+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

Date post: 01-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: nightbox07
View: 219 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 21

Transcript
  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    1/21Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1416922

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    1

    Assessing UK money supply measures in light of the credit crunch

    Toby BAXENDALE

    [email protected]  Founder and CEO, Seafood Holdings

    Anthony J. EVANS* 

    [email protected] 

    Assistant Professor of Economics, ESCP Europe

    June 2009

    Abstract

    Following the credit crunch renewed attention has been given to the relationship between

    the money supply and the operational efficacy of the Bank of England. We present a

    theoretical definition of the money supply developed by Frank Shostak, called “Austrian

    money supply” (MA) and present calculations for the UK economy. We find preliminary

    evidence that MA provides a constructive interpretation of broader macroeconomic

    activity and warrants further attention from academics and policymakers

    Key words: asset bubble, credit creation, liquidity, monetary policy, money supply

    JEL classification: B53, E41, E51, E52

    * Contact author: Anthony J. Evans, Assistant Professor of Economics, ESCP Europe,

    527 Finchley Road, Hampstead, London, NW3 7BG, United Kingdom; Email:[email protected]. We appreciate data and helpful comments from Frank

    Shostak and Peter Stellios. The usual disclaimer applies.

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    2/21Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1416922

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    2

    “Credit creation is not just an important macroeconomic variable, it is the important

    macroeconomic variable” George Cooper (2008, p.125)

    Introduction

    Following the 2008 credit crunch renewed attention has been given to the ability of

    central banks to effectively monitor the quantity of money in circulation. This bucks the

    trend of declining interest in monetary measures and warrants a reassessment of some

    seminal questions. Any measurement of the money supply must ultimately rest on a

    sound definition of money, however this is routinely taken for granted. This article

    contests the orthodox treatment of money supply measures by policymakers, by

    contrasting current measures of the narrow and broad money supply (M0 and M4) with a

    measure pioneered by Frank Shostak (Shostak 2000), which we label “MA”. We find

    evidence that MA is a more useful means to interpret broader macroeconomic activity

    and warrants further attention from academics and policymakers. Section 1 provides a

    coherent and robust definition of money. Section 2 looks at various types of financial

    asset in light of the definition to determine what should and should not constitute being

     part of the money supply. Section 3 applies these distinctions to the UK and presents the

    UK MA. Section 4 concludes.

    1.  Definitions of money

    It is worth considering whether the measurement of the money supply is a futile

    endeavour. At least two important aspects of money imply difficulty in measurement –

    it’s emergent properties, and its inherent subjectivism.

    Carl Menger provided the seminal account of the origins of money in 1892 (Menger

    1892). In it, he describes how money emerged as a consequence of its “saleability”. A

     barter economy was unable to support a growing market economy, and a single

    commodity – universally valued - emerged to satisfy the so-called double coincidence of

    wants. Thus money emerged as a social institution to facilitate economic exchange, and it

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    3/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    3

    is this key characteristic that drives the definition.1 Our definition of money comes from

    Rothbard:2 

    “Money is the general medium of exchange, the thing that all other goods and

    services are traded for, the final payment for such goods on the market” (Rothbard1978, p.144)

    Although its use as a medium of exchange is the primary function of money, this also

    allowed money to serve secondary (and derivative) uses such as a store of value or units

    of account. However this emergent property can make the boundary between what

    constitutes money and what doesn’t appear blurred. Indeed as Horwitz says, “financial

    assets have degrees of “moneyness” about them, and… different financial assets can be

     placed along a moneyness continuum” (Horwitz, 1990, p.462). Although this might make

    the classification of “money” more onerous, the existing practice of measuring the money

    supply predicates an attempt to provide a less arbitrary definition. And yet even though

    the emergent properties create a continuum of moneyness, these same properties tend to

    result in a single asset being used in exchange. The fact that the value of money stems

    from its use in exchange suggests that people will coordinate around relatively few

    currencies.

    The second reason why money is hard to measure is the inherent subjectivity. If an

    entrepreneur chooses to retain cash balances it is because he deems that to be the most

     profitable use of his scarce resources. The option to buy goods or lend the money is

    1  On this see Menger and Mises, “And so it has come to pass, that as man became

    increasingly conversant with these economic advantages, mainly by an insight becometraditional, and by the habit of economic action, those commodities, which relatively to

     both space and time are most saleable, have in every market become the wares…Moneyhas not been generated by law. In its origin it is a social, and not a state institution”

    (Menger 1892); “There would be an inevitable tendency for the less marketable of theseries of goods used as media of exchange to be one by one rejected until at last only a

    single commodity remained, which was universally employed as a medium of exchange;in a word, money” (Mises 1980, p. 45)2  “As the general medium of exchange, money is a good universally and routinely

    accepted in exchange by market participants... the one good that is traded for all other

    goods on the market” (Salerno 1987, p.1)

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    4/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    4

    always available – at the right price. Therefore it is misleading to deem cash balances

    “idle” or bemoan “hoarding” - the value of money, like the value of any other

    commodity, is subjective, and stems from its availability (Hutt 1956, Horwitz 1990). The

    whole point of a medium of exchange is that it is ready for use, and the only difference

     between money that is “in circulation” or “idle” is the fraction of time in which it changes

    ownership. This point drives straight to the heart of Keynesian orthodoxy that finds

    relevance in the motivation that people have when holding cash balances and other liquid

    assets. In reality the typical distinction between transaction, precaution and speculation

    are not mutually exclusive, and “in analyzing them, it is less important to keep them

    distinct than to keep track of the common element that binds them – the adaptation of

    business dealings to uncertainty” (Hart and Kenen 19483).

    Despite these difficulties, there are two main reasons why efforts to measure the money

    supply make sense. Firstly, by grounding the concept of money in a tight definition it is

     possible to make judgments about whether assets constitute being part of the money

    supply in a non-arbitrary manner. Secondly, measures of the money supply currently

    exist and to some extent the debate is not about the idealised ability to form monetary

    aggregates, but given that aggregates are used, which are the least flawed. In practice that

    which serves as the generally accepted medium of exchange tends to be easier to identify

    than it might appear.

    In March 2009 the Bank of England approached a lower bound for setting the Bank Rate

    (0.5%) and to inject liquidity into the economy engaged in quantitative easing.

    Consequently the “one target one tool” approach of managing the Consumer Price Index

    through interest rates was replaced with a broader attention to the quantity of money.

    According to the Governor, Mervyn King, “when we looked at the numbers we said…

    that we thought that both broad money and the growth of nominal demand in the

    economy were running at a growth rate which was too low to enable us to meet the

    3 Cited in Salerno 1987, footnote 28, p.6, emphasis in original

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    5/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    5

    inflation target and see economy recovery.”4 This demonstrates that despite theoretical

    and empirical doubts about the ability to define and measure the money supply, these

    instruments are of direct policy significance.

    In order to operationalise the definition of money, we identify the following

    characteristics that would constitute whether an asset is part of the money supply:

    A.  A claim transaction - the depositor does not relinquish ownership of the asset

    B.  Redeemable for cash at par - the cash value does not fluctuate

    C.  Redeemable on demand - the saver does not need to give advanced notice

    D. 

    Routinely accepted - commonly agreed to be “legal tender”

    E.  The final means of payment - it fully discharges a debt

    2.  Money supply measures

    Before wading too deep in empirical associations, it’s important to stress the difficulties

    in identifying robust statistical relationships. Arguments remain about whether key

    indicators are leading or lagging, and what the stylised facts are, “these characteristic

    qualitative features of most business fluctuations have not corresponded to persistence

    regularities of the quantitative  relationships that constitute the main focus of modern

     business cycle analysis” (Friedman 1986). Indeed in the US in the early 1980s the

    statistical relationship between M1 growth and major economic indicators (such as GDP)

     began to fail as people moved money from savings accounts into NOW accounts5.

    According to The Federal Reserve “M2 has been downgraded as a reliable indicator of

    financial conditions in the economy, and no single variable has yet been identified to take

    4 Comments made to a Treasury select committee in late March, cited in “Money supply

    supplants rates on Bank’s agenda”, The Times, by Norma Cohen5 The former are part of M2 whereas the latter are also in M1. On the other hand, M1 has

     been misleadingly low due to “sweeps”, which occur when banks shift funds from

    checking accounts (M1) into savings accounts without reserve requirements.

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    6/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    6

    its place”6. It is commonly held that in the 1980s and 1990s financial deregulation led to

    greater instability in the demand for money, thus making it harder to track. According to

    some “the reliability of various money measures as useful indicators on which to base

     policy has become seriously compromised” (Carlson and Keen 1996, p.15). Indeed the

    Federal Reserve abandoned M1 targets in 1987, and M2 targets in 1992. In March 2006

    they stopped publishing M3 statistics. The Bank of England abandoned M0 in May 2006.

    These actions all call into question the usefulness of money supply aggregates, but what

    if the aggregates were the wrong ones?

    Our claim is that the failure of previous measures is due to the detail of their composition

    rather than a fundamental problem with finding monetary aggregates. Typically the

    definition of money stems from an arbitrary mixture of various liquid assets that happen

    to correlate with national income. But if any mixture of liquidity is accepted, can’t retail

    good inventories be included? A basket of commonly used shopping may well be as

    liquid as stocks or bonds, yet without a tight definition of the money supply it’s hard to

     justify their exclusion (see Baxendale 2005). According to Salerno,

    “Measures of the U.S. money stock in current use in economic and business

    forecasting and in applied economics and historical research are flawed precisely

     because they are not based on an explicit and coherent theoretical conception of

    the essential nature of money. Given the all-pervasive role of money in the

    modern market economy, existing money-supply measures therefore tend to

    impede, rather than to facilitate, a clear understanding of the past or future

    development of actual economic events.”

    Salerno 1987, p. 17 

    6 Comments by Alan Greenspan to a Congressional Testimony, July 1993

    7  This view is supported by Shostak, “for the mainstream, the definition of money is

    established through an arbitrary mixing of various liquid assets and then correlating this

    mixture with another dubious statistic labelled national income” Shostak 2000, p.69

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    7/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    7

    In terms of prevailing US measures, M1 contains items such as currency in circulation,

    travellers checks, demand deposits (i.e. checking account balances), and “other checkable

    deposits”. M1 is typically about 10% of GDP. M2 also includes savings account, money

    market deposit accounts, time deposits under a certain amount, and retail market money

    mutual funds. MZM is a newer measure, which focuses on money with zero maturity (it

    is essentially M2 less small time deposits but with institutional MMMFs) and is produced

     by the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis. M3 – an even broader measure – includes large

    time deposits, balances in institutional money market funds, but excludes US government

    assets or foreign banks and official institutions. Note that the broader the measure, the

    less liquid the assets, and thus “money” is being defined more in terms of its function as a

    store of value than as a medium of exchange. This creates a notorious degree of

    arbitrariness in terms of where the line gets drawn between the degree of liquidity to

    include.

    Looking more specifically at the United Kingdom, M0 comprises of cash in circulation

    outside the Bank of England plus banks’ operational deposits at the Bank of England.

    This was a measure of narrow money, which was replaced in May 2006 by “Notes &

    Coin and Reserve Balances”. Reserve balances are held by private banks at the Bank of

    England, and bear interest. Due to the fast pace of financial innovation it had become

    increasingly easy for people to substitute between narrow money (liquidity) and broad

    money (interest bearing assets), leading the Bank of England to view little middle ground

     between M0 and M4. According to a popular economics textbook, “Once we leave cash

    in circulation, the first sensible place to stop is M4” (Begg et al, p.442). However the

    convention of this dual narrow/broad approach takes for granted the theoretical validity

    of the categories being incorporated. We follow seminal works by economists that

    attempt to measure the money supply based on a clear definition of the defining

    characteristics of money. For example, the “True Money Supply” (TMS) is compiled and

    made available by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Alabama. This follows Salerno

    (1987).8 The other main Austrian measure is the “Actual” or “Austrian Money Supply”

    8 Also see Rothbard (1978): “ Ma (a = Austrian) = total supply of cash-cash held in the

     banks + total demand deposits + total savings deposits in commercial and savings banks

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    8/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    8

    (AMS), presented by Shostak (2000). The benefit of an Austrian approach is to apply a

    coherent theoretical definition of money. Using our previous definition of money we can

    make judgments about various asset classes:

    Currency in circulation (cash)

    The simplest place to start is the notes and coins held in the pockets and shoeboxes of

    countries citizens. This is the chief component of the money supply – it is a universally

    accepts means of payment. Cash provides the “physical embodiment of the generally

    accepted medium of exchange” (Salerno 1987, p.2).

     Demand deposits (checking account)

    Irving Fisher made a distinction between cash (M) and demand deposits (M1), however

    these deposits should be included in the money supply since they are redeemable for cash

    at par on demand. If a consumer transfers cash from under the mattress to a checking

    account, there is no change in the money supply (one component falls, another rises).9 As

    Salerno states, “checkable deposits held at federally-insured banks and thrifts are readily

    acceptable in exchange as perfect substitutes, dollar for dollar, for Federal Reserve notes”

    (Salerno 1987, p.2)10

     

    + total shares in savings and loan associations + time deposits and small CDs at current

    redemption rates + total policy reserves of life insurance companies—policy loansoutstanding—demand deposits owned by savings banks, saving and loan associations,

    and life insurance companies + savings bonds, at current rates of redemption.” (Rothbard1978, p.153).9 In a world of fractional-reserve banking, however, demand deposits become a crucial

    source of monetary expansion since banks will lend out some of that checking account.

    This doesn’t alter the savers legal right to withdraw their asset at par and on demand, butdoes increase the amount of money in the economy.10

     Only under 100 percent reserve banking are demand deposits cash redeemable, but thisdoesn’t matter. Provided that agents treat deposits as redeemable they are part of the

    money supply (see Rothbard p.146) “ so long as  demand deposits are  accepted asequivalent to standard money, they will function as part of the money supply” (Rothbard

    1978, p.145, emphasis in original)

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    9/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    9

    Savings deposits (savings count)

    A distinction needs to be made between claim and credit transactions (Mises 1980). A

    claim transaction occurs when the owner of a given amount of money stores it in a bank,

     but retains ownership of the entire sum. This supposedly occurs in current accounts,

    where the owner is entitled to withdraw their deposit at any time. By contrast a credit

    transaction occurs when the owner of the money relinquishes immediate ownership,

     permitting the bank to act as an intermediary and lend it out. This occurs in savings

    accounts, where ownership is transferred from lender to borrower, and withdrawals can

    only be made following a given time period. Another term for a “claim transaction” is a

    demand   deposit, whilst a “credit transaction” is term  deposit. According to Salerno

    (1987) “Savings deposits, whether at commercial banks or thrift institutions are

    economically indistinguishable from demand deposits and are therefore included in the

    TMS. Both demand and savings deposits are federally insured under the same conditions

    and, consequently, both represent instantly cashable, par value claims to the general

    medium of exchange” (Salerno1987, p.2) Rothbard points out that the legal incidence

    isn’t as important as the economic reality, and the subjective beliefs of savers. If the 30-

    day notice is not enforced – and savers don’t expect it to be enforced – those savings

    should constitute the money supply. He claims that only a “ genuine time deposit…not

     being redeemable on demand, would instead be a credit instrument rather than a form of

    warehouse receipt” (Rothbard 1978, p.149, emphasis in original).

    However according to Shostak, the key point is that banks could  invoke a waiting period

     before savings accounts can be accessed; crucially “when a depositor places his money in

    a savings or fixed-term deposit, he temporarily relinquishes his ownership. This,

    however, is not the case with demand deposits” (Shostak 2000). This takes us back to the

    definition of money as a medium of exchange – if an asset is not directly transferable it

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    10/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    10

    will not be “routinely exchanged” and thus not be money.11

     Shostak rightfully excludes

    savings deposits because they are credit transactions. The key point is that although

     people can draw a check on a savings account, to meet that obligation they must liquidate

     part of their savings by transferring assets into a checking account. The savings account

    does not act as a final payment on goods and services. If financial innovation results in a

    savings account that can be drawn upon directly, this would no longer constitute

    “savings” as we’re using the term, and become de facto demand deposits. Whereas for

    Salerno savings are part of the money supply because they are “at all times transferable,

    dollar for dollar, into “transactions” accounts” (Salerno 1987, p.3), for Shostak and us

    they only enter the money supply if and when they are so transferred. Ultimately people

    do not settle bills with a savings account-to savings account transfer.

    The issue of savings accounts provides an example of the problems posed by the

    subjectivism of money. For Rothbard if the general public believe (falsely) that money in

    their savings accounts are instantly redeemable and act in accordance with this belief,

    does this mean we should treat it as part of the money supply? We would contend that

    money isn’t what people believe is purchasing power, but what is routinely accepted by

    others. This provides the binding constraint, since merchants would only accept “savings”

    that have been converted into either cash or a demand deposit.12

     

     Money market mutual funds (MMMF), retail market funds and other securities

    Crucially, the money supply is “all claims to dollars at fixed par values” (Rothbard 2005,

     p.182). MMMF’s are not money because they are a form of investment that has a

    11 (See footnote 10 of Salerno 1987, where he refers to White, "Definition and

    Identification of Money," p. 310, and Yeager, "The Medium of Exchange," pp. 40-46, 53-

    56). “The nub, however, is that savings deposits do not confer an unlimited claim”(Shostak 200, p.73)12

      In another passage Rothbard seems to accept this: “They continue as equivalent to

    money only so long as the subjective estimates of the seller of goods on the market think  

    that they are so equivalent and accept them as such in exchange” (Rothbard 1978, p.145,

    emphasis in original)

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    11/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    11

    fluctuating price, thus are not redeemable at par. If an investor wishes to liquidate a

    MMMF they must instruct a fund manager to sell a portion of their holdings and then

    transfer the proceeds. Since these proceeds will fluctuate according to market conditions

    it cannot be considered a final means of payment.

    Shostak (2000) raises the issue that money market mutual funds (MMMF) can be

    withdrawn on demand, but as Salerno points out “they are neither instantly redeemable,

     par value claims to cash, nor final means of payment in exchange” (Salerno 1987) – and

    thus not part of the money supply. Indeed it would be double counting to include

    MMMFs in the definition of the money supply since money isn’t created when a deposit

    is made – they are a neutral asset class. In addition to this retail market money funds are

    clearly not part of the money supply since short-term debt (e.g. Treasury bonds or

    commercial paper) are not routinely used as a media of exchange). Similarly shares are

    not part of the money supply since they can only be sold to the market at fluctuating rates

    and are thus not liquid enough to constitute “money”.

    Certificates of deposit (CDs)

    According to Rothbard small-denomination CD’s are redeemable at fixed rates (albeit

    with a penalty discount), and he suggests including the instrument at the penalty level as

     part of the money supply. For the US economy this also implies that federal savings

     bonds (and other assets that are redeemable at a fixed rate such as cash surrender values

    of life insurance policies) should go in. The crucial issue is whether there is indeed a

    fixed time frame that prevents the asset holder from liquidating the value.13

     

     Retail goods

    13 But note that according to Salerno, “the ultimate decision to exclude the item was also

    heavily influenced by the practical problem of obtaining the data necessary to permit areasonable estimate of its value in current dollars, i.e., net of penalty assessments”

    (Salerno 1987, p.4)

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    12/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    12

    The example of retail goods provides a curious critique of many attempts to measure the

    money supply.  If   liquidity is the main criteria (which is the case with stocks or bonds)

    then it becomes hard to see why retail goods shouldn’t also be included. The reason is

     because they are sold for money, and thus cannot actually be money.

     Domestic government deposits

    According to traditional measures if the government raises £1m through taxation, when

    the money is transferred out of their deposit accounts this reduces the money supply by

    £1m. If the money has simply been transferred from private to public accounts there

    should be no change in the overall money supply – the money is still in circulation. As

    Shostak points out, “in reality, however, the money is now available for government

    expenditure, meaning that money held in government deposits should be part of the

    definition of money” (Shostak 2000). We are concerned with “the total stock of money

    owned by all  economic agents” (Salerno 1987, p.5, emphasis in original).

     Foreign government deposits

    If foreign banks hold checking accounts in domestic institutions, these constitute part of

    the money supply, since they’re denominated in sterling. Obviously time deposits should

    not count for reasons mentioned above.

    Travellers’ checks

    Travellers checks are a credit transaction, and therefore should not be counted in the

    money supply. “Cashing a traveler’s check means that AMEX or VISA will transfer

    money from their deposits to the holder of the check, which will not change the amount

    of money in the economy“ (Shostak 2000). Also, they are not routinely accepted as a

    means of final payment, and “travelers’ checks issues by nonbank financial institutions…

    are excluded… because they neither are riskfree claims to immediate cash nor serve as

    final means of payment” (Salerno 1987, p.2) Traveller’s checks allow the existing money

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    13/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    13

    stock to operate more effectively, but they do not increase the availability of the media of

    exchange.14

     

    3. 

    The UK MA

    We follow Shostak (2000) and define the money supply as having the following

    components:

    1.  Cash

    2.  Demand deposits (with commercial banks and thrift institutions)

    3.  Government deposits (with banks and the central bank)

    In contrast to M0 and M4 we present “MA” as an “Austrian” measure of the money

    supply for the UK economy, and as shown in Table 1 the total value of MA as of March

    2009 was £116,973m (! £117bn).

    Table 1: Austrian money supply (MA) [Last updated: March 2009 ] 

    ComponentSeries name/code

    (Source: Bank of England)

    Latest

    Period

    Latest

    value (£m)

    1. Cash

    “Monthly average amount

    outstanding of total sterling notesand coin in circulation outside the

    Bank of England total (in sterlingmillions) not seasonally adjusted”

    LPMAVAA

    31/3/09 53,008

    2. Demand depositswith commercial

     banks and thrift

    institutions

    Monthly amounts outstanding ofUK resident banks' (inc. Central

    Bank) sterling retail deposits from

     private sector (in sterling millions)not seasonally adjusted

    31/3/09 852,968

    14  Finally, sweeps should be part of the money supply, but can be difficult to find

    accurate measures.

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    14/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    14

    LPMVQXW

    3. Governmentdeposits with banks

    and the central bank

    Monthly amounts outstanding ofmonetary financial institutions'

    sterling deposits from CentralGovernment (in sterling millions)

    not seasonally adjusted

    LPMVWLS

    31/3/0930,091 

    Adjustment15

      - 819,094

    Total MA £116,973m

    It is important at this point to note some data availability constraints. In July 2008 the

    Bank of England reclassified £14bn of interest bearing assets into non-interest bearing

    ones16

    . In his data series Shostak thus uses retail banks deposits as a proxy measure for

    “demand deposits”, and focuses on monthly changes from the pre-July 2008 measures

    rather than the absolute values. This is why such a large adjustment is required, because

    MA can no longer be measured directly.17

     

    However despite these concerns the MA provides some important results. Figure 1 shows

    the two predominant measures of the UK money supply (M0 and M4)18

      together with

    MA. This demonstrates that MA is a broader measure than M0 (since it also includes

    demand deposits and government deposits) but significantly more liquid than M4. Amore relevant comparison is shown in figure 2, which charts the year on year change of

    15 See comments in text

    16 Formally the demand deposit section could be taken from the following series,

    “Monthly amounts of UK residents banks (inc Central Bank) sterling non-interest bearing

    deposits (inc. transit and suspense) from private sector”(LPMAUYA). But following thedecision to lump £14bn of assets into this measure it is no longer appropriate.17

     By following Shostak’s method we replicated his measure of the Austrian moneysupply and this data is available on request. There is a period in late 1999 – early 2001

    where our replication overestimates the official data. This is due to massive increases ingovernment deposits recorded during this period, which were adjusted by Shostak. Aside

    from the fact that a perfect replication is not the objective of this paper, we acknowledgethat such adjustments constitute the added value of the analysis provided by Shostak.

    More importantly, this also demonstrates the limitations provided by the existing data.18

     Although M0 was discontinued we use this to label the narrow measure of the money

    supply out of convention

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    15/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    15

    all three measures. Both conventional measures exhibit little deviation over the 10-year

     period of study, demonstrating why money supply measures have lost favour as a means

    of interpreting economic activity. However MA provides some immediate points of

    interest. The period around the “dotcom bubble” can clearly be detected with over 25%

    growth rates in the quantity of money, and following this a deflationary period in early

    2003. The build up to the present financial crisis coincides with sustained positive growth

    (above the rate of consumer price inflation) that collapsed in early 2008 and remains

    negative throughout that year. Even a cursory inspection of the series suggests it is worth

    further attention.

    This paper intends to provide an interpretation of recent economic history through the

    lens of a new measure of the money supply. Carlson and Keen (1996), and Teles and

    Zhou (2005) provide a more formal approach to justifying attention on a new monetary

    aggregate, MZM (money of zero maturity). Interestingly MZM is a similar measure to

    MA in that it focuses on highly liquid assets, but no measure exists for the UK at present.

    This points to the lack of data that mitigates the confidence we have in compiling such

    “novel” series, and the inherent difficulty of relying on central bank data that is compiled

    with little attention to the theoretical considerations that concern us. We therefore feel it

    would be inappropriate to pursue a similar approach and instead the methodological goal

    is more focused on broad relationships than to provide a robust statistical test. In short,

    our focus is on the theoretical validity of the measure and the data is provided as a

    cautious justification of its relevance. Even at this level of abstraction the results are

    notable. Figure 3 takes “Real MA” (the MA measure adjusted for CPI) and plots against

    Industrial Production. Figure 4 correlates Real MA to GDP, where we have incorporated

    an arbitrary 12-month lag. Figure 5 shows Real MA against retail sales, also with a 12-

    month lag. On all counts MA offers close approximations for economic activity. The

    failure of Long-Term Capital Management following the Russian crisis of 1998 can be

    observed with a monetary deflation in that quickly turned into a massive expansion in the

    money supply during the dot com boom. At it’s peak the MA was running at over 25% a

    year, the subsequent bursting of this bubble led to a prolonged decline in the growth rate

    of MA (including a massive drop following September 11th

      2001) and subsequent

    deflation in 2003. The most remarkable observation is the consequence of the steady

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    16/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    16

    expansion during 2006 and 2007. In January 2008 the MA went from a 10% year on year

    growth rate to -4%, demonstrating the sharp contraction that resulted in Bear Stearns and

    Lehman Brothers. Contra M0 and M4 this monetary deflation continued throughout 2008

    reaching lows of -10% in October.

    4.  Conclusion

    This article investigates an alternative measure of the money supply, MA. Despite

    difficulties in data availability, a brief comparison with relevant economic indicators

    demonstrates that in contrast to M0 and M4 monetary aggregates can have an empirical

    manifestation. As policymakers increasingly target money growth instead of interest rates

    there will be increased attention to measures of the money supply. It is important to recap

    on the purpose of money supply measures. Traditionally these have been deemed to play

    a crucial role in explaining the future path of the real economy over the shorter term, as

    well as being the root cause of price inflation. Although existing monetary measures have

     been less than exemplary for forecasting, our contention is that this is primarily due to

    theoretical issues regarding the choice of measure. By providing a brief history of the

     present we see that MA deserves appropriate consideration and further scholarly research.

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    17/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    17

    References

    Baxendale, T. and A.J. Evans, 2008, “Austrian Business Cycle Theory in Light of

    Rational Expectations: The Role of Heterogeneity, the Monetary Footprint, and Adverse

    Selection in Monetary Expansion” Quarterly Journal Of Austrian Economics, Vol. 11, No.3

    Baxendale, T, 2005, “The Method of an Austrian Hedge Fund”  Mises Institute Daily

     Article, March 15th

     2005

    Böhm-Bawerk, E., 1891 The Positive Theory of Capital , Book 6, chapter 5, Macmillan

    and Co.,

    Carlson, J.B., and Keen, B.D., 1996, “MZM: A Monetary Aggregate for the 1990s?”

     Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review, II, pp. 15-23

    Cooper, G, 2008, The Origin of Financial Crises: Central banks, credit bubbles and the

    efficient market fallacy, Petersfield, Harriman House

    Evans, A.J., and T. Baxendale, 2008, “Testing Times for Central Banks: Is there room for

    Austrian ideas at the top table?” Economic Affairs, Vol. 28, Issue 4, pp.36-41

    Friedman, B.M., 1986, “Money, Credit and Interest Rates in the Business Cycle” in R.J.

    Gordon (ed.) The American Business Cycle Chicago: University of Chicago Press

    Hart, A.G., and Kenen 1948 Money, Debt and Economic Activity,

    Hayek, F.A., 1937, “Economics and Knowledge” Economica New Series

    Hazlitt, H. 2008, “The Velocity of Circulation” Mises Institute Daily Article, 17th

     March

    2008

    Horwitz, S., 1990, “A subjectivist approach to the demand for money”  Journal des

     Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, Vol 1, No.4, pp.459-471

    Hutt, W.H., 1956 “The yield from money held” in Sennholz, M., ed, On Freedom and

     Free Enterprise: Essays in Honour of Ludwig von Mises, Princeton: Von Nostrand

    Menger, C., 1892, “On the Origins of Money” Economic Journal , Vol. 2 pp. 239-55

    Mises, L.von, 1980, [I912] The Theory of Money and Credit  Indianapolis: Liberty Press

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    18/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    18

    Rothbard, M.N., 1978, “Austrian Definitions of the Supply of Money” in New Directions

    in Austrian Economics, Spadaro, L.M. (ed), Kansas City” Sheed Andrews and McMeel

    Rothbard, M.N., 2005, What has government done to our money?  Mises Institute (5th 

    Edition)

    Salerno, J.T., 1987, “The “True” Money Supply: A Measure of the Supply of the Medium

    of Exchange in the U.S. economy”  Austrian Economics Newsletter , Ludwig von Mises

    Institute

    Shostak, F., (1999) “Asian Recovery?” The Asian Wall Street Journal   June 15th

    Shostak, F., 2000, “The Mystery of the Money Supply Definition” The Quarterly Journal

    of Austrian Economics, Vol. 3, No. 4, pp.69-76

    Teles, P. and Zhou, R., 2005. “A stable money demand: Looking for the right monetary

    aggregate” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago  Economic Perspectives pp.50-93

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    19/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    19

    Appendix

     Figure 1: UK money stocks 

     Figure 2: Change in UK money stocks 

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    20/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    20

     Figure 3: Real MA vs. Industrial Production

     Figure 4: Real MA vs. GDP (12 month lag)

  • 8/9/2019 Assessing UK Money Supply Measures in Light of the Credit Crunch

    21/21

    FIRST DRAFT – PLEASE DO NOT CITE

    21

     Figure 5: Real MA vs. Retail sales (12 month lag)


Recommended