+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Almeida the Labor

Almeida the Labor

Date post: 03-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: erydmardhatillah
View: 215 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 22

Transcript
  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    1/22

    The labor market effects of foreign owned firms

    Rita Almeida

    The World Bank, United States

    Received 15 March 2004; received in revised form 28 September 2006; accepted 31 October 2006

    Abstract

    Foreign firms have a more educated workforce and pay higher wages than domestic firms even after

    controlling for worker quality, at a given moment in time. This does not imply that foreign ownership

    improves the labor market outcomes of the workers since foreign investment may be guided by unobservable

    firm and worker characteristics correlated with schooling or wages. This paper asks whether foreign investors

    acquire firms with high human capital or wages, or whether foreign acquisition improves these outcomes.

    Using a matched employeremployee data set, I find that foreign acquisitions of domestic firms have small

    effects on the human capital and on average wages of the acquired firms. Instead, foreign investors cherry

    pick those domestic firms that are already very similar to the group of existing foreign firms.

    2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Foreign direct investment; Acquisitions; Employment; Wage structure; Panel data

    JEL classification: C31; F23; J31

    1. Introduction

    A large empirical literature documents that, in the cross-section, foreign firms are larger, more

    productive, more capital intensive, pay higher wages and have a more skilled workforce than

    Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

    www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

    I am very grateful to Antonio Ciccone for raising my interest in the topic and for his guidance and to Pedro Carneiro for

    very valuable comments. I am also very grateful to the editor and two anonymous referees for many detailed comments that

    substantially improved the paper. I am grateful to the Department of Statistics of the Portuguese Ministry of Employment for

    access to the data. I thank Koen Debacker, Jaume Garcia, Maia Gell, Adriana Kugler andJos Mata forseveral suggestions.

    I benefited from comments made at the Spie, UPF, Simposio de Analisis Economico, UNL, CEPR conference

    Globalization and labor markets(Bergen), World Bank and IIOC (Chicago). All the errors are my own. I gratefully

    acknowledge the financial support ofFundao para a Cincia e Tecnologia

    . 1818 H Street, NW, MSN MC3-301, Washington, DC 20433, USA.

    E-mail address: [email protected].

    0022-1996/$ - see front matter 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.10.001

    mailto:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.10.001http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.10.001mailto:[email protected]
  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    2/22

    domestic firms. This suggests that foreign investors may have a positive effect on the welfare of

    the workforce of the host economy. This argument has been used to justify regional or national

    industrial policies to attract and secure foreign investment. But, while cross-sectional differences

    are large, they are not necessarily causal. For example, they may arise because foreigners acquiredomestic firms that already have a more educated workforce and pay higher wages than the

    average firm, because foreign investment leads to an increase in the demand for skills and average

    wages of the acquired firms, or both. Disentangling correlation from causality is crucial for

    understanding the welfare effects of foreign investment in the host economy and for designing

    appropriate policies.

    In this paper, I analyze the interaction between foreign ownership and labor market outcomes

    using a Portuguese matched employeremployee data set during the nineties. The paper

    addresses the following questions: (1) Do foreigners acquire domestic firms with high human

    capital and that pay higher wages even after controlling for worker quality? (2) Does foreign

    ownership improve the labor market outcomes of the acquired firms? To quantify the effects offoreign ownership, I analyze the evolution in total employment, human capital of the workforce

    and average wages conditional on worker quality following a foreign acquisition of a domestic

    firm.1 The main findings of the paper can be summarized as follows. Most of the large cross

    sectional differences between foreign and domestic firms are explained by foreigners cherry

    picking the domestic firms. In the years prior to the acquisition, firms that will become

    acquired are already larger, employ a more educated workforce and pay higher hourly wages for

    a given worker quality (both to low and high educated workers) than the average domestic firm

    in the sector. Moreover, before the foreign acquisition firms are already very similar to the group

    of existing foreign firms. Consistently with the few theories of foreign acquisitions, these

    findings strongly suggest that foreign acquisitions are not random. When foreign firms enter anew country and/or a new product market, by acquiring an existing firm it is more likely that

    they choose firms with relatively high productivity and with technological characteristics that

    are similar to their own (Hennart and Park, 1993; Buckley and Casson, 1998). Otherwise,

    foreigners would face very high costs of adapting the technology, changing the workforce and

    gaining experience in the host country. In Portugal the costs of adjusting the workforce are

    particularly high since it has one of the most restrictive employment protection regulations in

    the world. I also find evidence that the change in the nationality of the ownership has little effect

    on different labor market outcomes of the acquired firms. By comparing the same firms before

    and after the acquisition, I find that following the acquisition the size of the firm increases but

    that there is no significant change in the human capital of the average worker in the firm. 2

    Moreover, there is evidence that following the acquisition average wages increase slightly in

    manufacturing firms but these results are in stark contrast with the large cross sectional

    estimates of the foreign wage premium. Suggestive evidence shows that this might not be

    specific to foreign acquisitions since wages go up by similar magnitudes following domestic

    acquisitions.

    The Portuguese case is interesting because it combines two important features. First, Portugal

    had a permissive legal framework for the operation of foreign firms that translated into substantial

    1 Other papers have used foreign acquisitions to quantify the foreign wage premium (e.g., Aitken et al., 1996; Conyon

    et al., 2002a; Lipsey and Sjoholm, 2002). See Navaretti and Venables (2004) for a survey.2 I find that employment in the firm increases on average by 14% following the foreign acquisition. However, this

    evidence should be interpreted cautiously since there is also evidence of selection of foreign investment into firms where

    employment was growing faster prior to the acquisition.

    76 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    3/22

    amounts of foreign direct investment (FDI) in the late eighties and nineties. Before becoming an

    European Union member in 1986, the amount of FDI in Portugal had never reached 1% of GDP

    (3.2% of total investment) and in the beginning of the nineties this influx had more than tripled to

    3.2% of GDP (12% of total investment in 1990).

    3

    Second, there exists a census of all the firmsoperating in Portugal covering the nineties. For each firm in this data set, foreign participation can

    be traced over time so that the identification of foreign acquisitions of domestic firms is possible.

    Moreover, since it is a matched employeremployee data set, workforce characteristics can also

    be traced over time making this data particularly well suited for the analysis of the effects of

    foreign ownership on labor market outcomes.

    One of the contributions of the paper is to provide a systematic evaluation of the impact of

    foreign investment on different labor market outcomes of workers in the host country. While

    there is some evidence for the UK that foreigners buy domestic firms with above average

    productivity and wages, little is known about the human capital characteristics of firms that are

    acquired by foreigners (e.g., Harris and Robinson, 2002; Girma and Grg, 2003a,b; Conyonet al., 2002a).4 There is also evidence that following a foreign acquisition average wages

    increase slightly but it is unclear whether this is the result of worker reallocation and changes in

    the firm's human capital or as a result of increases in labor productivity (e.g., Conyon et al.,

    2002a; Girma and Grg, 2003a,b). The main reason for this lack of knowledge is the difficulty

    in obtaining datasets that simultaneously have information on characteristics of the firm and of

    its workforce over time. Using a sample of Indonesian manufacturing firms Lipsey and Sjoholm

    (2002) focus on the evolution of employment and average wages within broad skill groups

    following a foreign acquisition.5 The Portuguese data has the advantage of covering both

    manufacturing and non-manufacturing sectors and to have, for each year, detailed information

    on all wage earners in the private sector. Since each individual is uniquely matched with a firm,several workforce characteristics are observed for each firm. Interestingly, my findings for

    foreign acquisitions in Portugal are closer to those found for the UK and are quite different from

    those found by Lipsey and Sjoholm (2002) for Indonesia. Lipsey and Sjoholm (2002) do not

    find evidence of selection of foreign investment into high wage firms and show that following

    the acquisition average wages increase substantially, possibly due to increases in productivity.6

    They also show that the employment of blue collar workers and average wages within

    occupations increase after the acquisition. The stark contrast with my findings suggest that the

    effects of foreign acquisitions in the labor markets in developed and developing countries can be

    quite different.

    My paper is also related with the literature that investigates the foreign wage premium (seeTable A.1 in the appendix for a summary). If foreigners are in a disadvantaged position to attract

    the best workers, they would have to pay higher wages than comparable domestic firms with

    3 The most important sources of FDI into Portugal is the European Union and OECD, with 76% and 89% of the FDI in

    1992.4 Harris and Robinson (2002) and Girma and Grg (2003a,b) find evidence ofcherry picking of foreign investment

    into UK firms with a high level and growth of productivity. Conyon et al. (2002a) also find evidence that acquired firms

    pay above average wages.5 Table A1 shows that Lipsey and Sjoholm (2002) have information on average wages for blue and white collar

    workers but they do not have information on schooling or other worker characteristics. Lipsey and Sjoholm (2004) have

    information on schooling but it is only available in 1996.6 Arnold and Javorcik (2005) find evidence for Indonesian plants that foreign ownership leads to an increase in

    productivity in the acquired plants by approximately 30% over the three years following the acquisition. In contrast,

    Harris and Robinson (2002) find that for the UK, average firm productivity falls in the short run following a foreign

    acquisition.

    77R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    4/22

    similar worker quality.7 I am also motivated by the evaluation of the effects of acquisitions on

    labor reallocation. Ownership changes are often associated with the real-location of resources

    from inefficient to efficient firms. This can cause the displacement of jobs and lower wages and it

    is a source of preoccupation for workers and labor unions (e.g., Harris and Robinson, 2002).Furthermore, firm acquisitions may change the allocation of monopoly rents between firms and

    workers which can also lead to wage changes (McGuckin and Nguyen, 2001). Finally, my work

    also relates to the literature that studies the profile of firms acquired by foreigners, and the motives

    for a foreign acquisition of a domestic firm.

    The paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, I describe the data and the sample used.

    Section 3 presents evidence on how much better foreign-owned firms look at any point in time

    and asks whether foreigners select the best domestic firms to be acquired. Section 4 analyzes the

    effects of foreign acquisitions on different labor market outcomes. Section 5 discusses the

    robustness of the results. Section 6 concludes.

    2. Data

    The data set used is a based on a mandatory yearly survey conducted by the Portuguese

    Ministry of Employment, Quadros do Pessoal. The survey covers all the firms with wage-earners

    in Portugal excluding the public sector. It is a matched employeremployee data where firms can

    be traced over time and each period workers can be matched to firms.8 The survey collects firm

    information on the ownership of the capital (foreign, domestic private and public), five digit-ISIC

    sector, region, size and age of the firm. It also reports detailed worker characteristics like gender,

    age, schooling, tenure on the job, monthly hours worked (normal and extra hours) and gross

    monthly wage.To construct the sample, I identified all the firms that changed the nationality of their

    ownership during the period covered 19911998.9 I consider a firm to be foreign owned if the

    share of foreign capital is larger than 10%.10 I selected all the firms that are continuously owned

    by domestic and foreign owners. I kept only those firms that report information on key variables

    in the paper like wages, hours worked and schooling. I identify 1381 firms that change the

    nationality of their ownership between 1991 and 1998, of which 688 are foreign acquisitions

    (domestic firms acquired by foreigner firms) and 505 domestic acquisitions (foreign firms

    7 There are different reasons for foreigners paying higher wages (e.g., Navaretti and Venables, 2004). First, workers

    could have a preference for domestic firms. This could happen if, for example, foreign firms are perceived to be morevolatile employers. There is little evidence supporting this claim, though. Second, foreigners might be more likely to

    minimize turnover if they invest more in training or want to avoid the leakage of their technological advantages. Third, a

    foreigners might be interested in attracting the best workers.8 By law the information collected is sent to the Ministry of Employment and latter is made available to all the workers

    in the firm. Since the data is administrative and it is made available it tends to be very reliable. The survey has been

    conducted since 1982 and is organized in firm, plant and individual files. The firm level data covers 148,044 firms in

    1991 and 224,456 in 1998. The individual files cover approximately 2 million workers each year.9 Some observations report missing information on the ownership structure of the capital. I tested the robustness of the

    results to excluding these firms and to make different assumptions on the nationality of the capital. Firms observed just

    once are assumed to be domestic firms, given its similarity in size, education and average wages to the average domestic

    firm in the same sector. Firms observed more than once, are assumed that they kept either their last ownership structure or

    an average of the past ownership's structure (more than 95% of these firms are assumed to be domestic). Since I suspect

    measurement error problems for those firms with more than one ownership change, these firms were excluded from the

    sample (less than 3% of the acquisitions).10 The choice of the 10% threshold is not restrictive since 95% (75%) of the firms with positive foreign ownership have

    more than 10% (50%) of foreign capital and 50% of the firms with a foreign participation have a full foreign ownership.

    78 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    5/22

    acquired by domestic firms).11 About 90% of the acquisitions in the sample are observed for three

    or more periods.12

    Since I am interested in analyzing the effects of foreign ownership on firm's characteristics of

    the workforce, I aggregate these at the firm level. This aggregation is possible because eachworker has a unique firm identifier. I consider a worker to be low educated if it has nine or less

    years of schooling and a worker to be high educated if it has more than nine years of schooling.13

    Gross monthly wages are computed summing up monthly labor earnings for regular and extra

    work hours. Hourly wages are gross wages divided by total monthly hours worked. Firm average

    wages are computed excluding extreme values for hourly wages.14 The price cost margin is

    defined as total sales minus total labor costs divided by total sales.15 The consumer price index

    comes from National Department of Statistics. The level of aggregation used for sector

    composition was two-digit ISIC sector (total 46 sectors).

    3. Evidence on selection of foreign investment

    In this section I document the differences between foreign and domestic owned firms and

    examine whether firms that become acquired by foreigners have an average worker with a very

    different quality than the typical domestic firm. The latter is important to understand the

    motivations for foreign entry. Moreover, there is almost no evidence in the literature on the human

    capital profile of the average worker in acquired firms. This is important since foreign firms are

    often associated with a better technology and a more intensive use of skilled labor than domestic

    firms. However, this need not translate into an increase in the employment of skilled workers, as

    long as foreigners acquire firms that already have the desired worker profile.

    Looking at the theoretical and empirical literature on mergers and acquisitions it is difficult toextract strong predictions about the profile of the acquired firm and its post acquisition

    performance. This literature has identified two motives for acquisitions independently of the

    nationality of the acquiring firm. The neoclassical approach views acquisitions as a form of

    natural selection motivated by profit maximizing managers which result in the replacement of

    inefficient firms (Lichtenberg and Seigel, 1987, 1990).16 Alternatively, acquisitions could be

    made by managers motivated to acquire operating efficiency (McGuckin and Nguyen, 1995). In

    11 Domestic firms are firms with at least 90% of national capital each year, foreign firms are firms with at least 10% of

    foreign capital each year and acquisitions are firms that changed once their ownership nationality over the sample period.In the final sample there are 194,560 domestic firms, 2350 foreign firms and 1381 acquisitions. In the manufacturing

    sample, there are 40,873 domestic firms, 701 foreign firms and 205 foreign acquisitions of domestic firms.12 81% and 72% of the foreign acquisitions are observed one year before and one year after the acquisition, respectively.

    About 50% and 52% of the foreign acquisitions are observed two years before and two years after the acquisition,

    respectively.13 I prefer the aggregation by education groups rather than by occupational groups since it is less ambiguous and also

    less likely to be affected by ownership changes. In the worker level data there is a positive correlation between education

    and skills: 84% of the high educated are skilled workers and 40% of the low educated are unskilled workers.14 Workers with implausibly low earnings (hourly wage lower than 50% of the minimum wage) or implausibly high

    earnings were excluded from the sample. There were less than 1% of the workers in each years in these cases.15 Unfortunately, the Portuguese data does not collect sufficient information to compute firm's productivity. It collects

    information on total sales but there is no information on raw materials or stock of capital in the firm. Approximately 9%

    of the firms in the sample report zero sales and hence do not have a price cost margin. I exclude from the analysis those

    firms with values below percentile 1 and above percentile 99 of the distribution for price cost margin.16 This theory also predicts that firms will perform better after the acquisition since they are disciplined by managers

    with cost savings policies.

    79R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    6/22

    this case, firms with high levels of productivity are more likely to change ownership.17 The

    empirical literature also shows different results. Lichtenberg and Seigel (1987, 1990) and Conyon

    et al. (2002b) find that firms with lower productivity or profits are more likely to be acquired by

    domestic firms, in the US and UK, respectively. Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987), Matsusaka(1993) and McGuckin and Nguyen (1995) find for the US that the more profitable and high

    productivity firms are more likely to change ownership.18

    The theory looking at the motivations of foreign acquisitions is more scarce but less

    ambiguous. Markusen (1995) shows that foreign firms prefer to establish capacity in the host

    country, in opposition to export or technology licensing, whenever firms have specific advantages

    that overcome the costs of entry. Caves (1996) and Pfaffermayr (1999) relate these advantages to

    economies of scale, brand names, management know-how and other types of advantages that can

    be exploited in different locations without incurring in additional costs. The literature on the

    motivations of the different entry modes argues that foreign firms are more likely to acquire an

    existing firm rather than start a new firm if they have little experience in producing in the hostcountry and learning costs are high, if they are entering a new product market or if there are high

    costs of increasing competition (Hennart and Park, 1993; Buckley and Casson, 1998). Moreover,

    conditional on choosing to acquire, foreign firms are more likely to buy domestic firms with

    relatively high productivity and with technological characteristics that are similar to their own.

    Otherwise, foreigners firms would face very high costs of adapting the technology, changing the

    workforce or of gaining experience in the host country.

    In Portugal, the costs of adapting the workforce are particularly important since it has one of the

    most restrictive employment protection regulations in the world. The legislation on collective

    dismissals imposes a long, complex and very costly dismissal process on employers. In particular,

    the employer must justify a worker's dismissal. The employer must also notify the impendingdismissal to the commission of workers as well as the Ministry of Employment. The dismissal will

    only become official after the commission issued an appraisal and after the worker is given the

    opportunity to dispute the allegations made. Dismissed workers must receive a written notice at least

    60 days prior to the dismissal. These workers then have certain benefits, which include time off to

    look for a new job, a financial compensation and a special right to resign. Except in the case of a

    disciplinary dismissal (serious infraction by the worker), the employer must pay the employee one

    monthly wage per year worked, with a minimum of three monthly payments. No maximum ceiling is

    established in the law for the severance payments. However, Portugal has a relatively flexible wage

    policy. The minimum wage is set annually at the national level and collective bargaining agreements

    establish the starting wage for each occupation. These wage floors are established at relatively lowlevels so that, in practice, employers have some flexibility in setting the wages. ( Bover et al., 1998,

    discuss in detail the Portuguese labor regulation). Together, these arguments suggest that in my

    sample, when foreigners choose to enter the market by acquiring an existing firm, they tend to select

    those firms that already have many of the characteristics that are desirable to them.

    17 Theoretical models also yield conflicting predictions for firm performance in the period following the acquisition.

    When acquisitions are motivated by managerial discipline, some models predict that firm performance improves

    following the acquisition. When acquisitions are motivated by the acquisition of operating efficiency, models predict that

    firm performance remains unchanged or decreases slightly following the acquisition. A negative performance could be

    more likely to occur with foreign acquisitions, where assimilation problems could potentially be larger.18 Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987) and Matsusaka (1993) show that firms and had little or no gain in productivity in the

    post-acquisition period. Conyon et al. (2002b) look specifically at the evolution of employment following a change in

    ownership. They find that acquisitions are generally followed by reductions in employment and output resulting in an

    increased efficiency in the use of labor.

    80 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    7/22

    The empirical analysis of foreign acquisitions for developed countries is focused on the UK

    and finds that acquiring foreign firms cherry pick domestic firms. However, nothing is known

    about the human capital of firms acquired by foreigners. For example, in the procedure of

    selection of foreign investment into firms with more educated workers, these firms would payhigher average wages in the pre acquisition period but would not necessarily pay higher wages

    conditional on worker's schooling. Alternatively, if selection of foreign investment is also based

    on unobservable firm characteristics (e.g., technological or organizational advantages) average

    wages for a given worker quality would already be higher in the pre acquisition period. One way

    of testing for selection of foreign investment, is to compare firms that will become acquired by

    foreigners, existing foreign firms and domestic owned firms that will not be acquired in the near

    future.19 I estimate the following equation for different outcomes:

    yjt bAj dFjXS

    s1

    gsDs XT

    t1

    gtDt jt 3:1

    whereyjtis the outcome of interest for firmjin period t(employment, average schooling, age, tenure,

    share of females in the firm, average hourly wage and pricecost margin),Aj is a dummy variable that

    assumes the value one in the years before the acquisition for those firms that will be acquired by

    foreigners,Fjis a dummy variable that assumes the value one if firmjis foreign owned in yeartandDsis a two digit sector dummy andDt is a time dummy for yeart. The foreign premium , represents the

    average difference in outcomeybetween foreign and domestic firms in the same sector of activity and

    year. If (future) foreign acquisitions are already better performers relatively to domestic firms in the

    years prior to the acquisition,should be large and statistically significant. Moreover, if future foreign

    acquisitions are very similar to existing foreign firms, I expect to see to be very similar to . On theother hand, if foreigners do notcherry pick domestic firms, should be small and different from .

    However, one would expect foreign firms to pay higher hourly wages simply because their

    workforce has a different human capital composition than the workforce in domestic firms.

    Mincer (1974), and a large literature that followed, shows that differences in education, age,

    tenure and gender are associated with significant differences in hourly wages. Hence, when the

    dependent variable in Eq. (3.1) is average hourly wages, I also control for differences across firms

    in average education, age, tenure and gender of the workers, so that the wage premiums captured

    by and exclude these composition effects.20 Eq. (3.1) is estimated by least squares using all

    the firms. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. The estimates are reported in columns (1)

    to (10) of Table 1. The table also reports the p-values for the test: =.I start by examining how foreign owned firms differ from the average firm in the same sector. In the

    sample, foreign firms are approximately twice the size of a domestic firms, but do not have more

    average hours of work per worker. The average years of schooling is almost two years higher than in a

    domestic firm of the same sector. The workforce in foreign owned firms is, on average, less than 1 year

    younger and the share of females is 3 percentage points higher than the workforce in domestic firms.

    19 An alternative way to test for selection is to estimate a probit model for the event of being acquired. This approach has

    been used by Clerides et al. (1998) to document selection of exporting firms. Using this approach the sign of the effect of

    each variable on the probability of being acquired would be the same as the sign in Table 1 (not reported).20 The estimated model is identical to the one reported in Eq. (3.1) where the dependent variable is the logarithm of real

    hourly wages per employee in firm j. The only difference is that I also control for Xjt, a vector of workforce

    characteristics including average years of schooling, average age, average job tenure and share of females in the

    workforce. A similar model is used to estimate the foreign wage premium for each education group. The only difference

    is that average wages and worker characteristics are relative the each education group.

    81R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    8/22

    Table1

    Differencesbetweenfutureforeignacquisitionsand

    foreignownedfirmsrelativelytodomesticfirms

    Employment

    Hourswork/

    totalworkers

    Yearsof

    schooling

    Age

    workforce

    Tenure

    workforce

    Females/

    totalworkers

    Average

    hourly

    wag

    e

    Loweducated

    hourlywage

    Higheducated

    hourlywage

    Price-cost

    margin

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10)

    Futureforeign

    acquisitions

    0.85

    0.0000

    1.6

    5

    1.37

    1.0

    7

    0.02

    0.32

    0.2

    4

    0.40

    0.001

    [0.0

    62]

    [0.0

    04]

    [0.0

    97]

    [0.2

    53]

    [0.2

    20]

    [0.0

    10]

    [0.014]

    [0.0

    13]

    [0.0

    17]

    [0.0

    01]

    Foreignfirms

    1.05

    0.0003

    1.9

    3

    0.66

    0.0

    1

    0.03

    0.40

    0.3

    2

    0.48

    0.0

    00

    [0.0

    30]

    [0.0

    02]

    [0.0

    43]

    [0.1

    20]

    [0.1

    08]

    [0.0

    04]

    [0.006]

    [0.0

    06]

    [0.0

    08]

    [0.0

    00]

    Sectordummie

    sincluded?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Timedummies

    included?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Av.schooling,

    age,tenure,

    sh.

    Females

    included?

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    No

    Ftest:Futureforeignacquisitions=

    Foreignfirm

    s(Pvalue)

    0.00

    0.7

    5

    0.0

    0

    0.00

    0.0

    0

    0.25

    0.00

    0.0

    0

    0.00

    0.0

    4

    N

    647,984

    647,9

    84

    647,9

    84

    647,984

    647,9

    84

    647,984

    647,9

    84

    616,4

    91

    256,9

    37

    579,2

    88

    Rsquared

    0.22

    0.0

    6

    0.4

    0

    0.11

    0.0

    6

    0.47

    0.43

    0.3

    9

    0.39

    0.1

    7

    Thenumbersin

    column(1)representthecoefficients

    ofaregressionoflogemploymentonadummyvariableifafirmwillbeco

    meacquiredbyforeignersandonadummyvariable

    ifthefirmisforeignowned.Controlsfortwodigitsectordummiesandyeardummiesincluded((3.1)intext).Standarderrorsa

    reclusteredatthefirmlevel.N

    isthe

    samplesizein

    eachregression

    .Pvaluesareforthetestthatthecoefficientonthefutureforeignacquisitionsisequaltothatofforeignownedfirms.Thecoefficientsforemploy

    ment,hoursof

    work,average

    hourlywages(average,lowandhigh)arebeinterpretedaspercentagedifferences(logdependentvariable).E.g.,

    0.85incolumn(1)impliesthatfutureforeign

    acquisitionsare

    85percentagepointslargerthantheaveragedomesticfirmintheyearspriortotheacquisition.1.6

    incolumn(3

    )impliesthattheaverageyearsofsch

    oolinginfirms

    acquiredbyforeignersis1.6yearshigherthaninth

    eaveragedomesticfirminthesecto

    r.

    82 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    9/22

    These differences in the workforce characteristics, if not accounted for, translate into differences in

    hourly wages across ownership types.21 Columns (8) and (9) of Table 1 report the foreign wage

    premium for each education group after controlling for differences across firms in average schooling,

    age, tenure and gender for each group respectively: it is 32% for the low education workers and 48%for the high education workers.22 This finding is consistent with Lipsey and Sjoholm's (2004) result of

    a foreign wage premium which is increasing with workers' skill.

    The estimates forreported in the table show that firms that in the future will become acquired by

    foreigners are already very different from the average domestic firm in the sector in the years prior to

    the acquisition. Future foreign acquisitions are 85% larger than domestic firms but do not differ in the

    average hours of work per employee. Two years before the acquisition they already have a more

    educated workforce since their average number of years of schooling is 1.6 years above the one in

    existing domestic firms. The workforce in these firms is also younger, less tenured and with more

    females than the workforce in domestic firms. Controlling for the differences in these human capital

    characteristics, I find evidence of selection of foreign investment into higher wage firms. Firms thatwill become acquired pay 32% higher average hourly wages than domestic firms. This premium

    holds for each education group since hourly wages are 24% and 40% higher for low and high

    educated workers, respectively. These wage premiums are below the average wage differences

    between foreign and domestic owned firms (32% for low educated and 48% for the high educated).

    The price cost margin is 0.1 percentage points lower than in the average domestic firm before the

    acquisition. However, one should be cautious when interpreting these findings since I cannot control

    for differences across firms in input prices. Finally, firms that will become acquired by foreigners are

    not statistically identical to foreign owned firms in the years prior to the acquisition, even though the

    differences are small in magnitude (the large size of the sample leads to very small standard errors).

    In sum, the results presented in this section, together with a large empirical literature, confirm thatthere are substantial differences between foreign and domestic firms. Foreign firms have a younger

    and more educated workforce than domestic firms. They also pay higher average wages, controlling

    for the quality of the workforce. Not accounting for differences in worker's quality leads us to

    overestimate the foreign wage premium by approximately one third. The findings also show that

    foreigners do not randomly pick domestic firms to be acquired. Several years prior to the acquisition,

    these firms outperform the typical domestic firm in the sector in terms of size, worker quality and

    hourly average wages. Moreover, I find evidence that selection on unobservable firm characteristics

    is also important. Controlling for observed worker quality, in the years prior to the foreign acquisition,

    the average hourly wages in acquired firms are much higher than in the average domestic firm.

    4. Does foreign ownership improve labor market outcomes?

    Since foreigners select the best domestic firms to be acquired and I do not observe all the

    variables foreigners select on, cross sectional estimates of the causal effects of foreign ownership

    on labor market outcomes are biased. Take, for example, the case of the foreign wage premium

    and assume that foreigners buy firms with more educated workers. If unobserved worker ability

    were independent of foreign acquisitions and positively correlated with schooling, then least

    21 In appendix A, available at http://econ.worldbank.org/staff/ralmeida, I show how the foreign hourly wage premium

    varies once I control for differences across firms in several workforce characteristics and when I allow the foreign

    premium to vary across sectors. Throughout the paper I assume a nationally competitive labor market so that workers

    move freely across regions. Relaxing this assumption leads to foreign wage premiums that are very similar.22 The number of observations for the hourly wage of high educated workers is smaller than in the other regressions

    since 60% of the firms do not report having high educated workers.

    83R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

    http://econ.worldbank.org/staff/ralmeidahttp://econ.worldbank.org/staff/ralmeida
  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    10/22

    squares estimates for the foreign wage premium may be downward biased (if foreign acquisitions

    and worker's schooling are positively correlated). Alternatively, unobservable technological

    characteristics of the firm or unobservable organizational capital which are positively correlated

    with the foreign acquisition may imply that the cross sectional estimates are biased upwards.Considering the motives for firm acquisition reviewed in the previous section, one would

    expect to observe at least some changes in the acquired firm due to technological or organizational

    restructuring of the firm. For example, plant closings can lead to large employment reductions.

    Technological change can lead to an increased use of more skilled workers and changes in the

    human capital, or it can lead to more on-the-job training with possibly different effects in the wages

    of different workers. All this depends on the characteristics of labor markets, on the importance of

    foreign acquisitions in the economy and on the directions of changes in the labor demand of

    acquired firms. For example, productivity increases can lead to shifts in the labor demand and, as a

    result, wages and employment may change. If foreign acquisitions correspond to a small part of

    employment in the sector and if labor markets are competitive, wages will not increase and therewill be only increases in the employment of the firm. Alternatively, wages may increase if foreign

    acquisitions have a strong impact on aggregate labor demand or if rigidities in the labor market

    imply that firms face an upward sloping labor supply curve (e.g., due to monopsony). In this

    section, I present reduced form estimates of the total effect of foreign acquisitions on a variety of

    labor market variables. The relationship I estimate is not a structural labor demand equation (e.g.,

    as in Hammermesh, 1993). However, it can be derived from it in some cases.23

    In order to obtain unbiased estimates of the effect of foreign ownership on different labor

    market outcomes, I need to take into account the possibility that foreign acquisitions are

    endogenous, i.e., they might occur as a reaction to some kind of unobserved firm specific shock.

    The findings in the previous section showed that foreign acquisitions are not random and thatforeigners acquire firms that systematically differ from the average domestic firm in the sector. If

    foreign acquisitions are driven mainly by (unobserved) permanent differences across firms, this

    endogeneity problem can potentially be addressed by examining the same firm over time and to

    compare the outcomes of interest in the period before and after the foreign acquisition.

    Econometrically, this would amount to estimating the following model with firm fixed effects:

    yjt kj dFjtXT

    t1

    gtDt jt 4:1

    where all notation is as above and j is a firm fixed effect. The error term, jt, is assumed to beuncorrelated across firms and time. The estimation of this equation requires longitudinal data for

    each firm. The identification of is done exclusively by firms that change the nationality of their

    ownership, i.e., that switch from a domestic to a foreign ownership.

    Estimating Eq. (4.1) only for the sample of foreign acquisitions could yield biased estimates of.

    In particular, it would be identical to comparing outcome yj in the pre and post-acquisition period

    without taking into account other aggregate shocks contemporaneous to the acquisition (Meyer,

    1994). Therefore, I include in the analysis a control group of domestic firms that identify the

    aggregate shocks in the economy captured by t . Domestic firms are a good control group for the

    23 In particular, under the assumption that labor supply curves faced by the firms are not affected by the nationality of

    their ownership, the reduced form effects are all due to changes in labor demand. Otherwise, they are the combination of

    labor supply and labor demand changes. Lichtenberg and Seigel (1992), Brown and Medoff (1988) and McGuckin and

    Nguyen (2001) use a specification (for employment) that is closer to this approach.

    84 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    11/22

    sample of acquired firms if both types of firm are growing at similar rates in the years prior to the

    acquisition (and hence are likely to be affected similarly by aggregate shocks). In other words, this

    approach would be invalid if firms which are acquired grow at systematically different rates than the

    average domestic firm. This evidence would suggest that foreign acquisitions would be correlatedwith some firm unobserved shock in growth rates and hence the beforeafter comparison would be

    invalid. Even though there is no formal way to test this claim, I present some evidence that this

    problem is not very important for several outcomes of interest. To do this I estimate a model similar to

    Eq. (3.1) but having the growth rate of the outcome yjt as dependent variable:

    lnyjtlnyjt1 bAj dFjXS

    s1

    gsDs XT

    t1

    gtDt ejt 4:2

    where all the notation is as in Eq. (3.1). This equation is estimated for all firms acquired by foreigners

    and for existing domestic and foreign owned firms. In this specification, measures the percentagepoint difference in the growth rate between firms that will be acquired by foreigners over the

    following years and domestic firms in the same sector. Analogously, measures the percentage point

    difference in the growth rate in existent foreign owned firms and domestic firms in the same sector.

    The results of estimating Eq. (4.2) for several outcomes with least squares are presented in

    columns (1) to (10) of Table 2. The evidence suggests that acquired firms are growing in the pre-

    acquisition period at rates that are not statistically different from the rates of growth in domestic firms

    in the same sector. The only exception is for the size of the firm, average tenure of the workers and the

    price cost margin. In these cases, there is evidence that firms acquired by foreigners were growing at

    higher rates prior to the acquisition than domestic firms (7 percentage points above for employment,

    0.03 years above for average tenure of the workforce and 1 percentage point above for the price-costmargin). Existing foreign firms tend to grow at a different rate than the rates acquired firms are

    growing in the pre-acquisition period, even though the quantitative differences are small.24 I interpret

    these findings as suggestive that for most of the outcomes of interest foreign acquisitions are a

    reaction to a permanent firm specific shock (and hence a first difference approach would yield

    unbiased estimates for the effect of foreign acquisitions) but that foreigners tend to acquire firms

    whose employment, tenure and price cost margin is growing above the average for the sector.

    The results of estimating Eq. (4.1) for foreign acquisitions and for existing domestic firms are

    reported in Table 3.25 Panel A reports the results when the sample includes firms in manufacturing

    and non-manufacturing sectors. The findings suggest that following an acquisition there is an

    increase of 14.5% in the total size of the firm. I do not find evidence of substantial restructuring of theworkforce in the acquired firm. There are no significant changes in the average education of the

    workforce following the acquisition, measured by the average years of schooling. I also do not find

    evidence that other demographic characteristics of the workforce (like age, tenure or gender) change

    substantially.26 All this evidence strongly suggests that the profile of the average worker in the firm is

    24 For most of the outcomes, I accept the null hypothesis that =. The exceptions include total employment, average

    hourly wage of high educated workers and the pricecost margin. Because firms could anticipate the effects of the

    acquisition, I tested the robustness of the results to including only growth rates two and three years before the acquisition

    for those firms that become acquired. The results are very similar (not reported).25 Since the differences in growth rates between acquired and foreign owned firms are quantitatively small (Table 2), I

    also test the robustness of the estimates in Table 3 to the inclusion of foreign owned firms as a control group. I do not find

    significant differences in the outcomes relatively to those reported in Table 3 (not reported).26 The coefficients for average age, tenure on-the-job and share of females in the workforce are statistically strong

    though quantitatively small.

    85R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    12/22

    Table2

    Differencesinthegrowthofoutcomesbetweenfutureforeignacquisitionsandforeignownedfirmsrelativelytodomesticfirms

    Employment

    Hours

    work

    perem

    ployee

    Yearsof

    schooling

    Age

    workforce

    Tenure

    workforce

    Females/

    totalworkers

    Average

    hourlywage

    Loweducated

    hourlywage

    Higheducated

    hourlywage

    Price-cost

    margin

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10)

    Futureforeign

    acquisitions

    0.0

    7

    0.000

    0.005

    0.0

    01

    0.03

    0.002

    0.001

    0.005

    0.0

    1

    0.01

    [0.0

    16]

    [0.0

    03]

    [0.0

    05]

    [0.0

    03]

    [0.0

    19]

    [0.0

    17]

    [0.0

    06]

    [0.0

    06]

    [0.0

    10]

    [0.0

    05]

    Foreignfirms

    0.0

    2

    0.01

    0.003

    0.0

    1

    0.002

    0.01

    0.01

    0.004

    0.01

    0.002

    [0.0

    05]

    [0.0

    01]

    [0.0

    01]

    [0.0

    01]

    [0.0

    05]

    [0.0

    03]

    [0.0

    01]

    [0.0

    02]

    [0.0

    02]

    [0.0

    01]

    Sectordummie

    sincluded?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Timedummies

    included?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Growthav.sch

    ooling,age,

    tenureandsh.

    females

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    No

    Ftest:Futureforeign

    acquisitions=Foreign

    firms(Pvalue)

    0.0

    0

    0.11

    0.68

    0.11

    0.07

    0.52

    0.35

    0.17

    0.0

    4

    0.05

    N

    384,8

    02

    384,80

    2

    384,8

    02

    384,802

    384,8

    02

    384,8

    02

    384,802

    363,223

    139,094

    344,439

    Rsquared

    0.0

    1

    0.01

    0.00

    0.00

    0.01

    0.00

    0.02

    0.04

    0.0

    8

    0.00

    Thenumbersincolumn(1)representthecoefficientsofaregressionofemploymentgrowthonadummyvariableifafirmw

    illbecomeacquiredbyforeignersan

    donadummy

    variableifthefirmisforeignowned.Controlsfortw

    odigitsectordummiesandyeardum

    miesareincluded(Eq.

    (4.2

    )inthetext).

    Incolumns(7)to(9)controlsfo

    rthegrowthin

    averageschooling,age,tenureandfemalesareincluded.Standarderrorsareclusteredatthefirmlevel.Nisthesamplesize

    ineachregression.Pvaluesareforthetestthatthe

    coefficientonthefutureforeignacquisitionsisequaltothatofforeignownedfirms.The

    coefficientsforemployment,hourso

    fworkandaveragehourlywages(av

    erage,lowand

    high)areinterp

    retedaspercentagedifferences(logdependentvariable).E.g.,

    0.07incolumn(1)impliesthatfutureforeignacquisitionsgrow7percentagepointsabovetheaverage

    domesticfirminthesectortwoyearsbeforetheac

    quisitiontakesplace.0.0

    05incolumn(3)impliesthatthegrowthintheaverageyearsofschoolinginfirm

    sacquiredby

    foreignersis0.0

    5percentagepointslowerthanintheaveragedomesticfirminthesecto

    r.

    86 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    13/22

    not significantly affected. Moreover, after controlling for the human capital characteristics of the

    workforce, average hourly wages remain constant following the acquisition. This result is robust

    within education groups. Column (10) reports an increase in the price-cost margin by 0.4 percent-age

    points for the whole sample, suggesting that productivity increases following the foreign acquisition.To keep the comparability with papers in the literature, panel B reports the results of estimating

    Eq. (4.1) only for manufacturing firms. I find evidence that employment increases by 10.1% and

    that there are very small changes in the human capital composition of the average worker in the

    firm.27 Average hourly wages increase by 1.7% following the acquisition (reflecting an increase

    in average wages and of hours of work by 2.6% and 1.2%, respectively). Hourly wages for the

    high educated workers increase by 3.5% following the acquisition and average hourly wages for

    the low educated workers remain unchanged.

    In sum, my findings show that following the foreign acquisition there are no substantial changes

    in the human capital of the workforce or on the average wages of acquired firms. There is also

    evidence that firms increase total employment following the acquisition, even though this estimateis likely to be upward biased since acquired firms were growing at faster rates in the pre-acquistion

    period. For manufacturing firms, there is evidence of an increase in average hourly wages for the

    high educated workers, after controlling for changes in the quality of the workforce. I interpret

    these findings as consistent with a model where foreign firms are relatively risk averse and enter a

    new market where learning and adjustment costs are high. Foreigners are more likely to buy the

    best performers since they are already similar to their own characteristics. Otherwise, they would

    face very high costs of adapting the technology, the workforce or by gaining experience in the host

    country. Furthermore, acquired firms only account for a very small share of total employment. As a

    result, changes in the labor demand of these firms will not affect the equilibrium wages in the

    economy and most of the observed changes will be on the employment margin. Foreign investmentmay lead to an increase in the productivity of the labor force and to a rise in labor demand but, if

    wages are fixed, employment will increase. In the manufacturing sector foreign acquisition leads to

    an increase in wages of the more educated workers. This could happen if foreign firms provide

    more training to these workers than domestic firms, making them different from other educated

    workers in the rest of the economy, and therefore paying them higher wages. Alternatively, if there

    are rigidities in the labor market for educated workers, it is also possible that foreign acquisitions

    lead to higher wages due to an increase in labor demand, even in the absence of training.

    The most credible solution to the endogeneity problem of foreign acquisitions would be to find an

    external instrument to the foreign acquisition. This instrument had to be uncorrelated with all the

    outcomes of interest except through the acquisition itself but such an instrument does not exist in thedata. Alternatively, I could estimate a VAR model and test whether foreign ownership Granger

    causes firm characteristics. Unfortunately, the panel dimension of the data is not sufficiently long to

    allow me to estimate a specification without serial correlation in the error terms.28

    5. Robustness tests

    One possible concern is that the findings in Table 3 are driven by the 10% threshold imposed to

    define foreign ownership. Mansfield and Romeo (1980) argue that the transfer of foreign technology

    27 The only quantitatively important change is associated with a decrease in the share of females in 1.4 percentage

    points.28 Details on the results using this approach are available in appendix B at http://econ.worldbank.org/staff/ralmeida.

    There, I also discuss other robustness tests for the main findings in the paper.

    87R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

    http://econ.worldbank.org/staff/ralmeidahttp://econ.worldbank.org/staff/ralmeida
  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    14/22

    Table3

    Fixedeffectsestimatesoftheeffectsofforeignacquisitionsusingascontrolgroupdomesticfirms

    Employment

    Hourswork

    peremployee

    Yearsof

    schooling

    Age

    workforce

    Tenure

    workforce

    Females/

    totalworkers

    Hourly

    wage

    Loweducated

    hourlywage

    Higheducated

    hourlywage

    Price-cost

    margin

    (1)

    (2

    )

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    (10)

    A.A

    llSample

    Foreignownership

    0.145

    0.017

    0.0

    08

    0.7

    6

    0.3

    2

    0.004

    0.004

    0.001

    0.008

    0.0

    04

    [0.0

    35]

    [0.0

    04]

    [0.0

    60]

    [0.1

    57]

    [0.1

    08]

    [0.0

    06]

    [0.009

    ]

    [0.0

    10]

    [0.0

    16]

    [0.0

    01]

    Timedummies

    included?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Av.schooling,

    age,

    tenure,sh.females

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    No

    N

    638,896

    638,896

    638,896

    638,8

    96

    638,896

    638,8

    96

    638,89

    6

    608,551

    248,671

    571,6

    05

    Rsquared

    0.94

    0.68

    0.90

    0.8

    8

    0.91

    0.9

    3

    0.85

    0.86

    0.85

    0.7

    2

    B.Manufacturing

    Foreignownership

    0.101

    0.012

    0.0

    22

    0.7

    73

    0.4

    65

    0.014

    0.017

    0.009

    0.035

    0.0

    05

    [0.0

    18]

    [0.0

    07]

    [0.0

    50]

    [0.1

    71]

    [0.1

    06]

    [0.0

    05]

    [0.009

    ]

    [0.0

    08]

    [0.0

    17]

    [0.0

    01]

    Timedummies

    included?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Av.schooling,

    age,

    tenure,sh.females

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    No

    N

    133,985

    133,985

    133,985

    133,9

    85

    133,985

    133,9

    85

    133,98

    5

    132,775

    49,9

    65

    122,9

    87

    Rsquared

    0.96

    0.63

    0.85

    0.9

    1

    0.93

    0.9

    7

    0.85

    0.87

    0.85

    0.7

    2

    Thenumbersincolumn(1)representthecoefficien

    tsofaregressionoflogemploymen

    tatthefirmlevelonadummyvaria

    blethatequalstooneifthefirmisforeignowned,

    controllingfor

    yearandfirmtimeinvarianteffects(Eq.

    (4.1

    )inthetext).Incolumns(7)

    to(9)thespecificationincludesasexplanatoryvariableaverageyearsofschooling,age,

    tenureandsharefemalesintheworkforce.Standarderrorsareclusteredatthefirmlevel.N

    isthesamplesizeineachregression.

    Thecoefficientsforemployment,hoursofworkand

    averagehourly

    wages(average,lowandhigh)areinterpretedaspercentagedifferences(logdependentvariable).E.g.,

    0.1

    4inco

    lumn(1)impliesthatfollowingafore

    ignacquisition

    theemploymen

    tinacquiredfirmsisonaverage14p

    ercentagepointshigherthantheaverageemploymentinadomesticfirm.P

    anelAincludestheestimatesforallthefirmsinthe

    sampleandPanelBincludesonlymanufacturingfirms.

    88 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    15/22

    is greater in fully owned foreign firms, specially when competitive advantage of the foreign firm is

    based on intangible assets. Larger technological transfers from foreign firms increase productivity

    and can possibly increase the use of more educated workers or average wages in the acquired firm. In

    this case, the choice of the 10% threshold could be biasing the results against the finding on any effecton wages and workforce composition. I reestimate Eq. (4.1) considering foreign firms only those

    firms with full foreign ownership. Given that most of the firms in the sample have majority

    participations the results in Table 3 do not change significantly (results are available upon request).

    A different concern, specific to the effect of foreign ownership on hourly wages, relates to

    possibility that the foreign acquisition changes the composition of the workforce in some unobservable

    workforce characteristics (e.g. worker's ability). In Section 2 I showed that foreign and domestic firms

    differ significantly with respect to the human capital profile of the workforce. This heterogeneity is

    likely to be much more important when comparing different firms rather than when comparing the

    same firms over time (which is my approach in Eq. (4.1)). In fact, if the workforce were to be constant

    over time, the unobserved ability of the workforce would be perfectly captured by a firm time invarianteffect. However, with a changing workforce this needs not be the case. Moreover, depending on the

    correlation between ability and the foreign acquisition the sign of the bias in Table 3 is unclear.

    To address this concern, I exploit the fact that in the data firms and workers are matched in each

    point in time and that both can be traced over time.29 The best way to account for the bias would be

    to compute average wages for those workers that have remained in the firm throughout the entire

    period the firm is observed.30 This approach ensures that the set of workers remains constant over

    time and one can fully isolate the effect of the foreign acquisition from the effect of omitted ability.

    The problem with this approach is that there are very few firms with at least one worker that

    complies with this criteria, mostly because of large measurement error in worker identifiers. In

    particular, the total number of acquired firms for which there is information on wages is reducedfrom a total of 1381 to approximately 360 firms. An alternative to this approach which

    simultaneously mitigates the omitted ability problem and maximizes the information available

    over time, is to keep the composition of the workforce fixed only before and after the acquisition.

    To do this I compute average wages for a moving window of workers across three consecutive

    periods. For existing firms, I identify the group of workers that are currently employed in the firm

    and that were employed in the previous year as well as in the following year. For new firms I

    identify the group of workers that are currently employed in the firm and that will remain employed

    in the following year. For example, consider a domestic firm that exists for the period 19931997

    and that is acquired in 1995. The (moving) average wages obtained for this firm in 1994 and 1995

    (used to identify the effect of the foreign acquisition) use information for the same set of workersexcept for those workers that were in the firm in 1993 but are no longer there in 1996 and vice-

    versa. Using this criteria, I am able to compute the average wages for 1, 346 acquired firms in the

    sample, which is approximately 95% of the total number of acquisitions in the data.31

    29 The Portuguese data is a matched employer-employee data set. For a review of the litertaure using matched employer

    employee see Abowd and Kramarz (1999).30 The worker identifier in this data is the worker's social security number. This identifier is much less reliable than the

    firm identifier because the Ministry of Labor, specially in the first years of the sample, did not check the validity of the

    codes provided. I have excluded workers without a unique identifier within a firm when tracing the workers over time.

    This criteria could still present some problems (e.g., workers with non-valid social security numbers might remain in the

    sample as long as they only show up once within each firm) but it maximizes the number of workers for which there is

    information. The share of workers that are not unique according to this definition is between 12% (1991) and 7% (1998).31 Using this criterion, between 42% (1998) and 32% (1992) of the workers in the sample in each period are used to

    compute average wages.

    89R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    16/22

    Table 4 report the results of estimating Eq. (4.1) for the average wages for this group of workers.

    Columns (1) to (3) report the results with least squares ignoring the firm fixed effects (cross

    section) and columns (4) to (6) report the results with firm fixed effects. As before, the least squares

    estimates of the effect of foreign ownership are always above the firm fixed effects estimates. This

    finding suggests that the cherry picking of the foreign investors of domestic firms is robust to

    keeping the workforce composition constant. The main difference of keeping the composition

    fixed (relatively to Table 3) is that there are slightly larger effects of foreign ownership for averagewages in manufacturing (panel B). In particular, average wages following the acquisition increase

    by 2.2% for the low educated workers and 4.3% for the high educated workers.32 However, the

    magnitude of these effects are very small when compared to the least square estimates. These

    results suggest that the firm expands following the foreign acquisition but that the average quality

    of the new entrant is slightly below the quality of the average worker. This is consistent with

    foreigners buying the domestic firms with the best workers and hiring the immediately next to the

    best when they are expanding in the years following the acquisition (Table 3 shows that average

    schooling, age and tenure decrease slightly following the acquisition).

    Table 4

    Estimates of the effects of foreign acquisitions on wages only for workers that remain in the firm (stayers)

    Estimation method: All Low

    Educated

    High

    Educated

    All Low

    Educated

    High

    Educated

    OLS Fixed effects

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    A. All sample

    Foreign ownership 0.36 0.27 0.43 0.009 0.015 0.025

    [0.014] [0.013] [0.017] [0.009] [0.009] [0.015]

    Sector dummies included? Yes Yes Yes No No No

    Time dummies included? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Av. schooling, age, tenure, sh. females Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    N 550,288 514,406 182,036 550,288 514,406 182,036

    R squared 0.40 0.37 0.36 0.86 0.86 0.88

    B. Manufacturing

    Foreign ownership 0.23 0.18 0.32 0.028 0.022 0.043

    [0.018] [0.017] [0.026] [0.013] [0.012] [0.023]

    Sector dummies included? Yes Yes Yes No No No

    Time dummies included? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Av. schooling, age, tenure, sh. females Yes Yes Yes Yes Ye Yes

    N 123,715 122,031 37,633 123,715 122,031 37,633

    R squared 0.42 0.42 0.36 0.85 0.87 0.87

    Table reports the foreign wage premium of all the workers that remain in the same firm throughout 3 consecutive periods. The

    table reports the least squares estimates of Eq. (4.1) in the text ignoring firm fixed effects in columns (1) to (3) and including

    them in columns (4) to (6). Columns (1) and (4) report the results for all the workers, columns (2) and (5) for all the low

    educated workers and columns (3) and (6) for the high educated workers. Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.Nisthe

    sample size in each regression. Panel A reports the results for the whole sample and Panel B includes only manufacturing firms.

    32 I thank the editor for one possible explanation for why there could be a higher increase in average wages for the high

    educated workers. If following the acquisition total rents increase and the high educated workers have higher bargaining

    power (due to the accumulation of firm specific skills), then their wage adjustment could be higher. Unfortunately my

    data does not allow me to test this hypothesis.

    90 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    17/22

    One concern that could still remain with these findings relates to the whether they could be

    attributed to the foreign ownership or if they can attributed to the acquisition itself, independently

    of the nationality. To the extent that domestic firms also cherry pick the acquired firms, my

    results for the selection and for the evolution following the acquisition would be driven by theacquisition itself and not by the foreign acquisitions. As discussed in Section 4 it is difficult to

    extract strong predictions about the post acquisition firm performance from the extensive

    theoretical literature on mergers and acquisitions. Unfortunately, in the Portuguese data I cannot

    identify domestic acquisitions of domestic firms even though I can identify the group of domestic

    acquisitions of foreign owned firms.33 To address this concern, I estimate the following model:

    yjt kj bFAjt hDAjtXT

    t1

    gtDt jt 5:1

    where FAjt is a dummy variable that assumes the value one in the periods following a foreign

    acquisition of a domestic firm, DAjt is a dummy variable that assumes the value one in the periodsfollowing a domestic acquisition of a foreign firm and Dt are year dummies.

    34 The results are

    reported in Table 5. The findings suggest that the effects on employment are different for foreign

    and domestic acquisitions. While employment in the firm increases between 10% and 15%

    following a foreign acquisition, in the domestic acquisitions, there is a 5% reduction in total

    employment (which fails to be statistically significant but is in line with Conyon et al., 2002b).

    Moreover, there is also evidence that the effects on average wages are common to the two types of

    ownership changes. The estimates in columns (7) to (9) show that, after keeping the composition of

    the workforce constant, average wages in acquired firms increase by a very similar magnitude,

    independently of the nationality of the acquiring firm (even though I never reject that the increase

    in wages in slightly higher in the foreign acquisitions).Perhaps surprisingly, there is evidence that average years of schooling decrease following a

    domestic acquisition. This pattern is puzzling even though the magnitude of the effect is very

    small (average schooling in the sample is 6.3 years and the standard deviation of 2.3 years). A

    further investigation shows that this effect is not driven by the evolution in the years of schooling

    in the existent domestic firms. One possible explanation for this can be that the new workers in

    firms that become acquired by domestics are less educated than the existing workers in these

    firms. Actually, the average years of schooling of an European worker is higher than for a

    Portuguese worker. Since approximately 75% of the Portuguese FDI in this period came from the

    E.U., these changes could be simply reflecting the exit of some foreign workers following the

    domestic acquisition. On the contrary, when a domestic firm is acquired by a foreign

    multinational there is no evidence that foreigners change significantly the average schooling of

    the firm, perhaps because this is already very close to the one in fully foreign firms.

    Finally, another concern with the estimates in Table 3 is that they are capturing the effects of

    other firm practices that change simultaneously with the nationality of the ownership. Since

    foreign activities tend to take place in bundles, those firms that are acquired by foreigners are likely

    to simultaneously become exporters or importers of some of their intermediate inputs (e.g. Tybout,

    33 Foreign acquisitions of domestic firms (or foreign acquisitions of domestic firms) are identified when the share of foreign

    ownership changes from being less or equal to 10% to being more than 10% (and vice versa). Given that domestic acquisitions

    do not necessarily translate into changes in the share private domestic capital, they cannot be identified in the data set.34 A similar analysis than the one reported in Table 1 (not reported) suggests that foreign owned firms that will be

    acquired by domestics are smaller in size, pay lower average hourly wages and have a less educated workforce than the

    average foreign firm in the same sector. Still, these firms always outperform the typical domestic firm in the sector.

    Again, there are no significant differences in the growth of the outcomes of interest in the pre acquisition period.

    91R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    18/22

    Table5

    Estimatesoftheeffectsofforeignanddomesticacq

    uisitionsusingascontrolgroupdom

    esticfirms

    EmploymentYearsof

    schooling

    Price-cost

    margin

    Hourly

    wage

    Loweducated

    hourlywage

    Higheducated

    hourlywage

    Hourly

    wage

    Loweducated

    hourlywage

    Higheducated

    hourlywage

    Allworkers

    Stayers

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6

    )

    (7)

    (8)

    (9)

    A.A

    llsample

    Foreignacquisitions

    0.145

    0.0

    07

    0.004

    0.0

    04

    0.0

    01

    0.008

    0.009

    0.0

    15

    0.025

    [0.0

    35]

    [0.0

    60]

    [0.0

    01]

    [0.0

    09]

    [0.0

    10]

    [0.0

    16]

    [0.0

    09]

    [0.0

    09]

    [0.0

    15]

    Domesticacquisitions

    0.016

    0.1

    75

    0.000

    0.0

    03

    0.0

    02

    0.014

    0.008

    0.0

    16

    0.009

    [0.0

    37]

    [0.0

    62]

    [0.0

    01]

    [0.0

    11]

    [0.0

    10]

    [0.0

    19]

    [0.0

    11]

    [0.0

    09]

    [0.0

    16]

    Timedummies

    included?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Av.schooling,age,tenure,sh.

    Femalesincluded?No

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Ftest:foreignacquisitions=domestic

    acquisitions(Pvalue)

    0.000

    0.0

    18

    0.001

    0.88

    0.9

    8

    0.64

    0.484

    0.0

    65

    0.232

    N

    641,475

    641,4

    75

    573,938

    641,4

    75610,8

    89

    250,914

    552,6

    93

    516,4

    69

    183,9

    84

    Rsquared

    0.94

    0.9

    0

    0.72

    0.86

    0.8

    6

    0.86

    0.86

    0.8

    6

    0.88

    B.Manufacturing

    Foreignacquisitions

    0.102

    0.0

    21

    0.005

    0.017

    0.0

    09

    0.034

    0.028

    0.0

    22

    0.043

    [0.0

    66]

    [0.1

    04]

    [0.0

    02]

    [0.0

    13]

    [0.0

    12]

    [0.0

    25]

    [0.0

    13]

    [0.0

    12]

    [0.0

    23]

    Domesticacquisitions

    0.050

    0.1

    73

    0.000

    0.0

    10

    0.0

    07

    0.000

    0.015

    0.0

    17

    0.040

    [0.0

    42]

    [0.0

    88]

    [0.0

    02]

    [0.0

    15]

    [0.0

    12]

    [0.0

    36]

    [0.0

    12]

    [0.0

    11]

    [0.0

    29]

    Timedummies

    included?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Av.schooling,age,tenure,sh.

    Femalesincluded?No

    No

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Ftest:foreignacquisitions=domestic

    acquisitions(Pvalue)

    0.15

    0.1

    4

    0.03

    0.36

    0.6

    7

    0.38

    0.039

    0.0

    62

    0.071

    N

    134,736

    134,7

    36

    123,679

    134,7

    36133,5

    18

    50,6

    21

    124,4

    37

    122,7

    36

    38,207

    Rsquared

    0.96

    0.8

    5

    0.72

    0.85

    0.8

    7

    0.85

    0.85

    0.8

    7

    0.87

    Thenumbersin

    column(1)representthecoefficients

    ofaregressionoflogemploymentat

    thefirmlevelonadummyvariableth

    atequalstooneifthefirmisacquired

    byforeigners,

    onadummythatequalsoneifthefirmsisacquiredb

    ydomesticsandcontrolsforyearand

    firmtimeinvarianteffects(Eq.

    (5.1

    )inthetext).Columns(1)to(6)reporttheresultsfor

    alltheworkers

    inthesamplewhilecolumns(7)to(9)reporttheresultsforthestayers.A

    llthewageequationsincludeasexplanatoryvariablesaverageyearsofschooling,age,

    tenureandsharefemalesintheworkforce.Standarderrorsareclusteredatthefirmlevel.Nisthesamplesizeineachregres

    sion.Thecoefficientsforemploymentandaverage

    hourlywages(average,lowandhigh)areinterprete

    daspercentagedifferences(logdependentvariable).Standarderrorsare

    clusteredatthefirmlevel.PanelAincludesallthe

    sectorsinthesampleandPanelBincludesonlyma

    nufacturingsectors.

    92 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    19/22

    2000; Bernard et al., 2005). Since the Portuguese data set does not collect any information on

    exports it is not possible to check empirically how controlling for these activities would affect the

    findings. However, given the findings in the literature on exporting, my results for the post

    acquisition performance should not be too much affected by the exporting activity even if it takesplace simultaneously with the foreign acquisition.35 For example, Clerides et al. (1998) and

    Bernard and Jensen (1999) find evidence that the best performers self select into exporting

    activities and no evidence of significant changes in productivity or wages after the firm becomes an

    exporter. The evidence of the effects of importing intermediate inputs are much less studied but

    several papers find evidence of a positive correlation between importing intermediate inputs and

    firm performance (e.g. Tybout and Westbrook, 1995). Assuming that the effects on productivity

    are quantitatively important and if they translate into high wage growth, my estimates for the

    changes in average wages could be overestimated. Since I find no or small effects in average hourly

    wages, this would imply that foreign acquisition are associated with a decrease in productivity and

    wages. This finding would be consistent with a short run decrease in the firm's productivityfollowing a foreign acquisition, which could be caused by assimilation problems when entering

    into a new market (e.g. Harris and Robinson, 2002; Ravenscraft and Scherer, 1987).

    6. Conclusion

    Foreign firms have a more educated workforce and pay higher wages than domestic firms even

    after controlling for worker quality, at a given moment in time. This does not imply that foreign

    ownership improves the labor market outcomes of the workers since foreign investment may be

    guided by unobservable firm and worker characteristics correlated with schooling or wages. Using a

    matched employer

    employee data set of Portuguese firms during the nineties, I illustrate theimportance of selection of foreign investment to high wage and high human capital firms and to

    isolate the effect of foreign ownership on several labor market outcomes. Existing empirical

    evidence for European countries is scarce and, apart from evidence for the UK, not much is known

    about the impact of foreign acquisitions on the labor markets outcomes. Portugal is an interesting

    case, as in the late 1980s and 90s there was a permissive legal framework for the operation of foreign

    firms that translated into generous amounts of FDI. Moreover, Portugal is a developed country

    although at the tail of the income distribution within the European Union. Therefore, the findings in

    the paper may be particularly important to understand the effects of foreign direct investment in the

    labor markets of the transition economies as they will soon join the European Union.

    My findings suggest that most of the cross sectional differences between foreign and domesticfirms are driven by foreigners cherry picking domestic firms to be acquired. Acquired firms have

    a more educated workforce, and pay higher wages for a given workforce quality. Moreover, these

    firms are already much more similar to the group of existing foreign firms and, following the

    foreign acquisition, there are no significant changes in the human capital of the workforce. There

    is evidence that the size of the firm increases and that the hourly wages for those workers that

    remain in the firm increases slightly following the acquisition by foreigners. Nevertheless, the

    increase in average wages are modest (between 2% for the low educated and 4% for the high

    educated workers) and well below the cross sectional estimates of the foreign wage premium.

    Suggestive evidence shows that it might not be specific to foreign acquisitions since wages go up

    by similar magnitudes following domestic acquisitions.

    35 Bernard and Jensen (1999) find that employment growth is higher for exporters. Therefore, the estimated increase in

    employment following the acquisition is likely to be biased upwards for those firms that export (in addition to the positive

    bias caused by selection of foreign investment into high growth firms).

    93R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    20/22

    TableA1

    Asummaryofth

    eliteratureonforeignwagepremiumusingfirmleveldata

    Country/period

    Data/samplecoverage

    Dep

    endentvariable

    Numberofacquisitions

    Independentvariables

    Foreignwagepremium

    Firmlevel

    W

    orkerlevel

    Crosssection

    Paneldata

    Aitken,Harrison

    and

    Lipsey(1996)

    Paneloffirms

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    byskillgroup

    N.A.

    sector,region,assets,size,ageN

    .A.

    25%skilled

    17%unskilled

    14%skilled

    9.3%unskilled

    Venezuela,

    19771989

    EncustaIndustrial.

    Manufacturing

    Girma,Greenaway

    andWakelin(1999)

    Paneloffirms.

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    N.A.

    sector

    N

    .A.

    9.50%

    0.40%

    UK,

    19911996

    OneSource.Manufacturing

    Conyon,Girma,

    Thompsonand

    Wright(2002)

    Paneloffirms.

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    129foreignacquisitions

    and331domestic

    acquisitions

    assets,sector

    averagewages

    N

    .A.

    3.30%

    UK,

    19891994

    OneSource.manufacturing

    GirmaandGorg

    (2003)

    Paneloffirms.

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    bys

    killgroup

    346foreign

    acquisitions

    averageregional-sector

    wage,averagewagein

    complementskillgroup,capitalN

    .A.

    2%4.9%

    skilled2%

    2.8%unskilled

    U.K.

    19801994

    ARD.

    Electronicsandfood

    Lipseyand

    Sjoholm(2004)

    Crosssectionoffirms.

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    bys

    killgroup

    sector,region,energy

    perworker,inputsper

    worker,size,public

    ownership

    E

    ducation,gender

    byskillgroup

    12%bluecollor,

    22%whitecollar

    Indonesia,1996

    CensusManufacturing

    Lipseyand

    Sjoholm(2002)

    Paneloffirms.

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    bys

    killgroup

    1045foreign

    acquisitions1243

    domesticacquisition

    s

    sector,region,energy

    perworker,inputsper

    worker,size,publicownership

    N

    .A.

    28%bluecollar

    41%whitecollar

    17%blue

    collar33%

    whitecollar

    Indonesia,1975

    1999

    CensusManufacturing

    Almeida(2004)

    Paneloffirms

    (MEEDatfirmlevel)

    Log

    averagefirmwage

    bye

    ducationgroup

    688foreign

    acquisitions505

    domesticacquisition

    s

    sector,size,age,

    publicownership.

    E

    ducation,gender,

    age,tenure,

    hours

    w

    orkedbyeducation

    group

    31%loweducated

    46%higheducated

    0.1%low

    educated

    0.8%high

    educated

    Portugal,19911

    998

    CensusManufacturingand

    Nonmanufacturing

    Note:Tablereportsasummaryofthemainpapersthathaves

    tudiedtheforeignwagepremiumusingmic

    rodata.T

    hefirstevidencethatforeignfirmswereassociatedwithhigherwagescamefromstudiesusing

    industryleveldata(seee.g.FelicianoandLipsey,1999;Aitk

    en,

    HarrisonandLipsey,1996).Asdatasetsbecomeavailable,foreignwagepremium

    shavebeenestimatedusingplantorfirmlevelinformation.

    AppendixA.

    94 R. Almeida / Journal of International Economics 72 (2007) 7596

  • 7/28/2019 Almeida the Labor

    21/22

    Appendix B. Supplementary data

    Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in the online version, at

    doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.10.001.

    References

    Abowd, J., Kramarz, F., 1999. The analysis of labor markets using matched employeremployee data. In: Ashenfelter, O.,

    Card, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 3B. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 26292710.

    Aitken, B., Harrison, A., Lipsey, R., 1996. Wages and foreign ownership: a comparative study of Mexico, Venezuela and

    the United States. Journal of International Economics 40, 345371.

    Almeida, R., 2004. The labor market effects of foreign-owned firms. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, vol. 3300.

    Arnold, J., Javorcik, B., 2005. Gifted kids or pushy parents? Foreign acquisitions and plant performance in Indonesia.

    World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, vol. 3597.

    Bernard, A., Jensen, J., 1999. Exceptional exporter performance: cause, effect, or both? Journal of International Economics

    47, 125.

    Bernard, A., Jensen, J., Schott, P., 2005. Importers, exporters, and multinationals: a portrait of firms in the U.S. that trade

    goods. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, vol. 11404.

    Bover, O., Garcia-Perea, P., Portugal, P., 1998. A comparative study of the Portuguese and Spanish labour markets. Banco

    de Espana Working Paper, vol. 9807.

    Brown, C., Medoff, J., 1988. The impact of firm acquisition on labor. In: Auerbach, A. (Ed.), Corporate Take-overs:

    Causes and Consequences. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 925.

    Buckley, P., Casson, M., 1998. Analyzing foreign market entry strategies: extending the internalization approach. Journal

    of International Business Studies 29, 539562.

    Caves, R., 1996. Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Clerides, S., Lach, S., Tybout, J., 1998. Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence From Colombia,

    Mexico and Morocco. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 903

    947.Conyon, M., Girma, S., Thompson, S., Wright, P., 2002a. The productivity and wage effects of foreign acquisition in the

    United Kingdom. Journal of Industrial Economics 50, 85102.

    Conyon, M., Girma, S., Thompson, S., Wright, P., 2002b. Merger activity and firm employment. European Economic

    Review 46, 3149.

    Feliciano, Z., Lipsey, R., 1999. Foreign ownership and wages in the United States. National Bureau of Economic Research

    Working Paper, vol. 6923.

    Girma, S., Grg, H., 2003a. Multinational's productivity advantage: scale or technology. mimeo. Nothingham University.

    Girma, S., Grg, H., 2003b. Evaluating the causal effects of foreign acquisition on domestic skilled and unskilled wages.

    IZA Discussion Paper, vol. 903.

    Girma, S., Greenaway, D., Wakelin, K., 1999. Wages, productivity and foreign ownership in UK manufacturing.

    University of Nottingham Research Paper, vol. 99/14.

    Hammermesh, D., 1993. Labor Demand. Princeton University Press, USA.Harris, R., Robinson, C., 2002. The effect of forei


Recommended