+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the...

Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the...

Date post: 06-Jun-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
20
Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATIO N Burning Issues i n the Tobacc o Settlement : An Economi c Perspectiv e BY JANE G . GRAVELLE, PH .D . SENIOR SPECIALIST IN ECONOMIC POLIC Y CONGRESSIONAL RESEARCH SERVICE JULY 1998 BACKGROUND PAPER 1N0 .25
Transcript
Page 1: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

Sinc e

TAX IFOUNDATION

Burning Issues inthe Tobacco

Settlement: AnEconomicPerspective

BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH .D.SENIOR SPECIALIST IN ECONOMIC POLIC Y

CONGRESSIONAL RESEARCH SERVICE JULY 1998

BACKGROUND PAPER 1N0.25

Page 2: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

About the Tax FoundationIn 1937, civic-minded businessmen envisioned an independent group of researchers who, b y

gathering data and publishing information on the public sector in an objective, unbiased fashion ,

could counsel government, industry and the citizenry on public finance .

Six decades later, in a radically different public arena, the 'lax Foundation continues to fulfil l

the mission set out by its founders .Through newspapers, radio, television, and mass distributio n

of its own publications, the Foundation supplies objective fiscal information and analysis t o

policymakers, business leaders, and the general public .

The Tax Foundation's research record has made it an oft-quoted source in Washington an d

state capitals, not as the voice of left or right, not as the voice of an industry or even of busines s

in general, but as an advocate of a principled approach to tax policy, based on years of profes-

sional research .

Today, farsighted individuals, businesses, and charitable foundations still understand the nee d

for sound information on fiscal policy . As a nonprofit, tax exempt 501(c)(3) organization, the Ta x

Foundation relies solely on their voluntary contributions for its support .

About the AuthorJane G . Gravelle, Ph .D., is a Senior Specialist in Economic Policy at the Congressional Re -

search Service (CRS), Library of Congress, where she has worked since 1989 . She has also served ,

on leave, at the Labor Department and the Treasury Department's Office of Tax Analysis and ha s

taught at Boston Ilniversity .At CRS, Dr . Gravelle specializes in taxation, particularly the effects o f

tax policies on economic growth and resource allocation . In addition, she currently sits on the

editorial board of the National lax Journal and the Board of Directors of the National Tax Associa -

tion . She received her Ph .D. from George Washington University .

Page 3: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

Sinc e193 7

TAXFOUNDATION

Burning Issues inthe Tobacco

Settlement: AnEconomicPerspective

BY JANE G. GRAVELLIE, PH .D.SENIOR SPECIALIST IN ECONOMIC POLICY

CONGRESSIONAL RESEARCH SERVICE ULY 199 8

BACKGROUND PAPER I N0.25

Page 4: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

The Tax Foundation will on occasion publish important and timely works by outsid eauthors to expand or accelerate their distribution. The Tax Foundation is pleased to be abl eto publish this important paper by Jane Gravelle of the Congressional Research Service relat -ing to the tobacco settlement . We believe it provides an excellent discussion of the eco-nomic issues pertaining to the tobacco settlement . This paper will appear, as well, in Sep-tember 1998 issue of the National Tax journal, published by the National Tax Associatio n(NTA). The views in this paper do not necessarily represent those of the Congressiona lResearch Service or the Library of Congress .

Price : $10 .00$5 .00 for contributors

Add $2 .00 for postage and handling

Tax Foundation1250 H Street, NW

Suite 750Washington, DC 20005

202-783-2760 Tel202-942-7675 Fax

www.taxfoundation [email protected]

Page 5: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

Table of Contents

Executive Summary 1

I. Introduction 3

II. The Product Liability Framework 4

Deterrence 4

Insurance 5

III. The Settlement as a Pigovian Tax 9

Efficiency 9

Distributional Effects 12

Design and Budgetary Issues 1 3

IV. Conclusion 14

References 15

Page 6: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

Executive SummaryThe tobacco settlement currently be-

ing considered by Congress arose from aprivate settlement reached by the tobacc oindustry, state attorneys general, and privat eattorneys in June 1997 .The June settlemen twould have imposed annual payments fo rthree purposes : to settle the state suits, t oprovide a fund to pay individual claims, an dto provide public anti-smoking programs .

Annual payments under the Jun esettlement would have averaged 62 centsper pack of cigarettes and amounted to $1 5billion at 1996 prices and volumes. Penal -ties capped at 8 cents per pack would havebeen imposed on tobacco manufacturers i fcertain reductions in teenage smoking di dnot occur. Also, the industry would havebeen subject to greater FDA regulation an dnew restrictions on advertising . In return ,class action suits, nicotine addiction suitsand punitive damages would have been pre-

cluded; individual lawsuits would have ha dan annual cap and been paid from a fund ;and state claims would have been settled .

A bill agreed to by the Senate Com-merce Committee would have impose deven larger payments, at least $1 .10 perpack depending on projected volume in2003, but the disposition of funds was no tdetermined . Penalties for failing to reduceunderage smoking were larger and not taxdeductible.The bill capped payments for in-dividual suits but did not provide immuni-ty from various types of lawsuits . Some fi-nancial analysts suggested that the total pay -ments would have eventually exceeded $ 2per pack .

Understanding the SettlementThe settlement debate has been con -

fused because of conflicting rationales . Oneapparent rationale is to settle the lawsuits ,

a justification possibly enhanced by the re-lease of industry documents that bear onboth the industry's knowledge of tobacco'saddictiveness and health costs, and on theindustry's attempts to market to underagesmokers .

Another objective, probably viewed as

more important by the public health com-munity is to reduce smoking, particularlyunderage smoking, which has increased in

recent years .

The Product Liability ModelLike a product liability settlement, the

tobacco settlement is an agreement be-tween plaintiffs (the state attorneys genera l

and some private attorneys) and defendant s(the five tobacco companies) . It could beviewed as a way to settle a product liabilityclaim through legislation in order to mini-mize court costs . However, assessing th etobacco settlement from an economic per-spective, the product liability model doe s

not stand up to scrutiny.The economic objectives of product li-

ability law are deterrence and risk spread-ing, and the settlement does not appear t omeet either one. Evaluating its ability to de -ter future misbehavior, the settlement fallsshort for three reasons : (1) the product wil l

not be changed because of the payments ;(2) health warnings are already prominentlydisplayed on the product and its advertis-ing, and these costs are already known tothe public ; and (3) the payments are not im -posed as a fixed cost for past misbehavio ror damages, but are imposed as taxes . Thislast point is economically significant be-cause legal settlements are normally im-posed on companies in lump-sum amount sthat fall principally on stockholders' prof -

its instead of being passed on in price .

Could the settlement spread risk effi-ciently? A central objective of the settlemen twas to reimburse the federal and state gov-ernments for the costs of smoking .The mostpopularly cited number for the health cos tof smoking is $50 billion for 1993, pub-lished by the Center for Disease Contro l(CDC,1994).The study indicates the sharespaid by various groups : 21 percent by smok-ers, 33 .4 percent by private insurance, 20 . 4percent by Medicare, 10 .2 percent by Med-

icaid, 9 .5 percent by other federal programs ,

3 .2 percent by other state programs, and 2 . 2percent by other. Since states pay a bit ove r40 percent of Medicaid, their $3 .6 billion

1

Page 7: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

share of the $50 billion gives them th eweakest claim on compensation .

A more complete accounting of thecosts of smoking increases the size of thecosts, but it also reallocates costs and im-plies net financial benefits for some parties .The major factor in this recalculation is th epremature deaths of smokers .

Of course, smokers' premature death sare a loss to society, but the resulting finan -cial transfer from smokers to governmentscannot be ignored when estimating com-pensatory damages for the settlement . Themedical costs of treating illnesses that smok-ers would suffer if they lived longer aresaved, and the smoker loses retirement ben -efits in the form of Social Security . And ofcourse, smokers pay cigarette taxes .

When all aspects of public finance areaccounted for, smokers (past and present)currently save the federal government al -most $35 billion per year and state govern -ments $2 .1 billion. Private third parties save

$5 .4 billion, largely because a $22 billionsaving in pensions offsets the net costssmokers impose on employer health plans .

Reducing Smoking with a SettlementThe second section of the paper con-

siders the economic justification of usin gthe settlement as a way to correct an eco-nomic distortion; that is, would a correc-tive tax be an efficient, equitable, and ad-ministratively feasible method to dete rpeople, especially youngsters, from startin gto smoke without considering the high cos tof living unhealthily and dying early ?

It is difficult to control for all factor s

that affect underage smoking, but recen t

studies raise some doubts about the respon -

siveness of teenage smokers to pricechanges. While teenagers have less mone yand therefore might be expected to be moreprice responsive, they may not smoke a soften as adult smokers. According to the

University of Michigan's Monitoring th eFuture Survey, while 36 .5 percent of highschool seniors smoked at least one cigarettein the past month, only 24 .6 percentsmoked at least one cigarette daily and only

14.3 percent smoked more than ten ciga-rettes daily . Moreover, the objectives (e .g .status) may be different and maintained bysmoking less .Teenagers, in fact, tend to buyhigher priced premium brands .

These results cast doubt on the effec-tiveness of price increases as a tool to pre -vent smoking initiation by teenagers . Theysuggest that alternative approaches such aseducation, restrictions on smoking in pub-lic places, or greater restrictions on sales t ominors might be more effective.

If the corrective tax were to b eadopted in spite of this discouraging evi-dence about teenagers, what would it sother effects be? It is well known that to-bacco taxes are among the most regressivetaxes, and the large taxes proposed, particu-larly in the Senate Commerce Committe eproposal, would impose taxes that are esti -mated at $1 .10 but may exceed $2 .00 perpack by 2003, accounting for additiona lpenalties and volume reductions .

Tobacco taxes are especially regressivebecause smokers tend to consume the sam eamounts regardless of income, and smok-ing is more prevalent at lower incomes . Ifprices have a small effect on the participa-tion rates for underage smokers, then im-posing such a sizable tax on the relativelylow-income adult smokers who compose 9 8percent of the market would seem undesir -able .

ConclusionThis economic analysis of the tobacco

settlement suggests that the public polic yissue has not been framed appropriately.Whether viewed as a kind of product liabil-

ity settlement or as a corrective tax to dis-courage smoking, the settlement's eco-nomic consequences clearly include a redis-tribution of income that will harm low-in-come people . Considering the evidenc ethat teenage smokers are relatively imper-vious to price increases, a highly regressive$15 or $20 billion tax is a serious drawbackto any prospective settlement .

2

Page 8: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

I. IntroductionThe tobacco settlement currently be-

ing considered by Congress arose from aprivate settlement reached by the tobacc oindustry, state attorneys general, and privat eattorneys in June 1997 . Following an initialsuit filed by Mississippi, most states havenow filed suits to recover Medicaid cost sfor smoking-related illnesses . Four stateshave reached settlements with the industry .In addition, both class action and individualsuits have been filed on behalf of smoker sand their families .'I'here are also suits tha thave been filed with respect to secondhandsmoke .

The June settlement imposes annua lpayments to settle the state suits and pro -vide a fund to pay individual suits, and pub-lic programs (smoking cessation programs ,antismoking advertising, and child healt hinsurance) . These payments average 6 2cents per pack of cigarettes, and amount t o$15 billion at 1996 prices and volumes .Ad-ditional penalties would be imposed if cer-tain reductions in teenage smoking do no toccur, although these payments are capped .These payments amount to a maximum ofH cents per pack. The industry would besubject to greater FDA regulation and wouldrestrict advertising. In return, class actionand nicotine addiction suits and punitiv edamages would be precluded, individua llawsuits would have an annual cap and bepaid from a fund, and state claims wouldbe settled . A third of the payments woul dbe devoted to each of three purposes : stateclaims, individual claims and spending pro-grams (to include $2 billion for children' shealth, $1 .5 billion for smoking cessationand $1 .5 billion for a variety of purposes ,such as anti-smoking advertising, research ,regulation, and compensating sportingevents) .

A bill agreed to by the Senate Com-merce Committee would impose evenlarger payments than originally envisione dby the June 1997 settlement (at least $1 .10per pack, depending on projected volumein 2003), but the disposition of funds ha syet to be determined . Penalties for failing

to reduce underage smoking are larger thanin the June settlement, and are not tax de-ductible . Some financial analysts have sug-gest that the total payments would be morethan $2 per pack .'This bill capped paymentsfor individual suits but did not provide im-munity from various types of lawsuits .

The settlement debate has been con -fused because of competing rationales . Anapparent rationale was to settle the lawsuits ,a justification that has been viewed by manyto be enhanced by documents release dwhich claim to show industry knowledgeof the health costs of smoking and th eaddictiveness of smoking, and industry at -tempts to market to underage smokers .An-other objective, probably viewed as moreimportant by the public health community,is to reduce smoking, particularly underag esmoking, which has increased in recen tyears . This latter objective has largely beenthe focus of administration support for to-bacco legislation, while congressional de -bate has gone forward within both frame -works .

These two competing rationales areinconsistent . Legal settlements are normallyimposed on companies in lump-sumamounts that relate to past behavior. Suchsettlements would not normally be passe don in price but would fall on stockholders 'profits, unless they are thought to raise fu-ture manufacturing costs through productmodification . Such settlements can drivefirms into bankruptcy, and temporarily re-strict supply and raise price, but that is no tnormally an efficient outcome . Discourag-ing smoking through financial payments ,however, requires price increases, which isnot necessarily the objective of a lawsuit .Which is the proper framework for assess-

ing the settlement, and how does one evalu-ate the desirability of the settlement give nthat framework?

The first section of this paper assessesthe tobacco settlement in the framework o fproduct liability, and whether, from an eco-nomic perspective, the product liability ar-gument stands up to scrutiny.The economicanalysis suggests that, in fact, it does not .

3

Page 9: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

The second section considers the settle-ment as a way to correct an economic dis-tortion, mainly that smokers are making sub -optimal decisions that would be appropri-ately corrected with a tax ; this section alsodiscusses the accompanying effects on theincome distribution, some design issues ,and the income tax offset that is importantfor federal budgeting.

H. The Product LiabilityFramework

There are aspects of the initial settle-ment that resemble a product liability settle -ment. The settlement is an agreement be-tween plaintiffs (the state attorneys generaland some private attorneys) and the defen-dants (the five tobacco companies), andcould, therefore, be viewed as a way tosettle a product liability claim through leg-islation, in order to minimize court costs .

The economic objectives of liabilityare deterrence and/or risk spreading. How-ever, a number of considerations suggestthat the settlement should not be evaluatedin a product liability framework .

DeterrenceThe most obvious objective of prod-

uct liability law is deterrence, that is, induc-ing firms to impose appropriate safety stan -dards and to communicate product hazard sto customers . It contributes to economic ef-ficiency by helping to insure that economicexchange takes place between an informedbuyer as well as an informed seller. Wherethe firm has been negligent in producin gthe product expected by consumers (forexample, when a meat producer provide s

a product that is handled under inappropri -ate conditions of sanitation and is tainted)or where a firm fails to inform of know nhazards (an automobile manufacturer pro-duces a car with a known safety defect) ,product liability awards give notice to firm sthat costs will be imposed . Product liabil-ity litigation may not, however, be the mos tefficient way to insure these objectives ; theymay, alternatively, be met by regulation .

There are three reasons that the deter-rence objective is unrelated to the tobacc osettlement : (1) the product will not be

changed because of the payments ; (2)

health warnings are already prominently dis -played on the product and its advertising ,and these costs are already known to th epublic ; and (3) the payments are not im-posed as a fixed cost for past misbehavio ror damages, but are imposed as taxes .

Me Product Will Not Be Altered by thePayments

While the FDA will be granted regula-tory authority to reduce the nicotine con -

tent of cigarettes, it is not at all clear tha tsuch a move would be carried out, or is ad -visable if it is . The payments themselves ,however, have no effect on alterations of th eproduct by the companies because such al-terations will not affect the payments ,which will be set at a fixed amount per pac kand likely passed on to consumers . Indeed ,it is possible that consumers might switchto cigarettes with higher nicotine conten tif the price per unit increases substantially.But fundamentally, the product itself willnot be altered . Moreover, it is not in the sal e

of cigarettes that the firms could be viewedas negligent ; cigarettes' harmful effects havelong been known, and they were and wil lcontinue to be licensed for sale by the gov -ernment .

Knowledge of the Harmful Effects i sAlready Widespread

A related purpose of a product liabil-ity suit would be to insure that companie sreveal knowledge of any harmful conse-quences of the product that the consumer

does not know, even if consumers wouldcontinue to purchase the product .The fac -tors that are most closely related to this ra -tionale are the documents released in cour tcases that indicate that tobacco companie sdid not advertise their research regardinghealth effects and addictiveness of smoking ,and that they studied the habits of under -age customers .

But, regardless of the behavior of th e

4

Page 10: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

companies, were customers unaware of th enature of the product they were consum-ing? It seems fairly clear that this is not th ecase . Rather, the product is clearly know nby smokers to cause health problems, a sindicated by any number of surveys . Warn-ings have been placed by federal legislatio non cigarettes and in advertisements fo rsome time . Moreover, there is evidence thatsmoking has long been perceived as harm-

ful (Viscusi, 1992) and that individuals, es-pecially youngsters, actually exaggerat ethese health costs . Criticisms of negativ ehealth effects of cigarettes can be traced totheir invention in the late nineteenth cen-tury.A related argument, that smoking is no tknown to be habit forming, is also belied

by survey evidence . Excepting the issue o f

underage smokers, who are not legally al-

lowed to purchase the product, there is n oreason to believe that smokers did not haveadequate information on the potential dan-gers of using tobacco products . And evenyoung people are aware that it is difficultto quit smoking (Viscusi, 1992) .

The settlement objective most relatedto this issue is the restrictions on advertis-ing that might reach underage consumers ,who might not be able to exercise rationalconsumption choices .A small portion of thepayments may be directed towards smok-

ing education programs that reach youn gpeople, but this is not the primary use o fthe payments .There are also look-back pen -alties that are imposed if underage smok-ing does not drop enough; however, this ap-proach is not efficiently addressed throug hproduct liability.The manufacturing compa-nies cannot police underage smoking . Sinceit is retailers who make the final sales, andstate and local governments who are re-sponsible for enforcing restrictions on thos esales, tobacco manufacturers do not havethe tools available to achieve these objects .Anti-smoking critics allege that the compa-nies are targeting underage smoking in thei radvertising . However, the evidence that ad-vertising has an aggregate effect on under -age smoking, as opposed to influencin gbrand preferences, is weak . Indeed, it is

possible that advertising restrictions coul dincrease smoking, if firms compete instea dwith price reductions and young smoker sare sensitive to price . Logical ways to in -crease compliance with underage sales arefines on the retailers, or on the underagecustomers themselves, but not fines on themanufacturers .

InsuranceInsurance objectives are less likely to

be reasonable justifications for product li-ability suits, but there are problems, in anycase, with settlement payments to insur erisk-spreading.There are two aspects of thi sproblem : spreading risk for smokers acros sthose who get sick and those who do not ,and holding collective social insuranc eharmless for the costs of smoking .

Risk Spreading Among Smokers

Smokers experience various types o frisk: higher lifetime health costs, mor eworker disability and lost days from work ,and premature suffering and death, Ther eare several reasons that the legislative planto settle individual product liability suit sdoes not necessarily contribute to efficien trisk spreading . These include the existenceof private and social collective insurance ,the uncertainty with respect to cause of ill-ness for individual smokers, the cost of liti -gation, the small size of the settlement pay-ments, and the intergenerational transfer.The settlement may, however, contribute toeconomic efficiency by preventing th ewidespread use of product liability suits a sinsurance, which are likely to be an ineffi-cient method of risk-spreading .

Most of these risks can be insuredagainst in private markets, and indeed, th erisks of health costs and disability are fre-quently insured through third-party mecha -nisms. Smokers frequently purchase life in -surance with premiums adjusted for smok -ing status . Moreover, the risks of healt hcosts and disability are frequently insuredthrough third-party mechanisms, and it i snot entirely clear that medical expendituresover the lifetime are increased by smoking .

Page 11: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

These observations are sufficient t o

suggest that the failure in private marke thealth insurance is not likely to be much

greater for smokers than for nonsmokers .

But the most serious problem with usin g

individual product liability suits is the diffi -

culty in proving cause . In an automobile

accident, a malpractice case, or an indus-

trial accident there is generally a clear event

to demonstrate causality. Even though sta-

tistical studies estimate that 85 percent of

lung cancers are caused by smoking, som e

lung cancers occur in nonsmokers . Smok-

ing is a weaker risk factor for heart disease ;

only 20 percent of coronary deaths are at-

tributable to smoking. And these two ill-

nesses account for only half of smoking-re-

lated deaths. There would probably be no

way to establish sufficient proof of cause

for a death in the case of most of these ill-

nesses . Moreover, if smokers change d

brands during their lifetimes, it would be

difficult to demonstrate which companiesare liable and to what degree .The unwield y

and costly process of establishing cause fo r

individual liability suits suggests that prod-

uct liability is not a very good mechanism

for spreading risk .

Finally, the settlement amounts are fa r

too small to cover the total cost ; they wil l

go randomly to certain individuals and in-

terfere, rather than advance, risk-spreading .

Third-Party Costs

Is a liability suit appropriate to prevent

costs from being levied on third parties

through collective insurance plans? Perhap s

the most important plaintiffs in the case arethe state governments : monetary settle-

ments to be paid to the states are for the

purpose of compensating state treasurie s

for the Medicaid costs they incur in treat-

ing smoking-related diseases .There are also

suits by private health insurers and discus -sion of compensating the federal govern-

ment for costs . First let us consider the costs

to the states .

The most popularly cited numbers fo r

the health costs of smoking are the esti-mates of $ 50 billion per year for 1993 pub -

lished by the Center for Disease Contro l

(CDC, 1994) .This amount measures the es-

timated additional medical cost attributable

to smoking-related diseases in 1993 dollars ,

based on estimates of smoking attributable

risk (what share of each disease is due t o

smoking) . The study also indicates the

shares paid by various groups : 21 percen t

by smokers, 33 .4 percent by private insur-

ance, 20.4 percent by Medicare, 10 .2 per-

cent by Medicaid, 9 .5 percent by other fed-

eral programs, 3 .2 percent by other state

programs, and 2 .2 percent by other . The

Medicaid share thus amounts to $5 billion .

States, however, pay only a bit over 4 0

percent of Medicaid; assuming that "other "

is allocated to the same third-party category

as private insurance, we can establish the

following approximate amounts of the $5 0

billion paid for by different entities in 1993 :

$18.1 billion by the federal government ,

$3 .6 billion by the states, $17 .8 billion by

private insurance and other, and $10 .5 bil -

lion by individual smokers . By these num-

bers, the states have the least claim on com -

pensation, although preliminary updates ap -

parently place Medicaid costs at a consid-

erably larger value . (A recent study by some

of the same co-authors [Miller, et al ., 1998 1

estimated a sum for Medicaid that was over

twice as large ; no reason was given for the

much larger estimate of these costs . )

This calculation is, in any case, an in -

complete accounting of the costs of smok-

ing; aside from the direct cost of produc-

ing the product, there are morbidity an d

mortality costs that cause more absenc e

from work, and premature death. Indeed ,

the same CDC report includes an estimat e

of costs associated with morbidity and pre -

mature mortality of $6 .9 billion and $40 . 3

billion, also in 1993 dollars .

A more complete accounting of the

costs of smoking not only increases the siz eof the costs, but also reallocates costs an d

implies net financial benefits for some par -

ties . For example, total medical expendi-

tures due to smoking are reduced by off-

setting reductions in costs because of pre -

mature death . A person who dies from a

6

Page 12: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

smoking-related disease causes an increase

in medical cost at that time, but medical

costs are decreased in the future because

that person does not suffer the illnesses oth -

erwise suffered during a longer life . Simi-

larly, the smoker loses retirement benefit s

in the form of Social Security, which is a fi -

nancial saving for the government (since th e

smokers are generally alive during the con -

tribution period) .

The fact of savings from governmen t

transfers due to premature death does no t

imply that there is a social gain from pre-

mature death; there is clearly a loss that ac-

crues to the smoker who is part of society .

But it does alter financial effects and the ap -

propriate estimate of compensatory dam -

ages. In addition to these health-related fi -

nancial costs and savings, there is a trans-

fer from smokers to governments because

of the cigarette taxes .

Estimates by Manning, et al . (1991 )

updated and categorized for 1993 by Viscus i

(1995), can be used to roughly calculate th e

effects on third parties (federal, state, and

private third parties such as insurance com -

panies) . These estimates provided a per -

pack cost for each effect The original study

included the categories of medical costs ,

sick days, group life insurance, nursin g

homes, retirement benefits, effects of fires ,

and loss of taxes and contributions to these

plans. Viscusi further divides the medical

costs into those incurred under by people

under 65 and over 65 . By allocating these

categories to the different parties, the gen-

eral magnitude of these costs is estimated

for each group . In the calculations, the fed -

eral and state payments and contributions

made through the governments' role as em -

ployers are treated as private .

External medical costs (those not pai d

for by smokers) for the over-65 group are

primarily a federal responsibility because o f

Medicare ; the federal government is esti-

mated to account for 83 percent, the state

2 percent, and private insurance 15 percent .

Under-65 medical care is more heavily fi-

nanced by private insurance companie s

who account for 51 percent, with 20 per -

cent allocated to the state and 29 percen t

to the federal government . Nursing home

care is 61 percent federal, 35 percent state ,

and 4 percent private ; pensions are 64 per-

cent federal, 35 percent private, and 1 per-

cent state; contributions to these private

and public plans are 56 percent federal, 1 0

percent state, and 34 percent private .These

shares were developed from a variety o f

sources on health expenditures, sources o f

pension income, and taxes.

Manning, et al . (1991) discounted pay -

ments, with those occurring later in life

being valued less ; the purpose of that study

was to determine what tax would reflect

external costs for a new smoker.These num-

bers would not provide a measure of the

current cost, although Viscusi (1995) re -

ports an allocation at a zero percent dis-

count rate, which would probably be close

to how one would measure these current

costs . Since smoking has declined since th e

inception of these programs, measurement

of the annual costs should use a growth rat e

in place of a discount rate . Using a zero dis-

count rate therefore produces a better mea-

sure of the costs to the third parties whe n

considering cost from a compensation view -

point rather than a price correction mea-

surement . With a zero discount rate, eac h

of the external parties actually benefits fro m

smoking .

The following calculations allocate th e

per-pack costs and then multiply by th e

number of packs consumed. The federal

government saves about $29 billion per year

in net health and retirement costs (account -

ing for effects on tax payments) .These in-

clude a saving in retirement (largely Social

Security benefits) of about $40 billion an d

in nursing home costs (largely Medicaid) o f

about $8 billion. Costs include about $7 bil -

lion for medical care under 65 and abou t

$2 billion for medical care over 65 ; the re-

maining $10 billion cost is the loss in con -

tributions to Social Security and general rev -

enues that fund Medicaid. (Note that medi -

cal costs already include offsetting savings

for premature death and thus are muc h

smaller in the aggregate than in some ear-

7

Page 13: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

her estimates :Rice, et al ., 1994]) . The fed-eral government also collects $5 .6 billion incigarette taxes .This calculation implies thatsmokers (past and present) currently savethe federal government almost $35 billionper year.

State governments also have an over-all saving, albeit somewhat smaller, of $2 . 1billion. This saving takes into account th elarge saving in nursing home costs finance dthrough Medicaid ($4 .8 billion) which ex-ceeds net medical costs of $1 .5 billion .Theremaining difference reflects a cost of $1 . 8billion from foregone contributions and abenefit of $0 .6 billion in retirement savings .

States also receive about $7 .6 billion of ciga-rette taxes, for a total saving of almost $1 0billion .

Private third parties also have savingsof $5.4 billion largely because a $22 billio nsaving in pensions offsets the net costssmokers impose on employer health plans .

Costs are imposed on some segment sof society, with or without discount rate s(and benefits are received by others) . Pri-vate health insurance is one example wherea net cost occurs . One should not neces-sarily conclude that lump sum payments t othese firms is appropriate, however, sinc ethe higher costs were passed on to subscrib -ers, that is, to the large group of individu-als enrolled in private health insurance . I tis these individuals, not the stockholders o finsurance companies, that have paid thecost, but they are also the same individualswho benefit from smokers' lessened claimson payments from private pension plansand for the general benefit to taxpayers . In -deed, one could think of these third-partyprivate costs as falling on a broad segmentof society, so that it makes some sense toaggregate these external costs . Once allcosts, private, federal, state and local arecombined, whether one discounts or not ,the analysis indicates that smokers are trans-ferring financial benefits to nonsmokers .

Thus, whether we examine effects onstate finances, or the effects in general ,there is no reason for payments to be mad eto nonsmokers or their representatives to

compensate them for insurance .There are uncertainties, of course ,

about the magnitude of these effects, whic h

might be worth further study. Many of theseuncertainties are addressed in Gravelle andZimmerman (1994) . This earlier study als odiscussed the external costs of passivesmoking . The effects of passive smoking,however, were uncertain and likely to oc-cur within families ; in any case, they weretoo small to alter the findings regarding ag-

gregate external costs .

For a number of reasons, the settle-ment design does not fit into a product li-ability framework .The best that can be saidfor framing the settlement as a product li-ability settlement is that it may be the bes toutcome from a judicial system that oper-ates imperfectly. It is, after all, governmen tauthorities who have brought unjustifiedfinancial claims against the industry. More -over, it is not clear that these claims wouldhave been addressed appropriately, from aneconomic standpoint, in the judicial system .The judge in the Florida case, which wassettled by the industry, would not allow tes -timony about the financial savings from pre -mature death . Faced with these legal diffi-culties, it is not surprising that the industrywished to settle claims, particularly throughpayments that were made in such a way asto shift the burden from their stockholder s

to the consumers of tobacco products, andto create an economic environment with

some certainty with regard to future claims .Thus, the product liability framework couldbe seen as a way to correct a failure in th ejudicial system, particularly if the plan i sconsistent with an alternative public polic yframework .

Policymakers have not, however, ex-plicitly made this choice . For that matter,although a number of economic studieshave made the point that smokers do no timpose costs on others in the economy, thi sargument has had little attention and has ,indeed, been completely ignored in a Trea-sury Department study (1998) . It reinforce s

8

Page 14: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

the importance of considering distributionaleffects, since the imposition of a large ta xon smokers is not justified on the ground sof fairness, even if it may be justified on ef-ficiency grounds . Rather, smokers are bein gmade to bear a much heavier tax in orderto achieve a policy objective that is statedto be for their own benefit—a case that i snot easy to make but which we turn to now.

III. The Settlement as aPigovian Tax

The alternative paradigm is that of acorrective tax, which should then be evalu-ated in the typical framework of taxation .That is, does the tax achieve the goals ofefficiency, equity, and administrative feasi-bility? Is it designed appropriately and areits consequences understood ?

EfficiencyThe potential efficiency arguments for

imposing a tax are variously based on th e

imposition of medical costs on others, an dthe possibility of suboptimal decisions b ysmokers . The latter could be the case i fsmokers are either (a) uninformed abou trisk, or (b) have made an irrational decision ,an argument that is linked to th eaddictiveness of smoking, and the initiationof smoking by teenagers . Moreover, even i f

there is an efficiency justification, the de-sirability of corrective taxation should alsotake into account the price elasticity and theresultant deadweight loss . If smoking is no tresponsive to price changes within th erange of price corrections, then the dead-weight loss is either small or cannot be eas -ily altered with the tax mechanism .This lat-ter point is particularly important if thereare significant transitional or administrativecosts, or undesirable distributional effects .

External CostsThe external costs of smoking are re-

lated to the analysis of the costs impose don third parties, already discussed, but thi scost should use lifetime discounted costs o fsmoking. The Manning (1991) study, and

updates by Gravelle and Zimmerman (1994)

and Viscusi (1995) have generally show nthat discounted current taxes are larger thandiscounted external costs, which are smal lbecause of the offsetting benefits of prema-ture death .

Suboptimal DecisionsIn the absence of external costs, the

efficiency argument must rest on smoker smaking suboptimal choices . Making a sub-optimal choice cannot merely be inferre dfrom the undertaking of risky behaviors . I tis the cornerstone of utility theory that in-dividuals can engage in activities that ar erisky or costly, but whose pleasures out-weigh their costs . And there is ample evi-dence of a plethora of risky or unhealthyactivities that individuals engage in .

Rather, the indication of this type ofdistortion must rest either on imperfect in-formation with respect to risk or some othe rcomplicating factor that causes inefficientdecisions to be made . It is probably fair ,however, to dispense with the argumen tthat smokers are not making optima lchoices because they are not informed ofthe health risks of smoking . Viscusi (1992 )documents clearly that smokers are not onlyaware of the health costs but tend to exag-gerate the risk, and this exaggeration is eve n

greater among young people . Even the factthat costs occurring far in the future ar e

heavily discounted, as may be the case wit hyoung smokers, does not, in and of itself,imply a market failure .

The market failure must, therefore, res tin the addictiveness of smoking . Even thatargument, while it may be used to justify apaternalistic intervention, is not a clear-cu treason to identify a market failure .Any habit -forming activity, whether physically addic-tive or not, imposes transaction costs i nchanging behavior. In order for this issu e

to create an important distortion, ther emust be significant transaction costs t ochanging behavior and individuals must ei-ther be uninformed about the magnitude o fthese transaction costs or their decision -making must be impaired in some fashion .

9

Page 15: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

It is the combination of these factors thatprovides the potential justification for a cor -rective tax—namely that transaction cost sare significant and that smoking is initiatedby young individuals who are not fullyaware of the transaction costs of quittingsmoking. There is evidence for this argu-ment, in that most smoking is initiatedwhen young and these individuals do nothave the maturity to appropriately take intoaccount the significant transaction costs . I ntheory, both of these conditions must holdto generate the externality. If it were easyto quit smoking, then smoking by teenag-ers would be of little concern, since theywould alter their behavior with increase dmaturity, with negligible effects on health .And if individuals were aware of the trans -action costs, as might be expected of moremature consumers, they are not facing adistorted price .

The extent to which these condition shold is subject to some uncertainty . It i swidely known that smoking is habit-form-ing and physically addictive ;Viscusi (1992)also presents some evidence that even chil-dren know that it is hard to quit smoking .The evidence on the magnitude of transac-tion costs is also not entirely clear-cut . Many

smokers say they would like to quit an dmany people who try fail . On the otherhand, these characteristics are associate dwith many behaviors, and a lot of smokershave quit .

However, the economic justificationfor correcting a distortion must lie here —that the problem is largely the initiation o fsmoking by teenagers who may make a de-cision to become smokers without fully tak-ing into account the transaction costs o fquitting .

Having identified the potential marke tfailure, the tax mechanism should then b eevaluated with respect to its efficacy in re-ducing smoking by teenagers and by its suc -cess in comparison to other approaches, aswell as any undesirable consequences, forexample, in altering the income distribu-tion .

The focus of the desired behavioral

response has been on participation in smok-ing, with the notion that underage smok-ers who participate, even if they do notsmoke very much, may eventually increasetheir smoking . Alternative approaches in-clude strict restrictions on sales to minors ,public education programs, restrictions onadvertising, restrictions on smoking in pub-lic places, and funding of cessation pro-gratns .And, of course, another policy alter-native is to develop a safer cigarette . (Whilenicotine is thought to be associated withsome health problems, it is the tars that aregenerally implicated in cancer) .

Much of the initial drive for raisin gprices to reduce teenage smoking, particu-larly smoking participation which reflect sthe introduction to the habit, was based ona study of Lewit, Coate and Grossman(1981) that found a significant teenage elas -ticity: -1 .2 for participation, and a total con-sumption elasticity of -1 .4.This research hasexamined teenage smoking rates as a func-tion of price across jurisdictions, and cov-ered ages 12-17 .These elasticities are muchhigher than those typically estimated fo radults, which commonly fall between -0 .3and -0 .5, with most of the response due t oparticipation .

While a number of other studies ex-amined different age groups, includin gyoung adults, this was the only study, for anumber of years, that focused on underag esmokers . A study by Wasserman, et al .(1991) reported an insignificant elasticity,showed smoking rates rising with price, an ddid not separate participation and quantit yeffects . This study did not alter the prevail-ing views regarding prices and teenag esmoking, perhaps because the results wereviewed as potentially flawed by the lack o fcontrol for correlated regulatory restric-tions .

Recent research has suggested thatparticipation responses may be muc hsmaller. The difficulty with cross-sectio nstudies is that smoking rates may also b eaffected by correlated non-price factors .Where community attitude towards smok-ing in general and by teenagers in particu -

10

Page 16: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

lar is more negative, taxes may be larger,and regulatory restrictions (such as limit son smoking in public places or effectiveenforcement of restrictions on sales to mi-nors) may be stricter.

Chaloupka and Grossman (1996) at -tempted to measure some of these regula-tory restrictions and found that the partici-pation elasticity was lowered as a result, t o-0 .6 in the case where they also took ac-count of border crossing to control for pur-

chases in neighboring jurisdictions .Even if regulatory restrictions can b e

controlled for, there remains an unobserve dvariable in these studies : community atti-tude. The potential importance of this un-observed variable is highlighted in two re -cent studies that used panel data .A recentstudy by DeCicca, Kenkel and Mathio s(1997) found results similar to those o fChaloupka and Grossman, ranging betwee n-0 .5 and -0 .75, although they did not con-trol for border crossing. However, the yfound an interesting result : when teens whowere already smoking in the eighth grad ewere eliminated from their sample, the par-ticipation price elasticity dropped to zero .That is, there was no participation responseof high school students who had not alreadystarted to smoke before entering highschool . While there are some theoretica lreasons relating to rational addiction mod-els of smoking that might explain this re-sult, another possibility was that communit yattitude was correlated with smoking b ythese younger teens . Indeed, when the

three major tobacco producing states weredropped from the study, the participatio nelasticity also declined to virtually zer oacross 8th grade smokers .

Evans and Huang (1998) examine dwithin-state variation over time and foun delasticities that ranged from -0 .2 to -0 .5 ,depending on the time period . Their ap-proach allowed direct controls for state dif-ferences but are subject to the uncertain-ties of time series .

It is difficult to control for all factorsthat affect underage smoking, but these re -cent studies raise some doubts about the

responsiveness of underage smoking partici -pation to price changes .In some ways, suc ha finding might not be so surprising . In

theory, underage consumers might be ex-pected to be more price responsive becausecigarettes are a larger part of their budget .However, underage smokers may not smokeas often as adult smokers . According to theUniversity of Michigan's Monitoring th eFuture Survey, while 36 .5 percent of highschool seniors smoked at least one cigarett e

in the past month, only 24 .6 percentsmoked at least one cigarette daily and onl y

14.3 percent smoked more than ten ciga-rettes daily. Moreover, the objectives (e .g .status) may be different and maintained bysmoking less .Teenagers, in fact, tend to buyhigher priced premium brands .

These results cast doubt on the effec-tiveness of price increases as a tool to pre -vent smoking initiation by teenagers . Theysuggest that alternative approaches such as

education, restrictions on smoking in pub-lic places, or greater restrictions on sales t ominors might be more effective .At the sametime, they suggest that measures to reduceadult smoking, which might alter the com-munity environment, could be effective .These adult smoking objectives are also not ,however, likely to be addressed easil ythrough price increases, given the inelasti cresponse of adult smokers .An alternative isassistance with smoking cessation, for ex -ample, through counseling and providingcoverage under health insurance .Chaloupka and Grossman (1996) found thatthere were effects on teenagers of publicsmoking restrictions ; however, the reviewof the efficacy of these alternative ap-proaches by the Congressional Budget Of-fice (1998) found limitations on all of thesemethods . Smoking behavior may simply b ea behavior that is very difficult to influence ,and each approach has offsetting costs i nrestricting personal freedom and/or direc tenforcement costs that might be significant .

Ironically, two aspects of the curren tproposed settlements might not accomplishthe desired objectives and could, at least intheory, increase smoking .

11

Page 17: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

First, it is possible that giving firmsimmunity from future lawsuits by restrict-ing class action suits and punitive dam-ages—provisions that were in the originalsettlement but were removed in the Com-merce Committee's plan—actually helps t odiscourage smoking . If individuals are ratio -nal about their smoking behavior, then intheory the compensation for their potentialfuture illnesses would reduce the effectiveprice of smoking . This is another instancein which lack of a consistent public polic yframework has interfered with the designof the initiative . Providing these limits onindividual law suits would discourage smok-ing, other things being equal .

Secondly, the restrictions on advertis-ing have uncertain effects .There is little evi-dence that advertising has much effect o naggregate smoking behavior (as opposed to

market share) ; reducing the venues for ad-vertising may lead to more price competi-tion, particularly if advertising costs fall .

Another efficiency cost that has re-ceived some attention is the developmen tof an international black market in ciga-rettes if extremely high taxes are imposed .Canada experienced a surge in the blackmarket when higher taxes were imposed ,and various avenues for smuggling existed .Black markets are costly in foregone rev-enues, enforcement costs, and encouragin gdisrespect for laws in general .

Distributional EffectsA public finance economist might b e

startled by the virtual lack of discussion dur-ing the debate over the tobacco settlemen tabout the distributional effects of taxes ontobacco, particularly given that distribu-tional effects were a high profile issue dur-ing consideration of the 1997 tax cut . Al-though a Congressional Research Servicestudy by Gravelle (1998) first issued in 1997addressed this issue, neither the Treasur ystudy (1998) nor the recent study by th eCongressional Budget Office (1998) evenmentioned income distribution .

It is well known that tobacco taxes areamong the most regressive taxes, and the

large taxes proposed, particularly in the re -cent Commerce Committee proposal ,would impose taxes that are estimated a t$1 .10 but may exceed $2 .00 per pack by2003, accounting for additional penaltie sand volume reductions ; this amount is in ad-dition to the federal tax of 24 cents per packimposed by the federal government, in -creases already scheduled by the 1997 leg-islation of 15 cents per pack, and state andlocal taxes that range up to $1 .00 per packand average over 30 cents per pack . More -over, there is some evidence that a dollarin tax leads to slightly more than a dollar infinal price . (One reason for this might be amarkup by wholesalers and retailers ; sev-eral potential causes of this markup are le-gitimate even in a competitive industry

since distributors incur additional costs i nearnings on inventory, insurance and ad va -lorem taxes . Some states also have mini -mum pricing laws for tobacco which maybe binding in some cases) . For a smokerwho smokes a pack a day, a tax of $2 pe rpack amounts to over $730 per year and atax of $2 .50 per pack amounts to $912 . Fora full time minimum wage worker, the pay-roll tax (individual share) is $820 .

Tobacco taxes are especially regressivebecause smokers tend to consume the sam eamounts regardless of income, and smok-ing prevalence is greater at lower incomes .According to Viscusi's (1995) data for 1990 ,for those with incomes of less than $10,000 ,which account for the bottom ten percentof the population, smoking prevalence i s31 .6 percent, current cigarette taxes are1 .62 percent of median income in this class ,and 5 .1 percent of smokers' median in -comes. Since the cigarette tax would bemore than doubled, smokers in this clas swould pay in excess of 5 per cent of theirincome in additional taxes under the Jun e1997 settlement, and far more than thisamount under the Commerce Committeeproposal .

For the $10,000-$20,000 class, consti -tuting the next 18 percent of the popula-tion, with a participation rate of 29 .8 per-cent, the current tax is 0 .5 percent for all

12

Page 18: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

individuals and 1 .7 percent for smokers . Forthe $20,000-$35,000 class, constituting thenext 22 percent of individuals, here the par-ticipation rate is 26 .9 percent, the tax is 0 .25percent of income for all individuals and0 .93 percent for smokers . In the next group ,which earns $35,000-$50,000 and has asmoking prevalence of 23 .4 percent, the taxis 0 .14 percent of income for all individu-als and 0.6 percent of smokers' incomes .Finally, for the $50,000 and over class, wit ha smoking prevalence of 19 .3 percent, th etaxes are 0.08 percent of total income and0 .4 percent of the income of smokers .Thisis true even under the more modest in -creases in the June 1997 proposal, and th eSenate proposal would double these effect s(and perhaps more than double them) .

If prices have a small effect on the par-ticipation rates for underage smokers, the nthis distributional effect on the vast major-ity of smokers (98 percent) who composethe adult market would seem to be an im-portant offsetting cost for achieving thi spublic policy goal. At the minimum, som econsideration of recycling revenues t olower-income individuals would be a wa yto ameliorate this effect . Obvious choice sinclude increases in the earned income ta xcredit or allowing some exemption in th epayroll tax .

None of the proposals for disposing ofthe revenues seem particularly targeted t othis lower income group . How the state swould actually spend their share is un-known. Proposals to allow deductions forhealth insurance for individuals not coveredby employer plans will benefit middle andupper income classes and leave unaffecte dthe lowest income individuals, who do no tpay income taxes and who are unlikely topurchase health insurance . Some spendin gprograms, such as health care for uninsuredchildren, might benefit lower income indi-viduals, but would exclude smokers who d onot have children . Providing cessation as-sistance would help smokers in general, butwould not be targeted to lower incom esmokers .

Another distributional effect that

might be considered is the effect on stock -holders if one or more firms is driven intobankruptcy. Some financial analysis havepredicted that this effect might occur in th ecase of RJR which has experienced somefinancial problems, particularly if the pay-ments are large .

Design and Budgetary Issue sTwo problems with the design of th e

settlement payments make them less effi-cient in achieving the corrective tax objec-tive.Throughout the congressional debate ,there have been proposals to disallow de-ductibility of settlement payments .While allpayments in the June settlement were de-ductible, the penalties for underage smok-ing would not be deductible under the Sen -ate proposal . This desire not to make th esettlements deductible seems to derive fro mboth a desire to further punish the tobacc o

firms and from a misunderstanding of howexcise taxes should be treated .Any paymen t

that is expected to be passed on in pric eshould be made deductible in order to off-set the increased income taxes on the addi -tional revenues.Without deductibility, firm shave the explicit payments and an addi-tional income tax payment . Moreover, whil ean excise tax is a straightforward mecha-nism for altering prices of products, an in-come tax penalty could cause undesirabl econsequences, in particular, incentives forfirms to move their manufacturing opera-tions abroad and out of the reach of the in -

come tax. Disallowing deductibility also fa-vors imported products, whose producer sare not subject to the U.S . income tax .

Of course, while deductibility cause sthe firm's income tax to remain fixed, there

is an overall budgetary cost (assuming afixed overall price level) because productprices will have to fall slightly across theboard to accommodate the higher tobacc otax; thus, taxable income in the econom ywill fall . The rule of thumb is normally t o

reduce excise tax receipts by about 25 per-cent to account for this effect . This pointwas not recognized in the June settlementand again illustrates the problems that arise

13

Page 19: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

when an inappropriate policy framework i sused.

In addition, it is difficult to determin ewhat marginal effects on cost the penaltypayments might have . A fixed paymentwould fall on stockholders ; a tax would fal llargely on firms . (There has been some dis-cussion of the extent to which tobacco ex-

cise taxes are passed on in price, given thatthe industry is an oligopoly, but most em-

pirical evidence suggests that they are) . A

fixed payment allocated by market sharewould alter marginal cost in the same wayas a tax if the additional production wer eexpected to displace that of a competitor.If the firm expects to add to total consump-tion, however, there is only a partial effec ton marginal cost .A large firm will increaseindustry output by its share of the market ,causing the payment to have only a partia l

effect on marginal cost. For example, if afirm produces 50 units out of a market to-tal of 100 and pays half the fixed payment ,increasing its units to 51 and increasing thetotal market sales to 101 will increase itspayment by half the unit cost . A firm tha tproduces one unit will increase its share by99 percent of the unit cost . Of course, theanalysis of the effect of penalties is evenmore complicated because they relate t omarket share of the underage market .Whilethe rationale behind the penalties is presum -ably to discourage firms from marketing t ounderage consumers, firms do not have di-rect control over these sales .

Finally, as an administrative matter, i twould be most efficient to collect thes epayments through the same mechanism asthe existing excise taxes .

N. ConclusionThis economic analysis of the tobacco

settlement suggests that the public polic yissue has not been framed appropriately i nthe case of the tobacco settlement . Themost important consequences of this fail-ure to address the economic consequence sare a redistribution of income which hasbeen given little or no attention and that

will likely harm low-income people . Givenuncertainties about the efficacy of price in-creases and the magnitude of the distortion ,along with the general preference in the

federal tax system for progressive taxation ,enacting a highly regressive $15 or $20 bil-lion tax is a serious drawback that cast sdoubt on the desirability of the settlement .Disruptions in the market are also an inevi-table consequence of a large tax (the pay-ments in the Senate proposal involve a priceincrease of over 50 percent), which will im-pose transitional costs on stockholders an dfactors of production, including employee sof the firm .

This analysis also suggests some pos-sible policy initiatives, including recyclingsome of the revenues to lower income in-dividuals, considering non-tax measures t odiscourage underage smokers, and phasingin the increases more slowly, that might b edesirable .

14

Page 20: Buming Issues In The Tobacco Settlement, An …...Sinc e TAX I FOUNDATION Burning Issues in the Tobacco Settlement: An Economic Perspective BY JANE G. GRAVELLE, PH.D. SENIOR SPECIALIST

ReferencesCenter for Disease Control . "Medical -

Care Expenditures Attributable to Cigarett e

Smoking- United States, 1993," Morbidity

and Mortality Weekly Report, Volume 43 ,

No. 26 (July 8, 1994): pp. 469-472 .

Chaloupka, Frank J. and Michael

Grossman. "Price, Tobacco Control Policies

and Youth Smoking ." NBER Working Pape r

No. 5740 (Cambridge, MA : National Bureau

of Economic Research, 1996) .

DeCicca, Philip, Donald Kenkel, and

Alan Mathios . Putting Out the hires: Will

Higher Taxes Reduce Youth Smoking ?

Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, Decembe r

1997 .

Evans, William N . and Lynn Huang .

Cigarette Taxes and 'Peen Smoking : NewEvidence from Panels of Repeated Cross

Sections . College Park, MD: University o f

Maryland, January 6, 1996 .

Gravelle, Jane G . and Dennis

Zimmerman . "Cigarette Taxes to Fund

Health Care Reform ." National Tax journa l

Volume 47, No . 3 (September, 1994) : pp .

575-590 .Lewit, E . M ., D . Coate, and M .

Grossman . "The Effects of Government

Regulations on Teenage Smoking," .journal

of Law and Economics, Volume 24, (De-

cember, 1981), pp . 545-69 .

Manning,Willard 6 ., Emmett B . Keeler,

Joseph P Newhouse, Elizabeth M . Sloss, Jef-

frey Wasserman . The Costs of Poor Health

Habits, A RAND Study, Cambridge, MA :

Harvard University Press, 1991 .

Miller, Leonard S ., et al ."State Estimate s

of Medicaid Expenditures Attributable to

Cigarette Smoking, Fiscal Year 1993," Pub-

lic Health Reports, Volume 113 (March/

April 1998), pp . 140-151 .

Rice, D.P?, et al . Reported in "Medica l

Care Expenditures Attributable to Cigarette

Smoking, U .S. 1993," Morbidity and Mor-tality Weekly Report, Volume 43, No . 26

(July 8, 1994) .

Viscusi, W. Kip ." Cigarette Taxation an d

the Social Consequences of Smoking," TaxPolicy and the Economy, Volume 9, Na-

tional Bureau of Economic Research, Cam-

bridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995 .Viscusi, W. Kip . Smoking: Making th e

Risky Decision, New York: Oxford Univer-

sity Press, 1992 .

U.S . Congressional Budget Office ."The

Proposed Tobacco Settlement : Issues from

a Federal Perspective," (BO Papers, April

1988. Washington D.C . : Congressional Bud -

get Office .

U.S. Department of Treasury. The Eco-nomic Costs of Smoking in the U.S. andthe Benefits of Comprehensive Tobacco

Legislation, Washington, 1) .C . : U .S . Depart -

ment of Treasury, 1998 .

Wasserman, J . W.G., et al . "The Effect s

of Excise Taxes and Regulations on Cigarette

Smoking," .journal of Health Economics,

Volume 10 (1991), pp . 43-64 .


Recommended