+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of...

Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of...

Date post: 22-Aug-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
59
Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of Credit* Viral V. Acharya Heitor Almeida Murillo Campello NYUStern, CEPR, University of Illinois University of Illinois ECGI & NBER & NBER & NBER [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Abstract We model corporate liquidity policy and show that aggregate risk exposure is a key determinant of how rms choose between cash and bank credit lines. Banks create liquidity for rms by pooling their idiosyncratic risks. As a result, rms with high aggregate risk nd it costly to get credit lines and opt for cash in spite of higher opportunity costs and liquidity premium. Likewise, in times when aggregate risk is high, rms rely more on cash than on credit lines. We verify these predictions empirically. Cross-sectional analyses show that rms with high exposure to systematic risk have a higher ratio of cash to credit lines and face higher spreads on their lines. Time-series analyses show that rmscash reserves rise in times of high aggregate volatility and in such times credit lines initiations fall, their spreads widen, and maturities shorten. Our theory and evidence shed new insights on the relation between macroeconomic risk, nancial intermediation, and rm nancial decisions. Key words: Bank lines of credit, cash holdings, liquidity management, systematic risk, loan spreads, loan maturity, asset beta. JEL classication: G21, G31, G32, E22, E5. *Our paper beneted from comments from Peter Tufano (editor), an anonymous referee, Hui Chen, Ran Duchin and Robert McDonald (discussants), and Rene Stulz, as well as seminar participants at the 2010 AEA meetings, 2010 WFA meetings, DePaul University, ESSEC, Emory University, MIT, Moodys/NYU Stern 2010 Credit Risk Conference, New York University, Northwestern University, UCLA, University of Illinois, Vienna University of Economics and Business, and Yale University. We thank Florin Vasvari and Anurag Gupta for help with the data on lines of credit, and Michael Roberts and Florin Vasvari for matching these data with COMPUSTAT. Farhang Farazmand, Fabrcio DAlmeida, Igor Cunha, Rustom Irani, Hanh Le, and Quoc Nguyen provided excellent research assistance. We are also grateful to Jaewon Choi for sharing his data on rm betas, and to Thomas Philippon and Ran Duchin for sharing their programs to compute asset and nancing gap betas.
Transcript
Page 1: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of Credit*

Viral V. Acharya Heitor Almeida Murillo CampelloNYU�Stern, CEPR, University of Illinois University of IllinoisECGI & NBER & NBER & NBER

[email protected] [email protected] [email protected]

Abstract

We model corporate liquidity policy and show that aggregate risk exposure is a key determinant ofhow �rms choose between cash and bank credit lines. Banks create liquidity for �rms by pooling theiridiosyncratic risks. As a result, �rms with high aggregate risk �nd it costly to get credit lines and optfor cash in spite of higher opportunity costs and liquidity premium. Likewise, in times when aggregaterisk is high, �rms rely more on cash than on credit lines. We verify these predictions empirically.Cross-sectional analyses show that �rms with high exposure to systematic risk have a higher ratio ofcash to credit lines and face higher spreads on their lines. Time-series analyses show that �rms�cashreserves rise in times of high aggregate volatility and in such times credit lines initiations fall, theirspreads widen, and maturities shorten. Our theory and evidence shed new insights on the relationbetween macroeconomic risk, �nancial intermediation, and �rm �nancial decisions.

Key words: Bank lines of credit, cash holdings, liquidity management, systematic risk, loan spreads, loanmaturity, asset beta.

JEL classi�cation: G21, G31, G32, E22, E5.

*Our paper bene�ted from comments from Peter Tufano (editor), an anonymous referee, Hui Chen, RanDuchin and Robert McDonald (discussants), and Rene Stulz, as well as seminar participants at the 2010 AEAmeetings, 2010 WFA meetings, DePaul University, ESSEC, Emory University, MIT, Moody�s/NYU Stern2010 Credit Risk Conference, New York University, Northwestern University, UCLA, University of Illinois,Vienna University of Economics and Business, and Yale University. We thank Florin Vasvari and AnuragGupta for help with the data on lines of credit, and Michael Roberts and Florin Vasvari for matching thesedata with COMPUSTAT. Farhang Farazmand, Fabrício D�Almeida, Igor Cunha, Rustom Irani, Hanh Le, andQuoc Nguyen provided excellent research assistance. We are also grateful to Jaewon Choi for sharing his dataon �rm betas, and to Thomas Philippon and Ran Duchin for sharing their programs to compute asset and�nancing gap betas.

Page 2: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of Credit

Abstract

We model corporate liquidity policy and show that aggregate risk exposure is a key determinant ofhow �rms choose between cash and bank credit lines. Banks create liquidity for �rms by pooling theiridiosyncratic risks. As a result, �rms with high aggregate risk �nd it costly to get credit lines and optfor cash in spite of higher opportunity costs and liquidity premium. Likewise, in times when aggregaterisk is high, �rms rely more on cash than on credit lines. We verify these predictions empirically.Cross-sectional analyses show that �rms with high exposure to systematic risk have a higher ratio ofcash to credit lines and face higher spreads on their lines. Time-series analyses show that �rms�cashreserves rise in times of high aggregate volatility and in such times credit lines initiations fall, theirspreads widen, and maturities shorten. Our theory and evidence shed new insights on the relationbetween macroeconomic risk, �nancial intermediation, and �rm �nancial decisions.

Key words: Bank lines of credit, cash holdings, liquidity management, systematic risk, loan spreads, loanmaturity, asset beta.

JEL classi�cation: G21, G31, G32, E22, E5.

Page 3: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

�A Federal Reserve survey earlier this year found that about one-third of U.S. banks have tightened theirstandards on loans they make to businesses of all sizes. And about 45% of banks told the Fed that they arecharging more for credit lines to large and midsize companies. Banks such as Citigroup Inc., which has beenbattered by billions of dollars in write-downs and other losses, are especially likely to play hardball, resistingpleas for more credit or pushing borrowers to pay more for loan modi�cations.�

� The Wall Street Journal, March 8, 2008

1 Introduction

How do �rms manage their liquidity needs? This question has become increasingly important for

both academic research and corporate �nance in practice. Survey evidence indicates that liquidity

management tools such as cash and credit lines are essential components of a �rm�s �nancial pol-

icy (see Lins, Servaes, and Tufano (2010) and Campello, Giambona, Graham, and Harvey (2010)).

Consistent with the evidence from surveys, a number of studies show that the funding of invest-

ment opportunities is a key determinant of corporate cash policy (e.g., Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz, and

Williamson (1999), Almeida, Campello, and Weisbach (2004, 2009), and Duchin (2009)). Recent

work also shows that bank lines of credit have become an important source of �rm �nancing (Su�

(2009) and Disatnik, Duchin, and Schmidt (2010)). The available evidence further suggests that

credit lines played a crucial role in the liquidity management of industrial �rms during the recent

credit crisis (Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010)).

In contrast to the growing empirical literature, there is limited theoretical work on the reasons

why �rms may use �pre-committed�sources of funds (such as cash or credit lines) to manage their

liquidity needs. In principle, a �rm can use other sources of funding for long-term liquidity manage-

ment, such as future operating cash �ows or proceeds from future debt issuances. However, these

alternatives expose the �rm to additional risks because their availability depends directly on �rm

performance. Holmstrom and Tirole (1997, 1998), for example, show that relying on future issuance

of external claims is insu¢ cient to provide liquidity for �rms that face costly external �nancing.

Similarly, Acharya, Almeida, and Campello (2007) show that cash holdings dominate spare debt

capacity for �nancially constrained �rms that expect to have their �nancing needs concentrated in

states of the world where cash �ows are low. Notably, these models of liquidity insurance are silent

on the trade-o¤s between cash and credit lines.1

This paper attempts to �ll this gap in the liquidity management literature. Building on Holm-

strom and Tirole (1998) and Tirole (2006), we develop a model of the trade-o¤s �rms face when

choosing between holding cash and securing a credit line. The key insight of our model is that a

�rm�s exposure to aggregate risks � its �beta�� is a fundamental determinant of liquidity choices.1A recent paper by Bolton, Chen, and Wang (2009) introduces both cash and credit lines in a dynamic investment

framework with costly external �nance. In their model, the size of the credit line facility is given exogenously, thusthey do not analyze the ex ante trade-o¤ between cash and credit lines (see also DeMarzo and Fishman (2007)).

1

Page 4: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

The intuition for our main result is straightforward. In the presence of a liquidity premium (e.g.,

a low return on cash holdings), �rms �nd it costly to hold cash. Firms may instead manage their

liquidity needs using bank credit lines, which do not require them to hold liquid assets. Under a

credit line agreement, the bank provides the �rm with funds when the �rm faces a liquidity shortfall.

In exchange, the bank collects payments from the �rm in states of the world in which the �rm does

not need the funds under the line (e.g., commitment fees). The credit line can thus be seen as an

insurance contract. Provided that the bank can o¤er this insurance at �actuarially fair�terms, lines

of credit will dominate cash holdings in corporate liquidity management.

The drawback of credit lines is that banks may not be able to provide liquidity insurance for all

�rms in the economy at all times. Consider, for example, a situation in which a large fraction of

the corporate sector is hit by a liquidity shortfall. In this state of the world, banks might become

unable to guarantee liquidity since the demand for funds under the outstanding lines (drawdowns)

may exceed the supply of funds coming from healthy �rms. In other words, the ability of the

banking sector to meet corporate liquidity needs depends on the extent to which �rms are subject

to correlated (systematic) liquidity shocks. Aggregate risk thus creates a cost to credit lines.

We explore this trade-o¤ between aggregate risk and liquidity premia to derive optimal corporate

liquidity policy. We do this in an equilibrium model in which �rms are heterogeneous with respect

to their exposure to aggregate risks (�rms have di¤erent betas). We show that while low beta �rms

manage their liquidity through bank credit lines, high beta �rms optimally choose to hold cash,

despite the liquidity premium. Because the banking sector manages primarily idiosyncratic risk, it

can provide liquidity for low beta �rms even in bad states of the world. In equilibrium, low beta

�rms therefore face better contractual terms when initiating credit lines, demand more lines, and

hold less cash in equilibrium. On the �ip side, high beta �rms face worse contractual terms, demand

less lines, and hold more cash. This logic suggests that �rms�exposure to systematic risks increases

the demand for cash and reduces the demand for credit lines. In a similar fashion, when there is an

increase in aggregate risk there is greater aggregate reliance on cash relative to credit lines.

In addition to these basic results, the model generates a number of new insights on liquidity

management. These, in turn, motivate our empirical analysis. First, the model suggests that ex-

posure to risks that are systematic to the banking industry should a¤ect corporate liquidity policy.

In particular, �rms that are more sensitive to banking industry downturns should be more likely to

hold cash for liquidity management. Second, the trade-o¤ between cash and credit lines should be

more important for �rms that �nd it more costly to raise external capital. Third, the model implies

that the lines of credit should be more expensive for �rms with greater aggregate risk and in times

of higher aggregate volatility.

We test our model�s cross-sectional and time-series implications using data from the 1987�2008

2

Page 5: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

period.2 For the cross-sectional analysis, we use two alternative data sources to construct proxies for

the availability of credit lines. Our �rst sample is drawn from the LPC-DealScan database. These

data allow us to construct a large sample of credit line initiations. The LPC-DealScan data, however,

have two limitations. First, they are largely based on syndicated loans, thus biased towards large

deals (consequently large �rms). Second, they do not reveal the extent to which existing lines have

been used (drawdowns). To overcome these issues, we also use an alternative sample that contains

detailed information on the credit lines initiated and used by a random sample of 300 �rms between

1996 and 2003. These data are drawn from Su� (2009). Using both LPC-DealScan and Su��s data

sets, we measure the fraction of corporate liquidity that is provided by lines of credit as the ratio of

total credit lines to the sum of total credit lines plus cash. For short, we call this variable LC-to-Cash

ratio. While some �rms may have higher demand for total liquidity due to variables such as better

investment opportunities, the LC-to-Cash ratio isolates the relative usage of lines of credit versus

cash in corporate liquidity management.

Our main hypothesis states that a �rm�s exposure to aggregate risk should be negatively related

to its LC-to-Cash ratio. In the model, the relevant aggregate risk is the correlation of a �rm�s �-

nancing needs with those of other �rms in the economy. While this could suggest using a �cash �ow

beta,�we note that cash �ow-based measures are slow-moving and available only at low frequency.

Under the assumption that a �rm�s �nancing needs go up when its stock return falls, the relevant

beta is the traditional beta of the �rm with respect to the overall stock market. Accordingly, we em-

ploy a standard stock market-based beta as our baseline measure of risk exposure.3 For robustness,

however, we also use cash �ow-based betas. To test the prediction that a �rm�s exposure to banking

sector�s risk should in�uence the �rm�s liquidity policy, we measure �bank beta� as the beta of a

�rm�s returns with respect to the banking sector aggregate return.

Our market-based measures of beta are asset (i.e., unlevered) betas. While equity betas are

easy to compute using stock price data, they are mechanically related to leverage (high leverage

�rms will tend to have larger betas). Since greater reliance on credit lines will typically increase

the �rm�s leverage, the �mechanical� leverage e¤ect would then bias our estimates of the e¤ect of

betas on corporate liquidity management. To overcome this problem, we unlever equity betas in two

alternative ways. First, we back out and eliminate the leverage e¤ect using a Merton-KMV-type

model for �rm value. Second, we compute betas using data on �rm asset returns. Our data on

2To be precise, we use a panel dataset to test the model�s cross-sectional implications. Since most of the variationin our proxies for systematic risk exposure is cross-sectional in nature, we refer to this analysis as �cross-sectional�toclearly distinguish from the time-series analysis.

3 In addition, we use a �tail beta� that essentially uses data from the days with the 5% worst returns in the yearto compute beta (cf. Acharya, Pedersen, Philippon, and Richardson (2010)). This beta proxy captures the idea thata �rm�s exposure to systematic risks matters mostly on the downside (because a �rm may need liquidity when other�rms are likely to be in trouble).

3

Page 6: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

this alternative beta proxy come from Choi (2009), who computes bond and bank loan returns and

combines them with stock returns into an asset return measure that uses relative market values of

the di¤erent �nancial claims as weights. We also tease out the relative importance of systematic and

idiosyncratic risk for corporate liquidity policy. We do this by decomposing total asset risk on its

systematic and idiosyncratic components. The systematic component is estimated as squared asset

beta times the unlevered variance of market returns. The idiosyncratic component is equal to total

variance minus the systematic component.

We test the theory�s cross-sectional implications by relating systematic risk exposure to LC-to-

Cash ratios. In a nutshell, all of our tests lead to a similar conclusion: exposure to systematic risk

has a statistically and economically signi�cant impact on the fraction of corporate liquidity that is

provided by credit lines. Using the LPC-DealScan sample, for example, we �nd that an increase in

beta from 0:8 to 1:5 (this is less than a one-standard deviation change in beta) decreases a �rm�s

reliance on credit lines by 0:06 (approximately 15% of the standard deviation and 20% of the sample

average value of LC-to-Cash). We also �nd that the systematic component of asset variance has a

negative and signi�cant e¤ect on the LC-to-Cash ratio, while the idiosyncratic component is posi-

tively related to this ratio. These �ndings support our theory�s prediction that �rms use credit lines

to manage idiosyncratic risk, but they are increasingly likely to use cash as systematic risk exposure

increases. Notably, the inferences we draw hold across both the larger LPC-DealScan dataset and

the smaller, more detailed data constructed by Su� (both for total and unused credit lines).

The negative relation between systematic risk exposure and LC-to-Cash holds for all di¤erent

proxies of betas that we employ, including Choi�s (2009) asset-return based betas, betas that are

unlevered using net rather than gross debt (to account for a possible e¤ect of cash on asset betas),

equity (levered) betas, and cash �ow-based betas. Importantly, the results also hold for �bank be-

tas�(suggesting that �rms that are more sensitive to banking industry downturns are more likely to

hold cash for liquidity management) and �tail betas�(suggesting that a �rm�s sensitivity to market

downturns a¤ects corporate liquidity policy). These estimates agree with our theory and imply a

strong economic relation between exposure to aggregate risk and liquidity management.

In additional tests, we sort �rms according to observable proxies of �nancing constraints to study

whether the e¤ect of beta on LC-to-Cash is driven by �rms that are likely to be constrained. As

predicted by our model, the relation between beta and the use of credit lines only holds in samples

of likely constrained �rms (e.g., across small and low payout �rms). Our model also suggests that

�rms with high aggregate risk exposure hold more cash because it is more costly for banks to provide

them with liquidity. To investigate this channel, we study the relation between �rms�beta and the

spreads that they commit to pay on bank lines of credit. Indeed, we �nd that high beta �rms pay

signi�cantly higher spreads when opening and drawing on their credit lines.

4

Page 7: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Finally, we examine our model�s time-series implications. Our macro time-series tests gauge ag-

gregate risk using VIX, the implied volatility of the stock market index returns from options data.

VIX captures both aggregate volatility as well as the �nancial sector�s appetite to bear that risk. In

addition, we examine whether expected volatility in the banking sector drives time-series variation

in corporate liquidity policy. Since there is no available historical data on implied volatility for the

banking sector, we construct expected banking sector volatility using a GARCH model. We call this

variable Bank VIX.

Controlling for real GDP growth and �ight-to-quality e¤ects (see Gatev and Strahan (2005)), we

�nd that an increase in VIX and/or Bank VIX reduces credit line initiations and raises �rms�cash

reserves (Figure 4 provides a visual illustration). The maturity of credit lines shrinks as aggregate

volatility rises, and new credit lines become more expensive in those times (see Figure 5). We con-

�rm that these e¤ects are not due to an overall increase in the cost of debt by showing that �rms�

debt issuances are not a¤ected by VIX. In other words, the negative impact of VIX on new debt

operates through availability of lines of credit. These results point out that an increase in aggregate

risk in the economy is an important limitation of bank-provided liquidity insurance to �rms.

Our work has strong connections with recent literature that discusses �rms� liquidity choices

and it is important that we highlight our contributions. Su� (2009) examines the choice between

cash and credit lines and shows that �rms that are at risk of losing access to those facilities due

to a covenant violation and �rms with more cash �ow volatility are less likely to use credit lines.

Campello, Giambona, Graham, and Harvey (2010) study survey data collected during the �nancial

crisis and describe how cash �ows and cash stocks in�uence �rms�demand for credit lines. The

authors show that the relation between cash �ows and lines of credit is modulated by the level of

cash savings: pro�table �rm are less (more) likely to use credit lines when they have more (less)

cash. Looking at international survey data, Lins, Servaes, and Tufano (2010) document that cash

and credit lines are used for di¤erent purposes. Managers say that non-operational cash is used

to guard against future cash �ow shocks in bad times, while credit lines are used to fund business

opportunities that arise in good times. Disatnik, Duchin, and Schmidt (2010) investigate the role of

hedging in shaping �rms�liquidity preferences. The authors point to the importance of hedging in

reducing �rms�precautionary demand for cash and increasing preference towards credit lines.

While our work relates to this growing empirical literature, we are the �rst to advance and test

a full-�edged theory explaining how corporate exposure to aggregate risk drives the choice between

cash and credit lines. We also provide a novel assessment of the importance of �nancial intermediary

risk to the choice between cash and lines. In fact, papers in the cash�credit line choice generally

abstract from connections between the macroeconomy, banks, and �rms when examining liquidity

5

Page 8: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

management.4 We believe our paper represents a step forward in establishing a theoretical framework

describing these connections and in showing how they operate. Understanding and characterizing

these links should be of interest for future research, especially around important episodes such as

�nancial crises.

The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we develop our model and derive its em-

pirical implications. We present the empirical tests in Section 3. Section 4 o¤ers concluding remarks.

2 Model

Our model is based on Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) and Tirole (2006), who consider the role of

aggregate risk in a¤ecting corporate liquidity policy. We introduce �rm heterogeneity in their frame-

work to analyze the trade-o¤s between cash and credit lines.

The economy has a unit mass of �rms. Each �rm has access to an investment project that requires

�xed investment I at date 0.5 The investment opportunity also requires an additional investment at

date 1, of uncertain size. This additional investment represents the �rms�liquidity need at date 1. We

assume that the date-1 investment need can be either equal to �, with probability �, or 0, with prob-

ability (1��). There is no discounting and everyone is risk-neutral, so that the discount factor is one.Firms are symmetric in all aspects, with one important exception. They di¤er in the extent to

which their liquidity shocks are correlated with each other. A fraction � of the �rms has perfectly

correlated liquidity shocks; that is, they all either have a date-1 investment need, or not. We call

these �rms systematic �rms. The other fraction of �rms (1� �) has independent investment needs;that is, the probability that a �rm needs � is independent of whether other �rms need � or 0. These

are the non-systematic �rms. We can think of this set up as one in which an aggregate state realizes

�rst. The realized state then determines whether or not systematic �rms have liquidity shocks.

We refer to states as follows. We let the aggregate state in which systematic �rms have a liquidity

shock be denoted by ��. Similarly, (1� ��) is the state in which systematic �rms have no liquidity

demand. After the realization of this aggregate state, non-systematic �rms learn whether they have

liquidity shocks. The state in which non-systematic �rms do get a shock is denoted as � and the

other state as (1��). Note that the likelihood of both � and �� states is �. In other words, to avoidadditional notation, we denote states by their probability, but single out the state in which systematic

�rms are all hit by a liquidity shock with the superscript �. The set up is summarized in Figure 1.

� Figure 1 about here �4Exceptions are papers written on the 2008-9 crisis, such as Campello, Giambona, Graham, and Harvey (2010)

and Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010).5 In Tirole (2006), the �rm has date-0 wealth A but this plays no signi�cant role in our model. Hence, we have set

it equal to zero.

6

Page 9: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

A �rm will only continue its date-0 investment until date 2 if it can meet the date-1 liquidity

need. If the liquidity need is not met, then the �rm is liquidated and the project produces a cash

�ow equal to zero. If the �rm continues, the investment produces a date-2 cash �ow R which obtains

with probability p. With probability 1 � p, the investment produces nothing. The probability of

success depends on the input of speci�c human capital by the �rms�managers. If the managers

exert high e¤ort, the probability of success is equal to pG. Otherwise, the probability is pB, but the

managers consume a private bene�t equal to B. While the cash �ow R is veri�able, the managerial

e¤ort and the private bene�t are not veri�able and contractible. Because of the moral hazard due

this private bene�t, managers must keep a high enough stake in the project to be induced to exert

e¤ort. We assume that the investment is negative NPV if the managers do not exert e¤ort, implying

the following incentive constraint:

pGRM � pBRM +B, or (1)

RM � B

�p,

where RM is the managers� compensation and �p = pG � pB. This moral hazard problem im-

plies that the �rms�cash �ows cannot be pledged in their entirety to outside investors. Following

Holmstrom and Tirole, we de�ne:

�0 � pG(R�B

�p) < �1 � pGR. (2)

The parameter �0 represents the investment�s pledgeable income, and �1 its total expected payo¤.

In addition, we assume that the project can be partially liquidated at date 1. Speci�cally, a �rm

can choose to continue only a fraction x < 1 of its investment project, in which case (in its liquidity

shock state, � or ��) it requires a date-1 investment of x�. It then produces total expected cash �ow

equal to x�1, and pledgeable income equal to x�0. In other words, the project can be linearly scaled

down at date 1.

We make the following assumption:

�0 < � < �1. (3)

The assumption that � < �1 implies that the e¢ cient level of x is xFB = 1. However, the �rm�s

pledgeable income is lower than the liquidity shock. This might force the �rm to liquidate some of its

projects and thus have x� < 1 in equilibrium. In particular, in the absence of liquidity management

we would have x� = 0 (since x� > x�0 for all positive x). In particular, �rms have a shortfall equal

to x(�� �0) when hit by a liquidity shock. For each x, they can raise x�0 in the market at date-1.

As in Holmstrom and Tirole, we assume that the �rm can fully dilute the date-0 investors at date-1.

7

Page 10: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

In other words, the �rm can issue securities that are senior to the date-0 claim to �nance a part of

the required investment x� (alternatively, we can assume e¢ cient renegotiation of the date-0 claim).

Finally, we assume that even when x = 1, each project produces enough pledgeable income to

�nance the initial investment I, and the date-1 investment �:

I < (1� �)�0 + �(�0 � �). (4)

In particular, notice that this implies that (1� �)�0 > �(�� �0).

2.1 Solution using credit lines

We assume that the economy has a single, large intermediary who will manage liquidity for all �rms

(�the bank�) by o¤ering lines of credit. The credit line works as follows. The �rm commits to

making a payment to the bank in states of the world in which liquidity is not needed. We denote

this payment (�commitment fee�) by y. In return, the bank commits to lending to the �rm at a

pre-speci�ed interest rate, up to a maximum limit. We denote the maximum size of the line by w.

In addition, the bank lends enough money (I) to the �rms at date 0 so that they can start their

projects, in exchange for a promised date-2 debt payment D.

To �x ideas, let us imagine for now that �rms have zero cash holdings. In the next section we

will allow �rms to both hold cash, and also open bank credit lines.

In order for the credit line to allow �rms to invest up to amount x in state �, it must be that:

w(x) � x(�� �0). (5)

In return, in state (1��), the �nancial intermediary can receive up to the �rm�s pledgeable income,either through the date-1 commitment fee y, or through the date-2 payment D. We thus have the

budget constraint:

y + pGD � �0. (6)

The intermediary�s break even constraint is:

I + �x(�� �0) � (1� �)�0. (7)

Finally, the �rm�s payo¤ is:

U(x) = (1� �)�1 + �(�1 � �)x� I. (8)

Given assumption (4), equation (7) will be satis�ed by x = 1, and thus the credit line allows �rms

to achieve the �rst-best investment policy.

The potential problem with the credit line is adequacy of bank liquidity. To provide liquidity for

the entire corporate sector, the intermediary must have enough available funds in all states of the

8

Page 11: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

world. Since a fraction � of �rms will always demand liquidity in the same state, it is possible that

the intermediary will run out of funds in the bad aggregate state. In order to see this, notice that

in order obtain x = 1 in state ��, the following inequality must be obeyed:

(1� �)(1� �)�0 � [� + (1� �)�] (�� �0). (9)

The left-hand side represents the total pledgeable income that the intermediary has in that state,

coming from the non-systematic �rms that do not have liquidity needs. The right-hand side rep-

resents the economy�s total liquidity needs, from the systematic �rms and from the fraction of

non-systematic �rms that have liquidity needs. Clearly, from (4) there will be a �max > 0, such that

this condition is met for all � < �max. This leads to an intuitive result:

Proposition 1 The intermediary solution with lines of credit achieves the �rst-best investment pol-

icy if and only if systematic risk is su¢ ciently low (� < �max), where �max is given by the condition:

�max =�0 � ��(1� �)�: (10)

2.2 The choice between cash and credit lines

We now allow �rms to hold both cash and open credit lines, and analyze the properties of the

equilibria that obtain for di¤erent parameter values. Analyzing this trade-o¤ constitutes the most

important and novel contribution of our paper.

2.2.1 Firms�optimization problem

In order to characterize the di¤erent equilibria, we start by introducing some notation. We let L�

(alternatively, L1��) represent the liquidity demand by systematic (non-systematic) �rms. Similarly,

x� (x1��) represents the investment level that systematic (non-systematic) �rms can achieve in equi-

librium (under their preferred liquidity policy). In addition, the credit line contracts that are o¤ered

by the bank can also di¤er across �rm types. That is, we assume that a �rm�s type is observable

by the bank at the time of contracting. This assumption implies that the credit line contract is also

indexed by �rm type; speci�cally, (D�; w�; y�) represents the contract o¤ered to systematic �rms

and (D1��; w1��; y1��) represents the contract o¤ered to non-systematic �rms. For now, we assume

that the bank cannot itself carry liquid funds and explain later why this is in fact the equilibrium

outcome in the model.

Firms will optimize their payo¤ subject to the constraint that they must be able to �nance the

initial investment I, and the continuation investment x. In addition, the bank must break even. For

9

Page 12: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

each �rm type i = (�; 1� �), the relevant constraints can be written as:

wi + Li = xi(�� �0) (11)

I + qLi + �wi = (1� �)(Li + yi + pGDi)

yi + pGDi � �0.

The �rst equation ensures that the �rm can �nance the continuation investment level xi, given its

liquidity policy (wi; Li). The second equation is the bank break-even constraint. The bank provides

�nancing for the initial investment and the liquid holdings qLi, and in addition provides �nancing

through the credit line in state � (equal to wi). In exchange, the bank receives the sum of the

�rm�s liquid holdings, the credit line commitment fee, and the date-2 debt payment Di. The third

inequality guarantees that the �rm has enough pledgeable income to make the payment yi + pGDi

in the state when it is not hit by the liquidity shock.

In addition to the break-even constraint, the bank must have enough liquidity to honor its credit

line commitments, in both aggregate states. As explained above, this constraint can bind in state

��, in which all systematic �rms may demand liquidity. Each systematic �rm demands liquidity

equal to x�(�� �0)�L�, and there is a mass � of such �rms. In addition, non-systematic �rms thatdo not have an investment need demand liquidity equal to x1��(�� �0)� L1��. There are (1� �)�such �rms. To honor its credit lines, the bank can draw on the liquidity provided by the fraction of

non-systematic �rms that does not need liquidity, a mass equal to (1��)(1��). The bank receives apayment equal to L1��+y1��+pGD1�� from each of them, a payment that cannot exceed L1��+�0.

Thus, the bank�s liquidity constraint requires that:

�[x�(�� �0)� L�] + (1� �)�[x1��(�� �0)� L1��] � (1� �)(1� �)[L1�� + �0]. (12)

As will become clear below, this inequality will impose a constraint on the maximum size of the

credit line that is available to systematic �rms. For now, we write this constraint as follows:

w� � wmax. (13)

We can collapse the constraints in (11) into a single constraint, and thus write the �rm�s opti-

mization problem as follows:

maxxi,Li

U i = (1� �)�1 + �(�1 � �)xi � (q � 1)Li � I s.t. (14)

I + (q � 1)Li + �xi� � (1� �)�0 + �xi�0w� � wmax

This optimization problem determines �rms�optimal cash holdings and continuation investment,

which we write as a function of the liquidity premium, Li(q) and xi(q). In equilibrium, the total

10

Page 13: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

demand from cash coming from systematic and non-systematic �rms cannot exceed the supply of

liquid funds:

�L�(q) + (1� �)L1��(q) � Ls. (15)

This equilibrium condition determines the cost of holding cash, q. We denote the equilibrium price

by q�.

2.2.2 Optimal �rm policies

The �rst point to notice is that non-systematic �rms will never �nd it optimal to hold cash. In the

optimization problem (14), �rms�payo¤s decrease with cash holdings Li if q� > 1, and they are

independent of Li if q� = 1. Thus, the only situation in which a �rm might �nd it optimal to hold

cash is when the constraint x�(� � �0) � L� � wmax is binding. But this constraint can only bind

for systematic �rms.

Notice also that if Li = 0 the solution of the optimization problem (14) is xi = 1 (the e¢ cient

investment policy). Thus, non-systematic �rms always invest optimally, x1�� = 1.

Given that non-systematic �rms use credit lines to manage liquidity and invest optimally, we can

rewrite constraint (12) in simpler form as:

�[x�(�� �0)� L�] + (1� �)�(�� �0) � (1� �)(1� �)�0, or (16)

x�(�� �0)� L� � (1� �)(�0 � ��)�

� wmax.

Thus, the maximum size of the credit line for systematic �rms is wmax = (1��)(�0���)� . The term

(1� �)(�0���) represents the total amount of excess liquidity that is available from non-systematic

�rms in state ��. By equation (4), this is positive. The bank can then allocate this excess liquidity

to the fraction � of �rms that are systematic.

Lemma 1 states the optimal policy of systematic �rms, which we prove in the appendix.

Lemma 1 Investment policy of systematic �rms, x�, depends upon the liquidity premium, q, as

follows:

1. If �� �0 � wmax, then x�(q) = 1 for all q.

2. If �� �0 > wmax, de�ne two threshold values of q, q1 and q2 as follows:

q1 = 1 +�0 � ��� I�� �0 � wmax

, (17)

q2 = 1 +�(�1 � �)�� �0

. (18)

11

Page 14: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Then, x� satis�es:

x�(q) = 1 if q � min(q1; q2) (19)

=(1� �)�0 � I + (q � 1)wmax

(�+ q � 1)(�� �0)if q2 � q > q1

2 [0; 1] (indi¤erence over entire range) if q1 > q = q2

= 0 if q > q2.

In words, systematic �rms will invest e¢ ciently if their total liquidity demand (� � �0) can be

satis�ed by credit lines (of maximum size wmax), or if the cost of holding cash q is low enough. If

the maximum available credit line is low, and the cost of carrying cash is high, then systematic �rms

will optimally reduce their optimal continuation investment (x� < 1). If the cost of carrying cash is

high enough, then systematic �rms may need to fully liquidate their projects (x� = 0).

Given the optimal investment in Lemma 1, the demand for cash is given by L�(q) = 0 if ���0 �wmax, and by the following condition

L�(x�) = x�(�� �0)� wmax, (20)

when �� �0 > wmax, for the optimal x�(q) in Lemma 1.

2.2.3 Equilibria

The particular equilibrium that obtains in the model will depend on the fraction of systematic �rms

in the economy (�), and the supply of liquid funds (Ls).

First, notice that if � � �0 � wmax (that is, if the fraction of systematic �rms in the economy

is small, (� � �max), then there is no cash demand and the equilibrium liquidity premium is zero

(q� = 1). Firms use credit lines to manage liquidity and they invest e¢ ciently (x� = x1�� = 1).

On the �ip side, if �� �0 > wmax (that is, � > �max), then systematic �rms will need to use cash

in equilibrium. Equilibrium requires that the demand for cash does not exceed supply:

�L�(q) = �[x�(q)(�� �0)� wmax] � Ls: (21)

Given this equilibrium condition, we can �nd the minimum level of liquidity supply Ls, such that

systematic �rms can sustain an e¢ cient investment policy, x�(q) = 1. This is given by:

�[(�� �0)� wmax] = Ls1(�): (22)

If Ls � Ls1(�), then systematic �rms invest e¢ ciently, x� = 1, demand a credit line equal to

wmax, and have cash holdings equal to L� = (�� �0)� wmax. The equilibrium liquidity premium is

zero, q� = 1.

12

Page 15: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

When Ls drops below Ls1(�), then the cash demand by systematic �rms must fall to make it

compatible with supply. This is accomplished by an increase in the liquidity premium that reduces

cash demand. In equilibrium, we have q� > 1, x�(q�) < 1, and equation (21) holding with equality

(such that the demand for cash equals the reduced supply):6

�[x�(q�)(�� �0)� wmax] = Ls. (23)

2.3 Summary of results

We summarize the model�s results in form of the following detailed proposition:

Proposition 2 When �rms can choose between both cash holdings and bank-provided lines of credit,

the following equilibria are possible depending on the extent of aggregate risk and the supply of liquid

assets in the economy:

1. If the amount of systematic risk in the economy is low (� � �max), where �max is as given

in Proposition 1, then all �rms can use credit lines to manage their liquidity. They invest

e¢ ciently and credit line contracts are independent of �rms�exposure to systematic risk.

2. If the amount of systematic risk in the economy is high (� > �max), then �rms that have

more exposure to systematic risk will be more likely to hold cash (relative to credit lines) in

their liquidity management. The bank�s liquidity constraint requires that credit line contracts

discriminate between idiosyncratic and systematic risk. There are two sub-cases to consider,

which vary according to the supply of liquid assets in the economy (see Figure 2 for the case

when q1 < q2):

(a) If the supply of liquid assets is higher than a minimum cuto¤ Ls1(�) de�ned by Ls1(�) =

�[(� � �0) � wmax(�)] and wmax(�) = (1��)(�0���)� , then in equilibrium all �rms invest

e¢ ciently (irrespective of their exposure to systematic risk), and there is no liquidity

premium. Firms use both cash and credit lines to manage systematic risk, and they use

credit lines to manage idiosyncratic risk.

(b) If the supply of liquid assets is lower than Ls1(�), then systematic liquidity risk generates

a liquidity premium and investment distortions. Firms that have greater exposure to

systematic risk hold more cash and less credit lines, and under-invest in the event of a

liquidity shock.

6There are two cases to consider here, depending on whether q1 is higher or lower than q2. Please see the appendixfor deatils.

13

Page 16: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

� Figure 2 about here �

Notice that the maximum credit line that is available to each systematic �rm, wmax(�), is de-

creasing in �. The aggregate demand for credit lines from systematic �rms is given by �wmax(�) =

(1� �)(�0 � ��), which is also decreasing in �. It follows that the aggregate demand for credit linesdecreases when the fraction of systematic �rms in the economy goes up.

In all of these situations, there is no role for cash held inside the intermediary. In equilibrium,

cash is held only to manage systematic risk. Thus, �rms gain no diversi�cation bene�ts by deposit-

ing the cash with the intermediary (they all need the cash in the same state of the world, and so

the intermediary must carry the same amount of cash that the �rms do). Firms would bene�t from

diversi�cation when managing non-systematic risk, but for that they are always better o¤ using the

credit line (which does not involve a liquidity premium).

2.4 Empirical implications

The model generates the following implications, which we examine in the next section.

1. A �rm�s exposure to systematic risk is an important determinant of whether it manages its

future liquidity needs through cash reserves or bank-provided lines of credit. In particular, an

increase in a �rm�s exposure to aggregate risk should increase its propensity to use cash for

corporate liquidity management, relative to credit lines. We test this prediction by relating

the fraction of total corporate liquidity that is held in the form of credit lines to proxies for a

�rm�s systematic risk exposure (e.g., beta).

2. A �rm�s exposure to risks that are systematic to the banking industry is particularly important

for the determination of its liquidity policy. In the model, bank systematic risk has a one-to-one

relation with �rm systematic risk, given that there is only one source of risk in the economy

(�rms�liquidity shock). However, one might imagine that in reality banks face other sources

of systematic risk (coming, for example, from consumers�liquidity demand) and that �rms are

di¤erentially exposed to such risks. Accordingly, a ��rm-bank asset beta� should also drive

corporate liquidity policy. Firms that are more sensitive to banking industry downturns should

be more likely to hold cash for liquidity management.

3. The trade-o¤ between cash and credit lines is more important for �rms that �nd it more costly

to raise external capital. In the absence of �nancing constraints, there is no role for corporate

liquidity policy, thus the choice between cash and credit lines becomes irrelevant. We test this

model implication by sorting �rms according to observable proxies for �nancing constraints,

14

Page 17: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

and examining whether the e¤ect of systematic risk exposure on the choice between cash and

credit lines is driven by �rms that are likely to be �nancially constrained.

4. Firms with higher systematic risk exposure should face worse contractual terms when raising

bank credit lines. In the model, if the amount of systematic risk in the economy is high, then

the bank�s liquidity constraint requires that credit line contracts discriminate between idiosyn-

cratic and systematic risk. In particular, systematic �rms should face worse contractual terms

since they are the ones that drive the bank�s liquidity constraint. We test this implication by

relating asset beta to credit spreads, after controlling for �rm characteristics and other credit

line contractual terms.

5. An increase in the amount of systematic risk in the economy increases �rms�reliance on cash

and reduces their reliance on credit lines for liquidity management. The model shows that when

economy-wide aggregate risk is low, �rms can manage their liquidity using only credit lines

because the banking sector can provide them at actuarially fair terms.7 When aggregate risk

increases beyond a certain level, �rms must shift away from credit lines and towards cash so

that the banking sector�s liquidity constraint is satis�ed. In addition, the greater is the amount

of systematic risk in the economy, the lower is the amount of liquidity that is provided by bank

credit lines.8 We test this implication by examining how aggregate cash holdings and credit

line initiations change with aggregate risk. We measure aggregate risk using VIX, the implied

volatility of the stock market index returns from options data. In addition, and similarly to

Implication 2 above, we also examine whether �Bank VIX�, a measure we compute of the ex-

pected volatility in the banking sector, drives time-series variation in corporate liquidity policy.

6. An increase in the amount of systematic risk in the economy worsens �rms�contractual terms

when raising bank credit lines. In the model, an increase in the cost of credit lines is the

mechanism that induces �rms to shift into cash for their liquidity management. Thus, when

aggregate risk increases, credit line contractual terms worsen.9 We test this implication by ex-

amining how credit line spreads and maturities change with changes in economy-wide (VIX ),

and banking sector (Bank VIX ) aggregate risk.10

7Recall that in the model, economy-wide aggregate risk is captured by the fraction of �rms that are systematic, �.8As explained above, the aggregate demand for credit lines is a decreasing function of �.9Speci�cally, as the demand for cash increases the liquidity premium goes up. Thus, credit line terms must worsen

in equilibrium.10Our model has the additional empirical implication that the liquidity risk premium is higher when there is an

economic downturn since in such times there is greater aggregate risk and lines of credit become more expensive. Thisis similar to the result of Eisfeldt and Rampini (2009), but in their model, the e¤ect arises from the fact that �rms�cash �ows are lower in economic downturns and they are less naturally hedged against future liquidity needs.

15

Page 18: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

3 Empirical tests

3.1 Sample selection criteria

The main implication of our model is that �rms are more likely to use cash in their liquidity man-

agement if they are subject to a greater amount of systematic risk. We use two alternative sources

to construct our line of credit data. Our �rst sample (which we call LPC Sample) is drawn from

LPC-DealScan. These data allow us to construct a large sample of credit line initiations. We note,

however, that the LPC-DealScan data have two potential drawbacks. First, they are mostly based

on syndicated loans, thus are potentially biased towards large deals and consequently towards large

�rms. Second, they do not allow us to measure line of credit drawdowns (the fraction of existing

lines that has been used in the past). To overcome these issues, we also construct an alternative

sample that contains detailed information on the credit lines initiated and used by a random sample

of 300 COMPUSTAT �rms. These data are provided by Amir Su� on his website and were used on

Su� (2009). We call this sample Random Sample. Using these data reduces the sample size for our

tests. In particular, since this sample only contains seven years (1996-2003), in our time-series tests

we use only LPC sample. We regard these two samples as providing complementary information on

the usage of credit lines for the purposes of this paper. In addition, this allows us to document that

several previously reported patterns prevail in both samples.

To construct the LPC Sample, we start from a sample of loans in LPC-DealScan in the period

of 1987 to 2008 for which we can obtain the �rm identi�er gvkey (which we later use to match to

COMPUSTAT).11 We drop utilities, quasi-public and �nancial �rms from the sample (SIC codes

greater than 5999 and lower than 7000, greater than 4899 and lower than 5000, and greater than

8999). We consider only short term and long term credit lines, which are de�ned as those that have

the LPC �eld �loantype�equal to �364-day Facility,��Revolver/Line < 1 Yr,��Revolver/Line >=

1 Yr,�or �Revolver/Line.�We drop loans that appear to be repeated (same gvkey and loan_id). In

some cases, the same �rm has more than one credit line initiation in the same quarter. In these cases,

we sum the facility amounts (the total available credit in each line) for each �rm-quarter, and average

the other variables using the facility amount as weights. We let LCi;t denote the total value of credit

lines initiated in quarter t by �rm i, and let Maturityi;t denote the average maturity of these lines

in quarters. We also collect data on the spreads paid by �rms when raising these lines. All-in drawn

spread captures the total (fees and interests) annual spread paid over LIBOR for each dollar drawn

down from the facility. Undrawn spread is the total (fees and interest) annual spread over LIBOR,

for each dollar available under commitment. Maturity is the maturity of the credit line in quarters

from initiation. This sample is then matched to COMPUSTAT annual data, as described below.11We use several procedures to obtain gvkeys, including a �le provided by Michael Roberts, which was used in Chava

and Roberts (2008), �rm tickers (which are available in LPC), and manual matching using �rm names.

16

Page 19: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

To construct the Random Sample, we start from the sample used in Su� (2009), which contains

1,908 �rm-years (300 �rms) between 1996 and 2003. Su��s data set includes information on the

total credit line facilities available to �rm j in the random sample during an year t between 1996 to

2003 (Total Linej;t), and the amount of credit in these lines that is still available to �rm j in year t

(Unused Linej;t). We use this information to construct our proxies for credit line usage. These data

are then matched to annual data from COMPUSTAT.

Finally, we merge these data with data on �rm-level betas and stock-price based volatility mea-

sures. These data are described in more detail below.

3.2 Variable de�nitions

Our tests combine data that comes from multiple sources. It is useful to explain in detail how we

construct our variables.

3.2.1 COMPUSTAT variables

We follow Su� (2009) in the de�nitions of the variables that we use for our credit line tests. We

use a book asset measure that deducts the amount of cash holdings, that is, �rm Assets are de�ned

as at � che. The other COMPUSTAT-based variables that we examine in our tests are de�ned as

follows (in terms of annual COMPUSTAT �elds). Cash is given by che. Tangibility is equal to ppent

scaled by assets. Size is de�ned as the log of assets. Q is de�ned as a cash-adjusted, market-to-book

asset ratio, (Assets + prcc_fc�sho � ceq)/Assets.12 NetWorth is de�ned as (ceq � che)/Assets.

Pro�tability is the ratio of EBITDA over assets. Age is measured as the di¤erence between the

current year and the �rst year in which the �rm appeared in COMPUSTAT. Industry sales volatility

(IndSaleVol) is the (3-digit SIC) industry median value of the within-year standard deviation of

quarterly changes in �rm sales (saleq minus its lagged value) scaled by the average asset value (atq)

in the year. Pro�t volatility (Pro�tVol) is the �rm-level standard deviation of annual changes in the

level of EBITDA, calculated using four lags, and scaled by average assets in the lagged period. We

winsorize all COMPUSTAT variables at the 5th and 95th percentiles.

3.2.2 Line of credit data

When using Random Sample, we measure the fraction of total corporate liquidity that is provided

by credit lines for �rm i in year t using both total and unused credit lines:

Total LC-to-Cashi;t =Total Linei;t

Total Linei;t + Cashi;t, (24)

12Su� (2009) also deducts deferred taxes from the numerator. We excluded deferred taxes from this calculationbecause including it causes a signi�cant drop in the number of observations when using sample B.

17

Page 20: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Unused LC-to-Cashi;t =Unused Linei;t

Unused Linei;t + Cashi;t. (25)

As discussed by Su�, while some �rms may have higher demand for total liquidity due to better

investment opportunities, these LC-to-Cash ratios should isolate the relative usage of lines of credit

versus cash in corporate liquidity management.

When using LPC Sample, we construct a proxy for line of credit usage in the following way.

For each �rm-quarter, we measure credit line availability at date t by summing all existing credit

lines that have not yet matured. This calculation assumes that LCs remain open until they mature.

Speci�cally, we de�ne our measure of line of credit availability for each �rm-quarter (j; s) as:

Total LCj;s =Xt�s

LCj;t�(Maturityj;t � s� t), (26)

where �(:) represents the indicator function, and the variables LC and Maturity are de�ned above.

We convert these �rm-quarter measures into �rm-year measures by computing the average value of

Total LC in each year.

We then measure the fraction of corporate liquidity that is provided by investment-related lines

of credit for �rm j in quarter s using the following variable:

LC-to-Cashj;t =Total LCj;t

Total LCj;t + Cashj;t. (27)

This ratio is closely related to the Total LC-to-Cash ratio of equation (24).

In addition, to examine the time-series impact of systematic risk on liquidity management we

construct aggregate changes in credit lines and cash as follows:

LC Initiationt =

Pj LCj;tPj atj;t

; (28)

Change in Casht =

Pj(Cashj;t � Cashj;t�1)P

j atj;t:

These ratios capture the economy�s total demand for cash and credit lines in a given year, scaled

by total assets.

3.2.3 Data on betas and variances

Wemeasure �rms�exposure to systematic risk using asset (unlevered) betas.13 While equity betas are

easy to compute using stock price data, they are mechanically related to leverage: high leverage �rms

will tend to have larger betas. Because greater reliance on credit lines will typically increase the �rm�s

leverage, the leverage e¤ect would then bias our estimates of the e¤ect of betas on corporate liquidity

management. Nonetheless, we also present results using standard equity betas (Beta Equity).

13Similar to the COMPUSTAT data items, all measures of beta described below are winsorized at a 5% level.

18

Page 21: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

We unlever equity betas in two alternative ways. The simplest way to unlever betas is to use

a model that backs out the �mechanical�e¤ect of leverage, using for example a Merton-KMV type

model for �rm value. Our �rst set of betas is computed using such a model, starting from yearly

equity betas that are estimated using the past 12 monthly stock returns for each �rm (using CRSP

data). We call the set of betas that we obtain using this method Beta KMV. We also compute a

measure of total asset volatility, which is used as a control in some of the regressions below. This

measure (denoted Var KMV ) is estimated yearly using the past 12 monthly stock returns and the

KMV-Merton model. The appendix details the procedure that we used to compute this set of asset

betas and volatilities.

The second way to unlever betas and variances is to directly compute data on �rm asset re-

turns. The data we use come from Choi (2009). Choi computes bond and bank loan returns using

several data sources and then combines them with stock returns into an asset return measure that

uses relative market values of the di¤erent �nancial claims as weights.14 The �rm-level asset return

measure is then used to compute annual betas against the aggregate equity market. We call this

beta measure Beta Asset, and the associated return variance measure Var Asset. Given the stricter

requirements (including some proprietary information), these data are only available for a subset of

our �rms. Because of data availability, we use Beta KMV as our benchmark measure of beta, but

we verify that the results are robust to the use of this alternative unlevering method.

One potential concern with theses beta measures is that they may be mechanically in�uenced

by a �rm�s cash holdings. Since corporate cash holdings are typically held in the form of riskless

securities, high cash �rms could have lower asset betas. Notice that this possibility would make it

less likely for us to �nd a positive relation between asset betas and cash. However, we also verify

whether this e¤ect has a signi�cant bearing on our results by computing KMV-type asset betas that

are unlevered using net debt (e.g., debt minus cash) rather than gross debt. We call this variable Beta

Cash, which is computed at the level of the industry to further mitigate endogeneity. Speci�cally,

we measure Beta Cash as the median cash-adjusted asset beta in the �rm�s 3-digit SIC industry.

We also compute a �rm�s �bank beta� (which we call Beta Bank) to test the model�s implica-

tion that a �rm�s exposure to banking sector�s risks should in�uence the �rm�s liquidity policy. We

compute this beta by unlevering the �rm�s equity beta relative to an index of bank stock returns,

which is computed using a value-weighted average of the stock returns of all banks that are present

in the LPC-DealScan database. We use the LPC banks to compute the aggregate bank stock return

to ensure that our measure of the banking sector�s risk captures a risk that is relevant for the �rms

in our sample. This beta is unlevered using the same procedure to compute Beta KMV.

In the model, a �rm�s exposure to systematic risks matters mostly on the downside (because a

14We refer the reader to Choi�s original paper for further details on the construction of Beta Asset.

19

Page 22: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

�rm may need liquidity when other �rms are likely to be in trouble). To capture a �rm�s exposure to

large negative shocks, we follow Acharya, Pedersen, Philippon, and Richardson (2010) and compute

the �rm�s Tail Beta. The �rm�s tail beta is de�ned as the ratio of Marginal Expected Shortfall (MES)

of a �rm, divided by Expected Shortfall (ES) of the market, where MES is the average percentage

loss su¤ered by a �rm on days when the CRSP value-weighted market return is in its worst 5% days

in the previous year, and ES is the average percentage loss su¤ered by the market on those same

days. MES is a common risk measure used by �rms for enterprise-wide risk aggregation. This beta

is unlevered using an identical procedure used to compute Beta KMV and Beta Bank.

All of the betas described above are computed using market prices. As discussed in the intro-

duction, using market data is desirable because of their high frequency, and because they also re�ect

a �rm�s �nancing capacity that is tied to its long-run prospects. However, the model�s argument

is based on the correlation between a �rm�s liquidity needs, and the liquidity need for the overall

economy (which a¤ects the banking sector�s ability to provide liquidity). While market-based betas

should capture this correlation, it is desirable to verify whether a beta that is based more directly

on cash �ows and �nancing needs also contains information about �rm�s choices between cash and

credit lines. In order to do this, we compute to alternative beta proxies. First, we compute a �rm�s

�nancing gap beta (Beta Gap) in the following way. In each year, we compute a �rm�s �nancing gap

at the level of the 3-digit SIC industry by taking the di¤erence between total industry investment

and total industry cash �ow, scaled by assets (at).15 Then we compute the beta of the �rm�s �nanc-

ing gap with respect to the aggregate �nancing gap (the di¤erence between investment and cash

�ows for the entire COMPUSTAT sample), using 10 years of data. We de�ne the �rm�s �nancing

gap at the industry level to mitigate the endogeneity of �rm-speci�c investment, and to reduce the

error in measuring the gap betas.16 Second, we use a similar procedure to compute an industry-level

cash �ow beta. That is, we compute the beta of the �rm�s 3-digit industry cash �ow, against the

aggregate cash �ow across all COMPUSTAT �rms, using 10 years of past data.

3.2.4 Decomposing total risk into idiosyncratic and systematic components

In addition to using asset and cash �ow betas to measure systematic risk exposure, we also attempt

to tease out the relative importance of systematic and idiosyncratic risk for corporate liquidity pol-

icy. We do this by decomposing total asset risk on its systematic and idiosyncratic components.

Using the Merton-KMV betas and variances, the systematic component for �rm j at time t can be

15We use COMPUSTAT item capx to measure investment (ib), and de�ne cash �ow as earnings before extraordinaryitems (ib).16We restrict the sample to industry-years with at least 15 �rms to further improve measurement.

20

Page 23: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

estimated as:17

SysV ar KMVj;t = (Beta KMVj;t)2 � V ar KMVt, (29)

where V ar KMVt is the unlevered variance of the market. We compute V ar KMVt as the value-

weighted average of �rm-level asset variances, Var KMV j;t. The systematic component is essentially

the variance of asset returns that is explained by the market. Given this formula, the idiosyncratic

component can be computed as the asset variance that is not explained by the market:

IdV ar KMVj;t = V ar KMVj;t � SysV ar KMVj;t. (30)

3.2.5 Addressing measurement error

One common shortcoming of the measures of systematic risk that we construct is that they are

noisy and subject to measurement error. While this problem cannot be fully resolved, it can be

ameliorated by adopting a strategy dealing with classical errors-in-variables. We follow the standard

Griliches and Hausman (1986) approach to measurement problem and instrument the endogenous

variable (our beta proxy) with lags of itself. We experimented with alternative lag structures and

chose a parsimonious form that satis�es the restriction conditions needed to validate the approach.18

Throughout the analysis, we report auxiliary statistics that speak to the relevance (�rst-stage F -

tests) and validity (Hansen�s J -stats) of our instrumental variables regressions.

3.2.6 Time-series variables

We proxy for the extent of aggregate risk in the economy by using V IX (the implied volatility on

S&P 500 index options). VIX captures both aggregate volatility, as well as the �nancial sector�s

appetite to bear that risk. We also add other macroeconomic variables to our tests, including the

commercial paper�Treasury spread (Gatev and Strahan (2005)) to capture the possibility that funds

may �ow to the banking sector in times of high aggregate volatility, and real GDP growth to capture

general economic conditions.

In addition, we proxy for the extent of aggregate risk in the banking sector by computing Bank

V IX (the expected volatility on an index of bank stock returns). Since there are no available his-

torical data on implied volatility for an aggregate bank equity index, we compute expected volatility

using a GARCH (1,1) model and the Fama-French index of bank stock returns.19 Appendix D details

the procedure that we use.

17We focus on the KMV measures to decompose variances, but the results are robust across di¤erent measures.18An alternative way to address measurement error is to compute betas at a �portfolio,�rather than at a �rm-level.

We explore this idea as well, using industry betas rather than �rm-level betas in some speci�cations below.19We also use a Risk Metrics procedure to compute expected volatility, and obtain virtually identical results.

21

Page 24: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

3.3 Empirical tests and results

3.3.1 Summary statistics

We start by summarizing our data in Table 1. Panel A reports summary statistics for the LPC-

DealScan sample (for �rm-years in which Beta KMV data are available), and Panel B uses Su��s

sample. Notice that the size of the sample in Panel A is much larger, and that the data for Beta

Asset are available only for approximately one third of the �rm-years for which Beta KMV data are

available. As expected, the average values of asset betas are very close to each other, with average

values close to one. The two alternative measures of variance also appear to be very close to each

other. The spread data are available at the deal-level, and thus the number of observations re�ect

the number of di¤erent credit line deals in our sample.

� Table 1 about here �

Comparing Panel A and Panel B, notice that the distribution for most of the variables is very sim-

ilar across the two samples. The main di¤erence between the two samples is that the LPC-DealScan

data is biased towards large �rms (as discussed above). For example, median assets are equal to

270 million in LPC Sample, and 116 million in Random Sample. Consistent with this di¤erence,

the �rms in LPC Sample are also older, and have higher average Qs and EBITDA volatility. The

measure of line of credit availability in LPC Sample (LC-to-Cash) is lower than those in Random

Sample (Total LC-to-Cash and Unused LC-to-Cash). For example, the average value of LC-to-Cash

in LPC Sample is 0:33, while the average value of Total LC-to-Cash is 0:51. This di¤erence re�ects

the fact that LPC-DealScan may fail to report some credit lines that are available in Su��s data,

though it could also re�ect the di¤erent sample compositions.

In Table 2, we examine the correlation among the di¤erent betas that we use in this study. We

also include the asset variance proxies (Var KMV, Var Asset, SysVar KMV and IdVar KMV ). Not

surprisingly, all the beta proxies that are based on asset return data are highly correlated. The

lowest correlations are those between the cash �ow-based betas (Beta Gap and Beta Cash Flow)

and the asset-return based betas (approximately 0:10). The correlations among the other betas (all

of them based on asset return data) hover between 0:3 and 0:9.

� Table 2 about here �

To examine the e¤ect of aggregate risk on the choice between cash and credit lines, we perform

a number of di¤erent sets of tests. We describe these tests in turn.

22

Page 25: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

3.3.2 Firm-level regressions

Our benchmark empirical speci�cation closely follows of Su� (2009). We expand his speci�cation by

including our measure of systematic risk:

LC-to-Cashi;t = �+ �1BetaKMV i;t + �2 ln(Age)i;t + �3(Pro�tability)i;t�1 (31)

+�4Sizei;t�1 + �5Qi;t�1 + �6Networthi;t�1 + �7IndSalesV olj;t

+�8Pro�tV oli;t +Xt

Y eart + �i;t,

where Year absorbs time-speci�c e¤ects, respectively. Our theory predicts that the coe¢ cient �1

should be negative. We also run the same regression replacing Beta KMV with our other proxies

for a �rm�s exposure to systematic and idiosyncratic risks (see Sections 3.2.3 and 3.2.4). And we use

di¤erent proxies for LC-to-Cash, which are based both on LPC-DealScan and Su��s data. We also

include industry dummies (following Su� we use 1-digit SIC industry dummies) and the variance

measures that are based on stock and asset returns (Var KMV and Var Asset).

The results for the KMV-Merton betas and variances, and LPC-DealScan data are presented in

Table 3. In column (1), we replicate Su��s (2009) results (see his Table 3). Just like Su�, we �nd

that pro�table, large, low Q, low net worth, low cash �ow volatility �rms are more likely to use bank

credit lines. The fact that we can replicate Su��s results is important, given that our dependent

variable is not as precisely measured as that in Su�. In column (2), we introduce asset variance (Var

KMV ) in the model. Var KMV is negatively correlated with the LC-to-Cash ratio, and it drives out

the signi�cance of Su��s pro�t volatility variable. This �nding suggests that Var KMV is a better

measure of total risk than the pro�t volatility variable used by Su�. Since Var KMV contains both

systematic and idiosyncratic risk, it is not clear which type of risk explains this negative coe¢ cient.

� Table 3 about here �

Next, we introduce our measures of systematic and idiosyncratic risk in the regressions. The

coe¢ cient on Beta KMV in column (3) suggests that systematic risk is negatively related to the

LC-to-Cash ratio. The size of the coe¢ cient implies that a one-standard deviation increase in asset

beta (approximately 1) decreases �rm�s reliance on credit lines by approximately 0:08 (about 20%

of the standard deviation of the LC-to-Cash variable). In columns (4) and (5) we introduce SysVar

KMV and IdVar KMV in the regressions. The results suggest that while systematic risk exposure is

negative correlated to the LC-to-Cash ratio, idiosyncratic risk is positively correlated with the use of

credit lines in corporate liquidity policy. Finally, in columns (5) and (6) we report results of speci�ca-

tions that include both Beta KMV and Var KMV (column (5)), and SysVar KMV and IdVar KMV

together in the same regressions. The results support our model�s implication that systematic risk

23

Page 26: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

exposure reduces �rms�reliance on credit lines for liquidity management. In addition, the evidence

suggests that idiosyncratic risk exposure is positively correlated with the usage of credit lines.

Table 4 uses Su��s (2009) measures of LC-to-Cash rather than LPC-DealScan data. In Panel A

we use Total LC-to-Cash, and in Panel B we use Unused LC-to-Cash. Column (1) in both tables repli-

cates the results in Su��s Table 3. Notice that the coe¢ cients are virtually identical to those in Su�.

We then introduce our KMV-based proxies for total, aggregate, and idiosyncratic risk exposures. As

in Table 3, the evidence suggests that systematic risk exposure is negatively correlated with the use

of credit lines. We reach this conclusion both when we use Beta KMV (columns (3) and (6)) and Sys-

Var KMV (columns (4) and (7)) to proxy for systematic risk exposure. Idiosyncratic risk exposure

is positively correlated to credit line usage, though statistical signi�cant is weaker than in Table 3

(t-statistics are close to 1:6 for IdVar KMV ). These results suggest that the relation between system-

atic risk exposure and liquidity management that we uncover in this paper is economically signi�cant

and robust to di¤erent ways of computing exposure to systematic risk and reliance on credit lines.20

� Table 4 about here �

It is important that we consider the validity of our instrumental variables approach to the mis-

measurement problem. The �rst statistic we consider in this examination is the �rst-stage exclusion

F -tests for our set of instruments. Their associated p-values are all lower to 1% (con�rming the

explanatory power of our instruments). We also examine the validity of the exclusion restrictions

associated with our set of instruments. We do this using Hansen�s (1982) J -test statistic for overiden-

tifying restrictions. The p-values associated with Hansen�s test statistic are reported in the last row

of Tables 3 and 4. We generally �nd high p-values (particularly when using Su��s sample in Table 4).

These reported statistics suggest that we do not reject the joint null hypothesis that our instruments

are uncorrelated with the error term in the leverage regression and the model is well-speci�ed.

Tables 5 and 6 replace Beta KMV with our alternative beta measures.21 Table 5 shows the

results for the LPC-DealScan sample, while Table 6 shows the results for Su��s (2009) sample. The

results in the �rst column of Table 5 suggest that the results reported in Table 3 are robust to the

method used to unlever betas. Beta Asset (which is based directly on asset return data) has a similar

relation to liquidity policy as that uncovered in Table 2. The economic magnitude of the coe¢ cient

on Beta Asset is in fact larger than that reported in Table 2. Using industry-level cash-adjusted

betas, Beta Cash, also produces similar results (column (2)). In column (3), we show that a �rm�s

20 In our model, both cash and credit lines are used by the �rm to hedge liquidity shocks. This raises the questionof whether derivatives-based hedging would a¤ect our results. We believe this is unlikely for a couple of reasons.First, notice that the use of derivatives and other forms of hedging should be re�ected in the betas that we observe.Second, while derivatives hedging is only feasible in certain industries (such as those that are commodity-intensive),our results hold across and within industries, for a broad set of industries.21We obtain similar results when using SysVar KMV to measure systematic risk exposure.

24

Page 27: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

exposure to banking sector risks (Beta Bank) a¤ects liquidity policy in a way that is consistent with

the theory. The coe¢ cients are also economically signi�cant. Speci�cally, a one-standard deviation

increase in Beta Bank (which is equal to 0:7) decreases LC-to-Cash by 0:21, which is half of the

standard deviation of the LC-to-Cash variable. Column (4) shows that a �rm�s exposure to tail risks

is also correlated with liquidity policy. Firms which tend to do poorly during market downturns

have a signi�cantly lower LC-to-Cash ratio. In column (5), we use equity (levered) betas instead of

asset betas. The coe¢ cient on beta is comparable to the similar speci�cation in Table 3 (which is in

column (3)), though somewhat smaller. Thus, adjusting for the leverage e¤ect increases the e¤ect of

beta on the LC-to-Cash ratio (as expected). However, even the equity beta shows a negative relation

to the fraction of credit lines used in liquidity management. In column (6) we use value-weighted

industry betas rather than �rm-level betas in the regression. Using industry betas is an alternative

way to address the possibility that �rm-level betas are measured with error. Thus, in column (6) we

do not instrument betas with the �rst two lags (as we do in the other columns). The results again

suggest a signi�cant relation between asset beta and the LC-to-Cash ratio. Columns (7) and (8)

replace market-based beta measures with cash �ow-based betas (Beta Gap and Beta Cash Flow).

Consistent with the theory, cash �ow betas are signi�cantly related to the LC-to-Cash ratio, though

economic signi�cance is smaller than for the market measures.22

� Table 5 about here �

Table 6 replicates the analysis in Table 5 for Su��s (2009) sample. The results show that the

relation between beta and liquidity management also holds when using that sample, for both mea-

sures of liquidity management (using total and unused credit lines). The only di¤erence between the

results in Table 5 and Table 6 is that in some cases the statistical signi�cance of the beta coe¢ cients

is lower in Table 6 (such as for Beta Bank and Beta Gap). This di¤erence is probably due to the

decrease in the number of observations in Table 6.

� Table 6 about here �

3.3.3 Sorting �rms according to proxies for �nancing constraints

One of the implications of the model in Section 2 is that the choice between cash and credit lines

should be most relevant for �rms that are �nancially constrained. This line of argument suggests that

the relation that we �nd above should be driven by �rms that �nd it more costly to raise external

funds. In this section we employ speci�cations in which we sort �rms into ��nancially constrained�

and ��nancially unconstrained�categories. We do not have strong priors about which approach is

best and follow prior studies in using multiple alternative schemes to partition our sample:22The coe¢ cient in column (7), for example, suggests that a one-standard deviation increase in Beta Gap decreases

LC-to-Cash by approximately 1:5%.

25

Page 28: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

� Scheme #1: We rank �rms based on their payout ratio and assign to the �nancially constrained(unconstrained) group those �rms in the bottom (top) three deciles of the annual payout distri-

bution. The intuition that �nancially constrained �rms have signi�cantly lower payout ratios

follows from Fazzari et al. (1988), among many others, in the �nancial constraints literature.

In the capital structure literature, Fama and French (2002) use payout ratios as a measure of

di¢ culties �rms may face in assessing the �nancial markets.

� Scheme #2: We rank �rms based on their asset size, and assign to the �nancially constrained(unconstrained) group those �rms in the bottom (top) three deciles of the size distribution.

This approach resembles that of Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1995), who also distinguish be-

tween groups of �nancially constrained and unconstrained �rms on the basis of size. Fama and

French (2002) and Frank and Goyal (2003) also associate �rm size with the degree of external

�nancing frictions. The argument for size as a good observable measure of �nancial constraints

is that small �rms are typically young, less well known, and thus more vulnerable to credit

imperfections.

� Scheme #3: We rank �rms based on whether they have bond and commercial paper ratings.A �rm is deemed to be constrained if it has neither a bond nor a commercial paper rating. it

is unconstrained if it has both a bond and a commercial paper rating.

We repeat the regressions performed above, but now separately for �nancially constrained and

unconstrained subsamples. Due to space constraints we report only results for the LPC-Deal Scan

sample, though results are similar for Su��s sample. To measure systematic risk, we use both Beta

KMV and Beta Tail (which measures �rms�exposure to tail risks). The results are qualitatively

similar if we use the other proxies used above.

Table 7 presents the results we obtain. Panel A presents results for Beta KMV, and Panel B

shows the Beta Tail results. The table shows that the negative relation between systematic risk and

the usage of credit lines obtains only in the constrained samples (the exception is the coe¢ cient for

the high-payout sample when using Beta Tail). These results are once again consistent with the

model in Section 2.

� Table 7 about here �

3.3.4 Asset beta and loan spreads

The empirical �ndings so far all suggest that �rms with high aggregate risk exposure hold more cash

relative to lines of credit. This e¤ect arises in our theoretical model since �rms with greater aggregate

risk exposure face a higher cost of bank lines of credit. We perform an additional test to further

investigate this channel. Speci�cally, we provide evidence on the relation between spreads paid by

26

Page 29: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

�rms on their credit lines and systematic risk. To do this, we regress the average annual spreads

paid by �rm i in deals initiated in year t,23 on systematic risk proxies and controls. We control for

the size of credit line facilities raised in year t scaled by assets ( LCi;tAssetsi;t

), and the level of the LIBOR

in the quarter when the credit line was raised.24 Our empirical model has the following form:

Spreadi;t=�0 + �1Betai;t + �2(LCi;t

Assetsi;t) + �3LIBORi;t + �4Xi;t +

Xt

Y eart + �i;t, (32)

where X is the vector of �rm characteristics used in equation (31). To save space, the analysis in

this section focuses on a set of three risk proxies (namely, Beta KMV, Beta Tail, and SysVar KMV ),

but our results hold robustly across di¤erent proxies for systematic risk.

Our �ndings are presented in Table 8. The coe¢ cients on systematic risk proxies in columns (1)

to (3) suggest that All-in drawn spread is higher for �rms with greater exposure to systematic risk

(though statistical signi�cance for the coe¢ cient on Beta KMV is weaker). For example, the coe¢ -

cient estimate of 10 on SysVar KMV indicates that a one-standard deviation change in systematic

risk exposure (equal to 0:018 according to Table 1) is associated with an increase of 18 basis points on

credit line spreads (approximately 16% of the standard deviation in All-in drawn spread). Columns

(4) through (6) show similar results for the alternative spread measure (Undrawn spread). The

evidence suggests that an increase of one standard deviation in systematic risk exposure increases

undrawn spreads by 6 basis points, 35% of the standard deviation reported in Table 1. These results

provide evidence that �rms with high exposure to systematic risk face worse contractual terms when

initiating credit lines.

� Table 8 about here �

3.3.5 Time-series tests

In this section, we examine the time-series implications of the model. The model suggests that an

increase in aggregate risk makes it more di¢ cult for the banking sector to provide new credit lines.

Accordingly, high aggregate risk should be associated with lower credit line initiations, and worse

terms for new credit lines (for example, higher spreads and shorter maturities). In response, �rms

should attempt to build up cash reserves. The model also suggests that both economy-wide and

banking sector risk should matter for corporate liquidity policy. We examine these dynamics in turn.

We focus �rst on the impact of aggregate risk on credit line initiations and changes in cash

23This annual average is weighted by the amount raised in each credit line deal.24The data on LIBOR refers to the level of LIBOR in the quarter in which �rm i initiates the credit line. We

annualize this variable by computing the facility size-weighted, �rm-year average (LIBORi;t). Notice that since �rmsinitiate credit lines in di¤erent quarters, this proxy varies both over time and across �rms.

27

Page 30: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

holdings (de�ned in equation (28) above). To do so, we run the following time-series SUR model:

LCInitiationt = &0 + &1V IXt�1 + &2TimeTrendt + &3Controlst�1 +$t (33)

Change in Casht = 0 + 1V IXt�1 + 2Time Trendt + 3Controlst�1 + �t.

To allow for variation in our tests, in some speci�cations we replace V IX (a measure of economy-wide

aggregate risk) with Bank V IX (expected volatility of banking sector equity returns).25 We also

include both volatility measures together in the regressions in some speci�cations. Our model would

suggest that &1 < 0, and 1 > 0. The control variables are the 3-month commercial paper�Treasury

spread and real GDP growth. Previous banking literature suggests that during crises, banks expe-

rience an in�ow of deposits coming from the commercial paper market. This e¤ect, in turn, helps

them honor their loan commitments (e.g., Gatev and Strahan (2005)). Banks�increased ability to

honor their commitments during bad times may then counteract the e¤ect of V IX on corporate

liquidity management. As shown by Gatev and Strahan, this in�ow e¤ect tends to happen in times

when the spread of commercial paper over Treasury rates is high. Real GDP growth captures general

economic conditions and investment opportunities. We lag both V IX and the control variables one

period, since it may take time for macroeconomic conditions to a¤ect corporate liquidity manage-

ment variables. Also, corporate variable may be measured at di¤erent times of the year based on

�scal-year ends.

Before reporting the results, we examine the relation between V IX, LC Initiation, and Change

in Cash in a simple plot. Figure 3 shows a clear negative correlation between VIX and credit line

initiations in our sample period. The correlation between V IX and changes in cash is less clear, but

there seems to be a positive correlation throughout the sample period.

� Figure 3 about here �

Table 9 reports the regression outputs. The results for credit lines are presented in Panel A,

and those for cash are in Panel B (recall that each equation is estimated using a SUR procedure).

Column (1) shows that the negative relation between V IX and LC Initiation is statistically sig-

ni�cant. The coe¢ cient on V IX suggests that a one-standard deviation increase in V IX (which is

equal to 0:07) decreases LC Initiation by approximately 0:7 standard deviations of that variable.

This e¤ect is economically relevant. In addition, V IX has a positive relation with aggregate change

in cash holdings. The coe¢ cient on Panel B suggests that a one-standard deviation in V IX in-

creases aggregate cash holdings by 0:43 standard deviations of that variable. Column (2) suggests

that Bank V IX also has a negative relation with LC Initiation. However, the coe¢ cient on the

cash regression is virtually zero. When we include both V IX and Bank V IX together in the same25The correlation between V IX and Bank V IX in our time-series data is equal to 0:39:

28

Page 31: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

regression (see column (3)), we �nd that both are negatively related to LC Initiation, suggesting

that banking sector matters for credit line provision, over and above economy-wide aggregate risk.

This result supports the implications of our model.

� Table 9 about here �

One potential issue with the results above is that the right-hand side variables are simple aggre-

gates (see equation (28)). In particular, these results leave open the possibility that contemporaneous

changes in other �rm-level variables may a¤ect our inferences. In order to address this possibility,

in columns (4) to (6) we use the average residual value of �rm-level cash holdings and credit line

initiations to compute our aggregate quantities. The �rm-level residual values are computed using

the same explanatory variables as in equation (31) (excluding year e¤ects and Beta). Columns (4)

through (6) show that our results become even stronger after this change in the speci�cation. While

the relation between V IX, LC Initiation, and Change in Cash is robust to this modi�cation (col-

umn (4)), column (5) shows that Bank V IX is now positively correlated with Change in Cash. In

addition, column (6) suggests that both V IX and Bank V IX seem to matter for corporate liquidity

policy in the way suggested by our theory.26

Table 9 suggests that in times of high aggregate risk, new credit line initiations decrease and

cash holdings increase. Thus, �rms appear to be substituting cash holdings for credit lines when

aggregate risk is high. This pattern is consistent with our model, which predicts that the banking

sector�s ability to provide new credit lines decreases when aggregate risk is high. However, there are

other explanations for the correlations depicted in Table 9. For example, even though we control

for GDP growth, it is possible that V IX is capturing general economic conditions, which reduce

investment opportunities and �rms�demand for new credit lines. Second, it is possible that aggre-

gate risk increases the cost of debt for corporations, causing �rms to reduce demand for any type of

debt (including credit lines).27 It is thus important that we perform tests that are designed to help

counter these alternative explanations and provide additional support for our model.

To address the possibility that the results in Table 9 capture a decrease in overall demand for

credit and liquidity in the economy, we examine aggregate changes in credit line contractual terms

(spreads and maturities). The idea is as follows. If the reduction in credit line initiations re�ects

a decline in demand that is caused by poor investment opportunities, then we would expect the

spreads on new credit lines to decrease as well (as the economy moves along the supply curve, and

26We also performed tests of joint signi�cance for V IX and Bank V IX in the regressions depicted in columns (3)and (6), both for credit line initiations and cash (Panels A and B). In all cases we reject the hypothesis that thecoe¢ cients on V IX and Bank V IX are jointly equal to zero (the highest p-value that we obtain is approximately0:03, in the cash regression in column (3)).27For example, one argument is that �nancial distress costs are systematic and increase in times of high aggregate

risk (see Almeida and Philippon (2007) and Chen (2010)).

29

Page 32: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

adjusts to the reduction in credit line demand). On the other hand, if the underlying cause for the

decline in observed initiations is as suggested by our model, then we would expect credit line spreads

to increase following an increase in VIX. In addition, according to our model, we would also expect

other contractual terms such as credit line maturities to become tighter (e.g., shorter maturities).

We examine the relation between V IX, Bank V IX, and credit line terms in the four �rst

columns of Table 10. To do so, we measure the average credit line maturity and spread (weighted

by the size of the credit line facility) in each year of our sample. We then estimate a SUR model in

which average maturities and spreads are used as dependent variables:

Average Maturityt = 0 + 1V IXt�1 + 2TimeTrendt + 3Controlst�1 + {t (34)

Average Spreadt = %0 + %1V IXt�1 + %2TimeTrendt + %3Controlst�1 + �t.

The demand-investment opportunity story would suggest that 1 > 0 and %1 < 0, while our model

would predict 1 < 0 and %1 > 0.

The main result is presented in Table 10 and Figure 4. Notably, aggregate risk appears to tighten

credit line contractual terms. In other words, following increases in aggregate volatility, credit line

spreads increase, and maturities decrease. This result is visually obvious in Figure 4, and it is

con�rmed in Table 10 (�rst four columns). In addition, notice that the impact of aggregate risk

on credit line contracts is economically substantial. A one-standard deviation increase in V IX de-

creases average credit line maturity by approximately 60% of its standard deviation, and increases

average spread by 50% of its standard deviation.28 The results are similar for Bank V IX, though

the coe¢ cient on the spread regression is not statistically signi�cant.29

� Figure 4 about here �

� Table 10 about here �

While these results are consistent with our model, they can still be explained by an overall in-

crease in the cost of debt for corporations, following an increase in aggregate risk. A simple way

to examine whether this is a plausible explanation for the results is to replace credit line initiations

with aggregate changes in total debt, and see whether lagged changes in aggregate risk also predict

reductions in total debt in the economy. We test this idea by estimating a debt-taking model in

which the dependent variable is computed similarly to changes in cash holdings:

Change in Debtt =

Pj(Debtj;t �Debtj;t�1)P

j Assetsj;t. (35)

28For example, the standard deviation in V IX is 0:07. Multiplying by the coe¢ cient of �26 on the maturityregression gives 1:82, which is 61% of the standard deviation of the maturity variable (which is equal to 3).29We have also used an alternative speci�cation that controls for other �rm-speci�c variables (similar to Table 9),

with virtually identical results.

30

Page 33: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

In this equation, we de�ne debt as the sum of short- and long-term debt from COMPUSTAT. We

then replace LCInitiationt in Equation 33 above with Change in Debtt.

Columns (5) and (6) of Table 10 report the results for the debt regression, using both V IX (col-

umn (5)) and Bank V IX (column (6)). The SUR model also includes an equation for Change in

Cash, but coe¢ cients are not reported since they are identical to those reported in Table 9 (columns

(1) and (2)). As it turns out, neither lagged V IX nor Bank V ix predict an overall reduction in

debt in the economy. The coe¢ cient on the Change in Debt variable is positive, economically small,

and statistically insigni�cant in column (5), and negative and statistically insigni�cant in column

(6). These results suggest that the negative impact of aggregate risk on new debt is strongest for

credit line initiations. This is consistent with our model�s suggestion that increases in aggregate risk

compromise the baking sector�s ability to provide credit lines for liquidity management.30

4 Concluding Remarks

We show that aggregate risk a¤ects �rms�choice between cash and credit lines. For �rms with high

exposure to systematic risk, the folk statement that �cash is king� appears to be true. In contrast,

for �rms that only need to manage their idiosyncratic liquidity risk, bank credit lines dominate

cash holdings. In our empirical tests we measure �rm-level exposure to systematic risk using asset

betas and systematic variance (the component of �rm-level variance that is explained by aggregate

variance). Our results show a negative, statistically signi�cant and economically large e¤ect of sys-

tematic risk exposure on the fraction of total liquidity that is held via credit lines. We also measure

time-series changes in aggregate volatility using V IX, and show that �rms tend to hold more cash

and initiate fewer credit lines when aggregate risk rises. These results shed light on an important

trade-o¤ between cash and credit lines for corporate liquidity management, and they suggest a new

role for aggregate risk exposure in corporate �nance.

There are many ways in which our paper can be extended. One of the most interesting extensions

has to do with the role of bank capital for corporate liquidity management. The current framework

has no role for bank capital, given that cash can be e¢ ciently held inside the corporate sector.

However, in a more general framework this conclusion may not hold. If aggregate risk (proportion

� of systematic �rms in our model) were uncertain, then bank capital or excess liquidity bu¤ers can

enable the economy to transfer resources from low aggregate risk states to high aggregate risk states.

Further, a �rm�s decision to manage liquidity needs through cash holdings or lines of credit should

be a¤ected by unexpected shocks to capital of its relation bank(s), especially during crises (when

30We have also examined the relationship between V IX and aggregate corporate liquidity instruments separatelyfor di¤erent sample partitions (those in Section 3.3.3). We �nd that the negative relationship between V IX (or BankV IX) and credit line initiations is stronger for small, low-payout and non-rated �rms.

31

Page 34: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

other better-capitalized banks also �nd it di¢ cult to o¤er further lines of credit given heightened

aggregate risk levels). Finally, in such a framework of bank capital, government bailouts and/or

guarantees during aggregate crises can lead to ex-ante under-investment in bank capital, generate

moral hazard in the form of banks issuing lines of credit to risky �rms, and potentially lead to

excessive aggregate risk in the economy. In all, these arguments highlight that it is important for

researchers and policy-makers to better understand the dynamics of liquidity management in the

economy as aggregate risk varies.

32

Page 35: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

References

Acharya, V., H. Almeida, and M. Campello, 2007, �Is Cash Negative Debt? A Hedging Perspectiveon Corporate Financial Policies,�Journal of Financial Intermediation 16, 515-554.

Acharya, V., L. H. Pedersen, T. Philippon, and M. Richardson, 2010, �Measuring Systemic Risk,�Working Paper, NYU-Stern.

Almeida, H., M. Campello, and M. Weisbach, 2004, �The Cash Flow Sensitivity of Cash,�Journalof Finance 59, 1777-1804.

Almeida, H., M. Campello, and M. Weisbach, 2009, �Corporate Financial and Investment Policieswhen Future Financing is not Frictionless,�forthcoming Journal of Corporate Finance.

Almeida, H., and T. Philippon, 2007, �The Risk-Adjusted Cost of Financial Distress,�Journal ofFinance, 62, 2557�2586.

Bharath, S., and T. Shumway, 2008, �Forecasting Default with the Merton Distance to DefaultModel,�Review of Financial Studies 21, 1339-1369.

Bolton, P., H. Chen, and N. Wang, 2009, �A Uni�ed Theory of Tobin�s q, Corporate Investment,Financing, and Risk Management�, Working Paper, Columbia University and MIT.

Campello, M., E. Giambona, J. Graham, and C. Harvey, 2010, � Liquidity Management and Cor-porate Investment During a Financial Crisis,�Working Paper, University of Illinois, Universityof Amsterdam, and Duke University.

Chava, S., and M. Roberts, 2008, �How Does Financing Impact Investment? The Role of DebtCovenant Violations,�Journal of Finance 63, 208-221.

Chen, H., 2010, �Macroeconomic Conditions and the Puzzles of Credit Spreads and Capital Struc-ture.�forthcoming, Journal of Finance.

Choi, J., 2009, �What Drives the Value Premium: Assets or Leverage?�Working Paper, Penn StateUniversity.

DeMarzo, P., and M. Fishman, 2007, �Optimal Long-Term Financial Contracting,� Review ofFinancial Studies 20, 2079-2128.

Denis, D., and V. Sibilikov, 2007, �Financial Constraints, Investment, and the Value of CashHoldings,�forthcoming, Review of Financial Studies.

Disatnik, D., R. Duchin and B. Schmidt, 2010, �Cash Flow Hedging and Liquidity Choices,�Work-ing Paper, Tel Aviv University, Michigan University, and Emory University.

Duchin, R., 2009, �Cash Holdings and Corporate Diversi�cation,�Working Paper, University ofMichigan.

Eisfeldt, A., and A. Rampini, 2009 �Financing Shortfalls and the Value of Aggregate Liquidity,�Working Paper, Duke University.

Fama, E., and K. R. French, 2002, �Testing Tradeo¤ and Pecking Order Predictions about Divi-dends and Debt,�Review of Financial Studies 15, 1-33.

33

Page 36: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Fazzari, S., R. G. Hubbard, and B. Petersen, 1988, �Financing Constraints and Corporate Invest-ment,�Brooking Papers on Economic Activity 1, 141-195.

Frank, M., and V. Goyal, 2003, �Testing the Pecking Order Theory of Capital Structure,�Journalof Financial Economics 67, 217-248.

Gatev, E., and P. Strahan, 2006, �Banks� Advantage in Hedging Liquidity Risk: Theory andEvidence from the Commercial Paper Market,�Journal of Finance 61, 867-892.

Gatev, E., T. Schuermann, and P. Strahan, 2005, �How Do Banks Manage Liquidity Risk? Evidencefrom Deposit and Equity Markets in the Fall of 1998.� In: M. Carey and R. Stulz, Editors,Risks of Financial Institutions, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Gilchrist, S., and C. Himmelberg, 1995, �Evidence on the Role of Cash Flow for Investment,�Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 541-572.

Griliches, Z., and J. Hausman, 1986, �Errors in Variables in Panel Data,�Journal of Econometrics31, 93-118.

Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole, 1997, �Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the RealSector,�Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 663-691.

Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole, 1998, �Private and Public Supply of Liquidity,�Journal of PoliticalEconomy 106, 1�40.

Ivashina, V., and D. Scharfstein, 2010, �Bank Lending During the Financial Crisis of 2008,�Journalof Financial Economics 97, 319-338.

Kahl, M., A. Shivdasani, and Y. Wang, 2008, �Do Firms Use Commercial Paper to EnhanceFinancial Flexibility?�Working Paper, University of North Carolina.

Kashyap, A., R. Raghuram, and J. Stein, 2002, �Banks as Liquidity Providers: An Explanation forthe Co-Existence of Lending and Deposit-Taking,�Journal of Finance 57, 33-73.

Lins, K., H. Servaes, and P. Tufano, 2010, �What Drives Corporate Liquidity? An InternationalSurvey of Strategic Cash and Lines of Credit,�forthcoming, Journal of Financial Economics.

Opler, T., L. Pinkowitz, R. Stulz, and R. Williamson, 1999, �The Determinants and Implicationsof Corporate Cash Holdings,�Journal of Financial Economics 52, 3-46.

Pennacchi, G., 2006, �Deposit Insurance, Bank Regulation, and Financial System Risks,�Journalof Monetary Economics 53, 1-30.

Shockley, R., and A. Thakor, 1997, �Bank Loan Commitment Contracts: Data, Theory and Tests,�Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 29, 517-534.

Su�, A., 2009, �Bank Lines of Credit in Corporate Finance: An Empirical Analysis,�Review ofFinancial Studies 22, 1057-1088.

Tirole, J., 2006, The Theory of Corporate Finance, Princeton University Press.

Yun, H., 2009, �The Choice of Corporate Liquidity and Corporate Governance,� forthcoming,Review of Financial Studies.

34

Page 37: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Appendix A Proof of Lemma 1

First, notice that if constraint (13) is satis�ed for x� = 1 and L� = 0, then systematic �rms willnot �nd it optimal to hold cash (since the solution to (14) would then be equivalent to that ofnon-systematic �rms). This situation arises when:

�� �0 � wmax. (36)

In such case, both systematic and non-systematic �rms can use credit lines to manage liquidity.Notice that this corresponds to scenarios in which � � �max in Proposition 1.

If in turn �� �0 > wmax, systematic �rms will generally demand cash in addition to credit lines.For each x�, their cash demand is given by equation (20).

Next, we consider the �rm�s optimal investment policy x� as a function of the liquidity premiumq, x�(q). The �rm�s liquidity demand can then be derived from equation (20). To �nd the �rm�soptimal policy, notice that the �rm�s payo¤ increases with x� as long as q < q2 which is de�ned as:

q2 = 1 +�(�1 � �)�� �0

. (37)

In the range of prices such that q < q2, the �rm�s optimal choice would be x� = 1. If q > q2, the�rm�s optimal choice is x� = 0. The �rm is indi¤erent between all x� 2 [0; 1] when q = q2. Inaddition to these payo¤ considerations, the budget constraint in problem (14) can also bind for apositive level of x�. The budget constraint can be written as:

I + (q � 1)hx�(�� �0)� wmax

i+ �x�� � (1� �)�0 + �x��0, or (38)

x� � (1� �)�0 � I + (q � 1)wmax(�+ q � 1)(�� �0)

. (39)

The right-hand side of equation (39) is greater than one since (1��)�0� I ��(�� �0) > 0 (by (4)).Thus, there exists a maximum level of q such that the budget constraint is obeyed for x� = 1. Callthis level q1. We can solve for q1 as:

q1 = 1 +�0 � ��� I�� �0 � wmax

. (40)

Clearly, for q < min(q1; q2) we will have x�(q) = 1. As q increases, either the �rm�s budgetconstraint binds, or its payo¤ becomes decreasing in cash holdings. The �rm�s speci�c level of x(q)will then depend on whether q1 is larger than q2.

Appendix B Characterization of the equilibrium when Ls < Ls1(�)

Suppose �rst that q1 > q2, such that the �rm�s budget constraint never binds in equilibrium. In thiscase, if Ls < Ls1 we will have that q

� = q2 > 1. To see why, notice that if q < q2 then systematic �rmswould choose x� = 1, which is not compatible with equilibrium. If q > q2, then x� = 1, generatingan excess supply of cash. Thus, we must have q� = q2. Since systematic �rms are indi¤erent betweenany x� between 0 and 1 when q = q2, we can sustain an equilibrium such that:

�[x�(q2)(�� �0)� wmax] = Ls. (41)

35

Page 38: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

This is the unique equilibrium of the model. To see why, notice that for x� > x�(q2), cashdemand would be larger than supply, and if x� < x�(q2), cash supply would be greater than demandand thus the cost of cash would drop to q = 1.

If q1 < q2, then the �rm�s budget constraint will bind in equilibrium, and we will have q1 < q� �q2. The cost of cash q� is such that the demand for cash exactly equals supply:

�[x�(q�)(�� �0)� wmax] = Ls. (42)

Since q1 < q�, then x�(q�) < 1. Since q� � q2, then systematic �rms would like to increase theirdemand for cash beyond x�(q�), but they cannot a¤ord to do so. Thus, q� is the equilibrium cost ofcash in this case.

Finally, notice that since the cost of cash cannot be greater than q2, there is a level of liquiditysupply (denoted by Lsmin) such that for all L

s < Lsmin, the equilibrium is q� = q2. Lsmin is such thatthe maximum level of x� that satis�es the budget constraint when q = q2 yields a demand for cashexactly equal to Lsmin:

�[x�(q2)(�� �0)� wmax] = Lsmin. (43)

Appendix C Computing Beta KMV and V ar KMV

To compute Beta KMV and Var KMV we make the following assumptions. First, suppose thatthe total value of a �rm follows:

dV

V= �dt+ �V dW (44)

where V is the total value, � is the expected continuously compounded return on V , �V is thevolatility of �rm value, and dW is a standard Wiener process. In addition, assume that the �rmissued one discount bond maturing in T periods. Under these assumptions, the equity of the �rmis a call option on the underlying value of the �rm with a strike price equal to the face value of the�rm�s debt and a time-to-maturity of T . The value of the �call option�is:

E = V N(d1)� e�rTFN(d2) (45)

where E is the market value of a �rm�s equity, F is the face value of the �rm�s debt, r is theinstantaneous risk-free rate, N(:) is the cumulative standard normal distribution function, d1 isgiven by

d1 =ln(V=F ) + (r + 1

2�2V )T

�VpT

, (46)

and d2 is given byd2 = d1 � �V

pT

Given the value of equity, the underlying value of the �rm, or market value of asset is:

V =E + e�rTFN(d2)

N(d1)(47)

Since the value of equity is a function of the value of the �rm and time, using Ito�s lemma weobtain:

�E =V

E

@E

@V�V =

V

E

1

N(d1)�V (48)

36

Page 39: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

To implement the model, we need to simultaneously solve equations (47) and (48). We followBharath and Shumway (2008), and adopt an iterative procedure as follows. First, equity volatility�E is estimated from historical stock returns. We use the last 12 months to do so (e.g., T = 12

months). We also set r = 0:03. To compute the face value of debt for each �rm, we use the �rm�stotal book value of short-term debt plus one-half of the book value of long-term debt. This is aknown rule-of-thumb used to �t a KMV-type model to an annual horizon. Then, we propose aninitial value for asset volatility, �V , which is computed as:

�V = �EE

E + F(49)

We use this value of �V ; and equation (47) to infer the market value of the �rm�s assets forevery month. We then calculate the implied log monthly return on assets, and use that return seriesto generate new estimates of �V and �. Finally, we iterate on �V until the procedure converges.Similarly to unlevering volatility using (48), asset beta is then unlevered using:

�Asset = �EquityE

VN(d1) (50)

Finally, we let V ar KMV = �V , and Beta KMV = �Asset.

Appendix D Computing Bank V IX

Three distinct forecasts of daily bank return volatility are computed. The purpose is to construct aforecast of volatility on day t+ 1 given all information up to and including day t.

First, the daily estimates of volatility are computed using the return series available for the�nancial sector index from Kenneth French�s website. The data span July 1st 1963 through October29th 2010.

Next, we compute a volatility forecast based on a Gaussian GARCH(1,1) model. This procedureis a fully parametric one and uses a statistical model to forecast future volatilities. The parametricapproach requires the estimation of model parameters for which all data up to time t are used. In thecase of value-weighted �nancial sector return series, at least 105 days of observations were requiredto obtain reliable estimates of the parameters. Hence, the �rst run of the model uses the samplewindow [t0; t105] to estimate the model parameters and subsequently forecasts the volatility on dayt106. To obtain volatility forecasts for all dates, the procedure is repeated for each individual day onan expanding sample size basis.

Finally, we compute the average yearly value of the expected volatility series (Bank VIX ) tomatch the frequency of the other data that we use.

37

Page 40: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 1: Summary statisticsThis table reports summary statistics for empirical proxies related to firm characteristics. LC-to-Cash isthe fraction of corporate liquidity that is provided by lines of credit, specifically the ratio of the firm’stotal amount of open credit lines to the sum of open credit lines plus cash balances. Assets are firmassets net of cash, measured in millions of dollars. Tangibility is PPE over assets. Q is defined as acash-adjusted, market-to-book assets ratio. NetWorth is the book value of equity minus cash over totalassets. Profitability is the ratio of EBITDA over net assets. Industry sales volatility (IndSaleVol) is the(3-digit SIC) industry median value of the within-year standard deviation of quarterly changes in firmsales, scaled by the average quarterly gross asset value in the year. ProfitVol is the firm-level standarddeviation of annual changes in the level of EBITDA, calculated using four lags, and scaled by averagegross Assets in the lagged period. Age is measured as the difference between the current year and the firstyear in which the firm appeared in COMPUSTAT. Unused LC-to-Cash and Total LC-to-Cash measurethe fraction of total corporate liquidity that is provided by credit lines using unused and total credit linesrespectively. Beta KMV is the firm’s asset (unlevered) beta, calculated from equity (levered) betas anda Merton-KMV formula. Beta Asset is another proxy for the firm’s asset (unlevered) beta, calculateddirectly from data on asset returns as in Choi (2009). Var KMV and Var Asset are the correspondingvalues for total asset variance. Beta Cash is the (3-digit SIC industry median) asset Beta, adjusted forcash holdings. Beta Bank is the firm’s beta with respect to an index of bank stock returns. Beta Tail is ameasure of beta that is based on the average stock return of a firm in the days in which the stock markethad its worst 5% returns in the year. Beta Gap is computed using the difference between investment andcash flows at the 3-digit SIC level, and the aggregate financing gap. Beta Cash Flow is computed usingindustry cash flows at the 3-digit SIC level, and aggregate cash flows. Beta Equity is the equity (levered)beta. IdVar KMV is a measure of firm-level idiosyncratic variance of asset returns, and SysVar KMV isa measure of firm-level systematic variance of asset returns. All-in drawn spread is the total spread oncredit lines in the LPC-Deal Scan sample, including both drawn and undrawn spreads. Undrawn spreadis the corresponding value for undrawn spreads only .Both spreads are measured in percentage, and aremeasured relative to LIBOR.

Page 41: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Panel A: LPC credit line data

Variables Mean StDev Median Firm-years

Panel A: LPC credit line data

Tangibility 0.350 0.232 0.297 43250Assets 2,594 17,246 270 43309Q 1.961 1.314 1.475 43288Networth 0.381 0.248 0.404 43288Profitability 0.137 0.120 0.141 43309IndSalesVol 0.043 0.031 0.034 44823ProfitVol 0.063 0.053 0.044 44821Age 18.855 14.339 14.000 44825

Beta KMV 0.986 1.032 0.856 44402Beta Cash 0.970 0.574 0.920 44714Beta Bank 0.445 0.703 0.390 44440Beta Tail 0.742 0.567 0.697 44367Beta Gap 0.906 1.420 0.681 35532Beta Cash Flow 0.926 1.397 0.697 35532Beta Equity 1.110 1.319 1.037 44402Beta Asset 0.919 0.926 0.756 14646Var KMV 0.017 0.019 0.009 44825

Var Asset 0.012 0.017 0.005 14646IdVar KMV 0.004 0.014 0.002 44402SysVar KMV 0.013 0.018 0.006 44402

All-in drawn spread 1.771 1.124 1.750 11408Undrawn spread 0.315 0.167 0.300 9865

Page 42: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Panel B: Sufi data

Variables Mean StDev Median Firm-years

Panel B: Sufi data

Unused LC-to-Cash 0.450 0.373 0.455 1906Total LC-to-Cash 0.512 0.388 0.569 1908

Tangibility 0.332 0.230 0.275 1908Assets 1,441 7,682 116 1908Q 2.787 3.185 1.524 1905Networth 0.426 0.300 0.453 1905Profitability 0.015 0.413 0.126 1908IndSalesVol 0.043 0.026 0.036 1908ProfitVol 0.089 0.078 0.061 1908Age 16.037 13.399 10.000 1908

Beta KMV 1.002 1.068 0.804 1559Beta Cash 0.974 0.639 0.915 1881Beta Bank 0.479 0.756 0.400 1561Beta Tail 0.631 0.494 0.584 1003Beta Gap 1.000 1.755 0.892 1677Beta Cash Flow 0.904 1.549 0.733 1677Beta Equity 1.086 1.280 0.968 1596Beta Asset 0.957 0.995 0.705 643

Var KMV 0.026 0.026 0.015 1568Var Asset 0.023 0.025 0.011 643IdVar KMV 0.006 0.018 0.003 1559SysVar KMV 0.019 0.023 0.008 1559

Page 43: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Tab

le2:

Corr

ela

tion

sT

his

tab

lesh

ows

the

corr

elat

ion

sfo

rth

ed

iffer

ent

pro

xie

sof

asse

tb

eta,

idio

syn

crat

ican

dsy

stem

ati

cri

sk.

See

Tab

le1

for

ad

escr

ipti

on

of

the

vari

ab

les.

Bet

aK

MV

Bet

aC

ash

Bet

aB

an

kB

eta

Tail

Bet

aG

ap

Bet

aA

sset

Var

As-

set

Var

KM

VB

eta

Equ

ity

Bet

aC

ash

Flo

w

IdV

ar

KM

V

Bet

aC

ash

0.45

0B

eta

Ban

k0.

642

0.28

0B

eta

Tail

0.38

70.

330

0.2

22

Bet

aG

ap

0.11

30.

232

0.0

96

0.0

86

Bet

aA

sset

0.88

90.

463

0.5

59

0.4

69

0.1

81

Var

Ass

et0.

387

0.23

80.2

63

0.2

58

0.1

51

0.4

41

Var

KM

V0.

380

0.21

70.2

59

0.2

00

0.1

14

0.4

00

0.9

18

Bet

aE

quit

y0.

944

0.37

10.6

21

0.3

12

0.0

85

0.8

17

0.2

98

0.2

80

Bet

aC

ash

Flo

w0.

092

0.19

60.0

98

0.0

83

0.6

11

0.1

68

0.1

49

0.0

96

0.0

75

IdV

ar

KM

V-0

.375

-0.1

34-0

.220

-0.0

90

-0.0

22

-0.3

98

0.2

94

0.4

43

-0.3

44

-0.0

09

Sys

Var

KM

V0.

737

0.34

70.4

63

0.2

86

0.1

29

0.7

09

0.6

15

0.6

34

0.5

96

0.0

98

-0.3

38

Page 44: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 3: The choice between cash and credit lines: LPC-Deal ScansampleThis Table reports regressions of a measure of line of credit usage in corporate liquidity policy on proxiesfor asset beta, asset variance and controls. The dependent variable is LC-to-Cash, defined in Table 1.Beta KMV is the firm’s asset (unlevered) beta, calculated from equity (levered) betas and a Merton-KMV formula. Var KMV is the corresponding value for total asset variance. IdVar KMV is a measure offirm-level idiosyncratic variance of asset returns, and SysVar KMV is a measure of firm-level systematicvariance of asset returns. All proxies for Beta and variances are instrumented with their first two lags.All other variables are described in Table 1. Robust t-statistics presented in parenthesis.

Dependent variable: LC-to-Cash

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Var KMV -3.920*** -1.681(-7.010) (-1.209)

Beta KMV -0.083*** -0.059*(-4.947) (-1.778)

SysVar KMV -6.213*** -5.674***(-8.231) (-8.070)

IdVar KMV 4.250* 4.861**(1.946) (2.187)

Profitability 0.136*** 0.031 0.101*** 0.044 0.193*** 0.063 0.110***(5.435) (0.959) (3.274) (1.396) (5.069) (1.633) (2.767)

Tangibility 0.012 0.005 0.004 0.002 0.013 0.004 0.002(0.606) (0.215) (0.173) (0.072) (0.566) (0.168) (0.074)

Size 0.044*** 0.039*** 0.051*** 0.047*** 0.054*** 0.047*** 0.056***(16.151) (12.285) (16.151) (16.045) (10.563) (8.726) (10.733)

Networth -0.138*** -0.146*** -0.132*** -0.133*** -0.149*** -0.136*** -0.126***(-9.817) (-9.253) (-8.008) (-8.259) (-9.116) (-7.883) (-7.566)

Q -0.055*** -0.052*** -0.050*** -0.046*** -0.059*** -0.049*** -0.046***(-23.840) (-18.017) (-14.211) (-14.156) (-21.334) (-14.941) (-13.669)

IndSalesVol -0.197 -0.206 -0.219 -0.202 -0.220 -0.208 -0.217(-1.343) (-1.271) (-1.349) (-1.241) (-1.363) (-1.279) (-1.333)

ProfitVol -0.250*** 0.148* 0.033 0.221** -0.304*** 0.121 0.074(-3.751) (1.673) (0.380) (2.492) (-3.343) (1.316) (0.744)

Age -0.047*** -0.054*** -0.052*** -0.056*** -0.043*** -0.053*** -0.054***(-7.933) (-7.165) (-6.819) (-7.394) (-5.803) (-7.049) (-7.002)

Constant 0.379*** 0.568*** 0.465*** 0.514*** 0.344*** 0.511*** 0.417***(5.710) (7.307) (6.044) (6.704) (4.039) (6.064) (4.742)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.001 0.385 0.001 0.089 0.013 0.026

Observations 43009 35374 35372 35372 35372 35372 35372R2 0.173 0.167 0.168 0.169 0.167 0.169 0.170

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 45: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 4: The choice between cash and credit lines: Sufi’s (2009) sampleThis table reports regressions of a measure of line of credit usage in corporate liquidity policy on proxies forasset beta, asset variance and controls. The dependent variables are Unused LC-to-Cash and Total LC-to-Cash, defined in Table 1. Beta KMV is the firm’s asset (unlevered) beta, calculated from equity (levered)betas and a Merton-KMV formula. Var KMV is the corresponding value for total asset variance. IdVarKMV is a measure of firm-level idiosyncratic variance of asset returns, and SysVar KMV is a measureof firm-level systematic variance of asset returns. All proxies for Beta and variances are instrumentedwith their first two lags. All other variables are described in Table 1. Robust t-statistics presents inparenthesis.

Panel A: Total LC-to-Cash

Dependent variable: Total LC-to-Cash

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Var KMV -8.491*** 3.114(-4.306) (0.654)

Beta KMV -0.336*** -0.419***(-5.489) (-2.801)

SysVar KMV -17.119*** -19.274***(-5.789) (-3.868)

IdVar KMV 12.714 21.265(1.555) (1.547)

Profitability 0.078** -0.028 -0.013 -0.004 0.109 0.003 0.098(2.269) (-0.561) (-0.226) (-0.083) (1.573) (0.052) (0.907)

Tangibility 0.040 -0.098 -0.089 -0.110 -0.007 -0.081 -0.069(0.560) (-1.151) (-1.098) (-1.318) (-0.083) (-0.938) (-0.669)

Size 0.047*** 0.031** 0.071*** 0.055*** 0.072*** 0.083*** 0.097***(5.110) (2.481) (5.593) (4.593) (3.524) (3.621) (3.098)

Networth -0.097** -0.106** -0.077 -0.071 -0.071 -0.072 -0.023(-2.293) (-2.024) (-1.345) (-1.231) (-1.111) (-1.141) (-0.259)

Q -0.036*** -0.037*** -0.019*** -0.018** -0.033*** -0.016 0.003(-8.495) (-7.142) (-2.656) (-2.472) (-3.603) (-1.516) (0.162)

IndSalesVol 1.094* -0.057 -0.156 -0.345 0.368 -0.138 -0.452(1.691) (-0.079) (-0.215) (-0.484) (0.501) (-0.186) (-0.527)

ProfitVol -0.596*** 0.182 0.315 0.548* -0.589** 0.272 0.519(-3.209) (0.683) (1.022) (1.694) (-2.242) (0.887) (1.104)

Age -0.039* -0.077*** -0.086*** -0.097*** -0.024 -0.083*** -0.079**(-1.846) (-2.656) (-2.818) (-3.028) (-0.808) (-2.731) (-2.058)

Constant 0.748*** 0.381*** 0.306** 0.294** -0.207 0.250 -0.138(8.612) (2.766) (2.359) (2.306) (-0.944) (1.516) (-0.455)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.006 0.283 0.059 0.788 0.569 0.762

Observations 1905 1326 1321 1321 1321 1321 1321R2 0.401 0.428 0.437 0.445 0.408 0.444 0.448

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 46: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Panel B: Unused LC-to-Cash

Dependent variable: Unused LC-to-Cash

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Var KMV -7.391*** 1.649(-3.990) (0.387)

Beta KMV -0.270*** -0.322**(-4.893) (-2.438)

SysVar KMV -15.026*** -17.139***(-5.327) (-3.651)

IdVar KMV 11.788 19.987(1.535) (1.569)

Profitability 0.061* -0.028 -0.012 -0.008 0.095 -0.004 0.087(1.955) (-0.601) (-0.238) (-0.176) (1.459) (-0.074) (0.870)

Tangibility 0.025 -0.101 -0.091 -0.113 -0.021 -0.088 -0.075(0.371) (-1.262) (-1.184) (-1.439) (-0.245) (-1.092) (-0.764)

Size 0.053*** 0.041*** 0.074*** 0.062*** 0.077*** 0.081*** 0.101***(6.106) (3.510) (6.481) (5.687) (4.102) (3.992) (3.555)

Networth -0.054 -0.067 -0.043 -0.036 -0.034 -0.040 0.010(-1.396) (-1.373) (-0.819) (-0.678) (-0.581) (-0.708) (0.118)

Q -0.029*** -0.030*** -0.016** -0.013* -0.025*** -0.013 0.007(-7.263) (-6.027) (-2.398) (-1.918) (-2.978) (-1.479) (0.385)

IndSalesVol 1.042 -0.017 -0.073 -0.278 0.352 -0.075 -0.379(1.549) (-0.022) (-0.093) (-0.355) (0.442) (-0.095) (-0.422)

ProfitVol -0.554*** 0.139 0.198 0.461 -0.541** 0.192 0.440(-3.162) (0.549) (0.711) (1.512) (-2.134) (0.716) (0.991)

Age -0.023 -0.056** -0.061** -0.074** -0.009 -0.061** -0.057(-1.125) (-2.001) (-2.101) (-2.438) (-0.304) (-2.102) (-1.558)

Constant 0.148 0.246* 0.165 0.172 -0.282 0.141 -0.232(1.377) (1.876) (1.332) (1.404) (-1.349) (0.945) (-0.830)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.004 0.174 0.033 0.869 0.296 0.661

Observations 1903 1324 1319 1319 1319 1319 1319R2 0.3713 0.396 0.399 0.411 0.381 0.406 0.414

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 47: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 5: The Choice Between Cash and Credit Lines - Varying BetasThis table reports regressions of a measure of line of credit usage in corporate liquidity policy on asset(unlevered) beta and controls. All variables are described in Table 1. In columns (1) to (7), beta measuresare instrumented with their first two lags. In column (8), we use an industry beta rather than the firm-levelinstrumented beta in the regression. Robust t-statistics presented in parenthesis.

Dependent variable: LC-to-Cash

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Beta Asset -0.137***(-6.006)

Beta Cash -0.127***(-9.258)

Beta Bank -0.291***(-4.952)

Beta Tail -0.137***(-7.417)

Beta Equity -0.054***(-3.453)

Beta KMV -0.029***(-4.919)

Beta Gap -0.010***(-3.428)

Beta Cash Flow -0.013***(-4.515)

Profitability 0.042 0.116*** 0.078** 0.128*** 0.113*** 0.124*** 0.117*** 0.118***(0.675) (5.088) (2.284) (4.364) (3.878) (5.008) (4.779) (4.853)

Tangibility -0.017 -0.004 -0.015 -0.001 0.006 0.048** 0.025 0.026(-0.400) (-0.239) (-0.629) (-0.027) (0.269) (2.400) (1.320) (1.372)

Size 0.042*** 0.050*** 0.055*** 0.059*** 0.052*** 0.042*** 0.049*** 0.049***(6.965) (19.963) (15.334) (16.679) (15.804) (14.520) (17.865) (17.905)

Networth -0.127*** -0.109*** -0.120*** -0.118*** -0.149*** -0.114*** -0.124*** -0.125***(-4.169) (-8.612) (-6.836) (-7.169) (-9.720) (-8.204) (-9.080) (-9.162)

Q -0.050*** -0.049*** -0.048*** -0.044*** -0.053*** -0.052*** -0.056*** -0.056***(-8.136) (-23.028) (-12.198) (-12.330) (-17.681) (-22.093) (-25.415) (-25.507)

IndSalesVol -0.341 -0.128 -0.156 -0.174 -0.190 0.132 -0.187 -0.172(-1.029) (-1.066) (-0.936) (-1.063) (-1.207) (0.826) (-1.356) (-1.255)

ProfitVol -0.315* -0.013 0.120 0.065 -0.065 -0.198*** -0.254*** -0.254***(-1.747) (-0.199) (1.168) (0.797) (-0.780) (-2.785) (-3.608) (-3.592)

Age -0.029** -0.048*** -0.054*** -0.053*** -0.053*** -0.046*** -0.042*** -0.043***(-2.064) (-8.494) (-6.916) (-7.005) (-7.535) (-6.902) (-6.678) (-6.710)

Constant 0.448** 0.614*** 0.468*** 0.415*** 0.477*** 0.362*** 0.453*** 0.454***(2.529) (21.435) (5.800) (5.613) (6.472) (13.516) (16.661) (16.738)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes No Yes Yes No No Yes NoYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.101 0.005 0.555 0.000 0.873 0.001 0.156

Observations 9536 46865 35499 35343 37485 37813 38760 31811R2 0.211 0.162 0.166 0.170 0.155 0.155 0.168 0.164

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 48: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 6: Varying Betas: Sufi (2009) sampleThis table reports regressions of measures of line of credit usage in corporate liquidity policy on asset(unlevered) beta and controls. All variables are described in Table 1. Panel A uses Total LC-to-Cash asa dependent variable, while panel B uses Unused LC-to-Cash as a dependent variable. In both panels, incolumns (1) to (7) Beta measures are instrumented with their first two lags. In column (8), we use anindustry beta rather than the firm-level instrumented beta in the regression. Robust t-statistics presentedin parenthesis.

Page 49: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Panel A

Dependent variable: Total LC-to-Cash

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Beta Asset -0.265***(-3.330)

Beta Cash -0.238***(-5.327)

Beta Bank -0.619***(-2.866)

Beta Tail -0.285**(-2.326)

Beta Equity -0.263***(-4.020)

Beta KMV -0.096***(-3.616)

Beta Gap -0.012(-1.318)

Beta Cash Flow -0.009(-0.774)

Profitability -0.134** 0.100*** 0.048 0.229** -0.045 0.108*** 0.061* 0.057(-2.094) (2.762) (0.845) (2.489) (-0.720) (2.843) (1.760) (1.286)

Tangibility -0.079 -0.030 -0.026 0.037 0.036 0.098 0.088 0.132(-0.651) (-0.433) (-0.273) (0.343) (0.371) (1.117) (1.183) (1.578)

Size 0.109*** 0.048*** 0.077*** 0.032* 0.077*** 0.037*** 0.047*** 0.049***(7.573) (5.025) (4.474) (1.882) (5.432) (3.242) (4.852) (4.451)

Networth -0.090 -0.057 -0.127* -0.159 -0.038 -0.103** -0.076* -0.039(-1.157) (-1.356) (-1.912) (-1.430) (-0.576) (-2.378) (-1.814) (-0.743)

Q -0.015* -0.031*** -0.031*** -0.033*** -0.030*** -0.035*** -0.038*** -0.045***(-1.957) (-7.147) (-3.938) (-2.731) (-3.758) (-8.413) (-8.880) (-9.419)

IndSalesVol 1.299 0.452 0.370 0.245 1.043* 1.790** 1.471** 1.495**(1.375) (0.845) (0.467) (0.318) (1.713) (2.373) (2.541) (2.267)

ProfitVol 1.033* -0.252 0.236 -0.241 0.127 -0.381* -0.655*** -0.465*(1.922) (-1.224) (0.604) (-0.821) (0.385) (-1.734) (-3.131) (-1.893)

Age -0.040 -0.041** -0.080** -0.077** -0.072** -0.030 -0.032 -0.035(-1.006) (-1.961) (-2.344) (-2.363) (-2.390) (-1.156) (-1.450) (-1.285)

Constant 0.680*** 0.367* 0.550*** 0.565*** 0.371*** 0.331***(6.857) (1.955) (4.093) (3.115) (3.962) (5.174)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes No Yes Yes No No Yes NoYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.004 0.000 0.011 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.063 0.041 0.043 0.086 0.023 0.203 0.160

Observations 434 1866 1322 866 1659 1116 1050 1241R2 0.651 0.427 0.416 0.366 0.401 0.350 0.382 0.383

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 50: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Panel B

Dependent variable: Unused LC-to-Cash

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Beta Asset -0.257***(-3.591)

Beta Cash -0.170***(-3.879)

Beta Bank -0.523**(-2.406)

Beta Tail -0.210(-1.422)

Beta Equity -0.233***(-3.560)

Beta KMV -0.073***(-2.854)

Beta Gap -0.013(-1.302)

Beta Cash Flow -0.009(-0.769)

Profitability -0.127** 0.084** 0.036 0.247** -0.047 0.081** 0.049 0.04(-2.175) (2.500) (0.636) (2.384) (-0.853) (2.358) (1.516) (1.035)

Tangibility -0.220* -0.027 -0.057 0.058 -0.015 0.040 0.054 0.063(-1.889) (-0.367) (-0.584) (0.411) (-0.164) (0.483) (0.687) (0.825)

Size 0.100*** 0.045*** 0.068*** 0.016 0.080*** 0.041*** 0.049*** 0.053***(6.858) (4.669) (4.026) (0.857) (6.209) (4.007) (5.103) (5.366)

Networth -0.094 -0.044 -0.132** -0.181* 0.015 -0.083** -0.052 0.001(-1.203) (-1.152) (-2.159) (-1.740) -0.248 (-2.130) (-1.341) (0.013)

Q -0.012 -0.025*** -0.025*** -0.028** -0.020*** -0.029*** -0.029*** -0.036***(-1.591) (-6.459) (-3.772) (-2.244) (-2.725) (-7.450) (-7.449) (-8.000)

IndSalesVol 3.049** 0.820 0.438 0.054 0.863 1.652** 1.420** 0.96(2.209) (1.183) (0.385) (0.0415) (1.414) (2.160) (2.170) (1.473)

ProfitVol 0.787 -0.259 0.200 -0.389 0.094 -0.373* -0.518** -0.391*(1.502) (-1.269) -0.562 (-1.253) (0.293) (-1.769) (-2.541) (-1.690)

Ln Age -0.053 -0.017 -0.063 -0.048 -0.033 -0.008 -0.012 0.007(-1.306) (-0.727) (-1.487) (-1.074) (-1.132) (-0.320) (-0.491) (0.281)

Constant 0.458*** 0.304 0.383*** 0.402*** 0.232*** 0.162*(4.695) (1.373) (2.981) (3.977) (2.632) (1.657)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes No Yes Yes No No Yes NoYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.003 0.000 0.022 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.081 0.337 0.080 0.155 0.262 0.058 0.085

Observations 348 1437 963 574 1396 1114 1048 1241R2 0.632 0.388 0.388 0.310 0.373 0.318 0.346 0.352

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 51: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 7: Sorting on proxies for financing constraintsThis table reports regressions of a measure of line of credit usage in corporate liquidity policy on differentproxies for asset beta and controls. The dependent variable is LC-to-Cash, defined in Table 1. Beta KMVis the firm’s asset (unlevered) beta, calculated from equity (levered) betas and a Merton-KMV formula.V ar KMV is the corresponding value for total asset variance. Beta Tail is a measure of beta that isbased on the average stock return of a firm in the days in which the stock market had its worst 5% returnsin the year. All beta and variance measures are instrumented with their first two lags. In column (1) weuse a sample of small firms (those with Assets in the 30th percentile and lower). In column (2) we usea sample of large firms (those with Assets in the 70th percentile and higher). In column (3) we use asample of firms with low payouts (those with payout in the 30th percentile and lower). In column (4) weuse a sample of firms with high payouts (those with payout in the 70th percentile and higher). In column(5) we use a sample of firms that have neither a bond, nor a commercial paper rating. In column (6) weuse a sample of firms that have both bond and commercial paper ratings. Panel A reports results usingBeta KMV, and Panel B reports results using Beta Tail. All other variables are described in Table 1.Robust t-statistics presented in parenthesis.

Panel A - Beta KMV

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Small Large Low payout High payout Non-rated Ratedfirms firms firms firms firms firms

Beta KMV -0.236** -0.002 -0.191*** 0.027 -0.069 0.092(-2.077) (-0.029) (-3.483) (0.492) (-1.467) (0.789)

Var KMV 6.628 -6.751** 2.739 -4.972** -0.634 -14.317*(1.523) (-2.387) (1.260) (-2.170) (-0.329) (-1.706)

Profitability 0.136* 0.156 0.217*** -0.039 0.029 0.038(1.663) (1.560) (3.882) (-0.640) (0.670) (0.155)

Tangibility -0.011 -0.003 -0.011 0.036 0.013 0.007(-0.338) (-0.080) (-0.404) (1.112) (0.532) (0.089)

Size 0.109*** 0.004 0.072*** 0.036*** 0.056*** 0.010(4.655) (0.447) (7.508) (4.897) (6.109) (0.496)

Networth -0.060** -0.186*** -0.080*** -0.174*** -0.119*** -0.267***(-2.008) (-4.821) (-3.463) (-6.371) (-6.235) (-3.478)

Q -0.006 -0.066*** -0.026*** -0.053*** -0.044*** -0.054***(-0.458) (-9.372) (-4.273) (-10.778) (-10.392) (-3.140)

IndSalesVol 0.188 -0.149 0.000 -0.581** -0.090 0.104(0.668) (-0.474) (0.002) (-2.454) (-0.494) (0.199)

ProfitVol -0.201 0.365* -0.047 0.192 0.164 0.154(-1.012) (1.732) (-0.394) (1.266) (1.611) (0.249)

Age -0.009 -0.039*** -0.037*** -0.051*** -0.054*** -0.048*(-0.521) (-2.995) (-3.741) (-4.793) (-6.044) (-1.800)

Constant -0.046 0.819*** 0.293** 0.548*** 0.437*** 0.551**(-0.231) (5.966) (2.239) (4.288) (4.389) (2.238)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.913 0.001 0.284 0.012 0.400 0.262

Observations 8436 12578 14908 14162 22546 4344R2 0.105 0.148 0.182 0.170 0.138 0.164

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 52: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Panel B - Beta Tail

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Small Large Low payout High payout Non-rated Ratedfirms firms firms firms firms firms

Beta Tail -0.228*** -0.019 -0.178*** -0.091** -0.151*** 0.077(-4.518) (-0.385) (-4.452) (-2.481) (-4.556) (0.736)

Var KMV 2.578* -6.301*** -0.305 -1.787 0.199 -12.204*(1.833) (-3.194) (-0.260) (-1.319) (0.193) (-1.766)

Profitability 0.133*** 0.161 0.207*** 0.013 0.077* 0.061(2.621) (1.589) (4.448) (0.228) (1.943) (0.248)

Tangibility -0.010 -0.005 -0.012 0.030 0.005 0.008(-0.353) (-0.122) (-0.461) (0.928) (0.221) (0.098)

Size 0.109*** 0.006 0.070*** 0.048*** 0.069*** 0.006(8.191) (0.541) (9.223) (7.639) (9.636) (0.301)

Networth -0.076*** -0.182*** -0.083*** -0.150*** -0.103*** -0.276***(-3.878) (-4.730) (-4.063) (-5.829) (-5.789) (-3.430)

Q -0.003 -0.066*** -0.025*** -0.048*** -0.036*** -0.061***(-0.520) (-9.072) (-4.638) (-9.650) (-8.922) (-4.136)

IndSalesVol 0.155 -0.142 0.156 -0.560** -0.073 0.052(0.592) (-0.450) (0.724) (-2.370) (-0.406) (0.100)

ProfitVol 0.012 0.375* 0.079 0.161 0.186** 0.179(0.095) (1.793) (0.773) (1.062) (1.972) (0.291)

Age -0.023* -0.038*** -0.043*** -0.050*** -0.057*** -0.050*(-1.679) (-2.956) (-4.465) (-4.736) (-6.458) (-1.852)

Constant 0.047 0.810*** 0.334*** 0.474*** 0.358*** 0.600**(0.404) (5.787) (2.820) (3.693) (3.921) (2.369)

Industry Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesYear Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

First-stage F-stat p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.084 0.001 0.000 0.076 0.000 0.345

Observations 8418 12573 14892 14151 22528 4344R2 0.108 0.149 0.184 0.171 0.140 0.164

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 53: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 8: Aggregate risk exposure and credit line spreadsThis table reports regressions of line of credit spreads on systematic risk exposure and controls. LIBORis the level of the LIBOR (in percentage) in the quarter in which a deal was initiated, for each firm. NewLC is the total size of deals initiated in a firm-year, scaled by assets. All other variables are described inTable 1. All proxies for beta are instrumented with their first two lags. Robust z-statistics presented inparenthesis.

Dependent variables:

All-in drawn spread Undrawn spread(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Beta KMV 0.104 0.051***(1.525) (3.560)

SysVar KMV 10.029*** 3.124***(2.740) (4.047)

Beta Tail 0.142** 0.047***(2.347) (4.077)

LIBOR -0.005 -0.005 -0.001 0.003 0.001 0.005(-0.242) (-0.230) (-0.051) (0.631) (0.188) (1.291)

New LC -0.236*** -0.237*** -0.240*** -0.018*** -0.020*** -0.020***(-3.355) (-3.555) (-3.503) (-5.102) (-6.620) (-6.954)

Profitability -1.852*** -1.732*** -1.897*** -0.095*** -0.073** -0.120***(-11.885) (-10.871) (-12.435) (-3.163) (-2.359) (-4.351)

Tangibility 0.131** 0.142** 0.140** 0.027** 0.030** 0.030**(2.192) (2.390) (2.367) (2.205) (2.451) (2.555)

Size -0.368*** -0.362*** -0.376*** -0.046*** -0.044*** -0.049***(-45.526) (-48.126) (-41.431) (-27.482) (-26.389) (-26.738)

Networth -1.212*** -1.217*** -1.237*** -0.193*** -0.188*** -0.196***(-20.204) (-21.222) (-20.412) (-17.657) (-18.006) (-18.657)

Q -0.150*** -0.164*** -0.154*** -0.036*** -0.038*** -0.035***(-10.034) (-10.493) (-11.052) (-12.703) (-12.967) (-14.002)

IndSalesVol 0.238 0.219 0.131 -0.057 -0.046 -0.099(0.521) (0.488) (0.291) (-0.629) (-0.512) (-1.149)

ProfitVol 2.266*** 1.823*** 2.275*** 0.128* 0.047 0.173***(6.337) (4.695) (7.392) (1.880) (0.623) (2.978)

Constant 4.790*** 4.726*** 4.828*** 0.668*** 0.659*** 0.683***(21.626) (22.075) (22.695) (18.972) (19.000) (21.034)

Year Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed-effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesFst.-stage F-stat p-val 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Hansen J-stat p-value 0.017 0.082 0.652 0.942 0.753 0.381

Observations 6799 6895 6774 5977 6084 5973R2 0.559 0.550 0.559 0.404 0.405 0.405

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 54: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 9: Aggregate risk and the choice between cash and credit lines:Time-series testsThis table reports regressions of aggregate credit line initiations and changes in aggregate cash holdings onmacroeconomic variables. We estimate the SUR (seemingly-unrelated regression model) in equation (33)in the text. The dependent variable in columns (1) to (3) of Panel A is LCInitiations, which is definedas the sum of all credit line initiations in the LPC-Deal Scan sample in a given year, scaled by aggregateassets. The dependent variable in columns (1) to (3) in Panel B is Change in Cash, which is defined as thechange in aggregate cash holdings in the LPC-Deal Scan sample scaled by aggregate assets, see equation(28) in the text. The dependent variable in columns (4) to (6) of Panel A (Panel B) is the average residualvalue of LC Initiations (Change in Cash) after controlling for the firm characteristics in equation (31),excluding Beta and year fixed effects. The independent variables are V IX, the implied volatility on S&P500 index options, BankV IX, the expected volatility on an index of bank stock returns (computed using aGARCH model), CP Spread, the 3-month commercial paper-treasury spread, Real GDP Growth, and atime trend. All independent variables are lagged one period. Robust z-statistics presented in parenthesis.

Dependent Variables:LC Initiations Resid. LC Init.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Panel A:

V IXt−1 -0.040*** -0.022** -0.054*** -0.022(-3.856) (-2.259) (-2.632) (-1.064)

Bank V IXt−1 -0.033*** -0.024*** -0.053*** -0.044***(-4.944) (-3.463) (-4.122) (-3.005)

CP Spreadt−1 0.002 0.007** 0.006* 0.001 0.010 0.008(0.459) (2.116) (1.887) (0.122) (1.503) (1.309)

Real GDP Growtht−1 0.087* -0.013 0.013 0.159 -0.002 0.024(1.756) (-0.261) (0.300) (1.592) (-0.022) (0.252)

Time Trendt−1 -0.066 0.282** 0.192* 0.429** 0.989*** 0.899***(-0.631) (2.430) (1.726) (2.051) (4.412) (3.847)

Constant 0.014*** 0.020*** 0.021*** 0.000 0.013* 0.013**(4.512) (5.733) (6.580) (0.023) (1.860) (1.989)

Observations 20 20 20 20 20 20R-squared 0.487 0.598 0.679 0.404 0.566 0.589

Chg. Cash Resid. Chg. CashPanel B:

V IXt−1 0.040** 0.054*** 0.092** 0.060(2.213) (2.642) (2.358) (1.367)

Bank V IXt−1 0.002 -0.019 0.066** 0.042(0.120) (-1.299) (2.328) (1.321)

CP Spreadt−1 -0.003 -0.003 0.001 0.006 -0.005 -0.001(-0.448) (-0.383) (0.078) (0.449) (-0.342) (-0.085)

Real GDP Growtht−1 -0.084 -0.078 -0.143 0.057 0.258 0.186(-0.959) (-0.728) (-1.498) (0.301) (1.246) (0.907)

Time Trendt−1 0.058 0.039 0.265 0.223 -0.478 -0.227(0.316) (0.150) (1.114) (0.565) (-0.963) (-0.447)

Constant 0.000 0.007 0.006 -0.024** -0.035** -0.036**(0.043) (0.944) (0.885) (-2.086) (-2.303) (-2.509)

Observations 20 20 20 20 20 20R-squared 0.240 0.054 0.299 0.240 0.235 0.301

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 55: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Table 10. Aggregate risk, credit line contractual terms and changes intotal debtThis table reports regressions of credit line contractual terms (maturity and spreads) and changes inaggregate debt on macroeconomic variables. In columns (1) and (2), and (3) and (4), we estimate theSUR (seemingly-unrelated regression model) in equation (34) in the text. The dependent variable incolumns (1) and (3) is AverageMaturity, which is defined as the average maturity (weighted by the sizeof the facility) in the LPC-Deal Scan sample for each year in the sample period. The dependent variablein columns (2) and (4) is AverageSpread, which is defined as the average all-in-drawn spread (weightedby the size of the facility) in the LPC-Deal Scan sample for each year in the sample period. In columns(5) and (6) we estimate a SUR model such as that in equation (33) in the text, replacing LCInitiationswith ChangeinDebt, which is defined in equation (35) in the text. The variable represents the aggregatechange in total debt (short plus long term) in the LPC-Deal Scan sample for each year, scaled by aggregateassets. The independent variables are V IX, the implied volatility on S&P 500 index options, BankV IX,the expected volatility on an index of bank stock returns (computed using a GARCH model, CPspread,the 3-month commercial paper-treasury spread, Real GDP Growth, and a time trend. All independentvariables are lagged one period. Robust z-statistics presented in parenthesis.

Dependent Variables:

Avg.Maturity

Avg.Spread

Avg.Maturity

Avg.Spread

Agg.Changein totaldebt

Agg.Changein totaldebt

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)V IXt−1 -26.192*** 1.756** 0.026

(-3.808) (2.284) (0.668)Bank V IXt−1 -12.269** 0.733 -0.011

(-2.063) (1.214) (-0.390)CP Spreadt−1 -4.475* 0.500* -2.483 0.382 0.025* 0.027*

(-1.870) (1.869) (-0.817) (1.238) (1.809) (1.832)Real GDP Growtht−1 55.280* -4.497 17.584 -2.243 0.601*** 0.567***

(1.661) (-1.209) (0.403) (-0.506) (3.178) (2.709)Time Trendt−1 -184.984*** 2.416 -53.980 -5.414 -0.787** -0.669

(-2.650) (0.310) (-0.516) (-0.510) (-1.984) (-1.333)Constant 17.892*** 0.567** 18.138*** 0.590* -0.002 0.008

(8.898) (2.523) (5.732) (1.836) (-0.140) (0.556)

Observations 20 20 20 20 20 20R-squared 0.582 0.328 0.405 0.211 0.516 0.509

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.

Page 56: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Figure 1: Timeline of the model 

 

 

Page 57: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Figure 2: Equilibrium with cash holdings for systematic firms when systematic risk is high (θ ≥ θmax) 

 

Page 58: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Figure 3: Aggregate risk and time series changes in cash and credit line 

initiations 

This figure reports changes in aggregate credit line initiations and changes in aggregate cash holdings. LC Initiations is defined as the sum of all credit line initiations in the LPC-Deal Scan sample in a given year, scaled by aggregate assets. Change in Cash is defined as the change in aggregate cash holdings in the LPC-Deal Scan sample scaled by aggregate assets. VIX is the implied volatility on S&P 500 index options, lagged one period (VIX is divided by 10 in this figure).

-0.01

-0.005

0

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025

0.03

0.035

1988 1993 1998 2003 2008

Lvix

ChgCash

LC Init

 

Page 59: Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines of ...pages.stern.nyu.edu/~sternfin/vacharya/public_html/lccash_0101201… · Aggregate Risk and the Choice between Cash and Lines

Figure 4: Aggregate risk and time series changes in credit line 

contractual terms 

This table reports over-time changes in credit line contractual terms (maturity and spreads). Average Maturity is defined as the average maturity (weighted by the size of the facility) in the LPC-Deal Scan sample for each year in the sample period. Average Spread is defined as the average all-in-drawn spread (weighted by the size of the facility) in the LPC-Deal Scan sample for each year in the sample period. It is expressed in basis points and divided by 10. VIX is the implied volatility on S&P 500 index options, lagged one period. VIX is expressed in percentage points, and divided by two.

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

1988 1993 1998 2003 2008year

AvgMaturity

AvgSpread

Lvix

 


Recommended