+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

Date post: 03-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: marechal
View: 222 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 30

Transcript
  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    1/30

    Abstract

    The necessity to express the relative price of a commodity in terms of an-

    other commodity makes it impossible to distinguish, within a variation of

    its relative price, that part of the change that can be ascribed to the char-

    acteristics of the commodity itself from that part that is to be ascribed to

    the characteristics of the commodity of reference, i.e. the numeraire. Ricar-

    do (1817) pointed out this problem and the necessity to find an invariablemeasure of value, but he was not able to solve this problem. Sraffa (1960)

    suggested to use a composite commodity (that is, a bundle of commodi-

    ties) to accomplish this function. Within his framework of production of

    commodities by means of commodities he built the Standard commodity,

    which is a composite commodity which he claims to be a standard of value

    invariant with respect to changes in the distribution of income. But in Sraf-

    fas book there is no explicit proof of this claim. This gave rise to a lot of

    misunderstandings about the standard commodity and its role as invariable

    measure of value. In several contributions Sraffas solution to the Ricardos

    problem was questioned. In this work I shall try first to clarify what itmeans, for a numeraire, to be an invariable measure of value. Then I shall

    show that Sraffas standard commodity does satisfy this condition. On this

    basis I will re-examine the function of the standard commodity within the

    analysis of income distribution. A survey of the literature on the problem

    is presented at the end of the paper.

    KEYWORDS: standard commodity, invariable measure of value, price the-

    ory, Sraffa price system, value theory, distribution theory.

    J.E.L. CLASSIFICATION: B12, D33, D46, E11 .

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    2/30

    On Sraffas Standard Commodity as Invariable

    Measure of Value

    Enrico Bellino1

    Universita Cattolica del Sacro Cuore (Milano)

    C.O.R.E. (Louvain-la-Neuve)

    English not accurately checked

    1I would like to thank professor Luigi Pasinetti for his stimulus to go deep into

    some issues concerning the standard commodity and for his detailed comments on

    previous versions of this work. I would like to thank also Christian Bidard, Flavia

    Cortelezzi, Pierangelo Garegnani, Marco Piccioni, Fabio Ravagnani, Angelo Reati,

    Neri Salvadori, Ernesto Savaglio, Ian Steedman, Paolo Varri and the participants to

    a seminar in Catholic University for useful discussions on this topic. Usual caveats

    apply.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    3/30

    2 [Introduction

    1 Introduction

    The problem to isolate within a variation of the relative price of a commodity

    that part of it that can be ascribed to the price of commodity itself from

    that part that is to be ascribed to the commodity used as numeraire was

    emphasized at least two centuries ago by Ricardo. It is useful to start by

    quoting those passages where Ricardo states the main points of the problem.

    Two commodities vary in relative value, and we wish to know in

    which the variation has really taken place. If we compare the present

    value of one, with shoes, stockings, hats, iron, sugar, and all other com-

    modities, we find that it will exchange for precisely the same quantity

    of all these things as before. If we compare the other with the same

    commodities, we find it has varied with respect to them all: we may

    then with great probability infer that the variation has been in this

    commodity, and not in the commodities with which we have compared

    it. If on examining still more particularly into all the circumstances

    connected with the production of these various commodities, we find

    that precisely the same quantity of labour and capital are necessary

    to the production of the shoes, stockings, hats, iron, sugar, &c.; but

    that the same quantity as before is not necessary to produce the single

    commodity whose relative value is altered, probability is changed into

    certainty, and we are sure that the variation is in the single commod-

    ity: we then discover also the cause of its variation. Ricardo (1817,pp. 1718)

    When commodities varied in relative value, it would be desirable

    to have the means of ascertaining which of them fell and which rose in

    real value, and this could be effected only by comparing them one after

    another with some invariable standard measure of value, which should

    itself be subject to none of the fluctuations to which other commodi-

    ties are exposed. Of such a measure it is impossible to be possessed,

    because there is no commodity which is not itself exposed to the same

    variations as the things, the value of which is to be ascertained; that

    is, there is none which is not subject to require more or less labour forits production. Ricardo (1817, pp. 4344)

    But along with technological change (the change in the quantity of labour

    necessary to produce a commodity) Ricardo considers another source of

    variation of relative prices: the change in income distribution.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    4/30

    Introduction] 3

    But if this cause of variation in the value of a medium could be

    removedif it were possible that in the production of our money forinstance, the same quantity of labour should at all time be required,

    still it would not be a perfect standard or invariable measure of value,

    because, as I have already endeavoured to explain, it would be sub-

    ject to relative variations from a rise or fall of wages, on account of

    the different proportions of fixed capital which might be necessary to

    produce it, and to produce those other commodities whose alteration

    of value we wished to ascertain. Ricardo (1817, p. 44)

    Thus Ricardo was looking for a standard of value that were invariant to

    technical change as well as with respect to changes in the distribution of

    income.1 And he concludes:

    If, then, I may suppose myself to be possessed of a standard so

    nearly approaching to an invariable one, the advantage is, that I shall

    be enabled to speak of the variations of other things, without embar-

    rassing myself on every occasion with the consideration of the possible

    alteration in the value of the medium in which price and value are

    estimated. Ricardo (1817, p. 46)

    Nobody has been able to solve Ricardos problem in its entirety. Sraf-

    fa (1960) offered a partial solution to this problem by building, within his

    framework of production of commodities by means of commodities, a nu-

    meraire, called Standard commodity, that he claims to be an invariable

    measure of value with respect to exogenous changes in the distribution of

    income.2 But the notion of standard commodity and its r ole within the

    Sraffas framework has always been one of the most discussed and often

    misunderstood in Sraffian and in anti-Sraffian literature. Actually Sraffa

    explains very clearly the Ricardos problem. He writes:

    The necessity of having to express the price of one commodity in

    terms of another which is arbitrarily chosen as standard, complicates

    1An attempt of reconstruction of the Ricardos search for an invariable measure of

    value has been done by Kurz and Salvadori (1993). In that paper they also refer toan invariance property with respect to interspacial comparisons that the standard that

    Ricardo was looking for should have had to exhibit (see Kurz and Salvadori (1993, pp. 96

    98)).2The solution of the other side of the problem that is, a unit of value invariant with

    respect to technical change has been performed by Pasinetti (see (1981, 1993)); he called

    such a unit dynamic standard commodity.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    5/30

    4 [Introduction

    the study of the price-movements which accompany a change in dis-

    tribution. It is impossible to tell of any particular price-fluctuationwhether it arises from the peculiarities of the commodity which is be-

    ing measured or from those of the measuring standard. The relevant

    peculiarities, as we have just seen, can only consist in the inequality

    in the proportions of labour to means of production in the successive

    layers into which a commodity and the aggregate of its means of pro-

    duction can be analyzed; for it is such an inequality that makes it

    necessary for the commodity to change in value relative to its means

    of production as the wage changes. Sraffa (1960, p. 18)

    But, at the same time, Sraffa is not equally clear in showing why his stan-

    dard commodity solves the requirement of invariance with respect to changein income distribution. He gives some intuitive hints in 21 before building

    the standard commodity; later he concentrates on the building of the stan-

    dard commodity ( 2328 and 3335), on the properties of the standard

    system (chap. V) and on the fact that if in a single production model this

    commodity is used as numeraire then the relationship between the wage rate

    and the profit rate becomes independent on prices ( 2932). But after the

    building of the standard commodity there is no explicit discussion about

    if and why the standard commodity is a measure of value invariant with

    respect to changes in income distribution. And all those scholars that dealt

    with and discussed the Sraffas standard commodity offered very few hintsto understand this point. 3 Only Baldone (1980, pp. 274277) and Kurz

    and Salvadori (1993, pp. 121-122, n. 16) sketch two proofs of the invariance

    of the standard commodity with respect to changes in the distribution of

    income.

    In this work I present a proof of this result in a way that seems more

    suitable to understand the whole topic from the economic point of view and

    that is easier to be connected with the economic intuitions suggested by

    Sraffa in his 21.

    The paper is organized as follows: in section 2 the essentials of the

    Sraffas single product price framework will be recalled; in section 3 thecapability of the standard commodity to be an invariable measure of value

    with respect to changes in income distribution will be dealt and in section

    4 some observations concerning the analysis of distribution will be drawn in3A quick survey of the literature on the standard commodity can be found, later, in

    Section 6.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    6/30

    Basic framework] 5

    light of the properties of invariance of the standard commodity. In section 5

    we will see some generalizations and extensions of the obtained results and in

    section 6 we will present a synthetic survey of the existing literature on the

    standard commodity, emphasizing the most common objections, criticisms

    and misunderstanding about this notion.

    2 Review of the basic framework

    The reference framework is the single product Sraffas price system with

    circulating capital:

    pT = (1 + )pTA + waT0 (1a)

    pTb = 1, (1b)

    where p is the (n, 1) vector of prices, A is the (n, n) non-negative input-

    output matrix, and w are two scalars indicating the rate of profit and

    the wage rate, respectively, a0 is the (n, 1) non-negative vector of labour

    input coefficients and b is an (n, 1) non-negative vector representing the

    commodity bundle used as numeraire. Symbol T denotes the transpose ofa vector. System (1a) is constituted by n equations in n + 2 unknowns,

    i.e. the n prices, the profit rate and the wage rate. System (1) determines

    relative prices once one of the two distributive variables is fixed from outside.

    Following Sraffa, we fix the profit rate exogenously with respect to the price

    system. By solving equation (1a) with respect to p we obtain:

    pT = waT0 [I (1 + )A]1; (2)

    thanks to Perron-Frobenius theorems on non-negative matrices the inversematrix in (2) exists and is non-negative for 0 < , where := 1/M1

    and M is the dominant eigenvalue ofA. In order to assure > 0 we assume

    M < 1, that is, that technique A is viable.

    By substituting vector p given by (2) in equation (1b) we obtain the

    expression of the relationship between the profit rate and the wage rate,

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    7/30

    6 [Basic framework

    this latter being expressed in terms of numeraire b:4

    w(b)() :=1

    aT0 [I (1 + )A]1b

    . (3)

    Again, thanks to Perron-Frobenius theorems, the elements of the inverse at

    the denominator are non-decreasing functions of for 0 < ; hence the

    wage rate is a non-increasing function of the rate of profit. (If matrix A is

    indecomposable the wage rate comes to be a strictly decreasing function of

    the rate of profit.)

    Re-substituting this expression into equation (2) we obtain the expres-

    sion of the vector of prices as a function of the profit rate only:

    pT(b)() =1

    aT0 [I (1 + )A]1b

    aT0 [I (1 + )A]1. (4)

    As [I (1 + )A]1 is non-negative the solutions with respect to the

    wage rate (3) and the price vector (4) are non-negative for any within the

    interval [0, ).5

    Turning to the quantity-side the standard system is an economic sys-

    tem in which the various commodities are represented among its aggregate

    means of production in the same proportions as they are among its prod-

    ucts. (Sraffa 1960, p. 19; emphasis in the original). Let q the (n, 1) vector

    of the total quantities to be produced of the various commodities; in thestandard system q must satisfy the following conditions:

    q = (1 + R)Aq (5a)

    aT0 q = 1, (5b)

    where R is the uniform physical rate of surplus and the total quantity of

    labour employed has been normalized to unity. Let us indicate by q the non-

    negative vector that satisfies system (5); mathematically it is the right-hand4In what follows we will use te convention to indicate by index (b) the (composite)

    commodity, b, in terms of which the wage rate, w(b), and the vector of relative prices,

    p(b) = [p(b)i], i = 1, . . . , n, are expressed. In the case in which the commodity used asnumeraire is a single commodity, j, we will write w(j) and p(j) = [p(j)i], i = 1, . . . , n.

    Obviously we have pT(b)b = 1 or p(j)j = 1. (We will indicate explicitly the numeraire in

    terms of which the wage rate and prices are expressed every time there is the need to

    recall the attention on this point.)5For the details of this analytical formulation of the Sraffas price system see Pasinetti

    (1977, chap. 5) or Kurz and Salvadori (1994, chap. 4).

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    8/30

    Theory of value] 7

    eigenvector of matrix A correspondent to its dominant eigenvalue (A) =

    1/(1 + R) = 1/(1 + ). Vector q is called gross standard product. The net

    standard product is defined by:

    y := (I A)q =R

    1 + Rq;

    thus y is proportional to q, hence

    Ay

    =

    1

    1 + R y

    (6)

    holds; moreover as q satisfies equation (5b) we obtain:

    aT0 y =

    R

    1 + R. (7)

    The standard net product can be considered a composite commodity; it is

    what Sraffa calls the standard commodity.

    3 The standard commodity within the theory of

    value

    The key to an understanding of the sense in which the standard commodity

    is an invariable measure of value is an analysis of the reason why relative

    prices change when distribution is varied.6

    Consider singularly the price equations of the various commodities and

    6As recalled in the Introduction, the property of invariance of a commodity can be

    intended at least in two ways: with respect to technical changes and with respect to change

    in income distribution. For brevity here and in what follows the property of invariance is

    to be intended, unless differently specified, with respect to changes in income distribution.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    9/30

    8 [Theory of value

    express prices in term of whatever (composite) numeraire, b:7

    p(b)1 = (1 + )pT(b)a

    1 + w(b)a01...

    p(b)i = (1 + )pT(b)a

    i + w(b)a0i...

    p(b)n = (1 + )pT(b)a

    n + w(b)a0n

    (8a)

    pT(b)b = (1 + )pT(b)Ab + w(b)a

    T0 b = 1, (8b)

    where ai is the ith column of matrix A, representing the input coefficientsof the various commodity used in industry i and a0i is the i

    th element of

    vector a0, representing the input coefficient of labour used in industry i,

    i = 1, , n.

    Suppose now that a variation of the rate of profit, for example an in-

    crease, takes place. How should the other variables, i.e. the wage rate and

    relative prices vary? Obviously the whole reasoning is quite complex, as

    there is full interdependence among all variables. To throw light on the

    argument, Sraffa carries out a causal argument. We shall follow Sraffa in

    this attempt. Suppose for the moment that we keep all prices unchanged.

    Then a uniform reduction (whatever it may be) of the wage rate wouldnot be sufficient to restore the balance in all industries: in fact in those

    industries which employ a sufficiently high proportion of labour to means

    of production there would arise a surplus, while in those industries which

    employ a sufficiently low proportion of labour to means of production there

    would arise a deficit. If we want to eliminate the surpluses and the deficits

    caused by such a change in distribution it is necessary that the prices of the

    various commodities, p(b)i, i = 1, , n, vary.8 In general this possibility is

    7The case of a numeraire constituted by a single commodity, i, can be obtained as a

    particular case by setting b = ei, where ei is the ith elementary vector.

    8

    Sraffa crucial claim is that this necessity does not arise for that commodity if it exists which is produced by employing labour and the means of production in that critical

    proportion which marks the watershed between deficit and surplus industries. Sraffa

    (1960, p. 13). We will see later ( 6.1) that this does not mean that the price of such a

    commodity remains constant; it does vary, but the causes of such a change are to be

    ascribed to the necessity to restore the balance in other industries, not in the industry

    characterized by the critical proportion.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    10/30

    Theory of value] 9

    available for all commodities with the exception of the commodity used as

    numeraire, as its price, by definition, is equal to 1. Yet the overall decrease of

    the wage rate will not be sufficient in general to eliminate the surplus or the

    deficit originated in the (aggregate) industry that produces the numeraire,

    because of the differences in the proportions between labour and the means

    of production that characterize the various industries. On the other hand,

    by observing equation (8b), which fixes the price of numeraire at 1, we see

    that the prices of all commodities, p(b), appear in it as variables. So for the

    various levels of equation (8b) imposes a constraint on p(b).9 Hence when

    the rate of profit is varied, the price system, p(b), will have to vary also in

    order to restore the balance in the industry that produces the numeraire.

    Then when distribution changes, there are not one but two sorts of pres-

    sures on the price of each commodity; we shall call them own Industry

    effect and Numeraire effect:

    (I) own Industry effect: the variation of the price of a commodity arising

    from the necessity to restore the balance within the corresponding

    industry;

    (N) Numeraire effect: the variation of the price of all commodities arising

    from the necessity to restore the balance in the industry that produces

    the numeraire.

    This second sort of push, undergone by all prices, is at the root of the

    Ricardos problem, as it makes

    impossible to tell of any particular price-fluctuation whether it

    arises from the peculiarities of the commodity which is being

    measured or from those of the measuring standard. Sraffa (1960,

    p. 18)

    By contrast, we could define invariable measure of value a commodity

    that, if used as numeraire, renders effect (N) null, that is, a numeraire thatdoes not engender pressures on the prices of the various commodities in

    order to restore the balance in its own industry.

    9System (8) is, in fact, a fully interdependent system of n + 1 equations in n + 1

    unknowns, i.e., the n prices and the wage rate (the rate of profit is to be considered here

    as an exogenous parameter).

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    11/30

    10 [Theory of value

    At this point we have all elements to verify that Sraffas standard com-

    modity satisfies such requirement of invariance. Consider again the price

    equations of the various commodities and express all prices and the wage

    rate in terms of standard commodity, y:

    p(y)1 = (1 + )pT(y)a

    1 + w(y)a01...

    p(y)i = (1 + )pT(y)a

    i + w(y)a0i...

    p(y)n = (1 + )pT(y)an + w(y)a0n

    (9a)

    pT(y)y = (1 + )pT(y)Ay

    + w(y)aT0 y

    = 1. (9b)

    Let us focus the attention on the last equation of this system, (9b). By

    using equations (6) and (7) equation (9b) becomes:

    (1 + )1

    1 + RpT(y)y

    + w(y)R

    1 + R= 1.

    But as pT(y)y = 1 we have

    1 +

    1 + R + w(y)R

    1 + R = 1,

    i.e.

    w(y) = 1

    R. (9b)

    Hence system (9) reduces to:

    p(y)1 = (1 + )pT(y)a

    1 + w(y)a01...

    p(y

    )i= (1 + )pT

    (y

    )ai + w

    (y

    )a

    0i...

    p(y)n = (1 + )pT(y)a

    n + w(y)a0n

    (9a)

    w(y) = 1

    R. (9b)

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    12/30

    Analysis of distribution] 11

    In this case we see that the vector of prices has disappeared from the

    last equation of system (9). Equation (9b) has now become an equation in

    the variable w(y) only ( is here considered as an exogenous parameter). If

    w(y) decreases according to this rule the variations of the value of capital

    plus profit component and of the wage component entirely compensate each

    others within the industry of the numeraire, and thus the prices of all other

    commodities have notto vary in order to restore the balance in this industry

    the standard commodity industry. Hence the standard commodity, if used

    as numeraire, makes effect (N) null. It is precisely in this sense that it can

    be claimed that the standard commodity is an invariable measure of value.

    This property descends from the particular proportions between labour and

    the means of production that characterize its (aggregate) industry and that

    assure that each variation of the wage component is always exactly offset by

    an opposite variation of the value of capital plus profit component. In this

    situation the variation of each relative price pi arises only from the necessity

    to restore the balance in the respective industry i. Hence the standard

    commodity, when used as numeraire, permits to observe the variations of

    the relative price of each commodity in response to changes in the rate

    of profit in isolation (as in a vacuum, Sraffa (1960, p. 18), without the

    disturbances arising from the peculiarities [...] of the measuring standard

    (Sraffa 1960, p. 18).

    4 The standard commodity within the analysis of

    distribution

    It is worth to recall here briefly the role played by the standard commodity

    within the analysis of distribution. Relationship (3) between the profit rate

    and the wage rate can be written in an alternative form, more suitable to

    understand the underlying argument. Suppose to express all prices and the

    wage rate in term of commodity bundle b; substitute equation (1a) into

    (1b); by solving with respect to w we obtain:

    w(b)() =pT(b)b (1 + )p

    T(b)()Ab

    aT0 b=

    1 (1 + )pT(b)()Ab

    aT0 b. (10)

    As the wage rate and the profit rate are uniform across sectors we see that,

    once the numeraire has been chosen, the level of the wage rate in terms

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    13/30

    12 [Analysis of distribution

    of that numeraire can be calculated, for any given rate of profit, from

    the price equation of the industry that produces the numeraire, b, whose

    technical coefficients are given by vector Ab and by scalar aT0 b.10

    Relationships (10) or (11) show the strict interdependence between prices

    and distribution. They permit to single out the three phenomena that take

    place simultaneously when varies:

    (D) change in Distribution: the variation of the wage rate due to the a

    change in the distribution of income i.e. due to a different way of

    dividing of the pie of net income between workers and capitalists ;

    (C) change in the value of Capital: the variation of the (relative) value ofcapital required to produce the numeraire, pT(b)()Ab or p

    T(i)()a

    i,

    variation due to the change of the whole price system, p(b)() or

    p(i)(), in response to a change in distribution;

    (W) Wage-numeraire effect: as the wage rate is expressed in terms of the

    numeraire, b or i, part of the variation of w(b) or of w(i), in response

    to a change in , are caused by the peculiarities of the industry of the

    numeraire, i.e. by the necessity to restore the balance in this industry.

    Effects (C) and (W) overlap effect (D) which is the main goal of the

    analysis of distribution and make it unobservable in isolation. The use

    of the standard commodity as numeraire permits to isolate effect (D) from

    effects (C) and (W). In fact:

    effect (W) is eliminated because as we saw in section 3 the standard

    commodity is an invariable measure of value;

    10As a particular case if we want to express all prices and the wage rate in terms of

    commodity i we set b = ei. The corresponding wage rate-profit rate relationship reduces

    to

    w(i)() =p(i)i (1 + )p

    T(i)()a

    i

    a0i =

    1 (1 + )pT(i)()ai

    a0i . (11)

    Also in this case we see that the wage rate w(i) can be calculated, for any given rate of

    profit, from the price equation of the industry that produces the numeraire i. (The tech-

    nical coefficients involved in this relationship are ai and a0i but the production processes

    of all other basic commodities are however indirectly involved through the vector of prices

    at the numerator.)

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    14/30

    Analysis of distribution] 13

    effect (C) is eliminated as the vector of prices disappears from the

    relationship between the wage rate and the profit rate if we use the

    standard commodity as numeraire; in fact, if we set b = y in equation

    (1b), that is if we set pT(y)y = 1 we obtain

    w(y)() =pT(y)()y

    (1 + )pT(y)()Ay

    aT0 y

    = (12)

    =1 (1 + )/(1 + R)

    R/(1 + R), (13)

    that is,

    w(y)() = 1

    R, (14)

    which is the well-known Sraffas relationship.

    It is easy to see the economic reason why the vector of prices disappears

    from the wage-profit relationship. As said before the wage rate, for any

    given rate of profit, can be obtained from the price equation of the industry

    of the numeraire, that, in this case, is the standard commodity, y. y,

    by definition, has the property that the various single commodities that

    appear in it are represented in the same proportions in the set of capital

    goods necessary to produce it, Ay (from equation (6) we have that y =

    (1 + R)Ay); in other words, the standard commodity and the set of capital

    goods necessary to produce it are the same (composite) commodity. Hence

    the wage rate, expressed in terms of this commodity, can be calculated

    simply by a subtraction between quantities of the samecommodity, without

    the need to use the price vector to evaluate them.

    The economic interest of the result contained in equation (14) is the fact

    that the price system p cancels out and disappears from the relationship

    between the rate of profit and the wage rate. This finding gives a rigorous

    basis to the possibility of treating the problem of distribution of income in-

    dependently of the price system.11 12 It should be noted that prices do not

    11On this see Sraffa (1960, Appendix D), Broome (1977), Garegnani (1984) or Lippi

    (1998).12Analytically this independence of distributive relationships from the price system

    can also be seen by comparing our previous systems (8) and (9). System (8) is a fully

    interdependent system in p(b) and w(b), while system (9) is a causal system, in which,

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    15/30

    14 [Analysis of distribution

    disappear completely from the problem of distribution: in fact the indepen-

    dence of the wage-profit relationship from the price system is obtained if

    all prices and the wage rate are expressed in terms of standard commodity.

    But this latter does not constitute, in general, the bundle of commodities

    consumed by workers, bw; when workers spend their wages to buy bundle

    bw the number of such bundles they can buy turns out to depend on the

    price system, that is, the interdependence between prices and distribution

    reappears:

    w(bw) =w(y)

    pT(y)

    bw=

    1 /R

    pT(y)

    bw.

    But by re-writing the above expression in the form

    w(bw) =

    1

    R

    R

    (R )aT0 [I (1 + )A]1bw

    , (15)

    we could see that the use of the standard commodity has permitted to

    separate a physicalkernel of the distributive relationships (our previous effect

    (D)), described by the linear factor of (15), from the complications arising

    from the variation of the whole price system (our previous effects (C) and

    (W)), described by the non-linearfactor of (15).13 This separation permits

    to individuate in analogy to what happens into a one-commodity economy

    the physical aspect of the distribution problem for a multi-commodityeconomy, notwithstanding profits, wages and outputs must be expressed

    in value terms by using the price system. Ricardo caught this point very

    clearly, disproving thus the illusion, deriving by the definition of prices as

    sum of wages, profits (and rents), that the trade-off between the distributive

    variables can be accommodated by suitable variations of prices.14 (For

    further details on this aspect see Garegnani (1984, in particular sections

    IIIVII).) These conclusions reflect one reconstruction of Ricardos thought.

    An alternative line of interpretation is expressed in Porta (1982). I will not

    enter into these issues here.

    firstly, equation (9b) determines w(y), then, given w(y), equations (9a) determine p(y).The notion of causality here used is to be intended in the sense given by Luigi Pasinetti

    in Pasinetti (1965)13I owe this observation and the analytics to present it to Neri Salvadori.14Suitable variations of prices do not break down the trade-off between wages and

    profit as any increase of prices would affect at the same time both sides of price equations

    (1a), that is either the revenues or the costs of each industry.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    16/30

    Extensions and generalizations] 15

    5 Extensions and generalizations

    5.1 Plurality of standard commodities

    In the second part of the seventies there appear some independent contribu-

    tions in which it was proved that, in some cases, the standard commodity is

    not the only commodity that makes the relationship between the wage rate

    and the profit rate linear.15 It has been shown (see Miyao (1977), Abraham-

    Frois and Berrebi (1978), Bidard (1978)), that under certain circumstances

    there exist other composite commodities, that Miyao called generalized s-

    tandard commodity, that make the job. Consider the following matrix,

    called by Miyao labour profile matrix:

    K(n,n)

    =

    aT0aT0 A

    aT0 A2

    ...

    aT0 An1

    .

    Miyao (1977, Theorem 3, pp. 158159), proved that each composite com-

    modity defined by

    y = y + z o,

    where y is the Sraffas standard commodity, is a sufficient small scalar

    and z satisfies

    Kz = o, (16)

    is a generalized standard commodity. Let

    r(K) = H( n).

    If

    H < n. (17)

    we can find up to nH linearly independent vectors zh, h = 1, , nH,

    satisfying system (16). Thus by choosing sufficiently small we can build

    15On the faultiness of this way to characterize the standard commodity see our Section

    6.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    17/30

    16 [Extensions and generalizations

    up to n H generalized standard commodities,

    yh = y + zh o, h = 1, , n H.

    There are two extreme cases. i) H = n: in this case system (16) has only

    the trivial solution z = 0 and the Sraffas standard commodity is the unique

    standard commodity. ii) H = 1: in this case we have n 1 generalized

    standard commodities; this latter case corresponds to the assumption of

    uniform capital intensity among sectors, and in this case each commodity is

    a generalized standard commodity.

    The possibility of existence of a plurality of standard commodities is

    thus linked to the drop of rank of matrix K. This condition has no prac-

    tical interest from the economic point of view, as the elements of K are

    given by technology. Notwithstanding as this case has (someway inexplica-

    bly) attracted the attention of many economists we could ask whether the

    generalized standard commodities yh, when they exist, are or not invariable

    measure of value. The response is positive. In fact if we use a generalized

    standard commodity as numeraire we set:

    pTyh = 1 pTy + pTzh = 1, h = 1, . . . , n H.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    18/30

    Extensions and generalizations] 17

    As it is easy to prove that pTzh = 0 for h = 1, . . . , n H16 we have that

    pTyh = 1 pTy = 1,

    (1 + )pT(yh)A + w(yh)aT0 y

    = 1

    w =R

    Rh = 1, . . . , n H,

    that is, the price system disappears also from the equation that sets the price

    of this numeraire, yh, at 1. As before in this way the price equation of each

    generalized standard commodity does not impose any further constraint on

    the variations of the price system in response to changes in . Thus each

    generalized standard commodity yh

    is an invariable measure of value.As a by-product we can observe that there is no difference in expressing

    prices and the wage rate in terms of the Sraffas standard commodity y or16Miyao defines the generalized standard commodity as that composite commodity that

    makes the wage rate-profit rate relationship linear, that is, that composite commodity y

    that satisfies

    w

    pT(IA)y=

    1

    aT0 y

    1

    r

    R

    . (18)

    Miyao (1977, theorem 1, p. 154) proves that equation (18) is equivalent to

    aT0A

    ty = (1 + R)aT0A

    t+1y, t = 0, 1, 2, . . . , (19)

    hence yh = y + zh satisfies the following recurrence conditions on labour inputs:

    aT0A

    t(y + zh) = (1 + R)aT0At+1(y + zh), h = 1, . . . , n H, t = 0, 1, 2, . . . .

    Thus we have that

    aT0A

    tzh = (1 + R)aT0A

    t+1zh

    , h = 1, . . . , n H, t = 0, 1, 2, . . . . (20)

    Moreover as Kz = o we have

    aT0A

    tzh = 0, h = 1, . . . , n H, t = 0, 1, . . . , n 1. (21)

    Hence thanks to (20) and (21) we have

    aT0A

    tzh = 0, h = 1, . . . , n H, t = 0, 1, 2, . . . .

    Returning to pTzh we have:

    pTzh = waT0 [I (1 + )A]

    1zh =

    = w

    +t=0

    aT0A

    tzh = 0, h = 1, . . . , n H .

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    19/30

    18 [Extensions and generalizations

    in terms of the generalized standard commodity yh: in fact as pTyh = 1

    pTy = 1, the solutions with respect to prices and to the wage rate of the

    two systemspT = (1 + )pTA + aT0

    pTyh = 1and

    pT = (1 + )pTA + aT0

    pTy = 1

    coincide not only in relative terms but also in absolute value. From the

    economic point of view it could be objected that this equivalence is only

    formal as prices p(yh) are expressed in terms of commodity yh while prices

    p(y) are expressed in terms of commodity y. But as pTyh = pTy(= 1)

    each unit of yh

    can command one unit of y

    , hence the equivalence issubstantial.

    5.2 Joint production

    It is possible to extend our previous conclusions to those cases in which the

    introduction of joint production does not raise problems for the existence of

    an economic meaningful standard commodity.

    Consider a square system (i.e. in which there are as many processes as

    many commodities). The standard gross product of the system is defined

    by:

    Bq = (1 + R)Aq (22a)

    aT0 q = 1, (22b)

    where B is an (n, n) non-negative matrix of outputs of the various processes.

    Suppose that system (22) has a real non-negative solution with respect to

    q and to R. Let q be this non-negative vector. The standard commodity

    is defined, as usual, as the net product of the standard system:

    y := (B A)q = RAq. (23)

    Consider now the system of prices expressed in terms of the standard com-

    modity:

    pTB = waT0 + (1 + )pTA (24a)

    pTy = = 1. (24b)

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    20/30

    Literature] 19

    Equation (24b) entails

    pT(B A)q = RpTAq = 1 (25)

    By combining equations (24a) with equation (24b) we get:

    1 = pT(B A)q = waT0 q + pTAq.

    Thanks to (22b) and (25) the price vector p disappear from equation (24b)

    that set the price of numeraire equal to 1 and we yield:

    w(y) = 1

    R,

    that is,

    prices have not to vary in order to restore the balance in the industry

    that produces the numeraire; this entails that the composite commod-

    ity y is an invariable measure of value;

    prices disappear from the relationship between the wage rate and the

    profit rate: this permits to separate the analysis of distribution from

    the price system.

    6 A quick survey of the literature

    The literature that focused upon the standard commodity is enormous. Yet

    most part of it has not been very helpful in shedding light on this topic.

    In particular it is possible to single out some common misunderstandings

    arisen about the standard commodity. As in the previous sections it turns

    out to be useful to distinguish whether we are considering aspects involving

    the standard commodity within the theory of value or within the analysis

    of distribution.

    6.1 The standard commodity within the theory of value

    The standard commodity within the theory of value is used to isolate

    when chosen as numeraire the variations of the price of each commodity i

    originating exclusively from the peculiarities of industry i from those arising

    from the industry of the numeraire. As said in the Introduction, Sraffa does

    not provide a satisfactory proof of this property for the standard commodity.

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    21/30

    20 [Literature

    Almost all those authors that accepted the property of invariance of the

    standard commodity limited themselves to re-phrase and in some cases

    just to quote what Sraffa said in his 21, without any further clarifi-

    cation: see, for example, Napoleoni (1962, sect. 8 and 9), Newman (1962,

    sect. IV), Bharadwaj (1963, pp. 14511452), Levine (1974, pp. 875876),

    Bacha, Carneiro, and Taylor (1977, pp. 4448), Harcourt and Massaro (1964,

    sect. 1).

    Only Baldone (1980, pp. 274277), Mainwaring (1984, chap. 7), Kurz

    and Salvadori (1993, pp. 121-122, n. 16) and Abraham-Frois and Berrebi

    (1989) gave some hints or sketched out a proof of this invariance property,

    but they did not clarify the issue satisfactorily.17

    The rest of authors rejected the property of invariance of the standard

    commodity considering it as a non-sense (see, for example, Johnson (1962),

    Catz and di Ruzza (1978), Flaschel (1986), Woods (1987)).18

    It is worth to see in some details the two main objections raised against

    the invariance in value of the standard commodity, as they permit to bring

    to light some common misconceptions concerning the requirements that an

    invariable measure of value should have to satisfy.

    Objection 1 The standard commodity is not an invariable measure of value

    since its value obviously expressed in terms of another (composite)

    commodity, b, is not constant with respect to .

    In fact, if we calculate it we obtain:

    pT(b)()y = w(b)()a

    T0 [I (1 + )A]

    1y;

    17In particular the conclusions reached in Abraham-Frois and Berrebi (1989) are subject

    to all criticisms raised by Catz and di Ruzza (1990).18It is curious the attitude undertaken by Joan Robinson, that in her book review of

    Sraffas Production of Commodities considers the standard commodity as an ingenious

    and satisfying solution to the problem that flummoxed Ricardo Robinson (1961, p. 10);

    subsequently she softens her enthusiasm by saying that Sraffa takes great trouble to

    provide a foolproof numeraire in which prices can be expressed, but the Keynesian wageunit serves as well Robinson (1979, p. xx), till to conclude that The definition of the

    standard commodity takes up a great part of Sraffas argument but personally I have never

    found it worth the candle. [...] This is not the unit of value like a unit of length or of

    weight that Ricardo was looking for. Robinson (1985, p. 163). An attempt to reconstruct

    the Joan Robinsons position on the standard commodity has recently been presented by

    Gilibert (1996); see also Porta (1995).

  • 7/28/2019 Bellino, Enrico - On Sraffa's Standard Commodity as Invariable Measure of Value

    22/30

    Literature] 21

    by developing the inverse in a power series (we can do this for 0


Recommended