+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

Date post: 06-Jul-2018
Category:
Upload: stevano-andreas
View: 217 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 23

Transcript
  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    1/23

    J O U R N A L  O F F I NA NC I A L  A N D OU ANTITATIVE ANALY SIS Vo l , 4 4 , No , 2 , Ap r , 2009 ,  p p ,  3 6 9 - 3 9 0

    COPYRIGHT 2009, MICHAEL G, FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY

     OF

     W ASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195

    do i :  10 ,1017 /S0022109009090127

    Anchoring Bias in C onsensus Forecasts and

    Its Effect on Market Prices

    Sean

     D

    Campbell and Steven

     A

    Sharpe

    Abstract

    Previous empirical studies

     on the

      rationality

    of

     economic

     and

     financial forecasts gener-

    ally test

     for

     generic properties such as bias or autocorrelated errors but provide only limited

    insight into

     the

     behav ior behind inefficient forecasts. This paper tests

     for a

      specific form

    of forecast bias.

     In

     particular, we examine whether expert consensus forecasts

     of

     monthly

    econom ic releases are systematically biased toward the value

     of

     previous m onth s' releases.

    Such

      a

      bias would

      be

      consistent with

      the

     anchoring

      and

      adjustment heuristic described

    by Tversky and Kahneman (1974) or could arise from professional forec asters ' strategic

    incentives,'We find broad-based  and  significant evidence for  this form  of  bias, which in

    some cases results  in  sizable predictable forecast errors. To  investigate whether market

    participants' expectations

     are

     influenced

      by

     this bias,

     we

      examine interest rate reactions

    to economic news.

     We

     find that bond yields react only

     to the

     residual,

     or

     unpredictable,

    component

     of the

      forecast error

     and not to the

      component induced

      by

     anchoring,

     sug-

    gesting that expectations

      of

      market participants anticipate this bias embedded

      in

     expert

    forecasts,

      •

    I Jntroduction

    Professiotial forecasts of macroeconomic releases play an importatit role

    in markets, informing the decisions of both policymakers and private economic

    decision makers. In light of this, and the substantial effects of data surprises on

    asset prices, we might expect professional forecasters to avoid making systematic

    prediction errors. Previous research has approached this topic by testing time se-

    ries of forecasts for rationality, an approach with a fairly long and not entirely

    satisfying history. Generally, such studies focus on testing for a few generic prop-

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    2/23

    37 Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

    limited insight into the nature of apparent bias. In addition, such studies provoke

    but do not answer, the question: W hat are the implications of nonrational forecasts

    for market prices? In particular, where persistent forecast biases exist, do the users

    of these forecasts take predictions at face value when making investment dec isions

    or dispensing advice? Or do they see through the biases, which would make such

    anomalies irrelevant for market prices?

    As noted by Tversky and Kahneman (1974), psychological studies of fore-

    cast behavior find that predictions by individuals are prone to systematic biases,

    which induce large and predictable forecast errors. One widely documented form

    of systematic bias that influences predictions by nonprofessionals is anch oring ,

    or choosing forecasts that are too close (anchored) to some easily observable prior

    or arbitrary point of departure. Such behavior results in forecasts that underw eight

    new information and can thus give rise to predictable forecast erro rs.

    We investigate whether anchoring influences expert consensus forecasts col-

    lected in surveys by Money Market Services (MMS), a widely used source of

    forecasts in financial markets, between 1991 and 2006. In particular, we focus

    on monthly macroeconomic data releases that are highly value-relevant, that is,

    for example, Balduzzi, Elton, and

    (2005)). Others, such as Aggarwal

    those previously found to have substantial effects on market interest rates (see.

    Green (2001), Gurkaynak, Sack, and Swanson

    , Mohanty, and Song (1995) and Schirm (2003),

    have subjected MMS consensus forecasts to tests of forecast efficiency and found

    some evidence of systematic bias) We test the more specific hypothesis, borne of

    years spent monitoring data releases and market reactions, that recent past values

    of the da ta release act as an anchor on expert forecasts. For instance, in the case

    of retail sales, we investigate whether the forecast of January sales growth tends

    to be too close to the previously released estimate of December sales growth.

    In short, we find broad-based and significant evidence that professional con-

    sensus forecasts are indeed anchored toward the recent past values of the series

    being forecasted. The degree and pattern of anchoring we measure is remarkably

    consistent across the various data releases. Moreover, the influence of the anchor

    in som e cases is quite substantial. We find that the typical forecast is weighted too

    heavily toward its recent past. These results thus indicate that anchoring on the

    recent past is a pervasive feature of expert consensus forecasts of economic data

    releases known to move market interest rates.

    These findings imply that the forecast errors or surprise s are at least partly

    predictable in a fashion consistent with anchoring. Of course, interpreting this

    as evidence of the behavioral bias spelled out in Tversky and Kahneman (1974)

    requires the joint hypothesis that

    these are meant to be unbiased forecasts. It is

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    3/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 371

    Our second major contribution thus involves assessing whether anchoring

    bias in economic forecasts affects market interest rates. Specifically, do interest

    rates respond to the predictable, as well as the unpredictable, component of the

    surprise? To answer this question, we decompose the surprise in each data release

    into a predictable component induced by anchoring, plus a residual that can be

    interpreted as the true surprise to the econometrician. We then test whether market

    participants anticipate the bias by regressing the change in the two-year (or 10-

    year) U.S. Treasury yield in the minutes surrounding the release onto these two

    components of the forecast error.

    We find that the bond market reacts strongly and in the expected direction

    to the residual, or unpredictable, component of the surprises. On the other hand,

    interest rates do not appear to respond to the predicted piece of the surprise in-

    duced by anchoring. The results are similar for almost every release we consider.

    We thus conclude that, by and large, the market looks through the anchoring bias

    embedded in expert forecasts, so that this bias does not induce interest rate pre-

    dictability or excess volatility.

    The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II lays out the

    conceptual and empirical framework for the analysis. Section III describes basic

    properties of the data releases and MM S consensus forecasts. Section IV estimates

    the proposed model of anchoring b ias. Section V tests whether the anchoring bias

    affects the response of market interest rates to data releases. Section VI concludes.

    I I.

      Forecast Bias Anchoring and Research Design

    A. Rationality Tests and Anchoring

    Many psychological and behavioral studies find that, in a variety of situa-

    tions,

      predictions by individuals systematically deviate too little from seemingly

    arbitrary reference points, or anchors, which serve as starting points for those

    predictions. As a result, those predictions underweight the forecasters' own infor-

    mation.' Tversky and Kahneman (1974) define anchoring to occur when people

    make estimates by starting from an initial value that is adjusted to yield the final

    answer ... adjustments are typically insufficient... [and] different starting points

    yield different estima tes, which are biased towards the initial values (p. 1128).

    In this section, we characterize the relation between traditional tests of forecast

    rationality and our proposed model of anchoring.

    Testing whether macroeconomic forecasts have the properties of rational ex-

    pectations has a fairly long tradition. A variety of early studies (for example,

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    4/23

    37 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    While the more recent studies brought some new methodological consider-

    ations to the table, they have largely followed the basic formulation of this line

    of research. In particular, the typical analysis involves running regressions with

    the actual (realized) value of the data release,

     A,,

     as the dependent variable on the

    most recent forecast,  F,, as the independent variable; that is,

    (1)

      A\

      = ß,F,  e,.

    The hypothesis of rationality holds that ß \  is not significantly different from unity

    and the errors are not autocorrelated,^ Broadly speaking, the results from such

    regressions tend to be mixed, with rationality being rejected in a substantial frac-

    tion of the tests. Both Aggarwal et al, (1995) and Schirm (2003) find that, when

    rationality is rejected, it is almost always due to a slope coefficient

      ßi

      greater than

    unity. As an example of a strong rejection. Schirm (2003) estimates a slope coef

    ficient of 1,62 in equation (1) for Durable Goods Orders, which suggests that the

    MMS consensus predictions are too cautious; that is, errors would be reduced if

    forecasted deviations (from average growth) were magnified 62%,

    If forecasts could be improved by system atically magnifying them, the impli-

    cation would be that forecasters are too slow or cautious when incorporating new

    information. Indeed, in a different setting, Nordhaus (1987) provides direct evi-

    dence of forecast inertia—that forecasters hold on to their prior view too long,

    That inference is drawn from an analysis of fixed-event forecasts of GDP growth,

    which shows that forecast revisions tend to be highly serially correlated,^ That set-

    ting differs from the more conventional time series with rolling-event forecasts,

    including the MMS forecasts that iw analyze.

    If forecasters in the standard rolling-event setting put too little weight on new

    information, this raises the question: What is the prior, or anchor, on which fore-

    casters place too much weight? One plausible scenario is that forecasters treat the

    value of the previous month's data as the most salient single piece of information

    that has come to the fore in the time between their previous-month and current-

    month forecasts. If so, then the previous month's realization might be treated as

    a starting point, or anchor, for the current forecast, * More generally, forecasters

    might place some weight on a few lags of the release, particularly when the fore-

    casted series tends to bounce around from month to month (i,e,, exhibits negative

    autocorrelation). At the extreme, forecasters might conceivably anchor their fore-

    cast on a long-run average value for the series.

    To develop this set of ideas more formally, consider the following transfor-

    mation of equation (1), whereby the forecast is subtracted from both sides. This

    yields an alternative version of the basic rationality test, where the forecast error

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    5/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 373

    Now, the canonical test of rationality examines whether the slope coefficient is

    significantly different from zero. Under our alternative hypothesis, we look for

    evidence in favor of the following model of forecast anchoring:

    (3) F, =  XE[A,]

      {\-X Ä,„

    where E[A,] represents the forecaster's unbiased prediction of next month's re-

    lease and

      Äh

      represents the average value of the forecasted series over the pre-

    vious

      h

      months. If A < 1, then we would conclude that consensus forecasts

    are anchored to the recent past. Using the implication from equation (2) that

    E[A,] =   E[S ]

      F,

      and substituting for E[A ]  in (3) yields an expression for ex-

    pected surprise: E[5,] = 7(F, —  Â;,), where 7 = (1 - A)/A. This suggests the

    following regression test for anchoring bias:

    (4)  S, =  7 ( F , - Â / , ) + £ , .

    A positive coefficient estimate would imply that consensus forecasts are system-

    atically biased toward lagged values of the release (and A 

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    6/23

    374 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    the surprise, or forecast error, arising from anchoritig bias in the same way they

    react to the residual component of the surprise? Or do market participants antici-

    pate the bias and thus respond only to the residual component of the surprise?

    We study this question by estimating secotid-stage event-study regressions

    in which the change in the two- ori 10-year Treasury yield around the time of the

    release is regressed on the two components of equation (4):

     5)

    Ai =

    where

     S ,  =

      E(S,) refers to the forecasted component of the surprise identified

    from ordinary least square (OLS) estimates of equation (4). If financial mar-

    kets respond to the forecasted component of the surprise induced by anchoring

    in the same way they respond to the residual, or unforecasted component, then

    we should find  6\ =   02-  Alternatively, if financial markets see through the bias

    in forecasts induced by anchoring] then we would expect that

      5\ =

     0. These two

    alternative hypotheses are explored in Section V.

    I. Data and Sam ple Characteristics

    A. Macroecononnic Re leas es Forecasts and Surprises

    Our analysis covers eight macroeconomic data releases: Consumer Confi-

    dence, Consumer Price Index (CPI), Durable Goods Orders, Industrial Produc-

    tion, Institute for Supply Management (ISM) Manufacturing Index, New Homes

    Sales, and Retail Sales.^ In two cases, we also examine the consensus forecasts of

    a key subcomponent of the top-line figure in the release (CPI ex-Food and Energy

    (Core CPI) and Retail Sales ex-Auto). In both cases, these data are released si-

    multaneously with the top-line release and are considered by market participants

    to contain more value-relevant news than the top line.

    Table

     

    lists each release, thebeginning of our sample period, the timing of

    the release, and the reporting convention, that is whether the release is reported as

    a level, a change, or a percent change. While our last observation is March 2006

    in each case, the starting date vaiiies between September 1992 and June 1996,

    determined by the availability of the forecast data. For each release, we define the

    consensus forecast,

      F

    as the mean forecast from the MMS survey.* The surprise

    is measured as the difference between the release and the associated MMS mean

    forecast.

    We focus on these eight key releases because of their previously identi-

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    7/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 375

    TABLE 1

    Économie Release Summary and Schedule

    In Table  1, we report each data release, the month and year in whioh our sample period begins, the period in the foliowing

    month when it is released, the time of the release, and whether the release is reported as a level, change, or percent

    change.

    Release

    Consumer Ccni idence

    Consumer Price index (CPi)

    Core CPI

    Durable Goods Orders

    Industrial Production

    ISM Index

    Ncnfarm Payroll Employment

    New Home Sales (in thousands)

    Retail Sales

    Retail Sales ex-Auto

    Beginning of

    Sample

    09/1992

    01/1993

    01/1993

    12/1992

    12/1992

    10/1992

    10/1992

    06/1996

    01/1993

    01/1993

    Release Day

    (next month)

    Finai Tuesda y^

    Third Wednesday

    Third Wednesday

    Fourth Thursday

    Third week

    First business d ay

    First Friday

    Fourth Wednesday

    Second week

    Seoond week

    Release

    Time (AM)

    10:00

    08:30

    08:30

    08:30

    09:15

    08:30

    08:30

    10:00 •

    08:30

    08:30

    Reporting

    • Convention

    Levei

    % change

    % change

    % change

    % change

    Levei

    Change

    Level

    % change

    % change

    ^Released in current month.

    In Tahle 2, we present some summary statistics for each release   A),  its as-

    sociated MMS forecast (F), and forecast surprise (5). For each variable we report

    the sample mean (ju), standard deviation  a),  and the sum of the autoregressive

    coefficients from a fifth-order autoregression ( ^  pj), a  measure of persistence.^

    Releases expressed in levels appear at the top of Table 2, followed by the remain-

    ing releases. The mean surprise, reported in Table 2, is typically close to zero,

    suggesting that the forecasts are unconditionally unbiased. Also, the standard de-

    viations of the forecasts are in every case smaller than that of the releases. As one

    would hope, the standard deviation of the surprises is typically smaller than that

    for the underlying release, with Core CPI being the only exception. Not surpris-

    ingly, for data releases that are expressed in levels, which have a high degree of

    persistence, surprises are a lot less variable than the underlying release.

    TABLE 2

    Summary Statistics:  iVIacroeconomic Releases, Forecasts, and Surprises

    In Table 2, we report the sample m ean (/x), standard deviation (a ), and sum of the autoregressive coeffic ients from an

    AR(5)  {J2 Pi)  'Of the underiying reiease

      .A),

      its forecast (F), and the surprise (S = A - F). In the case of the sum of the

    autoregressive coefficients  J2 Pi), '. .  and * denote signif icance at the 10%, 5%, and  1%  levels, respectiveiy.

    Release (A ) Forecast (F) Surprise (S )

    Consumer Confidence

    ISM ind ex

    M

    104.73

    52.92

    er

    22.40

    5.07

      Pi

    0 . 9 6 *

    0.88—

    ß

    104.24

    53.02

    er

    21.87

    4.64

      Pi

    0.96***

    0.89***

    M

    0,50

    - 0 . 1 0

    (T

    4.97

    2.06

      Pi

    - 0 . 1 4

    0.18

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    8/23

      76 Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

    The persistence properties of the variables listed in Table 2 are informative

    about the conditional properties of the MMS forecasts. In the case of the level

    variables, both the release and the

    releases and forecasts show small

    forecast are highly persistent. The remaining

    to moderate degrees of persistence, with the

    exception of Durable Goods Orders and Retail Sales. These releases exhibit a

    substantial and statistically significant degree of negative serial correlation; for

    Durable Goods Orders,  J^Pj =

      - 2 . 0 8 ,

      while for Retail Sales,  ^pj =  - 1 . 4 1 . ^ ' '

    However, neither of the associated forecasts exhibits a significant amount of neg-

    ative serial correlation, and thus the negative serial correlation of the data shows

    up in the surprises. Interestingly, these are not the only releases where the surprise

    exhibits significant negative serial correlation. The surprise is negatively serially

    correlated in every case except for the ISM release. It is also statistically sig-

    nificant in the case of the CPI, New Home Sales, Retail Sales, and Retail Sales

    ex-A uto, suggesting that the MM S forecasts are conditionally b iased.

    The finding that the serial correlation in surprises tends to be negative rather

    than positive suggests that serial correlation in surprises could be due to the an-

    choring of forecasts on the most recent lagged value of the release. This can be

    illustrated by a simple example in which the release is serially uncorrelated. Sup-

    pose forecasts were strongly anchored toward the recent past; in particulaif, that

    the current forecast is set equal to the lagged actual value  F, =  A,_i). In this

    simplified setting it is easy to see that

    (6)

    E [(/I, -

      F

    = E

     [{A,

     - A,_ , ) ( / ,_

     I

     - A,_2)]

    that is, successive surprises will be negatively correlated.

    Finally, before moving on to the main results, we note the unusual empirical

    properties of the Core CPI and its associated forecasts. As shown in Table 2, the

    Core CPI is by far the least variable of all releases; that is, both the release and the

    associated surprise are significantly less volatile than any other release or surprise.

    Over our sample period, the MMS

    to 0.2% (monthly inflation rate) in

    forecast of Core CPI is nearly constant, equal

    117 out of 176 months. Thus , in the case of the

    Core CPI, this sample period seems poorly suited to conducting our tests. Still,

    we include the Core CPI release in our analysis because C ore CPI surprises have

    substantial interest rate effects, which might otherwise be spuriously attributed to

    top-line CPI surprises.

    B Interest Rate Reactions to \/lacroeconomic New s Re lease s

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    9/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 377

    Bloomberg, For each release and maturity, we extract the quoted yield from a

    trade occurring both five minutes prior and 10 minutes after the release. The in-

    terest rate reaction is defined as the difference between the post- and pre-release

    quote. If no quote exists five minutes before (10 minutes after) the release, we use

    the last quote available between five and 30 minutes before the release (the first

    quote available between 10 and 30 minutes after the release),'

    In Table 3, we display the mean, standard deviation, and sum of au toregres-

    sive coefficients of the interest rate reactions. The average interest rate response

    is always close to zero, which is consistent with the near-zero mean of the as-

    sociated surprises. The standard deviations of the interest rate reactions provide

    some information about how much releases affect interest rates. Consistent with

    the findings of Gurkaynak et al, (2005), the standard deviations of the two- and

    10-year yield change are roughly similar. Also, consistent with the findings of

    Balduzzi et al, (2001), the Nonfarm Payroll Employment release produces the

    largest interest rate reactions.

    TABLE 3

    Summary Sfatisfics: Inferesf Rate Reactions to Macroeconomic Releases

    In Table 3, we report the sample mean ((j), standard deviation

      (CT),

      and sum of the autoregressive coefficients

    from an AR(5)  Y, Pi)  for the chang e in the tvïo-year U.S, Treasury yieid {AÍ2)  an d the 10-year U.S. Treasury

    in the moments surrounding each reiease. In the case of the sum of the autoregressive coefficients

    and • '* den ote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1 % ievels, respectively.

    Consumer Confidence

    ISM Index

    New Heme Sales

    Consumer Price index (CPI)

    Core CPI

    Durable Goods Orders

    Industriai Production

    Retaii Sales

    Retaii Saies ex-Auto

    Nonfarm Payroil Employment

     

    0.0Ó

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    - 0 . 0 1

    - 0 . 0 1

    0.00

    Tvïo-Year R esponse

    ÍAÍ

    0,02

    0.03

    0.02

    0,03

    0.03

    0,03

    0.02

    0,04

    0.04

    0.09

    .  EP ,

    0 . 2 7

    0,37—

    0,38

    - 0 . 0 5

    - 0 . 0 5

    - 0 , 6 9 —

    0.27- '

    0.17

    0.17

    - 0 . 1 8

     

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    0.00

    - 0 . 0 1

    - 0 . 0 1

    0.00

    10-Year Response

    î to

    7

    0.03

    0.03

    0.02

    0.03

    0.03

    0.02

    0.02

    0.03

    0.03

    0.07

    ^P i

    0,37—

    0,28--

    - 0 . 2 7

    - 0 . 0 5

    - 0 . 0 5

    - 0 . 3 3

    0 . 2 9

    0.12

    0,12

    - 0 , 2 8

    Looking at the persistence properties of the interest rate reactions indicates

    that the degree of serial correlation in the interest rate responses is typically sm all,

    ranging from -0,3 to 0,3 in most cases. In the case of Consumer Confidence,

    ISM , Durable Goods O rders, and Industrial Production, however, the serial corre-

    lation is statistically significant, which suggests that interest rate reactions might

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    10/23

    378 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    IV Estimates of Anchoring Bias

    As discussed in Secfion II, our test for anchoring bias in MMS consensus

    forecasts is based on the regression

    (7)  S,  j{F,-Á, +e,,

    where the dependent variable is the realized forecast error (or surp rise ) and the

    independent, or prediction, variable equals the difference between the forecast

    and the hypothesized an cho r. Implemen tation requires specifying the history of

    release values  h) used in our estimate of the anchor  Ah). We focus on two cases;

    in the first,

     Äh

     is simply the lagged value of the release '(/i= 

    ),

     while in the second

    it equals the average value of the release over the lagging three months  {h

     

    3).'^

    A positive value of the coefficient 7 would constitute evidence that forecast e rrors

    are biased in a predictable fashion

    Before proceeding, it should

    that is consistent with anchoring.

    be noted that this regression has some fairly

    close an tecedents in the literature on rationality tests. In particular, equation (7) in

    Aggarwal et al. (1995) would look very similar if the forecast were subtracted

    from both sides

     of

     their equation.

     In

     add ition, their regression differs

      in

     two

    respects: i) they effectively include only one lagged value of the release, mul-

    tiplied by a constant (the autoregressive parameter of the forecasted series); and

    ii) their estimation places no testable constraint on the coefficient estimates. In

     

    sense, our main innovation relative to that regression is to employ a somew hat dif-

    ferent set of testable constraints, which are suggested by our somewhat different

    analytical orientation,'-'

    We present the two alternative estimates of equation (4) for each of the

    macroeconomic releases listed in

    Table 1, The results for the three releases re-

    ported (and predicted) in the form of levels are shown in the top three rows of

    Table 4, The resu lts for the remaining re leases follow. The first two colum ns show

    the coefficient on the forecast-anchor gap , the 7, and the R ^ for the case where the

    anchor is assumed to be the prior

    month's release

      It =

      1). The t;hird and fourth

    columns show the analogous statisfics when the anchor is set to the average value

    of the release over the prior three m onths

      h=3).

      For each macroeconomic release,

    the results from the model with the highest R ^ are shown in bold.

    Broadly speaking, the results indicate a fairly consisten t pattern of bias in

    macroeconomic forecasts. The estimated coefficient

      on

     the gap between

     the

    consensus forecast and the previous month's release (one-month anchoring)

     i

    positive for every release, and, in six of 10 cases, it is significant at  the 1%

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    11/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 379

    TABLE 4

    Anchoring in Macroeconomic Forecasts

    In Table 4, we report estimated slope coefficient, 7 , and f l^ from the modei, S( = 70 + 7(^ 1 — A_ f, ) + £|, The results that

    equa te the previous m onth's value of the release vnith Âh fi = 1, are contained in the first tv O  columns. The results that

    equate the average of the three previous mon th's release with Ä/ i, h = 3, are contained in the final two columns, New ey

    and West (1987) I-statistics are reported in parentheses. Results from the modei with the highest

      R^

      appear in  bold.

    Consumer Confidence

    ISM Index

    New Home Sales

    Durable Goods Orders

    ^

    Industrial Production

    Nonfarm Payroii Empioyment

    Retaii Sales

    Retail Sales ex-Auto

    Consumer Price Index (CPI)

    Core CPI

    7

    0,71

     6,10

    0,22

     1,26

    0,53

     2,75

    0,16

    (4,51)

    0.14

     3.24

    0,06

    (0,75)

    0,25

     4,74

    0,29

     4,04

    0,06

    (1,52)

    0,04

     0,67

    One-Month

    Anchoring

    ñ 2 ( )

    11.52

    1.34

    4,85

    6,61

    7,30

    0,48

    25,09

    15,36

    1,49

    0.18

    Three-Month

    Anchoring

    7

    , 0,11

    (1,60)

    0,09

    (0,88)

    - 0 , 1 1

    (0,57)

    0.49

     5.74

    0,19

    - (2,92)

    0,25

     1,91

    0,34

    (2,82)

    0,37

    • (3,12)

    0,26

     4,89

    - 0 , 0 6

    (0,41)

    R 2 ( )

    1,38

    0,75

    0,36

    13.28

    6,81

    3,36

    17,79

    ,7,50

    15,36

    0,10

    level, Consideritig these results together with those frotn the three-motith atichor-

    itig model, we find that the dotnitiatit model (in bold) has a significantly positive

    coefficient for eight of 10 releases. Aside from the Core CPI, which earlier was

    shown to be a poor candidate for this analysis, the coefficient in the dominant

    (bold) model fails to be significant onlyjn the case of the ISM Manufacturing In-

    dex. The   ̂of the dominant models (again excluding the Core CPI) ranges from

    1.3 to 25 , with an average value of around 11 .

    The pattern of results is also sensible in light of the time series properties

    of the releases. The top three data releases, each of which is expressed in levels,

    were shown in Table 3 to display a high degree of persistence. In all three of

    these cases, we find that the model with the one-month lag as the anchor clearly

    dominates the model based on the three-month anchor. Although anchoring itself

    may or may not be rational, the forecasters seem sophisticated enough to treat

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    12/23

    38 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    value, (1 - A) = 7 /( 1 + 7 ) = 0.7|l/1.71 « 0.40. The

      R ^

      statistics of 11.5% for

    Consum er Confidence and 4.9% for New Hom e Sales are also notable. Given the

    importance of these releases for bond markets and the relatively large variance of

    surprises, an

     R ^

     of even 5% represents a substantial amount of predictability with

    potentially noticeable implications for interest rate responses to these releases.

    The remaining releases in Table 4 are expressed in terms of changes or

    percent chan ges . Am ong these, the evidence for anchoring is pretty strong for both

    the one-month and the three-month anchoring models. In three of the six cases

    (again leaving aside the Core CRI), the one-month anchoring model yields the

    best fit. And in four cases (Durable Goods Orders, Industrial Production, Retail

    Sales, and Retail Sales ex-Auto), the null hypothesis of no anchoring is rejected

    at all conventional significance levjels regardless of whether a one- or three-m onth

    anchor is employed. For CPI and Nonfarm Payroll Employment, anchoring is

    significant in the case of the three- month anchor but not the one-month anchor.

    The magnitude of anchoring in the MMS forecasts of the change variables

    is generally somewhat less than that of the level variables, though it appears to

    be economically meaningful in most cases. The magnitude for Retail Sales falls

    close to the middle of the pack; the coefficient of 0.25 in the one-lag model for

    Retail Sales implies forecasters place roughly 20% (0.25/1.25 = 0.20) of the

    weight on that anchor. In addition, the forecast errors for Retail Sales appear to be

    unusually predictable: the

     R ^

      suggests that the forecast-anchor gap explains 25%

    of the variance in surprises. Among the other change variables, the   R ^   covers a

    range comparable to that ofth e level variables.

    An implicit assumption of the OLS framework is that the professional fore-

    casters' goal is to minimize the squared forecast errors. But they might face in-

    centives under which this goal is not optimal, making our evidence potentially

    misleading. As an alternative, Basu and Markov (2004) suggest the use of a lin-

    ear loss function, which is implemented vis-à-vis median regression, based on the

    notion that a 3% forecast error may only be three times m ore costly than a 1% er-

    ror, rather than nine times as costly. Indeed, in a study of earnings forecasts, they

    find that evidence of bias is significantly weakened when the median regression

    approach is adopted.

    We examine the robustness of our results by estimating equation (7) using

    the median regression approach and find remarkably consistent results to those

    in Table 4.''* Specifically, we find significant evidence of anchoring (i-statistic

    in excess of 2.0) in all but one ease where the OLS produced significant evi-

    dence of anchoring, the exception being New Home Sales (the three-month c ase).

    Moreover, median regression estimates also resulted in statistically significant an-

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    13/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 381

    The results in Table 4 indicate that the gap between the current forecast and

    the anchor predicts future surprises in almost every release we consider. In those

    tests,

      the alternative hypothesis is that forecast errors are unpredictable, that is,

    orthogonal to all known information. A more dem anding test of our model would

    involve testing it against a more general model, for instance, a model where the

    forecast error m ight be related to the current forecast for some unspecified reason.

    To implement this, we test whether the coefficient on the hypothesized anchor is

    opposite in sign and equal in magnitude to the coefficient on the current forecast.

    In Table 5, we show estimates of the un restricted anchoring model,

     8) ,  S =

    For these regressions, we choose the anchor from the best-fitting model in Table 4.

    The first column in Table 5 denotes the choice of anchor. The next two columns

    display the point estimates of 7/ and 7^. The final two colum ns display the Wald

    test that 7f = - 7 ^ and the model  R^.

    TABLE 5

    Anchoring in Macroeconomic Forecasts:

    Predicting Surprises with Forecasts and Lagged Reieases

    In Table 5, we report estimates from the model,  Si =  7f F, .̂ -TAA- I ,  + £(. The number' of months (h) used in construct-

    ing the anchor  {Ah ,  is seiected from the best-fitting model in Table 4 and is reported in the first column. The second

    and third column report  yp  an d  - I A .  The fourth column reports the asymptotic p-vaiue of the Wald test of the re-

    striction 7f =   —fA .  and the fifth coium n reports the  R^.  Newey and West (1987) f-statistics appear in parentheses.

    h 7 ,  - A   Wa ld fl2 ( )

    Consumer Confidence

    ISM Index

    New Home Sales

    Durabie Goods Orders

    industriai Produotion

    Nonfarm Payroii Empioyment

    Retaii Saies

    Retaii Sales ex-Auto

    Consumer Price index (CPi)

    1

    1

    1

    3

    1

    3

    1

    1

    3

    0.76

    (5.92)

    0.25

    (1.29)

    0.46

    (2.14)

    0.55

    (3.35)

    • 0.23

    (3.11)

    0.36

    (2.18)

    0.31

    (2.59)

    0.36

    (2.11)

    0.35

    - 0 . 7 4

    (6.03)

    - 0 . 2 4

    (1.31)

    - 0 . 5 0

    (2.50)

    - 0 . 4 2

    (2.00)

    - 0 . 1 1

    (2.47)

    - 0 . 2 3

    (1.77)

    - 0 . 2 3

    (5.80)

    - 0 . 2 7

    (3.48)

    - 0 . 1 5

    0.27

    0.72

    0.38

    0.68

    0.06

    0.08

    0.43

    0.61

    0.07

    12.00

    1.43

    5.40

    13.38

    9.42

    4.92

    25.43

    15.53

    17.22

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    14/23

    38 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    the difference in the coefficients' magnitude is often remarkab ly sm all (e,g,, for

    Consumer Confidence, 7/ = 0,76 and 7^ = —0,74),

    The Wald tests reported in the fourth column of Table 5 show that only in

    the aberrant case of Core CPIis the null hypothesis that 7/ =  —7̂ rejected at

    all conventional significance levels. Elsewhere, the Wald statistic provides scant

    evidence against the null hypothesis. The possible exceptions are Industrial Pro-

    duction and Nonfarm Payroll Employment, where the null hypothesis can be re-

    jected at the 10 , but not the 5 , level. Even there, the discrepancies betw een

    7/

      and 7^ are relatively small. Finally, comparing the fit of the unrestricted and

    restricted (Table 4, bold) models reveals only a small deterioration in fit when we

    impose the 7/ = -74 restriction (in the original specification); the decline in

      ^

     i

    typically on the order of a percentage point.

    Our model of anchoring bias

    assumes that forecasters always tilt their fore-

    cast toward the value of the previous m onth 's (or few m onth s') release by a simila

    proportion. On the other hand, it is plausible that the extent to which forecasters

    treat a lagged release as a reasonable starting point for current-month forecasts

    could depend on whether that lagged release is viewed as representative or nor-

    mal. For instance , when lagged realizations are far out of line with recent trends or

    broader historical experience, they may have,less influence on current forecasts.

    Of course, the opposite might be true; that is, it might be that most of the anchor-

    ing occurs on the heels of outliers or trend-breaking obse rvations, while very little

    anchoring occurs in normal times.

    In principle, such considerations would suggest that a more complex spec-

    ification than our simple anchoring model might be informative, but there is no

    clear a priori case for any particular alternative. Thus, rather than postulate a m ore

    complicated anchoring model, we simply re-estimate equation (4) on a subsam-

    ple of observations that excludes outliers. Specifically, we exclude observations

    in which the change in the release from month f

     —

      2 to f

     —

      1 is larger than

    standard deviations of the historical monthly change in the release. The results are

    contained in Table 6,

    As with the model restrictioi tests in Table 5, we report results only for the

    best-fitting model (one- or three-month anchoring) based on the Table 4 regres-

    sions. The second and third columns report the estimates of 7 and the   ̂ statistic

    from the full sample, while the final two columns report the same for the sample

    that excludes outliers. Broadly speaking, the outlier exclusion does not substan-

    tially alter the picture. The estimates of 7 are all still positive; in most cases, the

    estimated degree of anchoring appears to increase somewhat. The most notable

    change is in the case of the ISM Manufacturing Index release, where the coeffi-

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    15/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 383

    TABLE 6

    Anchoring in Macroeconomic Forecasts: Excluding Outliers

    In Table 6. we report estimates from the mo del, S| =  7 ( F | — / \ _ (, )  £(. using the fuli samp le and a subsa mp ie that excludes

    observations in which the change in the previous month's release over the prior month is large (see text for detaiis). The

    first column reports the number of months (fi) used in constructing the anchor (Äh). The second and third columns report

    the parameter estimate. 7. and

      ^

      from the fuil sampie. The fourth and fifth columns report the parameter estimate.

    7. and

      ^

      from the subsampie. Newey and West (1987) t-statistics appear in parentheses.

    Consumer Confidence

    iSM index

    New Home Saies

    Consumer Price index (CPI)

    Core CPI

    Durable Goods Orders

    ihdustriai Production

    Nonfarm Payroii Employment

    Retaii Sales

    Retail Sales ex-Auto

    Consumer Price index (CPI)

    Core CPI

    Lags

    h

    1

    1

    1

    3

    1

    3

    1

    3

    1

    1

    3

    ,1

    Ail

    Observations

    7

    0.71

    • (6.10)

    0.22

    (1.26)

    0.53

    (2.75)

    0.26

    (4.89)

    0.04 •

    (0.67)

    0.49

    (5.74)

    0.14

    (3.24)

    0.25

    (1.91)

    0.25

    (4.74)

    0.29

    • (4.04)

    0.26

    (4.89)

    0.04

    (0.67)

    R 2  ( )

    11.52

    1.34

    4.85

    15.36

    0.18

    13.28

    7.30

    3.36

    25.09

    15.36

    15.36

    0.18

    7

    0.79

    (5.48)

    0.44

    (2.17)

    0.54

    (2.01)

    0.21

    (1.41)

    0.03

    (2.24)

    0.61

    (3.67)

    0.17

    (2.19)

    0.17

    (1.83)

    0.23

    (3.78)

    0.41

    (3.33)

    0.21

    (1.41)

    0.03

    (2.24)

    Outiiers

    Excluded

    R2

      ( )

    13.16

    4.89

    3.41

    10.54

    0.03

    17.98

    4.89

    1.68

    15.59

    15.86

    10.54

    0.03

    variance in future surprises. The pattern in the results is remarkably uniform. Ac-

    cordingly, anchoring appears to be an important and robust feature of the MMS

    forecast data. These findings thus raise the question that we examine in the sec-

    ond part of our analys is: How does anchoring bias in these forecasts affect market

    reactions to the measured surprises?

    V. Testing Market Reactions

    A, The Framework

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    16/23

    384 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    (9)

    Ai,  =

      6S

    y

    where Ai represents the change in the asset price in a small window surrounding

    the release and the coefficient

      ô

     measures the sensitivity of the asset price to the

    surprise, S = A

      F .

    The results above imply that these surprises—or forecast errors, to be

    precise—are partly predictable due to anchoring bias in the MMS forecasts. If

    markets are informationally efficient and market participants understand the na-

    ture of this bias, then market prices should anticipate this component of the fore-

    cast error. In particular, market interest rates should not respond to the p redictable

    component of the forecast error. We investigate this hypothesis using the model

    laid out in equation (5) of Section II,  Ai =

     Ô\S^  Ô2{S —

     5f) +v,. Again,   Ai r

    resents the change in either the two- or 10-year U.S. Treasury bond yield in the

    moments surrounding the release and 5f = 7(F, —  Â;,) represents the predicted

    component of the surprise induced by anchoring. We thus refer to the second

    regressor as the residual component of the surprise—the true surprise, from the

    econometrician s point of view.

    We focus on two hypotheses concerning how market participants react to the

    predicted and residual components of the surprise. If market participants take the

    forecasts at face value and are unaware of the predictability in surprises, then we

    would expect to find no difference in the response to the predicted and residual

    components of the surprise, or ¿i  =62. Finding ¿ =62  would indicate that the bond

    markets are not informationally efficient in the sense that data known at the time

    of the forecast can help predict movements in bond p rices. Alternatively, if market

    forecasts are informationally efficient—market participants are aware of the pre-

    dictability induced by anchoring in the MMS forecasts—then we would expect to

    find no response of interest rates to variation in the predictable component of the

    surprise, or ô\ =  0,

    Our investigation of the response of interest rates to the predicted and resid-

    ual components of surprises in macroeconomic releases is related to the previous

    work of Mishkin (1981). Mishkin examines whether the surprise implied by the

    reaction of interest rates to inflation news is consistent with the unpredictable

    component of inflation identified from an autoregressive specification. Specifi-

    cally, Mishkin estimates the following system.

    (10)

    Ai,

      = a

      ô

      v ,

    and

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    17/23

    Campbell

     and

     Sharpe

      85

    which presumably incorporate  a  wealth  of  information beyond  the lags of the

    series being forecasted. Moreover, our analysis differentiates between forecasters

    and trader/investors.

    B Em pirical Results

    Before reviewing  the empirical results, we first introduce  two variations on

    the basic specification

      of

     equation (5) that apply

     to

     some o fthe releases. First,

     we

    control for revisions to previously released data that are announced along with the

    current month's data. This is done by  including the value ofthe revision as an ad-

    ditional regressor. Revisions

     are

      announced with the release

     of

     Industrial Produc -

    tion, Nonfarm Payrolls, and Retail Sales (both the top-line and ex-Auto releases).

    For Nonfarm Payrolls and Retail Sales, revisions to two previous months of data

    are released

      and

     included

      as

     regressors;

     but to

      conserve space,

     we

      only report

    the parameter estimate

     for

     the most recent m onth's revision.

     In

     the Nonfarm Pay-

    rolls regression, we also include a control for the surprise to the unemployment

    rate (based on the MM S survey), which  is  released simultaneously  but generally

    with less market impact than

     the

     payroll num bers. Thus,

     our

     general event-study

    regression

     can be

     written

     as

    (11)

      Ai, =

      6\S ,+52{S,-S ,)  + R,-\-v,.

    The second variation, used   for  Retail Sales  and the CPI, is to  include the

    surprise decom positions

     of

     tw forecasted releases, the top-line release,

     5 f,

     and

     its

    key subcomponent,

     ¿ Xf

     (Retail Sales ex-Auto or Core CPI, ex-Food and E nergy):

    (12)  Ai, = 5iS ,+02{S,-S ¡)+o\SX ¡ +

    Here,  {5\, Ô2 are the coefficients

      on

     the predicted surprise and the residual

     for

     the

    top-line release, whereas {ô[, ¿2)

     are the

     coefficients

      on the

     key subcomponents.

    The model

     is

     estimated via generalized method

     of

     moments (GM M).

     In

     par-

    ticular, note that the terms  S^{SXf)  that appear in equations (11) and (Í2) are not

    directly observed

     and

     must

     be

     estimated from

      the

     first-stage anchoring model

     in

    equation

      (4).

     These generated regressors infiuence

      the

      sampling distribution

     of

    the interest rate response coefficients   {Si,S2,ô[,Ô2).  In  particular,  the sampling

    variability induced

     by

     using generated regressors tends

     to

     increase

     the

     amount

     of

    sampling variability

     in the

     secon d-stage coefficients. We follow

      the

     approach

     of

    Newey (1984) by including the first-stage anchoring model (equation (4)), along

    with

      the

      second-stage event-study regressions (equations

      (11) and

     (12)),

      in the

    GMM system.'^

     The

     resulting variance-covariance matrix fully accounts

     for the

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    18/23

    386 Journal of Financial and Qua ntitative Analysis

    one standard deviation of the (total) surprise,

      S .

      The ¡first three columns report

    the parameter estimates. The fourth column reports the Wald test of the null hy-

    pothesis that bond yields react symmetrically to the predictable and unpredictable

    component of th MMS surprise,

      \

     = ¿ 2 ' ' ' T he fifth column reports the model

     R^.

    TABLE 7

    Interest Rate Reactions to Ma croeconomic Releases

    n Tabie 7, we report GMM estimates of the model,

    the Wa id test that (5i = 62, the mod el's

     R^.

      and th

    R | ,  in the final three columns. *** and ** deno te st

    Consumer Confidence

    2-year

    10-year

    ISM Index

    2-year

    10-year

    New Home Sales

    2-year

    10-year

    Durable Goods Orders

    2-year

    10-year

    Industrial Production

    2-year

    10-year

    Nonfarm Payroii Empioyment

    2-year

    10-year

    Retail Saies: Auto

    2-year

    10-year

    Retail Sales: ex-Autc

    2-year

    10-year

    CPI: Food and Energy

    2-year

    10-year

    Core CPI

    2-year

    10-year

    Looking down

    0.19

    0.07

    - 2 . 3 3

    - 3 . 4 5

    0.09

    0.10

    - 0 . 2 5

    - 0 . 4 5

    - 0 . 1 2

    0.00

    1.06

    0.97

    0.03

    0.09

    - 0 . 2 0

    - 0 . 3 2

    - 0 . 3 2

    - 0 . 7 4

    7.43

    6.50

    the columns

    Ail =

      ¿1S, + Ri

      .̂ V|. We also report the p -value o

      R^ from a regression of the interest rate chang e on the total surprise

    itistical significance at the

      1%

     an d 5% levels, respectiveiy.

    ¿2

    1 69

    1 60

    2.31***

    2.09***

    0.85***

    0.82***

    1 39

    1 16

    0.76***

    0.74***

    6.27***

    4.96***

    1 44

    1.31***

    3.28***

    2.80***

    - 0 . 3 8

    - 0 . 3 6

    2 2 9 —

    2.14***

    of Table

    -

    -

    -

    -

    0.55***

    0.49***

    1 65

    1 08

    1 62

    1 02

    1 23

    1 08

    -

    -

    7 reveals

    0.00

    0.00

    0.23

    0.21

    0.21

    0.23

    0.00

    0.00

    0.07

    0.09

    0.08

    0.07

    0.17

    0.12

    0.02

    0.01

    0.96

    0.71

    0.68

    0.69

    R 2 ( % )

    46.9

    44.0

    52.4

    51.9

    17.3

    17.6

    • 22.6

    19.4

    20.7

    19.2

    57.3

    50.8

    30.4

    29.2

    30.4

    29.2

    28.8

    28.6

    28.8

    28.6

    three broad findings.

    fl| (•%

    38.1

    39.4

    49.6

    47.4

    16.6

    17.0

    18.5

    14.4

    19.2

    18.2

    56.3

    49.8

    25.4

    23.5

    25.4

    23.5

    28.5

    28.3

    28.5

    28.3

    First

    consistent with previous research, we find that the releases account for a

     signif

    icant fraction of bond yield movements, ranging from roughly 20% to 50%, as

    measured by the iO^. Second, the estimate of

     ¿2,

     the coefficient on the unexpect

    component of the surprise on bond yields, is significant at the 1% level for ev-

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    19/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe 87

    Wald test of the null hypothesis that bond yields react symmetrically to the un-

    expected and expected components of the surprise is rejected at the 10% level or

    lower in five out of eight cases,'^ This is notable, since the Wald test fully ac-

    counts for the extra variability in the measurement of

     ôi

     resulting from 5f being a

    generated regressor.

    Focusing on the results for individual releases indicates that the exceptions

    to the broad pattern of results can largely be rationalized as special situations.

    First, for the (top-line) CPI, both the expected and unexpected components of

    the surprise are not significant, so vve obviously would be unable to reject the

    hypothesis that the components have the same effect. But this owes to the finding

    that, conditional on Core CPI, shocks to the total CPI (including Food and Energy)

    have little incremental effect on bond yields,'^ The market perceives the Core

    CPI as a better indicator of future inflation and Federal Reserve policy. The o ther

    obvious exception is in the Core CPI results. Here, we find that the estimated

    magnitude of ¿2 is large and not significantly different from ¿1, But this result

    presumably owes to the poor performance of the anchoring model for the Core

    CPI, which explains less than 1% of the variation in the surprise. As previously

    argued, this could be attributable to the granularity of Core CPI and its resultant

    lack of time-series variation in our sample period,

    A few other aspects to our finding s in Table 7 are notable, even if not central

    to our main hypotheses. First, we are comforted by the finding—consistent with

    previous research findings and views on Wall Street—that the employment release

    shows the largest interest rate effects and has the most explanatory power of all

    the releases (in the event study window). It is also interesting to note that in every

    case where it is available, the revision to the previous month's data (^) also has

    a significant positive effect on interest rates. Surprisingly, in most of these cases,

    the coefficient on the revision is almost as large as the coefficient on the current

    month (residual) surprise.

    Finally, for comparison purposes, column (6) shows

      R^

      statistics from the

    standard event study regression model of data surprises (equation (9)), which

    does not split up the forecast error into two pieces. Comparing these statistics

    to those in column (5) provides one quantitative measure of how much better our

    anchoring model explains interest rate movements compared to that benchmark.

    Comparing columns (5) and (6) reveals that adjusting for the predictable com-

    ponent of the surprise increases the explanatory power of the releases for interest

    rate movements in every case that we consider,^° In some cases such as Consumer

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    20/23

    388 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    Confidence, Durable Goods, and Retail Sales the increase in   ̂ can be substan-

    tial, on the order of

      2 5 % ,

      while in the case of other releases the improvement is

    more modest, ranging between 1% and 10%,

    Summing up, the resuhs in Table 7 suggest that market participants do react

    to the unpredictable com ponent but not to the predictable component of the M MS

    surprises. Moreover, focusing on the unpredictable component of the surprise uni-

    formly increases the explanatory power of the releases for interest rate changes.

    Accordingly, these results suggest that the informational inefficiency of MMS

    forecasts identified in Tables 4, 5,

    and 6 does not lead to any important source of

    inefficiency in interest rate marke ts. Market participants apparently anticipate the

    anchoring behavior of professional forecasters.

    V I Conclusions

    We find that professional economic forecasts are biased in a manner consis-

    tent with a specific behavioral model of forecasting behavior: the anchoring and

    adjustment hypo thesis of Tversky and Kahnem an (1974), Specifically, we find

    that forecasts of any given release are anchored toward recent months' realized

    values of that release, thereby giving rise to predictable surprises. In some cases,

    such as Retail Sales, we find that up to 2 5 % of the surprise in the macroeconom ic

    release is predictable, due to a substantial weight being placed on the anchor by

    professional forecasters. Moreover, the evidence in favor of anchoring is remark-

    ably consistent across each of the key releases that we study and is robust to the

    exclusion of outliers.

    In light of the significant evidence of systematic bias in professional fore-

    casts,

      we examine the implications for market prices of U.S, Treasury bonds.

    Specifically, we exam ine whe ther ¡yields on two- and 10-year Treasury yields react

    to thé predictable component of forecast surprises induced by anchoring behav-

    ior. Across the board, we find that interest rates only respond to the unpredictable

    component of the surprise. Estimates of the market reaction to the predictable

    component of data surprise in every case are small and insignificant, whereas the

    estimated reaction to the unpredictable component is large and significant.

    We thereby conclude that market participants do not take professional fore-

    casts at face value when responding to macroeconomic news. To the contrary, at

    least some influential market participants are apparently able to parse the com-

    ponent of these forecasts due to anchoring from the component of the forecasts

    containing useful information about the expected future path of these macro-

    economic variables. As a result.

    the behavioral bias displayed by the forecasts

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    21/23

    Cam pbell and Sharpe  89

    In that case, minimizing mean squared or absolute error would not necessarily be

    the optimal strategy,

    A related point is that our findings only provide a characterization of the bias

    of a represen tative forecaster, and this ignores the likelihood that there are sub-

    stantial cross-sectional differences in ability. What is more, individual forecasts

    are likely to be influenced by strategic considerations, as suggested by Ehrbeck

    and Waldmann (1996) or Ottaviani and Sorensen (2006), Indeed, the latter study

    models circumstances in which forecasters might find it optimal to issue forecasts

    that underweight their own private signals.

    Finally, our findings raise the question of whether other markets are as adept

    as the U.S, Treasury market at processing the information in professional fore-

    casts.

     In

     particular, we wonder whether biases

     in

     professional forecasts are

     a

    source of inefficiency in markets that are comm only perceived to be less efficient

    than the U.S, Treasury market, such as markets for individual stocks.

    Appendix Specification of GM M System R eported in Table 7

    Following Newey (1984), we account for the generated regressors in equations (10)

    and (11) by including the specification of the anchoring model, equation (4), in the GMM

    system. Specifically, we estimate the following exactly identified GMM system for each

    data release (row) contained in Table 7:

     A-l

    =

      -h,

      (6 )

    =

      y

     5,-70-71

     {Pt-Ah))

      F,-Â,,)

    {Ai, -  ¿0 -  5|5f -

      Ö2

      (5 , -  5 0 -  0/?,)

    {Ai,  -

      ¿0

     -

      àxS',

     -

      Si {S,

     -

      SI)

     -

      4>R,)

     5f

    {Ai,

      -

      (5o

     -

      (5,5f

     -

      ¿2 (5 ,

     -

      5f)

     -

      R,) R ,

    in the case of Consumer Confidence, ISM Index, New Homes Sales, Durable Goods, In-

    dustrial Prod uction, and Nonfarm Payroll Employm ent, In the case of Retail Sales and CPI,

    we estimate the system

    (A-2)

    {S ,

     -

      10

     -

      jy {F,

     -

      Ak))

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    22/23

    39 Journal of Financial and Quan titative Analysis

    in the case of Retail Sales and the GPI. In each case the GMM system is estimated by

    minimizing,  gT{0)'gT{0),  over  6  andlnote the omission of a weighting matrix due to the

    just identified nature of the system. Finally, the variance-covariance matrix is estimated by

    (A-3)

    where

    (A-4)

    ST  =

    ' o , r

     

    E

    ^ ^ ^

      dgr {e) •

    system is estimated for each release and each bond maturity

    and

    (A-5)

    Finally, we note that a separate

    (two and 10 years).

    References

    Aggarwal, R.; S. Mohanty; and F. Song. | Are Survey Forecasts of Macroeconomic Variables Ratio-

    nal?

    Journal of Business, 68 (1995), 99-119 .

    Agga rwal, R., and D. Schirm. Bala ncelo f Trade Ann ouncem ents and Asset Prices: Influence on

    Equity Prices, Exchange Rates and Interest Rates. Journal of International Money and Finance

    11 (1992), 80 -9 5. I

    Ande rsen, T.; T. Bollerslev; F. Diebold; and C. Vega. M icro Effects of Macro Anno uncem ents: Real-

    Time Price Discovery in Foreign Exchange.

    American Economic Review,

     93 (2003), 38-62 .

    Balduzz i, P.; E. Elton; and T. Green. Econ om ic News and Bond Prices: Evidence from the U.S

    Treasury Market. Journal of F inancial and Qua ntitative Analysis,  36  2001

     ),

     523-543.

    Basu, S., and S. Markov. Loss Function Assum ptions in Rational Expec tations Tests on Financial

    Ana lysts' Earnings Forecasts. Journal of Accounting and Economics,  38 (2004), 171-203.

    Ehrbeck, T., and R. W aldmann. W hy are Professional Forecasters Biased? A gency versus Behaviora

    Explanations. Quarterly Journal of Econom ics,  111 (1996) , 21 -4 0 .

    Franke l, J., and K. Froot. Using Survey Data to Test Standard Propositions Regarding Exc hange R ate

    Expectations. America«  Economic Review, 77 (1987), 133-153.

    Gurkaynak, R.; B. Sack; and E. SwansonI 'The Sensitivity of Long-Term Interest Rates to Economic

    News: Evidence and Implications for Macroeconom ic Models. American Economic Review

    95 (2005), 42 5^ 36 . |

    Mishkin, F.  Are Market Forecasts Rational? American Economic Review, 71 (1981), 295-30 6.

    MuU ineaux, D. On Testing for Rationality: Another Look at the Livingston Price Expectations.

    Journal of P olitical Economy, 86 (197^8); 329-336.

    Newey, W. A Method of Mom ents Interpretation of Sequential Estimators.

    Economics Letters

    14(1984), 201-20 6. |

    Newey, W., and K. West. A Simple Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskeda sticity and Autoco rrelation

    Consistent Covariance Matrix. Econometrica,  55 (1987), 703-7 08.

    Nordh aus, W. Forecasting Efficiency: Cpn cepts and App lications. Review of Economics and Statis

  • 8/17/2019 Anchoring Bias in Consensus Forecasts

    23/23


Recommended