+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5...

Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5...

Date post: 04-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
29
1 Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be Expansionary? Márcio G. P. Garcia 12 Visiting Scholar, Sloan School – MIT and NBER Associate Professor, Department of Economics - PUC-Rio This version: September 3, 2013 Abstract: Contrary to conventional wisdom, sterilized foreign exchange (FX) purchases under monetary regimes with an interest rate rule, e.g., inflation targeting, generally increase aggregate demand. We develop a simple model with a credit channel to argue that sterilized FX purchases, by funding bank credit, end up increasing aggregate and money demand, while expanding loans and deposits, and reducing the loan interest rate. Therefore, restoring the interest rate to the level prior to the sterilized FX purchase is not sufficient to prevent an expansionary effect; the new money market equilibrium, at the same interest rate, will entail a larger money supply, higher output and greater money demand. Recent Brazilian evidence is reviewed, showing that this effect may be empirically relevant. If this is the case, inflation targeters may have another reason to be concerned when conducting FX sterilized interventions, besides their high cost and controversial effectiveness in preventing nominal appreciation. Even if FX sterilized purchases are effective in preventing nominal appreciation, they generally boost activity and inflation, thereby appreciating the real exchange rate. JEL Codes: F3, F4, E5 Keywords: Sterilized Interventions, Capital Flows, and Inflation Targeting 1 E-mail: [email protected] . Website: www.econ.puc-rio.br/mgarcia. 2 I thank Rogério Werneck, Eduardo Loyo, Linda Goldberg, Marcelo Abreu, Pablo Kurlat, Eduardo Levy- Yeyati, Samuel Pessoa, Alexandre Schwartsman, Mario Mesquita, Armínio Fraga, Afonso Bevilaqua, Luis Catão, Ricardo Velloso, Marcos Chamon, Irineu de Carvalho, Otaviano Canuto, Lucio Sarno, Gustavo Loyola, Fabio Giambiagi, Jonathan Ostry, Diogo Guillen, Pedro Maia, Bernard Appy and Nicholas Hope for invaluable comments and suggestions, as well as Alessandro Rivello, Carolina Machado, Bruno Balassiano and Guido Maia for expert research assistance. All errors are mine.
Transcript
Page 1: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

1

Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be Expansionary?

Márcio G. P. Garcia12

Visiting Scholar, Sloan School – MIT and NBER

Associate Professor, Department of Economics - PUC-Rio

This version: September 3, 2013

Abstract:

Contrary to conventional wisdom, sterilized foreign exchange (FX) purchases under monetary

regimes with an interest rate rule, e.g., inflation targeting, generally increase aggregate demand.

We develop a simple model with a credit channel to argue that sterilized FX purchases, by

funding bank credit, end up increasing aggregate and money demand, while expanding loans

and deposits, and reducing the loan interest rate. Therefore, restoring the interest rate to the

level prior to the sterilized FX purchase is not sufficient to prevent an expansionary effect; the

new money market equilibrium, at the same interest rate, will entail a larger money supply,

higher output and greater money demand. Recent Brazilian evidence is reviewed, showing that

this effect may be empirically relevant. If this is the case, inflation targeters may have another

reason to be concerned when conducting FX sterilized interventions, besides their high cost and

controversial effectiveness in preventing nominal appreciation. Even if FX sterilized purchases

are effective in preventing nominal appreciation, they generally boost activity and inflation,

thereby appreciating the real exchange rate.

JEL Codes: F3, F4, E5

Keywords: Sterilized Interventions, Capital Flows, and Inflation Targeting

1 E-mail: [email protected] . Website: www.econ.puc-rio.br/mgarcia. 2 I thank Rogério Werneck, Eduardo Loyo, Linda Goldberg, Marcelo Abreu, Pablo Kurlat, Eduardo Levy-Yeyati, Samuel Pessoa, Alexandre Schwartsman, Mario Mesquita, Armínio Fraga, Afonso Bevilaqua, Luis Catão, Ricardo Velloso, Marcos Chamon, Irineu de Carvalho, Otaviano Canuto, Lucio Sarno, Gustavo

Loyola, Fabio Giambiagi, Jonathan Ostry, Diogo Guillen, Pedro Maia, Bernard Appy and Nicholas Hope for invaluable comments and suggestions, as well as Alessandro Rivello, Carolina Machado, Bruno Balassiano and Guido Maia for expert research assistance. All errors are mine.

Page 2: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

2

Index

1. Introduction .....................................................................................................................3

2. A Simple IS-LM Model with Two Assets ..............................................................................6

3. Effects of Sterilized Interventions ......................................................................................9

4. Different Types of Capital Inflows and Policy Measures ..................................................... 15

5. FX Sterilized Interventions in Brazil and Money ................................................................ 17

6. Concluding Remarks ....................................................................................................... 26

7. References ..................................................................................................................... 29

Page 3: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

3

1. Introduction

Until recently, international financial markets were very liquid. The abundant liquidity,

together with the good prospects of many emerging markets, drove massive capital flows to

these economies.

Several emerging markets, like Brazil, have been conducting monetary policy in an inflation

targeting framework. Although this framework prescribes a free floating exchange rate, the

exchange rate appreciation caused by capital inflows is increasingly being seen as extremely

detrimental to long term growth. The specter of Dutch disease has often been invoked.

Therefore, several forms of intervention in exchange rate markets without violating the open

economy inconsistent trinity have been attempted. The main ones are controls on capital

inflows and foreign exchange (FX) sterilized purchases.

In a country with extremely high interest rates, as it was (and still is, although not so high)

the case of Brazil, the foreign exchange (FX) reserves purchased through sterilized

interventions are very expensive, thereby generating high fiscal costs.3 The theoretical and

econometric evidence as to the effectiveness of sterilized purchases of FX in depreciating the

home currency is also very mixed.4 Nevertheless, sterilized interventions have been conducted

in Brazil for a considerable period of time, generating a very large volume of foreign reserves

(around USD 370 bi, or over 16% of GDP).

Despite its flaws, sterilized purchases of FX are widely believed to have no effects on

economic activity. To illustrate this point, imagine an open economy with unemployment at

NAIRU, GDP growth at the normal rate, the real interest rate at the neutral rate and the

inflation rate equal to the inflation rate target.

Suddenly, capital starts to flow into this economy because oil, for example, has been found

or because risk aversion has decreased worldwide. The inflation-targeting-monetary-policy

maker decides to fully sterilize the capital inflow. Under an inflation targeting regime, this

means purchasing all the FX inflow with domestic currency, thereby lowering the nominal

interest rate, while simultaneously conducting contractionary open market operations that

restore the previous nominal interest rate.

Are such sterilized interventions under inflation targeting expansionary?5 Most

economists, at least those I have interviewed, will answer in the negative. This paper argues

that the answer is most likely to be positive.

3 According to Credit Suisse, “... evaluating the sterilization cost, according to the main market indicators for the cost of rolling over debt, the fiscal cost of carrying the reserves would be approximately 1.4% of GDP per year from 2004 to 2010. In the 12-month period through June 2011, the cost of carrying the reserves would be 2.7% of GDP, nearly equivalent to the central government´s primary surplus in the same period” (Credit Suisse, 2011). 4 Dominguez and Frankel (1993), Sarno and Taylor (2001) and Neely (2005) provide classical surveys. Engel (2013) provide a recent evaluation of the econometric results, ending with the following caveat:

“despite many empirical studies, it is not clear yet whether sterilized intervention meets the same criteria that regulators use to decide whether to approve a cancer drug—that is safe and effective” (p. 39). 5 The question abstracts from possible effects on the exchange rate.

Page 4: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

4

Policy-makers in developing countries have complained about capital inflows’

expansionary effect on credit aggregates. The Brazilian central bank, for example, considered

that: “… the fragility in some mature economies, combined with favorable perspectives for the

Brazilian economy, has determined an inflow of foreign resources, part of which has been going

to the credit market. In this sense, the excess of external inflows may weak (sic) the credit

channel, smooth its contribution to the aggregate demand moderation, as well as cause

distortions in the price of domestic assets” (Central Bank of Brazil, 2011). The Chilean central

bank warned: “… the main risks for financial stability associated with larger gross capital

inflows include the generation of currency and maturity mismatches, credit booms that lead to

a deterioration in loan quality, and local asset price misalignment” (Central Bank of Chile,

2011). The Turkish central bank admonished: “… in emerging economies, short-term capital

flows and rapid credit growth feed macro financial risks. … . The major risk factor for emerging

economies is the macroeconomic imbalances driven by rapid capital inflows. Central banks of

emerging economies continued to implement macroprudential measures to contain the

potential adverse effects of capital flows” (Central Bank of Turkey, 2011).

All these central banks have adopted the inflation targeting regime. They also intervene in

exchange rate markets through sterilized interventions. Therefore, if they are complaining

about the expansionary effects of capital inflows on credit aggregates, sterilized interventions

are not being effective in isolating the real economy from capital flows. However, current

models6 have no such expansionary effect.

In this paper, it will be shown that sterilized FX purchases, even if they are ineffective in

depreciating the exchange rate, do not immunize the domestic economy from the

expansionary effects of capital inflows, thereby justifying the policy-makers contentions.

Policy-makers, however, may be displeased to learn that, in order to counteract the

expansionary effect of sterilized FX purchases, contractionary policies (fiscal and/or monetary)

must be conducted. The idea that, by lowering interest rates, less capital will flow into the

country, thereby mitigating the expansionary effects of capital inflows is false. This is because

the capital inflows attracted to profit from high domestic government bond yields are not the

ones that generate the expansionary effect. The expansionary effect is generated by capital

that enters the country to finance aggregate demand expansion.

6 Signaling models could provide a rationale for sterilized FX purchases being expansionary. According to the signaling mechanism, those sterilized interventions would be a way for the Central Bank to signal future reductions in interest rates. As Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) recognize, “… there certainly seem to have been episodes in which sterilized interventions, when concerted among large groups of countries, have clarified governments’ views on exchange rates and shifted market opinion…” about macroeconomic policies. However, the inflation-targeting (IT) framework has many channels through which the central bank may communicate its intentions to markets: monetary policy committee (MPC) minutes, inflation reports, etc. In fact, increased transparency and accountability are believed to be key improvements of IT over previous monetary policy regimes (Mishkin, 2000). It is very unlikely that any central bank that adopts IT would resort to sterilized interventions to signal a change in monetary policy.

Furthermore, it will be shown that, in Brazil, after the increase in sterilized purchases, the basic interest rate was raised, not lowered, as well as the other contractionary monetary quantitative measures (e.g., increases in reserve requirements) taken.

Page 5: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

5

The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces a

new asset, credit.7 In Section 3, the model is extended to account for sterilized interventions.

The model shows that sterilized interventions under inflation targeting will, in general, be

expansionary. This result follows from two key features of the model: the existence of two

interest rates, the bond interest rate and the loan rate, as well as a portfolio effect, which

makes the banks increase loans, and reduce the loan rate, when their liabilities grow due to

the capital inflows. Section 4 develops elaborates on the model to conclude that FX inflows,

and therefore capital inflows, are not homogeneous as to their effects in the credit market.

This distinction is key to appreciating why lowering interest rates in times of high capital

inflows, with the aim of deterring these inflows, as Turkey did in 2010, may be ineffective and

fuel the credit market even more. Section 5 presents empirical evidence from Brazil supporting

the view that sterilized interventions under inflation targeting are expansionary. Finally,

section 6 concludes with a discussion of the policy implications of the expansionary effects of

sterilized interventions under inflation targeting.

7 Bernanke and Blinder (1988).

Page 6: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

6

2. A Simple IS-LM Model with Two Assets

To illustrate how sterilized FX purchases under inflation targeting may be expansionary, we

resort to a simple IS-LM model with two assets, akin to the one developed by Bernanke and

Blinder (1988), henceforth referred to as the BB model.

In models inspired by the traditional IS-LM model, “… loans and other forms of customer-

market credit are viewed as perfect substitutes for auction-market credit (“bonds”)” 8. In the BB

model, a third asset, loans, is added to money and bonds.

Borrowers and lenders observe the relevant interest rates (i on bonds, and on loans) and

decide how to allocate their wealth. The demand for loans is, therefore, represented by

equation (1), where y (GNP) “… captures the transaction's demand for credit”9:

𝐿𝑑 = 𝐿(𝜌, 𝑖, 𝑦) (1)

Loans supply is performed through the banking sector. To understand how it works,

Figure 1 displays the simplified balance sheet of the representative bank, which is analogous to

balance sheet of the entire banking sector.

Figure 1: The Simplified Balance Sheet of a Representative Bank

Bank Balance Sheet Assets Liabilities

R (bank reserves) D (deposits)

Bb (bonds)

Ls (loan supply)

Bank’s assets are bank reserves (R), bonds (Bb), and loans (Ls). Bank’s liabilities are deposits

(D). Bank reserves (R) are composed of required reserves (τ.D) plus excess reserves (E).

Therefore, from the bank’s balance sheet:

𝐵𝑏 + 𝐿𝑠 + 𝐸 = 𝐷(1 − 𝜏) (2)

The portfolio shares of bonds (β), loans (λ) and excess reserves (ε), β+λ+ε=1, are

determined according to returns (zero for excess reserves):

𝐿𝑠 = 𝜆(𝜌, 𝑖)𝐷(1 − 𝜏) (3)

𝐵𝑏 = 𝛽(𝜌, 𝑖)𝐷(1 − 𝜏) (4)

8 Bernanke and Blinder (1988), p. 435. 9 Bernanke and Blinder (1988), p. 435.

Page 7: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

7

𝐸 = 𝜀(𝑖)𝐷(1 − 𝜏) (5)

In this model, there is no paper currency. Money comprises only deposits (D). Equilibrium

in the money market is represented by a conventional LM curve in the y x i space. Money

supply (D, the model equivalent of M1) is given by the amount of reserves (R, the model

equivalent to M0), under the control of the central bank, multiplied by the money multiplier

(m):

𝑚(𝑖) = 1/[𝜀(𝑖)(1 − 𝜏) + 𝜏] (6)

Money demand (D) is quite conventional, depending on the interest rate and income (total

wealth is assumed constant and ipso facto eliminated). Therefore, equilibrium in the money

market is represented by the following LM curve, sloping upwards in the y x i plane:

𝐷(𝑖, 𝑦) = 𝑚(𝑖)𝑅 (7)

Having determined the money market equilibrium, we turn to equilibrium determination

in the remaining markets: loans, bonds and goods. The equilibrium in the loans market is given

by equation (8):

𝐿(𝜌, 𝑖, 𝑦) = 𝜆(𝜌, 𝑖)𝐷(1 − 𝜏) (8)

Given loan demand, L(ρ,i,y), and money demand, D(i,y), the nonbank public’s demand for

bonds is implicitly defined because total financial wealth is supposed constant. Finally, let’s

turn to the goods market equilibrium. It is summarized by an IS curve where the loan rate, ρ,

also enters:

𝑦 = 𝑌(𝑖, 𝜌) (9)

The key novelty of the BB model is precisely that ρ affects the IS curve. Since, by the

equilibrium in the loan market (equation (8)), ρ depends on D, which, in turn, by the

equilibrium in the money market (equation (7)), depends on R, monetary policy, i.e. the

amount of bank reserves (R), will also directly influence the goods market equilibrium .

The graphical representation is undertaken in the same familiar y x i plane, although a

tridimensional y x i x representation would probably be more instructive. To represent the

model in the y x i plane, we start by replacing D in the loans market equilibrium (equation (8))

by money supply, m(i)R, yielding:

𝐿 = (𝜌, 𝑖, 𝑦) = 𝜆(𝜌, 𝑖)𝑚(𝑖)𝑅(1 − 𝜏)

Then, the resulting equation can be solved to yield ρ as a function of the other variables: i,

y, R and τ:

𝜌 = Ø(𝑖, 𝑦, 𝑅, 𝜏) (10)

In (10), the derivative of ρ with respect to i is usually positive, because when i increases,

banks tend to allocate more of their free deposits to bonds, thereby lowering the amount of

Page 8: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

8

loans. Given a downward sloped demand curve for loans, this will increase ρ. This effect is akin

to the substitution effect in consumer theory.

However, there is another effect, akin to the income effect. When i increases, the money

multiplier also increases, yielding more deposits from the same amount of bank reserves, R. If

this “income” effect is very strong, it may overcome the former “substitution” effect, and

make ρ a negative function of i.

Substituting the ρ, given by (10), into the goods market equilibrium condition (9), we get

the new IS, which is baptized in BB as the CC (“commodities and credit”) curve, in honor of the

late Don Patinkin.

𝑦 = 𝑌{𝑖, [Ø(𝑖, 𝑦, 𝑅, 𝜏)]} (11)

The CC curve is also downward sloping in the y x i plane, for the same reasons as the

typical IS curve. However, it now responds to shifts in R, as well as to shocks in the loan

market, affecting either the supply or the demand side. In the next section, this model will be

adapted so that it can account for sterilized interventions. It will then be used to evaluate the

effects of sterilized interventions under inflation targeting.

Page 9: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

9

3. Effects of Sterilized Interventions

The BB model represents a closed economy, while the subject of this paper, sterilized

interventions, naturally suggests an open economy model. However, the introduction of a full

blown open economy model would distract us from the main goal of the paper: to show that

sterilized interventions (FX purchases) are generally expansionary even when they do not

affect (depreciate) the exchange rate. As already mentioned (see references in footnote 4),

both the theoretical and empirical evidences regarding the effectiveness of sterilized

interventions in affecting the nominal exchange rate are dubious. Of course, if sterilized FX

purchases depreciate the domestic currency, they would be, in most models, expansionary.

But what we aim to show here is another effect of sterilized interventions; even if FX sterilized

purchases do not depreciate the nominal exchange rate, they tend to be expansionary. The

expansionary effect studied in this paper is additional to the one derived from the possible

depreciation caused by sterilized FX purchases.

With that caveat in mind, we will proceed with minor adaptations of the BB model,

without explicitly introducing a foreign country or an exchange rate. The implicit assumption

will be that sterilized interventions will not affect the level of the floating exchange rate. As

previously noted, if they do, the expansionary effect of FX sterilized purchases would be even

stronger.

Sterilized interventions are usually defined as purchases or sales of FX that do not affect

the monetary base (R). However, in the inflation targeting framework, or any other monetary

policy framework in which the instrument is the interest rate (i) instead of a monetary

aggregate, the term sterilized interventions usually refers to FX transactions that do not alter

the interest rate that prevailed before the sterilized intervention (i*).10

Often, it is implicitly assumed that both definitions are equivalent, but it will be shown that

this is not the general case in models with a richer asset choice than the usual IS-LM one

between bonds and money.

Let us examine the mechanics of a sterilized FX purchase. For that, banks will be allowed to

have an alternative source of funding, foreign loans (FL), already denominated in domestic

currency units. For simplicity, these bank liabilities will not be subject to reserve requirements.

In order to account for foreign loans, equations (2), (3), (4), (5), (8), (10) and (11) of the

original model have to be modified in the following way.

𝐵𝑏 + 𝐿𝑠 + 𝐸 = 𝐷(1 − 𝜏) + 𝐹𝐿 (2’)

𝐿𝑠 = 𝜆(𝜌, 𝑖)[𝐷(1 − 𝜏) + 𝐹𝐿] (3’)

𝐵𝑏 = 𝛽(𝜌, 𝑖)[𝐷(1 − 𝜏) + 𝐹𝐿] (4’)

10 “Most central banks no longer target monetary aggregates, so instead, sterilized intervention can be thought of as foreign exchange market activity by the central bank that does not change its target interest rate” (Engel, 2013).

Page 10: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

10

𝐸 = 𝜀(𝑖)[𝐷(1 − 𝜏) + 𝐹𝐿] (5’)

𝐿(𝜌, 𝑖, 𝑦) = 𝜆(𝜌, 𝑖)[𝐷(1 − 𝜏) + 𝐹𝐿] (8’)

𝐿(𝜌, 𝑖, 𝑦) = 𝜆(𝜌, 𝑖)[𝑚(𝑖)𝑅(1 − 𝜏) + 𝐹𝐿] (8a’)

𝜌 = Ø(𝑖, 𝑦, 𝑅, 𝜏, 𝐹𝐿) (10’)

𝑦 = 𝑌{𝑖, [Ø(𝑖, 𝑦, 𝑅, 𝜏, 𝐹𝐿)]} (11’)

The interpretation of the expansionary effect of a sterilized FX purchase is the following.

Assume that a FX inflow enters the economy as foreign loans to banks. FL is the equivalent

amount of the foreign loans in domestic currency at the prevailing exchange rate, assumed to

be unaltered by the sterilized purchase. As previously explained, if sterilized purchases were

effective in depreciating the exchange rate, their expansionary effect would be even stronger.

First, the CB purchases all the foreign currency and issues domestic currency (R). Second,

the CB soaks up the newly issued domestic currency, exchanging it for government bonds. The

resulting bank sector balance sheet is shown in Figure 2.

Figure 2: Representative Bank Balance Sheet After the Sterilized FX Purchase

Bank Balance Sheet Assets Liabilities

R (bank reserves) D (deposits)

Bb + FL (bonds) FL (foreign loans)

Ls (loan supply)

Remember that the sterilized FX purchase under inflation targeting is supposed to restore

the interest rate to its previous level. Therefore, the asset allocation in Figure 2 cannot

represent an equilibrium for the bank with the same rates i and that prevailed before the

sterilized FX purchase. To view this, compare Figure 2 with Figure 1. Figure 2 shows that the

new bank liabilities, FL, were fully allocated to bonds. None was allocated to loans. For this to

be an equilibrium for the bank, at the previous interest rate, i, the loan interest rate, , must

have fallen. And, with a fall in the loan interest rate, , loan demand must have expanded. In

equilibrium, loan supply would also expand, provoking an expansion in output.

In fact, the sequence of events is the following. In the first stage of the sterilized FX

purchase, the CB purchases the foreign exchange and delivers the equivalent amount in

domestic currency (at the prevailing exchange rate) to the bank. This money injection causes

both i and to fall, shifting both the LM and the CC curves to the right, with [E’] being the new

equilibrium, as shown in Chart 1. Given this displacement of the CC curve, the resulting

interest rate is always higher than would be the case in the traditional IS-LM model ([E’’]),

where the IS curve does not respond to changes in R.

Page 11: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

11

Chart 1

As defined in most textbooks, a sterilized intervention would be completed by a

contractionary open market operation that would fully offset the increase in R, bringing back

the equilibrium to [E]. However, in the inflation targeting framework, what the CB has to do is

to restore i to its previous level. Given the change in the CC curve, this is obtained with a

smaller sale of bonds than would be the case in the IS-LM model.11 Chart 2 displays the

equilibrium ([E’’’]) at the end of the sterilized FX purchase that restores the previous interest

rate (i*). Note that LM2 remains to the right of the original LM0, showing that not all money

issues were removed by the sterilization procedure that restored the original interest rate.

The size of the contractionary open market operation needed to shift the interest rate (i)

back to the level determined by the MPC is always smaller than the amount necessary to bring

R back to its previous level. One way to understand why is to note that, in the second stage of

the sterilized FX purchase, the sterilization itself, what the CB does is to replace reserves by

bonds in banks’ assets. This operation contracts both the LM and the CC curves. However,

given their larger liabilities, the banks, facing the same i as before the sterilized FX purchase,

now provide more (and cheaper) loans, thereby expanding output. The final asset allocation

for the bank will have higher loan supply, as well as higher bank reserves.

Another way to appreciate how the interest rate rule leads to this incomplete sterilization

is the following. Imagine that, after the sterilized FX purchase is completed, the bank sector

balance sheet looked like the one in Figure 2. As argued before, this cannot qualify as

11 In fact, BB calls attention to the possibility that “… a rise in bank reserves might conceivably raise the

rate of interest in the credit model” (Bernanke and Blinder (1988), p. 437). If this were the case, the central bank would have to conduct an expansionary open market operation to shift the interest rate (i) back to the level determined by the MPC.

- +

Page 12: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

12

equilibrium with the same rates i and that prevailed before the sterilized FX purchase.

Therefore, banks will sell bonds to generate funds to make more loans. This portfolio

adjustment tends to increase the interest rate and decrease the loan rate. As the inflation-

targeting CB counteracts the interest rate increase with expansionary open market operations,

the amount of bank reserves is increased.

This latter interpretation has the advantage of better conveying the timing of the

expansionary effect in this static model. After all, sterilized interventions are financial

procedures that are conducted in a matter of minutes. Therefore, it is not reasonable to

assume that output would expand and contract in such a short period of time. However, this is

not the correct interpretation of the timing behind this static model. As explained in the

previous paragraph, once the sterilized FX purchase has been completed, and i is restored to

its previous level, the bank is not in equilibrium (see Figure 2), and will substitute loans for

bonds in its portfolio. As it does that, it pushes i up and down. The inflation-targeting CB

purchases the bonds and issues money to keep i at its target level, thereby monetizing the

economy. All these events, that may take days or weeks, eventually bring the economy to its

new equilibrium ([E’’’] in Chart 2). In summary, the timing of the effect, displayed in Chart 2,

has to do with the speed with which banks reallocate their portfolios from bonds to loans, not

with the speed of the sterilized intervention itself.

Bank reserves increase because, as output increases, the previous rate of interest is

restored at a higher level of money demand, which, in equilibrium, equals money supply. In

other words, the higher money supply is needed, in equilibrium, because, with higher y and

the same i, money demand increased after the sterilized FX purchase. That is, with a higher y,

the CB does not have to mop up all the money it had previously issued to restore the interest

rated, i. After the sterilized intervention, i is back to its previous level, but y is larger. This

occurs because there is more and cheaper credit in the economy. Given the shift in CC, due to

more and cheaper credit, to restore the initial level of output, y*, the CB would have to raise i

above the initial level i*.

Even if the CB were to remove all the money used to purchase the FX inflow, a small

expansionary effect would still occur. This may be seen in Chart 3. If the sterilization were to

remove all money issued, the previous LM curve would be restored. This is why LM3 lies on top

of LM0. However, given increased bank liabilities, the portfolio effect makes the CC3 curve

remain to the right of the original one, CC0, before the FX inflow, with more and cheaper loans

being provided. Therefore, output still expands when compared to its original level (compare

the new equilibrium, EIV, with the original one, E).

Page 13: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

13

Chart 2

Chart 3

For the sake of thoroughness, it is useful to examine one last case, when the CB contracts

monetary policy in order to eliminate any expansionary effect on output. As shown in Chart 3,

because larger bank liabilities increase the amount of loans and decrease the loan rate, the CC

- +

- +

Page 14: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

14

remains to the right of the original one when the original LM is restored. Therefore, in order to

restore the original output level, it is necessary to over-sterilize, as displayed in Chart 4. Note

that LM4 lies to the left of the original LM0. The new equilibrium, EV, has the original output

restored. The interest rate is higher than the original one. It is also higher than the one that

would have prevailed had the CB fully sterilized, in the textbook sense of mopping up all

money issued.

In sum, with monetary policy being conducted via an interest rate rule, as is the case in the

inflation targeting framework, sterilized FX purchases are expansionary. Even if the CB were to

fully offset the money issuance, a residual expansionary effect would still occur, because of the

portfolio effect on banks’ balance sheets.

Of course, whether or not such effects are of practical importance is an empirical issue. In

Section 5, empirical evidence will be provided in order to argue that this mechanism may have

played an important role in propping up aggregate demand in Brazil. However, before we

examine the empirical evidence, Section 4 develops the model in order to derive another

important policy conclusion regarding policy measures to counteract the detrimental effects of

capital inflows.

Chart 4

- +

Page 15: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

15

4. Different Types of Capital Inflows and Policy Measures

In the discussion regarding how to react to excessive capital inflows, it has been argued

that receiving countries would do well to reduce interest rates, in order to attract less so-called

hot money. In fact, the Central Bank of Turkey, on December 16, 2010, cut interest rates amid

rising inflation and a low output gap. The deputy governor of the Central Bank of Turkey,

Erdem Basci, argued that gradual rate cuts were the best way to prevent excessive capital

inflows fuelling asset bubbles and currency appreciation.12

The model described in the previous section may be used to analyze whether or not such

policy prescriptions are warranted. In order to do so, it is useful to differentiate two kinds of

capital inflows: those fully destined to the direct purchase of domestic government bonds and

all the others. The latter category includes all kind of inflows that, one way or another, will

fund increases in aggregate demand. Those flows will be absorbed by private firms and

financial institutions or even public institutions (including government-owned banks). Those

are the flows that were analyzed in Section 3’s model. The inflows that enter the country to

directly purchase government bonds do not have the expansionary effect described in this

paper, since they neither generate an expansion in base money, nor the portfolio effect

necessary to move the CC curve. A good example would be a special fund (SIV) set up

exclusively to buy government bonds for foreign investors. These inflows represent an external

source of demand for government bonds, thereby creating a downward pressure on interest

rates (therefore increasing government bond prices). This could, indirectly, increase aggregate

demand if the CB did not act to keep interest rates constant, but it does not create the

expansionary effect through the expansion of bank liabilities.

Both kinds of inflows are associated with currency appreciation, but only the latter form

cause credit to expand. And the capital inflows that fund bank credit are attracted by the high

, not the high i. Therefore, advocating reductions in interest rates to deal with an excessive

capital inflow situation may help to deter only the capital flows that are attracted by the high

interest rate differential of government bonds.

However, the lower interest rate will probably increase the expansionary effects of the

inflows that fund bank credit, because the lower interest rate will fuel aggregate demand,

through the usual interest rate channel. Remember that, in this model, the decline in the

interest rate is brought about by an increase in base money, R, which expands both the LM

and the CC curves, leading to a larger expansion in output, y. The fall in i tends to reduce , but

the expansion on y, by increasing the demand for loans, mitigate this effect. Even if the

elasticities are such that the fall in i substantially reduces , thereby mitigating capital inflows,

the final result may be worse, in terms of increasing aggregate demand, than what would have

happened in the absence of the monetary loosening . As shown in Chart 4, to eliminate the

expansionary effect of sterilized FX purchases, in the absence of a fiscal contraction, it is

necessary to increase interest rates, not reduce them.

Even if so-called macroprudential measures (increases in , in the model) are deemed

adequate for deterring credit expansion, the fall in interest rates will increase macroeconomic

12 Financial Times (2010).

Page 16: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

16

policy’s dependence on them. The high current inflation in Turkey (10.45% in January, 2012)

shows that the strategy of lowering the interest rates in face of massive capital inflows is not a

sensible one.

Page 17: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

17

5. FX Sterilized Interventions in Brazil and Money

After the peak of the 2008 crisis, Brazil resumed sterilized FX purchases as early as

February, 2009. Since then, foreign reserves have risen from USD 187 bi to USD 350 bi,

surpassing 15% of GDP in October, 2011.

Chart 5 shows that the monetary base has also expanded rapidly. In 2010, it increased

25%, or BRL 40 bi, compared to an inflation rate of 6%. Real GDP expanded by 7.5%.

As shown in Chart 5, FX purchases (almost BRL 80 bi in 2010) were one of the main factors

accounting for such a robust increase in money. Of course other CB operations affected the

monetary base, and it is very hard to show causality, but, prima facie, it seems plausible that

the story told by the previous model explains at least part of what has been happening in

Brazil.

Chart 5

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

Another important piece of evidence that suggests that the story behind this model might

be relevant is the behavior of credit markets in Brazil. Chart 6 makes it clear that, albeit very

expensive, bank credit has been expanding in Brazil while the average credit interest rate has

been declining. This is compatible with a supply of credit expansion larger than the increase in

credit demand, precisely what the model presented here predicts would happen with massive

sterilized interventions.

127

140

153

166

179

192

205

218

-40

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

Monetary Base and Its Main Expansion Factors(12-month-moving average; BRL bi)

Monetary Base - M0 (RHS) FX purchases (LHS)

MacroprudentialMeasures

Page 18: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

18

Chart 6

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

Furthermore, Chart 7 shows that the rate on loans to individuals follows the one-year-

interbank rate almost perfectly, with a three-month lag.13 This is quite reasonable, since the

interbank rate is the best proxy for banks’ cost of funding. However, since the beginning of

2010, this positive correlation seems to have broken down: while the interbank rate rose, the

loan rate kept following it until November,14 the month prior to the imposition of

macroprudential measures to deter credit growth.15 The interbank rate follows expectations

regarding the interest rate set by the Central Bank, the Selic, equivalent to i in the model. The

loan rate is the equivalent of the in the model. The model asserts that, under massive

sterilized FX purchases, the highly unusual negative correlation, as observed in 2010, should be

the outcome.

Econometrically, the best result is obtained when the loan rate to individuals is regressed

against its marginal cost, the one-year-interbank rate, lagged three-months, together with FX

purchases by the CB (12-month average) and a dummy for 2010 interacted with the FX

purchases. Table 1 displays the results. FX purchases by the CB become statistically significant

only when the 2010 dummy is included in the regression (interacted or not with FX purchases).

These econometric results are compatible with the main lessons from the model: the

resumption of FX purchases, after recovering from the 2008 crisis, kept the loan rate falling

13 In Chart 4, the interbank rate is leaded three months. 14 I wish to thank Eduardo Loyo for pointing this out to me. 15 The effects of macroprudential measures may also be observed at the end of Chart 6, when credit volume stops growing and the average credit interest rate increases.

700.000

740.000

780.000

820.000

860.000

900.000

940.000

980.000

1.020.000

1.060.000

30

32

34

36

38

40

42

44

% a.a.

Total Credit Freely AllocatedQuantity and Interest Rate

Total Credit (RHS) Average Interest Rate (LHS)

Macroprudential Measures

Page 19: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

19

even when the interest rate was rising. That lasted until macroprudential measures were

implemented in December, 2010. The Brazilian economy therefore performed as predicted by

the model, with the increase in sterilized FX purchases in 2010 causing the loan rate to fall

despite the increase in its marginal cost - the one-year-interbank interest rate.

Chart 7

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

In order to duly account for non-stationarity, endogeneity and autocorrelated errors,

the econometric analysis was performed using the Phillips-Hansen (1990) procedure. Table 2 displays the results. The FX purchases make the loan rate fall relatively to its long term equilibrium with the interest rate. That effect is even more pronounced in 2010. Note how the coefficients are very similar to the ones in the OLS regression, denoting that the results are quite robust.

34

42

50

58

66

74

82

90

7

11

15

19

23

27

31

% p

er y

ear

% p

er y

ear

Interbank Market Rates and Loan Rates

1-year interbank market rates (t-3) Rates on loans to individuals (t)

Macroprudential Measures

Page 20: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

20

TABLE 1: The Loan Rate and Sterilized Interventions

Dependent Variable: Loan rate to individuals

Independent Variables: One-Year-Interbank rate, FX Purchases (12-month average) and FX Purchases (12-month average) multiplied by a Dummy for 2010

Sample: 2000:12-2011:08 (T = 129)

Variable Coefficient Stand. Error t-Ratio P-Value

Constant 30.0487 1.28187 23.44 1.39e-047 ***

One-Year-Interbank Rate (t-3) 1,85388 0,0655097 28,30 3.40e-056 ***

FX Purchases (12-month average)

-0,0392121 0,00620752 -6.317 4.27e-09 ***

FX Purchases (12-month average) multiplied by a Dummy for 2010

-0,0877712 0,0122744 -7,151 6,38e-011 ***

Mean dependent variable 58,14132 S.D. dependent var. 12,53158 Sum squared resid. 1055,908 S.E. of regression 2,906418 R-squared 0,947470 Adjusted R-squared 0,946210 F(3, 125) 751,5366 P-value(F) 9,26e-80 Log-likelihood -318,6443 Akaike Criterion 645,2885 Schwarz Criterion 656,7278 Hannan-Quinn 649,9365

0,499275 Durbin-Watson 0,975744

TABLE 2: Cointegration Regression

Dependent Variable: Loan rate to individuals

Independent Variables: One-Year-Interbank rate, FX Purchases (12-month average) and FX Purchases (12-month average) multiplied by a Dummy for 2010

Sample (adjusted): 14 144 Included observations: 131 after adjustments Cointegrating equation deterministics: C Long-run covariance estimate (Prewhitening with lags = 1 from HQ maxlags = 5, Quadratic-Spectral kernel, Andrews bandwidth = 1.1543)

Variable Coefficient Stand. Error t-Ratio Prob

Constant 28.26229 2.396402 11.79364 0.0000

One-Year-Interbank Rate (t-3) 1.977465 0.122784 16.10528 0.0000

FX Purchases (12-month average)

-0.037931 0.011613 -3.266133 0.0014

FX Purchases (12-month average) multiplied by a Dummy for 2010

-0.105830 0.024147 -4.382788 0.0000

Mean dependent variable 58.31939 S.D. dependent var. 12.51822 Sum squared resid. 1261.924 S.E. of regression 3.152207 R-squared 0.938055 Adjusted R-squared 0.936592 Long-run variance 29.80132 Durbin-Watson 0.851448

Page 21: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

21

The model also predicts that deposits should increase in times of large sterilized FX purchases.

Note that Brazilian law forbids deposits in foreign currency in Brazilian financial institutions.

Chart 8 shows the increase of demand deposits and total deposits in Brazilian banks. Chart 9

displays the same data in % of GDP. It shows that they increased sharply as a % of GDP, until

the crisis, and then stabilized, as a % of GDP. Furthermore, Granger-causation runs from the

sterilized FX purchases to loans, but not the other way around.

However, when we look at all the liabilities of the banking sector (everything, except

capital), we see much higher growth since 2006, as a % of GDP (see Chart 10). Therefore, there

is evidence that banks liabilities have been growing, as predicted by the model. However, this

phenomenon has been happening since 2006, and was, apparently, not affected by the 2008

crisis.

Chart 8

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

0

50

100

150

200

250

0

200

400

600

800

1.000

1.200

1.400

1.600

1.800

Bill

ion

R$

Bill

ion

R$

Total Deposits and Demand Deposits

Total deposits Demand deposits

Macroprudential Measures

Page 22: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

22

Chart 9

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

Chart 10

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

Deposits / GDP

Total Deposits Demand Deposits

Macroprudential Measures

Macroprudential Measures

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

110%

120%

Bank Liabilities / GDP

MacroprudentialMeasures

Page 23: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

23

Chart 11

Source: Central Bank of Brazil

As mentioned before, several policy measures, besides sterilized interventions, were taken

to deal with what were perceived to be excessive capital inflows. Another set of policy

measures have targeted a subset of capital inflows. Since March 2011, short-term credit (up to

two years) obtained by Brazilian banks abroad has been taxed to deter further capital inflows.

These measures aim to deter the FX flows that prompt sterilized interventions.

An additional policy action was the decision taken in 2010 to let the Brazilian Central Bank

return to derivatives markets, trading with currency swaps. The purchase of a currency swap

by the Central Bank is equivalent to a sterilized intervention,16 in the sense of interventions

that keep money constant. As the previous results show, what are generally referred to as

sterilized interventions under inflation targeting are not equivalent to the textbook definition.

Therefore, the two forms of intervention may produce different results in terms of their

effectiveness in altering the exchange rate.

Since 2010, something seems to have changed in the behavior of the BRL/USD exchange

rate. Although there has been a historical correlation between terms of trade and the

exchange rate, improvements in the terms of trade since mid-2010 have not been

accompanied by a corresponding appreciation of the BRL, thereby transmitting the

commodities’ positive price (in USD) shock to domestic inflation. Chart 12 shows this

phenomenon.

16 Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996), pp. 597-9.

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

110%

Total Assets and Liabilities (BNDES not included)

Assets - Interbank Loans (%GDP) Liabilities (%GDP) Liabilities - Interbank Loans (%GDP)

MacroprudentialMeasures

Page 24: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

24

Chart 12

In addition, the volatility of the BRL/USD rate has fallen markedly, as shown in Chart 13.

These are evidences that government interventions may be affecting the exchange rate,

mitigating the appreciation that would occur under free floating.

Chart 13

0,20

0,28

0,36

0,44

0,52

0,60

0,68

0,76

0,84

60,00

75,00

90,00

105,00

120,00

135,00

150,00

165,00

180,00

BR

L/U

SD

Ind

ex

Exchange Rate and Commodities Prices

Exchange Rate CRB Index (in USD) CRB Index (in BRL)

0

0,01

0,02

0,03

0,04

0,05

0,06

-0,1

-0,05

0

0,05

0,1

0,15

Vo

lati

lity

Dai

ly C

han

ges

Exchange Rate (BRL/USD): Daily Changes and Volatility

Daily Changes in the BRL/USD Exchange Rate (LHS) Exchange Rate Volatility (20-day Rolling Window)

Page 25: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

25

As previously noted, the theoretical and econometric evidences regarding the

effectiveness of sterilized interventions in altering the exchange rate are mixed. However, this

paper argues that the kind of sterilized intervention conducted in Brazil does not correspond

to the canonic definition of sterilized intervention. The sterilization of the increase in money

caused by FX purchases is only partial, because the expansionary effect on output increases

money demand, thereby requiring less monetary contraction to return the interest rate to its

previous level. In a nutshell, Brazil has not been fully sterilizing its FX purchases, in the

“monetarist” sense of the expression. Therefore, it does not come as a surprise that FX

purchases may have been more efficient in mitigating nominal exchange rate appreciation.

In sum, this section has presented empirical evidence showing that many phenomena

observed in the Brazilian economy are compatible with the model’s predictions. Massive

sterilized interventions have not been neutral; they increased banks´ liabilities and the supply

of credit, making credit cheaper and more abundant, even when the Central Bank of Brazil was

raising interest rates. This, in turn, expanded aggregate demand, making it harder to keep

inflation at bay. The next section will summarize this paper’s main conclusions and policy

prescriptions.

Page 26: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

26

6. Concluding Remarks

Many countries have resorted to sterilized FX purchases to mitigate exchange rate

appreciation and large credit expansions caused by massive capital inflows. Sterilized FX

interventions are defined as FX purchases (sales) by the CB followed by open market

operations that offset their monetary impact.

Under inflation targeting, or any monetary policy regime with an interest rate rule,

sterilized FX interventions usually refer to FX operations followed by open market operations

that restore the interest rate to its target. Restoring the interest rate to its previous level may

not be equivalent to restoring the monetary base to its previous level.

We adapt a simple model17 with a banking sector and richer asset structure than just the

money and bonds present in the classical IS-LM model in order to argue that, in general, FX

sterilized interventions under inflation targeting are expansionary.

When bank credit is explicitly introduced into the IS-LM model, increases in the monetary

base (bank reserves) affect not only the LM curve, but also the new IS curve, termed CC, for

“commodities and credit”. This effect is caused by bank loans, which become cheaper and

more abundant when bank deposits rise because of the increase in bank reserves. Therefore,

when credit is incorporated into the model, monetary policy, by affecting banks’ behavior,

becomes more powerful. An increase in bank reserves will lead to a larger output expansion

than in the usual IS-LM model.

We use this model to argue that sterilized interventions under inflation targeting is

expansionary. When a foreign loan is taken out by a bank, its liabilities increase. The sterilized

FX purchase by the CB is aimed at making the bank hold all the increase in liabilities in the form

of government bonds. However, with increased liabilities, the bank wants to diversify its

holdings, and channels part of the new funds into loans. This pressure to reallocate the bank´s

portfolio—when the assets (bonds and loans) are imperfect substitutes, and given that the

previous interest rate has been restored after the sterilized FX purchase—increases loan

supply, lowers the loan rate, thereby expanding aggregate demand.

The model in this paper relies on a portfolio balance effect generated inside the bank.

Recent research on the behavior of financial institutions has shown that they tend to over

leverage in good times.18 The external funding provided by capital inflows constitutes one

important way through which this leverage may occur. As explained by the model, such an

effect occurs despite sterilization.

On the other hand, the expansionary effect of sterilized interventions has other

transmission channels apart from the one described in the model, which, in this case, is

constituted by the banking sector. The main idea is that capital flows will increase aggregate

demand when the CB keeps the interest rate constant at its level before the capital flows and

the sterilized FX purchases. This is true for banks that fund their domestic loans by borrowing

17 Bernanke and Blinder (1988). 18 Adrian and Shin (2009).

Page 27: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

27

from abroad, but is also valid for FDI or corporate securities issued abroad to fund investment

projects.

It is also true for trade flows that allow firms that export to fund their investment projects.

For example, if an exporter decides to undertake an investment project, and funds it with its

export proceeds, because, for example, the returns are higher than those obtained by

investing these export revenues in governments bonds, at prevailing interest rates (that will be

kept constant with the sterilized intervention), there will be an expansionary effect despite the

sterilization. This expansionary effect is akin to the effect displayed in the model in Section 3.

However, the expansionary effect does not hold for capital flows directly targeted to

purchase government bonds (e.g., carry-trade), for they would not increase aggregate

demand. Capital flows directly targeted to purchase government bonds represent an external

source of demand for government bonds, thereby creating a downward pressure on interest

rates (therefore increasing government bond prices). If the CB did not act to keep interest

rates constant, these capital inflows could lead to an increase in aggregate demand, but it

could not create the expansionary effect through the expansion of bank liabilities.

The part of the intuition that explains why money expands when the interest rate is kept

constant is the following. Capital flows not directly targeted to government bonds raise

aggregate demand, thereby also increasing money demand, at the prevailing interest rate.

Therefore, money supply has to increase, in equilibrium. In the model, an increase in the

monetary base is what leads, in the first place, to an increase in loans. Therefore, sterilized

interventions under inflation targeting—not fully sterilized in the sense of keeping money

constant—become expansionary.19 At the new equilibrium there will be higher aggregate

demand, a higher quantity of money, lower loan rate and higher quantity of loans at the same

interest rate. The timing to arrive at the new equilibrium has to do with how fast banks

reallocate their portfolios after the sterilized intervention, not with the few minutes the CB

takes to perform a sterilized FX purchase.

Brazil’s recent experience was reviewed to argue that the expansionary effect of sterilized

interventions may be significant. The monetary base expanded 25% in 2010, while GDP grew

7.5%. Credit also increased substantially, with most loans becoming cheaper. Besides timid

increases in interest rates, at the end of 2010, the government has resorted to

macroprudential measures, such as increases in reserve requirements. All these evidences are

compatible with the expansionary effect of sterilized interventions under inflation targeting.

One empirical evidence that the mechanism behind the model may be important to

explain what happened in Brazil is the joint behavior of the consumer loan rate and the

banks´marginal cost for loans, i.e., the one-year-interbank interest rate. They showed a

remarkably high correlation, as expected, until the end of 2009, a time when both rates were

falling. Since then, the interest rate has gone up, anticipating the increases signaled by the

Central Bank of Brazil, that were later actually implemented. However, the loan rate kept

19 The model shows that even if the CB would were to fully sterilize, a smaller expansionary effect would occur. This is because, with larger liabilities, banks will offer more and cheaper credit, thereby expanding the CC curve.

Page 28: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

28

falling. This unusual negative correlation is precisely what the model says would happen under

massive sterilized FX purchases. Econometric investigation confirms the intuition.

The main policy implication of this paper is that when a country receives large inflows of

FX that are not aimed at purchasing government bonds (including trade revenues), it is not

sufficient, in order to fully sterilize FX purchases, for the CB to restore the previous interest

rate level. If the FX flows affect aggregate demand, e.g. via bank credit, sterilized interventions

under inflation targeting will be expansionary.

Another policy implication is that policy strategies like the one adopted in late 2010 by

Turkey, that combine lower interest rates with the so-called macroprudential measures, are

inconsistent. The capital inflows that would be deterred by the fall in interest rates, those

aimed at purchasing government bonds, are not the ones that make FX sterilized purchases

expansionary. Therefore, the dependence on the so-called macroprudential measures to keep

inflation at bay would be even higher. The increase in inflation in Turkey corroborates the idea.

Only a model that differentiates the loan rate from the interest rate on government bonds, as

the one in this paper, can be useful to derive policy implications for these strategies, very

much in fashion among emerging markets, until recently, when capital flows turned back.

When and if capital resumes its flow toward emerging markets, inflation targeting

countries that conduct sterilized interventions to mitigate the appreciation of the exchange

rate in face of massive capital inflows will have another reason for concern. Even if those

sterilized interventions are effective in preventing nominal exchange rate appreciation, they

may represent a positive shock to aggregate demand, thereby increasing inflation with all its

detrimental effects, among them, the appreciation of the real exchange rate.

Page 29: Can Sterilized FX Purchases under Inflation Targeting Be ... › mgarcia › Artigos › 130903...5 The next section reviews a simple model à la IS-LM with a banking sector that introduces

29

7. References

Adrian, T. and H. Shin, 2009. The Shadow Banking System: Implications for Financial

Regulation, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, nº 382, July.

Bernanke, B. and A. Blinder, 1988. Credit, Money, and Aggregate Demand, American Economic

Review, May.

Central Bank of Brazil, 2011. Inflation Report, page 14. June. Available at

http://www.bcb.gov.br/htms/relinf/ing/2011/06/ri201106c6i.pdf.

Central Bank of Chile, 2011. Financial Stability Report, page 18. First Half 2011. Available at

http://www.bcentral.cl/eng/publications/policies/pdf/fsr1_2011.pdf.

Central Bank of Turkey, 2011. Inflation Report 2011-III, pages 11/12. Available at

http://www.tcmb.gov.tr/yeni/eng/.

Credit Suisse, 2011. Brazil Economics Digest, October 20. Available at http://www.credit-

suisse.com/researchandanalytics .

Dominguez, K. and J. Frankel, 1993. Does Foreign Exchange Intervention Work?. Washington,

DC: Institute of International Economics.

Engel, Charles, 2013, “Exchange Rates and Interest Parity”, NBER Discussion Paper #19336.

Financial Times, 2010. Turkey surprises with interest rate cut, by Delphine Strauss, December

16.

Mishkin, F., 2000. Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Countries. American Economic Review,

vol. 90(2), pages 105-109.

Neely, C., 2005. An Analysis of Recent Studies of the Effect of Foreign Exchange Intervention. Federal

Reserve Bank of Saint Louis Working Paper No. 2005-030B.

Phillips, P. and B. Hansen, 1990. Statistical Inference in Instrumental Variables Regression with I(1)

Processes. Review of Economic Studies, vol. 57, pages 99-125.

Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff, 1996. Foundations of International Economics, MIT Press,

Cambridge, MA, US.

Sarno, L. and M. Taylor, 2001. Official Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market: Is it

Effective? If so, how does it work, Journal of Economic Literature, 39(3): 839-868.


Recommended