possibility of inaction

Properties of Production Sets

Inaction is NOT possible when firms face sunk costs (i.e., 0 โˆ‰ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 19

y2

y1

Y0 Yโˆ‰

Sunk cost

4) Possibility of inaction

Properties of Production Sets

5) Free disposal: if ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ค ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, then ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ. ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ is less efficient than ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ:

โ€“ Either it produces the same amount of output with more inputs, or less output using the same inputs.

Then, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ also belongs to the firmโ€™s production set. That is, the producer can use more inputs

without the need the reduce his output:โ€“ The producer can dispose of (or eliminate) this

additional inputs at no cost.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 20

Properties of Production Sets

5) Free disposal (continued)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 21

Properties of Production Sets

6) Irreversibility Suppose that ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ

and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰  0. Then, โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆ‰ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ. โ€œNo way backโ€

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 22

y2

Y

y

-y โˆ‰ Yy1

y1

-y1

y2

-y2

Properties of Production Sets

7) Non-increasing returns to scale: If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, then ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ for any ๐›ผ๐›ผ โˆˆ 0,1 . That is, any feasible vector can be scaled down.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 23

Properties of Production Sets

7) Non-increasing returns to scale The presence of fixed or sunk costs violates

non-increasing returns to scale.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 24

Properties of Production Sets

8) Non-decreasing returns to scale: If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, then ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ for any ๐›ผ๐›ผ โ‰ฅ 1. That is, any feasible vector can be scaled up.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 25

Properties of Production Sets

8) Non-decreasing returns to scale The presence of fixed or sunk costs do NOT

violate non-increasing returns to scale.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 26

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Returns to scale:โ€“ When scaling up/down

a given production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = โˆ’๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 : We connect ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ with a ray

from the origin.

Then, the ratio ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1

must be maintained in all points along the ray. Note that the angle of

the ray is exactly this ratio ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 27

y2

y1

Y

y

, 1y ifฮฑ ฮฑ <

, 1y ifฮฑ ฮฑ >

Properties of Production Sets

CRS is non-increasing and non-decreasing.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 28

9) Constant returns to scale (CRS): If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, then ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ for any ๐›ผ๐›ผ โ‰ฅ 0.

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Alternative graphical representation of constant returns to scale:โ€“ Doubling ๐พ๐พ and ๐ฟ๐ฟ

doubles output (i.e., proportionally increase in output).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 29

L

K

1

1

2

2

Q=200

Q=100

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Alternative graphical representation of increasing-returns to scale:โ€“ Doubling ๐พ๐พ and ๐ฟ๐ฟ

increases output more than proportionally.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 30

L

K

1

1

2

2

Q=300

Q=100Q=200

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Alternative graphical representation of decreasing-returns to scale:โ€“ Doubling ๐พ๐พ and ๐ฟ๐ฟ

increases output less than proportionally.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 31

L

K

1

1

2

2

Q=200

Q=100Q=150

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Example: Let us check returns to scale in the Cobb-Douglas production function ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = ๐‘ง๐‘ง1

๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2๐›ฝ๐›ฝ.

Increasing all arguments by a common factor ๐œ†๐œ†, we obtain

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = (๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ง๐‘ง1)๐›ผ๐›ผ(๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ง๐‘ง2)๐›ฝ๐›ฝ= ๐œ†๐œ†๐›ผ๐›ผ+๐›ฝ๐›ฝ๐‘ง๐‘ง1๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐›ฝ๐›ฝ

โ€“ When ๐›ผ๐›ผ + ๐›ฝ๐›ฝ = 1, we have constant returns to scale;โ€“ When ๐›ผ๐›ผ + ๐›ฝ๐›ฝ > 1, we have increasing returns to scale;โ€“ When ๐›ผ๐›ผ + ๐›ฝ๐›ฝ < 1, we have decreasing returns to scale.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 32

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Returns to scale in different US industries (Source: Hsieh, 1995):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 33

Industry ๐›ผ๐›ผ + ๐›ฝ๐›ฝDecreasing returns Tobacco 0.51

Food 0.91

Constant returns Apparel and textile 1.01Furniture 1.02Electronics 1.02

Increasing returns Paper products 1.09Petroleum and coal 1.18Primary metal 1.24

Properties of Production Sets

Homogeneity of the Production Function Returns to Scale

๐พ๐พ = 1 Constant Returns๐พ๐พ > 1 Increasing Returns๐พ๐พ < 1 Decreasing Returns

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 34

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข The linear production function exhibits CRS as increasing all inputs by a common factor ๐‘ก๐‘กyields

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™โ‰ก ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)

โ€ข The fixed proportion production function ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = min{๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™} also exhibits CRS as

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = min ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘๐‘๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๏ฟฝ min ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™โ‰ก ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 35

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Increasing/decreasing returns to scale can be incorporated into a production function ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)exhibiting CRS by using a transformation function ๐น๐น(๏ฟฝ)

๐น๐น ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™) ๐›พ๐›พ, where ๐›พ๐›พ > 0

โ€ข Indeed, increasing all arguments by a common factor ๐‘ก๐‘ก, yields

๐น๐น ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™) ๐›พ๐›พ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๏ฟฝ ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)by CRS of ๐‘“๐‘“(๏ฟฝ) ๐›พ๐›พ

= ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐›พ๐›พ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ ๐›พ๐›พ

๐น๐น ๐‘˜๐‘˜,๐‘™๐‘™= ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐›พ๐›พ ๏ฟฝ ๐น๐น ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 36

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Hence, โ€“ if ๐›พ๐›พ > 1, the transformed production function

๐น๐น ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ exhibits increasing returns to scale;โ€“ if ๐›พ๐›พ < 1, the transformed production function

๐น๐น ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ exhibits decreasing returns to scale;

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 37

Properties of Production Sets

โ€ข Scale elasticity: an alternative measure of returns to scale.โ€“ It measures the percent increase in output due to

a 1% increase in the amounts of all inputs

๐œ€๐œ€๐‘ž๐‘ž,๐‘ก๐‘ก =๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ก๐‘ก๏ฟฝ

๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)

where ๐‘ก๐‘ก denotes the common increase in all inputs.โ€“ Practice: Show that, if a function exhibits CRS,

then it has a scale elasticity of ๐œ€๐œ€๐‘ž๐‘ž,๐‘ก๐‘ก=1.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 38

Properties of Production Sets

10) Additivity (or free entry): If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, then ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ + ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ. Interpretation: one plant produces ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, while

another plant enters the market producing ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ. Then, the aggregate production ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ +๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ is feasible.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 39

y2

y1

y(1 ) 'y y Yฮฑ ฮฑ+ โˆ’ โˆˆ

(1 ) 'y yฮฑ ฮฑ+ โˆ’

y'

y'

Properties of Production Sets

11) Convexity: If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ and ๐›ผ๐›ผ โˆˆ 0,1 , then ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ + (1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ)๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 40

Intuition: โ€œbalancedโ€ input-output combinations are more productive than โ€œunbalancedโ€ ones.

y2

y1

Y

y

yฮฑy'

(1 ) 'y y Yฮฑ ฮฑ+ โˆ’ โˆ‰

Properties of Production Sets

11) Convexity: violation

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 41

Note: The convexity of the production set maintains a close relationship with the concavity of the production function.

Properties of Production Sets

11) Convexity With fixed costs, convexity is NOT necessarily satisfied; With sunk costs, convexity is satisfied.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 42

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข The slope of the firmโ€™s isoquants is

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜ = โˆ’ ๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘™๐‘™

, where ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ€ข Differentiating ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜ with respect to labor yields

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™=

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™ + ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ + ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

2

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 43

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข Using the fact that ๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘™๐‘™

= โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

along an

isoquant and Youngโ€™s theorem ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™,

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™=

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜2

=๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ + ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™

2

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

2

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 44

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข Multiplying numerator and denominator by ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™=

๏ฟฝ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜2

+โž๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™

โˆ’

+ ๏ฟฝ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜

โˆ’๏ฟฝ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™

2+

โˆ’ 2๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜

+๏ฟฝ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜

โˆ’ or+

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜3

โ€ข Thus,

โ€“ If ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ > 0 (i.e., โ†‘ ๐‘˜๐‘˜ โŸน โ†‘ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™), then ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™

< 0

โ€“ If ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ < 0, then we have

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜2๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™ + ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™

2 >< 2๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ โŸน

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™<> 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 45

Diminishing MRTS

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 46

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ > 0 (โ†‘ ๐‘˜๐‘˜ โŸน โ†‘ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™), or ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ < 0 (โ†‘ ๐‘˜๐‘˜ โŸน โ†“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™) but small โ†“ in ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ < 0 (โ†‘ ๐‘˜๐‘˜ โŸน โ†“โ†“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™)

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข Example: Let us check if the production function ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = 600๐‘˜๐‘˜2๐‘™๐‘™2 โˆ’ ๐‘˜๐‘˜3๐‘™๐‘™3 yields convex isoquants. โ€“ Marginal products:

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ = 1,200๐‘˜๐‘˜2๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ 3๐‘˜๐‘˜3๐‘™๐‘™2 > 0 iff ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ < 400๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜ = 1,200๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™2 โˆ’ 3๐‘˜๐‘˜2๐‘™๐‘™3 > 0 iff ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ < 400

โ€“ Decreasing marginal productivity:๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™= ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™๐‘™ = 1,200๐‘˜๐‘˜2 โˆ’ 6๐‘˜๐‘˜3๐‘™๐‘™ < 0 iff ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ > 200

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜

= ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜ = 1,200๐‘™๐‘™2 โˆ’ 6๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™3 < 0 iff ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ > 200Advanced Microeconomic Theory 47

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข Example (continued):โ€“ Is 200 < ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ < 400 then sufficient condition for

diminishing ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€? No! We need ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ > 0 too in order to guarantee diminishing

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜.

โ€“ Check the sign of ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜:๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ = 2,400๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ โˆ’ 9๐‘˜๐‘˜2๐‘™๐‘™2 > 0 iff ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™ < 266

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 48

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข Example (continued):โ€“ Alternatively, we can represent the above

conditions by solving for ๐‘™๐‘™ in the above inequalities:

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™ > 0 iff ๐‘™๐‘™ < 400๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™

< 0 iff ๐‘™๐‘™ > 200๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘˜๐‘˜ > 0 iff ๐‘™๐‘™ < 400๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜

< 0 iff ๐‘™๐‘™ > 200๐‘˜๐‘˜

and

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜ > 0 iff ๐‘™๐‘™ < 266๐‘˜๐‘˜

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 49

Diminishing MRTS

โ€ข Example (continued):

โ€“ Hence, 200๐‘˜๐‘˜

< ๐‘™๐‘™ < 266๐‘˜๐‘˜

guarantees positive but diminishing marginal products and, in addition, a diminishing ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€.

โ€“ Figure: ๐‘™๐‘™ = 200๐‘˜๐‘˜

is a curve decreasing in ๐‘˜๐‘˜, never

crossing either axes. Similarly for ๐‘™๐‘™ = 266๐‘˜๐‘˜

.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 50

Constant Returns to Scale

โ€ข If production function ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™) exhibits CRS, then increasing all inputs by a common factor ๐‘ก๐‘ก yields

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™

โ€ข Hence, ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™) is homogenous of degree 1, thus implying that its first-order derivatives

๐‘“๐‘“๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ and ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™are homogenous of degree zero.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 51

Constant Returns to Scale

โ€ข Therefore,

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™ =๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™=

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™

= ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™โ€ข Setting ๐‘ก๐‘ก = 1

๐‘™๐‘™, we obtain

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™1๐‘™๐‘™

๐‘˜๐‘˜,๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘˜

= ๐‘“๐‘“๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

, 1

โ€ข Hence, ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™ only depends on the ratio ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™, but not

on the absolute levels of ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™ that firm uses.โ€ข A similar argument applies to ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘˜๐‘˜.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 52

Constant Returns to Scale

โ€ข Thus, ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ = ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘˜๐‘˜only depends on the

ratio of capital to labor.

โ€ข The slope of a firmโ€™s isoquants coincides at any point along a ray from the origin.

โ€ข Firmโ€™s production function is, hence, homothetic.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 53

L

K

q=4q=3

q=2

Same MRTSl,k

Ray from the origin

Elasticity of Substitution

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 54

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข Elasticity of substitution (๐œŽ๐œŽ) measures the proportionate change in the ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™ ratio relative to the proportionate change in the ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘™๐‘™,๐‘˜๐‘˜along an isoquant:

๐œŽ๐œŽ =%โˆ†(๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™)%โˆ†๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

=๐‘‘๐‘‘(๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™)๐‘‘๐‘‘๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

๏ฟฝ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™=

๐œ•๐œ•ln(๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™)๐œ•๐œ•ln(๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€)

where ๐œŽ๐œŽ > 0 since ratio ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™ and ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ move in the same direction.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 55

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข Both๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ and ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™will change as we move from point ๐ด๐ด to point ๐ต๐ต.

โ€ข ๐œŽ๐œŽ is the ratio of these changes.

โ€ข ๐œŽ๐œŽ measures the curvature of the isoquant.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 56

L

K

(k/l)B

(k/l)A

A

B

MRTSA

MRTSB

0q q=

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข If we define the elasticity of substitution between two inputs to be proportionate change in the ratio of the two inputs to the proportionate change in ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€, we need to hold:โ€“ output constant (so we move along the same

isoquant), and โ€“ the levels of other inputs constant (in case we

have more than two inputs). For instance, we fix the amount of other inputs, such as land.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 57

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข High elasticity of substitution (๐œŽ๐œŽ): โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ does not

change substantially relative to ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™.

โ€“ Isoquant is relatively flat.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 58

L

K

(k/l)B

(k/l)A

A

B

MRTSA

MRTSB

0q q=

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข Low elasticity of substitution (๐œŽ๐œŽ): โ€“ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ changes

substantially relative to ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™.

โ€“ Isoquant is relatively sharply curved.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 59

L

K

(k/l)B

(k/l)A

A

B

MRTSA

MRTSB

0q q=

Elasticity of Substitution: Linear Production Function

โ€ข Suppose that the production function is๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™

โ€ข This production function exhibits constant returns to scale

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™= ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)

โ€ข Solving for ๐‘˜๐‘˜ in ๐‘ž๐‘ž, we get ๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜,๐‘™๐‘™๐‘Ž๐‘Ž

โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘Ž

๐‘™๐‘™. โ€“ All isoquants are straight linesโ€“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™ are perfect substitutes

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 60

Elasticity of Substitution: Linear Production Function

โ€ข ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ (slope of the isoquant) is constant as ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™ changes.

๐œŽ๐œŽ =%โˆ†(๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™)%โˆ†๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

0

= โˆž

โ€ข This production function satisfies homotheticity.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 61

q3q2q1

Slope=-b/a

K

L

Elasticity of Substitution:Fixed Proportions Production Functionโ€ข Suppose that the production function is

๐‘ž๐‘ž = min ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž, ๐‘๐‘ > 0โ€ข Capital and labor must always be used in a fixed

ratioโ€“ No substitution between ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™โ€“ The firm will always operate along a ray where ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™ is

constant (i.e., at the kink!).

โ€ข Because ๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™ is constant (๐‘๐‘/๐‘Ž๐‘Ž),

๐œŽ๐œŽ =%โˆ†(๐‘˜๐‘˜/๐‘™๐‘™)%โˆ†๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

โˆž

= 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 62

Elasticity of Substitution:Fixed Proportions Production Functionโ€ข ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ = โˆž for ๐‘™๐‘™

before the kink of the isoquant.

โ€ข ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ = 0 for ๐‘™๐‘™ after the kink.

โ€ข This production function also satisfies homotheticity.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 63

q3

q2

q1

q3/b

q3/a

K

L

Elasticity of Substitution:Cobb-Douglas Production Function

โ€ข Suppose that the production function is๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐ด๐ด๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘ where ๐ด๐ด, ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž, ๐‘๐‘ > 0

โ€ข This production function can exhibit any returns to scale

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐ด๐ด(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘˜๐‘˜)๐‘Ž๐‘Ž(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘™๐‘™)๐‘๐‘= ๐ด๐ด๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘Ž๐‘Ž+๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘

= ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘Ž๐‘Ž+๐‘๐‘๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™)โ€“ If ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž + ๐‘๐‘ = 1 โŸน constant returns to scaleโ€“ If ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž + ๐‘๐‘ > 1 โŸน increasing returns to scaleโ€“ If ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž + ๐‘๐‘ < 1 โŸน decreasing returns to scale

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 64

Elasticity of Substitution:Cobb-Douglas Production Function

โ€ข The Cobb-Douglass production function is linear in logarithms

ln ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ln ๐ด๐ด + ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž ln ๐‘˜๐‘˜ + ๐‘๐‘ ln ๐‘™๐‘™

โ€“ ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž is the elasticity of output with respect to ๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œ€๐œ€๐‘ž๐‘ž,๐‘˜๐‘˜ =๐œ•๐œ•ln(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•ln(๐‘˜๐‘˜)

โ€“ ๐‘๐‘ is the elasticity of output with respect to ๐‘™๐‘™

๐œ€๐œ€๐‘ž๐‘ž,๐‘™๐‘™ =๐œ•๐œ•ln(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•ln(๐‘™๐‘™)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 65

Elasticity of Substitution:Cobb-Douglas Production Function

โ€ข The elasticity of substitution (๐œŽ๐œŽ) for the Cobb-Douglas production function:โ€“ First,

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ =๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘˜๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜

=๐‘๐‘๐ด๐ด๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘โˆ’1

๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐ด๐ด๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘Ž๐‘Žโˆ’1๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘ =๐‘๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘Ž

๏ฟฝ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

โ€“ Hence,

ln(๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€) = ln๐‘๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘Ž

+ ln๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 66

Elasticity of Substitution:Cobb-Douglas Production Function

โ€“ Solving for ln ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

,

ln๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

= ln ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ โˆ’ ln๐‘๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘Ž

โ€“ Therefore, the elasticity of substitution between ๐‘˜๐‘˜and ๐‘™๐‘™ is

๐œŽ๐œŽ =๐‘‘๐‘‘ ln ๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘™๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘‘ ln ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

= 1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 67

Elasticity of Substitution:CES Production Function

โ€ข Suppose that the production function is๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œŒ๐œŒ + ๐‘™๐‘™๐œŒ๐œŒ ๐›พ๐›พ/๐œŒ๐œŒ

where ๐œŒ๐œŒ โ‰ค 1, ๐œŒ๐œŒ โ‰  0, ๐›พ๐›พ > 0โ€“ ๐›พ๐›พ = 1 โŸน constant returns to scaleโ€“ ๐›พ๐›พ > 1 โŸน increasing returns to scaleโ€“ ๐›พ๐›พ < 1 โŸน decreasing returns to scale

โ€ข Alternative representation of the CES function

๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘™๐‘™ = ๐‘Ž๐‘Ž๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œŽ๐œŽโˆ’1

๐œŽ๐œŽ + ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™๐œŽ๐œŽโˆ’1

๐œŽ๐œŽ

๐œŽ๐œŽโˆ’1๐œŽ๐œŽ

where ๐œŽ๐œŽ is the elasticity of substitution.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 68

Elasticity of Substitution:CES Production Function

โ€ข The elasticity of substitution (๐œŽ๐œŽ) for the CES production function:โ€“ First,

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ =๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘™๐‘™

๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘˜๐‘˜=

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜

=

๐›พ๐›พ๐œŒ๐œŒ ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œŒ๐œŒ + ๐‘™๐‘™๐œŒ๐œŒ

๐›พ๐›พ๐œŒ๐œŒโˆ’1 ๐œŒ๐œŒ๐‘™๐‘™๐œŒ๐œŒโˆ’1

๐›พ๐›พ๐œŒ๐œŒ ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œŒ๐œŒ + ๐‘™๐‘™๐œŒ๐œŒ

๐›พ๐›พ๐œŒ๐œŒโˆ’1 ๐œŒ๐œŒ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œŒ๐œŒโˆ’1

=๐‘™๐‘™๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐œŒ๐œŒโˆ’1

=๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

1โˆ’๐œŒ๐œŒ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 69

Elasticity of Substitution:CES Production Function

โ€“ Hence,

ln(๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€) = ๐œŒ๐œŒ โˆ’ 1 ln๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

โ€“ Solving for ln ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

,

ln๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘™๐‘™

=1

๐œŒ๐œŒ โˆ’ 1ln ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

โ€“ Therefore, the elasticity of substitution between ๐‘˜๐‘˜and ๐‘™๐‘™ is

๐œŽ๐œŽ =๐‘‘๐‘‘ ln ๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘™๐‘™๐‘‘๐‘‘ ln ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€

=1

๐œŒ๐œŒ โˆ’ 1Advanced Microeconomic Theory 70

Elasticity of Substitution:CES Production Function

โ€ข Elasticity of Substitution in German Industries (Source: Kemfert, 1998):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 71

Industry ๐œŽ๐œŽFood 0.66Iron 0.50Chemicals 0.37Motor Vehicles 0.10

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข The elasticity of substitution ๐œŽ๐œŽbetween ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™ is decreasing in scale (i.e., as ๐‘ž๐‘ž increases).โ€“ ๐‘ž๐‘ž0 and ๐‘ž๐‘ž1 have very

high ๐œŽ๐œŽโ€“ ๐‘ž๐‘ž5 and ๐‘ž๐‘ž6 have very

low ๐œŽ๐œŽ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 72

L

K

q3

q2q1q0

q4

q5

q6

Elasticity of Substitution

โ€ข The elasticity of substitution ๐œŽ๐œŽbetween ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™ is increasing in scale (i.e., as ๐‘ž๐‘ž increases).โ€“ ๐‘ž๐‘ž0 and ๐‘ž๐‘ž1 have very

low ๐œŽ๐œŽโ€“ ๐‘ž๐‘ž2 and ๐‘ž๐‘ž3 have very

high ๐œŽ๐œŽ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 73

Profit Maximization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 74

Profit Maximization

โ€ข Assumptions:โ€“ Firms are price takers: the production plans of an

individual firm do not alter price levels ๐‘๐‘ =๐‘๐‘1, ๐‘๐‘2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘๐‘๐ฟ๐ฟ โ‰ซ 0.

โ€“ The production set satisfies: non-emptiness, closedness, and free-disposal.

โ€ข Profit maximization problem (PMP):max

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

s.t. ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, or alternatively, ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ) โ‰ค 0Advanced Microeconomic Theory 75

Profit Maximization

โ€ข Profit function ๐œ‹๐œ‹(๐‘๐‘) associates to every ๐‘๐‘ the highest amount of profits (i.e., ๐œ‹๐œ‹(๐‘๐‘) is the value function of the PMP)

๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = max๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ: ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œโ€ข And the supply correspondence ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) is the

argmax of the PMP, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ: ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘

where positive components in the vector ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ is output supplied by the firm to the market, while negative components are inputs in its production process.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 76

Profit Maximization

โ€ข Isoprofit line:combinations of inputs and output for which the firm obtains a given level of profits.

โ€ข Note that๐œ‹๐œ‹0 = ๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘1๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1

Solving for ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 =๏ฟฝ๐œ‹๐œ‹0

๐‘๐‘2intercept

๏ฟฝโˆ’

๐‘๐‘1

๐‘๐‘2๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1

slopeAdvanced Microeconomic Theory 77

y2

y1

( )F yโˆ‡

{ }: ( ) 0y y F y= โ‰ค

1,2 ( )slope MRT y= โˆ’

Increasing profit

y(p) Supply correspondence

2 2 1 1 ''p y p y ฯ€โˆ’ =

2 2 1 1 'p y p y ฯ€โˆ’ =

Profit Maximization

โ€ข We can rewrite the PMP asmax

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ‰ค๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ)๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

with associated Lagrangian

๐ฟ๐ฟ = ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ†๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 78

Profit Maximization

โ€“ Taking FOCs with respect to every ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜, we obtain

๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜ โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ†๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜โ‰ค 0

where ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—) is evaluated at the optimum, i.e., ๐น๐น ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ— = ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘)) .

โ€“ For interior solutions, ๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐œ†๐œ† ๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

, or in matrix notation

๐‘๐‘ = ๐œ†๐œ†๐›ป๐›ป๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)that is, the price vector and the gradient vector are proportional.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 79

Profit Maximization

โ€“ Solving for ๐œ†๐œ†, we obtain

๐œ†๐œ† = ๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

for every good ๐‘˜๐‘˜ โŸน ๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜

= ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™

which can also be expressed as

๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™

=๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐น๐น(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™

(= ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘˜๐‘˜,๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—))

โ€“ Graphically, the slope of the transformation frontier (at the profit maximization production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—), ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘˜๐‘˜,๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—), coincides with the price ratio, ๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 80

Profit Maximization

โ€ข Are there PMPs with no supply correspondence ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ , i.e., there is no well defined profit maximizing vector?โ€“ Yes.

โ€ข Example: ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง = ๐‘ง๐‘ง (i.e., every unit of input ๐‘ง๐‘ง is transformed into a unit of output ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 81

Profit Maximization: Single Output

โ€ข Production function, ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง , produces a single output from a vector ๐‘ง๐‘ง of inputs.

max๐‘ง๐‘งโ‰ฅ0

๐‘๐‘๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง

โ€ข The first-order conditions are

๐‘๐‘ ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜ or ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜ โ‰ค ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ€ข For interior solutions, the market value of the marginal product obtained form using additional units of this input ๐‘˜๐‘˜, ๐‘๐‘ ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜, must coincide with

the price of this input, ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 82

Profit Maximization: Single Outputโ€ข Note that for any two input, this implies

๐‘๐‘ = ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

for every good ๐‘˜๐‘˜

Hence,

๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘™๐‘™

=๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™

=๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™

(= ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜,๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—))

or ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

=๐‘€๐‘€๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™

๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™Intuition: Marginal productivity per dollar spent on input ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜ is equal to that spent on input ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 83

Profit Maximizationโ€ข Example : Are there PMPs with no supply correspondence

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘), i.e., there is no well defined profit maximizing vector? โ€“ Yes.

โ€ข If the input price ๐‘๐‘๐‘ง๐‘ง satisfies ๐‘๐‘๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ ๐‘๐‘, then ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0 and ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = 0.

โ€ข If the input price ๐‘๐‘๐‘ง๐‘ง satisfies ๐‘๐‘๐‘ง๐‘ง < ๐‘๐‘, then ๐‘ž๐‘ž = +โˆž and ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = +โˆž. โ€“ In this case, the supply correspondence is not well defined,

since you can always increase input usage, thus increasing profits.

โ€“ Exception: if input usage is constrained in the interval 0, ๐‘ง๐‘ง , then ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ is at the corner solution ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ = ๐‘ง๐‘ง, thus implying that the PMP is well defined.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 84

Profit Maximization

โ€ข Example (continued):

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 85

q=f(z)

zz

Increasing profit

f(z)=q q=f(z)

z

Increasing profit

f(z)=q

y(p)=0

If ๐‘๐‘๐‘ง๐‘ง < ๐‘๐‘, the firm can โˆ†๐‘ž๐‘ž and โˆ†๐œ‹๐œ‹.

If ๐‘๐‘๐‘ง๐‘ง > ๐‘๐‘, the firm chooses ๐‘ž๐‘ž =๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ = 0 with ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = 0.

Profit Maximization: Single Output

โ€ข When are these FOCs also sufficient? โ€“ When the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is convex! Letโ€™s see.

โ€ข Isocost line for the firm is๐‘ค๐‘ค1๐‘ง๐‘ง1 + ๐‘ค๐‘ค2๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = ๐‘๐‘

โ€ข Solving for ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

๐‘ง๐‘ง2 =๏ฟฝ

๐‘๐‘๐‘ค๐‘ค2

intercept๏ฟฝโˆ’

๐‘ค๐‘ค1

๐‘ค๐‘ค2slope

๐‘ง๐‘ง1

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 86

Profit Maximization: Single Output

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 87

โ€“ The FOCs (necessary) of ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ = ๐‘ค๐‘ค1

๐‘ค๐‘ค2are

also sufficient.

โ€ข Convex production set

Profit Maximization: Single Output

โ€“ the FOCs are NOT sufficient for a combination of (๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2)that maximize profits.

โ€“ the profit-maximizing vector (๐‘ง๐‘ง1

โˆ—, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2โˆ—) is at a

corner solution, where the firm uses ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 alone.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 88

โ€ข Non-convex production set

Profit Maximization: Single Output

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 89

โ€ข Example: Cobb-Douglas production functionโ€ข On your own:

โ€“ Solve PMP (differentiating with respect to ๐‘ง๐‘ง1and ๐‘ง๐‘ง2.โ€“ Find optimal input usage ๐‘ง๐‘ง1(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) and ๐‘ง๐‘ง2(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž).

โ€ข These are referred to as โ€œconditional factor demand correspondencesโ€

โ€“ Plug them into the production function to obtain the value function, i.e., the output that arises when the firm uses its profit-maximizing input combination.

Properties of Profit Function

โ€ข Assume that the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is closed and satisfies the free disposal property.1) Homog(1) in prices

๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘๐‘ = ๐œ†๐œ†๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ Increasing the prices of all inputs and outputs by a

common factor ๐œ†๐œ† produces a proportional increase in the firmโ€™s profits.

๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = ๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค1๐‘ง๐‘ง1 โˆ’ โ‹ฏ โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘›๐‘›๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘›๐‘›Scaling all prices by a common factor, we obtain

๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘๐‘ = ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ค๐‘ค1๐‘ง๐‘ง1 โˆ’ โ‹ฏ โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘›๐‘›๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘›๐‘›= ๐œ†๐œ† ๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค1๐‘ง๐‘ง1 โˆ’ โ‹ฏ โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘›๐‘›๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘›๐‘› = ๐œ†๐œ†๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 90

Properties of Profit Function

2) Convex in output prices Intuition: the firm

obtains more profits from balanced input-output combinations, than from unbalanced combinations.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 91

z

y(p)

y(pโ€™)

( )y p

Y

q

q=f(z)

Price vector Production plan Profits

๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ) ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ

๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘) ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ = ๐›ผ๐›ผ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ + 1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ๐›ผ ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ

Properties of Profit Function

3) If the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is convex, then ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ: ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ค ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ for all ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 Intuition: the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ can be

represented by this โ€œdualโ€ set. This dual set specifies that, for any given

prices ๐‘๐‘, all production vectors ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ generate less profits ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, than the optimal production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) in the profit function ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 92

Properties of Profit Functionโ€ข All production plans

๐‘ง๐‘ง, ๐‘ž๐‘ž below the isoprofit line yield a lower profit level:

๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ค ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘โ€ข The isoprofit line ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ =

๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง can be expressed as

๐‘ž๐‘ž =๐œ‹๐œ‹๐‘๐‘

+๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘๐‘

๐‘ง๐‘ง

โ€“ If ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘๐‘

is constant โŸน ๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๏ฟฝis convex.

โ€“ What if it is not constant? Letโ€™s see next. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 93

z

y(p)

Y

q

q=f(z)

p q w zฯ€ = โ‹… โˆ’ โ‹…

{ }2 : ( )y p q w z pฯ€โˆˆ โ‹… โˆ’ โ‹… โ‰ค

Properties of Profit Functiona) Input prices are a function of input usage, i.e., ๐‘ค๐‘ค =

๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง), where ๐‘“๐‘“โ€ฒ(๐‘ง๐‘ง) โ‰  0. Then, eitheri. ๐‘“๐‘“โ€ฒ ๐‘ง๐‘ง < 0, and the firm gets a price discount per unit of

input from suppliers when ordering large amounts of inputs (e.g., loans)

ii. ๐‘“๐‘“โ€ฒ ๐‘ง๐‘ง > 0, and the firm has to pay more per unit of input when ordering large amounts of inputs (e.g., scarce qualified labor)

b) Output prices are a function of production , i.e., ๐‘๐‘ =๐‘”๐‘”(๐‘ž๐‘ž), where ๐‘”๐‘”โ€ฒ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) โ‰  0. Then, eitheri. ๐‘”๐‘”โ€ฒ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) < 0, and the firm offers price discounts to its

customers.ii. ๐‘”๐‘”โ€ฒ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) > 0, and the firm applies price surcharges to its

customers.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 94

Properties of Profit Function

โ€ข If ๐‘“๐‘“โ€ฒ ๐‘ง๐‘ง < 0, then we have strictly convexisoprofit curves.

โ€ข If ๐‘“๐‘“โ€ฒ ๐‘ง๐‘ง > 0, then we have strictly concaveisoprofit curves.

โ€ข If ๐‘“๐‘“โ€ฒ ๐‘ง๐‘ง = 0, then we have straightisoprofit curves.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 95

Remarks on Profit Function

โ€ข Remark 1: the profit function is a value function, measuring firm profits only for the profit-maximizing vector ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—.

โ€ข Remark 2: the profit function can be understood as a support function.โ€“ Take negative of the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, i.e., โˆ’๐‘Œ๐‘Œโ€“ Then, the support function of โˆ’๐‘Œ๐‘Œ set is

๐œ‡๐œ‡โˆ’๐‘Œ๐‘Œ ๐‘๐‘ = min๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ โˆ’๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ : ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ

That is, take the profits resulting form all production vectors ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, then take the negative of all these profits, ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ โˆ’๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ , and then choose the smallest one.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 96

Remarks on Profit Function

โ€“ Of course, this is the same as maximizing the (positive) value of the profits resulting from all production vector ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ, ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ.

โ€“ Therefore, the profit function, ๐œ‹๐œ‹(๐‘๐‘), is the support of the negative production set, โˆ’๐‘Œ๐‘Œ,

๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๐‘๐‘ = ๐œ‡๐œ‡โˆ’๐‘Œ๐‘Œ ๐‘๐‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 97

Remarks on Profit Function

โ€“ Alternatively, the argmax of any objective function๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1

โˆ— = arg max๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ)

coincides with the argmin of the negative of this objective function๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2

โˆ— = arg max๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

โˆ’๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ฅ๐‘ฅ)

where ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1โˆ— = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2

โˆ—.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 98

y2

y1

y(p)

y(pโ€™)

{ }: ( )y p y pฯ€โ‹… โ‰ค

{ }: ' ( ')y p y pฯ€โ‹… โ‰ค

( )q f z=

y2

y1

y(p),straight segment of Y

{ }: ( )y p y pฯ€โ‹… =

Properties of Supply Correspondence

โ€“ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ has a flat surfaceโ€“ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) is NOT single

valued.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 99

1) If ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is weakly convex, then ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) is a convex set for all ๐‘๐‘.

y2

y1

Unique y(p)

{ }: ( )y p y pฯ€โ‹… =

( )q f z=

Properties of Supply Correspondence

1) (continued) If ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is strictly convex, then ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) is single-valued (if nonempty).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 100

Properties of Supply Correspondence

2) Hotellingโ€™s Lemma: If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘) consists of a single point, then ๐œ‹๐œ‹(๏ฟฝ) is differentiable at ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘. Moreover, ๐›ป๐›ป๐‘๐‘๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘).

โ€“ This is an application of the duality theorem from consumer theory.

โ€ข If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ) is a function differentiable at ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘, then ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘) = ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘

2๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ is a symmetric and positive semidefinite matrix, with ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ = 0. This is a direct consequence of the law of supply.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 101

Properties of Supply Correspondence

โ€“ Since ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐œ‹๐œ‹ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ ๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘ = 0, ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘) must satisfy:Own substitution effects (main diagonal

elements in ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘)) are non-negative, i.e.,๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜(๐‘๐‘)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜โ‰ฅ 0 for all ๐‘˜๐‘˜

Cross substitution effects (off diagonal elements in ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐‘)) are symmetric, i.e.,

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘๐‘)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜

= ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜(๐‘๐‘)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™

for all ๐‘™๐‘™ and ๐‘˜๐‘˜

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 102

Properties of Supply Correspondence

โ€ข ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘˜๐‘˜(๐‘๐‘)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ‰ฅ 0 , which

implies that quantities and prices move in the same direction, (๐‘๐‘ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ)(๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ) โ‰ฅ 0โ€“ The law of supply holds!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 103

Properties of Supply Correspondence

โ€ข Since there is no budget constraint, there is no wealth compensation requirement (as opposed to Demand theory).โ€“ This implies that there no income effects, only

substitution effects.

โ€ข Alternatively, from a revealed preference argument, the law of supply can be expressed as

๐‘๐‘ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ =๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ + ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฅ 0

where ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘) and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ(๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ).Advanced Microeconomic Theory 104

Cost Minimization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 105

Cost Minimization

โ€ข We focus on the single output case, where โ€“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง is the input vectorโ€“ ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) is the production functionโ€“ ๐‘ž๐‘ž are the units of the (single) outputโ€“ ๐‘ค๐‘ค โ‰ซ 0 is the vector of input prices

โ€ข The cost minimization problem (CMP) ismin๐‘ง๐‘งโ‰ฅ0

๐‘ค๐‘ค ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ง๐‘งs. t. ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ž๐‘ž

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 106

Cost Minimization

โ€ข The optimal vector of input (or factor) choices is ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž), and is known as the conditional factor demand correspondence.โ€“ If single-valued, ๐‘ง๐‘ง ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž is a function (not a

correspondence)โ€“ Why โ€œconditionalโ€? Because it represents the

firmโ€™s demand for inputs, conditional on reaching output level ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

โ€ข The value function of this CMP ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž is the cost function.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 107

Cost Minimization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 108

z1

z2

1

2

wslopew

= โˆ’

Cost minimization

Isoquant f(z)=q

{ }: ( , )z w z c w qโ‹… = { }: ( , )z w z c w qโ‹… >

( , )z w q

Cost Minimizationโ€ข Graphically,

โ€“ For a given isoquant ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง = ๐‘ž๐‘ž, choose the isocost line associated with the lowest cost ๐‘ค๐‘ค ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ง๐‘ง.

โ€“ The tangency point is ๐‘ง๐‘ง ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž .โ€“ The isocost line associated with that combination of

inputs is๐‘ง๐‘ง: ๐‘ค๐‘ค ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ง๐‘ง = ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž

where the cost function ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž represents the lowest cost of producing output level ๐‘ž๐‘ž when input prices are ๐‘ค๐‘ค.

โ€“ Other isocost lines are associated with either: โ€ข output levels higher than ๐‘ž๐‘ž (with costs exceeding ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž ),

or โ€ข output levels lower than ๐‘ž๐‘ž (with costs below ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž ).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 109

Cost Minimization

โ€ข The Lagrangian of the CMP isโ„’ ๐‘ง๐‘ง; ๐œ†๐œ† = ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง + ๐œ†๐œ†[๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง ]

โ€ข Differentiating with respect to ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜ โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ† ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ‰ฅ 0

(= 0 if interior solution, ๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜โˆ—)

or in matrix notation๐‘ค๐‘ค โˆ’ ๐œ†๐œ†๐›ป๐›ป๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—) โ‰ฅ 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 110

Cost Minimization

โ€ข From the above FOCs,

๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜

= ๐œ†๐œ† โŸน๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜

๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘™๐‘™=

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™

(= ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€(๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—))

โ€ข Alternatively,๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜

=

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘งโˆ—

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘™๐‘™

at the cost-minimizing input combination, the marginal product per dollar spent on input ๐‘˜๐‘˜ must be equal that of input ๐‘™๐‘™.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 111

z1

z2Cost-minimizing, z(w,q)

{ }: ( , )z w z c w qโ‹… =z

Isoprofit line{ }ห† ห†: , where ( , )z w z c c c w qโ‹… = >

Cost Minimizationโ€ข Sufficiency: If the

production set is convex, then the FOCs are also sufficient.

โ€ข A non-convex production set: โ€“ The input combinations

satisfying the FOCs are NOT a cost-minimizing input combination ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž).

โ€“ The cost-minimizing combination of inputs ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) occurs at the corner.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 112

Cost Minimization

โ€ข Lagrange multiplier: ๐œ†๐œ† can be interpreted as the cost increase that the firm experiences when it needs to produce a higher level ๐‘ž๐‘ž.โ€“ Recall that, generally, the Lagrange multiplier

represents the variation in the objective function that we obtain if we relax the constraint (e.g., wealth in UMP, utility level we must reach in the EMP).

โ€ข Therefore, ๐œ†๐œ† is the marginal cost of production: the marginal increase in the firmโ€™s costs form producing additional units.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 113

Cost Minimization: SE and OE Effects

โ€ข Comparative statics of ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž): Let us analyze the effects of an input price change. Consider two inputs, e.g., labor and capital. When the price of labor, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, falls, two effects occur:โ€“ Substitution effect: if output is held constant,

there will be a tendency for the firm to substitute ๐‘™๐‘™ for ๐‘˜๐‘˜.

โ€“ Output effect: a reduction in firmโ€™s costs allows it to produce larger amounts of output (i.e., higher isoquant), which entails the use of more units of ๐‘™๐‘™for ๐‘˜๐‘˜.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 114

Cost Minimization: SE and OE Effects

โ€ข Substitution effect:โ€“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง0(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) solves CMP at

the initial prices.โ€“ โ†“ in wages โŸน isocost

line pivots outwards.โ€“ To reach ๐‘ž๐‘ž, push the

new isocost inwards in a parallel fashion.

โ€“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง1(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) solves CMP at the new input prices (for output level ๐‘ž๐‘ž).

โ€“ At ๐‘ง๐‘ง1(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž), firm uses more ๐‘™๐‘™ and less ๐‘˜๐‘˜.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 115

K

Lwโˆ‡ 1st step

2nd stepz0(w,q)

z1(w,q)f(z)=q, isoquant

Substitution effect

Cost Minimization: SE and OE Effects

โ€ข Substitution effect (SE):โ€“ increase in labor

demand from ๐ฟ๐ฟ๐ด๐ด to ๐ฟ๐ฟ๐ต๐ต. โ€“ same output as before

the input price change.โ€ข Output effect (OE):

โ€“ increase in labor demand from ๐ฟ๐ฟ๐ต๐ต to ๐ฟ๐ฟ๐ถ๐ถ.

โ€“ output level increases, total cost is the same as before the input price change.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 116

K

Lwโˆ‡ (1st step)

(2nd st

ep)

A

f(z)=q0, isoquant

BC3

rd step

KA

KBKC

LA LB LC

0

TCw 1

TCw

f(z)=q1, where q1>q0

SE OETE

TCr

Cost Minimization: Own-Price Effect

โ€ข We have two concepts of demand for any inputโ€“ the conditional demand for labor, ๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘(๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) ๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘(๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) solves the CMP

โ€“ the unconditional demand for labor, ๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค) ๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค) solves the PMP

โ€ข At the profit-maximizing level of output, i.e., ๐‘ž๐‘ž(๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค), the two must coincide

๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค = ๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘(๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž(๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค))Advanced Microeconomic Theory 117

Cost Minimization: Own-Price Effect

โ€ข Differentiating with respect to ๐‘ค๐‘ค yields

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค

=๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘€๐‘€๐‘†๐‘† (โˆ’)

+๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘(๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

(+)

๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค

(โˆ’)

๐‘‚๐‘‚๐‘†๐‘† (โˆ’)๐‘€๐‘€๐‘†๐‘† (โˆ’)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 118

Cost Minimization: Own-Price Effect

โ€ข Since ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘‡๐‘‡ > ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘‡๐‘‡, the unconditional labor demand is flatter than the conditional labor demand.

โ€ข Both ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘‡๐‘‡ and ๐‘‚๐‘‚๐‘‡๐‘‡ are negative.โ€“ Giffen paradox from

consumer theory cannot arise in production theory.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 119

w

z

A

B C

SE OETE

lc(v,w,q1) lc(v,w,q2)

Cost Minimization: Cross-Price Effect

โ€ข No definite statement can be made about cross-price (CP) effects.โ€“ A fall in the wage will lead the firm to substitute away

from capital.โ€“ The output effect will cause more capital to be

demanded as the firm expands production.

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜ ๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค

๐ถ๐ถ๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘†๐‘† + or (โˆ’)

=๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘๐‘ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค๐ถ๐ถ๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘†๐‘† (+)

+๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘๐‘(๐‘Ÿ๐‘Ÿ, ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

(+)

๏ฟฝ๏ฟฝ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค

(โˆ’)

๐ถ๐ถ๐‘€๐‘€ ๐‘‚๐‘‚๐‘†๐‘† (โˆ’)Advanced Microeconomic Theory 120

Cost Minimization: Cross-Price Effect

โ€ข The + cross-price OE completely offsets the โˆ’ cross-price SE, leading to a positive cross-price TE.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 121

w

K

wโˆ‡

A

B C

SEOE

TE

w

w1

1( , , )ck r w q 2( , , )ck r w q

( , , )k p r w

Cost Minimization: Cross-Price Effect

โ€ข The + cross-price OE only partially offsets the โˆ’ cross-price SE, leading to a negative cross-price TE.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 122

w

K

wโˆ‡

A

BC

SEOE

TE

w

w1

1( , , )ck r w q

2( , , )ck r w q

( , , )k p r w

Properties of Cost Function

โ€ข Assume that the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is closed and satisfies the free disposal property.1) ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is Homog(1) in ๐‘ค๐‘ค That is, increasing all input prices by a common

factor ๐œ†๐œ† yields a proportional increase in the minimal costs of production:

๐‘๐‘ ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

since ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) represents the minimal cost of producing a given output ๐‘ž๐‘ž at input prices ๐‘ค๐‘ค.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 123

Properties of Cost Function

An increase in all input prices (w1, w2) by the same proportion ฮป,produces a parallel downward shift in the firm's isocost line.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 124

z1

z2

f(z)=q

( , )z w q

2 2

( , ) ( , )c w q c w qw w

ฮปฮป

=

1 1

( , ) ( , )c w q c w qw w

ฮปฮป

=1

( , )c w qwฮป

2

( , )c w qwฮป

2wโˆ†

1wโˆ†

z1

z2

f(z)=q1

1( , )z w q

f(z)=q0

0( , )z w q

1

1

( , )c w qw

0

1

( , )c w qw

0

2

( , )c w qw

1

2

( , )c w qw

Properties of Cost Function

Producing higher output levels implies a weakly higher minimal cost of production

If ๐‘ž๐‘ž1 > ๐‘ž๐‘ž0, then it must be

๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž1) > ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž0)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 125

2) ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is non-decreasing in ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

Properties of Cost Function

3) If the set ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ 0: ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ž๐‘ž is convex for every ๐‘ž๐‘ž, then the production set can be described as

๐‘Œ๐‘Œ = โˆ’๐‘ง๐‘ง, ๐‘ž๐‘ž : ๐‘ค๐‘ค ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘žfor every ๐‘ค๐‘ค โ‰ซ 0

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 126

Properties of Cost Function Take ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง = ๐‘ž๐‘ž. For input prices ๐‘ค๐‘ค =

(๐‘ค๐‘ค1, ๐‘ค๐‘ค2), find ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) by solving CMP.

For input prices ๐‘ค๐‘คโ€ฒ =(๐‘ค๐‘ค1

โ€ฒ , ๐‘ค๐‘ค2โ€ฒ ), find ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘คโ€ฒ, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) by

solving CMP. The intersection of โ€œmore

costlyโ€ input combinations ๐‘ค๐‘ค ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž , for every input prices ๐‘ค๐‘ค โ‰ซ 0, describes set ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 127

z1

z2

1

2

wslopewโˆ’

=

f(z)=q0

z(w,q)

z(wโ€™,q)

1

2

''

wslopewโˆ’

=

{ }: ( , )z w z c w qโ‹… =

{ }: ' ( ', )z w z c w qโ‹… =

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence

That is, increasing input prices by the same factor ๐œ†๐œ† does not alter the firmโ€™s demand for inputs at all,

๐‘ง๐‘ง ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 128

z1

z2

z(w,q)=(z1(w,q),z2(w,q))

Isoquant f(z)=q

{ }0 : ( )z f z qโ‰ฅ โ‰ฅ

Isocost curve

1

( , )c w qw1

( , )c w qwฮป

2

( , )c w qwฮป

2

( , )c w qw

1) ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is Homog(0) in ๐‘ค๐‘ค.

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence

2) If the set {}

๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ0: ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ž๐‘ž is strictly convex, then the firm's demand correspondence ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is single valued.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 129

z1

z2

Unique z(w,q)

Isoquant f(z)=q

{ }0 : ( )z f z qโ‰ฅ โ‰ฅ

Isocost curve

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence

2) (continued) If the set {

}๐‘ง๐‘ง โ‰ฅ

0: ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) โ‰ฅ ๐‘ž๐‘ž is weakly convex, then the demand correspondence ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is not a single-valued, but a convex set.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 130

z1

z2

Set of z(w,q)

Isoquant f(z)=q

{ }0 : ( )z f z qโ‰ฅ โ‰ฅ

Isocost curve

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence

3) Shepardโ€™s lemma: If ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž) consists of a single point, then ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is differentiable with respect to ๐‘ค๐‘ค at, ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, and

๐›ป๐›ป๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 131

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence

4) If ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is differentiable at ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, then ๐ท๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ค

2 ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐ท๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž is a symmetric and negative semidefinite matrix, with ๐ท๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž ๏ฟฝ ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค = 0. ๐ท๐ท๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘ง๐‘ง ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž is a matrix representing how the

firmโ€™s demand for every unit responds to changes in the price of such input, or in the price of the other inputs.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 132

Properties of Conditional Factor Demand Correspondence

4) (continued) Own substitution effects are non-positive,

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜

โ‰ค 0 for every input ๐‘˜๐‘˜i.e., if the price of input ๐‘˜๐‘˜ increases, the firmโ€™s factor demand for this input decreases.

Cross substitution effects are symmetric,๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘˜๐‘˜(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘™๐‘™= ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ง๐‘ง๐‘™๐‘™(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค๐‘˜๐‘˜for all inputs ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 133

Properties of Production Function

1) If ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) is Homog(1) (i.e., if ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) exhibits constant returns to scale), then ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) and ๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) are Homog(1) in ๐‘ž๐‘ž. Intuitively, if ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) exhibits CRS, then an

increase in the output level we seek to reach induces an increase of the same proportion in the cost function and in the demand for inputs. That is,

๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)and

๐‘ง๐‘ง ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐œ†๐œ†๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)Advanced Microeconomic Theory 134

Properties of Production Function

๐œ†๐œ† = 2 implies that demand for inputs doubles๐‘ง๐‘ง ๐‘ค๐‘ค, 2๐‘ž๐‘ž = 2๐‘ง๐‘ง(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

and that minimal costs also double

๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, 2๐‘ž๐‘ž = 2๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 135

z1

z2

q=10units

q'=20unitsz(w,q)

z(w,qโ€™)=2z(w,q)

1

2

1 2ฮป=2

ฮป=2

c(w,q)c(w,q')=2c(w,q)

Properties of Production Function

2) If ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง) is concave, then ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is convex function of ๐‘ž๐‘ž (i.e., marginal costs are non-decreasing in ๐‘ž๐‘ž). More compactly,

๐œ•๐œ•2๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž2 โ‰ฅ 0

or, in other words, marginal costs ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

are weakly increasing in ๐‘ž๐‘ž.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 136

Properties of Production Function

2) (continued) Firm uses more inputs

when raising output from ๐‘ž๐‘ž2 to ๐‘ž๐‘ž3 than from ๐‘ž๐‘ž1 to ๐‘ž๐‘ž2.

Hence,๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž3) โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž2) >

๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž2) โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž1) This reflects the

convexity of the cost function ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) with respect to ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 137

z1

z2

q1=10units

q2=20unitsz(w,q1)

c(w,q1) c(w,q2)

z(w,q2)

z(w,q3)

11z

21z

31z

32z

22z

12z

c(w,q3)

q3=30units

Alternative Representation of PMP

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 138

Alternative Representation of PMP

โ€ข Using the cost function ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž), we write the PMP as follows

max๐‘ž๐‘žโ‰ฅ0

๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

This is useful if we have information about the cost function, but we donโ€™t about the production function ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘“๐‘“ ๐‘ง๐‘ง .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 139

Alternative Representation of PMP

โ€ข Let us now solve this alternative PMPmax๐‘ž๐‘žโ‰ฅ0

๐‘๐‘๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

โ€ข FOCs for ๐‘ž๐‘žโˆ— to be profit maximizing are

๐‘๐‘ โˆ’๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘žโˆ—)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘žโ‰ค 0

and in interior solutions

๐‘๐‘ โˆ’๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘žโˆ—

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž= 0

โ€ข That is, at the interior optimum ๐‘ž๐‘žโˆ—, price equals marginal cost, ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘๐‘ ๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘žโˆ—

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 140

L

K

q0

q1

c(w,q0) c(w,q1)0cl 1

cl

2ck

1ck

0ck

c(w,q2)

q2

2cl

Expansion path

Firmโ€™s Expansion Path

โ€ข The curve shows how inputs increase as output increases.

โ€ข Expansion path is positively sloped.

โ€ข Both ๐‘˜๐‘˜ and ๐‘™๐‘™ are normalgoods, i.e.,

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

โ‰ฅ 0, ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

โ‰ฅ 0Advanced Microeconomic Theory 141

โ€ข The expansion path is the locus of cost-minimizing tangencies. (Analogous to the wealth expansion path in consumer theory)

Firmโ€™s Expansion Path

โ€ข If the firmโ€™s expansion path is a straight line:โ€“ All inputs must increase at a constant proportion as

firm increases its output.โ€“ The firmโ€™s production function exhibits constant

returns to scale and it is, hence, homothetic.โ€“ If the expansion path is straight and coincides with the

45-degree line, then the firm increases all inputs by the same proportion as output increases.

โ€ข The expansion path does not have to be a straight line. โ€“ The use of some inputs may increase faster than

others as output expandsโ€ข Depends on the shape of the isoquants.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 142

Firmโ€™s Expansion Path

โ€ข The expansion path does not have to be upward sloping.โ€“ If the use of an input falls

as output expands, that input is an inferior input.

โ€ข ๐‘˜๐‘˜ is normal๐œ•๐œ•๐‘˜๐‘˜๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘žโ‰ฅ 0

but ๐‘™๐‘™ is inferior (at higher levels of output)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘™๐‘™๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

< 0Advanced Microeconomic Theory 143

Firmโ€™s Expansion Path

โ€ข Are there inferior inputs out there?โ€“ We can identify inferior inputs if the list of inputs used

by the firms is relatively disaggregated.โ€“ For instance, we can identify following categories:

CEOs, executives, managers, accountants, secretaries, janitors, etc.

โ€“ These inputs do not increase at a constant rate as the firm increases output (i.e., expansion path would not be a straight line for all increases in ๐‘ž๐‘ž).

โ€“ After reaching a certain scale, the firm might buy a powerful computer with which accounting can be done using fewer accountants.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 144

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Let us assume a given vector of input prices ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค โ‰ซ0. Then, ๐‘๐‘(๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) can be reduced to ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž). Then, average and marginal costs are

๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐‘ž๐‘ž

and ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ = ๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐œ•๐œ•๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

โ€ข Hence, the FOCs of the PMP can be expressed as

๐‘๐‘ โ‰ค ๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘ž , and in interior solutions ๐‘๐‘ = ๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘ž

i.e., all output combinations such that ๐‘๐‘ = ๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘žare the (optimal) supply correspondence of the firm ๐‘ž๐‘ž ๐‘๐‘ .

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 145

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข We showed that the cost function ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is homogenous of degree 1 in input prices, ๐‘ค๐‘ค.โ€“ Can we extend this property to the AC and MC?

Yes!โ€“ For average cost function,

๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž =๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐‘ž๐‘ž=

๐‘ก๐‘ก ๏ฟฝ ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐‘ž๐‘ž

= ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๏ฟฝ ๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 146

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€“ For marginal cost function,

๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž =๐œ•๐œ•๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž=

๐‘ก๐‘ก ๏ฟฝ ๐œ•๐œ•๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

= ๐‘ก๐‘ก ๏ฟฝ ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ก๐‘ก๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘žโ€“ Isnโ€™t this result violating Eulerโ€™s theorem? No! The above result states that ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is homog(1) in

inputs prices, and that ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐œ•๐œ•๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

is also homog(1) in input prices. Eulerโ€™s theorem would say that: If ๐‘๐‘(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž) is

homog(1) in inputs prices, then its derivate with respect to input prices, ๐œ•๐œ•๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ค๐‘ค,๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ค๐‘ค, must be homog(0).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 147

TC

Total cost

c

output

Graphical Analysis of Total Cost

โ€ข With constant returns to scale, total costs are proportional to output.

๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) = ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ž๐‘žโ€ข Hence,

๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) =๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐‘ž๐‘ž= ๐‘๐‘

๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) =๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž= ๐‘๐‘

โŸน ๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) = ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)Advanced Microeconomic Theory 148

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Suppose that TC starts out as concave and then becomes convex as output increases.โ€“ TC no longer exhibits constant returns to scale.โ€“ One possible explanation for this is that there is a

third factor of production that is fixed as capital and labor usage expands (e.g., entrepreneurial skills).

โ€“ TC begins rising rapidly after diminishing returns set in.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 149

TCTC(q)

B

q

A

C

0 50

$1,500

ACMC

q0 50

Aโ€™

Aโ€™โ€™$10

$30

MC(q)

AC(q)

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข TC initially grows very rapidly, then becomes relatively flat, and for high production levels increases rapidly again.

โ€ข MC is the slope of the TC curve.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 150

Cost and Supply: Single Output

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 151

ACMC

q

MC(Q)

AC(Q)

min AC

TC becomes flatter

TC becomes steeper

Cost and Supply: Single Output

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 152

โ€ข Remark 1: AC=MC at ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0.โ€“ Note that we cannot compute

๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ 0 =๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ 0

0=

00

โ€“ We can still apply lโ€™Hopitalโ€™s rule

lim๐‘ž๐‘žโ†’0

๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) = lim๐‘ž๐‘žโ†’0

๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐‘ž๐‘ž

= lim๐‘ž๐‘žโ†’0

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

= lim๐‘ž๐‘žโ†’0

๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)

โ€“ Hence, AC=MC at ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0, i.e., AC(0)=MC(0).

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Remark 2: When MC<AC, the AC curve decreases, and when MC>AC, the AC curve increases.โ€“ Intuition: using example of gradesโ€“ If the new exam score raises your average grade, it

must be that such new grade is better than your average grade thus far.

โ€“ If, in contrast, the new exam score lowers your average grade, it must be that such new grade is than your average grade thus far.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 153

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Remark 3: AC and MC curves cross (AC=MC) at exactly the minimum of the AC curve.โ€“ Let us first find the minimum of the AC curve

๐œ•๐œ•๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

=๐œ•๐œ• ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐‘ž๐‘ž๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž

=๐‘ž๐‘ž ๐œ•๐œ•๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐œ•๐œ•๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) ๏ฟฝ 1

๐‘ž๐‘ž2

=๐‘ž๐‘ž ๏ฟฝ ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) โˆ’ ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)

๐‘ž๐‘ž2 = 0

โ€“ The output that minimizes AC must satisfy

๐‘ž๐‘ž ๏ฟฝ ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž โˆ’ ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0 โŸน ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž =๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž

๐‘ž๐‘žโ† ๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž

โ€“ Hence, ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ = ๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ at the minimum of ๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 154

q

-z q

Y

(a) (b) (c)

ห†( )slope AC q=

ห†'( )slope C q=

C(q)

q

p

Cโ€™(q)

AC(q)

q

Heavy trace is supply

locus q(p)q

z

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Decreasing returns to scale:โ€“ an increase in the use of inputs produces a less-than-

proportional increase in output. production set is strictly convex TC function is convex MC and AC are increasing

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 155

q

-z q

Y

(a) (b) (c)

C(q)

q

p

AC(q) = Cโ€™(q)

q(p)

No sales for p < MC(q)

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Constant returns to scale:โ€“ an increase in input usage produces a proportional

increase in output. production set is weakly convex linear TC function constant AC and MC functions

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 156

q

-z q

Y

(a) (b) (c)

C(q)

q

p

q(p)

Cโ€™(q)AC(q)

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Increasing returns to scale: โ€“ an increase in input usage can lead to a more-than-

proportional increase in output. production set is non-convex TC curve first increases, then becomes almost flat, and then

increases rapidly again as output is increased further.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 157

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข Let us analyze the presence of non-convexitiesin the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ arising from:โ€“ Fixed set-up costs, ๐พ๐พ, that are non-sunk

๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐พ๐พ + ๐ถ๐ถ๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ ๐‘ž๐‘ž

where ๐ถ๐ถ๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) denotes variable costsโ€ข with strictly convex variable costsโ€ข with linear variable costs

โ€“ Fixed set-up costs that are sunkโ€ข Cost function is convex, and hence FOCs are sufficient

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 158

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข CRS technology and fixed (non-sunk) costs:โ€“ If ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0, then ๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0, i.e., firm can recover ๐พ๐พ if it

shuts down its operation.โ€“ MC is constant: ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ = ๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐ถ๐ถ๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ

โ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐‘๐‘

โ€“ AC lies above MC: ๐ด๐ด๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž)๐‘ž๐‘ž

= ๐พ๐พ๐‘ž๐‘ž

+ ๐ถ๐ถ๐‘ฃ๐‘ฃ ๐‘ž๐‘ž๐‘ž๐‘ž

= ๐พ๐พ๐‘ž๐‘ž

+ ๐‘๐‘

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 159

q

-z q

Y

(a) (b) (c)

C(q)

q

pCv(q)=Cโ€™(q)

AC(q)

q

( )AC q

q(q)

q

Cost and Supply: Single Outputโ€ข DRS technology and fixed (non-sunk) costs:

โ€“ MC is positive and increasing in ๐‘ž๐‘ž, and hence the slope of the TC curve increases in ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

โ€“ in the decreasing portion of the AC curve, FC is spread over larger ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

โ€“ in the increasing portion of the AC curve, larger average VC offsets the lower average FC and, hence, total average cost increases.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 160

q

-z q

Y

(a) (b) (c)

C(q)

q

pCโ€™(q)

AC(q)q(p)

K

Cost and Supply: Single Output

โ€ข DRS technology and sunk costs:โ€“ TC curve originates at ๐พ๐พ, given that the firm must

incur fixed sunk cost ๐พ๐พ even if it chooses ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 0.โ€“ supply locus considers the entire MC curve and not

only ๐‘ž๐‘ž for which MC>AC.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 161

Short-Run Total Cost

โ€ข In the short run, the firm generally incurs higher costs than in the long runโ€“ The firm does not have the flexibility of input

choice (fixed inputs).โ€“ To vary its output in the short-run, the firm must

use non-optimal input combinationsโ€“ The ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ will not be equal to the ratio of input

prices.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 162

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข In the short-run โ€“ capital is fixed at ๏ฟฝ๐พ๐พโ€“ the firm cannot

equate ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€ with the ratio of input prices.

โ€ข In the long-runโ€“ Firm can choose

input vector ๐ด๐ด, which is a cost-minimizing input combination.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 163

A

F

K

L

C(w,Q0)

C(w,Q0)

r

w

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 1 million unitsโ€“ Firm chooses (๐‘˜๐‘˜1, ๐‘™๐‘™1)

both in the long run and in the short run when ๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘˜๐‘˜1.

โ€ข ๐‘ž๐‘ž = 2 million unitsโ€“ Short-run (point B): ๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘˜๐‘˜1 does not allow

the firm to minimize costs.

โ€“ Long-run (point C): firm can choose cost-

minimizing input combination.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 164

A B

K

L

C

Expansion path

Q=2

Q=10

K1

K2

L1 L2 L2

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข The difference between long-run, ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž), and short-run, ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž), total costs when capital is fixed at ๐‘˜๐‘˜ = ๐‘˜๐‘˜1.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 165

TC

Q0

rK1

A

B

C

1 million 2 million

TC(q)

STC(Q) when k=k1

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข The long-run total cost curve ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) can be derived by varying the level of ๐‘˜๐‘˜.

โ€ข Short-run total cost curve ๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) lies above long-run total cost ๐‘€๐‘€๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 166

TC

q0q 1q 2q

STC(q) where k=k0 STC(q) where k=k1

STC(q) where k=k2

TC(q)

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข Summary:โ€“ In the long run, the firm can modify the values of

all inputs.โ€“ In the short run, in contrast, the firm can only

modify some inputs (e.g., labor, but not capital).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 167

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข Example: Short- and long-run curvesโ€“ In the long run,

๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค1๐‘ง๐‘ง1 + ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค2๐‘ง๐‘ง2

where both input 1 and 2 are variable.

โ€“ In the short run, input 2 is fixed at ๐‘ง๐‘ง2, and thus๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž| ๐‘ง๐‘ง2 = ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค1๐‘ง๐‘ง1 + ๏ฟฝ๐‘ค๐‘ค2 ๐‘ง๐‘ง2

โ€ข This implies that the only input that the firm can modify is input 1.

โ€ข The firm chooses ๐‘ง๐‘ง1 such that production reaches output level ๐‘ž๐‘ž, i.e., ๐‘“๐‘“(๐‘ง๐‘ง1, ๐‘ง๐‘ง2) = ๐‘ž๐‘ž.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 168

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข Example (continued):โ€“ When the demand for input 2 is at its long-run

value, i.e., ๐‘ง๐‘ง2(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž), then

๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž|๐‘ง๐‘ง2(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)) for every ๐‘ž๐‘žand also

๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ ๐‘ž๐‘ž = ๐ถ๐ถโ€ฒ(๐‘ž๐‘ž|๐‘ง๐‘ง2(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž)) for every ๐‘ž๐‘ži.e., values and slopes of long- and short-run cost functions coincide.

โ€“ Long- and short-run curves are tangent at ๐‘ง๐‘ง2(๐‘ค๐‘ค, ๐‘ž๐‘ž).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 169

Short-Run vs Long-Run Total Cost

โ€ข Example (continued): โ€“ Since

๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž) โ‰ค ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž|๐‘ง๐‘ง2) for any given ๐‘ง๐‘ง2,

then the long-run cost curve ๐ถ๐ถ ๐‘ž๐‘ž is the lower envelope of the short-run cost curves, ๐ถ๐ถ(๐‘ž๐‘ž|๐‘ง๐‘ง2).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 170

Aggregation in Production

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 171

Aggregation in Production

โ€ข Let us analyze under which conditions the โ€œlaw of supplyโ€ holds at the aggregate level.

โ€ข An aggregate production function maps aggregate inputs into aggregate outputsโ€“ In other words, it describes the maximum level of

output that can be obtained if the inputs are efficiently used in the production process.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 172

Aggregation in Production

โ€ข Consider ๐ฝ๐ฝ firms, with production sets ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ1, ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ2, โ€ฆ , ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ๐ฝ๐ฝ.โ€ข Each ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ๐‘—๐‘— is non-empty, closed, and satisfies the free

disposal property.โ€ข Assume also that every supply correspondence ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘—(๐‘๐‘) is

single valued, and differentiable in prices, ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0.โ€ข Define the aggregate supply correspondence as the

sum of the individual supply correspondences

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ = ๏ฟฝ๐‘—๐‘—=1

๐ฝ๐ฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ: ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = ๏ฟฝ

๐‘—๐‘—=1

๐ฝ๐ฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘

where ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— โˆˆ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘—(๐‘๐‘) for ๐‘—๐‘— = 1,2, โ€ฆ , ๐ฝ๐ฝ.Advanced Microeconomic Theory 173

Aggregation in Production

โ€ข The law of supply is satisfied at the aggregate level.

โ€ข Two ways to check it:1) Using the derivative of every firmโ€™s supply

correspondence with respect to prices, ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘ .โ€“ ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘ is a symmetric positive semidefinite

matrix, for every firm ๐‘—๐‘—. โ€“ Since this property is preserved under

addition, then ๐ท๐ท๐‘๐‘๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ must also define a symmetric positive semidefinite matrix.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 174

Aggregation in Production

2) Using a revealed preference argument.โ€“ For every firm ๐‘—๐‘—,

๐‘๐‘ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘ โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ โ‰ฅ 0

โ€“ Adding over ๐‘—๐‘—,๐‘๐‘ โˆ’ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘ โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ ๐‘๐‘โ€ฒ โ‰ฅ 0

โ€“ This implies that market prices and aggregate supply move in the same direction the law of supply holds at the aggregate level!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 175

Aggregation in Production

โ€ข Is there a โ€œrepresentative producerโ€?โ€“ Let ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ be the aggregate production set,

๐‘Œ๐‘Œ = ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ1 + ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ2+. . . +๐‘Œ๐‘Œ๐‘—๐‘— = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ: ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = ๏ฟฝ๐‘—๐‘—=1

๐ฝ๐ฝ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘—

for some ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ๐‘—๐‘— and ๐‘—๐‘— = 1,2, โ€ฆ , ๐ฝ๐ฝ.โ€“ Note that ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = โˆ‘๐‘—๐‘—=1

๐ฝ๐ฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— , where every ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— is just a feasible production plan of firm ๐‘—๐‘—, but not necessarily firm ๐‘—๐‘—โ€™s supply correspondence ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘—(๐‘๐‘).

โ€“ Let ๐œ‹๐œ‹โˆ—(๐‘๐‘) be the profit function for the aggregate production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

โ€“ Let ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—(๐‘๐‘) be the supply correspondence for the aggregate production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 176

Aggregation in Production

โ€ข Is there a โ€œrepresentative producerโ€?โ€“ Then, there exists a representative producer:

โ€ข Producing an aggregate supply ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโˆ—(๐‘๐‘) that exactly coincides with the sum โˆ‘๐‘—๐‘—=1

๐ฝ๐ฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘— ๐‘๐‘ ; and โ€ข Obtaining aggregate profits ๐œ‹๐œ‹โˆ—(๐‘๐‘) that exactly coincide with

the sum โˆ‘๐‘—๐‘—=1๐ฝ๐ฝ ๐œ‹๐œ‹๐‘—๐‘— (๐‘๐‘).

โ€“ Intuition: The aggregate profit obtained by each firm maximizing its profits separately (taking prices as given) is the same as that which would be obtained if all firms were to coordinate their actions (i.e., ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘—๐‘—โ€™s) in a joint PMP.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 177

Aggregation in Production

โ€ข Is there a โ€œrepresentative producerโ€?โ€“ It is a โ€œdecentralizationโ€ result: to find the solution

of the joint PMP for given prices ๐‘๐‘, it is enough to โ€œlet each individual firm maximize its own profitsโ€ and add the solutions of their individual PMPs.

โ€“ Key: price taking assumptionโ€ข This result does not hold if firms have market power. โ€ข Example: oligopoly markets where firms compete in

quantities (a la Cournot).

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 178

Aggregation in Productionโ€ข Firm 1 chooses ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 given ๐‘๐‘

and ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ1.โ€ข Firm 2 chooses ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2 given

๐‘๐‘ and ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ2.โ€ข Jointly, the two firms

would be selecting ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 +๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2.

โ€ข The aggregate supply correspondence ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 + ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2coincides with the supply correspondence that a single firm would select given ๐‘๐‘ and ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ1 + ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 179

Efficient Production

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 180

Efficient Production

โ€ข Efficient production vector: a production vector ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is efficient if there is no other ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ such that ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰  ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ. โ€“ That is, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient if there is no other feasible

production vector ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ producing more output with the same amount of inputs, or alternatively, producing the same output with fewer inputs.

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient โ‡’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is on the boundary of ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient โ‡ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is on the boundary of ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 181

Efficient Production

โ€ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโ€ฒ produces the same output as ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, but uses more inputs.

โ€ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ uses the same inputs as ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, but produces less output.

โ€ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโ€ฒ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ are inefficient.

โ€ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient โ‡’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ lies on the frontier of the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 182

y

z

Y

y

y'

y''

Efficient Production

โ€ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficientโ€ข ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ is inefficient

โ€“ it produces the same output as ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, but uses more inputs.

โ€ข Hence, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ lies on thefrontier of theproduction set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ โ‡ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ is efficient.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 183

y

z

Y

yy'

Efficient Production: 1st FTWE

โ€ข 1st Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics (FTWE): If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is profit-maximizing for some price vector ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0, then ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ must be efficient.Proof: Let us prove the 1st FTWE by contradiction. Suppose that ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is profit-maximizing

๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฅ ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ for all ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œbut ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is not efficient. That is, there is a ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ such that ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ. If we multiply both sides of ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ by ๐‘๐‘, we obtain

๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, since ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0But then, ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ cannot be profit-maximizing. Contradiction!

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 184

y

z

Y

y

p

Isoprofit line

y

z

p

y'

y

Efficient Production: 1st FTWE

โ€ข For the result in 1st FTWE, we do NOT need the production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ to be convex.โ€“ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is profit-maximizing โ‡’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ lies on a tangency point

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 185

convex production set non-convex production set

y

z

Y

y

p

Profit maximizingProduction

plans

Efficient Production: 1st FTWE

โ€“ Any production plan in the flat segment of ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ can be profit-maximizing if prices are ๐‘๐‘ = (0,1).

โ€“ But only ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient.โ€“ Other profit-maximizing

production plans to the left of ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ are NOT efficient.

โ€“ Hence, in order to apply 1st FTWE we need ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 186

โ€ข Note: the assumption ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0 cannot be relaxed to ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ฅ 0.โ€“ Take a production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ with an upper flat surface.

Efficient Production: 2nd FTWE

โ€ข The 2nd FTWE states the converse of the 1st

FTWE: โ€“ If a production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient, then it must be

profit-maximizing.

โ€ข Note that, while it is true for convex production sets, it cannot be true if ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is non-convex.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 187

y

z

p

y'

yy

z

Y

y

p

Isoprofit line

Efficient Production: 2nd FTWE

โ€ข The 2nd FTWE is restricted to convex production sets.โ€ข For non-convex production set: If ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient โ‡

๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is profit-maximizing

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 188

convex production set non-convex production set

Efficient Production: 2nd FTWE

โ€ข 2nd FTWE: If production set ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is convex, then every efficient production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ is profit-maximizing production plan, for some non-zero price vector ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ฅ 0.Proof: 1) Take an efficient production plan, such as ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ on

the boundary of ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ. Define the set of production plans that are strictly more efficient than ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ

๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ = ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ โ„๐ฟ๐ฟ: ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ซ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ2) Note that ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ โˆฉ ๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰  โˆ… and ๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is convex set.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 189

Efficient Production: 2nd FTWEProof (continued): 3) From the Separating

Hyperplane Theorem, there is some ๐‘๐‘ โ‰  0such that ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ฅ ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโ€ฒ, for ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘ƒ๐‘ƒ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

4) Since ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ can be made arbitrarily close to ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, we can have ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ โ‰ฅ ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโ€ฒfor ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒโ€ฒ โˆˆ ๐‘Œ๐‘Œ.

5) Hence, the efficient production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ must be profit-maximizing.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 190

y

z

Y

p

Isoprofit line

y'

Py

y

Efficient Production: 2nd FTWE

โ€“ We just assume that the price vector is not zero for every component, i.e., ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ (0,0, โ€ฆ , 0).

โ€“ Hence, the slope of the isoprofit line can be zero.

โ€“ Both ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ and ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ are profit-maximizing, but only ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ is efficient.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 191

y

z

Y

yp

Profit maximizingProduction

plans

y'

โ€ข Note: we are not imposing ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ซ 0, but ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ฅ 0.

Efficient Production: 2nd FTWE

โ€ข Note: the 2nd FTWE does not allow for input prices to be negative.โ€“ Consider the case in which the price of input ๐‘™๐‘™ is

negative, ๐‘๐‘๐‘™๐‘™ < 0.โ€“ Then, we would have ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ < ๐‘๐‘ ๏ฟฝ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ for some

production plan ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ that is more efficient than ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, i.e., ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆโ€ฒ โ‰ซ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ, with ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™

โ€ฒ โˆ’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘ฆ๐‘™๐‘™ being sufficiently large.โ€“ This implies that the firm is essentially โ€œpaidโ€ for

using further amounts of input ๐‘™๐‘™.โ€“ For this reason, we assume ๐‘๐‘ โ‰ฅ 0.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory 192


Recommended