+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8....

Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8....

Date post: 02-Jan-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
16
The Economics of Contemporary American Jewish Family Life Carmel Ullman Chiswick (UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS AT CHICAGO) The Jewish community in the United States has experienced a remarkable economic transformation during the twentieth century, from a community of impoverished im- migrants to one of suburban professionals. 1 This transformation may be thought of as following two overlapping phases. In the first half of the century, most American Jews were either immigrants or the children of immigrants, born in poverty or near- poverty. Jewish men during this period focused on upward occupational mobility, ac- quiring high levels of secular education and moving into middle- and high-level oc- cupations with correspondingly high wage rates. During the later decades of the century, the community's new socioeconomic position would be consolidated as sec- ond- and third-generation suburban Jews, both men and women, attained even higher levels of education and the community shifted from business to professional occupa- tions. While the typical Jewish male at the beginning of the century may have been a tailor or a peddler, by mid-century he was a businessman, doctor, accountant, phar- macist or lawyer and by its end he would have been a professional (often salaried) in anyone of a variety of fields. Although lagging behind the experience of Jewish men by some decades, the typ- ical adult Jewish woman by 1990 was also a well-educated labor force participant, usually with some post-college training. In contrast to her mother or grandmother, she was less likely to be an unpaid worker in a family business (as her husband was less likely to have his own business) and more likely to be managing her own firm or de- veloping a career as a salaried employee. Labor force participation rates of married Jewish women were high: in 1990, about 75 percent of those with no children at home were working, as were 75 percent of the married women with school-age children and about half of those with very young (preschool) children. 2 This article considers some of the most important implications for the American Jewish family of these changes in its economic context. Nearly a century after the pe- riod of mass immigration, most American Jews are at least one or two generations re- moved from their immigrant forebears. They live and work among non-Jews in a sec- ular world where they expect to be respected for their personal qualities and technical expertise without regard to their Jewishness. Earnings from their professional occu- 6S
Transcript
Page 1: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Stephen J. Whitfield

~ The Suburbanization of the United States e For American Jews," 4; Edward S. Shapiro, ~ War II (Baltimore: 1992), 143-145; Kassel,

iI Concept," Newsweek 116 (8 Oct. 1990), 67. ~," Time 146 (28 Aug. 1995),53. ~n, Diner, xxi. on (ed.), Levinson on Levinson, 102.

~lp Out Broadway?" New York Times, 24 Sept.

:w York: 1939), 606. ununiry,144,213,242. 3, and in Ward, "Barry in Baltimore," 64.

The Economics of Contemporary American Jewish Family Life

Carmel Ullman Chiswick (UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS AT CHICAGO)

The Jewish community in the United States has experienced a remarkable economic transformation during the twentieth century, from a community of impoverished im­migrants to one of suburban professionals. 1 This transformation may be thought of as following two overlapping phases. In the first half of the century, most American Jews were either immigrants or the children of immigrants, born in poverty or near­poverty. Jewish men during this period focused on upward occupational mobility, ac­quiring high levels of secular education and moving into middle- and high-level oc­cupations with correspondingly high wage rates. During the later decades of the century, the community's new socioeconomic position would be consolidated as sec­ond- and third-generation suburban Jews, both men and women, attained even higher levels of education and the community shifted from business to professional occupa­tions. While the typical Jewish male at the beginning of the century may have been a tailor or a peddler, by mid-century he was a businessman, doctor, accountant, phar­macist or lawyer and by its end he would have been a professional (often salaried) in anyone of a variety of fields.

Although lagging behind the experience of Jewish men by some decades, the typ­ical adult Jewish woman by 1990 was also a well-educated labor force participant, usually with some post-college training. In contrast to her mother or grandmother, she was less likely to be an unpaid worker in a family business (as her husband was less likely to have his own business) and more likely to be managing her own firm or de­veloping a career as a salaried employee. Labor force participation rates of married Jewish women were high: in 1990, about 75 percent of those with no children at home were working, as were 75 percent of the married women with school-age children and about half of those with very young (preschool) children.2

This article considers some of the most important implications for the American Jewish family of these changes in its economic context. Nearly a century after the pe­riod of mass immigration, most American Jews are at least one or two generations re­moved from their immigrant forebears. They live and work among non-Jews in a sec­ular world where they expect to be respected for their personal qualities and technical expertise without regard to their Jewishness. Earnings from their professional occu­

6S

Page 2: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

I

66 Cannel Ullman Chiswick

pations place American Jews, and by extension the American Jewish community, comfortably in the upper middle class. The implications of this environment for American Jews' consumption patterns, including investments related to family life in general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows an analysis of the effect of economic incentives on marriage, fertility and parenting, along with the consequences for American Jewish demographic patterns. The final section presents a brief summary of findings and some implications for the future of the American Jewish family.

Jewish Consumption Patterns

Family, including the entire configuration of interpersonal relationships and con­sumption patterns understood by that phrase, is an economic "good" in that it is both desirable to have and costly to obtain.3 Yet by its nature, family life is not available for purchase; the marketplace provides only goods and services that are then used by family members to create shared experiences and consumption activities constituting the family "good." Thus family life may be viewed as the "output" of a home-pro­duction process for which the "inputs" include the time and effort of family members as well as purchased goods and services.4

The home-production approach to family is well known among economists.s In brief, the home-produced family "good" may be thought of as having an underlying "technology" (that is, production method) for combining purchased inputs with one's own time and effort to yield the desired output.6 Moreover, the productivity of a given set of inputs is enhanced by "human capital," by which is meant the entire spectrum of skills and prior experiences brought to bear on the process. For example, if regu­lar dinners are used as a vehicle for building and sustaining the relationships that con­stitute the family good, their effectiveness is enhanced by a variety of skills associ­ated not just with cooking but also with the social relationships themselves.

Religion in general, and Judaism in particular, is another example of an economic good (that is, something both desirable and costly) that necessarily must be self-pro­duced rather than purchased.7 Like family life, religious experience is an "output" ob­tained by combining purchased "inputs" (goods and services) with own-labor "in­puts" (the consumer's time and effort). A particular religion may be viewed as providing a set of "technologies" for producing religious experience, a context for the human capital (experiences and skills) specific to that religion. Jewish technologies would include the rules for observance of kashruth, Shabbat and brit rnilah, each of which infuses with religious meaning an otherwise secular activity.

Where religious expression becomes intimately involved with the particulars of family life, as in the observance of holidays or life-cycle events, they may be viewed as jointly produced by a single set of activities. This underlying approach provides a framework for the present analysis of American Jewish families, where the discus­sion focuses first on the time and money costs of this home-production process and then on productivity issues associated with human capital accumulation and changes in technology.

The Economics of Contemporary Ameri~an. Cost~

The cost of family life includes not onl services, but also the value of time devl budget their time among many different: opportunities; that is, the "opportunity c had been allocated instead to its next be spent on producing the family "good" (( tunity cost, the consumer would be bett more time on its best alternative use. Sim more than its opportunity cost, the consUl ily good. The most efficient allocation 0

realized by reallocating time from lower An important implication is that a com

among all available activities will find value of the least productive hour) is m value of marginal time may therefore be lected activity. For an adult labor force 1 with an additional hour of work (conven convenient first approximation of the v~

any other leisure activity. Although the wage rate is a good firsl

value of time for people making large ir For example, if students and new immig order to gain skills and experience, this d are part of the full "payment" for their' housewife is not her actual wage rate (Vi tivities as home-producer of services witl sons have access to market opportunitie~

an appropriate benchmark against whicl: With this important caveat, the value

tivities varies across individuals accordil rates. If these wage rates differ marked] sion of labor in home production can ell lization. Indeed, the within-family divisi age differences in the opportunity cost 0

ular consumption patterns. The gains ftc any special competence in an absolute Sf

family members with respect to each oth acteristics; productivity differences can who agree to specialize in different activi skills. 8 Thus, the family-based roles assi vary across time and space with econom

Although available data are not adeql. American Jews, shifts in the occupationa

Page 3: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

lsion the American Jewish community, -e implications of this environment for ding investments related to family life in will first be discussed. Then follows an

-es on marriage, fertility and parenting, Jewish demographic patterns. The final ; and some implications for the future of

ltion Patterns

of interpersonal relationships and con­:, is an economic "good" in that it is both hy its nature, family life is not available goods and services that are then used by

,; and consumption activities constituting , viewed as the "output" of a home-pro­je the time and effort offamily members

/ is well known among economists.5 In _y be thought of as having an underlying r combining purchased inputs with one's Jt.6 Moreover, the productivity of a given ." by which is meant the entire spectrum ~ar on the process. For example, if regu­and sustaining the relationships that con­

_s enhanced by a variety of skills associ­social relationships themselves.

:ular, is another example of an economic costly) that necessarily must be self-pro­le, religious experience is an "output" ob­soods and services) with own-labor "in­'\. particular religion may be viewed as :ing religious experience, a context for the :ific to that religion. Jewish technologies LllShruth, Shabbat and brit milah, each of berwise secular activity. jmately involved with the particulars of . or life-cycle events, they may be viewed jes. This underlying approach provides a ~rican Jewish families, where the discus­)sts of this home-production process and buman capital accumulation and changes

The Economics ofContemporary American Jewish Family Life

Cost ofFamily Life

The cost of family life includes not only the money spent on purchased goods and services, but also the value of time devoted to their consumption. Since consumers budget their time among many different activities, time is valued in terms of foregone opportunities; that is, the "opportunity cost" of time for one activity is its value if it had been allocated instead to its next best use. Whenever the value of an extra hour spent on producing the family "good" (or any other activity) is lower than its oppor­tunity cost, the consumer would be better off by rearranging his schedule to spend more time on its best alternative use. Similarly, if an extra hour of family time is worth more than its opportunity cost, the consumer gains by spending more time on the fam­ily good. The most efficient allocation of time is where all possible gains have been realized by reallocating time from lower- to higher-valued uses.

An important implication is that a consumer who budgets his or her time efficiently among all available activities will find that the marginal value of time (that is, the value of the least productive hour) is more or less the same for every activity. The value of marginal time may therefore be measured as its value in any arbitrarily se­lected activity. For an adult labor force participant, the earnings potential associated with an additional hour of work (conventionally measured as the wage rate) makes a convenient first approximation of the value of time spent in home-production or in any other leisure activity.

Although the wage rate is a good first approximation, it generally understates the value of time for people making large investments in market-related human capital. For example, if students and new immigrants are willing to accept low-wage jobs in order to gain skills and experience, this does not reflect the high future wage rates that are part of the full "payment" for their work. Similarly, the full value of time for a housewife is not her actual wage rate (which is zero) but rather the value of her ac­tivities as home-producer of services within the family. Yet to the extent that such per­sons have access to market opportunities, the wage rate that they could be earning is an appropriate benchmark against which to measure the value of their time.

With this important caveat, the value of time in both market and non-market ac­tivities varies across individuals according to the characteristics affecting their wage rates. If these wage rates differ markedly by gender and age, a corresponding divi­sion of labor in home production can enhance the efficiency of family resource uti­lization. Indeed, the within-family division of labor is often sustained by gender and age differences in the opportunity cost of time as they affect the efficiency of partic­ular consumption patterns. The gains from such specialization need not derive from any special competence in an absolute sense, but only from the relative efficiency of family members with respect to each other. Nor need they be based on inherent char­acteristics; productivity differences can arise even among equally able individuals who agree to specialize in different activities and so acquire different experiences and skills.8 Thus, the family-based roles assigned to various gender and age groups may vary across time and space with economic circumstances.9

Although available data are not adequate to establish the changing wage rates of American Jews, shifts in the occupational distribution of Jewish men reveal the broad

67

Page 4: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

68 Carmel Ullman Chiswick

Table 1. Occupation Shifts over Time: Adult Jewish Men

Occupation group 1890 1900a 1910a c.1948 1957 1970 c.1980 1990

Professions 4.6 2.3 2.3 13.8 20.3 27.2 43.0 47.4 Managerial 2.8 8.2 3.4 44.9 35.1 26.5 26.4 16.7

Subtotal 7.4 10.5 5.7 58.7 55.4 53.7 69.4 64.1

Clerical 19.5 1.5 1.4 3.9 8.0 8.3 8.3 6.3 Sales 56.7 7.6 16.6 12.0 14.1 19.7 13.2 16.1

Subtotal 76.2 9.1 18.0 15.9 22.1 28.0 21.5 22.4

Craft 11.5 19.0 27.1 13.1 8.9 8.4 4.2 6.4 Otherb 5.0 61.5 48.9 12.4 13.4 9.9 4.9 7.1

Subtotal 16.5 80.5 76.0 25.5 22.3 18.3 9.1 13.5

Total 100.1 100.1 99.7 100.1 99.8 100.0 100.0 100.0

Source: B. Chiswick, "The Occupational Attainment of American Jewry, 1890 to 1990: A Preliminary Report"; reprinted by permission of the author.

aJews identified as foreign-born men of Russian origin.

hlncludes laborers.

patterns of their earning capabilities (see Table 1). Occupations classified as "labor­ers" are associated with the lowest wages, whereas the high-level "professions" and "managerial" occupations include those with the highest earnings. At the beginning of the twentieth century, when more than three fourths of all Jewish men were labor­ers and craftsmen, Jewish families were poor and their wage rates were among the lowest in the United States. By mid-century, only a small (and aging) fraction of all Jewish men were laborers, whereas the high-earning business and professional occu­pations had grown to be a large proportion of the total, especially for younger cohorts.

This occupational transformation was very rapid, both in absolute terms and rela­tive to the upward mobility of non-Jewish Americans. Jewish immigrants were in­vesting heavily in American (secular) human capital during the early decades of the century, both directly in themselves and indirectly by educating their children for high-level occupations. The implicit value of this investment would have raised the value of their time substantially higher than their relatively low market wage. Subsequent rises in wage rates would reflect the value of these investments as immi­grant Jews assimilated into the American economy, succeeded in business and settled into comfortable middle-class patterns of work and consumption. Throughout the sec­ond half of the twentieth century, Jewish families would be characterized by high mar­ket wages whether in comparison with their former selves, with Jews in their coun­tries of origin, or with non-Jewish Americans as a group.

The implications of high wage rates for Jewish family life in America are funda­mental. While a high value of time discourages all consumption activities by raising their cost, it has a disproportionate effect on such time-intensive, home-produced goods as family and Jewish religious life. This wage effect differs from the implica­tions of high family income, which encourages increased consumption of all goods, including "expensive" ones like family and religion. To the extent that high family income is associated with, or even derived from, high wages, such increases in con-

I I

The Economics ofContemporary Amer~can •

sumption are typically accompanied ~l atively cheaper) home-production technl

The imperative to "save" time effectivi the efficiency of whatever time is stilI d achieving this is to substitute purchased. of purchases relative to own-time input. ward economic mobility, Jewish consulT pared foods, whether in packages (cam catessen or "appetizing" stores).l0 Hig extensive system of schools, synagogues ing their Judaism and for the Jewish edu much heavier demands on their pocketbl

Changes in consumption that systeml time are often referred to as a substitutic In this usage, a higher "quality" refers t penditure of time, presumably accomplis services. Whether or not this constitutes lot depends on the effectiveness of the n of "quality" associated with these quantit can be used to achieve the same goal, so tern would be preferred to a "quantity-i] time is relatively expensive.

Time quantity-quality substitutions in stable characteristic of high-wage Amer: lamented, as when "consumerism" and ,. for the time family members might oth lauded, as when high expenditures on cl ties are seen as expressions of caring and of view, however, goods-intensive COlli

high-wage American Jewish communit)­canization itself.

FamilyHr.

For given inputs of time and money, the with which the family "good" is produc ence of its members. Many such skills h best viewed as part of an individual's gE tant group of acquired skills and prior e: they enhance relationships associated wi. ily-specific" in that they are specialized: do not contribute to productivity in othe.

Marriage improves the efficiency of ec sociated with the family good. It also pr turn to investment in human capital speo

Page 5: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

er Time: Adult Jewish Men

1948 1957 1970 c.1980 1990

13.8 20.3 27.2 43.0 47.4

:M.9 35.1 26.5 26.4 16.7

58.7 55.4 53.7 69.4 64.1

3.9 8.0 8.3 8.3 6.3

12.0 14.1 19.7 13.2 16.1

15.9 22.1 28.0 21.5 22.4

13.1 8.9 8.4 4.2 6.4 7.112.4 13.4 9.9 4.9

25.5 22.3 18.3 9.1 13.5

00.1 99.8 100.0 100.0 100.0

ican Jewry, 1890 to 1990: A Preliminary Report"; reprinted

able 1). Occupations classified as "labor­whereas the high-level "professions" and Jh the highest earnings. At the beginning lfee fourths of all Jewish men were labor­Jor and their wage rates were among the y, only a small (and aging) fraction of all :I-earning business and professional occu­,f the total, especially for younger cohorts. ~ry rapid, both in absolute terms and rela­l Americans. Jewish immigrants were in­L3.Il capital during the early decades of the indirectly by educating their children for , of this investment would have raised the than their relatively low market wage.

oct the value of these investments as immi­conomy, succeeded in business and settled 'ork and consumption. Throughout the sec­nilies would be characterized by high mar­:ir former selves, with Jews in their coun­ans as a group. . Jewish family life in America are funda­rages all consumption activities by raising t on such time-intensive, home-produced This wage effect differs from the implica­rages increased consumption of all goods, ld religion. To the extent that high family l from, high wages, such increases in con­

\.

The Economics o/Contemporary American Jewish Family Life

sumption are typically accompanied by a search for less time-intensive (and thus rel­atively cheaper) home-production technologies.

The imperative to "save" time effectively raises the value of anything that improves the efficiency of whatever time is still devoted to family consumption. One way of achieving this is to substitute purchased goods and services for time, raising the ratio of purchases relative to own-time input. For example, during the early years of up­ward economic mobility, Jewish consumers became an eager market for kosher pre­pared foods, whether in packages (cans, bottles or boxes) or from counters (deli­catessen or "appetizing" stores).l0 High-wage American Jews also developed an extensive system of schools, synagogues, camps and community centers for express­ing their Judaism and for the Jewish education of their children, a system that makes much heavier demands on their pocketbooks than on their time budgets.

Changes in consumption that systematically raise the ratio of purchases to own­time are often referred to as a substitution of the "quality" of time for its "quantity." In this usage, a higher "quality" refers to the well-being achieved from a given ex­penditure of time, presumably accomplished by purchasing more or better goods and services. Whether or not this constitutes an improvement in the consumer's overall lot depends on the effectiveness of the new consumption pattern. Indeed, the notion of "quality" associated with these quantity-quality trade-offs is that alternative means can be used to achieve the same goal, so that a "quality-intensive" consumption pat­tern would be preferred to a "quantity-intensive" pattern only in those cases where time is relatively expensive.

Time quantity-quality substitutions in consumption are widely observed and are a stable characteristic of high-wage American Jews. 11 Sometimes the phenomenon is lamented, as when "consumerism" and "materialism" are viewed as poor substitutes for the time family members might otherwise spend together. Yet sometimes it is lauded, as when high expenditures on child care, health, education or leisure activi­ties are seen as expressions of caring and solid family values. Regardless of the point of view, however, goods-intensive consumption patterns are so pervasive in the high-wage American Jewish community that they are often associated with Ameri­canization itself.

Family Human Capital

For given inputs of time and money, the quality of family life (that is, the efficiency with which the family "good" is produced) depends greatly on the skill and experi­ence of its members. Many such skills have value in other activities as well and are best viewed as part of an individual's general human capital. Yet there is an impor­tant group of acquired skills and prior experiences for which the sole benefit is that they enhance relationships associated with marriage and family. Such skills are "fam­ily-specific" in that they are specialized for home production of the family good and do not contribute to productivity in other activities. 12

Marriage improves the efficiency of each partner in home-production activities as­sociated with the family good. It also provides security that enhances the rate of re­turn to investment in human capital specific to a particular set of family members.

69

Page 6: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

70 I

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

Some of these family-specific skills are general, arising simply from a shared con­sumption pattern (for example, skill in preparing meals at home). 13 Others are asso­ciated with the mutual knowledge and caring within the family and grow out of the in­timacy of ordinary family life. 14 Jewish religious ideals of family emphasize such commitments: to be a life companion (helpmeet) for one's spouse; to nurture and edu­cate children; to honor one's parents; and to care for the sick, the widow and the orphan.

Since various types of human capital are mutually complementary they tend to be highly correlated with each other, and people with high education levels tend to in­vest more in family-related skills. IS In effect, a higher level of one productive at­tribute (for example, health) improves the productivity of another (for example, edu­cation) and thus raises the rate of return to human capital investments generally. The very high level of secular education among American Jews thus provides a strong economic incentive for them to invest in family-specific human capital. This in tum raises the productivity of their family time and offsets (at least partially) those in­centives to reduce time-intensive family activities.

The positive relationship between education and family skills is sometimes ob­scured by the low time-intensity of consumption patterns among the highly educated, as high wage rates also alter the optimal composition of skills in ways that affect the very nature of family life. For example, the convergence of male and female wage rates in the United States has greatly reduced economic incentives for a household di­vision of labor between Jewish husbands and wives. By the end of the twentieth cen­tury, the kitchen skills of American women are much less time-intensive than those that are still nostalgically associated (perhaps fantasized) with Jewish motherhood. Similarly, Jewish fathers are more likely than their immigrant forebears to participate in day-to-day chores of food preparation and parenting. Even the process of skill ac­quisition is affected: instead of the relatively time-intensive leaming-by-helping methods of an earlier era, American Jews rely heavily on a wide variety of purchased materials (such as books, manuals, classes or professional counseling services) to learn how to carry out mundane home-production activities (such as raising children, preparing foods or tending to illness or infirmity).

Analogous changes are evident in the Jewish practices of American families. In an environment where time-intensive activities are relatively costly and purchased in­puts are correspondingly cheap, popular Judaism (including secular Jewish culture as well as religion per se) has exchanged the time-intensive customs of Eastern Europe in favor of typically goods-intensive expressions. Indeed, the pervasiveness of this "Americanization" has effectively produced a new Jewish subculture that differs markedly from its immigrant origins in such fundamentals as language, cuisine and daily rhythms of family life. 16

The Jewish quality of family life is also affected by the Jewish human capital of its members-skills that may have been acquired through Jewish education (formal or informal) and previous Jewish experiences in family, synagogue or community. 17

Like secular education, religious skills can be highly complementary with other forms of human capital, whether general or family-specific. Indeed, the complementarity between Jewish human capital and family human capital is especially strong for the many religious observances inextricably entwined in the particulars of family life: life-cycle celebrations, holiday observances and practices associated with kashruth.

The Economics ofContemporary Ameri~n j \ \

Yet the acquisition of Jewish experi~~

very costly in an economic environment attractive alternatives. Strategies for resp· oftwo basic approaches: Jewish lifestyle vestments in Jewish human capital or, a:: of Jewish human capital that are compler Both of these strategies are evident in thE pIe, combining English with Hebrew in t participation by persons with only a basi, avoiding the need to make the relatively requires. American Jewish schools (USUe

importance of language in their curricullJ teaching methods that complement (and. received by American Jews. Even so, the in Jewish-specific content: although SOlI

language, literature and history is infuse; as a universal ethical system that require~

bors. Jewish lifestyles adapted to low investJ

capital are especially attractive for famili selves have followed this strategy. Partly during the first half of the twentieth cell tury American Jewry is characterized by Whatever its cause, however, a human c secular skill with low levels of Jewish sk: that the value of time spent in Jewish ot than time spent in secular activities. In eff the time allocated to Jewish observance ~

in turn reduces the incentive to invest in ] While many family-based traditions ha

wage American Jews, others effectively c enhancing the quality of both. Some of Passover seder, have been practiced for CI

ented bar/bat mitzvah ceremony with its ious synagogue traditions in which famili religious observance with family life enh increases the efficiency, of two very time pecially receptive to innovations in Jewi ten willing to invest in the corresponding

Thus the high value of time, and the q fects both the very nature of Jewish hum life. Along with American Jews' occupat second half of the twentieth century h: American Jewish institutions designed to ilies. Jewish camps, schools and commm stitutes for their own time, thereby raisil

Page 7: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

leral, arising simply from a shared con­mng meals at home). 13 Others are asso­within the family and grow out of the in­

ligious ideals of family emphasize such .eet) for one's spouse; to nurture and edu­:u-e for the sick, the widow and the orphan. mutually complementary they tend to be .le with high education levels tend to in­~t, a higher level of one productive at­I'Oductivity of another (for example, edu­luman capital investments generally. The g American Jews thus provides a strong mily-specific human capital. This in tum . and offsets (at least partially) those in­:ivities. ltion and family skills is sometimes ob­,tion patterns among the highly educated, :nposition of skills in ways that affect the ~ convergence of male and female wage j economic incentives for a household di­d wives. By the end of the twentieth cen­. are much less time-intensive than those IpS fantasized) with Jewish motherhood. n their immigrant forebears to participate -d parenting. Even the process of skill ac­vely time-intensive leaming-by-helping .ly heavily on a wide variety of purchased ; or professional counseling services) to uction activities (such as raising children, nnity). "'ish practices of American families. In an ~s are relatively costly and purchased in­hism (including secular Jewish culture as :irne-intensive customs of Eastern Europe ~ssions. Indeed, the pervasiveness of this oed a new Jewish subculture that differs :h fundamentals as language, cuisine and

affected by the Jewish human capital of its .ired through Jewish education (formal or :s in family, synagogue or community. I?

Je highly complementary with other forms ily-specific. Indeed, the complementarity human capital is especially strong for the mtwined in the particulars of family life: ;'~d practices associated with kashruth.

\1

\ "­

The Economics o/Contemporary American Jewish Family Life

Yet the acquisition of Jewish experience and skills is itself a time-intensive process, very costly in an economic environment where it must compete for time with many attractive alternatives. Strategies for responding to this fundamental problem take one of two basic approaches: Jewish lifestyles can focus on practices that avoid costly in­vestments in Jewish human capital or, alternatively, they can innovate "new" forms of Jewish human capital that are complementary to high levels of secular investment. Both of these strategies are evident in the American Jewish community. IS For exam­ple, combining English with Hebrew in the rituals of home and synagogue facilitates participation by persons with only a basic familiarity with the Hebrew language, thus avoiding the need to make the relatively large investments that true Hebrew fluency requires. American Jewish schools (usually called "Hebrew schools" because of the importance of language in their curriculum) have adopted institutional structures and teaching methods that complement (and are complemented by) the secular schooling received by American Jews. Even so, the curriculum of Jewish schools varies widely in Jewish-specific content: although some schools view Judaism as a culture whose language, literature and history is infused with religious meaning, others approach it as a universal ethical system that requires few skills not shared by non-Jewish neigh­bors.

Jewish lifestyles adapted to low investments in specifically Jewish forms of human capital are especially attractive for families in which parents and grandparents them­selves have followed this strategy. Partly as a consequence of rapid upward mobility during the first half of the twentieth century, a large segment of late twentieth-cen­tury American Jewry is characterized by very low levels of Jewish human capital. 19

Whatever its cause, however, a human capital "portfolio" combining high levels of secular skill with low levels of Jewish skill is inherently unstable, insofar as it means that the value of time spent in Jewish observance is less "productive" at the margin than time spent in secular activities. In effect, it provides an incentive to further reduce the time allocated to Jewish observance and the Jewish content of family life, which in tum reduces the incentive to invest in Jewish-specific forms of human capital.

While many family-based traditions have difficulty competing for the time of high­wage American Jews, others effectively combine Jewish time with family time while enhancing the quality of both. Some of these traditions, like Shabbat dinner or the Passover seder, have been practiced for centuries. Others are new, like the family-ori­ented bar/bat mitzvah ceremony with its attendant wedding-like celebration, or var­ious synagogue traditions in which families participate together. A blending of Jewish religious observance with family life enhances the mutual complementarity, and thus increases the efficiency, oftwo very time-intensive activities. American Jews are es­pecially receptive to innovations in Jewish practice that accomplish this and are of­ten willing to invest in the corresponding forms of Jewish human capital.

Thus the high value of time, and the quality-quantity tradeoffs that it induces, af­fects both the very nature of Jewish human capital and the Jewish quality of family life. Along with American Jews' occupational stabilization at high levels during the second half of the twentieth century has come the development of a variety of American Jewish institutions designed to complement the scarce time of Jewish fam­ilies. Jewish camps, schools and community centers enable parents to purchase sub­stitutes for their own time, thereby raising the goods-intensity of family activities.

I

71

Page 8: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

72 Carmel Ullman Chiswick

Synagogues and IJavurot often sponsor family events for Shabbat or holidays that pro­vide relief from logistical duties as well as a shared social activity. Synagogue atten­dance itself has become a family activity in the United States, and synagogues have adapted to this phenomenon not only by mixed seating but also by distinctively American innovations that give the entire family a role in the religious service.

Family Formation and Life Cycles

For many American couples, including Jews, the most time-intensive non-work ac­tivity for which a family must budget is child-rearing (that is, parenting). The ex­tended education and investments associated with launching a high-wage career raise the cost of starting a family at a young age, often making it more efficient to estab­lish career before family rather than the reverse. High wage rates (especially for women) also raise the cost of having many children. These incentives are consistent with an observed pattern of later marriages, fewer children, and an extended period of financially independent single adulthood.2o

Family Human Capital and Marriage

Since individuals differ greatly in their preferences and aspirations for family life, the magnitude of the gain from marriage depends on the sorting of partners (whether by themselves or by helpful matchmakers) into mutually compatible couples. The con­ventional economic model views the marriage market as a search process that has costs but also yields benefits in the form of a potential marriage partner. Each person entering the marriage market is viewed as knowing (more or less accurately) his or her own characteristics and those of an "ideal" partner. Since any potential partner re­vealed by the search process inevitably falls short of this ideal, the searcher must de­cide whether to accept a given match or else continue looking; the outcome depends on whether the marginal benefit of additional search (finding a "better" partner) is likely to outweigh the additional cost. Matches occur when each partner decides that the other is "optimal," in the sense that additional search would cost more than the potential gain.21

If the economic basis of marriage is mutual productivity of the two partners, the multidimensional nature of consumption goals (as well as individual differences in tastes and preferences) make the selection of marriage partners especially complex. Yet whenever human capital raises productivity in some activity, it thereby enhances a person's desirability as a marriage partner. One implication of the economic theory of search is that the optimal sort (that is, the pairing that occurs if each person chooses his or her "optimal" partner) tends to match persons with similar levels of human cap­ital.22 Highly educated men and women thus tend to marry each other and, conversely, men and women with relatively little schooling also tend to pair together.23

Economic incentives affecting marital search match couples not only by secular education and career aspirations but also by the amount and content of their religious human capital. Complementarity between various types of human capital militates in favor of religiously homogamous families, especially for those who understand their

The Economics ofContemporary Ameri~n ) Judaism in terms of particularistic J~\vt: those who prefer to focus their religious: values shared by many Americans make man capital and hence have correspondil of a potential marriage partner. These h lated to the "exclusivist-ecumenical" co tions are sometimes ranked: human capi­far as it serves to differentiate members ( more general forms of Jewish human ca~

mote such a distinction.24 While Jewish among the Orthodox in comparison wid quently evident among the non-Orthodo: Jewish "ecumenism" in all American sYI pitable environment is among the Reforr: tion between the level of investment in _ its Jewish content, within-group variatio­across synagogue movements less than ~

Among American Jews, the religious ( depends to a crucial extent on the relev; this perspective, the extraordinarily high rive not so much from the American for: rather from the extremely low specifici many (but not nearly all) of these innoval

Table 2. Outmarriage Rc (First Spouse of Eve~

Size Denomination raised (%)

All Jews-by-birth 100

Orthodox and Traditional 24

Conservative, Reconstructionist 39 and "just Jewish"

Mixed Jewishb 3

Reform 26

Secular, miscellaneous, 3 and no religion

Non-Jewishc 5

Sample size: 2,282

Source: 1990 National Jewish Population Survey (houselc

aIncludes all Jews-by-birth ever married by 1990

'Persons raised as both Orthodox and Conservative. both

cJews-by-birth raised as non-Jews, including those who '"

Page 9: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

_y events for Shabbat or holidays that pro­t shared social activity. Synagogue atten­_the United States, and synagogues have mixed seating but also by distinctively :unily a role in the religious service.

I and Life Cycles

oIS, the most time-intensive non-work ac­:hild-rearing (that is, parenting). The ex­d with launching a high-wage career raise , often making it more efficient to estab­~everse. High wage rates (especially for children. These incentives are consistent

0, fewer children, and an extended period 1 20

·ital and Marriage

erences and aspirations for family life, the 1ds on the sorting of partners (whether by :0 mutually compatible couples. The con­iage market as a search process that has -a potential marriage partner. Each person knowing (more or less accurately) his or

:al" partner. Since any potential partner re­Is short of this ideal, the searcher must de­se continue looking; the outcome depends onal search (finding a "better" partner) is ches occur when each partner decides that iditional search would cost more than the

utual productivity of the two partners, the goals (as well as individual differences in l of marriage partners especially complex. tivity in some activity, it thereby enhances :r. One implication of the economic theory ~ pairing that occurs if each person chooses I persons with similar levels of human cap­IS tend to marry each other and, conversely, oling also tend to pair together.23

search match couples not only by secular y the amount and content of their religious various types of human capital militates in ~peciallY for those who understand their

The Economics o/Contemporary American Jewish Family Life

Judaism in terms of particularistic Jewish knowledge and experiences. In contrast, those who prefer to focus their religious aspirations on general (for example, ethical) values shared by many Americans make few investments in specifically Jewish hu­man capital and hence have correspondingly less to gain from the Jewishness per se of a potential marriage partner. These human capital considerations are closely re­lated to the "exclusivist-ecumenical" continuum along which Protestant denomina­tions are sometimes ranked: human capital specific to Judaism is "exclusivist" inso­far as it serves to differentiate members of the group from nonmembers, whereas the more general forms of Jewish human capital are "ecumenical" since they do not pro­mote such a distinction.24 While Jewish "exclusivism" in this sense may be stronger among the Orthodox in comparison with the other synagogue movements, it is fre­quently evident among the non-Orthodox as well. Similarly, there is some degree of Jewish "ecumenism" in all American synagogue movements, although its most hos­pitable environment is among the Reform. While there tends to be a positive correla­tion between the level of investment in Jewish human capital and the specificity of its Jewish content, within-group variations in Jewish education make the correlation across synagogue movements less than perfect.

Among American Jews, the religious compatibility of a potential marriage partner depends to a crucial extent on the relevant concept of Jewish human capital. From this perspective, the extraordinarily high outmarriage rates among American Jews de­rive not so much from the American fondness for innovation in Jewish practice but rather from the extremely low specificity of Jewish human capital with which so many (but not nearly all) of these innovations are associated. Table 2 presents the dis-

Table 2. Outmarriage Rates by Denomination Raised (First Spouse of Ever-Married Jews-by-Birth)

Alia Under age 65

Spouse Spouse Size not Jewish Size not Jewish

Denomination raised (%) (%) (%) (%)

All Jews-by-birth 100 25 100 32

Orthodox and Traditional 24 10 19 15

Conservative, Reconstructionist 39 22 42 29 and "just Jewish"

Mixed Jewishb 3 21 33 33

Reform 26 35 28 41

Secular, miscellaneous, 3 42 3 45 and no religion

Non-Jewishc 5 66 5 68

Sample size: 2,282 2,282 1,720 1,720

Source.' 1990 National Jewish Population Survey (household weights)

aInciudes all Jews-by-birth ever married by 1990

bpersons raised as both Orthodox and Conservative, both Orthodox and Reform, or both Conservative and Reform

cJews-by-birth raised as non-Jews, including those who were raised as "both" Jews and non-Jews

73

I

Page 10: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

I 74 Carmel Ullman Chiswick

tribution of American Jews by affiliation with the various synagogue movements along with the outmarriage rates (the proportion whose first marriage was to a non­Jewish spouse) for each group, both for all ever-married adults and for those under age sixty-five. Since human capital and marital decisions were somewhat different for immigrants than for those born in the United States, the figures for persons under age sixty-five are the most indicative of the American Jewish experience.

Table 2 ranks the main branches of American Judaism by the relative intensity of their Jewish-specific human capital. The Orthodox tradition emphasizes forms of family-related human capital most specific to Judaism and generates higher benefits to homogamous couples. The outmarriage rate of 15 percent among the Orthodox (who account for 19 percent of American Jewry) is indeed the lowest of all groups identified here.25 The Conservative movement, which seeks a balance between Jewish-specific human capital and secular lifestyles, is characterized by an interme­diate outmarriage rate of 29 percent and accounts for 42 percent of American Jewry. The Reform movement, with its focus on Jewish beliefs and practices shared by many non-Jewish Americans, is marked by a higher outmarriage rate of 41 percent.26 This is close to the 45 percent outmarriage rate among persons raised with "no" religion, though not nearly as high as the 68 percent rate for persons born Jewish but raised in other religions.

Jewish Family Life Cycles

The high schooling level characteristic of American Jews generally militates against marriage at young ages. Delayed marriage may be the consequence of early human capital investments made by young adults launching high-level careers, causing them to postpone heavy family-specific investments until later. Full-time schooling that ex­tends into early adulthood also delays the availability of information relevant for mar­ital search: career choices may not stabilize until relatively late, and important adult characteristics may not be revealed (either to oneself or to a potential partner) until after labor force entry and the acceptance of financial responsibility. Early marriages based on incomplete information tend to be unstable; indeed, early age at marriage is one of the strongest and most robust predictors of subsequent divorce. Overall, it is generally optimal for the highly educated to delay family formation until well into adulthood.27

The marital status of American Jews in 1990 (see Table 3) thus reflects their edu­cation and earning levels. American Jewish men and women remain single until their mid-twenties, the typical age of first marriage being about twenty-six years for men and twenty-four years for women.28 Somewhat earlier marriage ages are observed for cohorts born during the Great Depression and the Second World War (men aged fifty to fifty-nine and women aged forty-five to fifty-nine in 1990 who would have entered adulthood during the 1950s). These "baby boom" parents were presumably influ­enced by an exceptional set of economic circumstances, but apart from them, the pat­tern seems to have been fairly stable throughout the century.

Even in the twenty-five to thirty-four age cohorts (where exclusion from the sam­ple of those who have yet to marry at age thirty-five or older lowers the average age at first marriage), Jewish women remained single until well over the age of twenty-

The Economics ofContemporary Ameridan ~ Table 3. Mari~

Percentage Age at first of all marriageQ

Age in adult 1990 Jews Men Women Mer

25-29 10 24.4 22.8 65 30-34 11 26.0 23.4 34 35-39 12 26.2 24.6 17 40-44 12 26.3 24.5 15 45-49 9 26.3 21.8 7 50-54 6 24.6 21.2 12 55-59 7 25.9 21.9 8 60--64 7 26.5 22.7 4 ~65 27 26.9 24.3 3 All ages 100 26.2 23.4 17

Source: 1990 National Jewish Population Survey, (Jews-.

4Mean age at first marriage for ever-married persons

bMaritai status in 1990 was divorced, separated, or widoV'

three. Among those in their late twentie~

couples accounted for only one-third ot while 65 percent of the men and 39 perce single (never married). Among those age counted for a third of the Jewish men ar three-quarters of the men and women age ried, and the rest were more likely than I

If a stable marriage encourages im American Jewish couples generally vie\; ity of family time. 3o Yet raising a child is. make it expensive to have many childre smaller families than do couples whose also have more income and typically sp for each child. In analogy to the substit. this pattern is often described as a trade-Oo dren.3l

Much of the observed decline in Amer this quantity-quality trade-off and is sh. Evidence from the 1990 childbearing hi ous ages suggests that their birth rates m dren per woman (see Table 4). The excer: five to fifty-nine age cohorts are reflectec relatively large number of children, a Je: theless raised the average to no more thar: ber of children born to Jewish mothers ()

While Jewish birth rates have clearly c

Page 11: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

.vith the various synagogue movements rtion whose first marriage was to a non­ever-married adults and for those under

nital decisions were somewhat different lited States, the figures for persons under American Jewish experience.

rican Judaism by the relative intensity of Jrthodox tradition emphasizes forms of to Judaism and generates higher benefits rate of 15 percent among the Orthodox

Jewry) is indeed the lowest of all groups ement, which seeks a balance between lifestyles, is characterized by an interme­counts for 42 percent of American Jewry. wish beliefs and practices shared by many "ler outmarriage rate of 41 percent. 26 This among persons raised with "no" religion, rate for persons born Jewish but raised in

,I Life Cycles

...merican Jews generally militates against may be the consequence of early human

mnching high-level careers, causing them ,nts until later. Full-time schooling that ex­lailability of information relevant for mar­e until relatively late, and important adult : to oneself or to a potential partner) until If financial responsibility. Early marriages ~ unstable; indeed, early age at marriage is lctors of subsequent divorce. Overall, it is to delay family formation until well into

1990 (see Table 3) thus reflects their edu­~ men and women remain single until their iage being about twenty-six years for men what earlier marriage ages are observed for and the Second World War (men aged fifty fifty-nine in 1990 who would have entered ,y boom" parents were presumably influ­lrcumstances, but apart from them, the pat­19hout the century. ~e cohorts (where exclusion from the sarn­thirty-five or older lowers the average age [l'~ngle until well over the age of twenty­

\,

The Economics ofContemporary American Jewish Family Life

Table 3. Marital Status by Age and Sex

Percentage distribution

Age in

Percentage of all adult

Age at first marriagea

Never married Married

Previously marriedb

1990 Jews Men Women Men Women Men Women Men Women

25-29 10 24.4 22.8 65 39 34 53 I 8 30-34 II 26.0 23.4 34 24 60 69 6 7 35-39 12 26.2 24.6 17 II 72 75 II 14 40-44 12 26.3 24.5 15 12 74 75 II 13 45-49 9 26.3 2\.8 7 8 78 78 16 14 50-54 6 24.6 2\.2 12 7 77 74 II 19 55-59 7 25.9 2\.9 8 1 85 74 8 25 60-64 7 26.5 22.7 4 3 90 80 6 18 ~65 27 26.9 24.3 3 2 82 57 15 41 All ages 100 26.2 23.4 17 II 72 68 10 21

Source: 1990 National Jewish Population Survey, (lews-by-birth aged 25 and older) "Mean age at first marriage for ever-married persons bMaritai status in 1990 was divorced, separated, or widowed

three. Among those in their late twenties (ages twenty-five to twenty-nine), married couples accounted for only one-third of the men and just over half of the women, while 65 percent of the men and 39 percent of the women in this age group were still single (never married). Among those aged thirty to thirty-four, the never-married ac­counted for a third of the Jewish men and a fourth of the women. In contrast, some three-quarters of the men and women aged thirty-five to sixty-four in 1990 were mar­ried, and the rest were more likely than not to have been previously married.29

If a stable marriage encourages investment in family-related human capital, American Jewish couples generally view children as ipso facto enhancing the qual­ity of family time.3o Yet raising a child is intrinsically time-intensive, and high wages make it expensive to have many children. Thus, high-earning couples tend to have smaller families than do couples whose time is less costly. Yet high-earning couples also have more income and typically spend more on purchased goods and services for each child. In analogy to the substitution of quality for quantity in family time, this pattern is often described as a trade-off between the quantity and "quality" of chil­dren.31

Much of the observed decline in American Jewish birth rates is the consequence of this quantity-quality trade-off and is shared by other high-wage American groups. Evidence from the 1990 childbearing histories of American Jewish women of vari­ous ages suggests that their birth rates may have stabilized at an average of two chil­dren per woman (see Table 4). The exceptional economic circumstances of the forty­five to fifty-nine age cohorts are reflected here by their low rates of childlessness and relatively large number of children, a Jewish "baby boom" in the 1950s that never­theless raised the average to no more than 2.76 children. In contrast, the average num­ber of children born to Jewish mothers over age sixty-five in 1990 was only 2.25.

While Jewish birth rates have clearly declined over time, family size appears to be

75

Page 12: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

76 Carmel Ullman Chiswick

Table 4. Marital Fertility by Age (Born-Jewish Adult Women)

Ever-married women

Childless women Age at first marriage Children ever born (percent of all women) (mean) (mean)

Age in Never Ever Childless All 1990 married married women Mothersa women Mothersa

25-29 39 35 23.5 21.9 0.41 1.59 30-34 24 16 25.6 22.9 1.20 1.99 35-39 11 14 27.7 24.1 1.48 1.99 40-44 12 II 30.2 23.5 1.61 2.08 45-49 8 11 b 21.5 1.89 2.32 50-54 7 9 b 20.6 2.14 2.56 55-59 1 3 b 22.0 2.65 2.76 60-64 3 8 b 21.9 2.17 2.44 2:65 2 11 28.8 23.7 1.98 2.26 All Ages 11 13 26.2 22.9 1.55 2.25

Source: 1990 National Jewish Population Survey, (Jews-by-birth aged twenty-five and older)

aWomen with children ever born

bFewer than twelve women in sample

fairly stable in recent decades, averaging about two children per woman. If observed birth rates appear to be somewhat lower than this, much of the difference may be at­tributable to the patterns of delayed marriage and childbearing that were discussed earlier. For example, the first two columns of Table 4 indicate that fully 24 percent of all adult Jewish women are childless, yet the age distribution suggests that young women may be delaying rather than avoiding motherhood. Similarly, childlessness among married women is partly due to the recentness of their first marriage (at age twenty-six, compared to age twenty-three for women with children) and partly to the relative instability of young marriages, which is itself an incentive to postpone child-b~ri~. .

Although high-wage families with few children typically spend more resources per child than their low-wage counterparts, the selection of expenditure patterns will vary with parental goals. As it is the adults who ultimately control a family's resource al­location decisions, it is they who determine the balance between parental sacrifice and self-indulgence within the family. American Jews are typically willing to "sacri­fice" their own consumption in favor of their children's health and education.32 Yet both of these items are not just consumption; they are important forms of investment in human capital that may be understood as a bequest, transmitting high-level skills from parents to children. Apart from satisfying parental goals for their children, this understanding of the nature of child "quality" underlies intergenerational stability of the high-wage occupational structure characteristic of American Jewry.

The opportunity cost of a child's time is determined not by his or her current wage rate (which is typically very low or negligible) but rather by the value of his or her investments in human capital. Thus, heavy investments in child "quality" raise the value of children's time relative to that of their parents, providing an incentive for

The Economics ofContemporary American.

high-wage Jewish parents to enhance tiL do American Jewish parents hire service selves) of household chores, they also s: hancing their children's participation in • activities, frequently driving them from hind-the-scene parent groups.

The high-wage demographic patterns riages and small families) also have com acterized by relatively few children and; married adults. Middle-aged Jewish ad caring for young children, while some\' ents of single adults) have emerged as a between children and their grandparelll proved health and increased longevity e ents, they also increase the cohort of "v~

The demographic patterns that emerg. economic opportunities further alter the shaped. For example, Jewish families \¥

cidence of same-sex siblings and hence parents seek valid religious expression iii an important constituency for egalitariCli life. Similarly, the relatively high numbe increasing proportion of one-grandchild has neither siblings, cousins, aunts nor \L

sumably doting but inevitably aging) ~

stituency for revisions in the balance bet unrelated families join forces for a Pass. are shared in the synagogue, or when Je tergenerational activities with unrelated

Cor:

The basic approach of this analysis has b produced goods, potentially interrelated To the extent that high-wage occupatio: community is one in which time has a hi~

terns are correspondingly costly. ThiE American impulse to innovate new Jewi guishes contemporary American Jews 1 least to some extent, from other branche

The underpinning of the high-wage e an extremely high level of secular educa man capital, for both men and women, 1

of this community. This has important in while Jewish and secular education mlii

Page 13: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

~e (Born-Jewish Adult Women)

Ever-married women

~ at first marriage Children ever born (mean) (mean)

leSS All ::n Mothersa women Mothersa

21.9 0.41 1.59 22.9 1.20 1.99 24.1 1.48 1.99 23.5 1.61 2.08 21.5 1.89 2.32 20.6 2.14 2.56 22.0 2.65 2.76 21.9 2.17 2.44 23.7 1.98 2.26 22.9 1.55 2.25

JIh aged twenty-five and older)

out two children per woman. If observed n this, much of the difference may be at­se and childbearing that were discussed CTable 4 indicate that fully 24 percent of he age distribution suggests that young 19 motherhood. Similarly, childlessness ~ecentness of their first marriage (at age r women with children) and partly to the h is itself an incentive to postpone child­

ldren typically spend more resources per :lection ofexpenditure patterns will vary ltimately control a family's resource al­the balance between parental sacrifice

can Jews are typically willing to "sacri­r children's health and education.32 Yet they are important forms of investment a bequest, transmitting high-level skills Ig parental goals for their children, this , underlies intergenerational stability of eristic of American Jewry. termined not by his or her current wage e) but rather by the value of his or her ~vestments in child "quality" raise the

)" p"",n". providing an ficon'ivo tn,

The Economics o/Contemporary American Jewish Family Life

high-wage Jewish parents to enhance the quality of time for their children. Not only do American Jewish parents hire service providers to relieve their children (and them­selves) of household chores, they also spend much of their valuable leisure time en­hancing their children's participation in a wide variety of broadly defined educational activities, frequently driving them from one to the other and supporting them in be­hind-the-scene parent groups.

The high-wage demographic patterns of American Jews (especially the late mar­riages and small families) also have communal implications. American Jewry is char­acterized by relatively few children and an unprecedentedly high proportion of never­married adults. Middle-aged Jewish adults are more likely than ever before to be caring for young children, while somewhat older "empty-nesters" (usually the par­ents of single adults) have emerged as a significant demographic group. The age gap between children and their grandparents is larger than ever before, and while im­proved health and increased longevity extend the active lifespan of these grandpar­ents, they also increase the cohort of "very aged" Jews.33

The demographic patterns that emerge as Jewish families adapt to their high-wage economic opportunities further alter the environment in which American Judaism is shaped. For example, Jewish families with only one or two children have a high in­cidence of same-sex siblings and hence of families with only daughters. 34 As these parents seek valid religious expression in the absence of male offspring, they become an important constituency for egalitarianism in all dimensions of American Jewish life. Similarly, the relatively high number of one-child families leads invariably to an increasing proportion of one-grandchild families: that is, offamilies in which a child has neither siblings, cousins, aunts nor uncles and is the sole descendant of four (pre­sumably doting but inevitably aging) grandparents. Such families become a con­stituency for revisions in the balance between Jewish home and community, as when unrelated families join forces for a Passover seder, when Shabbat and holiday meals are shared in the synagogue, or when Jewish schools and youth groups organize in­tergenerational activities with unrelated "grandparents."

Conclusion

The basic approach of this analysis has been to view family and religion as two home­produced goods, potentially interrelated, that require as inputs both time and money. To the extent that high-wage occupations are characteristic of American Jewry, the community is one in which time has a high value and time-intensive consumption pat­terns are correspondingly costly. This fundamental fact underlies much of the American impulse to innovate new Jewish "traditions," an impulse that often distin­guishes contemporary American Jews from both their immigrant forebears and, at least to some extent, from other branches of world Jewry.

The underpinning of the high-wage economic environment of American Jewry is an extremely high level of secular education, a heavy investment in work-related hu­man capital, for both men and women, that for many is an identifying characteristic of this community. This has important implications for American Judaism as well, for while Jewish and secular education must compete with each other for the resources

77

Page 14: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

78 Carmel Ullman Chiswick

(especially time) of American youth, complementarities between the two types of ed­ucation increase the productivity of investments in Jewish human capital. Not sur­prisingly, American Jewish education tends to focus on skills best suited to a com­munity in which secular skills are high, time is costly and goods are relatively cheap.

As in most communities where high wages are the norm, families tend to be small. American Jews marry relatively late and spend generously on their few children, boys and girls alike. Heavy investments in the health and education of these children are typically a matter of course, an expectation (for both adults and children) associated with the essence of family and communal life. The consequent social and demo­graphic patterns have established themselves as economically successful, intergener­ationally stable, and hence enduring characteristics of American Jewish family life.

The high cost of time also underlies some of the apparent paradoxes in American Judaism. If high-wage men and women spend little time at home, they nevertheless devote much attention to their children and invest heavily in family-related skills. If the incentives of educated Jews are unfavorable to traditional religious observance, they nevertheless favor such new forms of Jewish education as the study-in English-of Jewish history, literature and social science. They also favor the devel­opment of new adaptations to the economic environment. Thus even as Americans seem to distance themselves from the large families and family-based religious ob­servance associated with their Jewish heritage, they have been prolific in the devel­opment of religious institutions and lifestyles that raise the quality of Jewish family life in the United States.

This article has examined some of the ways in which the American Jewish family, and Jewish family life in America, have been influenced by their economic environ­ment. The broad outlines of this economic influence provide a useful perspective on the Jewish family in its American context. This in tum yields insights into the histor­ical process of Jewish assimilation into the high-wage subculture of professionals in the United States. It will presumably also yield insight into the future of world Jewry, as more countries (including Israel) enter the orbit of modem economic development.

Notes

I. Two major new sources of data shed light on the economic transformation of the American Jewish community during the course of the twentieth century. Data on selected eco­nomic variables for American Jews and non-Jews, by decade from 1890 to 1990, have been developed from various census and survey sources and are now available for statistical analy­sis; see Barry R. Chiswick, "The Occupational Attainment of American Jewry, 1890 to 1990: A Preliminary Report" (unpublished manuscript, Nov. 1994). In addition, the 1990 National Jewish Population Survey (NJPS) contains a wealth of information on the social and demo­graphic characteristics ofAmerican Jews in 1990; see Sydney Goldstein, "Profile of American Jewry: Insights from the 1990 National Jewish Population Survey," American Jewish Yearbook 92 (New York and Philadelphia: 1992),77-173. These two complementary sources permit a more complete analysis of the economic transformation of twentieth-century American Jewry. Also see two previous studies by Barry R. Chiswick, "The Labor Market Status of American Jews: Patterns and Determinants," American Jewish Yearbook 85 (New York and Philadelphia: 1984), 131-153 and "The Postwar Economy ofAmerican Jews," in Studies in Contemporary Jewry, vol. 8, A New Jewry? America Since the Second World War, ed. Peter Y. Medding (New

The Economics ofContemporary American ~

York: 1992), 85-101; and Carmel U. Chis­Shofar 13, no. 4 (1995),1-19.

2. Ibid. (Carmel U. Chiswick). 3. Some people do not view family life a

not like ice cream. Since their presence in the: present analysis, this group will be ignored h

4. One implication of this approach is a 1)

consumption for self-produced goods. Indee ''production in consumption."

5. See, for example, Gary S. Becker, A 1 and T. Paul Schultz, "Symposium on Inves opment," Journal ofHuman Resources 28 (1

6. See Becker, A Treatise on the Family. 7. See Corry Azzi and Ronald Ehrenbe:

Attendance," Journal of Political Economy Formal Model of Church and Sect," Americc and Chiswick, "Economics of American Jud:

8. For example, if two equally productiV' and the other in home production, and each i: their productivity would then differ in each t:

9. See Chiswick, "Economics of Americ: 10. Although Jewish women often withdrc

twentieth century, they increasingly entered ( nal occupations that Jewish men were leavir value behavior reflected the importance plac.

11. See Jenna Weissman Joselit, The Wo 1880-1950 (New York: 1994).

12. These skills are commonly referred te marriage and divorce) as "marriage-specifl skills. Since the marriage relationship is onl~

referred to here as "family-specific" skills. 13. Other efficiencies associated with ma.

pie, housing or meals may be less expensive to be family-specific in that they are observe: sequence. Indeed, many of these gains are el ing units and are not unique to the family pel

14. See Carmel U. Chiswick and Evelyn l Perspective," Contemporary Jewry 12 (Jeru~

15. See Robert T. Michael, "Education: Economy 83 (1973),306-327.

16. See Chiswick, "Economics of Americ 17. See Azzi and Ehrenberg, "Household

Laurence R. Iannaccone, "Religious Practic Scientific Study ofReligion 29 (1990), 297-:

18. Jack Wertheimer documents this tet Religion: Apathy and Renewal" in his A Pee (New York: 1993), ch. 6.

19. Following economic incentives that] American Jewish immigrants made relativel: ucation. Moreover, the Jewish skills acquired to the high-schooling, high-wage suburban e as adults. See Carmel U. Chiswick, "The EcOl as a Case Study," Papers in Jewish Demogn

20. This pattern is generally shared by all It has been documented for American Jews t

Page 15: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

Carmel Ullman Chiswick

~mentarities between the two types of ed­~ents in Jewish human capital. Not sur­; to focus on skills best suited to a com­: is costly and goods are relatively cheap. ~s are the norm, families tend to be small. nd generously on their few children, boys ~alth and education of these children are (for both adults and children) associated

_life. The consequent social and demo­,s as economically successful, intergener­:teristics of American Jewish family life. oe of the apparent paradoxes in American :nd little time at home, they nevertheless invest heavily in family-related skills. If

..able to traditional religious observance, of Jewish education as the study-in ocial science. They also favor the devel­c environment. Thus even as Americans families and family-based religious ob­

1ge, they have been prolific in the devel­:es that raise the quality of Jewish family

)'S in which the American Jewish family, :n influenced by their economic environ­nfluence provide a useful perspective on "his in tum yields insights into the histor­high-wage subculture of professionals in eld insight into the future of world Jewry, ~ orbit of modem economic development.

es

ight on the economic transformation of the )f the twentieth century. Data on selected eco­'IS, by decade from 1890 to 1990, have been :es and are now available for statistical analy­\ttainment of American Jewry, 1890 to 1990: t, Nov. 1994). In addition, the 1990 National ~alth of information on the social and demo­I; see Sydney Goldstein, "Profile of American lpulation Survey," American Jewish Yearbook . These two complementary sources permit a mation of twentieth-century American Jewry. !Vick, "The Labor Market Status of American ish Yearbook 85 (New York and Philadelphia: I\merican Jews," in Studies in Contemporary econd World War, ed. PeterY. Medding (New

)

The Economics ofContemporary American Jewish Family Life

York: 1992), 85-101; and Carmel U. Chiswick, "The Economics of American Judaism," Shofar 13, no. 4 (1995), 1-19.

2. Ibid. (Carmel U. Chiswick). 3. Some people do not view family life as desirable, just as there are some people who do

not like ice cream. Since their presence in the American Jewish community does not affect the present analysis, this group will be ignored here.

4. One implication of this approach is a blurring of the distinction between production and consumption for self-produced goods. Indeed, the general topic is sometimes referred to as "production in consumption."

5. See, for example, Gary S. Becker, A Treatise on the Family (Cambridge, Mass: 1981); and T. Paul Schultz, "Symposium on Investments in Women's Human Capital and Devel­opment," Journal ofHuman Resources 28 (1993), 689-974.

6. See Becker, A Treatise on the Family. 7. See Corry Azzi and Ronald Ehrenberg, "Household Allocation of Time and Church

Attendance," Journal of Political Economy 83 (1975), 27-56; Laurence R. Iannaccone, "A Formal Model of Church and Sect," American Journal ofSociology 94 (suppl.), S241-S268; and Chiswick, "Economics of American Judaism."

8. For example, if two equally productive people agree to specialize, one in market work and the other in home production, and each invests in skills best suited to their respective job, their productivity would then differ in each type of work.

9. See Chiswick, "Economics of American Judaism." 10. Although Jewish women often withdrew from the labor force during the first half ofthe

twentieth century, they increasingly entered (often as volunteers) the educational and commu­nal occupations that Jewish men were leaving for more lucrative activities. Their high time­value behavior reflected the importance placed on these activities by American Jews.

11. See Jenna Weissman Joselit, The Wonders of America: Reinventing Jewish Culture, 1880-1950 (New York: 1994).

12. These skills are commonly referred to in the literature (primarily on the economics of marriage and divorce) as "marriage-specific," to distinguish them from "market-specific" skills. Since the marriage relationship is only one aspect of family life, however, they will be referred to here as "family-specific" skills.

13. Other efficiencies associated with marriage result from economies of scale; for exam­ple, housing or meals may be less expensive (per person) if shared. Gains of this sort tend not to be family-specific in that they are observed both before and after a divorce-and-remarriage sequence. Indeed, many of these gains are enjoyed by roommates or various other group liv­ing units and are not unique to the family per se.

14. See Carmel U. Chiswick and Evelyn L. Lehrer, "Religious Intermarriage: An Economic Perspective," Contemporary Jewry 12 (Jerusalem: 1992),21-34.

15. See Robert T. Michael, "Education in Nonmarket Production," Journal of Political Economy 83 (1973), 306-327.

16. See Chiswick, "Economics of American Judaism," and Joselit, Wonders ofAmerica. 17. See Azzi and Ehrenberg, "Household Allocation of Time and Church Attendance," and

Laurence R. Iannaccone, "Religious Practice: A Human Capital Approach," Journal of the Scientific Study ofReligion 29 (1990), 297-314.

18. Jack Wertheimer documents this tendency in his excellent discussion of "Popular Religion: Apathy and Renewal" in his A People Divided: Judaism in Contemporary America (New York: 1993), ch. 6.

19. Following economic incentives that led them to focus on secular achievement, many American Jewish immigrants made relatively small investments in their children's Jewish ed­ucation. Moreover, the Jewish skills acquired by these children were often imperfectly adapted to the high-schooling, high-wage suburban environment in which they would find themselves as adults. See Carmel U. Chiswick, "The Economics oflmmigrant Religion: American Judaism as a Case Study," Papers in Jewish Demography 1997 (forthcoming).

20. This pattern is generally shared by all high-wage American religious and ethnic groups. It has been documented for American Jews by data from the 1990 NJPS.

79

Page 16: Aug. Levinson on Levinson, Jewish Family Liferesearch.policyarchive.org/14999.pdf · 2013. 8. 24. · general and Jewish family life in particular, will first be discussed. Then follows

80 Carmel Ullman Chiswick

21. This discussion of the economics of marriage and family is based on a vast literature. The theory is concisely and elegantly presented in Becker's Treatise on the Family, which in­cludes an extensive bibliography, and has been applied elsewhere by many researchers (see, for example, Chiswick and Lehrer, "Religious Intermarriage"; and Evelyn L. Lehrer and Carmel U. Chiswick, "Religion as a Determinant of Marital Stability," Demography 30, no. 3 [1993],385-404).

22. This occurs because a person with higher levels of any attractive characteristic (for ex­ample, schooling) is more likely to be accepted by a "better" potential partner and is thus more likely to benefit from additional search. It follows that he or she is less likely to agree to marry a partner with less attractive characteristics.

23. See Becker, A Treatise on the Family. 24. See Dean M. Kelley, Why Conservative Churches are Growing: A Study in Sociology of

Religion (New York: 1972). 25. The fraction of American Jews raised as Orthodox is substantially higher than the frac­

tion currently identifying as such. This oft-noted "denominational drift" is a consequence of the economic assimilation of immigrants as well as the growth of non-Orthodox American syn­agogue movements.

26. As the movement most hospitable to those who view themselves as Jewishly "marginal" (for whatever reason), outrnarried Jews are most likely to be affiliated with Reform synagogues.

27. Sexual maturity is not subject to the same economic incentives as marriage and family formation, leading to a potential difficulty among young adults. One "solution" is a pattern of informal marriage (cohabitation) among young adults prior to formal marriage with a life part­ner. Another is a serial marriage pattern where an early pairing (preferably childless) is fol­lowed by divorce and subsequent remarriage in a more enduring relationship.

28. The mean age of first marriage reported in Table 3 is slightly lower than this because incomplete marital histories, especially in the youngest cohorts, exclude many who will marry later.

29. Higher rates of being currently married among men over age fifty-five reflect the longer life expectancy of Jewish women, among whom the incidence of widowhood increases corre­spondingly in older cohorts.

30. This perception is not specific to Jews but rather a generally shared value for nearly every society. Judaism reinforces the desire for children with its emphasis on parent-child re­lationships, both in specific religious observances and in an obligation to contribute to inter­generational communal survival.

31. The term "child quality" is conventional in the literature, although perhaps unfortunate since it refers not so much to the child as to parental aspirations for the child. The presumption is that parents allocate family resources to their children's consumption precisely because they view such expenditures as quality-enhancing.

32. Emphasis on education is not unique to Jews, but neither is it universal among high­wage groups. Some groups, for example, tend to place a greater value on attending a socially prestigious college than on education per se. Others place more emphasis on opportunities for their children to have "fun," to lead a fashionable lifestyle or to carry on a family business.

33. The emerging phenomenon of four-generation families is also of some importance. Four-generation families arise from the juxtaposition of longer life expectancy with relatively early childbearing for two or more generations of women, a condition that characterized the somewhat exceptional "baby-boom" cohorts and their mothers. Thus, the four-generation Jewish family should probably be viewed as a delayed consequence of the transition to later childbearing rather than as an enduring feature of the American Jewish family.

34. An equal probability for each sex implies that exclusively female children can be ex­pected in 50 percent of the one-child families, 25 percent of the two-child families, and 13 per­cent of the three-child families. To understand the implications of this, consider that most American Jewish families have two children and that most of the remaining families have only one child. This means that all-daughter families are somewhere between 25 and 50 percent of the total, tending toward the higher end of this range as the incidence of one-child families be­comes greater.

Children of Intermar

BrUCE

(HEBREW UNION COLI OF RELIGIOr-;

Until the 1960s, American Jews were: about intermarriage. In the first half of tl" uncommonly low. Just after the tum of records in New York City and found tl" New York Jews was only slightly highe blacks. 1 By mid-century, the statistics h ied in the late 1940s were the religious Heiss similarly found that the interman (18.4 percent) was significantly lower tl Catholics (21.4 percent ).3 In their cl~

Glazer and Daniel Moynihan described The year 1963 marked the tuming poi

1963, the American Jewish Year Bookp' Rosenthal's "Studies ofJewish Interman the publication of the first symposium c Jewish organization? Look magazine a American Jew," which raised the specte

Jewish public interest in intermarria National Jewish Population Survey (N Massarik, who had conducted the first reported that intermarriage had risen f percent for the period 1961.-1965, to 3

Over the next two decades an occas this intermarriage rate for the Jewish f these marriages, and social scientist! Massarik, the scientific director of the r of intermarriage, reasoning that if half I dren, there would be no net loss to the. increase. 10 Building on Massarik's am tor ofMoment magazine, Leonard Fein. ried about intermarriage. 11


Recommended