+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for...

Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for...

Date post: 11-Oct-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
14
Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas Gschwend. 2013. “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” Political Analysis. 1. European Parties on a Common Left-Right Scale (page 2) 2. Comparing Rescaled and Unscaled Party Estimates (page 3) 3. Dierences of our Scaling Procedure and Groseclose et al. (1999) (page 4) 4. Another Validation: Party System Polarization (page 5) 5. Estimation Details: A Spatial Model of Valence in the UK (page 8) 6. Problems of Extending our Approach to the European Integration Dimension (page 12) 7. Excluded Observations: Government Defection in the 2009 European Parliament Elec- tion (page 13) 1
Transcript
Page 1: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Appendix

James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas Gschwend. 2013.“A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.”

Political Analysis.

1. European Parties on a Common Left-Right Scale (page 2)

2. Comparing Rescaled and Unscaled Party Estimates (page 3)

3. Di↵erences of our Scaling Procedure and Groseclose et al. (1999) (page 4)

4. Another Validation: Party System Polarization (page 5)

5. Estimation Details: A Spatial Model of Valence in the UK (page 8)

6. Problems of Extending our Approach to the European Integration Dimension (page12)

7. Excluded Observations: Government Defection in the 2009 European Parliament Elec-tion (page 13)

1

Page 2: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Figure A-1: European Parties on a Common Left-Right Scale (2009)

Communist Party of Luxembourg (Luxembourg)The Left (Luxembourg)Extreme left (New Anticapitalist Party, Workers Struggle) (France)Left Alliance (Finland)Communist Party of Austria (Austria)Citizens List (Luxembourg)Libertas (Ireland)Communist Refoundation Party (Italy)Communist Party of Slovakia (Slovakia)Hungarian Communist Workers Party (Hungary)Party for Animals (The Netherlands)Ecological and Environmental Movement (Cyprus)Green Party (Ireland)Eestimaa Rahvaliit (Estonia)Alternative Democratic Reform Party (Luxembourg)Coalition Agreement for the Future − CenterLeft (Poland)Lithuanian Peasant Popular Union (Lithuania)Erakond Eestimaa Rohelised (Estonia)Hans−Peter Martins List (Austria)Democratic Party of Pensioners of Slovenia (Slovenia)Youth Party (Slovenia)Greater Romania Party (Romania)Conservative Party (Romania)National Union Attack (ATAKA) (Bulgaria)Slovenian National Party (Slovenia)National Resurrection Party (Lithuania)NAPRED (Bulgaria)Society for Other Politics (Latvia)Order, Lawfulness, and Justice (RZS) (Bulgaria)Green Party (Czech Republic)Slovenian Peoples Party (Slovenia)Libertas (Poland)Union of Greens and Farmers (Latvia)Christian Democratic Peoples Party (Hungary)Christian−Democratic National Peasants Party (Romania)The Right (Italy)Movement for a Better Hungary (Hungary)National Front (France)Alliance for the Future of Austria (Austria)Proud of the Netherlands (The Netherlands)Freedom Party of Austria (Austria)Party for Freedom (The Netherlands)British National Party (BNP) (United Kingdom)

Democratic Liberal Party (Romania)Christian and Democratic Union−Czechoslovak Peoples Party (Czech Republic)Union of Christian and Centre Democrats (Italy)Christian Democrats in Finland (Finland)Polish Peoples Party (Poland)Christian Democratic Appeal (The Netherlands)Fine Gael (Ireland)New Democracy (Greece)Social Democratic Party (Portugal)Christian Democratic Union/Christian Social Union (Germany)Civic Union (Latvia)Citizens for European Development of Bulgaria (GERB) (Bulgaria)Peoples Party (Latvia)Democratic Rally (Cyprus)SMK (Slovakia)New Era Party (Latvia)Civic Platform (Poland)Christian Democratic Movement (Slovakia)Austrian Peoples Party (Austria)Blue Coalition (SDS−DSB) (Bulgaria)Democratic and Social Center − Peoples Party (Portugal)Christian Social Peoples Party (Luxembourg)Slovenian Democratic Party (Slovenia)Slovak Democratic and Christian Union (Slovakia)New Slovenia − Christian Peoples Party (Slovenia)Isamaa ja Res Publica Liit (Estonia)The People of Freedom (Italy)Union for a Popular Movement (France)Democratic Union of Hungarians in Romania (Romania)National Coalition Party (Finland)Fidesz−Hungarian Civic Union (Hungary)Homeland Union − Lithuanian Christian Democrats (Lithuania)

Order and Justice Party (Lithuania)True Finns (Finland)Slovak National Party (Slovakia)Popular Orthodox Rally (Greece)Reformed Political Party (The Netherlands)North League (Italy)UK Independence Party (UKIP) (United Kingdom)

Election Action of Lithuanias Poles (Lithuania)Hungarian Democratic Forum (Hungary)Christian Union (The Netherlands)Conservatives (United Kingdom)For Fatherland and Freedom (Latvia)Law and Justice (Poland)Civic Democratic Party (Czech Republic)

Eesti Keskerakond (Estonia)Liberal Democrats (United Kingdom)Labour Party (Lithuania)For Real (Slovenia)Liberal Democracy of Slovenia (Slovenia)Democratic Movement (France)Italy of Values (Italy)Democrats 66 (The Netherlands)Democratic Party (Luxembourg)New Union Social Liberals (Lithuania)Young Liberals (Austria)Alliance of Free Democrats (Hungary)Peoples Party − Movement for Democratic Slovakia (Slovakia)Movement for Rights and Freedoms (DPS) (Bulgaria)European Party (Cyprus)National Movement for Stability and Progress (NDSV) (Bulgaria)Free Democratic Party (Germany)Free Forum (Slovakia)Latvias First Party/Latvias Way (Latvia)Centre Party (Finland)Swedish Peoples Party (Finland)Fianna Fail (Ireland)Liberal and Centre Union (Lithuania)Liberals Movement of the Republic of Lithuania (Lithuania)National Liberal Party (Romania)Peoples Party for Freedom and Democracy (The Netherlands)Eesti Reformierakond (Estonia)

Labour (United Kingdom)Social Democratic Party of Finland (Finland)Social Democratic Party (Romania)Socialist Party (France)Left and Freedom (Italy)Czech Social Democratic Party (Czech Republic)Labour Party (The Netherlands)Labour Party (Ireland)Social Democratic Party of Lithuania (Lithuania)Movement for Social Democracy (Cyprus)Harmony Centre (Latvia)Coalition for Bulgaria (BSP) (Bulgaria)Panhellenic Socialist Movement (Greece)Luxembourg Socialist Workers Party (Luxembourg)Democratic Left Alliance (Poland)Hungarian Socialist Party (Hungary)Direction − Social Democracy (Slovakia)Socialist Party (Portugal)Social Democratic Party (Germany)Social Democratic Party of Austria (Austria)Sotsiaaldemokraatlik Erakond (Estonia)Democratic Party (Italy)Democratic Party (Cyprus)Social Democrats (Slovenia)

Green Left (The Netherlands)Ecologist Greens (Greece)The Greens (Austria)Green Party (United Kingdom)For Human Rights in United Latvia (Latvia)Alliance 90 + The Greens (Germany)The Greens (Luxembourg)The Greens (France)Green League (Finland)Plaid Cymru (United Kingdom)Scottish National Party (United Kingdom)

Communist Party of Greece (Greece)The Left (Germany)Progressive Party of Working People (Cyprus)Democratic Union Coalition (Portuguese Communist Party and the Greens) (Portugal)Sinn Fein (Ireland)Left Bloc (Portugal)French Communist Party (France)Left Party (France)Communist Party of Bohemia and Moravia (Czech Republic)Socialist Party (The Netherlands)Coalition of the Radical Left (Greece)

●EUL.NGL

Greens.EFA

SD.PES

ALDE

ECR

EFD

EPP

No affiliation

−2 −1 0 1 2 3

Common European Left−Right Space

2

Page 3: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Figure A-2: Comparing Rescaled and Unscaled Party Estimates (2009)

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

● ●

−3 −2 −1 0 1 2 3

0

2

4

6

8

10

Rescaled Left−Right Party Positions

Uns

cale

d Le

ft−R

ight

Par

ty P

ositi

ons

Note: N=162 national party positions are shown in this comparison. Unscaled left-right party positions

are simple means of placements of parties in the EES survey, rescaled positions are our estimates. The two

sets of estimates correlate at r = 0.83. Outlier to far right is the British National Party, which is the most

right-wing party in Europe after rescaling, but ranks 98th when placed using simple means.

3

Page 4: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Di↵erences of our Scaling Procedure and Groseclose et al. (1999)

We further explain how our scaling procedure di↵ers from the ony by Groseclose et al.(1999). For Groseclose et al., ✓jkm are not party scores, but legislator ideal points obtainedfrom the Americans for Democratic Action (ADA). Moreover, Groseclose et al. calculatestandard errors for their adjusted ADA scores by inverting the Hessian of the likelihoodfunction. This may potentially understate the true uncertainty of the adjusted scores intwo ways. First, ADA scores are treated as data that are measured without error, yetthey are simply ideal points calculated using no more than 30 roll call votes each year.Secondly, the model specified assumes that the error term for an individual at any point intime is uncorrelated with past or future errors. While this assumption may be true, it isnoteworthy that other dynamic scaling techniques (e.g. Martin and Quinn, 2002) explicitlymake the opposite assumption of autocorrelated errors. By scaling across countries, we avoidthe second issue entirely, and we address the first issue by estimating uncertainty via thenon-parametric bootstrap (Efron and Tibshirani, 1994) in both stages of estimation.

Finally, a crucial di↵erence between the two methods lies in the interpretation of ✓m. ForGroseclose et al., ✓m is an individual meta-parameter that captures the mean ideal point ofthe legislator over time in the common space and is largely a “nuisance” parameter. In ourapplication, the estimates for ✓m instead represents the locations of the European politicalgroups on the common left-right scale, a substantively important set of estimates that cannototherwise be obtained from the EES.

4

Page 5: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Another Validation: Party System Polarization

We document additional analysis to validate the substantive value of our rescaling approachby aggregating information about voter and party dispersion. The party system literaturehas a long tradition of examining the polarization of party systems (e.g. Taylor and Her-man, 1971; Gross and Sigelman, 1984; Alvarez and Nagler, 2004; Sartori, 2005; Dalton, 2008;Rehm and Reilly, 2010). We choose to calculate one such measure o↵ered in the literatureby Alvarez and Nagler (2004). This particular measure was developed to precisely take intoaccount the scale perception issues discussed earlier. For Alvarez and Nagler, the ideolog-ical di↵erences between parties become comparable across countries in a measure of “thedispersion of parties in the issue space relative to the dispersion of voters in the same issuespace” (Alvarez and Nagler, 2004, p.48). As a result, party system compactness (or, itsinverse, polarization) is a function of three separate components. The first is the ideologicaldispersion of voters, the second is the ideological distance of the parties from a ideologicalcenter of gravity, and the third are the vote shares of the parties to take into account therelative size of the parties in the system. This weighted measure of compactness of countryk is calculated as follows (Alvarez and Nagler, 2004, p.50):

COMPACTNESSk =�kPN

j=1 Vj|(Pjk � Pk)|,

where �k is the standard deviation of voter self-placements on left-right, Vj is the j-th party’sshare of the vote in the 2009 European elections, Pjk is the placement of the j-th party onleft-right, and Pk is the weighed mean of parties on left-right, where each party is weighted byits vote share. Alvarez and Nagler (2004, p.49) then argue that a large value of compactness“indicates that voters place themselves across a wide range of the issue space but the partiesare clustered in a very narrow range of the issue space”, suggesting a compact ideologicalspace. By incorporating both voter placements and party positions, this measure shouldbe robust to scale perception issues. We examine this by calculating two versions. In thefirst version, we follow the original approach and input the original survey self-placementsand the mean perceptions of the parties on left-right. In the second version, we use rescaledvoter placements and rescaled party positions to calculate the measure. We use the EEScontextual dataset for the vote shares of the parties (EES, 2011; Czesnik et al., 2010). Thetotal vote share covered in each country ranges between 64.04% in France and 99.99% inAustria and Luxembourg. The average total vote share of the parties is 88.64%. When usingthe rescaled data, we exclude respondents with negative A-M weights.

Figure A-3 presents a scatterplot of party system compactness using the unscaled and therescaled data. Because the measure is the ratio of voter dispersion to party dispersion, themeasures are comparable and the line on the plot indicates if the two measures are identical.The two sets of measures correlate at 0.73, suggesting a high robustness of this measure.Yet, the plot shows some important di↵erences. For example, while the unscaled datasuggest that Poland is the most compact party system relative to voters, this changes whenusing the rescaled data where Poland has the third most compact system after Romaniaand Slovakia. At the other end of the scale, the unscaled measure suggests that CzechRepublic, Cyprus, and Hungary are the most polarized, whereas the rescaled data suggests

5

Page 6: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

that Austria, Cyprus, and France are. This implies that while Alvarez and Nagler’s partysystem compactness measure appears indeed robust in the majority of cases, rescaling thedata does make a small yet potentially substantively significant di↵erence in how partysystems are ranked on the compactness dimension.

6

Page 7: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Figure A-3: Party System Compactness Measures

●●

1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

Compactness Meaureusing Raw Data

Com

pact

ness

Mea

sure

usi

ng R

esca

led

Dat

a

Austria

BulgariaCyprus

Czech Republic

EstoniaFinland

France

Germany

Greece

Hungary

Ireland

Italy

Latvia

Lithuania

Luxembourg

Poland

Portugal

Romania

Slovakia

Slovenia

The Netherlands

United Kingdom

PolarizedParty System

CompactParty System

Pola

rized

Party

Sys

tem

Com

pact

Party

Sys

tem

7

Page 8: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Estimation Details: Spatial Model of Valence in the UK

Here we report additional results from the re-scaling of British left-right voter and partyplacements in the 2009 EES. Substantively, our valence estimates make sense in the contextof the spatial mapping of actors that we produce in Figure 1. To illustrate this point moreclearly, Figure A-4 replicates the left panel of Figure 1 along a cumulative distributionfunction of the population. Note that approximately 30% of the UK electorate lies to theleft of Labour, the most left-leaning party in the UK. Under perfect one-dimensional spatialvoting with no valence or stochastic utility, Labour should win all the votes of that part ofthe electorate. Labour should also win over voters lying between the Labour and LiberalDemocrat cutline as well — this only strengthens our argument that Labour has a valencedisadvantage relative to other parties. However, Labour only won 15.7% of the vote in the2009 European election, which suggests that they are at a valence disadvantage relative toother UK parties, consistent with our valence estimates in Table 2.

A similar mode of reasoning also helps to explain our valence estimate for the UK Con-servatives. Under the same assumption of perfect spatial voting, the Conservative party ispredicted to win the support of all voters lying between the Conservative/UKIP cutline andthe Conservative/Liberal Democrat cutline. While our cumulative distribution plot suggeststhat this block of voters comprises about 20% of the UK electorate, the Conservatives won27.7% of the total vote share. This strong performance above the expectations of perfectspatial voting is reflected in the high valence estimate we observe for the UK Conservativeparty. Again, this finding is also consistent with what theories of voting behavior wouldpredict for the success of opposition parties in European elections.

In light of our estimates, one interesting counterfactual to consider is the impact thata Liberal-Democrat move to the left might have on voters to the left of the Labour party,assuming the other three major parties stayed in the same spatial location. The counterfac-tual is clearly unrealistic because shifts in party location by any major party are likely tocause other party shifts (Fowler and Laver, 2008). Rather, our larger point is that one cansimulate vote probabilities across a wide range of di↵erent assumptions about how partiesbehave under electoral competition. The counterfactual is substantively intriguing in thesense that with two parties with strong valence on their right, a move to the right by theLiberal Democrats is unlikely to win many more voters on the right. Would a move to theleft instead win over many Labour voters from a Labour party with weak valence? Ourmodel suggests that this is unlikely.

Figure A-5 simulates the e↵ect of a leftward shift in position by the Liberal Democrats onthe probability of a vote for Labour. We simulate this probability for voters with ideal pointsat Labour’s current position, and to the left of Labour at x = �1 and x = �2, and allow theLiberal Democrat location to vary between their current location and the current locationof Labour. Our simulation shows little e↵ect on the probability of a Labour vote for voterslocated at Labour’s position and x = �1, and an 8% decrease in the probability of a vote forLabour for a voter at x = �2. While this may seem like a large shift, Figure A-4 shows thatonly a tiny fraction of the UK electorate lies in the neighborhood of x = -2. The graphicalso presents an intriguing puzzle — if only 21% of voters at Labour’s position are voting forLabour regardless of where the Liberal Democrats place themselves, who are the other 79%

8

Page 9: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Figure A-4: Party Locations along Cumulative Distribution of Voters in United

Kingdom, 2009 European Elections.

−2 −1 0 1 2

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Stimuli and Population CDF

Location

Cum

ulat

ive D

ensi

ty

● ● ● ● ●● ● ●● ●● ●●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●● ●●●

●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●●●

●●●●●●

●●●●● ●● ● ● ● ●● ●● ●● ● ●● ●● ●

Labour

Conservatives

LibDem

Scot.NatsPlaid.Cymru

UK.Indep

Brit.Nats

Green

Note: More than 30% of all voters are to the left of the Labour party, which is the most left-leaning party in

the UK. Under perfect spatial voting with no valence or stochastic utility, Labour should win all the votes

of that part of the electorate. However, Labour only won 15.7% of the vote in the 2009 European election,

which suggests that they are at a valence disadvantage relative to other UK parties, consistent with our

valence estimates on Table 2.

voting for? A similar fraction are voting for the Liberal Democrats, but importantly, manyare voting for the other two major parties, especially the Conservatives. Our results suggestthat significant numbers of voters with ideal points around the Labour party’s position arevoting Conservative because at that position, high levels of Conservative party valence, i.e.issues orthogonal to left-right, trump spatial considerations. Only when voters are located farfrom the Conservatives (i.e. the voter at x = -2) does the spatial component of utility beginto trump Conservative valence. Voters are more likely to punish the government by refusingto vote along spatial considerations and instead defect to a opposition party. According tothis theory the valence term consists of factors such as government popularity and economicfactors that are not simply a consequence of traditional ideological position of voters andthe perceived position of parties on the left-right dimension.

9

Page 10: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Figure A-5: The Impact of a Liberal-Democratic shift in the United Kingdom on

the probability to vote Labour, 2009 European Elections.

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

0.50

Liberal−Democrat location

Prob

abilit

y of

Lab

our V

ote

Labour LibDem

Voter at Labour position

Voter at x = −1 (left of Labour)

Voter at x = −2 (far left of Labour)

Note: X-axis bounds are the current Labour and Liberal Democrat position. We simulate the probability of

a vote for Labour for three individuals — one at the current Labour position (x = -0.363), and two voters to

the left of Labour (at x = -1 and x = -2), as the Liberal Democrats move from the current Liberal Democrat

position to the current Labour position.

10

Page 11: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Problems of Extending our Approachto the European Integration Dimension

In addition to the left-right dimension, the EES ask respondents to place themselvesand parties on a European integration dimension. Theoretically, this creates an opportunityof extending our rescaling approach to this dimension. However, parties to a large degreealign with European party groups on a left-right dimension (McElroy and Benoit, 2010).Therefore, the party group membership would not serve as good bridging observations for acommon European space. Our intuition on this appears to be correct — in replicating thisprocedure with the European integration question, there is virtually no di↵erence in locationsfor every European Party group in our data except the EFD and the EUL-NGL, which were tothe extremes on the Euroskeptic and pro-European ends of the scale. Furthermore, estimatesare largely bimodal, with a large group of EFD members on the Euroskeptic mode and allother parties clustered in a larger pro-European mode. Therefore, rather than using partygroup membership, we tested an alternative set of bridging observations: roll call votes ofMEPs on constitutional issues (e.g. treaty reform). The problems here are the definitionof a national party position (majority, two-thirds, unanimity?) and missing observations (ifMEPs abstain on particular votes). In the end, using roll call votes, which were for the mostpart heavily lopsided on EU constitutional issues, we were not able to identify more thantwo “blocs” of a pro- and an anti-European camp of parties. In short, while the techniqueappears to identify which parties lie at which extremes of the European integration scale,the metric information that can be recovered through joint scaling appears questionable.

11

Page 12: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Excluded Observations: Government Defection in the 2009 EuropeanParliament Election

Here we describe which observations were removed from the dataset prior to analysis. First,we excluded all observations with estimated negative AM weights. Second, we excluded alldata from France because there are no Benoit-Laver scores on the left-right dimensions avail-able. Third, as explained in the paper we did not include data in our rescaling procedurefrom Sweden, Belgium, Denmark and Spain due to unresolved data cleaning issues in theEES data. Forth, we excluded all observations from Malta, as its two party system makes thefirst rescaling step impossible (the two country-specific parameters for Malta are uniquelyidentified). In sum, these criteria leave us with observations from 21 di↵erent countries.Consistent with Hobolt et al. (2009) we consider a party as a governmental party even if itleft the government just before the election (e.g., the Hungarian SzDSz left the governmentin April 2009) while we have to exclude governmental parties if they are not included inESS (e.g., ADK of Cyprus). See table A-1 below for more details. Finally, while trying tomaximize the number of countries in our model, our results are robust to the exclusion ofobservations from countries such as Latvia, Luxembourg, and Ireland because of concurrent(national or local) elections. It could be argued, that concurrent elections provide incen-tives for voters that are not comparable with the situation in countries without concurrentelections.

12

Page 13: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

References

Alvarez, R. and J. Nagler (2004). Party System Compactness: Measurement and Conse-quences. Political Analysis 12 (1), 46–62.

Czesnik, M., M. Kotnarowski, and R. Markowski (2010). EES 2009 Contextual Dataset

Codebook: Advance Release Notes 16/5/2010. www.piredeu.eu.

Dalton, R. (2008). The Quantity and the Quality of Party Systems. Comparative Political

Studies 41 (7), 899.

Doring, H. and P. Manow (2010). Parliament and government composition database (Parl-

Gov): An infrastructure for empirical information on parties, elections and governments

(Version 10/02). http://parlgov.org.

EES (2011). European Parliament Election Study, Voter Data, Advance Release (23 June2011). www.piredeu.eu.

Efron, B. and R. Tibshirani (1994). An Introduction to the Bootstrap. London: Chapmanand Hall.

Fowler, J. and M. Laver (2008). A Tournament of Party Decision Rules. Journal of ConflictResolution 52 (1), 68–92.

Groseclose, T., S. Levitt, and J. Snyder (1999). Comparing Interest Group Scores acrossTime and Chambers: Adjusted ADA Scores for the US Congress. American Political

Science Review 93 (1), 33–50.

Gross, D. and L. Sigelman (1984). Comparing Party Systems: A Multidimensional Approach.Comparative Politics 16 (4), 463–479.

Hobolt, S. B., J.-J. Spoon, and J. Tilley (2009). A Vote Against Europe? ExplainingDefection at the 1999 and 2004 European Parliament Elections. British Journal of Political

Science 39 (1), 93–115.

Martin, A. D. and K. Quinn (2002). Dynamic Ideal Point Estimation via Markov ChainMonte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953-1999. Political Analysis 10, 134–153.

McElroy, G. and K. Benoit (2010). Party Policy and Group A�liation in the EuropeanParliament. British Journal of Political Science 40 (02), 377–398.

Rehm, P. and T. Reilly (2010). United We Stand: Constituency Homogeneity and Compar-ative Party Polarization. Electoral Studies 29 (1), 40–53.

Sartori, G. (2005). Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis. European Con-sortium for Politcal Research.

Taylor, M. and V. Herman (1971). Party Systems and Government Stability. American

Political Science Review 65 (1), 28–37.

13

Page 14: Appendix James Lo, Sven-Oliver Proksch, and Thomas ...... · “A Common Left-Right Scale for Voters and Parties in Europe.” ... Problems of Extending our Approach to the European

Table A-1: Descriptive Statistics: Government Defection in the 2009 European

Parliament Election

Country N Defectors % Parties in Government 2009

Austria 474 24.1 SPO, OVPBelgium 385 25.7 CDV, PVV, PSC, MR, PSBulgaria 130 30.8 DPS, NDSVCyprus 391 12.5 AKEL, DIKO, ADK*Czech Republic 493 10.3 CSSD, ODS, SZDenmark 317 32.8 KF, VEstonia 349 45.8 IRL, ERe, SDE-MFinland 459 17.0 VIHR, KESK, RKP-SFP, KOKFrance 248 13.7 UMPGermany 516 21.1 CDU/CSU, SPDGreece 336 22.3 NDHungary 252 17.5 MSZP, SzDSz**Ireland 322 51.6 FF, Greens, PDItaly 258 8.1 PDL, LNLatvia 255 53.3 TB/LNNK, TP, ZZS, LPP/LCLithuania 207 9.7 LiCS, LRLS, TS-LKDLuxembourg 353 25.8 CSV, LSAPMalta 313 10.2 PNThe Netherlands 423 26.0 CDA, CU, PvdAPoland 346 11.0 PSL, POPortugal 275 19.6 PSRomania 442 13.6 PS-D, PD-LSlovakia 406 8.1 SMER, SNS, HZDSSlovenia 431 24.1 ZL-SD, LDS, ZARES, DeSUSSpain 305 6.2 PSOESweden 458 38.4 KD, M, FP, CPUnited Kingdom 311 28.6 Labour

Source: 2009 European Election Study and ParlGov database (Doring and Manow, 2010).All parties which held cabinet seats in June 2009 were treated as government parties. Dueto data availability issues regarding the independent variables, only 21 countries of the27 member states could be considered in the final multivariate analysis (for details, seedescription in the article and the appendix above).* ADIK (CY) were not included in the EES survey.** The Hungarian government was reshu✏ed in April 2009, as the SzDSz left the coalition,leaving the MSZP to form a minority government.

14


Recommended