+ All Categories
Home > Documents > ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS...

ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS...

Date post: 21-Jan-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 7 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
44
"ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS" Alain BULTEZ* Els GIJSBRECHTS** Philippe NAERT*** Piet VANDEN ABEELE**** N° 88 / 47 Alain BULTEZ, Professor of Marketing, Catholic University of Mons (FUCAM), and Directore of EIASM. * * Els GIJSBRECHTS, Associate Professor of Marketing, Antwerp (UFSIA). *** Philippe NAERT, Professor of Marketing and Dean, INSEAD, Fontainebleau. **** Piet VANDEN ABEELE, Professor of Marketing, Catholic University of Leuven (KUL). Director of Publication : Charles WYPLOSZ, Associate Dean for Research and Development Printed at INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France
Transcript
Page 1: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

"ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEENSUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS"

Alain BULTEZ*Els GIJSBRECHTS**Philippe NAERT***

Piet VANDEN ABEELE****

N° 88 / 47

Alain BULTEZ, Professor of Marketing, Catholic University of Mons(FUCAM), and Directore of EIASM.

* * Els GIJSBRECHTS, Associate Professor of Marketing, Antwerp (UFSIA).

*** Philippe NAERT, Professor of Marketing and Dean, INSEAD,Fontainebleau.

**** Piet VANDEN ABEELE, Professor of Marketing, Catholic Universityof Leuven (KUL).

Director of Publication :

Charles WYPLOSZ, Associate Deanfor Research and Development

Printed at INSEAD,Fontainebleau, France

Page 2: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS

LISTED BY RETAILERS

Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert

and Piet Vanden Abeele*

+ This paper is the outcome of the authors' close collaboration through the

European Institute for Advanced Studies in Management (EIASM, Brussels).

It was presented by Alain Bultez at the EIASM's Workshop on Marketing,

Decision Support Systems : From MIS to MESs ? (March 17-18, 1988).

* Alain Bultez is Professor of Marketing at the Catholic University of Mons

(FUCAM), and Director of EIASM ;

Els Gijsbrechts is Associate Professor of Marketing at the University of

Antwerp (UFSIA) ;

Philippe Naert is Professor of Marketing and Dean of INSEAD (Fontaine-

bleau) ;

Piet Vanden Abeele is Professor of Marketing at the Catholic University

of Leuven (KUL).

Page 3: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

1.

Abstract

SH.A.R.P. (Bultez and Naert, 1988) aims at optimizing the alloca-

tion of a retail outlet's selling area, across the items composing its as-

sortment. Demand interdependencies are introduced by focusing on substitu-

tion occurring within each homogeneous product category. They are modelled

through an attraction-type specification of the items' share in the cate-

gory's total sales volume. The latter, however, implies fully symmetric

patterns of substitution.

Here, by adopting the asymmetric variant of the attraction model

proposed by Vanden Abeele, Gijsbrechts and Vanhuele (1987), we generalize

the SH.A.R.P. optimization rule so as to integrate the diversity of substi-

tution effects that may be caused by brand loyalty, preference for a spe-

cific variety, or package size purchasing habits. The extended model is

empirically validated on a sample of data collected during an experiment

run on the canned dog-food category of a large Belgian hypermarket. Norma-

tive results point to the benefits which can be derived from using

SH.A.R.P. II.

Page 4: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

2.

1. Introduction

A retail business is continuously confronted, more than any other

firm, with the monitoring of the interdependencies generated within its

multiproduct assortments. Thus retailers managing large self-service stores

are facing, within each of their lines, internai competitive interactions.

The jargon they use - typically, the word "cannibalism" - clearly denotes

their concern for the multiple forms that substitution effects may take

within their departments : competition between brands, either within or

across variety-types, and vice-versa substitution between variety-types,

either within or across brand lines.

In addition, positive interactions may also co-exist. Price pro-

motions, retail advertising and special displays boost the sales of the

items featured but hopefully contribute to the favorable positioning of the

shop, or of the entire chain, and are likely to increase store-wide or

chain-wide traffic. For illustrations of interesting approaches to these

aspects of retailing, refer to e.g., Corstjens and Doyle (1981), Doyle and

Saunders (1987), McGoldrick (1986) and Wilkinson et al. (1981, 1982).

Whether positive or negative, cross-product effects occuring

within retailers' assortments are difficult to measure and make the plan-

ning and control of merchandising activities quite complex ... or messy.

Reibstein and Gatignon's article (1984) of fers evidence of the problems met

by marketing model builders when trying to tackle those issues rieorously.

The overwhelming number of commodities carried further compounds the

retailer's task and most often prevents him from assessing their direct

cost and profitability. This in turn explains the current craze for the

so-called DPP systems, integrating costing and space allocation rules.

Page 5: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

3.

(e.g., P & G's approach to "Total System Efficiency" presented to its cus-

tomers as en impartial, disinterested methodology especiaily designed for

helping them in the audit and management of their retail operations).

However determining those "linkages" are in the retailer's "chain

value" (reference to Porter's terminology appears particularly appropriate

in this case), rare are the marketing scientists who have systematically

explored their normative implications. Here, in this article, we focus on

those which relate to shelf space allocation within superstores.

More specifically we extend SH.A.R.P., a general model developed

by Bultez and Naert (1988) and experimented with some success in the

allocation of the shelf space available for display of items forming

homogeneous product categories. SH.A.R.P. includes sales interdependencies

which take the form of symmetric substitution effects modeled through a

simple attraction-type specification. Yet in many situations, brand and/or

package-size loyalty e.g., may introduce asymmetries that an MCI model

cannot account for. To remedy this inadequacy, we adapt SH.A.R.P. by

incorporating into it a variant of the "competitive cluster asymmetry"

model, proposed by Vanden Abeele, Gijsbrechts and Vanhuele (1987).

In section 2, the theoretical background of SH.A.R.P. is reviewed.

Section 3 shows how asymmetry can be introduced. Generalized cross-elasti-

cities and optimization results are then derived in sections 4 and 5, res-

pectively. In sections 6 and 7, calibration and implementation procedures

are discussed and illustrated through an application in a real setting. A

sensitivity analysis aims at estimating how much ignoring asymmetry would

cost to the retailer.

Page 6: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

4.

2. Optimal Shelf Space Allocation : Theoretical background

Bultez and Naert (1988) examine how a retailer, seeking to maxi-

mize the total profit (H) produced by his multi-item assortment, should

allocate the limited space available in his store (S). The assortment is

defined along two dimensions : its depth (D), determined by the set of

brands offered to the buyer, and its width (W), delimited by the variety of

item types, i.e. the range of tastes, package forms and sizes, constituting

the various brands' product lines. Thus each item is identified by both its

variety-type (v c W) and its brand name (b c D). Each item's sales volume

(qvb) depends not only on its own visibility, hence on the space allocated

specifically to itself (s vb ), but also on the other items' display (sic).

Its contribution to profit (rvb) is defined by the difference between the

gross margin generated by its sales (gvb

qvb

) and the cost (Cvb) its hand-

ling entails.

Such a problem definition is quite general, except for the res-

triction that the assortment composition cannot be altered : the set of

items considered is fixed a priori. Therefore the allocation rule derived

therefrom presents an interesting degree of generality. Bultez and Naert

(hereafter, B & N) show that the space available should be shared according

to the following equations,

a = s /Svb vb = (Yvb cvb -I vb )/( fg) '(1)

for v E W and b E D;

Page 7: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

5.

where : cvb

= Cvb

/H, represents the ratio of the handling cost resulting

from carrying brand b's item v to the assortment overall

profitability l ;

=-(aCvb/asvb ), stands for the absolute value

Yvb Idelvb = °)(svb/Cvb

of the partial elasticity of item v's handling cost with respect to

the space allocated to it (of a constant sales level) ;

nvb = E E r. n(m. ,s )jc jc vbcED jcW

is the weighted mean of all items' sales elasticities, n(m. , s),jc vb

with respect to the space allocated to brand b's item v ;

jc7:withr=/11, the relative contribution of brand c's item j tojc

the assortment profitability,

and

= E Evb

and d = E E yvb cvb,

bel) ve b v

are the normalizing ternis.

For notation convenience, but without loss of generality, let us con-

sider that if a brand is not listed among the items of a specific variety-

type carried by the retailer, then the corresponding variables character-

izing it are all set equal to zero.

The apparent complexity of the ternis entering (1) is due to the

fairly general implicit functions underlying this non-linear mathematical

(2)

Page 8: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

6.

programming problem. Their interpretation is not too difficult, however :

the space share allocated to brand b's item v should be proportional to the

extent that its visibility contributes to push up the sales of the most

profitable items in the category considered (ivb ) ;

it should also be in-

creased in so far as its piling up on the shelf may reduce handling and re-

plenishment operations (yvb

.cvb

).

Implementing (1) calls for the explicit specification of the

handling cost and sales response. B & N assume that the cost is a constant

elasticity function of the frequency of replenishment, i.e.

C = f (q /s )Yvb

vb vb vb vb '

with fvb

> O, a constant scaling factor. Interested in rather homogeneous

product categories constituting classes of differentiated substitutes, they

suggest the attraction model for the description of the competition pre-

vailing between brands, as well as of the cannibalism which may also occur

within each brand's line2, i.e.

Pm = se /E E a. s. ,vb vb vb jc jcc j

where : mvb = qvb/Q•denotes the share of brand b's item v in the product

category total sales volume (Q = E

qvb' supposed to remainb v

constant) ; a, ja and 5 are non-negative parameters.

vbc

(3)

(4)

Page 9: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

7.

B & N extensively report on various tests of their model and al-

location procedure. Their analyses, however, omit the distinction between

the two dimensions of the retailer's assortment : items are either clus-

tered together brandwise (i.e., they focus on the aggregate brand level :

S.b

= Z svb), or their belonging to their respective brand lines is

i vb).

Indeed the intrinsically symmetric nature of model (4) fits well

in the absence of a hierarchical structure or partitioning in the

retailer's assortment. It implies identical cross-elasticities of sales

shares, i.e.

n(mjc , svb ) = n(mjb' svb ) = n(mvc' svb ) = 13111vb•

Thus when an item's visibility is increased, the sales share of any other

item gets reduced by a fixed proportion, which only depends on the relative

importance of the item whose visibility is enhanced (measured by mvb , here),

and not on the alternative item affected (j,c). Therefore substitution

between variety types offered by the same brand (j v) and competition

opposing different brands (c b) are treated similarly : both sorts of

interdependencies are assumed to be of the same strength.

As a matter of fact, such an assumption is quite restrictive.

Should, e.g., brand loyalty prevail, then one would expect relatively

stronger substitution effects between items of the same brand than between

items offered by different brands, i.e.

in(m. , s )1>in(m s )1 .jb vb jc' vb

Page 10: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

S.

3. Asymmetric Variant of the Attraction Model

Model (4) can be presented under the classic relative attraction

form,

m = t /E E t. ,vb vb . jcc j

where each of the terms, tvb' stands for the attractiveness of each respec-

tive item.

Let avb be the intrinsic attraction exerted by brand b's item v,

i.e. the attraction which it exerts independently of the choice context

(i.e., other items bearing the same brand narre, or of the same variety or

package size), e.g.

a = a s6 .vb vb vb

If tvb

is assimilated to avb'

model (4) is obtained. This shows that its

symmetry results from the fact that each of the terms, tvb'

uniquely

depends on the context-free attraction exerted by the corresponding

specific item (v,b). Consequently the ratio of two items' sales shares is

determined only by the ratio of their respective attractions, i.e.

jm /m = t /t j= a /ac vb jc vb e vb •

It appea • s absolutely unrelated to the visibility of any other item,

whether from the same brand line (either b or c) or from the same variety

type (either v or j).

(5)

(6)

Page 11: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

(7)

(8)

9.

In order to circumvent this limitation of the attraction model,

Vanden Abeele, Gijsbrechts and Van Huele (1987) develop a generalized for-

mulation, by raaking the ternis, tvb'

functions not only of the specific

item's attraction, avb , but also of the attraction exerted by clusters of

related items, i.e.and/or a .ajbvc

Here, adapting Vanden Abeele et al.'s suggestion, we propose to

adjust the ternis by the total attraction exerted by the items of the same

brand line and/or of the same variety. More explicitly, we postulate that

2tvb

= avb

/(Aev.l A

eb

)

where :

Av.

= E a and A = a. ,vc

account for the total attraction exerted by items of the v-th variety type

and by those offered by brand b, respectively ; 0 < ek < 1, are parameters

regulating the degree of asymmetry caused by the k-th cluster of items.

Deflating the original attraction according to (7) and (8) yields

the following ratios of sales shares,

02.

m. /m = [a. MAe.1

A'2

)]/[avb

/(Av.

01 A .b ))jc vb jc j. .c

Page 12: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

(9)

(10)

10.

the meaning of which becomes clear if we consider e.g. the special case

when brand loyalty is the single source of asymmetry (i.e. 8 1 = 0 and

82 = 8), i.e.

m. /m = [a. /a HA /Ae

jc vb jc vb .b .c 1

The latter expression demonstrates the impact of our "deflation". In the

case of full asymmetry (6 = 1), the sales shares ratio corresponds to the

ratio of the items' shares within their own brand i s sales, i.e.

m. /m = m. /mjc vb jl.c vl.b '

where :

mvl.b

= avb

/A.b •

Thus full asymmetry reveals synonymous of absolute intra-brand

product-line cannibalism. As illustrated further in figure 1, (9)-(10)

implies that an increase of the visibility of brand b's item v will eat up

the sales of brand b's items exclusively. At the other extreme, i.e. , when

asymmetry is reduced to nil (8 = 0), the degree of cannibalism within the

brand line is as strong (or as moderate) as it is across brands.

Insert figure 1 about here

Figure la shows that in the case of symmetric substitution the increase in

item (1,b) sales cornes equally at the expense of item (2,b) and of brand c.

Page 13: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

11.

In contrat, as demonstrated by figure lb, when asymmetry is present, the

sales share of item (2,b) is dramatically affected while brand c's items

hardly suffer.

4. Generalized Cross-Elasticities :

Economists traditionally rely on the concept of demand cross-

elasticities to characterize product interdependencies and especially their

degree of substitutability3. The nature and relative strengths of

competitive interactions are indeed reflected in the structure of the

matrix of direct and cross-elasticities. Thus we shall measure the exact

incidence of introducing asymmetry into the attraction model by reference

to the cross-elasticity standard.

Substituting (7) and (8) into (5), we obtain the asymmetric ver-

sion of the model,

82

-0 - m. = a. A. A /E SaA A,

2 .

jc jc j..c deD weJ wd w '

81

'a

Let T. =Etjd

Tc = E t

wc and T =EEtwd. Then the marginal direct/

' .d d w

cross-effects of a variation in the visibility of brand b's item v is de-

fined by,

1cjam

T

--12at

m. Zasvb

asvbjc

d w asvb

(12)

11.1.111

Page 14: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

12.

Observing that

at. t.JC - _ 16 6 _ aas s [6 * (e /A ' )6bcvj bc vb vj 1 j. (82/A.dll, (13)

we deduce that

atwd 0 ,

E L - [6 62(T

.b/A .b ))}(14)

d w asvb

svb

{t

a 1

Integrating (13) and (14) into (12) gives,

am. _ 1

62

asvb

T sp

vb 6 vj 6 bc tjc av v3 A

v.b [6 • 6b A ]t•c b 3c

- m. [t - a (81 A

+ 8 2 T'/))1

'jc vb vbV.

2 A=b)]}

By multiplying both sides by (sjc/mvb)

and rearranging ternis appropriately,

we ultimately get a general formula for the direct as well as cross-elasti-

cities implied by model (11) i.e

-n (mje svb) = 13[(6vj 6bc mvb) 8 1 /1blv. (6vj Nv.)-6211vi.b(6bc M .b )] ' (15)

where : pblv. = avb

/Av.

and pvi.b

= avb

/Ab'

represent the relative

attraction of brand b's item v within the v-th variety type, and

the relative attraction cf that same item within brand b's line

M .b = E mwb = T /T and Mv. = mvd = T /T , are brand b'sw d

aggregate sales share, and variety v's global sales share, respec-

tively.

vb vb

Page 15: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

13.

The various cases implied by (15) are reviewed in figure 2. Direct

elasticities are displayed in the top part (i.e.(:)) of the tree-structure

((sbc-'v; = 1).

Insert figure 2 about here

Cross-elasticities measuring intra-brand cannibalism appear on

the second set of branches ; while the intra-variety cannibalism is il-

lustrated by the third group. Subset (2) corresponds to cannibalism between

items of various types (6j = 0), offered by distinct brands

(6 bc = 0).

Setting both asymmetry parameters equal to zero (6 1 = e 2 = 0),

one of course recovers the direct and cross-elasticities that the simple

attraction model (4) generates, i.e.

n(mvb' svb ) = 5(1 - mvb) ; n(mjc' svb ) = - 5 mvb •

Naturally, the intensity of cannibalism varies with the 8's. This

is best demonstrated when comparing intra-cluster (i.e., intra-brand or

intra-variety) cross-elasticities to the across-cluster ones. For example,

if brand loyalty dominates preference for specific variety types so

strongly that it constitutes the only source of asymmetry, 8 1 = 0 and

82 = 8 # 0, and figure 2 indicates that,

1n(m. , s )1jb vb 1n(m. , s )1jc vb

(1 - M b )1 + 8[ ]

Mb= Pb1 - 6

Page 16: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

14.

Since 0 < 8 < 1, then : pbc[1, +.0 [ and therefore,

i n (mi b , svb)I I n (mi c , svb)I

which means that cannibalism between items of the same brand exceeds can-

nibalism between brands.

Moreover,

lim [n(m. , s )] = 0 ,jc vb

8->1

and

lim [n(m. s )] g[mvb/m.b] mvl.b',2„1. j b vb

Thus extreme asymmetry in cannibalism relationships leads to complete inde-

pendence between items offered by different brands ; substitution occurs

only within brands (also refer to our comment on (9)). From a pragmatic

market research point of view it should be realized that such an extreme

situation (0 = 1) disqualifies the application to the whole product

category of the attraction model (whether in its symmetric or asymmetric

form). If 8 gets close to one, the latter should be split into distinct

sub-categories which should then be analyzed separately.

The situation in which consumers'preference for specific variety-

types takes precedence of their brand attachment up to a point that it

constitutes the only source of asymmetry (i.e., 9 1 = e and 0 2 = 0) can be

interpreted analogously.

Page 17: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

15.

5. SH.A.R.P. II

Extending SH.A.R.P. to take into account asymmetric substitution

effects of cannibalism within the product categories carried by a retailer

requires the substitution of the generalized cross-elasticities (15) in

optimization rule (1). Focusing on the only terms involving elasticities,

we note that according to (2) and (15),

r1,11) =9EEr. c [(6 .6 -m )- 8p (6 -M )-8u (dc j j vj bc vb 1 blv. vj v. 2-vi.b' bc M.b)]'

but since E r. = 1, this reduces toc j

nvb = e[(tvb - mvb)- 6 1 gblv. (Rv. - Mv. )- 8 2gvl.b(R b - M b)]

'(16)

where : Rv. = E r and R = S r. , denote variety-type v's (Rv.) andvc .b b.

brand b's (R .b) aggregate relative contribution to the profitabil-

ity of the product category.

Summing (16) over v and b,

b v v' b v

- 82 E(R

.b - M .b )E v l .b 'v

yet because b

b = E avb

/Av.

= Av /A

v = 1 and similarly E g .bv . = 1,. .

= B[1 - 1 - 9 1 E(Ry. - My. ) - 8 2 E(R b - M b )] = 0 .b

N =Es7.1 = g[ssrvb -zzin -e E(R -M )Z111b v vb 1 y v. v. b b v.

Page 18: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

16.

This result is not unexpected. The nil "balance" of the competitive inter-

actions derives from the consistency of the attraction model : what is

gained by an item cornes at the expense cf another within the same category.

Using (16) and keeping in mind that N = 0, we easily see that

rule (1) can be generalized to,

avb c:b mturvb nvb) e lPb lv. (Rv. mv.) m.b)], (17)

where c* = ' vb

cvb

id and g* g/a .vb

The various cases encompassed by (17) are enumerated in figure 3.

The space share allocated to a brand i s entire line, S .b , is determined by

adding the shares obtained by the items that make it up, i.e. Sb = E evb'

bLikewise, the portion of the gondola to be saved for a variety-type, Sv.,

is obtained by summing over brands that offer items of that same type, i.e.

Sv. = avb .

Insert figure 3 about here

The extent to which asymmetry alters the distribution of shelf

space can be evaluated by comparing the new formulas, II, with the original

one, I, at the aggregate brand (or variety type) level. Let us concentrate

on an example :

S b = Ce% 4. (1 - 6)6*(R b - M b )

(1 8)

Page 19: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

17.

Not too surprisingly, 8 makes the difference : it operates as a factor

damping down the primary effect of the item's visibility on the buyer's

choice (i.e., 0*). The larger the 8, the higher the relative importance

attached to handling cost considerations in dividing up the product catego-

ry's selling area. Intuitively, this can be justified by realizing that as

0 approaches unity, brands' sales shares tend to stabilize : because

substitution gets restricted within the limits of each brand i s line and

does no longer extend across brands. Therefore no discernible impact on the

brands' sales distribution is produced by reallocating space.

6. Empirical illustration :

Since its development in 1983, SH.A.R.P.I has been tested on four

different product assortments and in five large grocery stores. We use here

the data collected by Alen (1986) during the most recent of the experiments

designed by B & N, on which no result has yet been reported. It took place

over a 20-week period during the Spring of 1986, in the largest Belgian

hypermarket, the 16,440 sq. mt. CORA-DISTRIMAS, located in Rocourt (Liège,

54 check-out cash-registers) and owned by the medium-sized FRADIS chain

(ranked 7th among Belgian retailers). Highly decentralized as compared with

its retailing competitors, FRADIS operates 6 hypermarkets and 3 groups of

supermarket franchisees (Choc-Discount, Courthéoux and Match). Its annual

sales revenue amounts to BF 15 billion and its gross margin reaches 14 Z.

The experiment was run on the 20-item canned dog food assortment

carried by CORA-DISTRIMAS. The product category examined was selected for

its high turnover (or to be more precise its high sales-to-inventory ratio,

facilitating the rapid observation of the impact producad by changes in

merchandising), for the stability of its total sales volume, and last but

Page 20: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

18.

not least, because the buyers are not the consumers so that the purchasing

behavior is likely to be influenced significantly by the items' visibility.

It included 6 national brands and one private label, essentially offered in

large package sizes (basically in 0.8 and 1.2 kgs ; only two 0.4 kg-items

were listed). Weekly observations on sales volume, allocated shelf space

and promotions were gathered for all items. Three distinct space arrange-

ments were considered, hence three periods can be distinguished in the ana-

lysis.

Experimental changes were implemented over three consecutive

4-week periods. During the first period, it was striven for the

equi-repartition of the available shelf space ; only items on promotion

were allocated relatively more space. At the beginning of the second

period, the visibility of some high-margin national brands was increased at

the expense of the low-margin private label. On the contrary, in period 3

the allocation was reversed so as to favor low-priced items. Given that the

purpose was the validation of SH.A.R.P.I, possibilities of asymmetry were

ignored and the analysis was restricted to aggregate effects at the brand-

level (see Alen, 1986). No systematic variation along the package-size di-

mension was planned. In period 2, however, one such variation happened to

occur. Weekly observations were averaged out per period ; hence, we deal

with a combination of 2 pre-test-post-test cross-sections of 20 items

each period 2 vs. period 1 and period 3 vs. period 2.

Since the promotional activities under the control of the

manufacturers coud not be stopped, a promotion covariate has to be

introduced into the specification of the intrinsic attraction exerted by

Page 21: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

19.

(19)

each item, i.e.

0 YPvb,Tavb,T

= Svb,T

with v = 0.4, 0.8 or 1.2 kg (i.e., package sizes) ;

b = Bonzo, Chappi, Fido, Loyal, Pal, Pluto or Produits Francs (i.e.,

brands) ;

T = 1, 2, 3 or 4 (i.e., time periods) ;

and where the promotion variable, o ,

is determined by both the monetary-vbT'

value of the price-cut and the duration of the promotion.

Taking into account the specific nature of the product, we

hypothesize a priori that asymmetry in cannibalism results from the buyer's

preference for a specific package-size. For dog food (as opposed to cat

food) the size of the dog itself appears to be a key-determinant of the

buyer's choice. Note also that the major axes along which brands diversify

their lines are the package sizes for dogs, and food components (e.g., fish

vs. meat) for cats. Thus we assume 82 = 0 and 8

1 = O. Accordingly, the

attractiveness terms (7) are defined by

tvb,T

= avb,T

/A8V.,T , (20)

YPvb,T), ,

where A = E (seVT VbT

Let us observe that the variation of an item's sales share can be

studied under the ratio form,

Page 22: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

20.

mvb,T+1

/mvb,T

= (avb,T+1

/avb,T

)(AV.,T

/Av.,T+1 )8

(T ..,T

/T ..,T+1 ).

Transforming this ratio into logarithms yields the following equation,

= 13.[ln svb,T+1 - ln svb,T] + y.[pvb,T+1

pvb,TYvb,T

3

+ 8.[ln A - ln Av.,T+1 J + E dL.6L,T ;V.,T

L=I

where : v = ln mvb,T+1

- ln mvb,T, T = 1, 2, 3 ;-vb,T

di, stands for [ln T L - ln T L+1 ] ;

denotes a dummy variable equal to one if L = T, and to zeroL,T

otherwise (introduced to capture the variation over time of

the denominator of the attraction model).

In the absence of asymmetry (0 = 0), equation (21) is linear in

the parameters. Thus our linearization reveals similar to Nakanishi and

Cooper's (1982) structural transformation of the MCI model into a dummy

variable multiple regression equation. As 8 is the remaining cause of

non-linearity, we propose the following iterative estimation procedure.

Step # 0 : Assume 8 = 0 and estimate e and y by applying the OLS method

to the so-reduced form of equation (21). Then set h = 1.

Step # h : Use the estimates obtained for g and y in the previous step

(i.e., h-1) to determine the attraction of each item and the total

attraction exerted by items of the same package size (A .,T ). Thenv

re-estim.te g and y, together with 8, by applying OLS to the full form

of equation (21). Set h = h + 1 and return to step # h. Stop when

convergence occurs, i.e. when the difference observed between the new

(2 1)

Page 23: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

21.

set of estimates just obtained and the one derived at the previous

stage becomes negligible.

Insert table 1 about here

Simulation experiments run by Gijsbrechts and Vanden Abeele

(1988) prove that an equivalent iterative process converges quickly to

unbiased estimates.

Table 1 summarizes the results we obtained when applying this

stepwise method to our sample. Standard errors (in parentheses) and

t-ratios are reported below the OLS-estimates. Package-size asymmetry

shows up as significantly as the item visibility effect. The alternative

hypothesis, i.e. whether asymmetry could be caused by brand loyalty, was

also tested but as expected, it was rejected.

The estimates of y and 5 reveal remarkably stable. Furthermore,

given the transversal nature of our sample 4 , the goodness-of-fit measure

(R2) indicates that the model offers a fairly reliable description of the

cannibalism prevailing within the retailer's assortment.

7. Normative Implications

Introducing a couple of simplifying assumptions can greatly help

in the process of reconciling theory with practice. Those are indeed

necessary to relate allocation formula (17) to the rules-of-thumb commonly

employed by retailers to determine the shelf-arrangement. Referring to the

Page 24: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

22.

the replenishment cost function (3), let us regard it as a linear function

of the frequency of the handling operations. This amounts to setting

yvb

= 1. Then if we consider that the available space is equally

distributed among items (i.e.,= S/n = s),svb

Cvb

= fvb

(qvb

/s) '

and

c* = C /E EC =f m /E E f. m .vbvb.jcvbvb.jc jc

c c

But if we further recognize that product handling operations essentially

depend on the packaging of the goods and not so much on the brand concer-

ned, then fvb = fv and

c* = f m /E f. M. .vb v vb j j j.

In that case the relative cost of handling items of the v-th variety type

can be written,

C* = E c* = E f m IE f. M. = f M ,v. vb v v. (22)

where 4' stands for the weighted mean of the unit costs of replenishment.

Page 25: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

23.

Substituting (22) into the formula for the space to be

allocated to the v-th variety-type, defined by SII

in figure 3, we getv.

Sv. = (f MM + (1 - e) a* (R - M ), (23)

v v. v. v.

where g* = g/(E E c,k ) = g(sn/Q ).

b b

Now if we let w/ = (1 - 8) See and w2 = (fvive) - co l , the following

relationship is arrived at,

Sy.

= w1 Ry .

+ w2 V. (24)

Since (24) is derived from (17) on the basis of the equi-repartition of the

selling area, it constitutes a reasonable approximation to the optimal al-

location. As will be shown numerically hereafter, it will in fact provide

us with a solution close to the best one.

Thus (24) throws light on a rather simple and interesting inter-

pretation of the optimization result. It now appears as a linear combina-

tion of the two most regularly used rules-of-thumb : on one hand the allo-

cation strictly proportional to the relative contribution to the assortment

profitability (R.), and on the other hand the allocation determined inv

direct proportion to the relative sales volume (Mv. ). On examining the

coefficients, one realizes that w1 will most often lie in the [0,1]-range

and in cases where variations in the packaging of the goods are negligible

(i.e. when fv "e 9e ), they will add up to one so that (24) can almost be as-

similated with a weighted mean of the twc ratios.

Page 26: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

24.

The incidence of the degree of asymmetry is quite clear : the

higher it is, the heavier the relative weight attached to the sales share

ratio. This confirms the emerging pre-eminence of handling cost effects as

asymmetry becomes more pronounced.

Actual determination of the true optimum calls for sophisticated

techniques designed for solving complex systems of non-linear equations. To

circumvent a similar difficulty met with SH.A.R.P.I, B & N have suggested a

heuristic approach which, adapted to our problem, consists of exploring

system (17) iteratively, with the equi-repartition as the arbitrary initial

allocation : the allocation derived at one stage is fed back into the

formula to determine the next (hopefully better) allocation. However

rudimentary such a heuristic might seem, it was proved to converge rapidly

towards excellent solutions.

When extended and applied in our case, it performs reasonably

well. Table 2 introduces an hypothetical, yet fairly realistic, example of

a 12-item assortment, with 4 brands each presented in 3 different variety-

types. The values chosen for the key-parameters, g and 9, are those esti-

mated for CORA-DISTRIMAS.

Insert table 2 about here

la order to make the meaning of the results intuitively obvious,

the basic attraction coefficients (avb),

determining the item's sales shares

when their visibility is identical to each other's, have all been set equal

to 1.00. Only the unit gross margins are differentiated, and by quite a

Page 27: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

25.

substantiel amount, in fact. Although the cost figure used for all variety-

types may appear large when compared with profit, it represents slightly

more than 63 % of the net margin (in practice it might well exceed 70 %).

The optimal space allocations produced by three different vectors

[e,ê] of parameter estimates are compared in table 3. The top one (bold-

face) is generated by the unbiased estimates : te 0.38 ; 6 = 0.61] ; the

second and third allocations correspond to cases where the retailer ignores

the existence of asymmetries and either uses all the information available :

= 0.524 ; 8 = 0], or only a subsample : [A = 0.698 ; 8 = 0]. Starting by

focusing on the third allocation, one easily verifies that the most

profitable items get the largest space shares ; i.e., those offered by the

fourth brand (which gets 32.4 % against 23.1 % for brand 1) and of the

third variety-type (which gets 58.2 Z against 14.9 Z for type 1). A similar

pattern of space repartition is, of course, observed in both other cases

but as the visibility parameter (g) decreases and asymmetry takes place the

dispersion of the space distribution gets reduced (smoothing effect). Thus

the third variety-type obtains only 35.3 % of the available space when

asymmetry enters the picture, instead of the 45.8 Z it would be entitled to

if asymmetry could be disregarded.

Insert table 3 about here

Similarly to what B & N observed with SH.A.R.P. I the allocation

derived from the first iteration already defines a satisfactori solution :

it yields 70.4 % of the total profit incrément to be expected from the

optimization. Yet, from a pragmatic point of view the question must be

Page 28: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

26.

raised whether it pays for a retailer to care at all about asymmetry. This

issue is addressed in table 4 where we measure the opportunity loss

incurred by a "myopie" retailer - i.e., a retailer who completely neglects

the asymmetry.

Insert table 4 about here

The first row in this table gives the maximum profit that would be reached

when implementing the truly optimal allocation, i.e. based on the best,

unbiased estimated derived from the experiment. In contrast, other rows

show at which levels the retailer's profit would be limited5 should he

allocate the space available using the less reliable estimates. Thus if

asymmetry prevails as significantly as in the CORA-DISTRIMAS case, the

retailer's "myopism" could cost him between 3.5 % and 20 % of his net

profit. The relative importance of this opportunity loss can best be

evaluated by comparison to the negligible incidence of the sampling error,

reflected in the 0.07 % difference observed when only the first half cf the

data collected during the experiment is used.

8. Conclusion

Even though the experiment from which the data was drawn was not

designed specifically for this purpose, the detected impact of asymmetry

was not only statistically significant but it also affected the space

allocation to a non-negligible extent. Therefore we believe that additional

experiments, deliberately designed for capturing the effects of asymmetries,

are likely to substantiate our first conclusions.

Page 29: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

27.

As a direction for future research, let us suggest a thorough

examination of rules-of-thumb currently used by retailers for space

allocation purposes. To be sure, B & N (1988) have clearly established that

SH.A.R.P. I optimal allocation formula outperforms proportionality-to-sales

(or to profit-margins) norms at least, in cases where asymmetry can

safely be assumed away 1 But since we have just demonstrated here that

asymmetry smoothes (or dampens down) the allocation, one may Wonder whether

such simplistic tales might be rehabilitated in some instances.

Page 30: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

4:1

"I„

?çu; q AI m; ted tLl Itmorri( ,e)Ittorn(Z,e) eru rtd C

Figure la

SA LES D I SIR I EUT 1 1:11q.1it 2, 4:■ m got

--E]

0

D It*rn( 1,e)

Page 31: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

Figure lb

ES DI ST RIBUTION•4.rnmetry=4).7.5

0,9 -

47,03

0

4 n

t

F,

--

-1-1---Ii it4HTÎIT-1 r 1 4:>4>t)

5pq ç* .411;>Ç4AtIKI tst. Itiern(1,1e)t rn ( 1 ,0

Itu in( 2,e)

C

Page 32: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

Brands

o

Figure 2. Structure of Elasticities and Cross-elasticities

Variety types Source of asymmetry Elasticities/Cross -elasticities

General : 0, 0, 0 g[(1 - mvb) - 8 1 Pb

(1 - p (1 -.b )1

Brand : 01

='

2 =2 g (' - mvb)

8 vb1(1 m.b)/11

Variety : 0 1 = 0, 0 2 = - m - om 1 (1 - M. 11v. v.

General : 0, 0, 8 041vb - 0 1 pblv.v. + 82 pvi.b- M

.b)]

Brand : 01

= 0 02

= e 0 mvb

[1 + 8 {(1 - H .b)/M.b

1[

Variety : 0 1 = 9, 6 2 = vb[1 - 81

o

Page 33: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

Figure 2 (continued)

Brands Variety types Source of asymmetry Elasticities/Cross-elasticities

General. 6 8: 0,

Brand : 6 = 0 0 -,

Variety : 0 1 = 0, 8 2 = 0 f3 mvbEl 1- /3 1(1 Mv.)/Mv.1]

General : 6 0, 0Rlmvb - e t Vbly. Hv 2 b

---1Brand : 0 = 0 , 02 =

Variety : 0 1 = e, 8 2 - 0

- e I

P mvbEl - 61

Page 34: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

0.0341

(0.0046)

7.4549

0.0399

(0.0048)

8.2396

0.5240 0 0.6531

(0.1509)

3.4718

0.3799 0.6120 0.7023

(0.1512) (0.2321)

2.5123 2.6369

Table 1. Econometric Analysis of Experimental Results

Package-size asymmetry

Table la. Pooled 3-period sample (n=40)

Promotion Visibility Asymmetry R2

Y

8

Table lb. Period 2 versus period 1 (n = 20)

Promotion Visibility Asynunetry R2

Y

0.6981 0 0.6333

(0.2625)

2.6589

0.4814 0.8426 0.7231

(0.2467) (0.2988) b.)

1.9518 2.8199

0.0257

(0.0054)

4.7598

0.0345

(0.0058)

5.9857

Page 35: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

Table 2. Values Assigned to the Fixed Parameters

1. Assortment : 12 items, i.e. 4 brands x 3 variety types

Unit Cross Hargins

(g.b)

Assortment's width

Variety type (v) Brandis mean

1 2 3

Brand (b)

1)e

1

2

10

11

14

15

18

19

14

15Pth

3

4

12

13

16

17

20

21

16

17

Variety's mean

Grand-mean

(gv.)

(i )

11.5 15.5 19.5

15.5

2. Preference factors : avb

= 1.00, for all v's and b's

3. Replenishment costs : fv = 5,000, for all v's

4. Unbiased estimates of the visibility and asymmetry parameters : 0 = 0.38 and 0 = 0.61

Page 36: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

1.000Sv.

0.35280.45770.5824

0.33290.31640.2691

0.31430.22600.1485

Table 3. Comparison of Allocations

avb

Variety type (v)

1 2 3 .bBrand (b)

0.0727 0.0770 0.0816 0.23131

0.0501 0.0690 0.0987 0.2178

0.0307 0.0515 0.1040 0.1862

0.0765 0.0810 0.0858 0.24332

0.0540 0.0752 0.1085 0.2377

0.0344 0.0603 0.1274 0.2221

0.0804 0.0852 0.0903 0.25593

0.0585 0.0822 0.1193 0.2600

0.0389 0.0715 0.1570 0.2674

0.0847 0.0897 0.0951 0.26954

0.0634 0.0900 0.1312 0.2846

0.0445 0.0858 0.1940 0.3243

Page 37: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

Table 4. Sensitivity to Asymmetry and Estimation Bias

Assumed parameter estimates Profit/cost Opportunity loss

1.1. Unbiased estimates using the g 0.38 ; 8 = 0.61 190,471.0/120,469.5 None

full information available

1.2. Estimates derived from the 13 = 0.48 ; 8 = 0.84 190,343.1/120,603.8 0.067 Z

first two periods

2. Myopism in the full information 5 = 0.524 ; 8 = 0.00 184,152.2/129,465.7 3.431 Z

case

3. Myopism in the limited g = 0.698 ; 8 = 0.00 158,486.7/158,501.0 20.181 Z

information case

Page 38: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

36.

FOOTNOTES

1 As defined by B & N, II differs from the actual profit in that the mar-

ginal handling cost gets substituted for its average (per unit sold). Of

course, the items' sales volumes have to be measured in homogeneous "equi-

valent" units (taking into account differences in product forms and package

sizes) .

2 While for a manufacturer, cannibalism usually means substitution between

items within his own brand's line, for a retailer it covers also the

struggle between the competitive brands supplied by the various manufac-

turers with whom he is dealing.

3 To typify the various competitive market situations, see e.g., Triffin

(1940), Bishop (1952, 1955) and Hieser (1955). It should be noted,

however, that their conception of asymmetry differs from ours : while we

consider that it implies n(mib, svb ) # n(m ' svb ), vb)' they usually mean

that ri(mib , svb ) ri(mvb , svb ). Note that were we to adopt their idea,

the simple basic attraction model (i.e. 8 1 = 8 2 = 0) would have to be

regarded as an asymmetric specification.

4 Usually high R2 are obtained in time series analyses and lower ones for

cross-sections. It should further be realized that we voluntarily opted

for a transformation which should clear out the estimates of the spurious

correlation that across-item differences (within a given period) might

produce : (2.1) really catches hold of the causal relationship between

over-time action changes and sales response.

Ail profit levels are calculated under the assumption that 5 = 0.38 and

= 0.61 are the true parameter values.

Page 39: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

37.

REFERENCES

Alen, Véronique (1986), "Expérimentation en hypermarché visant à apprécier

l'incidence de la visibilité d'articles sur leurs ventes", Unpublished MBA

thesis, Faculté Universitaire Catholique de Mons (Belgium, June).

Bishop, Robert (1952), "Elasticities, Cross-Elasticities, and Market

Relationships" , American Economic Review, 42 (December), 779-803.

Bishop, Robert (1955), "Reply", American Economic Review, 45 (June), 382-6.

Bultez, Alain and Philippe Naert (1988), "SH.A.R.P. : Shelf Allocation for

Retailers' Profit", Marketing Science, 7 (Summer), forthcoming.

Carpenter, Gregory S., Lee G. Cooper, Dominique M. Hanssens and David F.

Midgley (1987), "AsymmeLric Market-Share Models", Center for Marketing

Studies, Anderson School of Management (UCLA), working paper 137 (June).

Corstjens, Marcel and Peter Doyle (1981), "A Model for Optimizing Retail

Space Allocations", Management Science, 27 (July), 822-33.

Doyle, Peter and John Saunders (1987), "Multiproduct Advertising

Budgeting", Loughborough University of Technology, Department of Management

Studies, working paper No. 156 (August).

Gijsbrechts, Els and Piet Vanden Abeele (1988), "A General Class of

Asymmetric Market Share Models : Specification and Estimation Issues",

Catholic University of Leuven, working paper 8804 (March).

Page 40: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

38.

Hieser, R. (1955), "Elasticities, Cross-Elasticities, and Market Relation-

ships : Comment", American Economic Review, 45 (June), 373-382.

McGoldrick, Peter. (1986), "A Multi-dimensional Framework for Retail

Pricing" in Miller, K. and M. Paltschik (eds-.), Contemporary Research in

Marketing, Proceedings of the XVth Annuel Conference of the European

Marketing Academy (Helsinki, June 3-6), 1229-48.

Nakanishi, Masao and Lee G. Cooper (1982), "Simplified Estimation

Procedures for MCI Models", Marketing Science 1 (Summer), 314-22.

Reibstein, David and Hubert Gatignon (1984), "Optimal Product Line

Pricing : Influence of Elasticities and Cross-Elasticities", Journal of

Marketing Research, 21 (August), 259-67.

Triffin, Robert (1941), Monopolistic Competition and General Equilibriam

Theory , Harvard University Press (Cambridge, Mass.).

Vanden Abeele P., E. Gijsbrechts and M. Vanhuele (1987), "Specification and

Empirical Evaluation of a Simple Asymmetric Market-Share Model", European

Institute for Advanced Studies in Management (Bruxelles), working paper

87-13 (October).

Wilkinson J.B., C.H. Paksoy and J.B. Mason (1981), "A Demand Analysis of

Newspaper Advertising and Changes in Space Allocation", Journal of Retailing,

57 (Summer), 30-48.

Wilkinson J.B., J.B. Mason and C.H. Paksoy (1982), "Assessing the Impact of

Short-Term Supermarket Strategy Variables", Journal of Marketing Research,

19 (February), 72-86.

Page 41: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

1986

86/01 Arnoud DE MEYER

INSEAD VORKING PAPERS SÉRIES

"The R & D/Production interface".

06/16 9 Emplen MCKSO andHerwig M. LANCOHR

86/17 David B. JEMISON

86/18 James TEBOULand V. MALLERET

"Les prises des offres putelAnutsm, la noced'information et le marché des transferts decontrôle des sociétés".

"Strategic capability transfer in acquisitionintegration", May 1986.

"Tovards an operational définition ofservices", 1986.

"Subjective estimation in integratingcommunication budget and allocationdecisions: a case study", January 1986.

"Sponsorship and the diffusion oforganizational innovation: a preliminary viev".

"Confidence intervals: an eupiricalinvestigation for the seri« in the If-Competition" .

"A note on the reduction of the vorkveek",July 1985.

"The real exchange rate and the fiscalaspects of s naturel resource discovery",Revised version: February 1986.

"Judgmental blases in sales forecasting",February 1986.

"Forecasting political risks forinternational operations", Second Draft:March 3, 1986.

"Conceptualizing the strategic process indiversified tiras: the role and nature of thecorporate influence process", February 1986.

86/19 Rob R. VEITZ

86/20 Albert CORHAY,Gabriel HAVAVINIand Pierre A. MICHEL

86/21 Albert CORBAY,Gabriel A. HAVAVINIand Pierre A. MICHEL

86/22 Albert CORHAY,Gabriel A. HAVAVINIand Pierre A. MICHEL

86/23 Arnoud DE MEYER

86/24 David GAUTSCHIand Vithala R. RA0

86/25 H. Peter GRAYand Ingo VALTER

86/26 Barry EICHENGREENand Charles VYPLOSZ

"Nostradamus: a knovledge-based forecastingadvisor".

"The pricing of equity on the London stockexchange: seasonality and size premium",June 1986.

"Risk-premia seasonality in U.S. and Europeanequity markets", February 1986.

"Seasonality in the risk-return relationshipssome international evidence", July 1986.

"An exploratory study on the integration ofinformation systems in manufacturing",July 1986.

"A methodology for specifleation andaggregation in product concept testing",July 1986.

"Protection", August 1986.

"The economic consequences of the FrancPoincare", September 1986.

86/02 Philippe A. NAERTMarcel WEVERBERGHand Guido VERSVIJVEL

86/03 Michael BRIMM

86/04 Spyros MAKRIDAKISand Michèle HIBON

86/05 Charles A. VYPLOSZ

86/06 Francesco GIAVAllI,Jeff R. SHEEN andCharles A. VYPLOSZ

86/07 Douglas L. MacLACHLANand Spyros MAKRIDAKIS

86/08 José de la TORRE andDavid H. NECKAR

86/09 Philippe C. HASPESLAGH

86/10 R. MOENART,Arnoud DE MEYER,J. BARBE andD. DESCHOOLMEESTER.

86/11 Philippe A. NAERTand Alain BULTEZ

86/12 Roger BETANCOURTand David GAUTSCHI

86/13 S.P. ANDERSONand Damien J. NEVEN

86/14 Charles VALDMAN

86/15 Mihkel TOMBAK andArnoud DE MEYER

"Analysing the issues concerningtechnological de-maturity".

"From "Lydiametry" to "Pinkhamization":aisspecifying advertising dynamics rarelyaffects profitability".

"The economics of retail firme, RevisedApril 1986.

"Spatial competition à la Cournot".

"Comparaison internationale des marges brutesdu commerce", June 1985.

"Hm the managerial attitudes of firme vithFMS differ from other manufacturing

86/31 Arnoud DE MEYER,Jinichiro NAKANE,Jeffrey G. MILLERand Kasra FERDOVS

86/32 Karel COOLand Dan SCHENDEL

"Plexibility: the next competitive battle",Revised Version: March 1987

Performance differences among strategic groupmembers", October 1986.

86/27 Karel COOL

"Negative risk-return relationships inand Ingemar DIERICKX business strategy: paradox or truism?",

October 1986.

86/28 Manfred KETS DE

"Interpreting organizational tests.VRIES and Danny MILLER

86/29 Manfred KETS DE VRIES "Vhy follov the leader?".

86/30 Manfred RETS DE VRIES "The succession gamet the real atory.

86/31 Arnoud DE MEYER

"Flexibility: the next competitive battle",October 1986.

Page 42: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

1987

87/01 Manfred KETS DE VRIES "Prisoners of leadership".

87/02 Claude VIALLET

87/03 David GAUTSCHIand Vithala RAO

87/04 Sumantra GHOSHAL andChristopher BARTLETT

"An empirical investigation of internationalasset pricing", November 1986.

"A methodology for specification andaggregation in product concept testing",Revised Version: January 1987.

"Organizing for innovations: case of themultinational corporation", February 1987.

87/05 Arnoud DE MEYER .Mensgerial focal points in msnufacturing. 1-1A raanova P.brumr, 1O07_

86/33 Ernst BALTENSPERGERand Jean DERMINE

"The role of public polley in insuringfinancial stability: e cross-country,comparative perspective", August 1986, RevisedNovember 1986.

87/06 Arun K. JAIN, "Customer loyalty as a construct in theChristian PINSON and marketing of banking services", July 1986.Naresh K. MALHOTRA

86/34 Philippe HASPESLAGHand David JEMISON

86/35 Jean DERMINE

86/36 Albert CORRAY andGabriel HAVAVINI

86/37 David GAUTSCHI andRoger BETANCOURT

86/38 Gabriel HAVAVINI

86/39 Gabriel HAVAVINIPierre MICHELand Albert CORHAY

86/40 Charles WYPLOSZ

86/41 Kasra FERDOVSand Vickham SKINNER

86/42 Kasra FERDOVSand Per LINDBERG

86/43 Damien NEVEN

86/44 Ingemar DIERICKXCarmen MATUTESand Damien NEVEN

"Acquisitions: myths and reality",July 1986.

"Measuring the market value of a bank, aprimer", November 1986.

"Seasonality in the risk-return relationship:some international evidence", July 1986.

"The evolution of retailing: a suggestedeconoaic interpretation".

"Financial innovation and recent developmentsin the French capital markets", Updated:September 1986.

"The pricing of common stocks on the Brusselsstock exchange: e re-examination of theevidence", November 1986.

"Capital flova liberalization and the EMS, eFrench perspective", December 1986.

"Manufacturing in a nev perspective",July 1986.

"PMS es indicator of manufacturing strategy",December 1986.

"On the existence of equilibrium in hotelling'smodel", November 1986.

"Value added tax and competition",December 1986.

87/07 Rolf BANZ andGabriel HAVAVINI

87/08 Manfred KETS DE VRIES

87/09 Lister VICKERY,Mark PILKINGTONand Paul READ

87/10 André LAURENT

87/11 Robert FILDES andSpyros MAKRIDAKIS

87/12 Fernando BARTOLOMEand André LAURENT

87/13 Sumantra GHOSHALand Nitin NOHRIA

87/14 Landis GABEL

87/15 Spyros MAKRIDAKIS

87/16 Susan SCHNEIDERand Roger DUNBAR

87/17 André LAURENT andFernando BARTOLOME

87/18 Reinhard ANGELMAR andChristoph LIEBSCHER

87/19 David BEGG andCharles WYPLOSZ

87/20 Spyros MAKRIDAKIS

87/21 Susan SCHNEIDER

87/22 Susan SCHNEIDER

87/23 Roger BETANCOURTDavid GAUTSCHI

"Equity pricing and stock market anomalies",February 1987.

"Leaders vho can't manage", February 1987.

"Entrepreneurial activities of European KBAs",March 1987.

"A cultural viev of organizational change",March 1987

"Forecasting and loss functions", Match 1987.

"The Janus Head: learning from the superiorand subordinate faces of the manager's job",April 1987.

"Multinational corporations as differentiatednetvorks", April 1987.

"Product Standards and Competitive Strategy: AnAnalysis of the Princlples", May 1987.

"METAPORECASTINC: Vays of improvingForecasting. Accuracy and Usefulness",May 1987.

"Takeover attempts: vhat does the language tellus?, June 1987.

"Managers' cognitive reps for upvard anddovnvard relationships", June 1987.

"Patents and the European biotechnology lag: astudy of large European pharmaceuticalJune 1987.

"Vhy the EMS? Dynamic games and the equilibriumpolicy regime, May 1987.

"A nev approach to statistical forecasting",June 1987.

"Strategy formulation: the impact of nationalculture", Revised: July 1987.

"Conflicting ideologies: structural andmotivational conséquences", August 1987.

"The demand for retail products and thehousehold production model: nev vievs oncomplamustaritv and substitutability".

Page 43: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

87/41 Gavriel HAVAVINI and 'Seasonality, size premium and the relationshipClaude VIALLET betveen the risk and the return of French

common stocks", November 1987

87/24 C.B. DERR andAndré LAURENT

87/25 A. K. JAIN,N. K. MALHOTRA andChristian PINSON

87/26 Roger BETANCOURTand David GAUTSCHI

87/27 Michael BURDA

87/28 Gabriel HAVAWINI

87/29 Susan SCHNEIDER andPaul SHRIVASTAVA

87/30 Jonathan HAMILTONW. Bentley MACLEODand J. F. TRISSE

87/31 Martine QUINZII andJ. F. THISSE

87/32 Arnoud DE MEYER

87/33 Yves DOZ andAmy SHUEN

87/34 Kasra FERDOWS andArnoud DE MEYER

87/35 P. J. LEDERER andJ. F. TRISSE

87/36 Manfred KETS DE VRIES

87/37 Landis GABEL

87/38 Susan SCHNEIDER

87/39 Manfred KETS DE VRIES1987

87/40 Carmen MATUTES andPierre REGIBEAU

"The internai and external careers: atheoretical and cross-cultural perspective",Spring 1987.

"The robustness of MDS configurations in theface of incomplete data", March 1987, Revised:July 1987.

"Demand complementarities, household productionand retail assortments", July 1987.

"Is there a capital shortage in Europe?",August 1987.

"Controlling the interest-rate risk of bonds:an introduction to duration analysis andimmunizetion strategies", September 1987.

"Interpreting strategic behavior: basicassuaptions themes in organizations", September1987

"Spatial competition and the Core", August1987.

"On the optimality of central places",September 1987.

"German, French and British manufacturingstrategies less different than one thinks",September 1987.

"A process framevork for analyzing cooperationbetveen firme, September 1987.

"European manufacturers: the dangers ofcomplacency. Insights from the 1987 Europeanmanufacturing futures survey, October 1987.

"Competitive location on netvorks underdiscriminatory pricing", September 1987.

"Prisoners of leadership", Revised versionOctober 1987.

"Privatization: its motives and likelyconsequences", October 1987.

"Strategy formulation: the impact of nationalculture", October 1987.

"The dark side of GEO succession", November

"Product compatibility and the scope of entry",November 1987

87/42 Damien NEVEN andJacques-F. THISSE

87/43 Jean GABSZEVICZ andJacques-F. THISSE

87/44 Jonathan HAMILTON,Jacques-F. THISSEand Anita VESKAMP

87/45 Karel COOL,David JEMISON andIngemar DIERICKX

87/46 Ingemar DIERICKXand Karel COOL

1988

88/01 Michael LAVRENCE andSpyros MAKRIDAKIS

88/02 Spyros MAKRIDAKIS

88/03 James TEBOUL

88/04 Susan SCHNEIDER

88/05 Charles WYPLOSZ

88/06 Reinhard ANGELMAR

88/07 Ingemar DIERICKXand Karel COOL

88/08 Reinhard ANGELMARand Susan SCHNEIDER

88/09 Bernard SINCLAIR-DESGAGNé

88/10 Bernard SINCLAIR-DESGAGNé

88/11 Bernard SINCLAIR-DESGAGNé

"Combining horizontal and verticaldifferentiation: the principle of max-mindifferentiation", December 1987

"Location", December 1987

"Spatial discrimination: Bertrand vs. Cournotin a Bodel of location choice", December 1987

"Business strategy, market structure and risk-return relationships: a causal interpretation",December 1987.

"Asset stock accumulation and sustainabilityof competitive advantage", December 1987.

"Factors affecting judgemental forecasts andconfidence intervals", January 1988.

"Predicting recessions and other turningpoints", January 1988.

"De-industrialize service for quality", January1988.

"National vs. corporate culture: implicationsfor humas resource management", January 1988.

"The svinging dollar: is Europe out of step?",January 1988.

"Les conflits dans les canaux de distribution",January 1988.

"Competitive advantage: a resource basedperspective", January 1988.

"Issues in the study of organizationalcognition", February 1988.

"Price formation and product design throughbidding", February 1988.

"The robustness of some standard auction gaineforms", February 1988.

"Vhen stationary strategies are equilibriumbidding strategy: The single-crossingproperty", February 1988.

Page 44: ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS · ASYMMETRIC CANNIBALISM BETWEEN SUBSTITUTE ITEMS LISTED BY RETAILERS Alain Bultez, Els Gijsbrechts, Philippe Naert and Piet Vanden

88/12 Spyros MAKRIDAKIS

"Business firas and managers in the 21stcentury", February 1988

88/13 Manfred KETS DE VRIES "Alexithymia in organizational life: theorganization man revisited", February 1988.

88/14 Alain NOEL "The interpretation of strategies: a study ofthe impact of CROs on the corporation",March 1988.

88/29 Naresh K. MALHOTRA,Christian PINSON andArun K. JAIN

88/30 Catherine C. ECKELand Theo VERMAELEN

88/31 Sumantra GHOSHAL andChristopher BARTLETT

"Consumer cognitive complexity and thedimensionality of multidiaensional scalingconfigurations", May 1988.

"The financial fallout from Chernobyl: riskperceptions and regulatory response", May 1988.

"Creation, adoption, and diffusion ofinnovations by subsidiaries of multinationalcorporations", June 1988.

88/15 Anil DEOLALIKAR andLars-Hendrik ROLLER

88/16 Gabriel HAVAWINI

88/17 Michael BURDA

88/18 Michael BURDA

88/19 M.J. LAVRENCE andSpyros MAKRIDAKIS

88/20 Jean DERNINE,Damien NEVEN andJ.F. THISSE

88/21 James TEBOUL

88/22 Lars-Hendrik RÔLLER

88/23 Sjur Didrik FLAPIand Georges ZACCOUR

88/24 B. Espen ECKBO andHerwig LANGOHR

88/25 Everette S. GARDNERand Spyros MAKRIDAKIS

88/26 Sjur Didrik FLANand Georges ZACCOUR

88/27 Murugappa KRISHNANLars-Hendrik RÔLLER

88/28 Sumantra GHOSHAL andC. A. BARTLETT

"The production of and returns from industrialinnovation: an econometric analysis for adeveloping country", December 1987.

"Market efficiency and equity pricing:international evidence and implications forglobal investing", March 1988.

"Monopolistic competition, costs of adjustmentand the behavior of European employment",September 1987.

"Reflections on "Vait Unemployment" inEurope", November 1987, revised February 1988.

"Individual bias in judgements of confidence",March 1988.

"Portfolio selection by mutual funds, anequilibriva model", Match 1988.

"De-industrialize service for quality",March 1988 (88/03 Revised).

"Proper Ouadratic Functions vith an Applicationto AT&T", May 1987 (Revised Match 1988).

"Équilibres de Nash-Cournot dans le marchéeuropéen du gaz: un cas où les solutions enboucle ouverte et en feedback colncident",Mars 1988

"Information disclosure, means of payment, andtakeover premia. Public and Private tenderoffers in France", July 1985, Sixth revision,April 1988.

"The future of forecasting", April 1988.

"Serai-competitive Cournot equilibrium inmultistage oligopolies", April 1988.

"Entry gaine vith resalable capacity",April 1988.

"The multinational corporation as a network:perspectives from interorganizational theory",

1988.

88/32 Kasra FERDOWS andDavid SACKRIDER

88/33 Mihkel M. TOMBAK

88/34 Mihkel M. TOMBAK

88/35 Mihkel M. TOMBAK

88/36 Vikas TIBREWALA andBruce BUCHANAN

88/37 Murugappa KRISHNANLars-Hendrik RÔLLER

88/38 Manfred KETS DE VRIES

88/39 Manfred KETS DE VRIES

88/40 Josef LAKONISHOK andTheo VERMAELEN

88/41 Charles WYPLOSZ

88/42 Paul EVANS

88/43 B. SINCLAIR-DESCACNE

88/44 Essam MAHMOUD andSpyros MAKRIDAKIS

88/45 Robert KORAJCZYKand Claude VIALLET

88/46 Yves DOZ andAmy SHUEN

"International manufacturing: positioningplants for success", June 1988.

"The importance of flexibility inmanufacturing", June 1988.

"Flexibility: an important dimension inmanufacturing", June 1988.

"A strategic analysis of investment in flexiblemanufacturing systems", July 1988.

"A Predictive Test of the NBD Model thatControls for Non-stationarity", June 1988.

"Regulating Price-Liability Competition ToImprove Velfare", July 1988.

"The Motivating Role of Envy : A ForgottenFactor in Management, April 88.

"The Leader as Mirror : Clinical Reflections",July 1988.

"Anomalous price behavior around repurchasetender offers", August 1988.

"Assyaetry in the Mi intentional orsystemic?", August 1988.

"Organizational development in thetransnational enterprise", June 1988.

"Group decision support systems implementBayesian rationality", September 1988.

"The state of the art and future directionsin combining forecasts", September 1988.

"An empirical investigation of internationalasset pricing", November 1986, revised August1988.

"From intent to outcome: a process framevorkfor partnerships", August 1988.


Recommended