+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of...

Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of...

Date post: 10-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: patrick-armshaw
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 23

Transcript
  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    1/23

    Patrick ArmshawWar and the Nation-State

    Final Paper

    Coal, Gold, and Nationalism: An Evaluation of Keynes' The

    Economic Consequences of the Peace

    The hand that signed the treaty bred a fever,And famine grew, and locusts came;

    Great is the hand that holds dominion over

    Man by a scribbled name.

    -Dylan Thomas1

    The early part of the Twentieth Century must surely rank as one of the more exciting, and

    dangerous, eras in the history of the West. From an expansionist (and not coincidentally imperialist)

    sense of optimism in the seeming ability of Freedom, Equality, Property, and Bentham to procure,

    from all corners of the earth, the requirements and accouterments of daily life, Europe tilted wildly

    towards a massive, and economically devastating war, leaving tens of millions dead, several Empires

    defunct, and a great power in the throes of revolution and civil war. In many ways, it was the end of an

    era, perhaps of an entire world. Keynes' description of this world, although heavily reliant on the

    experience of the middle- and upper classes, expresses this optimism (not to say complacency)

    admirably:

    The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea in bed, the various

    products of the whole earth, in such quantity as he might see fit, and reasonably expect their early delivery

    upon his doorstep; he he could at the same moment and by the same means adventure his wealth in the

    natural resources and new enterprises of any quarter of the world, and share, without exertion or even

    1 The Hand that Signed the Paper from the anthology Twenty-Five Poems (1936)

    1

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    2/23

    trouble, in their prospective fruits and advantages.

    This ideal situation reflects an ease of movement of goods and capital to be admired, even in our own

    situation of advancing globalization. It was in fact hoped that the advance of trade would help to quiet

    the militaristic urge, or at least push the arena of conflict out of Europe permanently. The last major

    European conflict had been the Franco-Prussian War in 1871, a period whose aftermath saw the

    incredible advance of industrialism throughout western Europe, the United States, and Japan. Such

    conflicts as did occur, such as the Fashoda Incident or the Mahdi Rebellion, were by and large colonial

    affairs: sited on colonial (or prospective colonial) territory, involving the defense of 'interests' rather

    than the nation, and to be fought mainly by colonial manpower. Even more difficult disputes between

    the colonial powers, such as the Moroccan Crises, had been no match for the combined sagacity of the

    Entente powers. War, in the old dangerous sense, could almost be assumed away in such a situation,

    for war, along with the militarism, nationalism, and racism which legitimized it, seemed antithetical to

    the business of business - little more than the amusements of [the inhabitant of London's] daily

    newspaper.2

    Yet war did come, in many ways spurred by the very imperialistic capitalism that had seemed

    to augur peace. And this war was to have a profound effect on its participants, revealing paradoxes in

    the ideologies of the States that fought it, necessitating drastic changes in the ways that States

    interacted with their economies, and ultimately unraveling the dense web of international trade that had

    been painstakingly built up over the preceding forty years. But it was the actions and choices of these

    States in the inter-war period that were to have the profoundest effects on the course of history. For

    while an economic downturn was almost certain in the post-war era, given the massive losses of human

    life, the destruction of physical capital by occupying armies, and the interruption of normal trade

    networks, it was by no means certain that the downturn would be as prolonged, and as destructive to

    2 Keynes, pp. 41 - 42

    2

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    3/23

    civil society, as the Great Depression turned out to have been. Keynes in particular was quite clear on

    this in his prescient work published in 1919 The Economic Consequences of the Peace. Keynes'

    critique of the Treaty of Versailles is founded on several basic elements, aside from simple questions of

    justice for the defeated. His focus can be divided up into three main points: the effects of the

    disruption of the coal industry on production, the maldistribution of gold in the global market (and

    particularly the lack of sufficient gold holdings by the German state to pay off the demanded

    reparations), and the political-economic effects of privation on the conquered German peoples. It will

    be the purpose of this paper to examine the actual history of the inter-war period, and particularly the

    effects of the Treaty on the global economy, in order to examine the linkages between the end of

    imperial capitalism, the rise of political instability (resulting in the challenges of Fascism and

    Communism), and the ultimate entrenchment of command-influenced economies in western Europe. I

    argue that Keynes' choice of variables (energy supplies, money supplies, and the political consequences

    of economic decisions) are ideal for these purposes, and that there is an interesting story to tell,

    regarding the collapse of the 'free-trade' system and the rise of domestic protectionism and autarky

    among the industrialized nations.

    Coal

    We begin by noting the fundamental importance of coal to the European economy. All

    economies are driven by some source of power, in the physical sense. The Roman economy was

    dependent upon slave labor, and the ceaseless demand for more slaves (along with the lack of a racial

    caste-system) lead eventually to imperial overstretch, stagnation, and downfall. The middle ages saw

    the institution of serfdom, providing for a class of labor whose movements could be circumscribed. By

    the 1800s, however, this dependence on human labor was being transformed into a reliance on

    machinery capital itself came alive, providing a massive expansion in the productive capabilities of

    3

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    4/23

    those nations and capitalists able to afford it. And coal was the preferred food of this mechanical

    Golem. In fact, coal was not simply a good, to be bought and sold, but was the underpinning of the

    national economy, whose movements in price affected the cost of manufacturing, and the brute fact

    that made trans-global trade (and the navy that protected it) possible. The introduction of coal-burning

    ships allowed maritime powers vastly to increase their effectiveness in combat, expand their reach, and

    shorten the length of time (as well as reduce the cost) of moving goods from one corner of the earth to

    another. This last point is of considerable importance for the internationalization of trade in the late

    Victorian era. While the early and mid 1900s saw the beginning of the switch from coal to petroleum

    as a primary energy source, even as late as World War II coal was still of no small importance. In

    1914 coal-driven ships accounted for 44 million tons, or around 97% of the total world tonnage, and by

    1937 coal still maintained a sizable 49% share, or 32 million tons.3

    During the war, the overarching importance of coal became apparent as the belligerents rushed

    to ensure a steady stream of fossil fuels to the military machine. The coal industry however, especially

    in the United Kingdom, seemed unable to meet the challenges. The UK, France, Germany, Austria,

    and Russia all faced decreases in coal production from 1913 to 1917, some of them quite serious.

    France's production dropped form around 41 million tons to 29 million, Austria from 60 million to 19

    million, and the Russian Empire from 36 million to just 13 million.4 The shortage itself was due to two

    major factors: disruptions in the labor market due to popular mobilization, and a disruption in the

    railroad systems that lead to bottlenecks in distribution. The disruption in labor was a direct result of

    the war: many nations drafted coal miners directly into the army at the outset of the war, 5 a policy that

    was walked back as the disruption in the coal industry became clear. Furthermore, a not insignificant

    portion of miners volunteered for duty, or left to gain higher wages in other industries (notably the

    3 Voskuil (1942), p. 2524 Notz (1918), p. 5685 As much as a third of Germany's coal miners were tapped for military service. (Notz, 1918)

    4

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    5/23

    munitions industry), leaving behind mining positions that were filled by less experienced hands,

    reducing productivity. The transportation situation was no better, and was to have profound effects on

    coal workers' ability to profit from their indispensability. While the shortage of coal and it's

    importance to the war effort did lead to higher wages, as governments, desperate to maintain

    production, inserted themselves into labor disputes (sometimes even on the side of labor), workers

    incomes were reduced through lost hours, as the rail- and waterways were taxed beyond their abilities

    by the demands of total war. This, combined with harsher discipline and relaxed safety standards led

    to considerable labor trouble, and made the job of keeping skilled workers in the mines more difficult.

    [T]here has been much unrest and numerous strikes have occurred among the coal miners of Great Britain,

    the United States, and Germany. The main causes for these labor troubles have been shutdowns at the

    mines on account of shortage of cars, thus decreasing the number of work days, and a heavy increase in

    mine fatalities, due partly to inexperienced labor and partly to less rigid enforcement of mine safety

    regulations in order to speed production.6

    Eventually, the situation became so desperate that the government was forced to play an

    increasingly strong hand in regulating the coal industry: the British government, owing to labor unrest

    in South Wales, seized control of the mines there on November 19th, 1916, and extended their control

    over the entire industry by February 22nd, 1917. Furthermore, high taxes were set on super-profits,

    prices set by government announcement, and elaborate zoning plans implemented to prevent

    transportation bottlenecks, by decreeing that coal produced locally was to be consumed locally. We

    see a major expansion of the public sphere to encompass what had previously been areas firmly

    considered private. We also see a powerful argument for the centralization of such crucial industries.

    One predictor of the level of disruption in a state's coal trade is the level of fragmentation before the

    war. Germany's highly centralized industry suffered from less disruption than the more fragmentary

    industry in the United Kingdom, and this lesson was not lost on the allies. The reliance on cheap

    6 Notz, p. 571

    5

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    6/23

    human labor also became problematic, and the aftermath of the war saw the extension of capital-

    intensive machinery into the industry.7 These experiences were to have a profound effect on

    economics, and lead directly to a popular consensus that some areas of the economy could not be

    efficiently directed by private interests. While the coal industry was cut loose from government control

    in March of 1921, the seeds of government dirigisme had been sown. That nationalization seemed

    possible, or even predictable, following the war was a direct result of the chaos unleashed when

    mobilization strained the old system to the breaking point.8

    To this wear and tear of war we must add the deliberate destruction of the enemy's coal-

    production as a strategic aim. Germany's route into France through Belgium put the vast majority of

    France's coal fields in the way of the invaders. The areas occupied by German forces produced an

    astounding 68% of French coal9 During the German retreat, much of this productive capacity was

    sabotaged, a Parthian shot with important consequences, as it further inflamed French feelings of

    victimization by Germany, and one major element in the resulting Treaty of Versailles involved

    Germany's responsibility to furnish France with sufficient coal to maintain its industry. All of these

    factors lead to a major increase in the market price of coal, producing large profits for the industry,

    combined with a shrinking supply of actual coal. And with any post-war peace dependent on a

    resurrection of industry, the chaos in the coal markets seemed to augur badly. Keynes' argument here

    is quite simple: (a) Germany, as the continents largest economy and greatest producer, is inextricably

    linked into the economies of its neighbors; (b) the repair of the Allied economies was dependent on the

    resumption of German's place in this economic system; (c) the Treaty, by preventing Germany from

    recuperating, also prevents the Allies from doing so. Specifically, the Treaty obliged Germany to ship

    7 Dintenfass, 1988

    8 As far as public sentiment can be gauged by the press, by parliamentary debates, and by reports of specialcommissions which have investigated the problems involved, it is a noteworthy fact that the view is apparently rapidlygaining ground the world over that, if not complete nationalization, at least a much greater degree of state regulationof the coal industry and trade than existed before the war is desirable and in the public interest. (Notz, 574)9 Notz, 1918

    6

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    7/23

    20 million tons of coal to France in reparation for the destruction of the Nord and Pas-de-Calais mines

    (half of France's total output), and another 25 or so million to France, Italy, Belgium, and Luxembourg.

    This, despite the impending German loss of the Upper Silesia deposits (providing about 23% of

    German production) to the new-born Polish state,

    10

    and the French occupation of the Ruhr Valley.

    Keynes argued that this was economic suicide due to Germany's centrality in the European economy:

    Round Germany as a central support the rest of the European economic system grouped itself, and on the

    prosperity and enterprise of Germany the prosperity of the rest of the Continent mainly depended. The

    increasing pace of Germany gave her neighbors an outlet for their products, in exchange for which the

    enterprise of the German merchant supplied for them their chief requirements at a low price. (Keynes , 65)

    And the major factor preventing a resumption of this system, in Keynes' view, would be the shortage of

    coal in Germany.

    In the event, however, the problems affecting the European economy did not spring from a coal

    shortage in the after-war years, but from relative overproduction. The decrease of manufacturing

    production in Europe, greater economies in the use of coal, the competition of lignite, oil, and

    electricity produced by water-power were all factors which contributed to the result that more coal was

    being produced than could be used (Macrosty, 1928). This fact, while seeming to contradict Keynes'

    assumptions, in fact reinforces them. Even if a Factory has closed due to higher energy prices, it is by

    no means certain that a drop in the same would result in the reopening of that business. The capital

    invested, once freed from its moorings, is under no obligation to be re-invested once conditions

    improve unless there is effective demand for it as indeed we see with the Great Depression that was

    to follow. The lack of this aggregate demand represents a capital market failure, leading to a less-than-

    optimum supply of capital being invested that is, some portion of capital freed through closing

    factories is instead held in liquidity, or spent on luxuries.11 The result for the British coal industry is

    10 The Treaty put Upper Silesia under an Allied mandate, with a final settlement to be determined by plebiscite. Notsurprisingly, it voted to join Poland.

    11 For a full treatment of the Theory of Effective Demand, see Keynes (1936), The General Theory of Employment,

    7

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    8/23

    indicative of the type of problems faced by other coal-producing nations. Oversupply led to low

    profits, and low wages, and resulted in major labor disruptions, including the 1926 General Strike,

    called in order to support the collier unions in their fight with the coal industry.12 Keynes' prediction

    was about the level of production that could be maintained given the constraints on the coal supply, not

    on the price of coal per se and it was precisely this level of production whose collapse reduced the

    demand for coal, leading to the drop in price.

    The war brought out many contradictions in the continental economic system. In particular, the

    seemingly impervious Liberal theory of laissez-faire was deeply undermined. Under the most urgent

    test that an industry can face, mobilizing for a war to the point of exhaustion, where every efficiency is

    needed, that industry, and many others, fell short. Increased demand, high prices and higher profits

    were not enough to induce owners to increase wages sufficiently to keep labor happy, fragmentation of

    the industry presented major problems, as firms had to alter their web of business partners to supply

    coal to the war effort, and inhibited the diffusion of new capital-intensive machinery among mines.

    The resulting spike in prices and disruption in the supply chain seemed to point conclusively to the

    necessity of government intervention. In this new era of total war, anything less was to take

    inappropriate chances with the fate of the nation itself. Eventually, the seriousness of the tensions

    resulting from the supply of coal among nations led to the creation after the second world war, in

    which control of coal supplies was an active part of Hitler's strategy for continental dominance

    (Voskuil, 1942), of the European Coal and Steel Community.

    Gold

    The achievement of a nearly universal international Gold Standard must count as one of the

    major achievements of the pre-war period. With the United States' conversion to Gold by 1900, all the

    Interest, and Money.12 See Macrosty, 1928

    8

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    9/23

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    10/23

    United States, whose economy was well suited to picking up the slack. Loans from the United States

    to the United Kingdom during the war came to 842,000,000, while those to France, Italy, Belgium

    and Russia amounted to 550 million, 325 million, 80 million, and 38 million respectively. In

    total, the United States lent out 1.90 billion: a vast sum indeed. These figures do not reflect the full

    measure of inter-Allied indebtedness. The United Kingdom itself made many loans to other Allied

    nations, in many cases acting as a clearing house for loans from the US. The United Kingdom had lent

    over the course of the war almost as much as the Americans: 1.74 billion. France acted in a similar,

    though far reduced capacity, loaning out 335 million.13

    Making the situation far worse was the destruction of physical capital that the war itself

    entailed. Invading armies were no more careful during the war to safeguard private property than

    today, and indeed the destruction of captured physical capital, either through malice or as an attempt to

    cannibalize matriale for the war effort. Furthermore, the requirements of the war machine dominated

    those of the civilian economy: necessary repairs were deferred, upkeep dropped, and shortages of basic

    materials meant that every year the war continued was another year of the degradation of the capital

    stock. Finally, we cannot ignore a certain speculation in the actions of these nations. During the war,

    it was certainly considered that the victors would be able to force the conquered to repay these debts in

    the form of reparations. And for precedent, the belligerents did not have to look far back in history.

    The peace treaty that ended the Franco-Prussian war in 1871 included a reparations clause forcing

    France to pay billions of dollars in gold to the new German Empire. This influx of capital was then

    used in the impressive industrial buildup that occurred in Germany from the 1870s to the 1890s.

    Surely such powerful states as had developed since then, capable of engaging in such devastating

    warfare for years on end would be able to sustain a flow of reparations sufficient to absorb this web of

    indebtedness. We may identify this as an example of 'moral failure' the economic term for the

    13 Keynes (1919), p. 276

    10

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    11/23

    practice of gambling with other people's money. If the costs of the war could be externalized

    successfully to the losing parties, then the clear economic crisis waiting in the wings might yet be

    avoided.

    This reliance on winning the war in planning the budget is no where clearer than in France.

    Here not only did reliance on foreign loans subsidize a major trade deficit, the French government's

    reluctance to raise taxes sufficiently to fund the war effort made winning, and the reparations it

    entailed, of the utmost importance. The progressive nature of the disease can be seen in the estimated

    trade imbalances in France recorded by Keynes. France's excess of imports over exports was 5 million

    pounds in 1913. By 1918 it had climbed to nearly 53 million pounds, and by 1919 the imbalance had

    reached almost 69 million pounds for July alone.14 Such a massive trade imbalance clearly made

    repayment of US loans through gold earned from trade a lost cause. Instead, the capital for repayment

    would have to come from the Axis powers, and since the utter collapse and dismemberment of the

    Austrian and Ottoman Empires meant that they could not be expected to pay, this meant the money

    would have to come from Germany. This explains in great part the absolute vehemence of French

    diplomats on the subject of reparations from Germany, and the alliance between France and the United

    Kingdom to ensure as Carthaginian peace as could be accomplished.

    The dislocations of wartime, and the outflow of gold to the United States had deep implications

    for the Gold Standard. By the midpoint of the war, most of the belligerents had abandoned gold in

    favor of fiat currency. With gold leaving the country, states could either revalue their currencies, see

    the value of the currency eaten away through wholesale inflation, or sever the link between paper and

    specie, relying on price controls and heavy regulation to maintain the currency's buying power. The

    damage done to currency prices was considerable, and every state involved looked forward to the day

    when they would be able to reinstitute the Gold Standard. 15 This reinstitution, however, was not

    14 Keynes (1919), p. 25415 Keynes estimated (according to Macrosty) that the value of the pound had fallen by 8 to 10%, while Italy's currency had

    11

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    12/23

    primarily an economic decision. The case of the United Kingdom is instructive in this regard. Under

    Prime Minister Stanley Baldwin, the government went forward with a plan, implemented by

    Chancellor of the Exchequer Winston Churchill, to return Britain to the Gold Standard. However, the

    chosen price of the pound was at $4.86, a price set not according to market fundamentals, but for more

    political reasons. Firstly, $4.86 was the price of the pound at the beginning of the war, and it was felt

    to be important that Britain regain its former financial leadership as quickly as possible. Secondly, this

    policy was of considerable importance to the Bank of England, whose position as the leading clearing

    house for international capital would have been threatened by a fall in the pound.

    For Keynes, this seeming act of madness was almost designed to make the post-war recovery as

    painful as humanly possible. In his tract, entitled The Economic Consequences of Mr. Churchill he

    estimated that the proper rate of exchange should have been around $4.48 in other words, in order to

    raise the pound to its previous level, the United Kingdom would have to suffer through an economic

    retrenchment, including major unemployment, that could conceivably lead to a world-wide depression.

    Just as the United Kingdom was looking to repair its tattered economy, Churchill's commission would

    make British exports more expensive, and imports cheaper, leaving the UK at a considerable

    disadvantage in terms of international trade. We can perhaps take comfort in the likely fact that the

    Bank of England predicted that the strong pound would allow the UK to resume its place as financial

    world leader, but the cost to the vast majority of the English people make such comfort decidedly

    cold.16 Finally, a strong pound would considerably ease Britain's debt load to the US, a consideration

    of no small importance. However, the effect on business was profound, as loans became considerably

    more expensive, and businesses became wary of adding to their debt, and the likelihood of deflation

    dropped by almost half (Keynes, 1918). France's peculiar budgetary difficulty was a constant source of instability forthe Franc, and the utter collapse of the German and Austrian Marks (as well as the Russian Ruble) is well known.

    16 The case for an inverse relationship between terms of trade and money wages is made by Taussig (1925). He alsodescribes the economic effects of so-called trade in 'invisibles' that is, export of capital and the returns on overseasinvestments.

    12

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    13/23

    raised the specter of repaying cheap money with dear.

    Keynes' argument that this situation was untenable was born out in spades in the next few years.

    By 1923 Germany had entered hyper-inflation, as the loss of its gold stocks to Allied repayment,

    combined with the extremely loose monetary policies put forward by the Reichsbank cut the value of

    the Mark inside the country to the bone. While Germany was able to improve its economy shortly after

    the war through increased exports, the lack of capital for expansion necessitated the bust by 1922.

    Without German exports to trade for gold to repay the Allies, the Allied governments were in no

    position to repay the United States. Making things worse, the debts incurred by the Allies from the US

    were interest-bearing: in other words, every day that went by added to the burdens of debt. Finally, the

    actions of the Federal Reserve during the war made any rational expectation of a new equilibrium

    being found impossible. The US, facing a massive influx of gold, decided to sterilize a significant

    portion of this booty, preventing it from passing into circulation in order to reduce inflation. This made

    normalization of the post-war currency market next to impossible. Under normal circumstances,17 as

    one country increases its gold stock, its currency rises compared to those countries whose stock is

    reduced. The result is inflation in the former, and deflation in the latter. Goods imported from the

    deflated economy are then considerably cheaper resulting (in the long run) in a reversal of the trade

    imbalance, and a movement of gold back towards the deflated country. With the US sterilizing the

    gold supply and with Britain maintaining an artificially high pound, however, this process was short-

    circuited. Britain's exports became more, not less, expensive, and the inflation in the US, while

    impressive, was not enough to allow for a major revaluation of the terms of trade. The result was a

    considerable advantage for the US in terms of trade, and increasing calls in Britain for the erection of

    tariff barriers to protect jobs from overseas competition.18 By 1926, the situation in Britain had gotten

    17 Here I am indebted to Friedman and Schwartz's arguments regarding monetary theory.18 One factor behind the push towards protectionism the high price of the pound played havoc with the British coal

    industry, one Britain's largest export goods. Viz. Shefftz (1967)

    13

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    14/23

    bad enough, and the political polarization advanced enough, that when the General Strike broke out in

    1926, government-allied newspapers (such as Winston Churchill's government-issued British Gazette)

    were willing to call the strike a mortal threat to the British state. Prime Minister Baldwin was quoted

    as stating Constitutional Government is being attacked. (.. .) The General Strike is a challenge to

    Parliament and is the road to anarchy and ruin.19

    With economic dislocation battering the European economies, it became increasingly clear that

    something would have to be done. The result was the institution of the Dawes Plan in 1924, and

    following its failure, the Young Plan in 1929. Under the Dawes Plan, the US would undertake to

    extend loans to Germany, in order to allow it to rebuild its industry, and switch more quickly to export-

    oriented redevelopment. The result would be greater exports from Germany, which could be used to

    pay down Germany's reparation debt. These reparations could then allow the Allied governments to

    make good on their own debt to the United States. The problem lay in the plan's very conception in

    essence, it allowed the US to pay out money now, to recoup its own bad debts. The money would flow

    from the US to the US. In the interim, however, Germany would be obliged to sink yet deeper into

    debt, the repayment of which was already taxing its to the utmost. At most, this arrangement would

    buy time for Germany to recover sufficiently to begin to reduce the ratio of debt to GDP. At worst, it

    would further wed the European economic system to the United States economy, allowing for the

    possibility of considerable financial contagion if a depression should hit the United States. And that

    depression was to hit with full fury in 1929. With the stock market in free-fall, and the passage of high

    tariffs under the Smoot-Hawley bill, capital available for export became increasingly rare, robbing

    Europe of both a major trading partner (whose imports were crucial to any hope for a system-wide

    recovery) and the primary source of the funds that allowed the financial house of cards to avoid

    collapse. Every state in the system was eventually to follow suit, driving up tariffs to increase

    19 British Gazette , May 6th, 1926, as quoted from Shefftz (1967)

    14

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    15/23

    domestic production, at the cost of trade and stability. Trade, it had seemed, had failed entirely, and for

    the duration of the Great Depression many states would move towards economic autarky of one form

    or another.20 It would not be until the Bretton Woods Agreement in 1944 that a new system of

    international trade would be put in place.

    Economic Nationalism

    In essence, every nation in the inter-war period was faced with an economic dilemma of the

    most serious consequence. The reconstruction of the national economies depended on two major

    strategies: the first was to increase exports to pay for debt payments and stimulate the economy, and

    the second was to close off the economy from international trade, protecting domestic jobs and cutting

    off the pathways of contagion that spread the economic disease throughout the system. The problem

    was the sheer number of major economies that would have to participate in this game of cooperation,

    and the ultimate reliance of that system on the United States as the buyer of last resort. The logic of the

    problem is easy enough to lay out, and we may do so with reference to the celebrated 'prisoners'

    dilemma.' Each country seeks to improve its economy through development of exports and the

    reduction of imports. But for every seller, there must be a buyer. And every import bought made the

    job of developing a favorable balance of trade more difficult. Each country in such a bind would

    therefore have been best rewarded by being the only player in the system to export more than they

    import. And in situations where only a minority of the global economy is reliant on exports, more

    wealthy nations are able to sustain the levels of imports to their economies without suffering undue

    dislocation in the domestic labor market that is, the incentive of the wealthier players is to engage in

    20 This rise of autarky, and concommitant collapse of faith in the Market, were major contributors to the rise of Fascismaccording to Karl Polanyi. In his 1944 work The Great Transformation he argues that Fascism results from an urge toretake control of the economy, in order to lessen the vicissitudes of the market. The use of labordirigisme in NaziGermany, Fascist Italy, and Soviet Russia (and to some degree in the Western powers as well) does much to supportsuch a contention.

    15

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    16/23

    as much trade as possible, since trade creates a surplus of wealth, making each nation theoretically

    better off. But in a generalized economic downturn, every player is faced with the same incentives.

    The result, according to theory, should be an equilibrium in which each player defects (shuts off

    imports through high tariffs), refusing to be the only player who has an unfavorable balance of trade.

    Viewed in this light, the question for the historian or political-scientist to answer is not why did global

    trade collapse' but rather 'why did it take so long?

    The logic of the game was apparent even in 1919. The Treaty of Versailles included several

    stipulations geared towards the dismantling of the German overseas empire, with Japan and the US

    gaining the Pacific islands, and Britain, France, and Belgium dividing up Germany's African

    possessions. To understand the importance of this, it is instructive to examine how colonies operated

    in the era of imperial capital. Colonies provided the 'mother country' with two major benefits: raw

    materials, which could be extracted and sold to feed the imperial industrial economy (located in the

    home territory), and a market for finished goods. Both of these would be necessary for the sustained

    growth of the economy, and it was the possession of these colonies that provided the economic

    breathing space for free trade between the empires. However, the expansionist nature of empire

    ensured that the colonial powers would come to fight each other, and with the Great War, the

    battlefront included Europe itself. With the Allied victory in 1919, the United Kingdom, Japan,

    France, Italy, and the other Allied belligerents would not pass up the chance not only to chasten an

    imperial (not to say hegemonic) rival, but to increase their own colonial holdings in the process. While

    these territorial possessions were discounted from the reparations in gold and in kind that Germany

    would have to pay, the loss of such territory, as well as the loss of East Prussia to Poland and of

    Alsace-Lorraine to France, reduced not only Germany's supply source of raw materials, but also its

    potential market for finished goods. The result was a decreased ability of Germany to make the

    reparation payments that were not met by its imperial denuding. Furthermore, the damage to railway

    16

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    17/23

    infrastructure among the belligerents was intense, and part of the Treaty called for the surrender by

    Germany of a considerable portion of its railway stock. We can see the importance of transportation to

    production in the above discussion of bottlenecks in the British coal industry.

    Germany, if it was to generate sufficient specie to pay the Allies, would have to sell its own

    goods to those European powers. But this avenue was also substantially blocked. In the first place, the

    popular mood in the Allied countries was positively murderous towards the Germans. After fighting

    an exhausting war of attrition for several years, and being subjected to major propaganda by their

    respective governments, and suffering the degradation of their own economies in the process, the

    voting populaces of the democracies were unwilling to sacrifice their own well being in the short run to

    ameliorate the bad condition of the Germans in the long run. The seriousness of the backlash against

    Germany is evident in the rapid volte-faceby British Prime Minister David Lloyd-George on the eve of

    the 1918 General Election. Faced by a popular wave of anger, and not a little financial and economic

    self-regard, the Liberal Party, in coalition with the Conservatives, was forced to swing considerably to

    the right to counter a challenge from the insurgent Labour Party, a cabinet member of which party

    declared I am for hanging the Kaiser!21 The result was an immediate cessation of all talk of

    Germany's inability to pay, and the institution of a party platform declaring the following:

    1. Trial of the Kaiser.

    2. Punishment of those responsible for atrocities.

    3. Fullest indemnities from Germany.

    4. Britain for the British, socially and industrially.

    5. Rehabilitation of those broken in the war.

    6. A happier country for all.

    The War Coalition had not originally intended to raise the hopes of the weary English by offering

    German punishment as a national panacea, but the exigencies of the moment made any other course

    politically suicidal. Similar emotions were at work in France and Italy, who regarded any settlement

    21 Keynes (1919), p. 170

    17

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    18/23

    that did not make them whole (and then some) as a betrayal of the aims for which the war was fought.

    In such an atmosphere, the idea of dropping barriers to trade with Germany in order to repair the

    German economy, even if the long term result would have been to make such reparations plausible,

    was simply impossible.

    But without a German economic recovery, there would be hardly any surplus for the Allies to

    garnish, threatening their own ability to repay US loans. Without the promise of substantial income

    from Germany, the Allied nations would have to raise the gold themselves, necessitating the retooling

    of their own economies for export. But the major customer for Western imports had been Germany

    itself before the war. One observer in 1920, F.W. Taussig, argued that a potential out would be to set

    up Russia as a potential trade partner with Germany, supplying raw materials in exchange for finished

    goods, or perhaps South America or the 'Orient'. (p. 34) While some economic cooperation did take

    place in the 1930s, the declared goals of the Bolshevik regime included the development of Russia's

    own industrial sector, making it an unlikely candidate for a replacement German colony. German trade

    with South America would have meant direct competition with British and US interests in the region,

    while the loss of Germany's Asian colonies had been effected precisely to block German access to

    these areas. That such ideas were put forward is perhaps indicative of the inability of the political

    class honestly to deal with the problems of debt and disequilibrium that first the war, and then the

    peace had brought.

    The United States, as we have already mentioned, was the linchpin of the economic system:

    loans floated by the US government were instituted to provide Germany with redevelopment capital,

    without which the entire system would come crashing down. But the US' interests were not in

    upholding the system alone. US financial interests, heavily represented on the Federal Reserve Board,

    and influential with the government, expected that the loans made to the Allies were to be repaid, and

    consequently, the issuance of further loans under the Dawes Plan became a dangerous necessity. The

    18

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    19/23

    US benefited mightily from the outcome of the war with the European economy in tatters, the US

    was in a perfect position to expand its own trade, increase its international presence, and maintain

    effective control of Europe for the duration of the reconstruction. Under the relatively free trade of the

    early 20s, the US economy expanded mightily, providing opportunities for advancement and expansion

    on a hitherto unseen level. But these astounding gains were built on a foundation of sand: they

    required a trade position that could not survive in equilibrium, where other economies borrow from the

    US to support domestic consumption, buy such goods from the US, and still be able to earn enough

    from foreign trade to make repayments. An excellent parable of this illusory, and ultimately dangerous

    expansion can be found in F. Scott Fitzgerald's The Great Gatsby, wherein the hero, Gatsby, attempts

    to infiltrate the upper echelons of society, but whose wealth cannot buy position. His life, like the

    economy, was a bubble and it burst. The financial system of extended loans paying each other off

    made contagion a certainty, and as Europe began raising tariffs, the over-investment in export goods

    and real estate crashed in the face of a severe cut in effective demand. While it would be unfair to say

    that the Crash of 1929 caused the Great Depression, it was at least a major symptom of the

    contradictions inherent in the inter-war order.

    Conclusion

    With the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930, and the abandonment of the Gold Standard during

    the 1930s, the last vestiges of the old system were swept away, and a system dominated by autarky and

    bilateral trade rose in its stead. Politically, the absurdity of the international loan situation and the

    harshness of the Treaty of Versailles encouraged the rise of extremist parties in the conquered powers,

    especially in Germany no mainstream party could have honestly offered to break the treaty, relying

    as they did on international loans, leaving this most popular of positions to be backed by the extreme

    Right and Left. The two largest parties in the 1932 German elections were the National-Socialist

    19

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    20/23

    Workers' Party and the Communist Party of Germany. The lessons of the 1st world war were not lost

    on the new fascist governments in Europe. Hitler's expansion into the east is argued for in Mein

    Kampf, as a means of securing, within Germany's own borders, the necessary raw materials to prevent

    a repetition of the deadly British blockade. Italy's corporatism was a direct response to an economic

    system that had seemingly gone haywire. And Stalin's insistence on industrial growth drew on the

    failure of the Tsarist economy to sustain a war effort of such magnitude.22

    While the Fascist countries were successful at creating less penetrated economies that were still

    capable of growth, their achievements were predicated on the arrest, and liquidation, of 'dangerous

    elements' in order to redistribute jobs and rewards to those who were considered part of the body

    politic. The demands of the economy for growth through political expansion did not ebb, but rather

    became more severe, as trade became less available as a means for securing raw materials and markets,

    leaving only conquest a zero-sum game in which there can be no compromise for long. Furthermore,

    the Western Democracies also experienced sharp swings away from economic liberalism, but in a more

    social-democratic manner, with the British Labour Party taking power in 1924 for 9 months, Franklin

    Delano Roosevelt elected President in 1932, and the rise of the Popular Front governments in France in

    the 1930s.

    The dislocation caused by the war, and the inability of the global economy to right itself

    through market mechanisms, signaled not just the end of an era, but the end of an entire economic,

    political, and social world. And much of the blame for this collapse can be laid on the system that

    birthed it a system wherein energy supplies were short, nations began to see international relations as

    a zero-sum game, and bad loans were the cement holding things together. Keynes' ability to see these

    problems in advance, during, in fact, the negotiations over the Treaty of Versailles, provided him the

    means to critique, and even to predict with considerable success the effects of that treaty. And those

    22 Following Polanyi, I include Stalin as a fascist leader, defining fascism primarily as a rejection of economic and socialliberalism, and not as an ideology of the Right or Left.

    20

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    21/23

    results were harsh: economic degradation, default, instability, revolution, and eventually, another Great

    War.

    21

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    22/23

    Bibliography

    Butchart, Ed, Employment and Non-Employment in Interwar Britain. Discussion Papers in

    Economic and Social HistoryNo. 16, University of Oxford, May 1997

    Dintenfass, Michael, Entrepreneurial Failure Reconsidered: The Case of the Interwar British Coal

    Industry. The Business History Review, Vol. 62, No. 1. (Spring, 1988), pp. 1-34.

    Egloff, Gustav, Modern Energy Supplies. The Scientific Monthly, Vol. 42, No. 4. (Apr., 1936), pp.

    291-300.

    Fremling, Gertrud M. Did the United States Transmit the Great Depression to the Rest of theWorld? The American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 5. (Dec., 1985), pp. 1181-1185.

    Hunter, James M. The Extent of the Legal Confines, the State-Idea, and the Zone of Function of

    France and Germany in the Saarland. International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 11, No. 3.

    (Sep., 1967), pp. 237-243.

    Knox, Crawford. Coal, Oil, and Water Power as Fuels. Economic Geography, Vol. 25, No. 2. (Apr.,

    1949), pp. 113-117.

    Macrosty, Henry W. Trade and the Gold Standard. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Vol. 91,

    No. 3. (1928), pp. 303-345.

    McCloskey, Donald M. Did Victorian Britain Fail? The Economic History Review, New Series,

    Vol. 23, No. 3. (Dec., 1970), pp. 446-459.

    Northedge, F.S. 1917 to 1919: The Implications for Great Britain. Journal of Contemporary

    History, Vol. 3, No. 4, 1918-19: From War to Peace. (Oct., 1968), pp. 191-209.

    Notz, William. The World's Coal Situation During the War: I The Journal of Political Economy,

    22

  • 8/8/2019 Armshaw (2007) - Coal, Gold and Nationalism; An Evaluation of Keynes' 'the Economic Consequences of the Peace'

    23/23

    Vol. 26, No. 6. (Jun., 1918), pp. 567-611.

    Phimister, Ian. Coal, Crisis, and Class Struggle: Wankie Colliery, 1918-1922. The Journal of

    African History, Vol. 33, No. 1. (1992), pp. 65-86.

    Polanyi, Karl. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of our Time. London:

    Beacon Press, 2001.

    Polanyi, Karl. Coal: The Case for a Free Market. The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 3, No.

    2. (Apr., 1955), pp. 122-133.

    Shefftz, Melvin C. The Trade Disputes and Trade Union Acts of 1927: The Aftermath of the General

    Strike. The Review of Politics, Vol. 29, No. 3. (Jul., 1967), pp. 387-406.

    Taussig, F.W. Germany's Reparation Payments. The American Economic Review, Vol. 10, No. 1,

    Supplement, Papers and Proceedings of the Thirty-second Annual Meeting of the

    American Economic Association. (Mar., 1920), pp. 33-49.

    Taussig, F.W. The Change in Great Britain's Foreign Trade Terms After 1900. The Economic

    Journal, Vol. 35, No. 137. (Mar., 1925), pp. 1-10.

    Voskuil, Walter H. Coal and Political Power in Europe. Economic Geography, Vol. 18, No. 3. (Jul.,

    1942), pp. 247-258.

    Wicker, Elmus R. Federal Monetary Reserve Policy, 1922-33: A Reinterpretation. The Journal of

    Political Economy, Vol. 73, No. 4. (Aug., 1965), pp. 325-343.

    Wright, J. F. Real Wage Resistance: Eighty Years of the British Cost of Living. Oxford Economic

    Papers, New Series, Vol. 36, Supplement: Economic Theory and Hicksian Themes.

    (Nov., 1984), pp. 152-167.

    23


Recommended