+ All Categories
Home > Science > Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Date post: 28-Jan-2018
Category:
Upload: carlbergstrom
View: 459 times
Download: 5 times
Share this document with a friend
91
Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health Carl T. Bergstrom Department of Biology University of Washington Department of Ecology and Evolution, UCLA January 6, 2016
Transcript
Page 1: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Anthropogenic evolution, ���externalities, and public health

Carl T. BergstromDepartment of Biology

University of Washington

Department of Ecology and Evolution, UCLA���January 6, 2016

Page 2: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Mark Tanaka Ben Althouse Ted Bergstrom Marc LipsitchUNSW IDM USCB Harvard

Participants in the 2011 Heron

Island Summit on Evolutionary Challenges in

Food, Health, and the Environment

Page 3: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Overview

Anthropogenic evolution and externalities.

Carroll et al (2014) Science 346:313

Public choice theory for public health

Althouse et al (2010) PNAS 107:1696

Timing of antiviral use during a pandemic

Tanaka et al (2014) Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health 2014:150

http://octavia.zoology.washington.edu

Page 4: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Anthropogenic evolution and externalities.Carroll al (2014) Science 346:313

Page 5: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Herbicide resistance

Heap (2012) OnlineGlyphosate (Roundup) resistant weeds

Page 6: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Antibiotic resistance

Bergstrom and Dugatkin (2016) Evolution 2nd ed.

Page 7: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Fisheries Induced Evolution

Borrell (2013) Nature

Page 8: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Harvesting Induced Evolution

Decreasing size in harvested, but not non-harvested, species of snow lotus in the Himalayas.

Law and Salick (2005) PNAS

Page 9: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Conservation & captive breeding

Page 10: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Gene drive

Harvard Wyss Institute Gene Drive FAQ

Page 11: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

In general, the problem with managing anthropogenic evolution is that

The species we ���want to evolve fast,evolve slow,

And the species we ���want to evolve slow,���evolve fast.

Images:  superbwallpapers.com,  free-­‐designer.net  

Page 12: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Evolutionary changes in wild populations generate externalities

Page 13: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

What are externalities? ���������

Economic side-effects that are���not captured by market prices.���

Page 14: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Negative ���externalities

Images:  Wikimedia  

Page 15: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Many other situations with negative externalities involve���common-pool resources: they are non-excludable, ���

but rivalrous. The result in tragedies of the commons.

Page 16: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

cc  by  flickr:bekhiann  

Positiveexternalities

cc  by  flickr:Brigit  Murphy  

Page 17: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Meanwhile, pure public goods are non-excludable ���and non-rivalrous. Creating these generates positive ���externalities.

Private markets tend to under-allocate to pure public ���goods. Governments need to intervene.

National Defense is the example acceptedmost broadly on bothsides of the political aisle.

cfr.org  

Page 18: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Evolutionary changes in wild populations generate externalities

Harmful changes tend to be common pool issues. •  Non-excludable but rivalrous•  Hard to monitor, hard to attribute cause / blame

Beneficial changes tend to be pure public goods•  Non-excludable, non-rivalrous

Page 19: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

How can we deal with externalities?���������

Economists have a rich toolkit���(and extensive theory, of course!)

Page 20: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Command ���and control���

policies

wikimedia  

Page 21: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Sir Alexander Fleming,

Nobel Prize Lecture, 1945

Page 22: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

wikimedia  

Page 23: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

(We need) Antibiotic regulation

Bergstrom and Dugatkin (2016) Evolution 2nd ed.

Page 24: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Tort Law

wikimedia  

Page 25: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Aventis Starlink Corn

Images:  NCI,  wikimedia.  

Page 26: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Establish property rights (cap and trade)

cc  flickr:Thomas  Berg  

Page 27: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Catch shares for fisheries

wikimedia  

Page 28: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Pigovian taxes

In Sweden, spirits are taxed €50 euro / liter

Page 29: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Pigovian subsidiesPoster:  Wikimedia  

Page 30: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

As evolutionary biologists we can explain how human actions lead

to anthropogenic evolution ���

We would do well to understand the the policy tools available for modulating these actions.

Page 31: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Public choice theory for public healthAlthouse et al (2010) PNAS 107:1696

Page 32: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

When should the government���get involved in public health?

When it can improve the lives of the most needy members of society.

Page 33: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

On efficiency grounds, when ���does government investment���in public health out-perform ���

private market solutions?

Page 34: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Public choice theory

SuscepEble� Infected � Removed  

Epidemiological modeling

Paul Samuelson 1955

Page 35: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Tetanus

Measles

Otitis media

Pandemic Influenza

Page 36: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Tetanus

Page 37: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Tetanus occurs when the soil microbe ���Clostridium tetani infects a deep wound.

It is not transmitted from human to humanVaccine targets the toxin, not the microbe.

Page 38: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

My tetanus vaccine doesn’t affect you, positively or negatively.

It is a pure private good. cc flickr : Penn State

Page 39: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Measles

Image: Helen Bergstrom, then age 6.

Page 40: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Images: kinderhelper.com

My problem�

Your problem �

Page 41: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Images: kinderhelper.com

Private good�

Positive externality�

Page 42: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

SuscepEble� Infected � Removed  

Vaccinate fraction p�

Page 43: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

SuscepEble� Infected � Removed  

Vaccinate fraction p�

Infections decrease linearly with ���fraction of the population vaccinated.

Page 44: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 45: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 46: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 47: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 48: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

OptimalSubsidy

Page 49: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

v(q) −C'(qN) − kX(q) = 0

Direct value of ���treating one individual

Cost of treating ���one individual

Effect of treating one ���person on all others.

First-order condition for social efficiency

Page 50: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

v(q) −C'(qN) − k q∂htreated (q)∂q

+ (1− q)∂huntreated (q)∂q

$

% &

'

( ) = 0

Direct value of ���treating one individual

Cost of treating ���one individual

Cost of one infection

Effect on other treated individuals

Effect on untreated individuals

Page 51: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

s = −k q∂htreated (q)∂q

+ (1− q)∂huntreated (q)∂q

$

% &

'

( )

In our measles example, vaccinationaffects untreated but not treated individuals

A Pigouvian subsidy of this magnitudealigns private and public interest

Page 52: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Otitis mediawikimedia

Page 53: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Otitis media is caused Streptococcus pneumonia and Haemophilus influenzae. ���Half of preschool aged children carry ���them asymptomatically.

Image: Dennis Kunkel

Page 54: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Otitis media occurs when these bacteria make their way up the eustachian tube into the tympanic cavity - and thus is rarely transmissible from the infection site.

www.patienteducationcenter.org

Page 55: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

American Academy of Pediatrics (2004)

Minimize use of antibiotics for uncomplicated otitis media.

Use amoxicillin rather than a late generation drug if antibiotics are necessary.

Page 56: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Patients vary in their ���need for the drug

Otherwise healthy children ���can easily clear the infection ���without treatment.

Children suffering from other complications mayneed drug treatment

Page 57: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

After Bonhoeffer et al. 1996

Steady-state resistanceincreases with fractiontreated.

Page 58: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Marginal private benefit

Marginal public benefit

Marginal cost

Page 59: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Optimaltax

Page 60: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

s = −k q∂htreated (q)∂q

+ (1− q)∂huntreated (q)∂q

$

% &

'

( )

In our Otitis media example, ���treatment affects other treated ���individuals but not those who are untreated

A Pigouvian tax of this magnitude aligns private and public interest

Page 61: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Pandemic Influenza

Images: http://www.coo.kz/

Page 62: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

•  Social distancing

•  Vaccination

•  Antivirals

Page 63: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Antivirals

Reduce mortality & morbidity������Reduce transmission ������Select for resistance

  Private good

  Positive externality

  Negative externality

Page 64: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

How should we distribute antivirals?

Flu Kits:���Families purchase in advance as insurance against pandemic

���Pharmacy distribution: Doses are distributed to individuals once infected

Page 65: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

After Lipsitch et al 2007

Page 66: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Flu kit scenario

Page 67: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Pharmacy distribution scenario

Page 68: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Timing of antiviral use during a pandemicTanaka et al (2014) Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health 2014:150

Page 69: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Staphylococcus aureus

Pseudomonas aeruginosa

Enterococcus sp.

Klebsiella pneumoniae

Page 70: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Surgical  ICU  central  line  catheter  infecEon  rates    Denver  Health  Quality  Report  2009  

Page 71: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 72: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 73: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

When should we deploy a limited stockpile of antimicrobials to maximize benefits over the course of an epidemic?

Page 74: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Direct benefits (private goods): reduction of mortality and morbidity in treated individuals.

Indirect benefits (externalities): changes in the epidemic trajectory due to antimicrobial use.

Page 75: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

See  Handel,  Longini,  and  AnEa  (2007)  Proc  R.  Soc.  B  274:833-­‐837  

Page 76: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

See  Handel,  Longini,  and  AnEa  (2007)  Proc  R.  Soc.  B  274:833-­‐837  

Page 77: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

See  Handel,  Longini,  and  AnEa  (2007)  Proc  R.  Soc.  B  274:833-­‐837  

Page 78: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

See  Handel,  Longini,  and  AnEa  (2007)  Proc  R.  Soc.  B  274:833-­‐837  

Page 79: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

X  

YSU  YST  

YR  

Z  θ   ν/(1-­‐ε)  

ν  

ν  

1-­‐fξ  

fξ  

Page 80: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Treatment  start  Eme  (days)  

FracEo

n  of  stockpile  used  successfully  

Page 81: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health
Page 82: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Model results (≠policy suggestions)

Limited stockpile? Don’t use it right away.

Even with an unlimited stockpile, the total social welfare is greatest when one delays antimicrobial use some time into the epidemic.

Page 83: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Why ?

Page 84: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Indirect benefits come from reducing overshoot by reducing transmission at and beyond the epidemic threshold, i.e., late in the epidemic, to minimize overshoot.

Page 85: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Direct benefits depend on the number ���of treatment failures due to resistance.Here timing is everything.  

Page 86: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Direct benefits depend on the number ���of treatment failures due to resistance.Here timing is everything.  

Page 87: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

To summarize:

Early use generates negative externalities by promoting the evolution of antiviral resistance.

Late use creates positive externalities, by reducing the overshoot of the epidemic.

You might take this as an argument in favor of delaying antiviral treatment until well into an epidemic.

Page 88: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Generally not a good idea to delay antiviral use.

Delaying use •  may not be ethical •  prevents any chance of early eradication•  risks wasting doses if use begins too late

Page 89: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Correctly ordering the use of multiple drugs may be feasible.

Compare  Wu  et  al.  2009  PLoS  Medicine  

Page 90: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

SummaryAnthropogenic evolution in wild populations has profound costs—and benefits—for society. ������But its consequences are diffuse and rarely captured by economic markets.

We can manage anthropogenic evolution—but we need the tools and theory from public choice economics to implement effective policy.

This is our chance as evolutionary biologists to be societally relevant. Let’s do this!

Page 91: Anthropogenic evolution, externalities, and public health

Mark Tanaka Ben Althouse Ted Bergstrom Marc LipsitchUNSW IDM USCB Harvard

Participants in the 2011 Heron

Island Summit on Evolutionary Challenges in

Food, Health, and the Environment


Recommended