+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Bachelor projekt moses vitkenstein og knutsen - IBP Union · the overarching institutional...

Bachelor projekt moses vitkenstein og knutsen - IBP Union · the overarching institutional...

Date post: 08-May-2018
Category:
Upload: buianh
View: 215 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
77
Bachelor Thesis “The Institutional Setup in Turkey” International Business and Politics Advisor: Dzmitry Bartalevich Hand-in date: 22 nd of May 2014 Number of pages: STUs: XXXXXXXXX Group number 7 Klaus Højland – 070283-xxxx Viktor Stauning – 120984-xxxx Martin Kastrup – 080591-xxxx
Transcript

Bachelor Thesis “The Institutional Setup in Turkey”

International Business and Politics

Advisor: Dzmitry Bartalevich

Hand-in date: 22nd of May 2014

Number of pages:

STUs: XXXXXXXXX

Group number 7

Klaus Højland – 070283-xxxx

Viktor Stauning – 120984-xxxx

Martin Kastrup – 080591-xxxx

JeppeMulvadJensen
Highlight

2

Declaration of Authorship

3

Abstract This thesis uses the Varieties of Capitalism to analyse the institutional setup facing firms in

Turkey. Using a conceptualization of institutions as a set of formal or informal rules that actors in

general follow, we examine the Turkish political economy to give a characteristic of the

operational environment for firms in Turkey.

By analysing five spheres of institutional coordination and holding these up against the

ideal types of the Varieties of Capitalism, we identify the characteristics of two distinct

institutional environments in Turkey, which have little operational interaction. Large firms

constitute one segment, which is characterised by measures associated with coordinated market

economies. Small firms populate the other segment and is characterised by fluid labour markets

and little regulation.

We find that each segment lean toward opposite ideal types of the Varieties of Capitalism

but diverge in some respects from the ideal types and have impediments to fruitful interplay.

Substituting for weak labour unions, onerous state regulation on labour protection only apply to

firms that fulfil conditions exclusively found in larger firms. We find that this peculiar feature of

the current institutional equilibrium influences the strategic impetus for both small and large

firms seeking to derive advantages from the institutional environment.

For large firms, investments in workers are protected and small firms benefit from high

flexibility of labour. This has facilitated the growth of a high productivity segment of the

economy while enjoying relatively low unemployment, providing political stability during the

on-going transition. However, due to low levels of education and know-how, small firms fail to

achieve productivity gains and missing fruitful interaction with larger firms who in turn lack an

educated labour force to recruit from.

4

Table  of  Contents  

DECLARATION  OF  AUTHORSHIP  .....................................................................................................................  2  

ABSTRACT  ...............................................................................................................................................................  3  

1.  INTRODUCTION  ................................................................................................................................................  6  

2.  METHODOLOGY  ................................................................................................................................................  9  

2.1  WHY  THE  VOC  ..................................................................................................................................................................  11  

2.2  SINGLE  CASE  STUDY  ........................................................................................................................................................  12  

2.3  SOURCES  .............................................................................................................................................................................  12  

2.4  DELIMITATIONS  ................................................................................................................................................................  14  

3. VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM  .........................................................................................................  17  

3.1  INSTITUTIONS  ...................................................................................................................................................................  17  

3.2  THE  FIRM  ...........................................................................................................................................................................  17  

3.3  THE  FIVE  SPHERES  AND  SIGNIFIERS  .............................................................................................................................  18  

3.3.1  The  Sphere  of  Corporate  Governance  ..............................................................................................................  19  

3.3.2  The  Sphere  of  Industrial  relations  ....................................................................................................................  21  

3.3.3  The  Sphere  of  Vocational  Training  ...................................................................................................................  23  

3.3.4  The  Sphere  of  Inter-­‐firm  Relations  ...................................................................................................................  25  

3.3.5  The  Sphere  of  Intra-­‐firm  Relations  ...................................................................................................................  27  

3.4  INSTITUTIONAL  COMPLEMENTARITIES  ........................................................................................................................  28  

3.5  COMPARATIVE  INSTITUTIONAL  ADVANTAGE  .............................................................................................................  31  

4. TURKEY IN BRIEF  ................................................................................................................................  34  

4.1  THE  STATE  AND  THE  INDUSTRY  PROFILE  ...................................................................................................................  34  

4.2  THE  DIVIDED  LABOUR  MARKET  ....................................................................................................................................  36  

4.3  POLITICAL  LEADERSHIP  AND  THE  EUROPEAN  UNION  ..............................................................................................  38  

5.  THE  FIVE  SPHERES  IN  TURKEY  .................................................................................................................  39  

5.1  CORPORATE  GOVERNANCE  IN  TURKEY  ........................................................................................................................  39  

5.2  INDUSTRIAL  RELATIONS  IN  TURKEY  ............................................................................................................................  43  

5.3  VOCATIONAL  TRAINING  IN  TURKEY  ..............................................................................................................................  48  

5.4  INTER-­‐FIRM  RELATIONS  .................................................................................................................................................  53  

5.5  INTRA-­‐FIRM  RELATIONS  IN  TURKEY  .............................................................................................................................  57  

6.  INSTITUTIONAL  COMPLEMENTARITIES  ................................................................................................  60  

THE  SME  SEGMENT  ................................................................................................................................................................  60  

5

THE  LARGE  ENTERPRISE  SEGMENT  .....................................................................................................................................  63  

7.  COMPARATIVE  INSTITUTIONAL  ADVANTAGE  AND  DISCUSSION  ..................................................  66  

8.  CONCLUSION  ...................................................................................................................................................  69  

10.  BIBLIOGRAPHY  ............................................................................................................................................  72  

6

1. Introduction For more than a decade, Turkey has shown impressive economic performance, averaging 5 per

cent GDP growth per year since 2002. Alongside relative political stability, economic

development has boosted incomes and welfare for millions of Turkish citizens. Structural reforms

stimulated by the EU accession process has increased the role of the private sector and spurred

Turkey to the forefront of globalization and international trade. However, Turkey is still in a

developing phase, with less than half the average disposable income of OECD countries, one in

five Turks is poor, and indices for human development are significantly lower than even the least

developed members of the EU which Turkey strive to become part of (OECD 2014c).

Sustained economic growth and prosperity have many precursors – history, politics,

culture, geography. A key component of economic growth, and the focus of this paper, is the

private sector and the efficiency of firms. It is our view that assessing efficiency and future

viability of firms throughout an economy requires a broader view than GDP growth or

productivity numbers. Each firm and each industry face specific challenges and possibilities, but

the overarching institutional framework in domains such as labour relations, access to finance,

and training outline the operational reality of firms.

To map the specific institutional setup facing firms in Turkey, we will utilize the

theoretical framework of the Varieties of Capitalism. The framework uses two ideal-types of

capitalist coordination and has the firm as main actor. Applications of the framework have for the

most part been to examine highly developed market economies (See for example Hall and

Soskice 2001 and Hancké, Rhodes and Thatcher, 2007). However, we believe that the

redeployment of this theoretical framework on a developing economy while provide a nuanced

view of the institutional setup in Turkey as well as offering a new perspective the theory

underpinning the VoC. The framework organizes the most important elements of the institutional

setup facing firms in five distinct spheres. With characteristics outlined, synergies across spheres

can be identified. The overall efficiency and potential for comparative advantages will become

discernible. Thus, instead of focusing on the characteristics of Turkey as a developing economy,

we hope that the VoC will assist to uncover synergies and disharmonies within the institutional

setup that can inform a further evaluation of the Turkish economy.

The capitalist mode of production in modern market based economies is made possible by

institutions ranging from basic protection of property rights, to complex government

arrangements facilitating upgrades in productivity. We believe that institutions across nations are

7

diverse and that a variety of equilibria are present and viable. This view is supported by the VoC,

which proposes two ideal-types that institutional setups in capitalist economies will resemble.

The VoC is distinguished from most models of comparative capitalism by the notion of two ideal

types that are not convergence points, but rather provide a conceptual framework and reference

points to evaluate data in. We believe that widening the application of the VoC does not

compromise the theoretical underpinnings of the framework, in fact, it is in the spirit of the

original work (Hall and Soskice, 2001: 2) that we apply the framework to Turkey and use the

ideal-types as a vehicle for analysis, while allowing for a unique, Turkish institutional setup.

Mapping the institutional setup in Turkey is necessary to uncover synergies and

disharmonies or discernable trajectories. This can provide a basis for considerations for future

domestic and international policymaking. Turkey is a major importer and exporter, and the EU is

the main export market of Turkey. This makes the economic potential and specifics of the

institutional setup in Turkey of vital interest to European policy makers, other regional and

international trade partners, as well as international investors or business interest. Furthermore,

by applying the framework of the VoC to a country, and indeed a type of country, that has not

been explored to great extent by this framework, we contribute to the development of the VoC.

We hope that these considerations can contribute to the broader discussion and continuing

development of typologies of capitalism. This leads us to the following research question:

What are the characteristics of the Institutional setup in Turkey when analysed using the

ideal-types of the Varieties of Capitalism?

The report is structured as follows: The first section will account for our methodological

considerations. The second section outlines in detail the specifics of the VoC framework and how

we intend to utilize it on Turkey. This will expand on the theoretical and methodological

considerations on choices of signifiers that will inform the analysis. The third section will briefly

deal with key elements of the Turkish society before analysing the five spheres and organizing

these in accordance with the theoretical framework. This section uncovers a deep division in the

Turkish economy with each segment representing different ideal-types.

The fourth section will observe and analyse synergies and disharmonies within and across

the five spheres. Among key findings in this section is the specifics of the divisions in the

Turkish economy: one with large, export-oriented firms with reasonably high productivity, access

to capital, collaborative tendencies, and a workforce protected by state regulation. Across the

divide, a vast quantity of small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) employ almost 80 per cent

8

of the Turkish labour force and most of the massive, informal working population. Unlike for

large firms, the institutional reality for SMEs in Turkey is practically unregulated and is

characterised by low levels of technology, low skill levels, and low productivity.

Lastly, the fifth section will wrap up the analytical narrative, discuss findings, and attempt

to put these in perspective. We find that applying the framework of the VoC shows that the two

segments of the economy operate in divergent environments. The underdeveloped SME segment

has the ability to soak up vast quantities of excess labour, providing political stability and

employment, but standards of living and job security remain low. Large enterprises in Turkey is

driving economic growth enjoying rising productivity as well as job security and rising wages for

employees.

We find that this investigation of the Turkish institutional setup provides a feasible

approach to evaluation of the efficiency and viability of the operational environment for firms in

Turkey.

9

2. Methodology This paper aims to depict the current institutional setup in Turkey. To do so, we will use the VoC

framework to compose an analytical narrative. Employing this framework and developing the use

of ideal-types allow us to simplify and organize our findings and thereby create a coherent story,

which will give a depiction of the current situation facing firms in Turkey today (Jackson 2011:

146). This application of the VoC relies on five spheres to guide the investigation of specific

elements of the Turkish institutional setup, and allow us to focus our research.

This methodology section will develop the core concepts used in this report in detail

and will create a solid foundation for our method of inquiry. We will then argue for the choice of

VoC framework and develop the use of ideal types in a single case study as a complement the

usual comparative use of the theoretical framework. This redeployment of the VoC theories

builds on the arguments made by Hall and Soskice (2001: 35). We will then outline the important

delimitations and justify our choices regarding the limited use of the theoretical framework.

Finally we will discus the sources used as well as the conception of knowledge adopted from

Patrick T. Jackson’s (2011: 126).

Institutions are at the centre of this report. The VoC framework informs our

understanding of institutions as the formal and informal rules of a nation. This paper focuses on

how institutions within the five spheres shape conditions for the firm (Hall and Soskice 2001: 9-

10). In effect, this is the institutional setup that is the focus of this report.

We assume that all actors in the political economy are acting rationally in order to

optimize their strategic position, and the firm is as the principal actors that follow rational

strategic paths, which are optimal in relation to the specific institutional setup (Hall and Soskice

2001: 6). The implication of this is that we focus on the institutions that have relevance for the

firm, since these will inform the strategic choices of the firm (Hall and Soskice 2001: 9-10).

We will create an analytical narrative that depicts Turkeys specific institutional

setup. This approach is dynamic and flexible to encompass the complexities of the institutional

setup as a whole and allow us to describe the particularities of the Turkish institutional setup as

well as simplify it by holding it up against ideal-types. Because we do not set out to trace the

history behind the current institutional setup, nor do we try to predict its future form, the

analytical narrative and thereby analyticism is a useful methodology (Jackson 2011: 114-115).

10

Having justified the choice of VoC we turn to the actual framework in order to

define the ideal-types used for the analysis. Important concepts such as institutions and the firm

are further developed and the five spheres will be introduced and one by one unwrapped and

explicit signifiers identified, which will serve as concrete points of reference and facilitate an

analysis of the institutional characteristics of the case when viewed in the light of the ideal-types.

In short this section will consider the relevant signifiers from the rich VoC literature, drawing up

a set of signifiers that will guide the analysis within the spheres, pinpointing the relevant points of

analysis in Turkey. We sketch out a general portrait of the case, giving context to the detailed and

at times very specific/deep focus of the five spheres guiding us to investigate very specific

elements of the Turkeys institutional setup, avoiding the risk of getting lost in details.

The case is set and the method of inquiry is set, thus we turn to analyse the five

spheres of institutional setup in Turkey. The analysis will follow the signifiers and by observing

these one by one, we will highlight the characteristics of the institutional setup in each sphere.

The five spheres tell by no means a clear and homogeneous narrative, but we will sum up the

most important findings in each of the spheres as we go through them. To create an analytical

narrative of the institutional setup in Turkey we analyse the synergies and complementarities that

cross between the spheres, creating a coherent institutional setup. The final analysis can be seen

as a horizontal analysis of the connecting strings that by careful investigation appear from the

previous vertical analysis of each of the spheres. This analysis reveals a deeply dualistic

institutional setup, which does inform not one but two analytical narratives characterizing

Turkeys institutional setup as a unique combination resembling both of the ideal-types.

Finally we will consider the implications of the strengths and weaknesses of this

institutional setup. E.g. when our findings are viewed in light of VoC literature on institutional

comparative advantage, does a dualistic institutional setup then imply a comparative advantage

because it creates a competitive vibrant network of sub contractors to the large and coordinated

firms dominating Turkey’s export sector?

11

2.1 Why the VoC

In the 2001 seminal volume – “Varieties of Capitalism: The institutional foundations for

comparative advantage” – Hall and Soskice sets out to find specific ideal institutional setup

within five key spheres of an advanced economy in order to categorize these and unearth

synergies and convergence tendencies. Two ideal types are identified, the Coordinated Market

Economy (CME), such as Germany and Japan, and Liberal Market Economy (LME), such as

USA and UK. Neither of the ideal types are better at creating superior macroeconomic

performance and each has their specific comparative institutional advantages. The suggestion is

that any advanced capitalist economy can be located in this spectrum. Furthermore,

macroeconomic performance is related to the degree of coherence within the institutional setup.

The argument by Hall and Soskice is that the closer an economy is to either of the two ideal types

the better it will perform in macroeconomic terms. The following section will account for the

original framework and how it will be applied to create an analytical narrative of the Turkish

institutional setup.

Much critique of the VoC (i.e. Crouch, 2005: 444-445) and of analysis inspired by ideal-

types concerns “unrealistic” assumptions and “oversimplified” conclusions (Jackson, 2011: 154).

We avoid these pitfalls by acknowledging the shortcomings of ideal-types and focusing on using

the framework to provide an orderly arrangement of the findings. The analytical narrative

provided by this paper is shaped by the VoC and employs the vocabulary of the framework.

However, it incorporates case-specific factors to explain peculiarities within this idealization, and

remains open for explanations or setups with no precedence in the literature (Hall and Soskice

2001: 2; Jackson 2011: 112-155). These points of caution are especially true for Turkey, which in

most respects differ substantially from the highly developed market economies that normally are

the subject of VoC analyses. The ability to depart from the theoretical framework to construct the

case-specific narrative thus becomes the strength of the ideal-types. Here it is relevant to

emphasize the precise scope of this paper: To map the institutional framework of Turkey, seen

from the perspective of the firm. The analysis is for the benefit of both domestic and international

business interests, large and small, as well as policy makers evaluating trade-related or other

partnerships. For this purpose, the framework of the VoC serves to deliver a vocabulary and a

12

framework of analysis for an analytical narrative that answer the research question. In the

delimitation section we justify our redeployment of the VoC framework to apply to a single case

study.

2.2 Single Case Study Analyticism (Jackson: 2011) has an ontological presumption, which does not rely on comparison

or falsification of theoretical frameworks. This report aims to create a better understanding of the

specific case at hand, and to utilize and thereby develop upon the vocabulary of the VoC. We do

not seek to make generalizable arguments that go beyond this case, neither do we seek to

empirically verify or falsify the ideal-types. The ideal-types of the VoC are applied to guide the

analysis and these ideal-types are based upon comparative studies and hypotheses regarding

bipolar institutional convergence and institutional comparative advantage. This does not alter the

preconditions of analyticism as the singular case study is unique, but it explains why, at times,

certain elements of the ideal type will be illustrated by taking examples from other cases, most

notably the two archetypes of the VoC, Germany and the US. Furthermore, the methods used to

qualify which of the two ideal-types a variable is leaning toward, is based upon a review of VoC

literature, which represents a variety of VoC analysis done on a wide range of cases (e.g.

Culpepper 2001, Cambel and Pedersen 2007, Goyer 2007, Thatcher 2007, and Feldman 2007).

2.3 Sources The notion of worldly knowledge (Jackson 2011: 195), a requisite for the analyticist approach, is

that despite the study being a singular case study it must contribute to a body of knowledge. In

order for this to be, we first need to define knowledge as we see it. Dewey defines “to know

something” as a shift from random doing, into a deliberate and intelligible doing (1920, in

Jackson 2011: 126). Being able to do something intelligibly enables us to judge whether this

doing is true, which in turn allows us to achieve some end. This implies that knowledge comes

from experience. Ultimately, the goal of experience and knowledge, and thereby science, is to

create and develop tools that can be applied to actual situations. Thus, knowledge is not a

shortcut to a divine truth but serve to create tools that can be applied to better understand reality

in a specific case (Jackson 2011: 126). In short, we see knowledge as experience, and in order for

knowledge to create science, it needs to be applied in a systematic manner to a worldly

13

phenomenon. In this sense our findings are not generalizable, but reliable and replicable within

the specific case. In the following we will describe how the choice of sources will be guided by

our perception of knowledge and method of inquiry.

In accordance with the ontology and principles adopted from analyticism (Jackson

2011), this paper sets out to identify particular institutional configurations by relaying an

analytical narrative employing the ideal-types of the VoC. The framework as well as the

methodological base emphasises the use of relevant and reliable data, organized and analysed to

most accurately describe reality. This implies that there is no inherent hierarchy in the data, as

long as they come from reliable sources.

Two types of sources are used in this report: qualitative and quantitative. This

report makes use of both quantitative reports from credible institutions and qualitative scholarly

articles that are subject to peer-review. These are found in academic databases through extensive

research using key-words and assistance from librarians. Quantitative data are mainly procured

from international and national statistical institutions. We have triangulated most data in this

report in order to ensure reliability and timeliness. Furthermore, we have implemented an

academic minimum standard in regards to secondary sources, meaning that we prioritise sources

from peer-reviewed articles from acknowledged universities, ensuring a further critical

perspective on the bias of our secondary sources.

The judgement of reliability is subjective and it is therefore important to explicitly

state what we understand by reliable sources. We perceive reliability as closely related to

reputation. If a source is dependent on its reputation, and its primary output is reliable

information, the source stand to lose his or her credibility, thus making the source reliable to the

extent that what it stand to lose is greater than what they gain from manipulating data. We have a

variety of sources, which can be split into four types. The first type is peer-reviewed articles and

peer-reviewed books. Credibility and reliability of these are subject to scholarly review and is

beyond questioning by the authors of this paper, albeit due attention is paid to subsequently

published critique or ontological conflicts. The second type of sources are reports and data from

international organisations such as the Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Development

(OECD), the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank (WB) and the International

Labour Organisation (ILO). These are not peer-reviewed but are generally accepted as credible

sources. Furthermore, data is scrutinized daily by a wide diversity of users, subjecting this to

continuous evaluation by a wide range of users. Reputation is important to the IO’s, because their

14

political clout is highly dependent on its reliability. The third type of sources is data from

government institutions such as Turkstat or Turkish ministries. This data can largely be viewed as

credible. However, these institutions might have bias in conclusions or presentation of data due to

political influence. The final type of sources used in this report is web sites of central actors in the

Turkish economy such as labour unions and employer organisations. We use websites of these

organisations to inform the analysis and validate findings in other reports on their involvement in

labour markets. These web sites have clear political agendas and the information is self reported,

which implies heavy bias, thus has to bee treated with caution. However these organisations do

have an interest in projecting their work and influence meaning that certain data can be valuable

as long as it can be confirmed by other sources.

2.4 Delimitations In this section we will outline the limitations and deliberate delimitations. By limitations we

understand limits that the researcher cannot control and needs to work around. Delimitations are

perceived as the choices we actively made to focus this report in answering the research question.

First of the researchers behind this thesis is limited by not mastering the Turkish

language. This is not an issue that has severe consequences because most scholarly knowledge is

published in English. Furthermore numbers and statistics from official organizations are also

published in English. This said the researcher team has encountered documents referred to by

scholars, which have been in the Turkish language creating a barrier in obtaining some

knowledge. The researcher team has also encountered some websites in Turkish regarding the

labour unions and employer organisations, however these sources were encountered in an attempt

to broaden the contextual understanding of scholarly reports and to monitor the latest

development in the field of the study. This introduces a limitation to the actuality of this report

since we have not been able to monitor the latest developments only relayed in Turkish. However

this report concerns the institutional setup, which we believe to be relatively rigid, thus this thesis

is more general than just the latest developments.

Moving on to delimitations brings us to our theoretical framework. The VoC takes a

specific set of signifiers in perspective and leaves out others. This analysis is not a conclusive

study on every aspect of all the institutions in Turkey, but it is broadening the perspective on the

institutions in Turkey seen from the perspective of the firm. This report should be seen as a

15

contribution to a broad debate about the institutions in Turkey. Notable variables that have some

impact on institutions in Turkey, but are not accounted for in depth by the VoC counts issues

related to worker welfare, corruption, regional and local politics, ethnical divisions and relations

to volatile neighbouring states and the EU. This report will need to be complemented in relation

to these variables, thus it cannot stand alone in creating a comprehensive analysis of all aspects of

the institutional setup in Turkey, but it does provide a solid analysis of the institutional setup seen

from the perspective of the firm by focusing on the variables within the five spheres dictated by

the VoC.

VoC is our theoretical framework meaning it provides us with ideal-types and a

vocabulary to understand and analyse the institutional setup in Turkey. In VoC, a significant

element is comparison with other countries. This brings us to a second delimitation, because we

have chosen not to compare Turkey to another country, thus removing a step in the VoC

approach. We argue that it is more relevant to understand the unique case of Turkey against the

ideal-types of the VoC, than comparing Turkey to another country (E.g. Mexico). If we were to

do such a comparison we would risk getting into a swirl of differences, clouding the real aim of

this report – understanding and characterizing the institutional setup in Turkey. Several scholars,

prior to this report, have focused on one case and not a country comparison, paving the

theoretical path in regard to a VoC single case study (e.g. Pedersen and Cambel: 2007). Hall and

Soskice themselves highlight that the VoC is “ a set of contentions that open up new research

agendas (Hall and Soskice 2001: 2) rather than it closes them down by dictating a rigid

theoretical approach. We argue that the first step is to understand Turkey, and this understanding

will provide the needed background to evaluate the relevance of comparing Turkey to other

political economies. Comparative studies of Turkey is by no means irrelevant, we merely argue

that in order to find a valid comparison, we need to understand Turkey’s institutional setup,

which is the aim of this analytical narrative.

The last delimitation concerns time and thereby institutional change. The VoC also

focus on institutional change, which has received much scholarly criticism (Crouch 2005: 444),

because the VoC ‘lack focus’ on why institutions are as they are, but instead focuses on where

the institutions ought to develop toward in order to become the most efficient setup. We do not

engage in this debate, because we do not want to trace the history behind the current institutional

setup, nor do we want to predict its future form.

16

We focus on a snapshot in time to enlighten interested actors about the Turkish

institutional setup. We do believe that institutions are rigid and evolve over longer periods of

time, which means that the analysis of an institutional setup delimited in time (i.e. a snapshot) is

relevant, as long as one notes that this report will not be an historical justification of the current

institutional setup, nor will it predict or make recommendations to how Turkey can improve its

efficiency by pursuing a certain set of institutional changes. This report aims to provide an

analytical narrative informing stakeholders about the synergies and disharmonies of the current

institutional setup in Turkey.

17

3. Varieties of Capitalism This section will account for the original framework by defining institutions, the role of the firm,

the spheres and its signifiers. Hence it will outline the vocabulary and the ideal institutional

setups that within each sphere will depict the ideal-types by observing typical characteris.

3.1 Institutions This section will define institutions, as we understand them, in order to clarify how

we understand the institutional setup and use it in this report. This report adopts the institutional

understanding from Hall and Soskice (2001), who defines institutions as “… a set of rules, formal

or informal, that actors generally follow, whether for normative, cognitive, or material reasons,

and organizations as durable entities with formally recognized members, whose rules also

contribute to the institutions of the political economy” (Hall and Soskice 2001: 9). This definition

allows for a wide interpretation of which factors are relevant to a particular setup of institutions.

A point emphasised is the role of deliberative institutions often found in CMEs. These are the

institutions that encourage actors to engage in networks with discussion, collaboration and

compromises, rather than the arms-length relationships of contracts and hard laws found in

LMEs. Furthermore the definition and VoC theory in general puts an emphasis on culture, history

and informal rules as being the foundation under the institutional setup.

3.2 The firm In the VoC analysis the firm is the central actor, and Hall and Soskice assumes that

the firm is a rational agent (Hall and Soskice 2001: 6), we will stick to this assumption, as it is a

crucial element of how the synergies between the spheres work. According to Hall and Soskice

the firm is at the forefront of experiencing technological shifts and adapting to shifts in supply

and demand. Thus for any country that base their economy on the market the firm will be the first

to react to changes in the market economy. Hence, countries that have any of the two ideal

institutional setups will give its firms the best possible settings for reacting to changes in the

market. The five spheres, which are the cornerstones of the VoC theory, are selected on the basis

of the relations that the firm engage in. The firm engage in a wide range of relationships, inside

and outside the firm. According to Hall and Soskice firms experience coordination problems with

18

employees, suppliers, customers, governments and so forth, each with different motives creating

a potential for coordination problems. The nature of the coordination problems vary and how they

are solved varies from economy to economy. Coordination problems occur in each of the five

spheres and will be elaborated in next section, one sphere at a time.

As Hall and Soskice accounts for, most OECD countries fall into the categories of

CME and LME. In effect they solve the coordination problems using market based or solution

based solutions. The CME relies on non-market relationships, such as unions, business

associations; network based monitoring and long-term strategic coordination between firms and

banks. By contrast, the LME relies on contractual agreements, antitrust legislation, publicly

available financial data, and adjustment to supply and demand (Hall and Soskice 2001).

3.3 The Five Spheres and signifiers We chose Varieties of Capitalism as our ideal type of theoretical framework due to

its ability to organise the political economy of Turkey into smaller, comprehensible parts and its

focus on the firm. The foundational work of Hall and Soskice (2001) laid out five spheres of

analysis. Each sphere is constructed by a careful analysis of relevant signifiers. Analysis of these

signifiers will guide the research for specific empirical data and mechanisms and will be

organised in relation to the ideal types. As outlined in the above sections, the Turkish economy

and specific institutional setup is unique in its entirety. Individual factors and mechanisms do,

however, resemble those of other market economies, either directly or indirectly. For instance,

the huge informal sector of Turkey has characteristics of no labour protection and wages are

entirely set by the market – these characteristics are market based corresponding to the LME

type. On the contrary, the formal sector has recently introduced a very strict labour protection

regime and very high minimum wages – characteristics of a coordinated economy. Together

these two signifiers tell an intelligible and coherent story, albeit the specifics are inherently

unique to Turkey. Which signifiers we deem relevant is based on more recent VoC literature that

uses these in their analysis. Each sphere will be outlined below together with a detailed

pinpointing of relevant signifiers following each of the spheres in order to guide the later analysis

of the institutional setup in Turkey.

19

3.3.1 The Sphere of Corporate Governance

The first sphere in the framework of the VoC is corporate governance, which refers

to the financial arrangements of firms in an economy. For both SMEs and large companies,

corporate governance covers ownership arrangements and access to capital. For large or listed

companies corporate governance also refers to board structure and the often much more complex

ownership arrangements. The coordination problems facing the firm are greatly influenced of

whether it is publicly listed or not. However, all firms face the coordination problem of ready

finance for projects (Hall and Soskice 2001: 7). The overarching legal framework, structure of

capital markets, investor relationships, as well as the specifics of monitoring together constitutes

the institutional setup of corporate governance.

The CME solutions to corporate governance, described by Hall and Soskice, closely

resembles the “insider system” known from literature on corporate governance. A 1999 paper on

Corporate Governance systems by Maher and Andersson (OECD 1999) describes the insider

system as characterised by concentrated ownership or voting rights with extensive inter-firm

relationships and corporate holdings. Furthermore, cross-shareholding, pyramidal structures and

close relationships with banks are other key features. The relationships between investors and

firms are a lot closer, and often the investor has intimate knowledge about the strategy of the

firms before they invest. Hall and Soskice (2001) describe how reputation plays an important role

between the investor and the firm. Capital can therefore be tied in long-term strategic business

plans aiming to increase economic performance over many years, rather than immediate results.

Maher and Anderson note that these are typical of Western continental Europe, Japan and Korea.

Most large German corporations are embedded in extensive networks with banks and other

sources of finance playing a crucial role in strategy approval, often with seats on the supervisory

boards of firms. Another key feature is interlocking directorship, where board members serve on

boards of several firms in the same industry in order to coordinate activities across industries.

In LMEs, corporate governance is based on marked based and arms-length

relations. Access to capital for large companies comes from financial institutions and institutional

investors, bond markets and stock markets. For smaller companies, equity funds, angel investors

and other risk willing capital is prevalent. Monitoring of performance is required by law and

rigorously enforced through publicly available disclosures of financial data. Furthermore,

investors use this information to base decisions on, meaning that financial possibilities for the

firm depends on the situation of the firm as it is reflected in the market. Inter-firm relations in

20

LMEs are characterised by intense competition, and an underperforming company is at risk of a

hostile take-over. Boards in LMEs represent shareholder interests and function primarily as a

check on the executive, but have little say in day-to-day activities. The following signifiers for

corporate governance are based on the above characteristics of the LME and CME within the

sphere of corporate governance and on relevant VoC literature (Hall and Soskice 2001; Börsch

2007; Goyer 2007; Feldman 2006).

Access to finance is a key component of corporate governance. An indicator for this

is stock market capitalization as percentage of GDP, which is widely used as a proxy for

importance of financial markets as source of capital for firms. In LMEs such as the US and the

UK, stock market capitalization as percentage of GDP average 112 per cent and 122 per cent

(foreign firms listed in the UK and the US pushes it above 100 per cent). In Germany the number

was 44 per cent and in other CMEs such as Japan and France it is 77 per cent. For emerging

market economies the number is even lower – the Next 11 has an average of 38 per cent (World

Bank 2014). Other major sources of finance for companies in industrialised countries are

institutional investors, other financial intermediaries as well as corporate bonds.

Stock market sophistication is likewise used as an indicator of coordinated or

market based solutions to corporate governance by the literature (Hall and Soskice 2001; Börsch

2007; Goyer 2007; Feldman 2006). While stock market sophistication is not a generic term per

se, the World Economics Forum has developed a ratio based on a composite index of availability

and affordability of financial services, financing through the local equity market, ease of access

to loans, venture capital availability, restriction on capital flows, soundness of banks, regulation

of securities exchanges and legal rights (WEForum 2008). This paper will use this ratio as a

signifier for corporate governance.The legal framework and structure of the board of directors,

coupled with analysis of occurrence of interlocking directorships are other crucial indicators.

There is no direct measure for board structure, other than descriptive analysis of the workings of

these. The role of the board in CMEs and LMEs differs extensively. In CMEs, two-tier boards

with representation of a diversity of interests are common. Furthermore, In LMEs, the board

functions primarily as a check on the CEO and the overall strategy making sure that the firm

operates in the interest of shareholders. While this is also to some degree true of CMEs, boards

can be much more involved in the day-to-day operations and are often not bound by legal

requirements. In LMEs, it is common to see one-tier boards representing shareholder interests

with ruled based arms-length relationship with the executive management. Common for both is

21

that the principal role of a board of directors is to separate ownership and control, in order to

overcome agency problems and to align interests of owners and managers. Atakan, Oba and

Ozsou (2010) argue that despite intentions of the legal framework, corporate governance in

emerging economies rarely resembles those of developed markets. In developed economies –

LME and CME alike – corporate governance is equity-market based. Emerging economies are

typically of family-based control systems. A key difference is that a major source of equity is

from the family instead of financial markets. This bridges the agency issue between managers

and owners and of monitoring, but presents an issue of minority shareholders vis-à-vis majority

shareholders (Atakan, Oba and Ozsou 2010).

Lastly, ownership structure of firms is analysed and covers the following. The level

of concentrated ownership, where high levels indicate coordination and non-market deliberations.

The market for corporate control and frequency of hostile take-overs, leaving firms in an LME at

constant risk of these, in CMEs they are rare or non-existent. Emerging economies are often

characterised by limited importance of autonomous financial institutions as equity is raised

within the family or groups, which is similar to the insider system and the CME.

3.3.2 The Sphere of Industrial relations

The second sphere in VoC is industrial relations. In this sphere the central

coordination problem facing the firms is the negotiation of wage levels and working conditions.

These are typically negotiated between the employee and the employer or the trade unions and

the employer’s organisation (Hall and Soskice 2001: 7). The coordination problems arise due to

different priorities. On the one hand there is the companies that has one set of priorities – profit,

efficiency and competitive strength – and on the other hand you have the employees with their

priorities – personal optimization, working hours and salary increase (Hall and Soskice 2001).

One cannot exclude that some firms are completely aligned with their employees’ priorities, but

in general one will detect conflicting interests between employers and employees, which is the

reason for the existence of labour unions and global labour organisations or unions like the

International Labor Organization (ILO). The coordination problems concern the productivity of

the firm and thereby its competiveness. “The wage and productivity will determine the success of

the firm and rates of unemployment or inflation in the economy as a whole” (Hall and Soskice

2001: 7). Hence the coordination problems therefore lie at the heart of the firm’ interest.

22

In typical CMEs where unionization is high, wage levels and working conditions

are coordinated between employer or industry organisations and trade unions. This will often

result in higher minimum wages. Higher wage levels are also a subject of negotiation and will

provide a stable wage level for specialised workers. Coordination of wage levels and working

conditions create spill over effects in the sphere of vocational training as it protects firms’

investments in their workers from poaching by other firms. Hence, increasing firm’ interest for

investing in vocational training of their employees. This makes it easier to hang on to employees

with high levels specialised skills. Additionally the coordinated solutions often affect the intra-

firm relations by having employees’ representatives on the supervisory board in firms. Hence the

coordinated solution to wage levels and working conditions can be complementary across the

spheres of vocational training and intra-firm relations (Hall and Soskice 2001: 24-25).

When wage levels and working conditions are solved through a market-based

solution as in LMEs, the employer and individual worker negotiate directly. Low unionization

renders unions with much less resources and influence, and it is up to the individual workers to

secure themselves. Employer organisations are often also more scattered than in the CMEs,

leaving them less powerful. Strict anti-trust regulation and enforcement furthermore limits inter-

industry coordination. The effect of weak trade unions and employer organisations is a

dependency of market competition between firms on wage levels and working conditions, to

secure the right level of wages and benefits. Additionally employment and inflation levels will be

more dependent on the macroeconomic policy since the labour market actors do not negotiate

overall wage levels (Soskice 2007: 119; Franzese 2001: 104-105).

Following a market-based solution to industrial relations creates a labour market in

which firms are able to hire and fire easily. Firms will thus discourage long-term employment

contracts and instead take advantage of the current opportunities in the market. Additionally the

vocational sphere tends to create general skills that the hire and fire mentality in the labour

market encourage. Furthermore the inter-firm relations sphere will often be affected, by the

flexible labour market and the use of general skills, since these lead to knowledge sharing when

workers moves from one company to another. Hence the market based solution to wage levels

and working conditions can be complementary across the spheres of vocational training and inter-

firm relations. (Hall and Soskice 2001: 29-30)

When using the VoC to investigate how a country solves its coordination problems

within the sphere of industrial relations, the following signifiers are used to determine whether

23

the country use coordinated or market based solutions. The first signifier is the power of

employer organisations, which needs to be investigated in order to qualify the representative

strength of firms in negotiations in the institutional setup about wage levels and working

conditions. This signifier will be investigated using number of members of the employer

organisation. Additionally this signifier will be investigated through economic output the

members of an employer organisation represent. Furthermore the ability of employer

organisations to create coordinated solutions within the five spheres will be investigated.

The second signifier regards how workers organise themselves. This will be

investigated using membership numbers in the largest trade unions, which will give an indication

of which labour unions are important. Once these are located, comparing their numbers to the

total unionisation in Turkey can assess their bargaining power. Furthermore an investigation of

the regulation that labour unions are subjected to will describe its bargaining power in

negotiations. Additionally this signifier will be investigated through the overall unionisation

numbers, which indicates the representative power of trade unions in collective bargaining.

Furthermore the ability of labour unions to create coordinated solutions within the five spheres

will be investigated. In effect these two signifiers will enable us to analyse the powers of actors in

the sphere of industrial relations (Hall and Soskice 2001: 24-25 and 29-30).

Following these signifiers a third signifier analyse how external factors influence

the above mentioned coordination problems. In effect the analysis will investigate if external

factors influence wage levels or the working conditions. External factors will be international

organisations that have the power to put pressure on the state to implement new regulation that

influence the coordination problems (Thatcher 2007: 147).

3.3.3 The Sphere of Vocational Training

The third sphere in the VoC is vocational training, which focuses on the skill base and training

systems for the labour force. The main coordination problem facing firms is having a workforce

with the necessary skills. Additionally the workers are faced with the problem of deciding in

which skills to invest in (Hall and Soskice 2001: 7). The choice of which leave consequences for

the firm. The institutional setup of an economy can either facilitate industry specific skills or

general skills. Estevez-Abe, Iversen and Soskice (2001: 145-148) define skills in three

categories: industry specific skills, firm specific skills and general skills. It is relevant to

distinguish between these as they differ substantially in portability. Firm specific skills are the

least portable and are generally obtained through on-the-job training and only relevant to that

24

specific firm. Industry specific skills are typically obtained through vocational schools and

apprenticeships, resulting in certificates, which are acknowledged within specific trades. Industry

specific skills are still in the specific category but more portable in the sense that they are widely

applicable in an industry and therefore useful for more than one firm. General skills are skills that

are acknowledged across all firms and industries and are typically associated with university

degrees and undergraduate qualifications. Specific skills, both firm and industry, are associated

with the CME and the general skills with the LME.

LMEs tend to facilitate institutions that promote general skills because employment

and unemployment protection is low. With little protection, workers find that the best way of

securing themselves is by obtaining high general education levels, making one-self attractive to a

variety of employers (Estevez-Abe, Iversen and Soskice 2001: 162). It enables workers to move

more easily from one firm to another. The institutional setup in LMEs favours a different strategy

for the firm. In the LME poaching are high and job tenures are short, which supports a system

where the educational responsibility lies with the employee who wants to be generally educated

thus opening oneself up to more job possibilities. This also indicates that the government

facilitates the educational and vocational training system. Every firm is basically competing alone

and cannot bear the cost of educating its own employees, especially not in the case of the LME

where poaching is often practiced.

CMEs tend to obtain its firm and industry specific skills by decentralized vocational

training coordinated by industrial organizations and labour unions. These organisations are able

to obtain intimate and relevant information from firms facilitating information circulation and

deliberation. Labour unions coordinate with the state in order to encourage firms to incur the

costs of vocational training (Culpepper 2001: 275-306). The idea is that in order for firms to

realize that they will gain from investing in employee’s skills, the state is required to create the

incentives initially. Once firms have realized the benefits, the state will withdraw subsidies and

decentralization is complete. The underlying assumption made by Culpepper is that “employers

and unions know best the requirements of a firm-based skill system, so it should be left to

regulate themselves, with minimal state intervention” (Culpepper 2001: 279).

Skills can be difficult to measure because they are not directly observable. Estevez-

Abe, Iversen and Soskice (2001: 169) use job tenure as indirect measures of skill level. Longer

job tenures indicate that employees have their careers bound up in specific firms. If careers are

connected to a single firm or industry, specific skills become good investments for workers.

25

Conversely, if job tenures are short workers prefer general skills, which are more portable. This

notion rests on an assumption that the employee looses ground if he/she starts to obtain specific

skills in relation to other employees not doing this. “Since most skills are maintained by use,

refreshment, and updating, the employee’s marketable skills will deteriorate.” (Estevez-Abe,

Iversen and Soskice 2001: 151).

The employee will therefore demand a certain level of protection before making an

investment in obtaining asset specific skills. This protection usually takes form of employment

protection, unemployment protection, and wage protection. (Estevez-Abe, Iversen and Soskice

2001: 150). Employment protection has a tendency to promote firm specific skills because it

ensures the employee reasonable conditions for holding on to his or hers job, making the

investment in the firm specific skills less risky. Unemployment protection will on the other hand

tend to promote industry specific skills, because it buys the employees time to relocate within the

industry if employment with a firm ends.

Employees are not the only ones that demand protection of their investments –

firms do as well. High skill levels are a product of educational and vocational training, which

comes at a cost, either directly when the employer pays, or indirectly through lost hours. The

employer will therefore be worried about poaching and demand protection of his or hers

investment. To convince an employer to take on this cost, the employee must be sure to return to

the firm putting newly acquired skills to good use by increasing efficiency, introducing new

knowledge or improving processes. In order to solve these coordination problems unions or other

institutional bodies needs to ensure or facilitate a common understanding of wages and cost

sharing, thus addressing the risk of investing in skills (Culpepper 2001).

Signifiers for vocational training are the general education system as well as

coordination of training efforts by the state, industry, industry associations, labour unions or other

employee associations. Furthermore, employment protection and unemployment benefits require

analysis, as well as job tenures. Lastly, dominant industries can influence tendencies and

requirements to vocational training.

3.3.4 The Sphere of Inter-firm Relations

The fourth sphere is inter-firm relations, where the central coordination problem facing firms

concern inputs for production, demand for products, access to market information and

participation in knowledge sharing (Hall and Soskice 2001: 7). The latter point is a point that is

26

becoming more important due to globalisation and this has made it a crucial parameter in

international competition. A modern economy within the OECD has to focus on how to create

technological advance in order to keep up and gain a competitive advantage.

In CMEs, supply and demand rely more on reputational and coordinated solutions

than contracts and enforcement by courts (Casper 2001: 387-388). In Germany, courts follow a

regulatory approach in disputes, which seek to balance risk between parts in the contract and

considering imbalances. The effect is that courts look beyond the written word of the contract and

considers intent, thereby facilitating coordination of the inter-firm relationship (Casper 2001:

390). In the LMEs, contractual disputes are solved with heavy emphasis on the written word

rather than intent of the contract, and courts resolve conflicts more to the point of the contract.

The goal of this approach is to protect the rights of each actor to form and participate in contracts.

Thus, information of actors becomes a source of competition in the process of forming and

participating in contracts. Using this approach courts seek to enforce the contract alone, which

supports the market-based solution of the contractual relation (Casper 2001: 390). Additionally,

LMEs enforce antitrust laws extensively to prevent firms from using non-competitive means such

as size and political power to squeeze smaller competitors (Hall and Soskice 2001: 30-31). LMEs

thus actively combat coordination within and across industries, and rely on competition instead.

In LMEs, due to the flexible labour market, knowledge transfer between firms is

mainly from movement of workers between firms. Large public research institutions breeds

workers at the cutting edge of technology, which transfers knowledge to the private sector.

Additionally development of knowledge comes from the competitive process of licensing

innovations. In LMEs, formal standard setting is rarely possible due to lack of strength of the

employer organisations and anti-trust legislation. Thus, the firm that come up with the best

solution to the market will be able to license the production to other firms leading to knowledge

transfers (Hall and Soskice 2001: 30-31).

When it comes to knowledge sharing in CMEs, firms have little knowledge transfer

from movement of workers from one company to another. Instead, firms engage in collaborative

research projects and joint ventures to secure the benefits of knowledge sharing. Additionally, the

state participates in or subsidises research projects to facilitate knowledge development and

sharing. In order to direct resources and effort in the most optimal direction employer

organisations use its collected firm specific data to support the process (Hall and Soskice 2001:

26). Hence, a coordinated solution to knowledge sharing is furthered by the use of coordinated

27

solutions in the spheres of vocational training and industrial relations. In effect specific skills and

the industry wide negotiated wage levels tend to generate a need for coordinated knowledge

sharing in order for it to exist.

Applying the analysis of the VoC to a country within the inter-firm relations sphere,

the following signifiers is used to determine whether a country uses a coordinated or market

based solution. The first signifier is how contractual relations are solved. This signifier

investigates the use of contracts and how these are enforced. In effect this signifier reveals how

firms conduct business together and how supply and demand is negotiated. The second signifier

is the strength of business organisations and to what extent these participate in collaboration and

coordination. As in the case with industrial relations this signifier will be using number of

members of the employer organisations and the economic output that the members of an

employer organisation represent. The third signifier is how knowledge is dispersed throughout

the economy.

3.3.5 The Sphere of Intra-firm Relations

The fifth sphere of the VoC is intra-firm relations. The central problem facing firms is to ensure

that its employees work in the best possible way to advance the objects of the firm. Each

employee in a firm will in due time come to possess firm specific skills and information.

However, in a capitalist economy, most employees are not owners, and thus require an incentive

to employ these skills and information in such a way that maximizes profits for the firm. Hall and

Soskice mention issues such as adverse selection and moral hazard. Additionally employees

become reservoirs of knowledge that can be to the benefit of the management if it is not withheld

(Hall and Soskice 2001: 7). Thus the two main coordination problems for firms in this sphere are

how to secure internal knowledge sharing and to determine the type of management system.

In LMEs, employees have little or no protection from legislation and collective

bargaining agreements. The lack of extensive protection gives the opportunity to ensure hard

work through the threat of firing. The ability to hire and fire combined with other elements in the

LME leaves the executive management of the firms with high degrees of autonomy. This also

translates into the overall management structure of firms in LMEs, which tend to have a structure

that gives unilateral control to the manager, which makes the CEO capable of making decisions

on his own, independent of the board. Furthermore, employees are incentivised to employ as

much of their specific firm knowledge to the benefit of the company in order to pursue higher

wages, as these are not coordinated centrally.

28

In coordination-based economies, employees are protected by legislation and

collective bargaining agreements making it difficult to lay off employees or requiring the

employer to pay costly severance fees. Furthermore, the employer is often required to pay for a

range of social services. Managers therefore have constraints on autonomy, sometimes followed

by employee representation on supervisory boards, as is the case of Germany. The CEO will

hence seldom enjoy universal control in the company, but needs to get his strategies approved by

a supervisory board. This board will often include employee representatives, other industrial

executives, owners and large investors. The employee representatives and other actors that

participate in the board will then have an interest in the viability of the long-term strategy, and

less interest on short-term management issues. This aligns their incentives with that of managers

if the overarching institutional infrastructure – notably a peaceful market for corporate control

and of capital being patient – is present.

A VoC analysis of Estonia and Slovenia by Feldman (2006) finds that average job

tenure is a useful signifier for intra-firm relations, where high tenures are indicative of a CME. In

general, a committed relationship between employer and the employee translates into a regime in

which employers and employees are committed to each other, facilitating investment in firm-

specific skills and human capital. Knowledge dispersion throughout the economy happens

through industry collaboration and employer associations

Noted by Hall and Soskice in the original volume, an indicator for coordination or

market-based solutions is the capacity for managers to make decisions unilaterally. That is, when

there is little employee protection or costly severance fees, and no need to consult employees or

employee representatives in matters of strategy. Furthermore, labour force protection and

unionisation are likewise important signifiers. Signifiers for intra-firm relations are therefore

executive autonomy, labour force protection and job tenure. For economies with limited

influence from unions, other signifiers for worker protection such as minimum wages and level of

wage coordination are likewise useful for analysis.

3.4 Institutional complementarities The notion of institutional complementarities is a key part of the VoC framework and informs the

second part of the analysis of the institutional setup in Turkey. A complementary good in the

classical economic sense is when an increase in the price of one good depresses demand for

29

another – a familiar example is bread and butter. Hall and Soskice extend this principle to the

institutions of the political economy. “Here, two institutions can be said to be complementary if

the presence or efficiency of one increases the returns from or efficiency of another” (Hall and

Soskice 2001: 17). As outlined in the previous section, CMEs and LMEs coordinate activities

based on a coordinated approach or a market approach. The analysis of the five spheres will be

analysed in relations to its institutional complementarities. Hence, observing key cross-sphere

mechanism

An example of an institutional complementarity from the ideal CME type of

Germany is within industrial relations and corporate governance. In the ideal CME type labour

unions provide protection for workers, across these spheres, allowing them to invest in firm

specific skills, and employer organisations, which collaborate on training systems, wages and

joint R&D ventures to minimize costs and eliminate fears of poaching (Goyer, 2007). This is

complemented by a corporate governance regime of patient capital and close supervision and

involvement by banks. During downturns, financial markets that emphasize current profitability

will demand lay-offs and the firm will be at risk for hostile takeovers.

For the LME, radical innovation and high general skill levels complement a flexible

labour market with high portability, as is the case in the US. Following critique for narrow-

minded focus on the specific setups in ideal-typologies in the VoC framework, Hancké, Rhodes

and Thatcher (2007) argue that the approach allows for a great variety in the specifics of

complementary mechanisms, but in practice, all can be characterised as either of the coordinated

kind, or of the market-based kind. Echoing this, Höpner (2005) accounts for different

mechanisms of institutional adjustments across countries as being conceivable and an integrated

part of the VoC approach. The aim of Hall and Soskice was not to present a final theory of the

specifics of the divergences, rather it was to point out that there is a divergence and not a

convergence, and that the overall equilibria will consist of complements. Substantial differences

in the specific institutional setup, which in practice works similarly is especially true for those

countries characterised as CMEs. For instance in Japan, Höpner (2005) describes a mode of

production related to the formation of long-term production teams. Organisation of workers in

teams makes it difficult to monitor individual workers, introducing the risk of moral hazard. This

is overcome by a credible contract of long employment, coupled with a culture of strong work

ethic, and the threat of liquidation by banks if the firm underperforms making it in the interest of

the worker to fully utilize firm-specific knowledge and innovative capabilities (Höpner 2005). In

30

practice, this resembles the German system of coordinated efforts, but the specifics and

underlying culture is quite different. The key point is that the German and Japanese system are

different in the particulars, but similar overall, and neither setup is necessarily superior, unless

disharmonies is rampant. A theoretical disharmony could be to remove the strong work ethic or

threat of liquidation out of the equation. This would potentially induce workers not to work their

best and a new solution would need time to develop and settle. Until a new equilibrium that

ensures alignment of incentives is found, the economy will function sub optimally.

The Turkish institutional setup is still evolving and the economy retains

characteristics of a developing economy with an abundance of cheap, low skilled labour. This

allows for alternative equilibria and alternative disharmonies. An example of an alternative

equilibrium is outlined by VoC analysis of Denmark, in which Campbell and Pedersen (2007)

argue that a labour market configuration of low protective, generous and government provided

unemployment benefits, and extensive re-training systems create a flexible labour market with

high levels of specific skills, and a correspondingly unique industrial mix. Supporting the notion

of alternative configurations, Börsch (2007) conducts a VoC analysis of Switzerland, and argues

that a regulatory institutional framework strongly resembling that of market based coordination,

does not necessarily entail a regime of hire-and-fire and low specialisation. In Switzerland,

despite a regulatory framework with little protection and low unionisation, there is a strong

tradition of peaceful industrial relations and long tenure. The strong culture has without support

of the institutional setup developed patterns of informal and voluntary networks, in effect

rendering Swiss intra-firm relations and skill development as of the coordination-based kind.

Following the basic notion of institutional complementarities the VoC states one

central claim regarding institutional change and equilibria: the setup of one institution breeds

complements in others. For instance, in a CME, there can be a high degree of collaboration

between business associations on vocational training. This will be conducive to collaboration on

wage setting and working conditions, as well as research projects or joint ventures. Furthermore,

these firms will push governments to defer from enforcing strict anti-trust legislation. Another

example is that patient capital complements high labour protection in that availability of capital is

not dependent on quarterly financial performance. This will push governments to make hostile

takeovers by foreign firms difficult or impossible, to ensure stability during downturns. This

creates a degree of complementary institutional path-dependence, resulting in institutional

31

clustering, consolidating the divergence, and making it possible to identify economies on a range

between LME and CME.

When assessing complementarities in Turkey we will allow for significant

divergences from the ideal type. Furthermore, dominant industries have yet to consolidate fully

and the stage of development in Turkey is currently at the potential for significant divergences

from any path dependency predicted by the VoC approach. Institutional developments in Turkey

are still heavily influenced by volatile domestic and regional politics, culture and religion, as well

as influence from the EU and other international actors. Thus, the aim is to identify possible

unique synergies or potential shortcomings in accordance with the objective of mapping the

current institutional setup in the language of the VoC.

3.5 Comparative Institutional Advantage In the VoC framework, the concept of comparative institutional advantage brings together the

five spheres of coordination, their institutional complementarities, national economic

performance and industrial mix. The concept builds on another idea from classical economics –

comparative advantage in international trade. The gist of the classical theory is that a country will

specialise in those products that they have a comparative advantage in and trade with countries

that has a comparative advantage in something else. This enables trade for countries that have no

absolute advantages, to the benefit of both trading partners (Krugman, Obstfeld and Melitz 2012:

56). To supplement this and explain the emergence and success of national industrial clusters, the

VoC approach states that countries have a specific institutional setup that favours specific

industries and specific kinds of innovation, making them competitive in industries that work well

within this institutional framework. Furthermore, these countries will attain higher degrees of

competitive advantages corresponding to the level of coherence of these institutions (Hall and

Soskice 2001: 38). The concept of industrial clustering is well accounted for in agglomeration

theory – put simply, companies that make related products tend to cluster, be that the intensely

competitive software firms in Silicon Valley or incrementally innovative and collaborative

mechanical engineering industries in Baaden-Würtemberg. The contribution of the VoC

framework is to uncover the reasons why these specific clusters appear in a particular nation at a

particular institutional equilibrium. Specifically, the comparative institutional advantage concept

in the VoC framework seeks to explain which institutional setup that foster a specific clustering.

Put shortly, industries benefiting from coordination and collaboration will cluster in CMEs and

32

CMEs will nurture these industries best by solving all their coordination problems by CME

means (Hall and Soskice 2001: 38).

Assessing comparative advantages for a still developing and emerging economy

such as the Turkish, presents significant challenges when using the framework of the VoC, as the

framework takes certain levels of institutional coherence and equilibria for granted. The result is

that the equilibria attained might lack precedent in VoC literature.

A key claim of the notion of comparative advantages in the VoC literature is that

economies with homogenous institutions perform better than economies with heterogeneous

institutions. The logic behind this theory is as follows: with two identical firms, the one that face

institutional barriers, however small, will perform worse. A cutting-edge software firm operating

in Germany will face issues acquiring high skilled labour without signing long-term contracts,

and will have difficulties luring them from their current position due to industry wage bargaining.

Furthermore, risk-willing capital is harder to come by. These can be surmountable challenges,

and the government can provide institutions that ameliorate difficulties and it is possible that it

will be cheaper than to trade due to transportation costs. However, it will still amount to a barrier,

and this theoretical firm will produce at greater total cost than a similar, theoretical firm in an

LME. The economy would thus benefit from increasing institutional coherence and focusing on

industries that benefit from this. The Turkish economy does present a degree of departure from

this element of comparative institutional advantage as it is characterised by a sharp duality, and

the notion of superior performance with homogenous institutions is challenged, as the two

segments benefit from different institutional setups.

Barry and Nienhueser (2010) investigate German aviation industry, which exhibits

dualistic tendencies that as such present an anomaly in the archetype. Findings suggest that there

is a tentative convergence in some industries toward LME solutions due to liberalization across

the European Union. A crucial difference to the Turkish case, however, is that the low-cost

segment in Germany employs equally productive workers and based on voluntary opt-outs by

smaller firms to compete in niches with different employment conditions. This is not at all the

case in Turkey, where the low cost segment is much less productive, and it is a lack of human

development and capital stock that inhibits movement to the coordinated segment.

The last element in comparative institutional advantage is that an economy leaning

either way has different capacities for innovation. An economy with the LME characteristics of

high levels of general education, fluid labour markets, and risk-willing capital will have the

33

institutional complementarities that facilitate extraordinary performance in rapidly changing

high-tech sectors such as pharmaceuticals or software. In CMEs incremental innovation in

industries such as mechanical engineering, which is characterised by long-term investments as

well as benefits from collaboration within the industry, and with public research facilities. While

Turkey has low levels of technology and still struggling to catch up with Western production

processes, it is relevant to assess which industries are dominant in Turkey, as these will still

benefit from an institutional setup that serves its needs.

To sum up, the section on comparative advantage will serve to highlight the

relevant synergies and disharmonies as well as the most notable elements of the specific

institutional setup in Turkey.

34

4. Turkey in Brief In 2014 The International Monetary Fund (IMF) voiced a concern about Turkey being able to

keep a GDP growth by four or five per cent annually (Dombey 2014: 1). In the 2000s Turkey has

had impressive growth rates compared to other OECD members, but the IMF warned that

political stability was dependent on the growth staying at this high level. Turkey currently has a

population of 74 million (Turkstat 2014a) and a GDP of $1561bn USD making it the 17th largest

economy in the world (OECD Statistics 2013a). Turkey is still a developing economy struggling

to catch up with industrialised Western economies. In 2023, the current government aims to

celebrate the 100th year, since the birth of the republic, with an average income per capita of

23.000 USD. According to IMF, this is highly optimistic with an average income per capita in

2014 of 10.000 USD. This goal demands higher growth rates than the four to five per cent

annually (Dombey 2014: 1). Turkey has had a steep economic developing curve the last decades,

but Turkey require further economic and political developments and reforms to accomplish the

goals of the Turkish government. In this section we will provide an overview of the elements in

the Turkish society that are relevant for the analysis that follows and will serve as context for the

following analytical sections, which will dig deep into the institutional setup of the five spheres.

4.1 The State and the Industry Profile Turkey has a tradition of a centralized and strong state dating back to the Ottoman Era. Despite

several military coups in the second half of the 20th century, the government is still centralized

and powerful. The state rather than the market is the main driver of both change and uncertainty,

which to a large extent influence markets, unions and media. These actors often avoid expressing

criticism, as this will attract unwanted attention from the government. Additionally Turkey has

the dubious honour of ranking first in the OECD for most journalists in jail (Oba and Semercioz

2005: 170).

Policymaking is highly centralized. Most policymaking processes grant political

bodies (e.g. employer and labour organizations) influence, but this is in most cases just for show

off, because politically appointed bureaucrats carry out the will of the administration with a firm

hand (Bolukbasi and Ertugal 2013: 245). The military has historically had a powerful position in

35

Turkish political life as a check on the government, resulting in five coups since World War II.

However, Bolukbasi and Ertugal (2013) argue that the current government has kept the military

from obstructing their hold on the power, thus giving the current Turkish government a firm grip

on legal, political and economic policymaking processes.

Turkey has moved from an import substitution industrialization (ISI) strategy to an

export oriented industrialization (EOI) strategy. This development occurred largely in the 1980’s

where neoliberal ideas inspired the Turkish government as well as most other market economies

on that side of the Iron Curtain (Wasti and Wasti 2008: 119-120). This resulted in a wave of

privatizations of large state owned enterprises and a large inflow of foreign direct investment.

These foreign direct investments included both currency and knowledge and spurred

industrialization of Turkey through the 1980s and 1990s. This development moved Turkey up the

economic ladder, and the living standards improved vastly, but also unevenly.

The main economic driver since 2000 is the medium- and high-tech industries1.

This is a significant change from the 1980s and 1990s where the economic driver was the move

from an agricultural based economy to medium- and low-tech industries. Furthermore, growth in

manufacturing industries that demands higher-skill levels accelerated in the 2000s and continues

to grow rapidly. The share of medium- and high-tech industries as share of total manufacturing

exports in Turkey increased from 30 per cent to more than 60 per cent between 2002 and 2008,

and their share in total output rose from 23 per cent to about 30 per cent (Gönenç et al. 2012: 16).

This is depicting the development in the Turkish economy as one depending increasingly on a

manufacturing industry that demands more technical knowhow and employees with high levels

of specific skills. OECD accordingly describes this as primary drivers of research and

development indicating a significantly higher labour productivity. OECD also points to medium-

and high-tech firms as “an important driver of Turkey’s aggregate productivity growth” (Gönenç

et al. 2012: 16).

The primary economic growth driver in Turkey is its medium- and high-tech

manufacturing industries, and follows that in order to reach its goal of becoming the 10th

largest economy in the world, Turkey is to a large extend dependant on the industrial

sector’s ability to stay competitive and keep growing (Dombey: 2014).

1  See  graph  1  –  Industry  profile  

36

Graph 1: Industry profile

4.2 The Divided Labour Market The labour participation rate is only about 50 per cent, which is closely connected to the women’s

share of the non-agricultural work force of a low 23 per cent (OECD 2014a). Approximately 65

per cent of the Turkish working-age population only have primary education or less and the rate

of youth in employment, education and training is 27 per cent. Despite significant improvements

in the 2000s, these numbers are poor in comparison with EU and the OECD countries (World

Bank 2013).

SMEs as a group are in aggregated numbers the largest employer of the Turkish

economy and employ 78 per cent of Turkeys labour force but deliver only 44.9 per cent of GDP

(OECD 2012). The Turkish Economy is divided in two respects: the first division is between

large corporations and SMEs. The other division is between the formal and informal labour

37

market. These two divides will be clear throughout the analysis in this report because the

conditions in each are fundamentally different.

In 2006, informal employment made up approximately 50 per cent of the labour

market (Bolukbasi and Ertugal 2013). For developing countries it is not uncommon that the

informal sector make up an even larger part of the labour market than in the case of Turkey (ILO

2014). The definition of informal labour is debated among scholars (Salem, Bensidoun and Pelek

2011: 58-59). In this paper we will use the definition used by the International Labour

Organisation (ILO). ILO divides informal labour in two definitions that can be used to measure

the magnitude of the informal sector and informal employment. The first is a definition of what

the informal sector is. Enterprises that meet the following criteria are part of the informal sector:

a) Individual owned enterprises or households in which it is difficult or impossible to distinguish

between private and business related activities. b) At least a part of the goods or services

produced are sold or used to barter. c) The enterprises employ below a certain level defined

according to country circumstances. In this case the number is set at five employees (Salem,

Bensidoun and Pelek 2011: 59).

The second part of the definition concerns what constitutes an informal job2. ILO

defines informal employment as being jobs that are undeclared and therefore not subject to labour

legislation or social security (Salem, Bensidoun and Pelek 2011: 60). This definition covers

owners of informal enterprises, contributing family members and employees holding informal

jobs that do not reside under national legislation (Hussmanns 2014: 6-7). The latter definition

implies that informal jobs can occur in the formal sector if these are not part of national

legislation.

In Turkey, informal jobs are those that are not covered by formal social security.

Additionally, numbers for informal employment can be further divided by excluding the

agricultural sector. Including the agricultural sector, approximately 50 per cent of employment in

Turkey was informal in 2006. Excluding the agricultural sector, informal employment was 35 per

cent in 2006. From 2000 to 2006, informal employment outside the agricultural sector increased

from 25 per cent to 35 per cent (Salem, Bensidoun and Pelek 2011: 61-62). However, more

recent data from ILO show a decrease in informal employment outside the agricultural sector,

reaching 30 per cent in 2012 (ILO 2012). The data uses the same measuring standards as

described above.

2  Informal  jobs  and  employment  are  used  interchangeable    

38

4.3 Political Leadership and the European Union Turkey is a parliamentary representative democracy. Kemal Atatürk formed the republic in 1923

on a foundation of secularism with strict curbs to religious symbols especially in political life.

Atatürk’s foundational principles have later become known as Kemalism, which has six core

principles: republicanism, populism, secularism, statism and reformism. As the head of the

Development and Justice Party (AKP) and prime minister, Recep Erdogan has had a firm grip on

power since 2002. The AKP has roots in Muslim culture which 99 per cent (CIA 2014) of Turks

identify themselves as. In March 2014, local elections confirmed the dominance of the AKP and

Erdogan, which puts them in a good position ahead of presidential and legislative elections in

August 2014 and June 2015 (EIU 2014).

AKP and Erdogan came into power in the wake of a deep economic crisis. Turkey

was forced to accept big loans from the IMF, which came with a range of policy requirements.

Public spending was reduced severely and the bank sector reformed. The AKP was stuck with the

direction of these policies, including public social spending at only 12,4 per cent, which is

significantly lower than the OECD level of 21,9 per cent (OECD 2014b).

Turkey has long fought for membership of the EU and has made considerable

headways since around the turn of the century. In 1999, the Helsinki summit acknowledged

Turkey as official applicant to EU. In 2005, 35 chapters of negotiation officially opened. The 35

chapters are substantial and it is still uncertain if the negotiations will succeed, but much progress

has been made and several chapters have been agreed upon. Policy areas regarding Cyprus, rights

to labour unions, environment and competition law are among those still contentious and

outstanding. A wide body of scholarship have covered the path to the EU admission for Turkey

but it is beyond the scope of this paper to go deeper into the EU admission process. However, it is

relevant to note that EU policies, requests and influence do have a significant impact on the

Turkish government’s policies (Bolukbasi and Ertugal 2013: 247).

39

5. The Five Spheres in Turkey Above we have laid down the theoretical and methodological foundation for this report. We have

listed our conduct of inquiry and portrayed how we understand VoC within our method. We have

in detail described the signifiers, which will be our core reference point in the following analysis

of the institutional setup in Turkey. The following analysis will analyse the empirical data related

to the signifiers in the context of the overall case, which we have just gone through. The analysis

will accordingly analyse the five spheres in Turkey, followed by an overarching analysis

deducting the institutional complementarities and institutional comparative advantages.

5.1 Corporate Governance in Turkey Corporate governance in Turkey is characterised by very concentrated ownership and control

structures, little influence of the stock market or institutional investors and limited protection for

minority shareholders. This section will argue that the corporate governance regime for large and

listed companies in Turkey exhibits extensive characteristics of coordination-based solutions

resembling those of a CME. Corporate governance in SMEs are primarily characterised by being

underdeveloped where basic financial management and access to credit are main obstacles.

The Turkish institutional setup for corporate governance has undergone several

transitions, from practically non-existent in the 1980s, to the modernized but still evolving legal

and institutional framework of today. These transitions broadly follow the many dramatic

political events as well as financial crises, capital shortages, and so forth, which troubled Turkey

in the latter part of the 20th century. The state has always had huge influence on Turkish

industrialization both as source of capital, but also as a source of uncertainty, because capital

flows could be inconsistent when political favours changed. It was not until the late 1980s, during

a shortage of public capital that private banks were permitted to engage in investment banking

activities. Most of the large family owned conglomerates quickly established their own banks to

limit reliance on the state as a source of funding. Following a major liquidity crisis in 2000 and a

deep financial crisis and recession in 2001, a wide range of reforms across the economy was

initiated. Included in these reforms were updated corporate governance principles and corporate

reporting, which all public listed companies complied with by 2004. The reforms also

strengthened a range of regulatory agencies, most important the Capital Markets Board and

Banking Regulatory and Supervisory Agency. The relative success of the reforms are attributed

40

both to the external anchors coming from terms agreed to with the IMF, following the bailout

also by IMF, but also from talks with the EU (Atakan, Oba and Ozsou 2010).

Stock market capitalization as a percentage of GDP reached a high of 44 per cent in

2007 but has since stabilized to an average of 33.5 per cent in the years 2006-2012 (World Bank

2014). This is below the average of the Next 11 countries (38 per cent), lower than the EU

average (67 per cent) and far below those countries usually labelled as liberal market economies,

which are usually above 100 per cent (World Bank 2014). The low stock market capitalization is

a clear indicator that firms turn to other sources of finance. Furthermore, a report on the Turkish

bond market decries the largely absent market for corporate bonds, which deprives Turkish

enterprises from a source of capital most firms in the developed world utilize to a great extent.

Furthermore, the lack of a bond market concentrates credit in banks and thereby also concentrates

risks for the corporate sector (World Bank 2012). According to this study, 88 per cent of financial

assets are accounted for by banks and less than 1 per cent by bonds. Large firms typically have

ownership stakes in banks or have established close networks with these – a characteristic

familiar to CMEs. While Hall and Soskice argue that this cooperation can present advantages as

capital is more patient, the World Bank cautions that it concentrate risk in banks and makes

corporations vulnerable to changes in inflation and exchange rates. Nonetheless finance for large

firms is raised in banks or other sources such as the family or business groups.

For smaller firms, the absence of multiple sources of finance inhibits the

possibilities to pursue opportunities or expand rapidly in times of growth, and difficulties in

financing small firms is by several accounts considered a major barrier for the economic growth

from this sector (World Bank 2011; KOSGEB 2012). The main culprit of SMEs lack of access to

finance is the banking system, only 20 per cent of bank loans are to an SME, with 66 per cent of

these loans maturing in less than one year.

To overcome this issue, the government founded the ‘Republic of Turkey Small and

Medium Enterprises Development Organization’ (KOSGEB) in 2003 under the ministry of trade

and industry. KOSGEB is primarily involved in a targeted investment credit interest support

program, in which banks can pool risks when lending to SMEs. Furthermore, KOSGEB is the

vehicle for a rapidly growing credit subsidizing scheme for SMEs. In 2011, 200.000 SMEs out of

2.5m SMEs in total received credit assistance from KOSGEB.

41

Another government initiative is a Credit Guarantee Fund, which assists SME’s

with collateral for credit (KOSGEB 2012). The World Bank cites 42 other, smaller, programs

using grants, loans and assistance directed at SME’s. However, these initiatives lack a systematic

approach and reach only few firms. While initiatives are lacking, the subsidized interest rate

scheme and involvement by business groups and civil society suggest moves toward less market

and more coordination, although still in its infancy.

A very high degree of family based ownership concentration in Turkey is widely

agreed upon as a central feature of the Turkish private sector (Mandaci and Gumus 2010; Kula

and Tatoglu 2006; Demirag and Serter 2003; Yurtoglu 2000). The number of companies listed on

the Istanbul Stock Exchange increased from 80 in 1986 to 274 in 1998 (348 companies was listed

in 2013), 75 per cent of the companies was majority owned by individuals or families in holding

companies (Yurtoglu 2000). For SME’s, the manager owns the company he runs 99 per cent of

the time (World Bank 2013). Furthermore, most of these owner-managers have technical or

engineering background with limited insight in accounting and corporate finance and lack

knowledge about general management including incentives or possibilities of hiring professional

managers (KOSGEB 2012).

Board Structure and corporate governance legal framework is primarily a concern

for the large and/or listed firms. Turkey has a principle-based and voluntary corporate

governance system with roots in the French-origin legal family of civil law (Aytekin, Miles and

Esen 2013). Civil law is characterised by hard regulation and code of law as opposed to the

British tradition of common law, which builds on consensus and precedence.

The Commercial Code of 1956 regulates listed companies, Capital markets Law of

1981, Decree-law no. 91 of 1983, enforced by the Capital Market Board and the Istanbul Stock

Exchange. Turkish law does not adopt the one-share one-vote principle and a legal loophole

protects shareholders with special voting rights by allowing holders of these rights to delay votes

on classification of shares indefinitely. This loophole allows the family-owned holding

companies to control a very wide range of companies, as they can sell off the majority of shares

without losing control, thereby freeing capital to pursue other ventures. With special voting rights

and concentrated ownership, the controlling shareholders and managers, who are often the same

person or a tightly knit group or family, dominate the supervisory boards.

The pyramidal structure of ownership is very common in Turkey. Here, a single

group, typically a family, owns a holding company that has controlling shares in a wide range of

42

listed and non-listed companies, (Demirag & Serter 2003). More recent data suggests a similar

picture with the two largest business-dynasties, Koc Holding and Sabanci Holding owning more

than 25 per cent of the market capitalisation of the Istanbul stock exchange and both groups

controlled by families (The Economist 2014b).

Furthermore, most Turkish private banks are under control of a business group,

which also serves as its main source of finance. Foreign ownership is also very high in the

Turkish stock market – 61.9 per cent in 2011. Foreign ownership is often an indicator of LME

characteristics, as foreign investors require protection of minority shareholders as well as sound

corporate governance. However, as this is not the case in Turkey a possible explanation could be

the combination of low domestic savings ratio and persistent current account deficits (IMF

2013a), leaving Turkey starved for foreign capital and consequently higher returns to these

investors. Furthermore, family holding groups are eager to sell off shares to pursue new ventures,

as they do not lose control of the firm as long as they keep the shares with special rights.

The family-owned conglomerates with pyramidal ownership structures constitutes a

complex web of inter-corporate shareholdings with reputational monitoring and agency issues to

overcome in-house. This limits the importance of institutional investors, as funding is mainly

from the family, banks – often owned by the very same group – the state, or business networks.

The structure of ownership for large firms in Turkey is quite different from that of Germany and

other developed CMEs. However, when a small business group or family owns and controls a

large number of firms across different industries in a conglomerate, it is possible to align

strategies, share market information, establish long-term supply chains, limit poaching and

competition – all in all, the concentrated ownership in practice resembles the cross-shareholding

and interlocking directorships of the German industry.

The level of sophistication in the stock market is by several accounts low. In 2008,

the World Economic Forum gave the Turkish stock market sophistication a total score of 5.0,

ranking 39th in the world. While scoring high on limits to restriction of capital flows, Turkey

scores very low on key indicators that are characteristic of an LME economy, such as ease of

access to loans (75th in the world), ‘venture capital availability’ (97th in the world). In 2013, the

influential annual ‘Doing Business’ report by the World Bank ranks Turkey as number 71st in the

most important indicator ease of doing business, another composite index. This report echo above

43

findings and Turkey scores low in key LME indicators such as ‘Protecting Investors’ and ‘Getting

Credit’.

It is clear that Turkey is not an LME in the sphere of corporate governance. In a

comprehensive study of corporate control of the 100 largest companies on the Istanbul Stock

Exchange, Demirag and Serter (2003) concludes emphatically that Turkey can be classified as an

“insider system” and that the dominant insiders are the richest families in Turkey. More recently,

Atakan, Oba and Ozsou (2010) describes the Turkish economy and Turkish corporate governance

as characterised by: “(...) a dominant state, an emerging economy, concentrated ownership by

families in the form of pyramidal structures, weak legal procedures in private property rights and

minor dependence on financial markets for equity concerns”(Atakan, Oba and Ozsou 2012: 2).

Turkey is still in the relatively early developing phase of institutions and there are

persisting legacies of the very large family owned conglomerates, many of which were

established in the 1950s. These business groups exhibit very high rates of concentrated ownership

and concentrated control. This ownership structure dominates large firms in Turkey and functions

in practice much like the corporate networks, cross shareholding, interlocking board

memberships, and industry associations in the CME archetype of Germany. It is crucial to note

that the many reforms throughout the 2000s have not made attempts to break up control of the

family dynasties or significantly foster competition over coordination. This creates both a legal as

well practical setup of coordination.

5.2 Industrial Relations in Turkey This section will investigate how Turkey solves its coordination problems within the sphere of

industrial relations. We will argue that while unionisation is very low and collective bargaining

agreements even lower, labour market reforms in the 2000s have provided Turkey with extensive

protection for eligible workers in the formal sector. This indicates a regulatory framework

resembling the CME where the employees are heavily protected. However, due to the huge

informal sector, strict eligibility criteria and low unionisation, in practice most workers have no

formal employment protection, few unemployment benefits, and wages set by the market.

Turkish industrial relations have historically been different from industrial relations

in Western Europe. Western European countries are often associated with collective bargaining

and social protection for instance in Scandinavian countries or Germany. In terms of the VoC,

44

Western European countries, Germany in particular, are associated with coordinated solutions to

wage and working conditions, which are the main coordination problems between firms and

workers within industrial relations. Turkey has a very low unionisation of 5 per cent (OECD

Statistics 2014b). In addition, unions are politically weak, resulting in low levels of collective

bargaining (Yildirim and Calis 2008: 213). Regarding formal labour force regulation, Turkey has

a very strict labour force protection system. According to an OECD measure for strictness of

employment protection, regular contracts score 2.47, over double that of the US (1.17) and

slightly less than Germany (2.98) (OECD Statistics 2014c). Regulation of temporary contracts is

even stricter, being four times as strict as that of Germany and almost 20 times that of the US.

What this initially tells us is that Turkeys institutional setup resembles the CME in as much as it

provides extensive benefits that coordinates markets and provides incentives for workers to

engage in obtaining specific skills. However as the following will depict, this is not a fair and

comprehensive presentation of the institutional setup in Turkey.

In 2003 a new labour act introduced a relatively high severance pay and redundancy

payment that is still applicable. However, it only come into force after one year of employment

and is only applicable for firms with more than 30 employees (Yildirim and Calis 2008: 218-

219). An OECD report on structural reforms in 2012 argues that this merely results in low-skilled

Turkish workers being fired just before the end of the first year of employment, and rehired the

next day (OECD 2012b). The effect is that the coordinated solutions introduced by the state are

avoided by the market, which instead conforms to market based solutions. Other circumventions

mentioned by the report are that some firms have fewer than 30 employees on contract and the

rest are informally employed. Thus these firms avoid the extensive regulation that the state

introduced in order to coordinate the market. The report establishes a link between the

persistency of informal employment, even in large, modern enterprises, as a by-product of strict

labour force protection.

On the contrary, as the duration of severance pay is based on seniority and only

paid out if workers are involuntary laid off – the employees who obtain a formal contract are very

disinclined to change job unless they have a new job on their hands. Hence the extensive

coordination can have the effect of keeping employees longer in the same position. However, the

strict CME protection of workers tends to create a labour market characterised by market based

solutions.

45

One of the key features of the extensive regulation of the formal labour market is

that Turkey has the highest minimum wages as percentage of average wage in the OECD (OECD

Statistics 2014a). However, as in the case of other parts of the regulated formal sector, the high

minimum wage is another reason employers use labour without contract. As with the high

severance pay, the CME regulation reinforces circumventions that give way to solutions

resembling the LME. Baskaya and Hülagü (2011) identify a wage gap in Turkey between formal

and informal labour of around 20 per cent in the years 2005 through 2009. Thus the informal

sector, which constitutes a large part of the Turkish labour market, is without protection from

regulation or by labour unions. Furthermore part time employment or employment on temporary

contracts is lower than the OECD average, indicating that this is relegated less extensive than full

time employment contracts (OECD Statistics 2014d).

Most firms in Turkey are represented by one of four employer organisations, which

are divided according to firm size, and type of industries. Members of the employer organisation,

which represent large firms, generate more than 50 per cent of all value adding in Turkey and

approximately 80 per cent of foreign trade (TUSIAD 2014). These numbers are impressive and

indicate that this employer organisation possesses great bargaining strength in representing large

corporations in Turkey. The other segment of employer organisations is the ones representing

small and medium sized firms within trade, crafts and industry sectors (Yildirim and Calis 2008:

214- 215). These labour organisations are by far the biggest in number of members, but

contribute relatively little to GDP due to low productivity per worker in these sectors (OECD

2004: 27).

These employer organisations participate in coordination of industrial relations

when they negotiate collective bargaining with labour unions on behalf of their members. Though

the employer organisations participate in the collective bargaining few are concluded due to the

low unionisation. Apart from this, evidence shows that a few employer organisations participate

in establishing educational institutions in order to promote skill level upgrading’s (Vega and

Parissaki 2008; TOBB 2014). However, these examples are rare and the employer organisations

main role is providing of information and participation in policy recommendations.

The great number of membership and economic representation normally put such a

labour union in a strong bargaining position, because, although the jobs are not the most

productive, they are employing the majority of the workers, keeping a lid on unemployment

numbers, which is both politically stabilizing and reducing social unrest. However, according to

46

Bolukbasi, and Ertugal (2013), even though unions are given hearing time and opinions are being

voiced in bargaining processes, government officials tend to stick to their own agendas. This

aligns very well with the reality facing the SMEs. The segment of the economy regarding the

SMEs is dimly regulated with weak institutions. Employer organisations representing SMEs on

the surface resemble CME characteristics, but in reality they have little coordinating power,

leaving coordination between stakeholders to the individual SME, thus resembling the LME in

practice.

Unionisation in Turkey was 11 per cent in 1999 but has since then declined by half

a percentage point every year reaching 5 per cent unionisation in 2011 (OECD Statistics 2014b).

In total, labour unions have around 3.8 million members out of a workforce of above 27 million

people (TPM 2014a). The relative low covering of collective agreements is the result of

historically preconditions and of very strict regulation of the possibility for labour unions to

negotiate collective agreements (Yildirim and Calis 2008: 215). Due to the very low unionisation

the main strength of the labour unions, which is to unite the voice of great numbers, is severely

limited. It is although depicting labour unions with limited collective influence not the least

because it is only representing approximately 5 per cent of the Turkish labour force, resembling

the LME approach further (Yildirim and Calis 2008: 215). The shrinking number of unionisation

and the following limitation of bargaining power are resulting in limited coordinated bargaining

on behalf of the employees.

The Turkish state employs 10 per cent of the labour force (OECD 2012c). These,

public employed workers, are represented by three labour unions that have the same bargaining

power (ETUC 2010: 5). In the general labour market one labour union dominate leaving more

bargaining power in the hands of the general labour market, since it is less fragmented (Yildirim

and Calis: 215). The picture of weak labour unions is further emphasized when we look at the

regulation of these.

Two laws regulate those unions, which represent the publicly employed. ‘The

Public Servants Act’ from 1965 and the ’Public Servants Trade Unions Act’ from 2001. Two

obligations stand out: (1) unions cannot engage in collective bargaining. This forces members to

make local agreements on the workplace or to have no collective agreements at all and to some

degree removes the ability of unions to negotiate higher wages or better working benefits. (2)

Removal of the right for the publicly employed to strike (Yildirim and Calis 2008: 214). Again

47

the power, and to some extent the whole idea of unions is obstructed with these laws, which gives

great autonomy to the state as employer.

Labour unions in the general labour market are subject to the Trade Unions Act of

1983 and the Collective Bargaining, Strike and Lockout Act of 1983. The first set strict rules for

who and how employees can become members of a labour union. In effect it hinders high

unionisation. The second act restricts the use of strikes by prohibiting general and solidary

strikes. This restriction removes power from labour unions and hinders the ability to put serious

pressure on the state or other employers. Additionally, it includes a number of workplaces in

which strikes are prohibited (Akan 2012: 328-329) – Yet another restriction to the power of the

labour unions. The restrictive nature of these acts comes from the trade unions role in numerous

strikes before 1980, which were argued to reduce the economic output. Thus the underlining

history of strikes took part in shaping the institutional setup that trade unions act within today.

In 2008 a range of amendments, intended to remove the harsh parts of these two

acts was introduced, including removal of the restriction on general and solidary strikes, but the

amendments have not yet been approved by parliament (Akan 2012: 339-340). These

amendments should be seen in the light of EU admission talks. Turkey initially applied in 1987,

was granted candidate status in 1999 and in 2005, 35 articles of negotiations were officially

opened. Among these, industrial relations are a point of concern, where the EU has made

demands of movements toward a more European system, with social rights and security for

workers. The Public Servants Trade Union Act of 2001 was adopted as a first step toward

meeting EU standards. This gave public employees the right to participate in trade unions and in

effect gave the publicly employed the right to participate in collective bargaining with the state.

However, since the act does not give the right to collective agreements, the International Labour

Organization and the EU remain critical of the progress (Yildirim and Calis 2008: 217-218).

To sum up in regards to the unionisation density and the subsequent institutional

setup, unions are scattered, have low membership ratios and little room to bargain on behalf of its

members. Workers in Turkey do not expect unions to drive the fight for extended labour rights,

leaving the playing field for the state and employer unions.

In an overall perspective the regulation can be characterized as increasing the

coordinated aspects of the formal industry primarily concerning the firms who employ more than

30 employees, but leaving the rest of the labour market as functioning by market based solutions.

The result within the sphere of industrial relations is one of division. First off, a huge part of the

48

labour market is unaccounted for because it reside in the informal sector. Hence the informal

sector is not part of the strict labour market regulations. In the formal sector, unions are scattered

and has low membership ratios, and even fewer members under collective bargaining

agreements. In addition, labour unions are severely restricted by regulation. However, in its

place, legislation, in particular the labour act of 2003 puts constraints on employers’ ability to lay

off workers once they are on contract, a clear CME incentive. Specialised workers have few

options to coordinate bargaining outside the rules set by the state, limiting incentives to invest in

own skills and the individual worker is left to negotiate directly with the firm. The result for the

low skilled worker is a very flexible labour market with low wages – a characteristic of LMEs.

On the other hand are employees on contract with long tenures dis-incentivised to switch jobs and

they are expensive to lay off – a characteristic of CMEs. In practice, the market solves most of

the coordination within the sphere of industrial relations. However, the state employs 40 per cent

of workers, and the legal protection of workers has moved toward greater protection of

employees. These are characteristic of the CME, in which the employer and the employee are

committed to each other.

5.3 Vocational training in Turkey The sphere of vocational training in Turkey is characterized by few coordinated training systems,

extensive protection for labour on contract, and an emerging industry requiring specialized high

skilled labour. The large informal sector in Turkey is uniformly characterized by unprotected low

skilled labour, which is still in high demand. This section will particularly focus on the formal

economy and regulatory aims, because it shows the deliberate institutional setup, indicating

which kind of setup Turkey strives towards in order to become a developed economy, eligible for

membership in the EU. The following will examine the signifiers outlined in the methodology

section.

Turkey has a centralized government structure, which is also visible in the

educational system. The state determines the structure of the educational system, which to a large

degree makes for a general and top-down regulated educational system. Mandatory school

attendance has recently been increased from 8 to 12 years of education. Similar to the German

school system, on the 8th school year, at an age of 13½, students will either choose an academic

secondary education or a vocational secondary education. It is possible to pursue an academic

49

career from the vocational high schools, but this group constitutes a minority3. The tertiary

educational institutions, which are reached at an average age of 17½, receive funding from the

national budget, tuition fees and self-generated revenues.

Tertiary educational institutions are closely supervised by the state, and ‘general’ in

its educational directives. The vocational education branch offers some influence to stakeholders

in the economy through the “Vocational Education Council.” This council decides on planning

and development, with representatives from relevant ministries, trade and employers' unions and

other key social stakeholders. The “Vocational Qualifications Authority” aligns Vocational

Education and Training (VET) professional qualifications with professional standards; and for

each province there is a “Board of Vocational Education” (OECD 2013). This does to some

extent ensure alignment to local and specific educational needs and wishes (i.e. decentralization).

Some vocational High schools and Universities are collocated with Organized Industrial Zones

(hereon after OIZ), thus enjoying closer coordination with the specific needs of the industries

represented in these zones.

We will in this paper look into one of these zones and use it as an indicator for the

rest of the zones. Ortadoğu Sanayi ve Ticaret Merkezi (OSTIM) is, according to the OECD, a

good representative for Turkish SMEs in general (Elci 2011). With approximately 5000

companies in eight main sectors and 50,000 employees it is “Turkey’s largest small and medium

sized industrial zones” (OECD 2013). Further more the vocational and educational training sites

and facilities tend to be concentrated around the concentration of its costumers (firms), so in

order to observe on this signifier the OIZ gives us best case. It is, however, relevant to note that

this does not reflect the situation of all SMEs. We consider the SME OIZ to be sufficient proxy,

keeping in mind that it might overstate the level of coordination.

The sphere of vocational training and education is in a developing phase according

to Prof. Dr. Sabahattin Balci from Cankiri Technical and Business College, Ankara University

(Balci and Gurbuz 2000). This is driven by Turkey’s positive economic development which has

been facilitated by strong growth in the manufacturing industry, which is becoming increasingly

sophisticated, thus demanding more specialization and higher skill levels of workers. The

shipbuilding industry is an example of this tendency. According to a study by the OECD, the

shipbuilding industry in Turkey is one of the most promising and important industries both 3  For  an  overview  of  the  Turkish  school  system  see  figure  in  appendix  2  

50

domestically and in terms of export (OECD 2011). Internationally Turkey has risen to become

the 5th largest producer in the shipbuilding industry.

This developing tendency is reflected in recent government regulation such as the

193 Income Law (September 2003), where a 100 per cent tax deduction can be provided for

contributions to education (OECD 2013). This creates institutional incentives for firms to invest

in industry specific skills. The state is promoting decentralizing of vocational training and

education in order to be able to keep up with the increasing need for specialized skills. Industries

like the ship building industry have embraced these initiatives by funding high schools and

tertiary educational institutions. Furthermore, in a recent regulation change of the “Private

Teaching Institutions Law” (January 2013), government funds have been provided to private

vocational and technical schools in organized industrial zones in addition to the funding available

to private schools with students in special education (OECD 2013). This state substitution of the

industry further increases firms’ incentive to invest in industry specific skills. Both these

regulations increase incentives to create coordinated solutions in the institutional setup for

vocational training. According to the Turkish Under-secretariate of Maritime Affairs, the amount

of high schools with ship construction departments increased from 17 to 31 in the years 2004 to

2008. Furthermore, four universities have specific shipbuilding departments (OECD 2011: 24).

The recent 10 years of development within the sphere of vocational training and industry profile

of Turkey is indicating that there is a wish to move towards an economy with a high level of

specific skills complementing the growing industries in Turkey. This regulation implemented by

the government is very close to being a copy of what Culpepper (2001) explained is the necessary

institutional setup for a decentralized vocational training systems to succeed. In short, recent

developments within the institutions regarding vocational training resemble distinct and clear

CME notions.

In contradiction to these ‘coordinated’ incentives, the school system is top-down

controlled and has limited room for firms and industry to influence curriculum. However some

large corporations, e.g. the shipbuilding industry, do get influence and tend to promote specific

skills. Drawing on the findings from the sphere of industrial relations it is visible that there is a

sharp distinction between the SMEs and large national ‘champions’. The two employer

organisations (representing respectively the SMEs and the large firms) have different access to

51

policymaking, and the large enterprises with political clout have all together different

preconditions.

Taking the above into perspective it is important to investigate if the same picture is

evident among the SMEs. As earlier pointed out, SMEs are by far the biggest employer in the

Turkish economy. They employ 78 per cent of Turkeys labour force and delivers 44.9 per cent of

GDP (OECD 2012). As mentioned above the preconditions for SMEs seeking specific skills are

different. SMEs, by nature, does not command the same resources to finance and support

educational initiatives as the large enterprises, which means that the need for coordinating

measures facilitating pooling of resources is more explicit.

OECD published a research paper in 2011 evaluating the use of vocational training

by SMEs in the OSTIM (Elci 2011). The report found that the use of training was surprisingly

low and three specific concerns were prevalent: (1) Difficulty in determining and measuring

benefits of investing in training, (2) fear of other SMEs poaching their employees once they had

obtained new specific skills, and (3) a lack of public funding (Elci 2011: 55). To ameliorate these

concerns the report recommends initiatives such as encouraging inter-firm collaboration,

coordination with the state and relevant institutions, development of mechanisms to ensure that

universities and vocational schools obtain information directly from SME’s. This signifies that

decentralizing vocational training and increased endorsement and focus on high levels of specific

skills have not yet been achieved at the SME level. Within the domain of SMEs, a high level of

general skills is therefore still the best social security for an employee. Initiatives for vocational

training for large firms indicate regulatory support for the CME approach, but this support is

lacking for SMEs, creating similarities to the LME. It is important to note that the LME notions

are based on a weak or non-existing institutional setup, and the cause of a institutional setup

deliberately promoting the synergies of the LME like we see it the USA and UK.

The above analysis of institutions and factors relate to the employer and state side

of the equation. This section will focus on the employee. Employment protection, unemployment

protection and job tenures are incentives that either facilitates a wish for specific or general skills

for the individual employee. The incentives facing employees in the formal and informal sector

are radically different. First off, informal workers are usually low skilled, and they have neither

the resources nor the access to formal training. Thus, the Informal industry is inherently flexible

because neither employer nor employee is under any form of institutional protection (Bolukbasi

and Ertugal 2013). No data on job tenures are available but due to the hire and fire nature of the

52

informal sector and flexible markets job tenures are low. This means that the best social security

policy in the informal labour market is obtaining general skills, thus optimizing the possibility of

finding a new job if laid off. However, this can be difficult due to lack of resources. It is not until

a worker is formally employed, and has become eligible for protection and benefits that

employers as well as the employee have incentives to invest in firm-specific skills.

The formal segment of the Turkish labour market provides a degree of security for

the employee. A new unemployment insurance scheme has been implemented for the first time in

Turkey. However, it is very difficult to qualify for the benefits and these are relative low

(Bolukbasi and Ertugal; 2013: 243). The difficulties in obtaining these social security benefits

make the Turkish social security system encourage workers to maximise job tenure, because the

alternative is to get no security. This does not explicitly dictate that all job tenures in the formal

sector are long, but it does indicate that conditions for long tenures are present in the formal

labour market.

This leaves us with a somewhat muddy picture of the incentives facing workers for

specific or general skills in the formal segment of the labour market for SMEs. On the one hand

employees is left without protection and on the other hand the state invest and encourage firms to

invest in industry specific skills. However, due to EU pressure and an increasing demand from

the industry, it is likely that the state will provide more incentives for coordination and higher

skill levels.

The profile of the Turkish economy does seem to call for a high level of specific

skills. Both SMEs and large corporations have voiced this through OECD reports, correlating

with a rapidly growing manufacturing industry, which is the biggest export sector. However,

public institutions do not support this, because they do not provide substantial security for

workers making it risky to pursue specific skills rather than general. This is especially true for the

informal sector where a social security system does not exist.

In sum we conclude that the Turkish government does pursue a high level of

specific skills to support their economic development. This pursue of specific skills by

decentralizing vocational training is difficult because the culture stemming from the strong

centralized state have set some difficult preconditions. Decentralization of vocational training

systems has only been successful when large corporations with political influence and financial

muscle can support the development. The present conditions facing firms in the sphere of

vocational training bear a resemblance to the LME, with mostly general skills. However, there is

53

a prevalence of low general skills, which does not support the industries usually combined with

LMEs. Recent regulatory developments such as tax incentives indicate that the Turkish

government is pursuing institutional reforms putting vocational training systems on a path

towards a CME. Furthermore, the promises of the manufacturing industry as the future export

engine will demand specific and higher skill levels filling gaps and spurring decentralization and

coordination.

5.4 Inter-firm Relations This section will analyse how the Turkish institutional setup solves the coordination problems of

conducting business with other firms and the spread of knowledge. The Turkish inter-firm

relations are characterised by networks relying heavily on reputation, rather than contractual

enforcement. Furthermore, knowledge sharing is characterised by both LME and CME solutions.

The three signifiers that will inform this analysis, of the inter-firm relations in Turkey, will use

the following structure. First, contractual relation between firms in Turkey is investigated by

analysing how Turkish firms conduct business with other firms. Second, the role of business

organisations will be analysed by investigating how SMEs in an industrial district conduct

business, and how large automotive firms conduct business with SMEs. Additionally the analysis

draws on knowledge about the large employer organisation described earlier. Third, an analysis

of how Turkish firms participate in knowledge sharing will be conducted.

The culture of contractual enforcement will be analysed through an investigation of

two representative sectors. The first sector is the leading textile district in Turkey, largely made

up by a multitude of SMEs, which, in this case defined as firms employing less than 300

employees (Oba and Semercioz 2005: 175). The second is the automotive industry in which

larger firms preside. The investigation of these two sectors will give us an indication of how

business communities in Turkey conduct business with each other.

The Merter textile district, located in Istanbul, the capital, is the leading district for

textile production in Turkey. It produces 40 per cent of the Turkish textile production and hosts

more than 2500 SMEs. It is the definition used by the Istanbul Chamber of Industry (Oba and

Semercioz 2005: 175). An industrial district is a geographical area that comprises many SMEs

that participate in the production of a final product. Hence, each firm in an industrial district

contribute with a specialised part of the production process and the district as a whole produces

the final product. In Merter, where SMEs are in close geographical proximity to each other,

54

workers and management know how other firms conduct business through long business

relationships. Reputation of firms in industrial districts is a crucial source of competition. Firms

in Merter primarily use verbal commitments to place or receive orders. This indicates a very high

degree of trust between firms in industrial districts and few formal contracts. Additionally many

firms in Merter believe that good reputation and long term relationship with business partners are

very important factors. Furthermore, only a few firms use social factors like affiliation to a

family, religion or geographical area, in their evaluation of trust to other business partners (Oba

and Semercioz 2005: 174-179). In effect the industrial district in Merter is characterized by the

use of coordinated solutions of the contractual setting they engage in.

Moving on to the automotive industry, which is the third largest industry in Turkey

(Wasti and Wasti 2008: 119). The automotive industry in Turkey is dominated by large

companies and will therefore give an understanding of how larger companies conduct business

with their SME suppliers. The Turkish automotive industry has existed for about 50 years and is

highly dominated by foreign brands like Ford, Renault and Toyota. The industry has been faced

with a highly volatile institutional setup. Among other things, the import-substitution strategy

pursued by the Turkish state from 1954 to 1980 created an industry in which foreign firms was

required to form joint ventures with Turkish firms to participate in the market. Today some car

manufactures participate in joint ventures and others do not (TPM 2014b). These manufacturers

buy parts for the production from smaller firms on the international market and on the Turkish

market. The end result is a tipped balance in the business relationship towards the large

manufacturers, since these can shift suppliers easily (Wasti and Wasti2008: 119-120).

Nevertheless, it is important for both parties to create a trustworthy relationship. This trust has

often been built by assistance of the manufacturer to the Turkish supplier. The large car

manufacturers have often desired implementation of soft technologies such as the famous Toyota

just-in-time delivery systems. However, since smaller Turkish firms often experience difficulties

implementing new technology, manufacturers have in many cases assisted them with the

implementation. Thus, instead of using other suppliers, either Turkish or foreign, manufacturers

have tied themselves more closely to Turkish suppliers. This helping hand has increased the trust

in the relationship between foreign car manufactures and small Turkish suppliers. As in the case

of Merter, the large automotive manufacturers and the SMEs use coordinated solutions to engage

in inter-firm relations.

55

Moving on to the strength of employer organisations the issue of receiving market

information is of great value for firms. However, firms can be reluctant to reveal market

information but interested in acquiring it. This section investigates how employer organisations

can solve this problem and inform its members of market tendencies. When firms participate in

various relationships with other firms in the market, information is key to establishing well-

functioning relationships. As seen above, trust is an important parameter when conducting

business in Turkey. In cases, unlike the Merter district, where firms find themselves more

distanced from their supplier or buyer they will search for information. The kind of information

they are looking for is general market information and reputational information about the firm

they engage with. In such cases employer associations and industry specific associations become

important for delivering such information. In the sphere of industrial relations we analysed the

largest employer organisations. Here we will look at the employer representative of the Merter

district. The MESIAD organisation, which has the job of representing its members at

governmental levels and is forming, ties to other associations. Additionally it provides national

and international market information to its members. Furthermore, it seeks to strengthen

relationships and unity between members through seminars and training sessions, (Oba and

Semercioz 2005: 170-171). In addition to small specific employer organisations, like the

MESIAD, the four large employer organisations TISK, TUSIAD, TESK and TOBB help

coordination of inter-firm relations. All of who represents large parts of the firms in Turkey.

The reluctance of sharing market information is evident within knowledge sharing.

Efficient knowledge sharing between firms can be a competitive advantage for an economy,

facilitating innovation and process evolution. For firms that participate in the global economy,

knowledge is an increasingly important source of competition. Knowledge has, in terms of

competitive resource, become as important as coal was during the industrial age. Knowledge is a

source used to innovate processes and products. Therefore knowledge becomes the source of

tomorrow’s organisations, product processes and products. The firms that form these innovations

will be at the forefront of international competition. Therefore, it is important for firms to be able

to structure how they acquire and participate in knowledge sharing. Developing knowledge in

firms can take many forms. For instance, on the basic level, firms hire new employees to increase

their stock of knowledge (Bozbura 2007: 209). However, existing knowledge inside an

organisation can also be combined or used in new ways. Thus the internal process of catching

56

knowledge and directing it towards the proper place in the organisation is essential (Kamasak

2009: 306-308).

A different venue for firms to obtain knowledge is to engage in knowledge sharing

with other firms. Sharing knowledge with other organisations can create many new structures of

knowledge. On the other hand it often makes organisations feel vulnerable of the risk for being

copied and outperformed (Bozbura 2007: 209). From the perspective of the state, it is important

that national firms are able to create innovations and thereby be at forefront of international

competition. When national firms succeed, with this innovative process, states will perform well

in economic terms. Indeed the future strength of a state depends highly on the market actor’s

ability to share knowledge.

Above we saw how large international firms in the automotive industry assist

Turkish SMEs to implement soft technologies. Now we will investigate the general tendency of

knowledge sharing involving Turkish SMEs. SMEs are by some scholars regarded as being very

important innovators in a market economy (Bozbura 2007: 209). In Turkey, where most of its

firms are SMEs, it becomes highly valuable for the economy if these have a great tradition for

sharing knowledge with other firms in the market. Turkish SMEs are primarily family-owned,

which tends to keep company knowledge inside the family. A study conducted on Turkish SMEs

showed that these did not find it important to share knowledge (Bozbura 2007). Instead, focus

was on diminishing outflows of knowledge. By diminishing information outflow the market as a

whole miss possible innovative development and firms lack the opportunity of acquiring new

knowledge from the outside. Evidence from other countries is that the individual firm miss out on

a healthy growth and improvement of the firm (Bozbura 2007: 209). The study indicates that

Turkish SMEs use a very conservative approach to knowledge sharing hindering their long term

growth potential. A countervailing effect is the great flexibility in the Turkish labour market.

When employees frequently move across the labour market they will take knowledge with them

and the new firms will benefit from this. Generally, these studies reveal no involvement of formal

research programs or intervention in the market by the state to facilitate knowledge sharing

between small and medium sized firms. Thus, the market is the primary vehicle for knowledge

sharing. For larger firms, joint ventures and industry collaboration, exacerbated by concentrated

ownership creates knowledge transfers.

As is the case in vocational training and industrial relations coordination problems

in the relationship between firms point in two directions. The fear of loosing know-how limits

57

spread of knowledge and information and the very flexible low-skill labour market creates

knowledge sharing across SMEs. The latter is a characteristic of LMEs. Conversely, reputational

and network monitoring solves contractual relations between firms, which is a coordination based

solution. For larger firms, concentrated ownership, joint ventures and some instances of vertical

coordination between large manufacturers and smaller suppliers indicate coordination based

solutions to knowledge sharing. Market information is kept in-house for both small and large

firms, although with concentrated ownership, in-house sharing for larger firms spreads across

industries.

5.5 Intra-firm relations in Turkey This sphere will draw on the analysis from the other spheres as the intra-firm sphere overlaps

these. Apart from this it will seek to observe and analyse the typical decision making processes in

Turkish firms, the average tenure and the cultural setting. Findings are that the intra-firm sphere

in Turkey is divided between SMEs and large firms, except for a pervasive culture of patriarchal

control systems. SMEs resemble LME solutions and large firms resemble CME solutions.

The formal regulatory framework of Turkey in the sphere of employment protection

is among the most rigid in the OECD, even to the point where incentives are distorted. However,

the informal sector, which by nature is unregulated, is highly flexible. This leaves CEOs with

great autonomy over the hiring and firing of informal labour, but limited autonomy over

employees on formal contracts. Low unionisation and strict regulation preventing collective

bargaining, relegates the bargaining of wages to the workplace in most cases. Formal labour force

protection is based on seniority, which in practice increases the threat of exit before the first year

of employment. Despite that the employer might be satisfied with the worker. Conversely, the

steep severance fees and employment protection pacifies the threat of firing workers employed

more than one year. Hence, committing employer and employee to each other when high

seniority is achieved. For workers that are ineligible for the formal labour force protection wages

are to a high degree based on market mechanisms. The market wage mechanism is especially

prevalent for the informal sector.

On the issue of capacity for unilateral decision-making by the executive of a

company, there is a sharp distinction between the informal and the formal sector. 80 per cent of

informal labour occurs in firms with less than 10 workers (Salem, Bensidoun and Pilek 2011: 65).

58

Managers of small firms, who are often also the owners, have high degrees of autonomy due to

employment of mainly un-contracted labour.

In the large family owned conglomerates, ownership is very concentrated, and as

accounted for in the section on corporate governance, boards are often merely for show. This

limits influence of employees on strategy. However, the extensive labour protection inhibits

managerial autonomy on firing. The OECD report on structural reforms in Turkey show that

compliance with severance payments, especially for firms that go bankrupt, is limited. However,

for large firms both private and publicly owned, employing mainly formal labour, the picture

remains as concentrated control over strategy, but limited autonomy on firing.

In a book on the culture of corporate governance from 2008, Mustafa A. A. use

social studies to gauge Turkish attitudes toward managers and enterprise. Key findings are that

Turkish people accept powers of seniors and of persons that are higher in a hierarchy and are

disinclined to question or disobey orders. Turkish people are in general very risk averse and

prefer to follow a leader, rather than individualistic initiative. Individualistic attitudes of the

working population were by his account 30 per cent, slightly higher than that of China, but far

lower than Anglo-Saxon countries, which scored 82-85 per cent. Furthermore, there is a distinct

tendency of secrecy and conservatism, where 99 per cent of SMEs are owned and managed by

the same person, usually the patriarch of a family. Generally these firms have non-public

financials and employ informal labour approximately half the time. Mergers and acquisitions are

very rare and with very limited access to risk-willing capital – or even basic credit from banks –

most SMEs stay small. By this account, management practices for both small and large

companies are authoritative with the ‘boss’ reluctant to listen to outsiders and decisions are based

on intuition, rather than long-term strategic planning.

Statistics for job tenure from Turkey is accounted for differently than in other

OECD member countries, measuring only those workers with tenure over 3 years, which is 54

per cent. This is lower than the German average of 71 per cent and closer to that of Australia, an

LME, which is 58 per cent. However, a classical example of an LME, the UK, is 70 per cent,

which is the same as Germany, but after 5 years of tenure, the two diverge significantly, with

Germany having 44 per cent with 10 years or more, and the UK only 34 per cent with 10 years or

more. It can thus be concluded that due to lack of data, the average job tenure in Turkey is

inconclusive.

59

The overall picture of intra firm relations in Turkey is that of a sharp division

between small and large firms, and formal and informal labour. Managers of small firms have

great autonomy on all accounts: Contracted employees are not covered if there are less than 30

workers in the firm, and informal labour has no protection at all. For large firms, employees are

extensively protected, but have little access to strategy. The overall picture reminisces of other

spheres where the informal sector and small firms strongly resembles the LME, while large firms

and the regulatory framework are leaning toward the CME.

60

6. Institutional complementarities Through the analysis of the five spheres of institutional coordination in Turkey, a picture of deep

division between large enterprises and small and medium sized enterprises have emerged. On the

one hand, large enterprises operate primarily in manufacturing and heavy industries with

economic growth, surging exports, relatively high productivity, labour protection and expanding

training systems. Firms with more than 1000 employees employ 11 per cent of the total labour

force but accounts for just over 20 per cent of total revenue and 25 per cent of total value added

in Turkey (Turkstat 2014). On the other hand, 2.5 million SMEs – of which 98 per cent have

fewer than 20 employees have low productivity, low skill levels, low levels of technology, absent

job or social protection and frequent use of informal labour. The institutional setup surrounding

these two segments is equally divided in solutions resembling CME for the large corporations

and resembling LME for SMEs.

The following section will analyse how the Turkish setups in the five spheres across

the institutional setup complement or impede each other. It is organized as follows: the first part

will explore institutional setup in which SMEs operate which finds that the predominant LME

characteristics has capacity for employing great numbers, but has low productivity and upgrading

or higher productivity through effective competition is impeded back lack of technology and

crucial LME institutions. Secondly the institutional setup facing large enterprises is largely of the

coordinated kind, and state polices have successfully ameliorated the lack of some

complementarities of the ideal type. Lastly the interplay between the two will be assessed and

finds that the technological gap limits interplay between the two sectors.

The SME Segment Across the five spheres of the institutional setup, the most evident characteristic of the SME

sector in Turkey is the interplay of institutions that creates an abundance of cheap and flexible

low skilled labour. The institutional setup that facilitates this characteristic, is constituted by the

combination of small-scale family ownership, widespread use of informal labour, strict eligibility

criteria for labour protection provided by the state, low and fragmented unionisation. These

characteristics gives creates a situation where the owner and hence the manager reigns supremely

internally over employees. Apart from enjoying full autonomy, the employer has the power to

hire and fire at will since the labour is absent of protective regulation and the labour unions are

left without the necessary power to participate in collective bargaining. The effect of the

61

institutional setup for SMEs is a cross-sphere regime of flexibility and market based solutions

resembling the LME.

However, this section will argue that in order for this market based institutional

setup to relate more closely to the ideal type, crucial complementary institutions in the spheres of

vocational training are lacking, as well as institutions facilitating competition in the market place.

Lastly, initiatives from the government and private sector organizations that are designed to

upgrade knowledge and disseminate know-how resemble coordinated based solutions. However,

these initiatives are ineffectual and reach few firms. A reason for this is lack of complementary

institutions such as unions or employer organisations.

The above regime, of flexibility and market based solutions, carries effects into the

sphere of vocational training for SMEs. Due to the lack of coordinated solutions to labour

contracts poaching of employees becomes the fear of the firm. For the firm, the fear of poaching

of their employees by other companies reduces the interest and incentives to invest in vocational

training of its employees. Additionally the culture of secrecy and conservatism in Turkey

(Mustafa 2008) exacerbate the reluctance for managers to invest in developing firm and industry

specific skills for their employees. This reluctance is prevalent even despite the implementation

of tax deductions for investments in upgrading skills for employees.

The reluctance for making investments in upgrading specific employee skills leaves

the employee with responsibility to find the balance of upgrading his or hers skills. However, for

the individual worker, little hope for promotion in SMEs due to family based ownership, the lack

of protection in cases of firing and the lack of protective rules for unjustifiable firings makes it

unattractive to invest in firm or industry specific skills – which are largely unavailable for

workers anyway, due to lack of supportive resources by the state or the firm. Rather than in

investing in specific skills the institutional setup emphasise investments in general skills that can

be used in many firms and industries. The acquisition of general skills will hence enable the

worker to move more easily from one firm to another in cases of firings. Thus the flexibility,

created due to the lack of protective regulation and strong labour unions, gives incentives for the

worker and the firm to promote general skill levels.

The favouring of general skill levels and the subsequent high portability of workers

will, according to the logic of the VoC approach, create a dynamic and adaptable economy.

However, in the case of Turkey low productivity (World Bank 2011), low human development

(UNDP 2013), low levels of technological penetration and insufficient know-how in SMEs

62

(OECD 2004) for SMEs in Turkey clearly show that education and skill levels are low, creating a

disharmony and inhibiting utilization of the flexible, market-based regime. Hence, even though

the Turkish labour force used by SMEs tends to develop general skills these are often low, which

hinders the growth potential that the market based flexible labour market presents.

The result of the low general skill level is a high number of SMEs with low

productivity, many workers with low skill levels and correspondingly low wages. These effects

create a high quantity of SMEs in the Turkish market economy with low skill requirements for

workers and correspondingly low wages. It gives these SMEs the ability to soak up excess labour

in the Turkish labour market. Additionally it facilitates high adaptability, to changes in supply

and demand, for the Turkish economy. However, with the absence of effective unions and

unemployment benefits from the state, this flexibility comes at great cost to the individual

worker, which is partly responsible for keeping skill levels low as the worker is forced to take

lower paying jobs, instead of upgrading skills in order to fit into the low skill requirement of

SMEs.

In the sphere of inter-firm relations, SMEs in Turkey mainly operate in labour

intensive sectors – trade, crafts and agriculture – with low barriers of entry. Reputation-based

relational networks are the main business partners for SMEs in Turkey and non-formal contracts

is the norm. Despite this, cooperation between SMEs is very limited. In an LME setting, this

combination fosters competition. However, as evidenced by the textile district in Merter,

industrial clusters are characterised by numerous non-competitive suppliers to a final product.

Hindering the competition that otherwise is a key driver of SMEs. Within the agricultural sector,

improving productivity requires extensive coordination to receive high enough skill levels as well

as momentous investments in large-scale production infrastructure – all of which are unavailable

for SMEs due to lack of institutional infrastructure and a corporate governance regime

unsupportive of small-scale entrepreneurship.

Lastly, these severe structural and financial barriers leave even the best SMEs with

limited opportunities for rapid or exponential economic growth. The latter is an intrinsic

characteristic of small firms in LMEs as a result of increased competition. Furthermore, without

rigorous anti-trust measures, as seen in ideal LMEs, large firms are in a position to exploit their

size to squeeze up-and-coming competitors from the SME segment. It is evident that the flexible

labour market is underutilized because of cultural factors and the competitive dynamics of the

production mix of SMEs.

63

Moving on to the complementarity between the industrial sphere and the sphere of

inter-firm relations, the flexible labour market in ideal LMEs facilitates knowledge dispersion

between firms when workers are fired and re-hired in new firms. However, in Turkey, benefits

from the flexible labour market in terms of knowledge dispersion, is severely limited due to the

low skill levels. Additionally the Turkish employer organisations representing SMEs are

hampered by lack of commitment by a broad and differentiated membership base. Employer

organisations in the ideal type and many developed economies provide knowledge sharing,

common vocational training facilities, distribute market insights or information on support

schemes or credit facilities. Throughout the 2000’s, initiatives to provide that which employer

unions have failed to do have been instituted by government agencies and a number of private

sector groups. These promote education and innovation in SMEs and provide subsidized credit

facilities, but reach few firms and issues of bureaucracy and slow procedures are prevalent

(World Bank 2011). Furthermore, firms decry top-down design and serious shortcomings in

stakeholder involvement in these support programs (World Bank 2011).

The chief characteristics of the SME sector is the capacity for employing large

numbers and a correspondingly abundance of available labour. However, the sector has low

productivity and improving productivity through effective competition is impeded by the lack of

crucial LME institutions. Low levels of knowledge and technology would benefit greatly from

institutionalized coordination of efforts to include stakeholder considerations, and crucially for

dissemination of basic know-how and market information.

The Large Enterprise Segment Across the five spheres of the institutional setup, large firms have solved the coordination

problems as understood in the framework of the VoC, through measures largely associated with

CMEs. One notable exception is the absence of labour unions and employer organisations, the

latter of which is mainly concerned with spread of information and policy recommendations for

the government. Thus, coordination of the institutional setup across the five spheres lacks a

crucial element to resemble the ideal CME type. However, as seen in the case of hybrids or

different configurations of coordination, other setups will resemble the ideal-type in practice.

This section will observe if this is the case in Turkey and conclude that the practical setup has the

preconditions for effective coordination and collaboration but lack the economy wide

collaborative institutions of the ideal type.

64

In the segment of large enterprises Turkey the lack of coordinated solutions in the

sphere of inter-firm and industrial relations create incentives to divert from CME solutions in the

sphere of vocational training. Within vocational training the two main problems hindering

upgrading of skill levels are poaching for firms and lack of coordinated solutions to support

incentives for workers. For firms the chief concern of investing in training for workers is

poaching of skilled workers by competing or other firms. Conversely, for the individual worker

the fear of being fired during downturns or not adequately compensated by the firm after

upgrading of skill levels keep workers from investing in firm or industry specific skills. In ideal

CME types, this is solved by coordinated efforts in the spheres of industrial and inter-firm

relations through employer or industry organisations, which coordinate wages with labour unions

and thereby create equal wage levels for the same skill level across the labour market.

Additionally the employer and industry organisations can create coordination incentives to share

costs of having training schemes or facilities, as seen in Germany, or with a culture of life-long

employment and upgrading in Japan.

In the case of Turkey, an interplay between several institutional spheres creates a

substitute that keeps workers at the same firm for longer tenures. This interplay is seen in the

sphere of corporate governance, which has concentrated ownership and family-owned

conglomerates that span a wide range of industries with patient capital from co-owned banks and

limited influence from financial markets. These function to some degree as employer

organisations in the sense that these actors can influence large parts of the Turkish labour market

and hence create coordination across it. This type of coordinated based solution allows for

coordination of wages and employment strategies, and reduces fear of poaching by other firms.

Additionally two other institutional setups create incentives for coordinated solutions in the

sphere of vocational training – High protection of employees and the industrial mix. In Turkey,

eligibility for protection from the government for workers does not take effect before one year of

employment, and benefits increase with seniority, rewarding workers for staying at the same

firm. Lastly, the industrial mix, with a rapidly growing emphasis on manufacturing, benefits

greatly from highly educated and specialized workers. Overall, these three complementary factors

makes it attractive for firms in Turkey to invest in workers as these have few places else to go

and are incentivized by the government to stay at the same firm.

For the worker, most employees in large firms are, or can, become eligible for the

extensive labour market protection granted by government regulation. Giving them coordinated

65

solutions. This compensates to some degree for the lack of collective bargaining and protection

excluded due to lack of strong labour unions. Furthermore, as accounted for in the section on

SMEs, employment and long tenure in a large firm is highly desirable, with higher wages and

greater security. Thus, skills of any kind are highly desirable for the worker, as it will likely be

the only means of security.

This combination creates a tentative synergy with longer employment tenures for

workers and with incentives for the workplace to upgrade qualifications of its employees

continuously. In the sphere of vocational training, current levels of human resources are low due

to lack of educational infrastructure in the past. The government exhibits efforts to coordinate and

promote training and education. Several large reforms and overhauls of the education sector in

the latter part of the 2000s and the start 2010s have yet to make its impact. The government

further supports vocational training through generous tax deductions to educational investments

and influence on curricula in technical schools. However, only the largest enterprises, such as the

shipbuilding industry have the financial muscle to create training facilities and exploit the

generous government tax deductions. Lastly, evidence suggests that research and development

cooperation between public facilities and industry does not utilize the full potential.

Lacking the flexible labour market of the LME, dispersion of knowledge

throughout the economy in the ideal CME type usually happens through industry organisations

and labour unions. In Turkey, employer organisations distribute market information, new

technological information and export advice but do not coordinate larger training schemes or

industrial collaboration. Industry pursues knowledge sharing and knowledge creation through

joint ventures with foreign or domestic firms.

To sum up, the non-governmental setup, namely trade unions and employer

organizations servicing large firms and their employees in Turkey is underdeveloped and have

little influence. Lacking these institutions, government regulation has created an institutional

regime where workers are protected and dis-incentivized to switch job. This is underpinned by

de-facto industrial collaboration due to the presence of huge family owned conglomerates and

concentrated ownership. This creates a regime where coordinated investments and efforts for

continuous education and upgrading is well rewarded, but lacks crucial CME institutions in order

to utilize its potential to the fullest.

66

7. Comparative Institutional Advantage and Discussion In this section, we will sum up on key findings, map the institutional setup facing firms in Turkey

and conclude the analytical narrative. Finally, we will discuss the implications of our findings,

taking into consideration a broader context.

For large enterprises in Turkey, the formal regulatory framework and industrial mix

resemble the CME. Within the sphere of corporate governance, the manufacturing and heavy

industries are characterised by concentrated ownership in conglomerates and pyramidal

ownership structures, which entails rampant executive autonomy. Furthermore, due to co-

ownership of banks, capital is patient. Within industrial relations, skeletal labour unions is

mitigated by governmental labour regulation that punishes layoffs severely, but encourages long

tenures. This incentivises long term investment in specific skills for workers. In vocational

training, education facilities are underdeveloped and suffer from limited stakeholder

coordination. Inter-firm relations are characterised by coordinated business networks within the

conglomerates. Vertical cooperation with SME suppliers is evidenced but scarce. However, joint

ventures with foreign companies facilitates some knowledge sharing. Lastly, intra-firm relations

are characterised by a culture of obedience and patriarchal hierarchies, exacerbating executive

autonomy. Large enterprises in Turkey have the ownership structure and regulatory environment

to operate as coordinated business groups aligning strategically within, and across, industries.

Across the divide, the institutional framework facing the massive SME segment

operates largely unregulated, but in most instances resembling the LME. On corporate

governance, access to credit is scarce and most companies are owned and run by the same

person, usually the head of a family. Industrial relations are best characterised as absent: labour

unions lack membership and are restricted by government regulation, employer organizations are

scattered and ineffectual, government regulation does not apply to firms with less than 30

employees. Furthermore, use of informal labour is rampant and cheap labour is abundant. On

vocational training, workers as well as the owner-managers have very low skill levels and little

access to training. Inter-firm relations are characterised by reputational monitoring and informal

contracts but due to a culture of secrecy, knowledge dispersion is slow. Intra-firm relations show

unbridled executive autonomy due to lack of regulation and the abundance of labour and high

turnover.

67

The preceding sections accounted for the dualism in the Turkish economy, with

large enterprises operating mostly in an institutional framework and industrial mix of the CME,

and SMEs operating largely unregulated in a setup with characteristics of the LME. The latter has

a critical lack of human resources and an absence of key institutions to attain the dynamic

competition that fosters the high productivity levels in developed LMEs. The result is that firms

face two discrete institutional setups, according to their size, in the Turkish market economy.

For large enterprises, the plethora of unregulated smaller firms provide a highly

flexible supply base and a readily available supply of low skill labour to produce during upturns.

However, SMEs lack basic technology and knowhow limiting the range of products supplied

from here. An example of this in the section on inter-firm relations is that large firms in the

automotive industry – Turkey’s biggest export sector - have been forced to assist with

implementation of basic technology for domestic suppliers. A crucial concern is the the lack of

access to credit for SMEs and the labour regulation which kicks in at 30 employees. This makes

it economically taxing for SMEs to grow beyond de-facto micro enterprises. The implication of

these constraints is that the SME segment is too far behind technologically to supply the

components for the larger firms or to harvest dynamic gains from competition for the position as

suppliers. Furthermore, the low skill levels for the SME labour force and slight correlation

between products and processes does little to prepare workers for switches between the two

segments. The lack of labour fluidity back and forth between large and small enterprises is

especially discouraging for SMEs, who are in dire need of technological upgrades.

The notion of comparative institutional advantage proposes that industries that

benefit from a CME setup, such as engineering and heavy industry, have institutional

complements when operating in an institutional setup that supports coordination and long term

strategic planning. Large firms in Turkey predominantly operates in the manufacturing and heavy

industry and are owned by one of the family-controlled conglomerates. The patriarchs of these

have near-autonomy on operations and strategy, which allows for great strategic manoeuvrability.

This provides a potential edge relative to competitors in developed CMEs where industry

collaboration has to consider a variety of stakeholders. Similarly, comparative advantages toward

developed LMEs can be derived where firms are subject to arduous anti-trust legislation. The

stock of human resources in Turkey is low, but the state provides generous tax subsidies for

training and education. This benefits the conglomerates, which has both the patient capital for

investment and intimate knowledge to inform curricula. Lastly, membership of the European

68

Customs Union provide Turkish industry with a huge export market, with has plenty of room for

exploitation due to the comparably low unit labour cost, which makes up for the still-developing

nature of Turkish industry. As accounted for above, the domestic market for SMEs is scarcely

utilized. Furthermore, the exporting part of the segment is primarily engaged in agricultural

products where growth potentials are limited.

A large and low productivity sector employing the bulk of the working population

is common for most developing countries. For a developing country, the transitional capabilities

and interplay with the high productivity sector is a major component of growth in the private

sector. Attempts to address some of the components of the ideal-types which have been identified

as lacking by this paper is currently under way: in 2012, as part of a major overhaul of the

educational system, the Turkish government increased mandatory education to 12 years. A range

of initiatives in the 2000s seeks to increase access to credit and knowledge for SMEs. EU

accession talks stress empowerment of unions and employer organisations. The effect of these

initiatives have yet to play out.

Firms in Turkey operate in two distinct institutional setups. The gap between the

two warrants further investigation of possible adjustment paths for the Turkish political economy.

Identifying the adjustment path for Turkey should correspond to an analysis of the most effective

institutional setup to produce high growth rates. This paper has mapped the institutional setup

facing firms. To fully inform such an analysis further studies would be needed, both comparative

as well as of institutions not covered by this study e.g. political structures and the distribution of

power in Turkey.

Finally, it would be of interest to compare the case of Turkey and a key

characteristic as identified by this paper such as the divided institutional setup, with recently

developed countries that have gone through a similar developmental stage. Economies of interest

that could inform further research agendas are Japan following World War II, South Korea in the

1990’s, China in this century or countries currently at a similar level of income such as Mexico,

Poland or Brazil.

69

8. Conclusion This thesis set out to analyse the institutional setup in Turkey using the theoretical framework of

Varieties of Capitalism. The Turkish institutional setup is characterised by a deep division

between two segments of the economy – SMEs and larger enterprises. The institutional setup

facing firms in each segment lean toward opposite ideal types of the VoC approach. However,

both lack crucial elements in order to be classified completely as either ideal type, and have

barriers blocking fruitful interplay between the two segments.

The SME segment employ the vast majority of workers in Turkey and the main

characteristic is the highly fluid labour market. In all spheres, a predominant feature is the

absence of formal rules or coordinated solutions. Outside the labour market, the functional

equilibria that solve market coordination problems rely on family and relational solutions. While

this setup does resemble the LME ideal type, vital parts are absent: lack of access to credit, very

low general skill levels, serious impediments to knowledge dissemination. In the framework of

the VoC a common LME solution to these problems are improvements to education, well-

functioning financial markets and no regulatory impediments to growth.

Large enterprises in Turkey has much higher productivity than that of the SMEs and

has significant room to grow. The institutional setup for large enterprises rely on coordinated and

formal solutions. Key characteristics are family dynasties and business groups that own or control

a wide range of industries, and the state-regulated labour-market protection that, in the absence of

unions, incentivises long tenures. The former enables long-term strategic investments and the

latter encourages investment in specific skills for workers. The CME ideal type benefits greatly

from collaborative and coordinated efforts by active labour and employer organisations. These

ensure that wide varieties of stakeholders are included in strategic planning. The dominant

industries for large enterprises in Turkey are manufacturing and heavy industries. This is in line

with VoC predictions on comparative advantages that derives from coordinated measures.

The interplay between these two segments is very weak and the LME

characteristics of the SME sector has not succeeded in stimulating dynamic competition nor of

providing technology and higher skill levels. This precludes them from becoming a source of

components for the larger enterprises. The CME segment constituted by large enterprises have

successfully driven the remarkable growth in the Turkish economy, but does not have the

capacity to employ the millions of low skill workers currently employed in the SME sector.

Following the logic of the VoC, Turkey does not display the institutional setup that generates the

70

comparative advantages as described by the original authors but the institutional dualism

provides jobs for the majority of Turkish citizens while the nation builds an internationally

competitive industry.

71

9. Appendix 1

72

10. Bibliography

- Akan, T. (2012) ‘The Political Economy of Turkish Conservative Democracy as a Governmental Strategy of Industrial Relations Between Islamism, Neoliberalism and Social Democracy’, Economic and Industrial Democracy 33(2) 317-349

- Akdemir, A., Kasimoglu, M. and Ekmekci, A. (2009): ‘Managerial and Leadership Perceptions of CEOs in Leading Turkish Companies’, International Journal of Business and Management, 2009, Vol.4 (5)

- Atakan, S., Oba, B. and Ozsou, Z. (2010) ‘Power in the boardroom: a study on Turkish family-owned and listed companies’, Emerald Group Publishing Limited vol. 10 no. 5, 603-616.

- Aytekin, Miles and Esen (2013): ‘Corporate Governance: A Comparative Study of Practices in Turkey and Canada’, The IUP Journal of Corporate Governance, vol XII, no. 2.

- Balci, S. and Gurbuz, R. (2000) ‘Overview of assessment and quality assurance on TVET and a proposal for Turkey’, Ankara University Cankiri College of Arts Technology, [Online] Available: http://hdl.voced.edu.au/10707/101723 [27 Apr 2014]

- Barry, M. and Nienhueser, W. (2010): ‘coordinated market economy/liberal employment relations: low cost competition in the German aviation industry’, The International Journal of Human Resource Management, vol. 21, no. 2, February 2010, 214-229

- Baskaya, Y. and Hülagü, T. (2011) ‘Informal-Formal Worker wage Gap in Turkey: Evidence from a Semi-Parametric Approach’, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey, Working paper No 11/15.

- Börsch, A (2007) – see Hancké,B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher M. (2007) - Bolukbasi, H. T. and Ertugal, E. (2013) ‘Europeanisation of Employment Policy in Turkey:

Tracing Domestic Change through Institutions, Ideas and Interests’, South European Society and Politics, 18:2, 237-257

- Bozbura, F. T. (2007) ‘Knowledge management practices in Turkish SMEs’, Journal of Enterprise Information Management Vol. 20 No. 2, 209-221, Emerald Group Publishing Limited, [Online] Available: www.emeraldinsight.com/1741-0398.htm [12 Apr 2014]

- Campbell, J. L. and Pedersen, O. K (2007) ‘The Varieties of Capitalism and Hybrid Success Denmark in the Global Economy’, SAGE Journals, Comparative Political Studies March vol. 40: 307-332.

- Casper, S. (2001) - see Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) - Central intelligence Agency (CIA) (2014), ‘World fact book – on Turkey’, [Online]

Available: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/tu.html [30 Apr 2014]

- Crouch (2009) – see Hancké,B. (2009) - Culpepper, P. D. (2001) - see Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) - Demirag, I. & Serter, M. (2003): ‘Ownership Patterns and Control in Turkish Listed

Companies’, Corporate Governance, vol. 11, no. 1.

73

- Dombey, D. (2014); ‘Six markets to watch’, Foreign affairs, issue: (January/February) [Online] Available: http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/140338/daniel-dombey/six-markets-to-watch-turkey [3 May 2014]

- Duran, .B and Yildirim, E. (2007) ‘Islamism, Trade Unionism and Civil Society: The Case of Hak-Is Labour Confederation in Turkey’, Middle Eastern Studies 41:2, 227-247

- Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU) (2014), ‘Country Data – Turkey’, [Online] Available: http://country.eiu.com.esc-web.lib.cbs.dk/Turkey: [30 Apr 2014]

- Elci, Sirin (2011). ‘Leveraging Training Skills Development in SMEs: an analysis of OSTIM organised industrial zone, turkey’, OECD report, [Online] http://www.oecd.org/cfe/leed/tsmes.htm [01 May 2014]

- Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T. and Soskice, D. (2001) – see Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) - European Trade Union Confederation (ETUC) (2010), ‘ Turkish trade unions and industrial

relations’, [Online] available: (http://www.etuc.org/sites/www.etuc.org/files/TURKISH_3.pdf [16 Apr 2014]

- Feldman, M (2006) ‘Emerging varieties of capitalism in transition countries: Industrial relations and wage bargaining in Estonia and Slovenia’, Comparative Political Studies vol. 39 no. 7, 829-854.

- Franzese, Jr. R. J. (2001) – see Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) - Goyer, M. (2007) – see Hancké,B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher. (2007) - Gumus, G., Mandaci, P. (2010): ‘Ownership Concentration, Managerial Ownership and

Firm Performance: Evidence from Turkey’, South East European Journal of Economics and Business, vol. 5, issue 1, pages 57-66.

- Gönenc, R. et al. (2012), ‘Structural Reform s to Boost Turkey's Long-Term Growth’, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 987, OECD [Online] available: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k92sm v7cnjl-en [14 Apr 2014]

- Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) Varieties of Capitalism, Oxford (UK), Oxford University Press. Contributors: - Franzese, Jr. R. J. (104-144) - Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, P. and Soskice, D (145-183) - Culpepper, P. D. (275-306) - Casper, S. (387-416)

- Hancké,B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (2007) Beyond varieties of capitalism, Oxford (UK), Oxford University press. Contributors: - Soskice, D. (89-121) - Thatcher, M. (147-172) - Börsch, A. (173-194) - Goyer, M. (195-222)

- Hancké,B. (2009) Debating Varieties of Capitalism, Oxford (UK): Oxford University press Contributors:

74

- Crouch, C (75-94) - Hussmanns, Ralf. (2004) ILO Switzerland ‘Defining and measuring informal employment’

Bureau of Statistics International Labour Office [Online] Available: http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/stat/download/papers/meas.pdf [1 May 2014]

- Höpner,M. (2005) ‘What connects industrial relations and corporate governance? Explaining institutional complimentarity’, Socio-Economic Reviw vol. 3, 331-358

- International Labour Organisation (ILO), (2012) ‘Statistical update on employment in the informal economy’, ILO - Department of Statistics June 2012 [Online] Available: http://laborsta.ilo.org/informal_economy_E.html [15 Apr 2014]

- International Labour Organisation (ILO), (2014) ‘Employment protection legislation database – Turkey, [Online] Available: http://www.ilo.org/dyn/eplex/termmain.showCountry?p_lang=en&p_country_id=21 [3 May 2014]

- International Labour Organization (ILO), (2014b), ’ Informal economy’ [Online] Available: http://www.ilo.int/global/topics/employment-promotion/informal-economy/lang--en/index.htm [2 May 2014]

- International Monetary Fund (IMF), (2013a) ‘Turkey: Increasing Saving to Reduce Vulnerabilities’ [Online] Available: www.imf.orgexternalpubsftsurveyso2013car122013a.htm [Accessed April 20 2014]

- Jackson, P. T. (2011) ‘The conduct of inquiry in international relations: Philosophy of science and its implications for the study of world politics’, New York and Abingdon, Routledge

- Kamasak, R. and Bulutlar, F. (2009) ‘The influence of knowledge sharing on innovation’, European Business Review, Vol. 22 No. 3, 306-317, Emerald Group Publishing Limited [Online] Available: www.emeraldinsight.com/0955-534X.htm [17 Apr 2014]

- KOSGEB (Republic of Turkey Small and Medium Enterprises Development Organization) (2012) ‘Enhancing the competitiveness of SMEs in Turkey’ [Online] Available: http://www.comcec.org/UserFiles/File/%C3%BClkeraporlar%C4%B1/28_isedak_%C3%BClke_rap/T%C3%BCrkiye.pdf (20 May 2014)

- Krugman P. R., Obstfeld M. and Melitz M. J. (2012) International Economics, Global Edition (Ninth Edition), Essex, Pearson Education Limited

- Kula,V. and Tatoglu, E. (2006): ‘Board process attributes and company performance of family-owned businesses in Turkey’, Corporate Governance vol. 6, No. 5, 624-634

- Mustafa A. A. in Güler A. and David Crowther (2008) ‘Culture and Corporate Governance’, Published online, Social Responsibility Research Network, Available: http://www.socialresponsibility.biz/ccgadvert.html [1 May 2014]

- Oba, Ozsoy and Atakan (2010): ‘Power in the boardroom: a study on Turkish family-owned and listed companies’, Corporate Governance vol. 10 no. 5 p. 603-616

- Oba, B. and Semercioz, F. (2005) ‘Antecedents of trust in industrial districts: an empirical analysis of inter-firm relations in a Turkish industrial district’, Entrepreneurship and

75

regional development (Routledge), Volume: 17 Issue: 3, 163-182 - OECD (1999) by Maria Maher and Thomas Andersson, ‘Corporate Governance: Effects on

Firm Performance and Economic Growth’ [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/2090569.pdf [10 May 2014]

- OECD (2004) ‘Small and medium-sized enterprises in Turkey’, [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/industry/smes/31932173.pdf [2 May 2014]

- OECD (2011) (Vocational training) ‘OECD Council Working Party on Shipbuilding (WP6) The Shipbuilding Industry in Turkey’, [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/turkey/48641944.pdf [26 Apr 2014]

- OECD (2012) ‘SME Policy Index: Western Balkans And Turkey’, [Online] Available: http://www.etf.europa.eu/webatt.nsf/0/09680DD332A0B554C1257AA30029407C/$file/SMEWBalkansTurkey2012.pdf [1 Apr 2014]

- OECD (2012b) ‘Structural Reforms to Boost Turkey’s Long-Term Growth’ [Online] Available: http://search.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=ECO/WKP(2012)64&docLanguage=En [27 Apr 2014]

- OECD (2012c) ‘Human Resources Management Country Profiles’, [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/gov/pem/OECD%20HRM%20Profile%20-%20Turkey.pdf [6 May 2014]

- OECD statistics (2013) ‘GDP comparison’, [Online] Available: http://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?queryid=557 [3 May 2014]

- OECD (2013), ‘EDUCATION POLICY OUTLOOK: TURKEY © OECD‘ [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/edu/EDUCATION%20POLICY%20OUTLOOK%20TURKEY_EN.pdf [26 Apr 2014]

- OECD Statistics (2014a) ’Minimum wage relative to average wages of full-time workers’ [Online], Available: http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=MIN2AVE [22 Apr 2014]

- OECD Statistics (2014b) ‘Trade Union Density’, [Online], Available: http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=UN_DEN [17 May 2014]

- OECD Statistics (2014c) ‘Strictness of employment protection – individual and collective dismissals (regular contracts)’, [Version 3], [Online], Available: http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=EPL_R# [17 May 2014]

- OECD statistics (2014d) ‘Full time and part time employment’, [Online] Available: http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DatasetCode=FTPTC_I [6 May 2014]

- OECD (2014a) (the case) ‘Society at a glance Society at a Glance 2014 – Social Indicators © OECD March 2014’ [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/turkey/OECD-SocietyAtaGlance20142014-Highlights-Turkey.pdf [1 May 2014]

76

- OECD (2014b) ‘Compare your country – data comparison’ [Online] Available:

(http://www.compareyourcountry.org/chart?project=crisis-impact&cr=tur&lg=en; [30 Apr 2014]

OECD (2014c) ‘Society at a glance 2014’ [Online] Available: http://www.oecd.org/turkey/OECD-SocietyAtaGlance20142014-Highlights-Turkey.pdf [15 Apr 2014]

- Salem, M., Bensidoun, I., and Pelek, S. (2011) ‘Informal Employment In Turkey: An Overview’, Région et Développement, no 34, 2011.

- Şengün, A. E. and Önder, C. (2011) ‘The Conditional Impact of Competence Trust on Inter-Firm Learning in a Collectivist SME Context’, Industry and Innovation, 18:8, 791-812

- Sengün, A. E. and Wasti, S. N. (2009) ‘Revisiting Trust and Control: Effects on Perceived Relationship Performance’, International Small Business Journal, Issue 27:(I), 39 – 69, Sage Puplications.

- Şengün, A. E. (2010) ‘Which Type of Trust for Inter-firm Learning?’, Industry and Innovation, 17:2, 193-213, Routledge. [Online] Available: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13662711003633447 [23 Apr 2014]

- Soskice, D. (2007) – see Hancké,B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (2007) - Thatcher, M. (2007) – see Hancké,B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (2007) - The Economist (2012): ‘The Battle for Turkcell’, Issue: Apr 21st 2012, [Online] Available:

http://www.economist.com/node/21553054 [19 Apr 2014] - The Economist (2014a): ‘Game of Courts’, Issue: Feb 6th 2014, [Online] Available:

http://www.economist.com/blogs/schumpeter/2014/02/battle-over-turkcell [19 Apr 2014] - The Economist (2014b): ‘Too big to fail, but in a good way’, Issue: Feb 1st 2014, [Online]

Available: http://www.economist.com/news/business/21595463-two-huge-family-firms-koc-and-sabanci-should-weather-turkeys-crisis-too-big-fail [23 Apr 2014]

- TOBB (2014) ‘The Union of Chambers and Commodity Exchanges of Turkey’, [Online] Available: http://www.tobb.org.tr/Sayfalar/Eng/AmaciveYapisi.php [3 May 2014]

- TUSIAD (2014) ‘Numbers from a employer organistation’, [Online] Available: http://www.tusiad.org/tusiad/tusiad-by-numbers/ [3 May 2014]

- Turkeys Prime Ministry (TPM), (2014a) ‘Investment support and Promotion Agency – Demography and Labour Force’, [Online] Available: http://www.invest.gov.tr/en-US/investmentguide/investorsguide/Pages/DemographyAndLaborForces.aspx [29 Apr 2014]

- Turkeys Prime Ministry (TPM), (2014b) ‘Automotive industry’, [Online] Available: (http://www.invest.gov.tr/en-US/infocenter/publications/Documents/AUTOMOTIVE.INDUSTRY.pdf [25 Apr 2014]

- Turkstat (2014a) ‘Demographic indicators’, [Online] Available: http://www.turkstat.gov.tr/UstMenu.do?metod=temelist [2 May 2014]

Turkstat (2014b) ‘Annual Industry and Service Statistics’

77

‘Foreign Trade, May 2013’ ‘Annual Industry and Service Statistics’ [Online] Available: www.turkstat.gov.tr

- United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), (2013), ‘Turkey Ranks 90th in Human Development Index’ [Online] http://www.tr.undp.org/content/turkey/en/home/presscenter/news-from-new-horizons/2013/03/15/turkey-ranks-90th-in-hdi/ [16 May 2014]

- Vega, S. V. and Parisaki, M. (2008) ‘Capasity building for social dialogue at sectoral and company level in the new Member States, Croatia and Turkey’, Eurofound, [Online] Available: ttp://www.eurofound.europa.eu/publications/htmlfiles/ef0791.htm [3 May 2014]

- Wasti, S. N. and Wasti S. A. (2008) ‘Trust in Buyer-Supplier Relations: The Case of the Turkish Automotive Industry’, Journal of International Business Studies (Palgrave Macmillan Journals), Vol. 39, No. 1, 118-131

- World Bank (2011) ‘Turkey – improving conditions for SME growth, finance and inovation’, [Online] Available: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2011/08/17068912/turkey-improving-conditions-sme-growth-finance-innovation [21 Apr 2014]

- World Bank (2012) ‘Turkey – corporate bond market development’, [Online] Available: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/12439 [2 May 2014]

- World Bank (2013) ‘Turkey: Evaluating The Impact of İşkur’s Vocational Training Programs’, [Online] Available: http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2014/02/27/000442464_20140227121911/Rendered/PDF/823060P12051400h0final0report0small.pdf [17 Apr 2014]

- World Bank, (2014): ‘Market capitalization of listed companies (% of GDP)’ [Online] Available: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/CM.MKT.LCAP.GD.ZS [20 April 2014]

- World Economic Forum (WEForum), (2008): ‘The Global Competitiveness Report 2008-2009 Section VII Financial market sophistication’ [Online] Available: http://www.weforum.org/pdf/GCR08/Section%20VIII_Financial%20market%20sophistication.pdf [20 Apr 2014]

- Yildirim, E. and Calis, S. (2008) ‘The Impact of EU Accession on Turkish Industrial Relations and Social Dialogue’, Industrial Relations Journal, Vol. 39 No. 3, 212-228

- Yurtoglu, B.B. (2000): ‘Ownership, Control and Performance of Turkish Listed Firms’, Empirica, vol 27, p 193-222

- Zehir, C. and Özsahin, M. (2008) ‘A field research on the relationship between strategic decision-making speed and innovation performance in the case of Turkish large-scale firms’, Management Decision, Vol. 46 No. 5, 709 – 724


Recommended