+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

Date post: 05-Jul-2018
Category:
Upload: carlos-martins
View: 216 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 13

Transcript
  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    1/13

    International taxation and multinational  rm location decisions☆

    Salvador Barrios  a, Harry Huizinga  b,⁎, Luc Laeven   c, Gaëtan Nicodème  d

    a European Commission, Joint Research Centre, IPTS b Tilburg University and CEPRc International Monetary Fund, Tilburg University and CEPRd European Commission, ULB, CEPR and CESifo

    a b s t r a c ta r t i c l e i n f o

     Article history:

    Received 3 November 2008Received in revised form 18 June 2012

    Accepted 18 June 2012

    Available online 14 July 2012

     JEL classi cation:

    F23

    G32

    H25

    R38

    Keywords:

    Corporate taxation

    Withholding taxes

    Dividends

    Location decisions

    Foreign direct investment

    Multinationals

    Using a large international  rm-level data set, we examine the separate effects of host and additional parent

    country taxation on the location decisions of multinational rms. Both types of taxation are estimated to have

    a negative impact on the location of new foreign subsidiaries. The impact of parent country taxation is esti-

    mated to be sizeable consistent with its international discriminatory nature. Our results show that interna-

    tional double taxation by the parent country   –  despite the general possibility of deferral of taxation until

    income repatriation  –  is instrumental in shaping the structure of multinational enterprise.

    © 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    1. Introduction

    With globalization and the progressive removal of barriers to trade,

    an increasing number of companies develop international activities. To

    access foreign markets, rms face a choice between producing goods at

    home for exports and producing abroad. A host of tax and non-tax fac-

    tors affect the decision whether to relocate production abroad. Among

    the non-tax factors are the size of a foreign market, its growth pros-

    pects, wage and productivity levels abroad, the foreign regulatory

    and legal environment, and distance from the parent country (see

    Görg and Greenaway (2004), Barrios et al. (2005), and Mayer and

    Ottaviano (2007) for recent reviews). The impact of taxation on for-

    eign direct investment (FDI) has been the subject of a sizeable liter-

    ature, as reviewed by De Mooij and Ederveen (2006) and Devereux

    and Maf ni (2007).

    Studies of the effect of taxation on FDI location decisions generally

    examine host country taxation to the exclusion of possible additional

    parent country taxation. The contribution of this paper is to jointly con-

    sider the impact of host and additional parent countrytaxation on mul-

    tinational  rm location decisions. As a  rst level of taxation, the host

    country may impose corporate income taxation on the income of localforeign subsidiaries. In addition, the host country could levy a non-

    resident dividend withholding tax on the subsidiary's earnings at the

    time they are repatriated to the parent   rm. But taxation need not

    stop at the host country level. The parent country can further choose

    to levy a corporate income tax on the resident multinational's foreign

    source income giving rise to internationaldouble taxation. We examine

    the independent impactof all three levelsof taxation on the location de-

    cisions of European multinationals over the period 1999–2003. Speci-

    cally, we examine how these three levels of taxation affect in which

    country a multinational headquartered in a certain country chooses to

    locate a new foreign subsidiary.

     Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946–958

    ☆   The authorsthank JimHines andJoel Slemrod (the Editors), twoanonymous referees,

    Wiji Arulampalam, Peter Finnigan, Andreas Hauer, Vanesa Hernandez Guerrero and

    seminar participants at the Bancode España, the European Commission, the SolvayBrussels

    School of Economics and Management, ZEW Mannheim, the CESifo area conference on

    public sectoreconomics in 2009,and theCentrefor BusinessTaxationof OxfordUniversity

    Summer Symposium in 2009 for valuable comments. The  ndings, interpretations, and

    conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They should not be

    attributed to the European Commission or the International Monetary Fund.

    ⁎   Corresponding author at: Department of Economics, Tilburg University, 5000 LE

    Tilburg, Netherlands. Tel.: +31 13 4662623.

    E-mail address: [email protected] (H. Huizinga).

    0047-2727/$  – see front matter © 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004

    Contents lists available at  SciVerse ScienceDirect

     Journal of Public Economics

     j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / j p u b e

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004mailto:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/00472727http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/00472727http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004mailto:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.06.004

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    2/13

    We have collected new detailed information on how parent country

    tax systems interact bilaterally with corporate taxation and non-

    resident withholding taxation in the host country. Specically, we use

    information on whether or not countries tax the income of their multi-

    nationalson a worldwide basis, and whether foreigntax credits arepro-

    vided for non-residentwithholding taxes only or also for theunderlying

    host country corporate tax (as, for instance, in the United States). As an

    alternative to worldwide taxes, parent countries may partially or fullyexempt foreign source income from taxation. For example, Germany

    exempts 95% of the foreign source income of German multinationals

    from taxation.

    Data on the structures of European multinationals, and in particular

    on newforeign subsidiarylocations, areobtained from theAmadeus da-

    tabase. This data set allows us to consider multinational companies

    resident in a broad set of countries, each potentially having foreign sub-

    sidiaries in many other countries. Thus, unlike earlier work this paper

    considers multinational  rm location choices in a multilateral setting

    of N by N countries. In addition to being an innovative approach, this

    multi-country framework is necessary to obtain suf cient variation in

    additional parent country corporate taxation (not highly correlated

    with host country corporate taxation) to be able to separately estimate

    its impact on international location decisions.

    Our results suggest that host country and additional parent coun-

    try corporate income taxation both discourage the location of foreign

    subsidiaries in a particular country. In our benchmark estimation, the

    estimated negative impact of the two types of taxation   –  as derived

    from statutory tax information   –  is about of equal size. Our  nding

    of a signicant role for the additional parent country tax in foreign

    subsidiary taxation is new, and perhaps surprising. Many countries

    allow parent country taxes on foreign source income to be deferreduntil dividend repatriation, reducing the scope for these taxes to af-

    fect location decisions. All the same, we  nd that foreign subsidiary

    location   – and the resulting international ownership pattern of sub-

    sidiaries –  is sensitive to additional parent country taxation. Multina-

    tional  rms act on an apparently signicant incentive to bring about

    an international ownership pattern of subsidiaries that is internation-

    ally tax-ef cient.

    We perform several robustness checks to better understand the role

    of host and parent country taxation in determining foreign subsidiary lo-

    cation. We  nd that location decisions of highly protable foreign sub-

    sidiaries are less responsive to both host and parent country taxation

    than location decisions of less protable foreign subsidiaries, perhaps be-

    cause high protability reects location- or owner-specic rents that

    would be destroyed by an alternative locationor nationalowner. Further,

     Table 1

    Corporate taxation and double tax relief methods for dividends received in European countries in 2003.

    Corporate tax rate including local

    taxes and surcharges (%)

    Treatment of foreign dividends

    from treaty countries

    Treatment of foreign dividends

    from non-treaty countries

    Austria 24 Exemption Exemption

    Belgium 33.99 Exemption (up to 95%) Exemption (up to 95%)

    Bulgaria 23.5 Indirect credit Direct credit

    Croatia 20 Exemption Exemption

    Cyprus 15 Exemption Exemption

    Czech Republic 31 Indirect credit DeductionDenmark 30 Exemption Exemption

    Estonia 26 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Finland 29 Exemption Direct credit

    France 35.43 Exemption (up to 95%) Exemption (up to 95%)

    Germany 39.59 Exemption (up to 95%) Exemption (up to 95%)

    Greece 35 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Hungary 19.64 Exemption Exemption

    Iceland 18 Exemption Exemption

    Ireland 12.5 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Italy 38.25 Exemption (up to 60%) Exemption (up to 60%)

    Latvia 19 Exemption Exemption

    Lithuania 15 Exemption Exemption

    Luxembourg 30.38 Exemption Exemption

    Malta 35 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Netherlands 34.5 Exemption Exemption

    Norway 28 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Poland 27 Indirect credit Direct CreditPortugal 33 Direct credit Direct credit

    Romania 25 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Russia 24 Direct credit No relief  

    Slovak Republic 25 Indirect credit No relief  

    Slovenia 25 Exemption Exemption

    Spain 35 Exemption Indirect credit

    Sweden 28 Exemption Exemption

    Switzerland 21.74 Exemption Exemption

    Turkey 33 Indirect credit Direct credit

    United Kingdom 30 Indirect credit Indirect credit

    Notes: Corporate tax rate denotes the statutory corporate tax rate including local taxes and surcharges. Statutory corporate tax rate in Estonia is 0% on

    retained earnings but a distribution tax of 26% is applied on distributed pro t. Corporate tax rate of France includes a 3% social surcharge and a special

    3.3% surcharge for large companies. Corporate tax rate of Germany includes a solidarity surcharge of 5.5%, an average deductible trade tax of 16.14%, and

    an exceptional surcharge of 1.5%. Corporate tax rate of Hungary includes a deductible local business tax. Corporate tax rate of Ireland applies to trading

    activities. For non-trading activities, the rate is 25%. Corporate tax rate of Luxembourg includes employment surcharges and local taxes. Corporate tax

    rate of Switzerland applies to the canton of Zurich and includes cantonal and local taxes in Zurich. Treatment of foreign dividends refers to double tax

    relief convention used by parent country. Foreign subsidiaries are assumed to be fully owned. The indirect credit system applies to foreign dividendsfrom treaty countries in Poland as long as the holding stake is at least 75% for the past 2 years and there exists a bilateral treaty or the EU

    parent-subsidiary directive applies. In Portugal, foreign dividends from treaty countries are exempt from corporate taxes if the EU parent-subsidiary di-

    rective applies, but the foreign withholding tax is not creditable. In some countries, dividend income is exempt from taxes up to a certain percentage,

    indicated between brackets. Source: International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation.

    947S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    3/13

    location choicesof foreign subsidiarieswithlowxed assetsare more re-

    sponsiveto both host andparent country taxation. This could reect that

    high  xed assets are a barrier to choosing an alternative physical loca-

    tion. Finally, we  nd that international location decisions are relatively

    sensitive to international double taxation – including the additional par-

    ent country taxation– if theparent country does notallowthe deferralof 

    foreign source income until dividend repatriation.

    Existing studies of the inuence of corporate taxes on multina-

    tionals’ location have in general paid little attention to the role played

    by parent country taxes. For instance, Devereux and Grif th (1998) in-

    vestigate how host country taxationaffects the subsidiary location deci-

    sions of US multinationals in several large European countries (France,

    Germany, and the United Kingdom) over the period 1980–1994. Theynd that   –   conditional on the choice to locate production abroad   –

    host country average effective tax rates (but not marginal effective tax

    rates) are important in determining foreign location choice, even if tax-

    ation does not appear to affect the earlier choice to locate abroad or to

    export. Buettner and Ruf (2007) in turn  nd that location choices of 

    German multinationals across 18 potential host countries between

    1996 and 2003 are affected more by host country statutory tax rates

    thaneffective average tax rates, while they nd no effect of marginal ef-

    fective tax rates.

    Several authors, however, have previously found a role for addi-

    tional parent country taxation to affect the location of FDI. For US

    multinationals, Kemsley (1998)  nds that the host country tax only

    affects the ratio of US exports to foreign production over the period

    1984–

    1992 if the multinationals   nd themselves in excess credit

    positions.1 Analogously, a role of parent country taxation in affecting

    FDI into the United States is found by  Hines (1996) who shows that

    foreign countries with worldwide taxation invest relatively much in

    US states with high state taxes. This reects that multinationals locat-

    ed in countrieswith worldwide taxation may be able to obtainforeign

    tax credits for US state corporate income taxes. Altshuler and Grubert

    (2001) evaluate the implications of a hypothetical switch to dividend

    exemption by the US to conclude, in contrast, that there is no evi-

    dence that such a change would materially affect international loca-

    tion decisions of US multinationals. Egger et al. (2009) construct an

    effective tax rate on a bilateral basis that reects overall host and

    home country taxation, and  nd that this bilateral effective tax rate

    has a negative impact on bilateral FDI stocks after controlling forhost and parent country unilateral effective tax rates.2 However,

    none of these papers studies a rm's location decision in a multilater-

    al setting of N by N countries, as we do.

     Table 2

    Bilateral dividend withholding tax rates in Europe in 2003.

    Sub sidiary c ountr y Par ent c ou ntr y A ustr ia Belgium B ulga ria C roat ia C yp rus C zech R ep . Denmar k Estonia Finla nd France Germa ny

    Austria X 0 0 0 10 10 0 5 0 0 0

    Belgium 0 X 10 10 10 5 0 25 0 0 0

    Bulgaria 0 10 X 5 5 10 5 15 10 5 15

    Croatia 0 10 5 X 10 5 5 15 5 5 0

    Cyprus 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Czech Rep. 10 5 10 5 10 X 15 5 5 10 5

    Denmark 0 0 5 5 10 15 X 5 0 0 0Estonia 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0

    Finland 0 0 10 5 29 0 0 0 X 0 0

    France 0 0 5 5 10 10 0 5 0 X 0

    Germany 0 0 15 15 10 5 0 5 0 0 X

    Greece 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Hungary 10 10 10 10 5 5 5 20 5 5 5

    Iceland 15 15 15 15 15 5 0 5 0 5 5

    Ireland 0 0 0 20 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Italy 0 0 10 10 15 15 0 5 0 0 0

    Latvia 10 10 10 5 10 5 5 5 5 5 5

    Lithuania 15 15 15 5 15 5 5 0 5 5 5

    Luxembourg 0 0 0 20 20 0 0 20 0 0 0

    Malta 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Netherlands 0 0 5 0 25 0 0 5 0 0 0

    Norway 5 15 15 15 0 5 0 5 0 0 0

    Poland 10 10 10 5 10 5 5 5 5 5 5

    Portugal 0 0 15 30 30 15 0 30 0 0 0Romania 10 5 10 5 10 10 10 10 5 10 10

    Russia 5 15 15 5 0 10 10 15 5 5 5

    Slovak Rep. 10 5 10 5 10 5 15 15 5 10 5

    Slovenia 5 5 15 15 10 5 5 15 5 5 15

    Spain 0 0 5 15 15 5 0 15 0 0 0

    Sweden 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Switzerland 5 10 5 35 35 5 0 35 5 5 5

    Turkey 16.5 16.5 16.5 11 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5

    United Kingdom 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Notes: Withholding tax rates apply to dividends paid by fully owned subsidiaries in subsidiary country to parent rm. Bilateral tax treaties are taken into account. Parent-Subsidiary

    Directive is binding between EU Member States and provides exemption from withholding tax if equity holding is at least 25%. The reported gures assume an equity holding in the

    subsidiary of at least 25%. In Ireland, subsidiaries owned by parent companies resident in EU or treaty countries are exempt from withholding tax provided that they are not under

    the control of persons not resident in such countries. In Italy, authorities can provide a refund equal to the tax claimed limited to 4/9 of the Italian withholding tax if the recipient

    can prove a tax is paid in his country on the dividend. In Luxembourg there is an exemption from withholding tax for EU and treaty partners if holding in company resident in

    Luxembourg is at least 10%. Source: International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation.

    1 US multinationals are subject to worldwide taxation in the United States. Thus,

    they have to pay tax in the United States on their foreign-source income, subject to

    the provision of a foreign tax credit for taxes already paid in the host country. The for-

    eign tax credit, in practice, is limited to the amount of US tax due on the foreign-source

    income. This implies that the overall tax on the foreign income is the host country tax if 

    this tax exceeds the US tax, while it is the US tax if this tax is the higher of the two. US

    taxes on foreign source income can be deferred until the income is repatriated.2 Repatriation taxes more broadly can affect multinational  rms' behavior. Desai et

    al. (2001) analyze the effect of repatriation taxes on dividend payments by the foreign

    af liates of US multinational  rms to nd that 1% lower repatriation tax rates are asso-

    ciated with 1% higher dividends.

    948   S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    4/13

    Using information on international M&As,   Huizinga and Voget

    (2009) nd that the international ownership pattern that emerges re-

    ects an effort to avoid international double taxation of foreignsource income. Desai and Hines (2002) argue that international dou-

    ble taxation imposed by the US can explain inversions of existing US

    multinationals, whereby the original US parent becomes a subsidiary

    and the earlier foreign subsidiary becomes the new parent rm. Voget

    (2011) nds that a multinational is more likely to relocate its head-

    quarters abroad, if it is located in a parent country with high taxation

    of foreign source income. This varied evidence on how international

    double taxation affects the structure of the multinational   rm is

    consistent with a pattern of foreign subsidiary location that avoids

    additional parent country taxation, as found in the present paper.

    Huizinga et al. (2012)   demonstrate that the international double

    taxes that are triggered by an international M&A are to a large extent

    capitalized into a lower takeover price. This also suggests that inter-

    national double taxes are economically burdensome to multinationalrms, providing them with an incentive to own foreign subsidiaries

    that are subject to low parent country taxation.

    At a theoretical level, Hartman (1985) makes a distinction between

    ‘mature’  foreign af liates that are  nanced at the margin by retained

    earnings, and   ‘immature’   foreign af liates that rely on funding from

    their parent rms. The af liate's required rate of return is shown to re-

    ect parent country taxation only if it is immature. Parent country tax-

    ation thus should be particularly important for the newly established

    foreign subsidiaries that are examined in this paper.

    In the remainder of this paper,  Section 2 describes the tax treat-

    ment of the foreign source income of multinational  rms.  Section 3

    discusses our  rm-level data. Section 4 presents estimates of the im-

    pact of international taxation on the location of foreign subsidiaries.

    Finally,  Section 5 concludes.

    2. The international tax system

    This section describes the corporate tax system applicable to amultinational company with foreign subsidiaries.3 Consider a multi-

    national company with a parent located in home country p and a sub-

    sidiary located in host country  s. Both home and host countries may

    tax the subsidiary's income. First, the host country may levy a corpo-

    rate income tax at a rate t s on this income. Table 1 shows the statutory

    corporate income tax rates for the 33 European countries in our sam-

    ple for the year 2003.4 These statutory tax rates are those on distrib-

    uted prots and include local taxes and applicable surcharges. In our

    sample, the corporate tax rate for 2003 ranges from a low of 12.5% in

    Ireland to a high of 39.6% in Germany.

    Next, the host country levies a non-resident dividend withholding

    tax at a rate ws on the subsidiary's net of corporate tax income upon

    repatriation of this income to the parent.  Table 2 provides informa-

    tion on the applicable withholding tax rates on dividends paid byfully owned subsidiaries to their non-resident parents in 2003. For

    example, a dividend paid by a Belgian subsidiary to its parent compa-

    ny located in Estonia will be subject to a withholding tax of 25%, while

    the withholding tax on a dividend paid by an Estonian subsidiary to

    its Belgian parent company has a zero rate. The withholding tax

    Greece Hungary Iceland Ireland Italy Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Norway Poland

    0 10 25 0 0 25 25 0 15 0 5 10

    0 10 25 0 0 25 25 0 15 0 5 10

    10 10 15 5 10 15 15 5 0 5 15 10

    5 5 15 15 10 5 15 15 5 5 15 5

    0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    15 5 5 5 15 5 5 5 5 0 5 5

    0 5 0 0 0 5 5 0 0 0 0 00 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    0 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    0 5 5 0 0 5 5 0 5 0 0 5

    0 5 5 0 0 5 5 0 5 0 0 5

    X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    10 X 20 5 10 20 20 5 5 5 10 10

    15 15 X 15 15 5 5 5 15 0 0 5

    20 0 20 X 0 0 0 0 20 0 0 0

    0 10 27 0 0 27 5 0 15 0 15 10

    10 10 5 5 10 X 0 10 5 5 5 5

    15 15 5 5 5 0 X 15 15 5 5 5

    0 0 0 0 0 20 20 X 0 0 0 0

    0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0

    0 5 0 0 0 5 5 0 5 X 0 0

    20 10 0 0 15 5 5 5 15 0 X 5

    15 10 5 0 10 5 5 5 5 0 5 X

    0 15 15 0 0 30 30 0 15 0 15 1510 5 10 3 10 10 10 5 5 5 10 5

    15 10 15 10 5 15 15 10 15 5 10 10

    15 5 15 0 15 10 10 5 5 0 5 5

    15 10 15 5 10 5 5 5 15 5 15 5

    0 5 5 0 0 15 15 0 15 0 10 5

    0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    5 10 5 10 15 5 5 0 35 0 5 5

    16.5 11 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 11 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 11

    0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    3 See Huizinga et al. (2008) for a more detailed description of corporate tax systems

    as they apply to multinational companies. This study is limited to the impact of the in-

    ternational taxation of dividends on location decisions, even though the taxation of 

    other forms of income such as royalties or interest could also be important in corporate

    location choices.4 For illustrative purposes, the tables report taxation data for the year 2003 only, al-

    though we have collected these data for the entire period 1999–

    2003.

    949S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    5/13

    rates for transactions involving two EU Member States currently are

    zero on account of the EU Parent-Subsidiary Directive.5

    The net of withholding tax dividend received by the parent com-

    pany is in principle taxed in the parent country–subject to some

    form of double tax relief as recommended by the OECD Model TaxTreaty or as prescribed by the EU Parent-Subsidiary Directive. Some

    countries operate an exemption system. In this instance, the dividend

    is not taxed in the parent country, if the provided exemption is full.

    The overall international rate of taxation on the subsidiary's income

    is then given by 1−(1− t s)(1−ws) or  t s+ ws− t sws.

    In other instances, the home country may tax the worldwide in-

    come of its multinationals and subject the received dividend to corpo-

    rate income taxation at a rate   t p. Generally, a foreign tax credit is

    provided for taxes paid in the host country, usually limited to the

    amount of the home tax due on the foreign source income. Some

    countries apply an indirect tax credit system under which both the

    corporate tax and the withholding tax paid in the host country are

    credited against the home corporate income tax. In case the home

    country's corporate income tax   t p   is higher than the overall hostcountry tax rate   t s+ ws−t sws, the   rm pays income tax in the

    home country at a rate t p− [t s+ws− t sws] so that the combined, ef-

    fective tax rate is equal to  t p. If instead the home country's corporate

    income tax rate is lower than the overall host country's rate, the  rm

    is said to be in excess foreign tax credit and it will pay no further tax

    in the home country (having reduced its home tax liability to zero by

    using foreign tax credits). In this instance, the combined, effective tax

    rate is t s+ws− t sws. In summary, for home countries with an indirect

    tax credit system, the combined, effective tax rate is equal to max

    [t p, t s+ ws− t sws].

    Home countries may restrict the foreign tax credit to cover only

    host country non-resident withholding taxes giving rise to a direct

    tax credit system. In this case, the multinational has to pay tax in

    the home country to the extent that  t p exceeds ws and the combined,

    effective tax rate is given by t s+(1−

    t s) max[t p, ws].Alternatively, some home countries offer neither exemption nor a

    foreign tax credit for taxes paid abroad, but instead allow foreign

    taxes to be deducted from home country taxable corporate income.

    This amounts to the deduction system with a combined, effective

    tax rate of 1−(1− t s)(1−ws)(1−t p).

    Finally, in some rather exceptional cases no double tax relief is

    provided at all. With full double taxation, the combined, effective

    tax rate becomes t s+ ws− t sws+t p.

    Columns 3 and 4 of  Table 1 indicate which doubletax relief system

    is applied by European countries in the sample. As seen in the table,

    some countries provide different double tax relief to treaty partners

    and non-treaty countries. Thus, we need to know whether there

    exist doubletax treaties among thecountries in oursample. On a bilat-

    eral basis, this information is provided in Table 3 with the value 1 in-dicating the existence of such a treaty and 0 its absence. The table

    indicates that for many countries the treaty network is not complete.

    Forexample,in 2003 theCzechRepublic hasa treaty with allcountries

    in the sample except Malta and Turkey. From Table 1, we see that this

    implies that dividends from all foreign subsidiaries paid to a Czech

    parent benet from an indirect tax credit, except for those paid by a

    Maltese or a Turkish subsidiary where the deduction system applies.

    Information from Tables 1–3 allows us to calculate the combined

    effective tax rate on foreign dividends for any pair of home and host

    countries. To  x ideas, consider the case of a dividend paid by a Mal-

    tese subsidiary to its Czech parent in 2003.  Table 1 shows that the

    statutory corporate tax rate in Malta is 35%. We infer from  Table 2

    that net prots paid as a dividend to a foreign company are never

    subject to a non-resident dividend withholding tax in Malta. As

    Subsidiary country Parent country Portugal Romania Russia Slovak Rep. Slovenia Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey United Kingdom

    Austria 0 15 5 10 5 0 0 0 25 0

    Belgium 0 5 10 5 5 0 0 10 15 0

    Bulgaria 10 10 15 10 15 5 10 5 10 10

    Croatia 15 5 5 5 15 5 15 5 10 5

    Cyprus 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Czech Rep. 10 10 10 5 5 5 0 5 15 5

    Denmark 0 10 10 15 5 0 0 0 15 0

    Estonia 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Finland 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 15 0

    France 0 10 10 10 5 0 0 5 15 0

    Germany 0 10 5 5 15 0 0 0 15 0

    Greece 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Hungary 10 5 10 5 10 5 5 10 10 5

    Iceland 10 15 15 15 15 5 0 5 15 5

    Ireland 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 20 0

    Italy 0 10 5 15 10 0 0 15 15 0

    Latvia 10 10 10 10 5 10 5 5 10 5

    Lithuania 15 10 15 10 5 5 5 5 10 5

    Luxembourg 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 20 0

    Malta 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

    Netherlands 0 0 5 0 5 0 0 0 5 0

    Norway 10 10 10 5 15 10 0 5 20 5

    Poland 10 5 10 5 5 5 5 5 10 5

    Portugal X 15 15 30 30 0 0 15 30 0

    Romania 10 X 10 10 5 10 10 10 10 10

    Russia 10 15 X 10 10 5 5 5 10 10Slovak Rep. 15 10 10 X 5 5 0 5 5 5

    Slovenia 15 15 10 5 X 5 5 5 15 5

    Spain 0 5 5 5 5 X 0 10 15 0

    Sweden 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0

    Switzerland 10 10 5 5 15 10 0 X 35 5

    Turkey 16.5 16.5 11 5.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 16.5 X 16.5

    United Kingdom 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X

     Table 2  (continued)

    5 Note that in 2003 prior to their accession, many new EU Member States still

    maintained non-zero rates vis-à-vis EU countries and vice versa.

    950   S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    6/13

    already mentioned, Table 3 indicates that no tax treaty was in force

    on income repatriated from Malta to the Czech Republic in 2003 so

    that from   Table 1   we see that incoming foreign dividends benet

    from a deduction system in Czech Republic. Finally, the same table

    indicates that the applicable corporate tax rate in this country is

    31%. From the formula above, the combined, effective tax rate equals

    1−(1−0.35)×(1−0)×(1−0.31)=55.2%. This rate is considerably

    higher than the Maltese corporate tax rate of 35%. This suggests

    that the additional taxation of multinational 

    rms, in the form of withholding taxes and home country corporate income taxation, po-

    tentially has an independent and signicant impact on international

    location decisions.

    Below, we will investigate the independent inuences of host

    country corporate income and dividend withholding taxation and

    home country corporate income taxation on corporate location deci-

    sions. To make parameter estimates comparable across tax measures,

    it is useful to construct all three tax measures as shares of the foreign

    subsidiary's pre-tax income. The host country tax rate is already de-

    ned as a share of the subsidiary's pre-tax income. Our withholding

    tax measure will be (1− t s) ws to reect that the withholding tax ap-

    plies to the subsidiary's income net of the host country corporate tax.

    Finally, the additional parent country corporate income tax   –   as a

    share of the subsidiary's pre-tax income  –  is computed as the differ-

    ence between the combined, effective tax rate and   t s+ ws− t sws.

    We will dene the international tax to be the sum of the withholding

    tax and additional parent country corporate tax both expressed as

    shares of the subsidiary's pre-tax income. Equivalently, the interna-

    tional tax is the difference between the combined, effective tax and

    the host country corporate income tax.

    Unlike host country corporateincome taxes, withholding taxesand

    home country corporate income taxes are generally deferred until the

    foreign source income is repatriated to the parent in the form of divi-

    dends. Deferral reduces the present value of taxation. Thus, withhold-

    ing taxes and home country corporate income taxes are expected to‘bite’ less than host country corporate income taxes. Whether the de-

    ferral of withholding taxes and home country corporate income taxes

    serves to make these taxes immaterial for location decisions is an em-

    pirical matter. This is what we turn to in the empirical section below.

    3. Multinational enterprise data

    Data on the structure of multinational  rms in Europe are taken

    from the Amadeus database. This database provides standard ac-

    counting data and data on ownership relationships within corporate

    groups.6 We have data on multinational rms operating in 33 Europe-

    an countries over the years 1999–2003. The ownership data enable us

    to match European rms with their domestic subsidiaries and foreign

    subsidiaries located in other European countries.7 We have owner-

    ship information for the years 1999, 2001, and 2003. A  rm is called

    a subsidiary if at least 50% of the shares are owned by a single other

    rm. A subsidiary is taken to be new in its year of incorporation.

    In our benchmark analysis below, we consider 909 new foreign sub-

    sidiaries. Information on the number of parent and subsidiary countries

    involved in these new locations is provided in Panel A of  Table 4. Our

    benchmark sample excludes new locations where the parent company

    becomes an intermediate company as it is a subsidiary itself of another

    parent company. The United Kingdom with 115 new parent companies

    has most new parent companies, followed by France with 84 new par-

    ent companies. Eachsubsidiary has a home country (where its parent is

    located) and a host country (whereit is located itself). For each country,the table lists the number of subsidiaries by home country and by host

    country. The table indicates that, for example, France, the Netherlands,

    and the United Kingdom are the home country to relatively many

    subsidiaries. Hence,there are relatively manysubsidiaries with a parent

    rm in one of these countries. Denmark, Germany and the United

    Kingdom, on the other hand, are the host country to relatively many

    subsidiaries.

    Our subsequent empirical work on foreign subsidiary location

    aims to predict the location of a new foreign subsidiary in 1 of 32 for-

    eign European countries. The dependent variable, called subsidiary

    location, takes on a value of one if a particular country is selected as

    a subsidiary's location and it is zero otherwise.

    Summary statistics on the subsidiary location variable, the tax vari-

    ables, and some controls are provided in Panel B of  Table 4 (see Table

    A1 in the Appendix for variable denitions and data sources). The

    26,648 observations reported in the table are identical to the number of 

    observations in the basic regression 1 of  Table 5.8 The mean value of the

    overall effective tax is 0.35. This mean effective tax, in effect, is the sum

    of a mean host country tax of 0.30 and a mean international tax of 0.05.

    Among the control variables, GDP bilateralis the ratio ofthe GDP of a

    potential host country andthe sumof theGDPs of allother potential for-

    eign (but not domestic) locations. This variable captures market size,

    and it is expected to exert a positive impact on the probability of subsid-

    iary location in a host country.

    Contiguity is a dummy variable signaling a common border be-

    tween host and home countries. A common border is expected to

    make location in the host country more likely.

    Difference in labor costs is the log of the ratio of labor costs in the

    home country and labor costs in the host country, expressed in a com-mon currency. The impact of higher labor costs in the host country on

    the probability of location is in principle ambiguous (see Kimino et al.

    (2007) for a review of the empirical evidence). Higher labor costs in

    the host country (or a lower difference in labor costs variable) are

    expected to discourage location for a given level of labor productivity

    in the host country. In contrast, they potentially encourage location to

    the extent that they signal high labor skills and productivity that are

    sought after by the multinational  rm.

    Economic freedom is an index of the extent of soundness of the legal

    system, absence of trade barriers, absence of price controls, and transfers

    and subsidies as a share of GDP. Economic freedom should make a coun-

    try attractive as a subsidiary location.

    Finally, EU membership is a dummy variable  agging EU member-

    ship of a prospective host country. EU membership, to the extent thatis signals commitment to high EU standards of dealing with foreign in-

    vestors, could engender subsidiary location. Moreover, establishing a

    subsidiary in one EU country allows non-EU rms to trade freely across

    all other EU countries by taking advantage of the EU common market.

    Panel C of  Table 4 provides correlation coef cients among the lo-

    cation, tax and control variables. Interestingly, location is positively

    and signicantly related to the host country tax, but negatively and

    signicantly to the international tax. The  rst correlation possibly re-

    ects that subsidiaries tend to be located in larger countries, which

    tend to have relatively high corporate income taxes. In the table,

    the host country tax is indeed positively and signicantly correlated

    6 The database is created by collecting standardized data received from 50 vendors

    across Europe. The local source for these data is generally the of ce of the Registrar

    of Companies.7 The Amadeus database only contains information on European rms and we there-

    fore only cover the European operations of the multinationals in our sample. In 2001,

    intra-EU25 FDI  ows amounted to 54% of all outward FDI  ows from EU25 countries,

    while intra-EU25 FDI stocks were 57% of outward FDI stocks of EU25 countries

    (according to Eurostat). Thus, European multinationals have most of their FDI out-

    standing in other European countries. All the same, our conditioning on a European lo-

    cation of new foreign subsidiaries potentially affects estimated sensitivities of location

    to taxation. In particular, by conditioning on European locations rather than locations

    worldwide, we increase the expected probability of location in any one country and

    potentially also the sensitivity of location to taxation. New foreign subsidiaries tend

    to be large relative to the overall assets and capital of the multinational. In our sample,

    a new foreign subsidiary on average represents 23% of the assets and 24% of the capital

    of the expanded multinational  rm including the new foreign subsidiary.

    8 Note that the mean value of the location variable is not exactly 1/32 due to the ab-

    sence of data for some specic combinations of countries and years.

    951S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    7/13

    with the GDP bilateral variable as an index of host country relative

    size. The negative correlation between location and the internationaltax could reect that subsidiary location is chosen so as to mitigate in-

    ternational double taxation. The host country tax and the internation-

    al tax are negatively correlated, perhaps reecting the operation of 

    the foreign tax credit mechanism.

    4. Empirical results on taxation and subsidiary location

    In this section, we estimate the impact of host and additional parent

    country taxation on the choiceof location of a newforeign subsidiary. In

    our estimation, we explain subsidiary location choice only in the initial

    year of establishment to ensure that observations regarding different

    location episodes are independent. We condition on a foreign subsidi-

    ary location, and hence examine the impact of international taxation

    on the location choice among competing foreign locations.Our sample consists of new foreign subsidiaries that incorporate

    in one of the years from 1999 to 2003. The data set encompasses 33

    European countries, which implies that for a multinational resident

    in a particular home country there are 32 foreign location options. Ac-

    cordingly, for each new foreign subsidiary we construct 32 binary

    variables that take on a value of one if the actual location is in a cer-

    tain foreign country and zero otherwise. Regarding each potential lo-

    cation for each new foreign subsidiary, there thus is a binary choice.

    Location choice is assumed to be determined by the various countries’

    tax rates and a range of other location or country characteristics.9 The

    underlying binary choice model is estimated using the conditional

    logit approach of  McFadden (1974, 1976).

    10

    In this approach, explana-tory variables vary across alternative outcomes. All regressions include

    year xed effects, which are not reported.11 We also control for possible

    clustering of the errors at the level of the potentialhostcountry to allow

    for the possibility that shocks to the attractiveness of host countries af-

    fect more than a single subsidiary location choice.12 Specically, we re-

    port heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors that are adjusted for

    clustering at the level of the host country.

    In regression 1 of  Table 5, we relate foreign subsidiary location only

    to the effective tax rate. The number of observations is 26,648 rather

    than 29,088 (or 909 new subsidiaries times 32 potential location coun-

    tries) due to missing observations of the effective tax variable for some

    combinations of countries and years. The effective tax variable enters

    with a negative coef cient of −0.87 that is statistically insignicant.

     Table 3

    Existence of bilateral tax treaties for European country pairs in 2003.

    Income From: Austria Belgium Bulgaria Croatia Cyprus Czech

    Rep.

    Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Iceland Ireland Italy

    To:

    Austria X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1

    Belgium 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1

    Bulgaria 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1

    Croatia 1 1 0 X 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 1

    Cyprus 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1

    Czech Rep. 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Denmark 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Estonia 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 X 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 1

    Finland 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    France 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Germany 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1

    Greece 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 X 1 0 1 1

    Hungary 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 X 0 1 1

    Iceland 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 X 0 0

    Ireland 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 X 1

    Italy 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 X

    Latvia 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0

    Lithuania 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 1

    Luxembourg 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Malta 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 1

    Netherlands 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Norway 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Poland 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1Portugal 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Romania 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1

    Russia 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1

    Slovak Rep. 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1

    Slovenia 1 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1

    Spain 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Sweden 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Switzerland 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Turkey 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 1

    United Kingdom 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    Notes: This table addresses whether a tax treaty was in effect to deal with income received by countries listed in the rows and originating from countries listed in the columns.

    Specically, 1 denotes that a bilateral tax treaty was applicable and 0 denotes that a tax treaty was not applicable. The table is not exactly symmetric as the dates of rst application

    of a treaty may slightly differ between two treaty partners. Source: International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation and various ministries ’ websites.

    9 Note that we explain changes in the  rm's structure by the level of international

    taxation. Expanding  rms may have a need to establish new subsidiaries even if there

    are no changes in the level of taxation.

    10 The conditional logit model imposes the axiom of independence of irrelevant alter-

    natives (IIA), which implies that adding a third option or changing the characteristics

    of a third alternative does not affect the relative odds between any two options consid-

    ered. As a robustness check, we have estimated a nested logit model that allows us to

    relax the IIA assumption yielding results broadly similar to the ones reported in  Table 5

    (unreported).11 To enable estimation of the year  xed effects, we simultaneously consider how a

    multinational selects the location of its foreign subsidiaries over the entire period

    1999–2003, rather than 1 year at a time.12 The possibility that multinationals' location choices might be correlated both geo-

    graphically and over time has been suggested in a number of recent empirical studies.

    Crozet et al. (2004), for instance, nd evidence of positive spillovers affecting the loca-

    tion choices of French   rms investing abroad suggesting that French multinationals

    cluster geographically in a gradual process of agglomeration and market penetration.

    Head and Mayer (2004)  study the determinants of the location choices of Japanese

    multinationals in Europe and  nd a similar tendency for these multinational  rms to

    cluster in the same countries.

    952   S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    8/13

    The corresponding estimate of the marginal effect of the effective tax

    rate on the probability of location is−0.22, meaning thata one percent-

    age point increase in theeffective taxrate (from a level of zero) reduces

    the probability of location by 0.22%.

    Next, regression 2 includes a host of non-tax control variables, and

    it yields an estimated coef cient for the effective tax rate variable of 

    −4.29 that is signicant at the 1% level. The corresponding estimate

    of the marginal effect of the effective tax rate on the probability of 

    location is −0.78. Among the controls, a country's relative GDP is es-

    timated to increase the probability of subsidiary location with signif-

    icance at the 1% level. Contiguous countries are also more likely to

    receive foreign subsidiaries with signicance at the 1% level. The dif-

    ference in labor costs variable enters with a negative coef cient that

    is signicant at 1%, perhaps suggesting that high wages in prospectivehost countries signal sought after labor skills. The economic freedom

    and EU membership variables both enter with positive coef cients

    that are signicant at 10% and 1%, respectively.13

    Regression 3 substitutes the host country corporate tax rate for the

    effective tax rate. The estimated parameter on the host country tax var-

    iablehas a value of −3.42and it is signicant at the 1%level. Inlinewith

    this, a one percentage point increase in the host countrytax rate is esti-

    mated to reduce the probability of location by 0.63%. The control vari-

    ables enter regression 3 in qualitatively the same way as before.

    Regression 4 in turn includes the international tax variable   –

    reecting both non-resident withholding taxation in the host country

    and additional parent country corporate taxation  –  with an estimated

    coef cient of −1.87 that is signicant at 5%. The corresponding mar-

    ginal effect of the international tax rate on the probability of location

    is estimated to be relatively small in absolute value at 0.19.

    Next, regression 5 jointly includes the host country tax rate and

    the international tax rate, yielding estimated coef cients of  −

    4.38and −3.93, that are both signicant at 1%, with corresponding esti-

    mated marginal effects of −0.82 and −0.73.

    Finally, regression 6 splits up the effective tax rate into its three com-

    ponents: the host country corporate tax rate, the non-resident withhold-

    ing tax rate, and the additional parent country corporate tax rate.

    Parameter estimates for the host country tax rateand parent country cor-

    porate tax rate are negative and statistically signicant at 1%, while the

    non-resident dividend withholding tax rateobtains a negative coef cient

    that is statistically insignicant. A one percentage point increase in the

    host country and additional parent country tax rates are estimated to re-

    duce theprobabilityof location by 0.90% and1.07% respectively,while the

    analogous estimated effect of the non-resident withholding tax is 0.06%.

    Our results suggest that host country and additional parent country

    taxation both play a signi

    cant role in multinationals' location choices.

    13 The presence of intangible assets or R&D intensity could similarly affect the sensi-

    tivity of international location decisions to taxation. Recent evidence provided by

    Dischinger and Riedel (2011) shows that corporate taxation signicantly affects the in-

    ternational location of intangible assets given a multinational  rm's structure. To test

    this, we distinguished between  rms that belong to sectors with low and medium or

    high R&D intensity using information from the OECD Science, Technology and Industry

    Scoreboard (see OECD, 2003). Following the OECD taxonomy, medium or high R&D in-

    tensity sectors have R&D expenditure exceeding 2% of total value added. We estimated

    separate regressions analogous to regression 2 of  Table 5 for the samples of  rms be-

    longing to the two groups of sectors, yielding very similar parameter estimates for

    the effective tax rate variable (unreported).

    Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Malta Netherlands Norway Poland Portugal Romania Russia Slovak

    Rep.

    Slovenia Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey United

    Kingdom

    0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 1

    1 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 1

    0 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 11 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    0 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 1

    0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 1

    1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1

    0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    X 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 1

    1 X 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 1

    0 0 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1

    1 0 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 1 1 0 1

    1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 10 0 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 1

    1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

    0 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 0 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 1 1 1

    1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 X 1 1 1 0 1

    0 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 0 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 1 1 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X 0 1

    0 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 X 1

    1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 X

    953S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    9/13

    To evaluate the implications of tax rate changes in host and parent coun-

    tries for location decisions,one needs to recognize thatsuch changes gen-

    erally alter both our host country and additional parent country tax

    variables. An increase in the host country corporate tax rate, for instance,

    would lead to an increase in the host country tax variable and an

    off-setting reduction in the additional parent country tax variable if a

    full foreign tax credit is available (this is the case if the host country tax

    rate remainsbelow theparent countrytax rate absent non‐resident with-

    holding taxes). In this instance, the effective tax rate would remainunchanged, and the implied estimated impact on location would be

    small, as the estimated marginal effects of the host and additional parent

    country tax variables on location probabilities of −0.90 and −1.07 are

    very similar. An increase in the host country corporate tax rate, however,

    increases the host country tax variable while leaving the additional par-

    ent country tax variable unchanged, if the host country tax rate exceeds

    the parent country tax rate. In this instance, a higher host country corpo-

    ratetax ratediscourages locationin the host country, while increasing the

    combined, effective tax rate. Overall, our estimation is consistent with a

    negative relationship between the host country corporate tax rate and

    subsidiary location as generally reported in the literature surveyed by

    De Mooij and Ederveen (2006).

    Our nding of a large role for the additional parent country tax in

    foreign subsidiary location is new, and perhaps surprising, as many

    countries in the world allow parent country taxes on foreign source

    income to be deferred until dividend repatriation, diminishing its po-

    tential to affect location decisions. Similarly, some countries allow

    so-called worldwide income averaging. This practice allows multina-

    tionals resident in, for instance, the U.S. to claim foreign tax credits for

    foreign taxes paid in high-tax countries against U.S. taxes due on in-

    come from low-tax countries, potentially reducing the burden of par-

    ent country corporate income taxation.

    The result that foreign subsidiary location is sensitive to additional

    parent country taxationreects thatparent country taxationis rather dis-

    criminatory, as it only applies to parent  rms residing in the pertinent

    parent country.Additional parent country taxationthus discouragesmul-

    tinational rm ownership of foreign subsidiaries that are subject to addi-

    tional parent country taxation. The estimated negative impact of parent

    country location on subsidiary location implies that multinationals acton an apparently signicant incentive to bring about an international

    ownership pattern of subsidiaries that is internationally tax-ef cient.

    Substantial withholding taxes also put particular foreign owners at a

    comparative disadvantage at owning local assets vis-à-vis any other for-

    eign owners that are lowly taxed and local owners. All the same, wend

    that non‐resident dividend withholding taxes are statistically insigni-

    cant in determining subsidiary location decisions. To explain this,  rst

    note that the EU Parent-Subsidiary Directive provides that no withhold-

    ing tax shall be levied on dividend payments between related cross-

    border companies. This makes the application of a withholding tax rare

    in our dataset. Second, companies can potentially avoid withholding

    taxes by creating conduit companies or by letting the subsidiary compa-

    ny provide the parent company with a loan instead of a dividend.14

    Next, Table 6 reports several robustness checks to gain additionalinsight in the impact of the international tax system on foreign

    subsidiary location.15 First, we recognize that the calculation of our

    effective tax variable is based on countries’  top statutory tax rates,

    thus ignoring potential differences in tax base denitions regarding,

    for instance, interest deductibility that equally affect the tax burden

    in a particular country. As an alternative effective taxmeasure, regres-

    sion 1 of  Table 6 includes the Effective Average Tax Rate (EATR) for

    outbound FDI as computed by ZEW (2008) starting from regression

    2 of  Table 5. The EATR reects statutory information on tax rates, in-

    terest deductibility, as well as allowances for capital depreciation,

    and it is constructed as the overall tax liability triggered by a projectdivided by the overall returns generated by the project in the absence

    of taxation (see Devereux and Grif th, 1999, 2003). The EATR approx-

    imatesan average taxon FDI, unlikeour effective tax rate based on top

    statutorytax rates,and thus canbe expected to inuence international

    location decisions. In regression 1, the EATR variable obtains a nega-

    tive coef cient of −2.51 that is statistically insignicant. The marginal

    effect in the EATR regression is −0.60. The ZEW (2008) data do not

    provide a split up theEATR variable into host and parentcountry com-

    ponents and hence we cannot perform regressions using EATR-like tax

    variables analogous to regressions 3–6 of  Table 5.

    Next, we investigate whether the responsiveness of subsidiary lo-

    cation is different for subsidiaries with a low or high return on assets.

    Subsidiaries with a low return on assets presumably pay low taxes,

    suggesting that there is a reduced role of taxation to affect loca-

    tion choices. Alternatively, subsidiary location of foreign subsidiaries

    with a high return on assets could be rather insensitive to taxation,

    if the high return on assets reects the realization of rents that are lo-

    cation and owner specic. To investigate this, columns 2 and 3 of 

    Table 6 report regressions for the samples of subsidiaries with a rate

    of return on assets below and above the sample median. Otherwise,

    these two regressions are analogous to regression 6 of   Table 5. The

    host country tax variable and the additional parent country tax

    enter with negative and statistically signicant coef cients in both

    regressions 2 and 3. Interestingly, the estimated marginal effects of 

    the host and additional parent country taxes on the probability of lo-

    cation are both smaller in absolute terms for the high-ROA sample,

    which suggests that subsidiaries with a high rate of return experience

    rents that are location or owner specic.

    Next, we consider whether the responsiveness of location is differ-ent for subsidiaries with low and high  xed assets. Subsidiaries that

    use high   xed assets may be dif cult to relocate physically, and

    hence one expects their location to be less sensitive to the host coun-

    try tax. Regressions 4 and 5 are based on samples of subsidiaries with

    ratios of  xed assets to total assets below and above the median. In

    regressions 4 and 5, the host country tax and the additional parent

    country tax both enter with negative and statistically signicant coef-

    cients (albeit at different levels of signicance). The implied margin-

    al effects of both tax rates on the probability of location are relatively

    large in absolute terms for the sample of subsidiaries with low  xed

    assets. These results suggest that the location of subsidiaries with

    low xed assets is relatively more sensitive to host and parent coun-

    try taxation.16

    As discussed, the option to defer parent country taxes may makeforeign subsidiary location less responsive to the additional parent

    country tax. Previously, Huizinga and Voget (2009) have collected in-

    formation on whether the deferral option is available for parent rms

    located in a particular home country. We can use this information to

    check whether the deferral option indeed mutes the responsiveness

    of location to additional parent country taxation. To start, regression

    6 in   Table 6   introduces an interaction of the effective tax and a

    14 The conversion of dividend payments into a loan to the parent potentially also

    eliminates parent country taxation on repatriated income. Under US CFC rules, howev-

    er, such loans could be labelled   ‘deemed dividends’   and trigger parent country taxa-

    tion. In the EU, transactions of this kind may be subject to transfer pricing rules, but

    adjustments of the transfers to qualify as dividends and subsequent adjustments of 

    parent country taxation seem to be the exception rather than the rule.15 As additional robustness checks, we have performed regressions that inter alia (i)

    exclude holding companies, (ii) include intermediate companies that are both parent

    and subsidiary, and (iii) include tax variable interactions with a dummy variable sig-

    naling a previously established subsidiary in the country. Our main results on the im-

    pact of the international taxsystem on foreign subsidiary location are unaltered in each

    of these regressions (unreported).

    16 We tested for the equality of coef cients on the tax variable across the two regres-

    sions that result from dividing the sample into low ROA/high ROA and low xed assets/

    high  xed assets subsamples as reported in Table 6 using a Wald test. The results indi-

    cate that only the withholding tax variable obtains signicantly different coef cients in

    each of the two pairs of regressions. In all four regressions, the withholding tax variable

    tax variable, however, obtains a coef cient that itself is insignicant.

    954   S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    10/13

    deferral option dummy in regression 2 of   Table 5. The effective tax

    variable now obtains a coef cient of −9.17 that is signicant at 1%

    and lower than the corresponding coef cient of −

    4.29 in regression

    2 of  Table 5. The interaction of the effective tax with the deferral op-

    tion dummy obtains a positive coef cient of 4.85 that is signicant at

    1%. The corresponding marginal effects on the probability of location

     Table 4

    Descriptive statistics for subsidiaries of European multinationals.

    Panel A. Number of parent companies and subsidiaries used in basic regression

    Country Number of parent companies by home country Number of subsidiaries

    By home country By host country

    Austria 9 9 6

    Belgium 29 36 34

    Bulgaria 9 11 2

    Croatia 0 0 1Cyprus 0 0 0

    Czech Republic 0 0 5

    Denmark 26 28 110

    Estonia 5 6 1

    Finland 19 23 30

    France 84 116 36

    Germany 56 75 97

    Greece 33 48 4

    Hungary 0 0 6

    Iceland 2 3 4

    Ireland 9 11 39

    Italy 64 78 38

    Latvia 1 2 2

    Lithuania 0 0 0

    Luxembourg 1 1 2

    Netherlands 64 89 51

    Norway 33 45 74Poland 5 6 39

    Portugal 19 21 11

    Romania 0 0 9

    Russia 1 1 0

    Slovak Republic 1 1 0

    Slovenia 6 6 0

    Spain 49 59 88

    Sweden 69 76 68

    Switzerland 13 14 6

    Turkey 0 0 0

    United Kingdom 115 144 146

    Total 722 909 909

    Panel B. Summary statistics for variables in basic regression

    Variable   n   Mean Standard dev. Min Max

    Subsidiary location 26,648 0.034 0.181 0 1

    Effective tax 26,648 0.353 0.073 0.125 0.750International tax 26,648 0.051 0.070 0 0.550

    Host country tax 26,648 0.302 0.083 0 0.567

    GDP bilateral 26,648 0.033 0.054 0.0003 0.264

    Contiguity 26,648 0.166 0.371 0 1

    Difference in labor costs 26,648 0.270 0.563   −2.098 2.373

    Economic freedom 26,648 6.430 1.021 3.800 8.425

    EU membership 26,648 0.464 0.499 0 1

    Panel C. Correlation matrix for variables in basic regression

    Subsidiary

    location

    Effective

    tax

    International

    tax

    Host

    country tax

    GDP

    bilateral

    Contiguity Difference in

    labor costs

    Economic

    freedom

    EU

    membership

    Sub sidiar y loca tion 1 .0 00 0

    Effective tax   −0.0059 1.0000

    International tax   −0.0798** 0.3369** 1.0000

    Host country tax 0.0628** 0.5976**   −0.5536** 1.0000

    GDP bilateral 0.1669** 0.2662**  −

    0.2907** 0.4830** 1.0000Contiguity 0.0733** 0.0794**   −0.1098** 0.1638** 0.2324** 1.0000

    Difference in labor costs   −0.0923* 0.0397* 0.1522*   −0.0945*   −0.2416   −0.1455 1.0000

    Economic f reedom 0 .1 03 0**   −0.1442**   −0.1667** 0.0144** 0.1943** 0.0794**   −0.6670* 1.0000

    EU membership 0.1402** 0.0622**   −0.4990** 0.4800** 0.4975** 0.2092**   −0. 4547**   −0.4891* 1.0000

    Notes: Subsidiary location is a dummy variable equaling 1 if a subsidiary is located in a country and 0 otherwise. Effective tax is the tax rate on dividend income generated in the potential

    subsidiary country resulting from corporate income taxation in host and parent countries and non-resident withholding taxation in the host country. International tax is the difference be-

    tweenthe effectivetax andthe host country corporatetax.Host country taxis thecorporate incometax in thesubsidiary country, includinglocaltaxes andpossiblesurcharges.GDP bilateral

    is the ratio of the GDP in a potential host country to the sum of GDP of all potential host countries. Contiguity is a binary variable equal to 1 if the parent and potential host countries have a

    commonborder. Difference in labor costs is thelog of theratioof labor costs in thehome country andlaborcosts in thepotential host country. Economic freedom is an index scaledbetween

    0and10reectingthe followingFraser indicators of thepotential host country: soundnessof legalsystem, absence of trade barriers,and absence of price controls.EU membership is a binary

    variable equal to 1 if the potential host country is a member of the European Union. Basic regression refers to regression 2 in  Table 5. * denotes signicance at 5%; ** signicance at 1%.

    955S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    11/13

    are −1.63 and 0.86.These resultssuggestthat the deferral option re-

    duces the responsiveness of location to the effective country tax by

    about half.

    In analogous fashion, regression 7 of  Table 6 includes an interac-

    tion of the international tax variable with the deferral option

    dummy in regression 5 of   Table 5. The international tax variable

    and its interaction with the deferral option dummy enter with neg-ative and positive coef cients, respectively, that are signicant at

    1% and 5% respectively. The implied marginal effects of the two var-

    iables on the probability of location are −3.10 and 2.48, which sug-

    gests that the deferral option reduces the responsiveness of location

    to the international tax variable by 80%. Finally, regression 8 of 

    Table 6   includes an interaction of the additional parent country

    tax with the deferral option dummy in regression 6 of   Table 5.

    The additional parent country tax obtains a negative coef cient

    that is signicant at 5%, while its interaction with the deferral op-

    tion dummy obtains a positive coef cient that is statistically insig-

    nicant. Estimated marginal effects of the two variables on the

    probability of location suggest that the deferral option reduces the

    responsiveness of location to the additional parent country tax by

    about 72%.

    Overall, the robustness checks conrm that international double

    taxation, as reected in our international tax and additional parent

    country tax variables, is important in explaining location decisions re-

    garding new foreign subsidiaries. More specically, our results sug-

    gest that foreign subsidiary location is relatively sensitive to

    international double taxation for subsidiaries with a low return on as-

    sets, low  xed assets and in the absence of the deferral option.

    5. Conclusions

    This paper provides evidence on the implications of international

    taxation for the location of the foreign subsidiaries of multinational

    rms. Our analysis uses panel data on the structure of multinational

    rms in 33 European countries over the period 1999–2003. This rich

    data set allows us to estimate the separate effects of host country

    corporate income taxation, host country non-resident dividend with-

    holding taxation, and additional parent country corporate income

    taxation on the location decisions of multinational  rms.

    Our main result is that the additional parent country corporate

    taxation of foreign source income has an independent, strongly nega-

    tive effect on the probability of foreign subsidiary location in potential

     Table 5

    Taxation and foreign subsidiary location. The dependent variable is subsidiary location equaling 1 if a subsidiary is located in a country and 0 otherwise. Effective tax is the tax rate

    on dividend income generated in the potential subsidiary country resulting from corporate income taxation in host and parent countries and non-resident withholding taxation in

    the host country. Host country corporate tax is the corporate income tax in the subsidiary country, including local taxes and possible surcharges. International tax is the difference

    between the effective tax and the host country corporate tax. Withholding tax is the non-resident withholding tax burden imposed by the host country. Additional parent country

    corporate tax is the additional corporate tax burden imposed by parent country after double tax relief. GDP bilateral is the ratio of the GDP in a potential host country to the sum of 

    GDP of all potential host countries. Contiguity is a binary variable equal to 1 if the parent and potential host countries have a common border. Difference in labor costs is the log of 

    the ratio of labor costs in the home country and labor costs in the potential host country. Economic freedom is an index scaled between 0 and 10 reecting the following Fraser

    indicators of the potential host country: soundness of legal system, absence of trade barriers, absence of price controls, and transfers and subsidies as a share of GDP. EU member-

    ship is a binary variable equal to 1 if the potential host country is a member of the European Union. All regressions include year  xed effects that are not reported. Sample reects

    location decisions of new foreign subsidiaries. Estimation is by conditional logit model. Standard errors that are heteroskedasticity-consistent and adjusted for clustering at the levelof the host country are reported between brackets. Marginal effect is the slope of the probability curve with respect to an included tax variable evaluated at zero while other ex-

    planatory variables are evaluated at their mean. * denotes signicance at 10%; ** signicance at 5% and *** signicance at 1%.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Variables (expected sign) Tax

    only

    Basic

    regression

    Host country

    corporate tax

    International

    taxation

    Host country corporate and

    international taxes

    Withholding and parent

    country corporate tax

    Effective tax (−)   −0.871   −4.292***

    ( 0.57 4) ( 0.63 4)

    Host country corporate tax (−)   −3.424***   −4.376***   −4.806***

    (0.500) (0.624) (0.654)

    International tax (−)   −1.869**   −3.927***

    (0.938) (1.042)

    Withholding tax (−)   −0.322

    (1.400)

    Additional parent country corporate

    tax (−)

    −5.731***

    (1.400)

    GDP bilateral (+) 7.420*** 7.196*** 5.404*** 7.470*** 7.620***(0.575) (0.548) (0.475) (0.566) (0.571)

    Contiguity (+) 0.396*** 0.372*** 0.372*** 0.395*** 0.402***

    (0.084) (0.085) (0.086) (0.084) (0.084)

    Differences in labor costs (+/−)   −0.692***   −0.768***   −0.573***   −0.705***   −0.737***

    (0.179) (0.190) (0.174) (0.186) (0.181)

    Economic freedom (+) 0.140* 0.139* 0.291*** 0.134* 0.133*

    (0.073) (0.073) (0.067) (0.074) (0.074)

    EU membership (+) 0.952*** 1.192*** 0.814*** 0.981*** 1.107***

    (0.105) (0.119) (0.117) (0.123) (0.129)

    Observations 26,648 26,648 26,648 26,648 26,648 26,648

    Pseudo R-squared 0.001 0.135 0.133 0.127 0.136 0.137

    Marginal effects of tax variables

    Effective tax   −0.218   −0.784

    Host country corporate tax   −0.632   −0.816   −0.895

    International tax   −0.189   −0.732

    Withholding tax  −

    0.060Additional parent country

    corporate tax

    −1.070

    956   S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    12/13

    host countries, despite the fact that parent country taxation can gen-

    erally be deferred until income is repatriated. This result may reect

    that a parent country's taxation is rather discriminatory as it only ap-

    plies to parent rms residing in the parent country. The high sensitiv-

    ity of foreign subsidiary location to parent country taxation suggests

    that this tax is particularly distortive. Paradoxically, the parent coun-

    try tax may be highly distortive on account of the foreign credit

    mechanism   –   aiming to alleviate international double taxation   –  as

    the foreign tax credit mechanism produces a high variability of the

    (post credit) parent country tax across foreign location choices. The

    sensitivity of foreign subsidiary location to parent country taxation

    strengthens the case for abolishing worldwide taxation in favor of 

    territorial taxation.

    Additional parent country taxation may not only distort the for-

    eign subsidiary location decision, but also the capital investment de-

    cision once location is determined. The impact of parent country

    taxation on capital investment abroad would be an interesting area

    for future research.

     Table 6

    Taxation and foreign subsidiary location: robustness tests. The dependent variable is subsidiary location equaling 1 if a subsidiary is located in a country and 0 otherwise. Effective

    tax is the tax rate on dividend income generated in the potential subsidiary country resulting from corporate income taxation in host and parent countries and non-resident with-

    holding taxation in the host country. Host country corporate tax is the corporate income tax in the subsidiary country, including local taxes and possible surcharges. International

    tax is the difference between the effective tax and the host country corporate tax. Withholding tax is the non-resident withholding tax burden imposed by the host country. Ad-

    ditional parent country corporate tax is the additional corporate tax burden imposed by parent country after double tax relief. GDP bilateral is the ratio of the GDP in a potential host

    country to the sum of GDP of all potential host countries. Contiguity is a binary variable equal to 1 if the parent and potential host countries have a common border. Difference in

    labor costs is the log of the ratio of labor costs in the home country and labor costs in the potential host country. Economic freedom is an index scaled between 0 and 10 re ecting

    the following Fraser indicators of the potential host country: soundness of legal system, absence of trade barriers, absence of price controls, and transfers and subsidies as a share of 

    GDP. EU membership is a binary variable equal to 1 if the potential host country is a member of the European Union. All regressions include year  xed effects that are not reported.

    The EATR is the cross-border Average Effective Corporate Tax Rate taken from  ZEW (2008). Deferral is a dummy variable equal to 1 if deferral is possible and zero otherwise. Re-gressions 2 and 3 split the sample into subsidiaries that have respectively a ratio of pre-tax prots to total assets below or equal to and above the median value. Regressions 4 and 5

    split the sample into subsidiaries that have respectively a ratio of  xed assets to total assets below or equal to and above the median value. Sample re ects location decisions of new

    foreign subsidiaries. Standard errors thatare heteroskedasticity-consistent and adjusted for clustering at the level of the host country are reported between brackets. Marginal effect

    is the slope of the probability curve with respect to an included tax variable evaluated at zero while other explanatory variables are evaluated at their mean. * denotes signicance at

    10%; ** signicance at 5% and *** signicance at 1%.

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Variables (expected sign) EATR Low ROA High ROA Low  xed

    assets

    High  xed

    assets

    Deferral Deferral

    two-way

    split

    Deferral

    three-way

    split

    EATR    −2.513

    (1.883)

    Effective tax (−)   −9.166***

    (1.798)

    Host country corporate

    tax (−)

    −4.367***   −5.238***   −5.911***   −3.930***   −4.504***   −4.882***

    (0.806) (0.912) (0.955) (0.869) (0.622) (0.652)

    International tax (−

    )  −

    16.61***(5.620)

    Withholding tax (−) 0.383   −1.330 1.036   −1.114   −0.202

    (1.725) (2.068) (2.191) (1.627) (1.400)

    Additional parent country

    corporate tax (−)

    −5.951***

    (1.802)

    −5.594***

    (1.982)

    −6.803**

    (3.239)

    −5.277***

    (1.475)

    −17.850**

    (8.167)

    Deferral× Effective tax (+) 4.853***

    (1.711)

    Deferral×International

    tax (+)

    13.26**

    (5.580)

    Deferral×Additional parent

    country tax (+)

    12.86

    (8.180)

    GDP bilateral (+) 4.765*** 7.066*** 8.094*** 9.367*** 5.980*** 7.365*** 7.478*** 7.616***

    (0.810) (0.779) (0.772) (0.811) (0.771) (0.574) (0.561) (0.568)

    Contiguity (+) 0.664*** 0.448*** 0.347*** 0.408*** 0.396*** 0.412*** 0.411*** 0.416***

    (0.109) (0.114) (0.119) (0.122) (0.113) (0.084) (0.084) (0.084)

    Labor cost (+/−)   −0.197   −1.027***   −0.353   −1.081***   −0.575***   −0.682***   −0.713***   −0.731***

    (0.693) (0.199) (0.300) (0.330) (0.214) (0.178) (0.186) (0.180)Eco nomic free dom (+) 0.038   −0.041 0.351*** 0.048 0.183* 0.149** 0.133* 0.133*

    (0.280) (0.080) (0.104) (0.113) (0.094) (0.072) (0.074) (0.073)

    EU membership (+) 1.446*** 0.902*** 1.407*** 1.552*** 0.849*** 0.897*** 0.977*** 1.112***

    (0.159) (0.168) (0.185) (0.213) (0.158) (0.107) (0.126) (0.131)

    Observations 12,175 14,176 12,384 11,658 14,990 26,648 26,648 26,648

    Pseudo R-squared 0.108 0.119 0.170 0.192 0.106 0.137 0.137 0.138

    Marginal effects of tax variables

    Effective tax   −0.603   −1.625

    Host country corporate tax   −1.093   −0.366   −1.342   −0.640   −0.841   −0.910

    International tax   −3.100

    Withholding tax 0.097   −0.094 0.237   −0.174   −0.037

    Additional parent country

    corporate tax

    −1.486   −0.391   −1.545   −0.854   −3.329

    Deferral×Included

    tax variable

    0.860 2.475 2.398

    957S. Barrios et al. / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 946 –958

  • 8/16/2019 Barrios Et Al. (2012) International Taxation and Multinational Firm Location Decisions

    13/13

     Appendix A 

    References

    Altshuler, R., Grubert, H., 2001. Where will they go if we go territorial? Dividend ex-emption and the location decisions of U.S. multinational corporations. NationalTax Journal 54, 787–809.

    Barrios, S., Görg, H., Strobl, E., 2005. Foreign direct investment, competition and indus-trial development in the host country. European Economic Review 49, 1761 –1784.

    Buettner, T., Ruf, M., 2007. Tax incentives and the location of FDI: evidence froma panelof German multinationals. International Tax and Public Finance 14, 151–164.

    Crozet, M., Mayer, T., Mucchielli, J.-L., 2004. How do  rms agglomerate? A study of FDIin France. Regional Science and Urban Economics 34, 27–54.

    De Mooij, R., Ederveen, S., 2006. What a difference does it make? Understanding theempirical literature on taxation and international capital  ows. Economic PapersNo. 261, European Commission. D-G for Economic and Financial Affairs, Brussels.

    Desai, M., Foley, C., Hines, J., 2001. Repatriation taxes and dividend distortions. NationalTax Journal 54, 829–851.

    Desai, M.A., Hines, J.R., 2002. Expectations and expatriations: tracing the causes andconsequences of corporate inversions. National Tax Journal 55, 409–440.

    Devereux, M.P., Grif th, R., 1998. Taxes and the location of production: evidence from apanel of US multinationals. Journal of Public Economics 68, 335–367.

    Devereux, M.P., Grif th, R., 1999. The taxation of discrete investment choices. WorkingPaper No. W98/16. Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.

    Devereux, M.P., Grif th, R., 2003. Evaluating tax policy for location decisions. Interna-tional Tax and Public Finance 10, 107–126.

    Devereux, M.P., Maf ni, G.,2007. The impact of taxation on the location of capital,rmsand prot: a survey of empirical evidence. Oxford University Centre for Business

    Taxation Working Paper 07/02.Dischinger, M., Riedel, N., 2011. Corporate taxes and the location of intangible assets

    within multinational  rms. Journal of Public Economics 95, 691–707.Egger, P., Loretz, S., Pfaffermayr, M., Winner, H., 2009. Bilateral effective tax rates and

    foreign direct investment. International Tax and Public Finance 16, 822 –849.Görg, H., Greenaway, D., 2004. Much ado about nothing? Do domestic  rms really ben-

    et from foreign direct investment? World Bank Research Observer 19, 171 –197.

    Hartman, D.G., 1985. Tax policy and foreign direct investment. Journal of Public Eco-nomics 26, 107–121.

    Head, K., Mayer, T., 2004. Market potential and the location of Japanese  rms in theEuropean Union. Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 959–972.

    Hines, J.R., 1996. Altered states: taxes and the location of foreign direct investment inAmerica. American Economic Review 86, 1076–1094.

    Huizinga, H., Voget, J., 2009. International taxation and the direction and volume of cross-border M&As. Journal of Finance 64, 1217–1249.

    Huizinga, H., Laeven, L., Nicodème, G., 2008. Capital structure and international debtshifting. Journal of Financial Economi


Recommended