+ All Categories
Home > Documents > cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

Date post: 02-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: garycwk
View: 220 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 23

Transcript
  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    1/23

    HOW CAN REAL OPTIONS APPROACHES

    VALUE UNCERTAINTY AND FLEXIBILITY

    IN OIL AND GAS INVESTMENTS?

    David C. Wilde

    29thJanuary, 2011.

    ABSTRACT: Investment projects in the oil and gas industry are typically

    characterised by a large degree of uncertainty and managerial flexibility. Accurate

    evaluation of such investment projects requires sophisticated appraisal methods

    beyond the traditional net present value approach. In this paper, currently used real

    options approaches are categorised and discussed with regards to their theoretical

    and conceptual strengths and weaknesses. The analysis shows that proposed real

    options approaches differ significantly in the underlying assumptions, the modelling of

    project uncertainty, required data and analytical complexity. Based on these results,

    recommendations for valuing oil and gas investments can be made.

    .

    The author is currently an MSc Candidate in Energy Studies and LLM Candidate in Energy Law andPolicy at the Univeristy of Dundee. He earlier graduated from the Univeristy of Cologne, Germany

    where he studied Business Administration with specialisation in Energy Economics, Business Finance

    and Banking Business. He is worked at Haarmann Hemmelrath, Ernst & Young AG, RWE AG, RWEPower AG and the Energy Institute at the University of Cologne (EWI).

    Email:[email protected] in CEPMLP Annual Review - CAR Volume 15 (2013) Editor-in-Chief: Dramani Bukari

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    2/23

    II

    TABLE OF CONTENTS

    Table of Contents .................................................................................................... II

    Abbreviations and Formula Symbols .................................................................... III

    1 Introduction ........................................................................................................ 1

    2 Replicating portfolio approach (RPA) ............................................................... 3

    2.1 Application ................................................................................................ 5

    2.2 Critical assessment .................................................................................... 6

    2.3 Subjective Replication Portfolio Approach .............................................. 7

    3 The Marketed Asset Disclaimer Approach (MAD) ........................................... 8

    3.1 Application ................................................................................................ 9

    3.2 Critical assessment .................................................................................. 11

    4 The Hybrid Real Options Approach (HROA) ................................................. 13

    4.1 Application .............................................................................................. 13

    4.2 Critical Assessment ................................................................................. 17

    5 Conclusion ....................................................................................................... 18

    Bibliography .......................................................................................................... 19

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    3/23

    III

    ABBREVIATIONS AND FORMULA SYMBOLS

    Annual volatility

    C Call option

    COFf Fixed cash outflow

    cofv Variable cash outflow

    d Down factor

    HROA Hybrid real options approach

    I Investment cost

    L Liquidation value

    M Market capitalisation

    MAD Marketed asset disclaimer

    MV Market value

    NPV Net present value

    OC Oil company

    OP Oil price

    prn Risk-neutral probability

    R Proved reserves

    rf Risk-free rate

    t Time index

    T Time to expiration

    u Up factor

    V Value of undeveloped oil field

    WACC Weighted average cost of capital

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    4/23

    1

    1 Introduction

    The financial evaluation of projects is at the centre of every firms investment

    decision. In the oil and gas industry, investment projects typically share three

    characteristics:1

    Property 1: Various uncertaintiescan be identified ex-antethat influence the value of

    the project. In the development stage of an oil or natural gas field, for example, these

    uncertainties refer to future commodity prices, the size of the business, technical

    aspects of the development, investment costs and regulatory uncertainty.

    Property 2: By investing, the firm is able to learnmore about the project and gather

    additional information regarding the associated uncertainties as they resolve over the

    course of time. After acquiring development rights, the firm can, for example, gain

    more information about flow rates and production profiles by testing the field before

    drilling.

    Property 3: During the investment process, management has theflexibilityto adapt its

    strategy to the new information. In the case that field tests turn out to be disappointing,

    management can decide to abandon the project before spending money for drilling.

    Similarly, management can decide to wait with production and observe oil prices

    before making the final decision to produce. In this sense, management is typically

    faced with severalsequentialinvestment decisions rather than a single decision at the

    beginning of the project.2

    In analogy to financial options, the managerial flexibilities inherent in investment

    projects can be termed real options. Real options in a broad sense provide

    opportunities for management to consider new information regarding project

    uncertainties, adapt the investment process and thereby actively influence the cash

    1Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1998), p. 198.

    2Mun, J., (2002), p.17.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    5/23

    2

    flow pattern of the project.3The conceptual analogy between financial and real options

    can be demonstrated by the example of an oil company acquiring development rights

    for an undeveloped field. The acquisition of these rights offers the firm the opportunity

    but not the obligation to enter into the production phase. Once the uncertainty

    regarding the size of the field has been resolved and management decides to produce,

    the option is exercised. Alternatively, management could decide to keep the option

    alive and wait for increasing oil prices before investing in production.

    Real options, i.e. managerial flexibility, can add significant value to an investment

    project, particularly when uncertainty regarding the project value is high.4 The

    evaluation of such projects requires sophisticated appraisal methods beyond the

    traditional net present value (NPV) approach.5Although the theoretical strengths of the

    real options methodology are widely accepted it has not become the standard in project

    evaluation in practice.6 Besides the conceptual and mathematical complexity of real

    options valuation, problems arise from the fact that the underlyingof a real option is

    not a standardised traded commodity like a stock or currency but an investment project

    with unique features, such as construction lags, regulatory uncertainty and complex tax

    and royalty structures.7

    Over the past 30 years, a variety of different, case-based real options approaches has

    been developed and applied in the academic literature. The approaches differ

    significantly in their underlying assumptions, applicability and mechanics.8This paper

    aims at categorising currently used approaches and discussing their application to the

    evaluation of oil and gas investment projects. In the following chapters, the three

    dominant types of real options approaches in the literature are described and critically

    3Dixit, A. K., Pindyck, R. S., (1994), p. 6.

    4Amram, M., Kulatilaka, N., (1999), p.8.

    5

    Dixit, A. K., Pindyck, R. S., (1994), p. 7.6Borison, A., (2005a), p. 17.7Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1999), p. 2.

    8Borison, A., (2005a), p. 18.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    6/23

    3

    assessed with regards to their theoretical and conceptual strengths and weaknesses. In

    order to illustrate the mechanics of real options valuation, each approach is applied to

    the following case study:

    Canadian Oil is evaluating an investment opportunity in an undeveloped oil field in

    Western Canada. The size of the field is uncertain but exploration activities estimated

    proved reserves to be RWC (in million barrels). Future oil prices represent the second

    uncertainty. The firm can either buy and develop the field today for I0or purchase an

    option Cwhich gives the firm the right to buy the field in three years from now (T) for

    I3. The option allows Canadian Oil to learn more about the project and the associated

    uncertainties through test drilling and market observations before making the final

    decision in T to exercise the option and develop the field or to reject further

    investment. The option premium C (call option) can be interpreted as a development

    right which has to be purchased from the Canadian government. Alternatively, the firm

    can decide not to invest at all.

    2 Replicating portfolio approach (RPA)

    Under the RPA, real options are valued by directly applying pricing formulas used to

    value financial options, such as the Black-Scholes or the Cox-Ross-Rubinstein

    models.9 A development right which offers the opportunity to invest in field

    development and production is therefore seen as completely analogous to a call option

    on a stock. The option is valuable if the value of the underlying oil field is volatile due

    to project uncertainties and if there is considerable time until the expiration date of the

    option.10A rational investor would exercise the option on expiration date Tonly, if the

    value of the field (V) in Texceeds the price I3 to be paid for the field. The resulting

    payoff in T is max[V-I3 ; -C]. Because the RPA as applied in Amram and Kulatilaka

    9This real options approach is used in: Amram, M., Kulatilaka, N., (1999); Brennan, M., Schwartz, E.,

    (1985), Trigeorgis, L., Mason, P., (1987); Trigeorgis, L., (1999)10

    Mun, J., (2002), p. 101.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    7/23

    4

    (1999) uses the Black-Scholes pricing formula for valuing real option, the value of the

    underlying oil field (V) is assumed to behave according to a Geometric Brownian

    motion.

    The calculated real option value represents financial market value, i.e. the price that

    would be paid for the investment in the capital markets.11 Regardless of subjective

    beliefs and preferences, all risk-averse decision makers can agree on the project value

    and the investment strategy.12

    The main assumption of the RPA is that the returns of the real option in question can

    be perfectly replicated in a dynamic manner by constructing a portfolio of market

    traded securities. Capital markets are thus assumed to be complete. According to no-

    arbitrage arguments in efficient markets, this portfolio (or single asset) must then have

    the same value as the real option. Brennan and Schwartz (1985), for example, suggest

    forming this replicating portfolio by trading in oil futures.13Alternatively, one could

    try to find a stock of a publicly traded oil firm that is analogous to the investment

    project.

    The possibility to dynamically replicate the value of the undeveloped oil field allows

    for the creation of a hedge position consisting of the replicating portfolio and the real

    option which earns a risk-free rate of return.14The real option value does therefore not

    depend on the required rate of return on the undeveloped field or investors risk

    preferences so that a risk-neutral world can be assumed for valuation purposes. In such

    as risk-neutral world, the estimation of a risk premium is not required.

    11

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 18.12Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1998), p. 199.13

    Brennan, M., Schwartz, E., (1985), p. 154.14

    Amram, M., Kulatilaka, N., (1999), p. 112.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    8/23

    5

    2.1 Application

    In order to evaluate the investment opportunities and find the value maximising

    strategy according to the RPA, the firm has to estimate the following option

    parameters:

    Table 1: Option parameters to be estimated under the RPA

    Parameter Real Option (European type)

    V Current (market) value of undeveloped field

    I3 Cost of investment (exercise price)

    rf Risk-free rate of return

    T (= 3) Time to expiration

    Volatility of value of undeveloped field

    Source: Author based on Amram, M., Kulatil aka, N., (1999), p. 121.

    One way of estimating the current market value of the field under consideration (V) is

    to identify the market capitalisation (MOC) of a publicly traded oil company (OC)

    whose assets (reserves =ROC) exactly replicate the cash flows of the field. The size of

    the investment relative to the replicating portfolio is given by the ratio of proved

    reserves RWC/ROC. The market value of the field can then be calculated as:

    V = (RWC/ROC)MOC.

    If short-term and long-term options on the OC-stock are available, the implied

    volatility can be calculated to obtain .As suggested by Amram and Kulatilaka (1999),

    the Black-Scholes formula can be used to calculate the market value of a call option on

    the undeveloped field (CMV):15

    CMV= N(d1)VN(d2)I3-rT, with (1)

    d1= [ln(V/I3) + (rf+ 0.52)T] / T0.5and (2)

    d2= d1T0.5. (3)

    15

    The RPA does not rely on option pricing based on the Black-Scholes model. Alternatively, otherclosed-form solutions or binomial approaches can be used to value American type options or options on

    a dividend paying underlying. All the potential pricing formulas under the RPA, however, rely on the

    no-arbitrage condition.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    9/23

    6

    Because the no-arbitrage condition implies that the replicating portfolio offers exactly

    the same return as the undeveloped oil field in all states of the world, shareholder value

    is only created if I0V. Analogously, purchasing the development right only creates

    shareholder value if C CMV. The investment decision is thus made as follows:

    If (V I0) max[CMV C;0] 0, invest in field development today to maximise

    shareholder value. In this case, the current market value of the undeveloped field (V)

    exceeds the investment costs (I0) by more than the difference between the market value

    of the call option (CMV) and the option premium (C).

    If (CMVC)max[VI0;0] 0, invest in call option on the field (development right)

    to maximise shareholder value. In this case, purchasing the call option is more valuable

    than investing in field development today.

    If (C CMV 0) and (I0 V 0), do not invest at all because the option and the

    investment project are overpriced and shareholder value is destroyed.

    2.2

    Critical assessmentA critical shortcoming of the RPA is the lack of generality. 16Single projects are not

    traded on capital markets and information regarding covariances between financial and

    real assets is generally not available.17 Therefore, portfolios consisting of traded

    securities that perfectly replicate the cash flows of single oil or natural gas investments

    are unlikely to be found.

    If oil futures are used in order to replicate the project, as suggested by Brennan and

    Schwartz (1985) or Siegel, Smith and Paddock (1987), only price risks can be hedged.

    Project specific risks, however, such as production rate risks cannot be perfectly

    replicated by this approach. Publicly traded companies, on the other hand, usually hold

    portfolios of numerous projects of different types and in different stages in order to

    16Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1998), p. 199.

    17Borison, A., (2005a), p. 19.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    10/23

    7

    mitigate risks. It cannot be expected that securities of such companies are highly

    correlated with single real assets.

    In the case that a required replicating portfolio cannot be found, the use of financial

    option formulas, such as Black-Scholes, is generally inappropriate.18

    All these

    formulas implicitly discount the projects cash flows at the risk-free rate (rf) based on

    the no-arbitrage condition. If the risk of a project cannot be fully hedged because

    capital markets are incomplete, the value of the real option to wait depends on the

    firms expectations regarding future cash flows and discounting this expected value at

    the risk-free rate results in inaccuracy. Furthermore, a correct calculation of the annual

    volatility () of the underlying which highly influences the option value becomes

    difficult. Amram and Kulatilaka (1999) who use the RPA point out that the attempt to

    dynamically replicate real assets can result in tracking errorsbut they do not provide

    a quantitative estimation of the resulting inaccuracy.19 Overall, using option pricing

    methods that rely on no-arbitrage conditions and the law of one price seems

    inappropriate in many real option applications.

    2.3 Subjective Replication Portfolio Approach

    A variation of the RPA described above which can be termed subjective RPA is used

    in some applications.20Under this approach, standard option pricing formulas are used

    to value real options without identifying a market based replicate portfolio.21Although

    the valuation relies on the same assumptions as the Black-Scholes methodology, the

    option input parameters are not determined based on objective market information but

    on subjective estimates.

    18Dixit, A. K., Pindyck, R. S., (1994), p. 137.

    19

    Amram, M., Kulatilaka, N., (1999), pp. 52-54.20Luehrman, T., (1998a); Luehrman, T., (1998b); Luehrman, T., (1997); Howell, S., Stark, A., Newton,

    D., Paxon, D., Cavus, M., Pereira, J., Patel, K., (2001)21

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 20.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    11/23

    8

    Referring back to the example in chapter 2.1, option parameters such as the current

    market value of the undeveloped field (V) and its volatility () could simply be

    estimated by using average values of the Canadian oil industry as comparables.22The

    option (market) value would then be calculated by applying the standard Black-

    Scholes formula. Using financial option formulas to value real options without making

    an attempt to identify a replicating portfolio cannot lead to reliable valuation results.

    Because of its conceptual inconsistency, this approach fails at serving as a reliable

    investment decision support.

    3

    The Marketed Asset Disclaimer Approach (MAD)

    As described in chapter 2, identifying a replicating portfolio in order to determine the

    parameters of options on real assets (V, ) and valuing these options using standard

    option pricing formulas can be a very difficult task. To overcome this problem,

    Copeland and Antikarov (2003) propose the MAD approach which does not require a

    traded replicating portfolio. Rather the replicating portfolio is represented by the net

    present value (NPV) of the projects expected cash flows without managerial

    flexibility.23

    According to the MAD approach, a project could theoretically be traded as a security

    in capital markets and the NPV of a project without flexibility can therefore be used as

    a proxi for its market price. In the same way that the fundamental value of traded

    equities, i.e. the present value of its future cash flows, can be used as an estimate of its

    spot price, the NPV represents an estimate of the projectscurrent market value (V).

    According to MAD, the NPV of a project without flexibility is the best estimate of a

    replicating portfolio because in most cases, it unlikely to find securities in capital

    markets that have a higher correlation with the cash flows of a real asset than the asset

    22Borison, A., (2005a), p. 21.

    23Copeland, T., Antikarov, V., (2003), p. 94. See also Brando, L. E., Dyer, J. S., Hahn, W. J., (2005)

    for a similar approach.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    12/23

    9

    itself.24 Following this argumentation, a real option on a projects NPV is the best

    estimate of the market value of that option.25

    The underlying reasoning for the assumptions made in real options valuation under

    MAD refers to the fact that similar assumptions are made in standard discounted cash

    flow valuations (DCF) of corporate investments. As stated by Brealey and Myers

    (2006), any investment project is valued under the DCF approach as if it were a firm

    whose shares can be traded in capital markets.26 The required rate of return on a

    project and the appropriate discount rate are thereby determined based on the risk

    characteristics (beta) and expected returns of publicly traded securities. Accordingly,

    the value of a real option on the NPV should be a good estimate of the market value of

    the flexible project if it were traded.27 The application of the MAD approach is

    illustrated in the next section.

    3.1

    Application

    As a first step, the projects NPV is calculated in order to determine the current market

    value of the undeveloped field (V). Vrepresents the market value of the project without

    any flexibility. The NPV calculation is based on a single deterministic scenario

    regarding oil reserves, the start of production, production rates, oil prices and

    production costs. For the assessment of future oil prices, Copeland and Antikarov

    (2003) suggest using either historical data or subjective, forward-looking estimates by

    management.28The costs of acquiring the option are not considered. As an appropriate

    discount rate, the weighted average costs of capital (WACC) of oil firms, mainly

    investing in Canada, could be used.

    24Copeland, T., Antikarov, V., (2003), p. 133.

    25

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 22.26Brealey, R., Myers, S., (2006), p. 622.27

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 22.28

    Copeland, T., Antikarov, V., (2003), p. 215.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    13/23

    10

    NPV = V = - I0+ T

    t=1((Ptcofvt) xtCOFft) q-t+ L qT where (4)

    t= time index; T= last year of project; I0= initial investment outlay; P= sales price;

    cofv= variable cash outflows per unit; x= sales volume; COFf= fixed cash outflows;

    q= 1/(1+WACC) = discount factor; L = liquidation value.29

    After having calculated V, probability distributions for the key uncertainties, such as

    reserves and oil prices, can be defined and a simulation program be used to determine

    the volatility of project cash flows (). The call option, i.e. the flexible part of the

    investment project, can now either be valued using the standard Black-Scholes formula

    or, as suggested by Copeland and Antikarov (2003), using a risk-neutral binomial

    valuation model. The valuation process is summarised in Figure 1.30

    Figure 1: Option valuation in the binomial model

    Source: Author

    At first, the value development of the underlying and the NPV of the project is

    modelled. After the first year, the current value can either increase to V0uor decrease

    29Gtze, U., Northcott, D., Schuster, P., (2008), p. 56.

    30For a detailed description of the binomial valuation model see Brealey, R., Myers, S., (2006).

    V0u

    V0d

    V0u2

    V0ud

    V0u2

    t0 t1 t3

    C1 = max[V0u3-I3;0]

    C2 = max[V0u2d-I3;0]

    C3 = max[V0ud -I3;0]

    C4 = max[V0d -I3;0]

    V0

    CMV

    2,2

    CMV

    2,1

    CMV

    2,0

    CMV

    1,1

    CMV

    1,0

    CMV

    0

    t2 t0t1t2

    1. Modelling the

    underlying (NPV)2. Option value

    at expirry

    3. Recursive determi-

    nation of option value

    Vj = V0ujd

    n-j

    Ci = {prnCut+1 + (1-prn)C

    dt+1}(1+rf)

    -1

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    14/23

    11

    to V0d, with ued nT

    /1/

    .

    (4)

    The up- and down-factors reflect a value process that follows the Geometric Brownian

    motion.31On the date of expiration T, the call option is exercised if the value of the

    NPV (V) is greater than the cost for investing (I3). In order to determine the current

    option value (CMV) the binomial tree is solved in a recursive manner using risk-neutral

    probabilities (prnand 1-prn) and discounting at the risk-free rate (rf), with

    prn= (erfT/nd) / (ud). (5)

    In analogy to the RPA, the goal of real options valuation under the MAD approach is

    to maximise shareholder value and its output reflects the value created for the firms

    diversified investors.32The investment decision results in:

    If (V0 I0) max[CMV,0 C;0] 0, invest in field development today to maximise

    shareholder value.

    If (CMV,0C) max[V0 I0; 0] 0, invest in call option on the field (development

    right) to maximise shareholder value.

    If (C CMV 0) and (I0 V 0), do not invest at all because the option and the

    investment project are overpriced and shareholder value is destroyed.

    3.2 Critical assessment

    The description of the MAD approach in the previous section shows that, in contrast to

    the RPA, the resulting market values are not based on a traded replicating portfolio.

    The NPV as the current market value of the underlying (V0) as well as the option value

    (CMV,0) are not purely determined by objective market data but are largely dependent

    on subjective estimates of future cash flows. Market data is only used to calculate the

    31The same process in assumed in the Black-Scholes model. Alternatively, a different process could be

    defined.32

    Borison, A., (2005b), p. 53.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    15/23

    12

    equilibrium discount rate in the NPV model.33 V0 as the fundamental value of the

    undeveloped oil field can be interpreted as an estimate of its current equilibrium value.

    Although the correlation between the fundamental value and the fields capitalisation

    on the market might generally be high, the degree of correlation depends on a market

    premium which can be highly variable due to changing market sentiments.34

    Compared to the subjective RPA, the oil field investment and the development right

    are priced consistently so that the non-arbitrage condition between the investment and

    the option may be met. However, the MAD approach does not ensure that the

    investment and option are priced correctly relative to the market.35Therefore, arbitrage

    opportunities between the investment project under consideration and related traded

    investments may exist. The values of oil and gas investments are particularly sensitive

    to future commodity prices. Liquid commodity markets, in which oil and natural gas

    products are traded with different time horizons, provide information regarding these

    markets risks which could be incorporated into the option valuation process in order to

    avoid arbitrage opportunities. If market and subjective expectations regarding future

    commodity prices deviate, arbitrage opportunities are introduced.

    The values of the undeveloped oil field and the development right under the MAD

    approach are also highly dependent on the assumed value process of the underlying

    investment (V). The Geometric Brownian motion within the binomial valuation model

    may not accurately reflect the true development of the project value. Rather, the value

    could be driven by specific events at specific points in time, such as the discovery of

    larger reserves than expected or higher discovery factors than anticipated.36 The

    assumed price process should account for such an evolution of value.

    33

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 24.34Guj, P., (2010), p. 2.35

    Borison, A., (2005b), p. 53.36

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 24.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    16/23

    13

    4 The Hybrid Real Options Approach (HROA)

    The HROA explicitly distinguishes between two types of risks associated with most

    investment projects: Public risks (market risks), such as price risk, and private risks,

    i.e. project specific risks.37

    In comparison to the RPA, the HROA does not assume that

    capital markets are complete and a replicating portfolio can be found which perfectly

    hedges all project risks. Rather, financial markets are assumed to be partially

    complete.38Whereas public risks associated with an investment project can be hedged

    in any state of the world by trading in existing securities, private risks cannot be

    hedged by trading and have to be assessed by subjective judgement. In that sense,

    option pricing methods are used to value public risks and decision analysis methods

    are used to value private risks.39

    It becomes obvious that under the HROA, real options valuation differs considerably

    from financial options valuation and standard option pricing formulas cannot be

    applied. Investment projects which are characterised by managerial flexibility are

    valued using a risk-adjusted decision tree. Such a decision tree incorporates decision

    analysis and option pricing approaches.

    4.1 Application

    The risk adjusted decision tree shown in Figure 2 indicates the logic of the HROA. In

    t=0, the firm is faced with three decision alternatives. The undeveloped oil field can

    either be bought and the field be developed. The resulting value of the investment

    project depends on two uncertainties which is the price and the amount of oil.

    Alternatively, the firm can decide to purchase the development right and wait for the

    uncertainties to resolve over time. The uncertainty regarding the amount of oil resolves

    after year one, whereas the price of oil evolves incrementally over the time to

    37

    The HROA is described and applied in Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1998); Smith, J. E., McCardle,K. F., (1999) and Smith, J. E., Nau, R. F., (1995).38

    Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1999), p. 199.39

    Borison, A., (2005a), p. 27.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    17/23

    14

    expiration of the call option. In year T=3, the firm must decide to either exercise the

    option to purchase and develop the oil field or let the option expire and the third option

    is not to invest at all.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    18/23

    15

    Figure 2: Risk-adjusted decision tree in HROA

    Source: Author

    Decision node Amount of oil Price of oil End node

    No

    No

    Exercise option

    Exercise option

    No

    Exercise option

    Down

    Down

    Up

    Up

    Up

    High

    Down

    Down

    Up

    Up

    Up

    Down

    No

    Exercise option

    Low

    Buy option

    Up

    Low

    High

    Up

    No investment

    Up

    Down

    Down

    Base

    Base

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    Down

    Up

    Up

    Buy oil field

    Down

    Up

    Up

    DownDown

    Up

    Down

    Down

    Down

    t = 0 t = 1 t = 2 T = 3

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

    NPV(rf)

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    19/23

    16

    For the application of the HROA, the uncertainties associated with the undeveloped oil

    field have to be defined as public and private risks. The oil price can be defined as a

    public risk and the size of the reservoir is defined as a private risk. The private risk is

    by definition not correlated with any individual investment or portfolio of investments

    in financial markets.40For the private risk, a beta of zero can therefore be assumed. For

    the amount of gas, three scenarios are defined and subjective probabilities are assigned

    for each scenario. These subjective probabilities can be determined based on

    geological experiences.

    The public risk which can be replicated in capital markets is treated differently.41The

    price risk is modelled using a discrete binomial model in which the oil price can either

    make an up-movement with a risk-neutral probability of prnor a down-movement with

    1-prnin each time period (Figure 3). The binomial model is constructed using market

    information regarding annual volatilities and convenience yields from traded oil price

    options and futures.

    Figure 3: Binomial oil price model within HROA

    Source: Author

    At each end node of the risk-adjusted decision tree, a spreadsheet cash-flow model is

    used to calculate state-contingent NPVs depending on the amount of oil in the field

    40Borison, A., (2005a), p. 26.

    41Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1998), p. 201.

    OP1 u

    OP0

    OP1 d

    OP2 uu

    OP2 ud

    OP2 dd

    OP3 uuu

    OP3 uud

    OP3 udd

    OP3 ddd

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    20/23

    17

    and incorporating expectations of capital markets regarding the development of future

    oil prices. From the perspective of diversified shareholders, the cash flows can be

    discounted using the risk-free rate (rf) because public risks can be perfectly hedged and

    private risks are not correlated with traded securities (beta = 0).

    The values of the undeveloped oil field (VHROA) and the development right (CHROA) are

    finally found by applying the roll-back method to solve the decision tree. Starting at

    T=3, the value maximising decisions are made and the state contingent NPVs are

    multiplied with the respective risk-neutral or subjective probabilities and discounted at

    the risk-free rate. As under the approaches in chapters 2 and 3, the following

    investment decisions are made:

    If (VHROAI0)max[CHROAC;0] 0, invest in field development today to maximise

    shareholder value.

    If (CHROAC)max[VHROAI0; 0] 0, invest in call option on the field (development

    right) to maximise shareholder value.

    If (CCHROA0) and (I0VHROA0), do not invest at all because the option and the

    investment project are overpriced and shareholder value is destroyed.

    4.2 Critical Assessment

    The HROA explicitly decomposes the uncertainty associated with investment projects

    and addresses market risks and private risks separately. The assumption that oil and

    gas investment projects are characterised by risks that can be hedged in capital markets

    and risks that cannot be replicated seems realistic and allows the HROA to be applied

    in a very broad range of corporate investments. In particular, it enables decision

    makers to overcome the problem of finding a perfectly replicating portfolio and

    applying standard option pricing formulas when capital markets are assumed to be

    incomplete. By incorporating available market information, the valuation process also

    mitigates the problem of introducing arbitrage opportunities.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    21/23

    18

    From a practical perspective, the HROA can be problematic due to its high degree of

    complexity. When several uncertainties and time periods are incorporated into the

    project valuation, structuring the problem can be difficult and the resulting decision

    tree quickly becomes very large with several thousand end nodes.42

    5 Conclusion

    In this paper, real option approaches currently used to value oil and gas investment

    projects are categorised and described with regard to the assumptions made, the

    treatment of project uncertainty and the necessary calculations. The analysis reveals

    significant differences between the various approaches.

    Applying the RPA and using standard option pricing formulas is only justified if

    capital markets are complete and the underlying investment project can be perfectly

    replicated. With regard to real-world investment projects, the assumptions made under

    the RPA are restrictive and limit its applicability.

    The subjective RPA as well as the MAD approach also use standard option pricing

    formulas to value real options. Both approaches, however, do not attempt to identify a

    replicating portfolio of securities traded in capital markets. Rather, the approaches

    heavily rely on subjective estimates which do not ensure consistent and arbitrage-free

    valuation results.

    The HROA incorporates option pricing and decision analysis in order to meet the

    assumption that capital markets are only partially complete. Due to its less restrictive

    assumptions, the approach is applicable in a broader range of investment cases. The

    valuation process is, however, more complex than under the above approaches which

    can be a trade-off for decision makers.

    42Smith, J. E., McCardle, K. F., (1999), p. 3.

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    22/23

    19

    BIBLIOGRAPHY

    BOOKS

    Amram, Martha; Kulatilaka, Nalin, Real Options (Boston, MA: Harvard Business

    School Press, 1999).

    Brealey, Richard; Myers, Steward, Principles of Corporate FinanceTheory (8 th ed.)

    (Boston, MA: Irwing McGraw-Hill, 2006).

    Copeland, Tom; Antikarov, Vladimir, Real Options: A Practitioners Guide (New

    York: TEXERE 2003).

    Dixit, Avinash; Pindyck, Robert, Investment Under Uncertainty (Princeton, NJ:

    Princeton University Press, 1994).

    Gtze, Uwe; Northcott, Deryl; Schuster, Peter, Investment Appraisal (Berlin: Springer,

    2008).

    Howell, Sydney; Stark, Andrew; Newton, David; Paxon, Dean; Cavus, Mustafa;Pereira, Jose; Patel, Kanak, Real Options: Evaluating Corporate Investment

    Opportunities in a Dynamic World (London: Financial Times/Prentice Hall, 2001).

    Mun, Johnathan, Real Options Analysis (New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons, 2002).

    ARTICLES

    Brennan, Michael; Schwartz, Eduardo, Evaluating Natural Resource Investments, 58

    Journal of Business, 135-157 (1985).

    Borison, Adam,Real Options Valuation: Where Are the Emperors Clothes, 17 Journal

    of Applied Corporate Finance, 17-32 (2005a).

    Borison, Adam,A Response to Real Options: Meeting the Georgetown Challenge, 17

    Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 52-55 (2005b).

  • 8/11/2019 cepmlp_car15_33_772422950

    23/23

    20

    Brando, Luiz E.; Dyer, James S.; Hahn, Warren J., Using binomial trees to solve real-

    option valuation problems, 2 Decision Analysis, 69-88 (2005).

    Guj, Pietro,A Practical real option methodology for the evaluation of farm-in/out joint

    venture agreements in mineral exploration, 18 Resources Policy, 1-11 (2010).

    Luehrman, Timothy, Whats It Worth? A General Managers Guide to Valuation,

    May-June Harvard Business Review, 132-142 (1997).

    Luehrman, Timothy,Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started on the

    Numbers, July-August Harvard Business Review, 3-15 (1998a).

    Luehrman, Timothy, Strategy as a Portfolio of Real Options, September-October

    Harvard Business Review, 89-99 (1998b).

    Paddock, James L.; Siegel, Daniel R.; Smith, James L., Option Valuation of Claims on

    Real Assets: The Case of Offshore Petroleum Leases, 103 Quarterly Journal of

    Economics, 479-508 (1988).

    Smith, James E.; McCardle, Kevin F., Valuing Oil Properties: Integrating Option

    Pricing and Decision Analysis Approaches, 46 Operations Research, 198-217 (1998).

    Smith, James E.; McCardle, Kevin F., Options in the Real World: Lessons Learned in

    Evaluating Oil and Gas Investments, 47 Operations Research, 1-15 (1999).

    Smith, James E.; Nau, Robert F., Valuing Risky Projects: Option Pricing Theory and

    Decision Analysis, 14 Management Science, 795-816 (1995).

    Trigeorgis, Lenos, Real Options: A Primer, in The New Investment Theory of Real

    Options and Its Application for Telecommunications Economics 14 (J. Alleman, E.

    Noam, ed., Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1999).

    Trigeorgis, Lenos; Mason, Scott P., Valuing Managerial Flexibility, 5 Midland

    Corporate Finance Journal, 14-21 (1987).