+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

Date post: 02-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: wayne-evans
View: 222 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 84

Transcript
  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    1/84

    1

    Chapter 5: Long-Run Economic Growth

    After reading this chapter, you should be able to:

    5.1 Discuss the connection between labor productivity and the standard of living (pages xx)

    5.2 Use the Solow Growth Model to Explain the Effect of Capital Accumulation on Labor

    Productivity (pages xx)

    5.3 Explain how total factor productivity affects labor productivity (pages xx)

    5.4 Explain the balanced growth path and convergence and the long-run equilibrium (pages x

    x)

    Chapter Opener: Labor Productivity and the Standard of Living in China and the United

    States

    In 2008 China had a population of 1.3 billion people and its economy employed 772.8 million

    workers while the United States has a population of just 301.3 million people and the U.S.

    economy employs 156.3 million workers. Given these differences in population and growth

    rates of real GDP, you might conclude that China had a much larger economy and a higher

    standard of living than the United States. However, the opposite is true; the standard of living

    was 5.5 times higher in the United States than China. How was this possible? The average

    worker in the United States produced 6.4 times as many goods and services than the average

    worker in China. Productivity is the key to understanding the standard of living. Understanding

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    2/84

    2

    why these productivity differences exist is the key to understanding why the standard of living

    varies across countries.

    Even though the standard of living is higher in the United States, the Chinese economy has

    been growing much more rapidly than the U.S. economy. The growth rate of real GDP in China

    has averaged 8.5 percent per year from 1980 to 2008 while the growth rate of real GDP in the

    United States has averaged just 2.9 percent over the same time period. Furthermore, the Chinese

    Premier Wen Jiabao on March 5, 2010 reaffirmed his countrys commitment to achieve 8 percent

    real GDP growth for 2010 and China is expected to aim for similarly high growth rates in the

    future. The rapid Chinese growth rates mean that the Chinese economy is growing larger

    relative to the U.S. economy. However, as we just saw the standard of living is still higher in the

    United States than in China.

    SOURCE: Penn World Tables. Poon, Terrence; Back, Aaron; and Wu, J.R. China Economy

    Still Needs Support, Wall Street Journal, March 5, 2010.

    An Inside Look [or An Inside Look at Policy] on page xx explores.

    Big Question for This Chapter:

    In Chapter 1, we introduced 10 big questions in macroeconomics. Here are the big questions we

    return to in this chapter:

    Big Question 1: Why has the standard of living increased over the last two hundred years?

    Big Question 2: Why have some countries failed to achieve sustained economic growth?

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    3/84

    3

    We start by explaining the connection between labor productivity and the standard of living.

    As you read this chapter, see if you can answer these questions. You can check your answers

    against those we provide at the end of the chapter.

    Continued on page xx

    [Transition statement]

    In Chapter 4, we learned that capital per worker hour and Total Factor Productivity (TFP) are the

    key determinants of potential real GDP per worker hour. In this chapter, we explain the

    determinants of capital per worker hour and total factor productivity. Real GDP per worker hour

    is important because both potential real GDP and potential real GDP per worker hour are closely

    tied to labor productivity.

    [End transition statement]

    5.1 Discuss the Connection between Labor Productivity and the Standard of Living

    The circular flow diagram in Figure 2-1 showed us that real GDP equals the income

    generated in an economy. So, real GDP per person is a measure of both the income available to

    the average person in the country and how many goods and services the average person can

    purchase. Economists assume that people are rational and purchase goods and services that

    make themselves better off. For example, if you are hungry then you buy food. If you are cold,

    then you buy shelter. As your income increases, you use the extra income to purchase goods and

    services that make you better off. For this reason, economists often use real GDP per person as a

    measure of the standard of living.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    4/84

    4

    Figure 5-1 shows real GDP per person from 1820 to 2008 for several countries and

    Figure 5-1 Real GDP per Person, 1820-2008

    SOURCE: Angus Maddison. Data available at:http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/ .

    Caption:The levels of real GDP per person varied significantly in 1820 with Africa at $420 per

    person and the United Kingdom at $1,706. However, the relative rankings of countries by real

    GDP per person have changed because the growth rates of real GDP per person have varied. For

    example, the growth rate of real GDP per person averaged just 0.8 percent per year in Africa.

    This is an extremely low growth rate and in 2008 real GDP per person was just $1,780 in Africa.

    Some African countries such as Malawi, Niger, and Zambia still have real GDP per persons of

    http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/
  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    5/84

    5

    $744, $514, and $845. For all intents and purposes, growth has not come to many countries in

    Africa. In contrast, Japans growth rate averaged 1.9 percent per year so real GDP per person in

    Japan rose from $669 in 1820 to $22,816 in 2008. Real GDP per person in China was stagnant

    until the 1970s and then accelerated rapidly from essentially zero percent to over eight percent

    per year. As a result, of these differences in growth rates, the relative rankings of regions by real

    GDP per person have also changed. In 1820, the United Kingdom had the highest real GDP per

    person, but now the United States has a higher and Japan has the same real GDP per person.

    End Caption

    regions around the world. The levels of real GDP per person varied significantly in 1820 with

    Africa at $420 per person and the United Kingdom at $1,706. However, the relative rankings of

    countries by real GDP per person have changed because the growth rates of real GDP per person

    have varied. For example, the growth rate of real GDP per person averaged just 0.8 percent per

    year in Africa. This is an extremely low growth rate and in 2008 real GDP per person was just

    $1,780 in Africa. Some African countries such as Malawi, Niger, and Zambia still have real

    GDP per persons of $744, $514, and $845. For all intents and purposes, growth has not come to

    many countries in Africa. In contrast, Japans growth rate averaged 1.9 percent per year so real

    GDP per person in Japan rose from $669 in 1820 to $22,816 in 2008. Real GDP per person in

    China was stagnant until the 1970s and then accelerated rapidly from essentially zero percent to

    over eight percent per year. As a result, of these differences in growth rates, the relative rankings

    of regions by real GDP per person have also changed. In 1820, the United Kingdom had the

    highest real GDP per person, but now the United States has a higher and Japan has the same real

    GDP per person.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    6/84

    6

    The standard of living is related to labor productivity through the following equation:

    (5.1)

    ,

    so the standard of living equals labor productivity, , times labor input,

    .

    Both labor productivity and labor inputs influence the standard of living, but the most important

    determinant of the standard of living is labor productivity. Even if every man, woman, and child

    in a country worked 24 hours a day 365 days a year, each person can work no more than 8,760

    hours per year because people need sleep and eat, children go to school, and older people retire.

    Although there is a clear limit to how much the labor input can increase real GDP per person,

    there is no limit to labor productivityas long as productivity increases, real GDP per person

    can also increase. Once we have explained labor productivity, we have explained most of real

    GDP per person and the standard of living.

    Labor productivity rose from $13.47 per worker hour in 1949 to $47.26 per worker hour

    in 2008, but labor inputs actually decreased somewhat from 837.3 hours per person in 1949 to

    830.0 hours per person in 2008 for reasons that we will discuss in Chapter 7. The decrease in

    labor inputs should reduce the potential real GDP per person. So, the entire increase in potential

    real GDP per person is due to increased productivity. We can use equation (5.1) to calculate

    what potential real GDP per person would have been if labor productivity had remained at 1949

    levels and if labor inputs had remained at 1949 levels. Figure 5-2 shows these two series along

    with the actual level of potential real GDP

    Figure 5-2 Influence of Labor Productivity and Labor Inputs on Real GDP per Person,

    1949 - 2008

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    7/84

    7

    SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of the Census, and Congressional Budget

    Office.

    Caption:The blue line represents potential real GDP per person, the green line represents real

    GDP per person if hours per person remained at 1949 levels, and the red line represents potential

    real GDP per person if labor productivity remained at 1949 levels. If labor productivity remains

    constant at the 1949 level, then potential real GDP per person barely changes and is just $11,177

    by 2007. However, if labor inputs remain constant at the 1949 level, then potential real GDP per

    person rises all the way to $39,574 by 2007. Clearly, labor productivity is the main determinant

    of the increase in potential real GDP per person.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    8/84

    8

    End Caption

    per person. The blue line represents potential real GDP per person, the green line represents real

    GDP per person if hours per person remained at 1949 levels, and the red line represents potential

    real GDP per person if labor productivity remained at 1949 levels. If labor productivity remains

    constant at the 1949 level, then potential real GDP per person barely changes and is just $11,177

    by 2007. However, if labor inputs remain constant at the 1949 level, then potential real GDP per

    person rises all the way to $39,574 by 2007. Clearly, labor productivity is the main determinant

    of the increase in potential real GDP per person.

    Problems with Real GDP per person as a Measure of the Standard of Living

    Real GDP per person is not a perfect measure of the standard of living, but it is likely the

    best measure that we have. As long as people use their income to purchase goods and services

    that make them better off, then the standard of living should increase with real GDP per person.

    Nevertheless, there are several objections to using real GDP per person as a measure of the

    standard of living that we consider in more detail:

    Distribution of income

    Value of leisure time

    Happiness

    Life Expectancy

    Distribution of Income

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    9/84

    9

    Real GDP per person is just an averageit tells you what the average person in the

    economy can consume. However, an average can be misleading because it does not tell you

    about the distributionof income. Table 5-2 illustrates this problem using an example of two

    people in two countries.

    Table 5-2 Income Distribution and Real GDP per Person

    Country 1 Country 2

    Person 1 $50,000 $99,000

    Person 2 $50,000 $1,000

    GDP per Person $50,000 $50,000

    In country 1, each person earns exactly $50,000 so GDP per person is $50,000 and tells you how

    many goods and services the typical person can consume. In this case, real GDP per person is a

    very good measure of the standard of living for the typical person. However, this approximation

    is not very good for country 2. In country 2, person 1 has an income of $99,000, and person 2

    has an income of just $1,000. GDP per person is still $50,000, but person 1 can consume much

    more than that amount and person 2 can consume much less. Person 1 has a higher standard of

    living and person 2 has a lower standard of living than GDP per person indicates.

    Uneven distribution of income is important to keep in mind when using GDP per person

    as a measure of the standard of living for the typical person. However, also keep in mind that

    two analyses suggest that increases in real GDP per person make the poor better off. First, as

    real GDP per person for the world rose by 1.8 percent per year from 1981 to 2005, the number of

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    10/84

    10

    people living on less than $1.25 per day fell from 1.9 billion in 1981 to 1.4 billion in 2005.1 That

    represents a 26 percent decrease in the number of extremely poor individuals in just 24 years.

    Even if economic growth did not cause the decrease in poverty, economic growth and substantial

    decreases in poverty are compatible. Second, if all the gains from economic growth went to only

    those individuals at the top of the income distribution, then increases in GDP per person would

    have little benefit for those at the bottom of the income distribution. However, there is some

    evidence that the poor do benefit from economic growth just as much as the rest of society.

    David Dollar and Aart Kraay, economists with the World Bank, found that as real GDP per

    person increased by about one percent, the income of the individuals in the bottom 20 percent of

    the income distribution also increased by one percent.2 As an economy grows, there is a

    tendency for the incomes of the individuals in the bottom of the income distribution to rise.

    Therefore, the rich do not get richer at the expense of the poor. Figure 5-3 shows the relationship

    between the

    Figure 5-3 Relationship between Real GDP per Person and Average Income of Individuals

    in the Lower 20 Percent of the Income Distribution

    1Data come from the World Banks PovcalNet and are available at

    http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROG

    RAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~pi

    PK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.html . Data downloaded on May 6, 2009.

    2Growth is Good for the Poor,Journal of Economic Growthvol.7, no.3, (2002) pp.195-225.

    http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.htmlhttp://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.htmlhttp://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.htmlhttp://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.htmlhttp://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.htmlhttp://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.htmlhttp://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXTPROGRAMS/EXTPOVRES/EXTPOVCALNET/0,,contentMDK:21867101~pagePK:64168427~piPK:64168435~theSitePK:5280443,00.html
  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    11/84

    11

    SOURCE: Dollar and Kraay (2002). Data is available on the web at:http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/0,,contentMDK:20311740~pagePK:

    64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469372,00.html#Growth__inequality_and_poverty

    Caption:As real GDP per person increases, the average income for individuals in the bottom 20

    percent of the income distribution also increases. On average, when real GDP per person

    increases by one percentage point, the average income for individuals in the bottom 20 percent of

    the income distribution also increases by about one percentage point. Therefore, there is no

    tendency for inequality to increase as real GDP per person increases. We see a similar pattern

    when we look at individual countries and regions such as Africa, China, Japan, the United

    Kingdom and the United States.

    http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/0,,contentMDK:20311740~pagePK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469372,00.html#Growth__inequality_and_povertyhttp://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/0,,contentMDK:20311740~pagePK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469372,00.html#Growth__inequality_and_povertyhttp://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/0,,contentMDK:20311740~pagePK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469372,00.html#Growth__inequality_and_povertyhttp://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/0,,contentMDK:20311740~pagePK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469372,00.html#Growth__inequality_and_povertyhttp://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/0,,contentMDK:20311740~pagePK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469372,00.html#Growth__inequality_and_poverty
  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    12/84

    12

    End Caption

    real GDP per person and average income for the bottom 20 percent of the income distribution.

    As real GDP per person increases, the average income for individuals in the bottom 20 percent of

    the income distribution also increases. On average, when real GDP per person increases by one

    percentage point, the average income for individuals in the bottom 20 percent of the income

    distribution also increases by about one percentage point. Therefore, there is no tendency for

    inequality to increase as real GDP per person increases. We see a similar pattern when we look

    at individual countries and regions such as Africa, China, Japan, the United Kingdom and the

    United States.

    Value of Leisure Time

    Because real GDP per person measures the income of the average person in a country, it

    tells us how many goods and services the average person can consume. But people care about

    more than the goods and services they can purchase. For example, people want time to spend

    with their friends, their spouses, or their children. In other words, individuals also care about

    leisure time. If the large increases in the standard of living shown in Figure 5-1 came solely

    from increases in labor inputs, then the increase in real GDP per person would have come at the

    expense of less leisure time. Whether individuals are better off would therefore depend on the

    value of the lost leisure time relative to the value of the goods and services that individuals

    gained.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    13/84

    13

    As we saw earlier, all of the increase in potential real GDP per person has come from

    increased productivity and average annual hours worked per person has remained essentially

    constant for the United States. Figure 5-4 shows average annual

    Figure 5-4 Annual Average Hours per worker hour in Western Countries, 1870 - 2000

    SOURCE: Huberman and Minns (2007).

    Caption:As real GDP per person has increased, annual average hours per worker hour tends to

    decrease. So, leisure time tends to rise as real GDP per person increases. Hours per year for the

    average worker in the United States decreased from 3,096 hours per year in 1870 to 1,878 hours

    per year in 2000. That is, a 39.3 percent decrease in the amount of time working and a

    significant amount of extra time available for leisure activities such as being with friends and

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    14/84

    14

    family. All western nations experienced a similar decrease in average hours per worker hour.

    For example, hours per year for the average worker in France decreased from 3,168 in 1870 to

    1,443 in 2000. The decrease in hours worked was larger outside of the United States, but

    average annual hours worked did decrease in the United States for reasons that we will explain in

    Chapter 7.

    End Caption

    hours of work per worker hour for several western countries: France, Germany, Italy, the United

    Kingdom, and the United States. Hours per year for the average worker in the United States

    decreased from 3,096 hours per year in 1870 to 1,878 hours per year in 2000. That is, a 39.3

    percent decrease in the amount of time working and a significant amount of extra time available

    for leisure activities such as being with friends and family. All western nations experienced a

    similar decrease in average hours per worker hour. For example, hours per year for the average

    worker in France decreased from 3,168 in 1870 to 1,443 in 2000. The decrease in hours worked

    was larger outside of the United States, but average annual hours worked did decrease in the

    United States for reasons that we will explain in Chapter 7.

    Happiness

    Richard Easterlin of the University of Pennsylvania looks at results from nineteen

    different countries and concludes that there is little relationship between self-reported happiness

    in surveys and real GDP per person across countries or within a country.3 This lack of

    3Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence, (1974) In Nations and Households

    in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramowitz edited by Paul David and Melvin Reder. Academic

    Press.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    15/84

    15

    correlation is called theEasterlin Paradoxbecause happiness does not necessarily increase with

    incomes. Why the lack of relationship? Easterlin argues that individuals judge themselves

    relative to their peer groups. Therefore, if your income increases by 10 percent, but the income

    of all your peers also increases by 10 percent then you will not report yourself as any happier

    because you have not improved relative to your peers. However, if your income increases by 10

    percent while everyone elses income remains constant then you have improved relative to your

    peers so you will report yourself as happier.4 Because the increased real GDP per person does

    not lead to increased happiness, Easterlin argues that economists and policymakers place too

    much emphasis on economic growth. Richard Layard of the London School of Economics notes

    that at low levels of real GDP per person an increase in income does lead to increased

    happiness.5 However, he also argues that there is little relationship between average income and

    happiness once real GDP per person exceeds $15,000 per year. At low levels of income,

    economic growth produces vital goods and services like food, shelter, and clothing. However,

    once these basic necessities are met economic growth tends to produce luxuries that do not

    necessarily make individuals better off. For example, investment bankers and lawyers often

    work long hours and neglect their personal lives. They have little time to interact with spouses,

    children, or friends. In this example, the extra goods and services may come at the cost of less

    fulfilling personal lives. Once individuals reach a certain level of income, they begin to make

    judgments about their happiness based on their income relative to their peers rather than their

    absolute level of income. Therefore, an increase in income will not make a person happier if

    4Will Raising the Incomes of All Increase the Happiness of All?Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization

    (1995) pp.35-47.

    5Happiness: Has Social Science a Clue? Lionel Robbins Memorial Lecture 2002/2003, London School of

    Economics. Available at:http://cep.lse.ac.uk/events/lectures/layard/RL030303.pdf.

    http://cep.lse.ac.uk/events/lectures/layard/RL030303.pdfhttp://cep.lse.ac.uk/events/lectures/layard/RL030303.pdfhttp://cep.lse.ac.uk/events/lectures/layard/RL030303.pdfhttp://cep.lse.ac.uk/events/lectures/layard/RL030303.pdf
  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    16/84

    16

    everyone elses income increases by just as much. Absolute income is no longer important, but

    relative income is important.

    The Easterlin Paradox shows that money cannot buy happiness as the saying goes. Or

    does it? Justin Wolfers and Betsey Stevenson of the Wharton School at the University of

    Pennsylvania reexamined this issue using a wider range of countries.6 They find a robust

    positive relationship between self-reported happiness and GDP per person across 131 countries.

    In addition, Wolfers and Stevenson also find a positive relationship between economic growth

    and happiness within a country. Their work suggests that economic growth and higher absolute

    levels of income do make individuals happier.

    Life Expectancy

    Modern economic growth generates pollution. Consumers create air pollution by burning

    gasoline to power their cars and natural gas to heat their homes. Firms create air pollution when

    they produce electricity, pesticides, or plastics. This pollution affects the air we breathe, the

    water we drink, and the food we eat. Sometimes pollution is a minor irritant that spoils scenic

    views, but pollution can also contribute to dangerous diseases such as cancer. In addition, busy

    workers have less leisure time, which can create stress and negative health consequences,

    potentially shortening life spans. Therefore, the costs to higher real GDP per person might offset

    the benefits of the increase in the amount of goods and services that individuals can purchase.

    Does life expectancy decrease with real GDP per person? No. In fact, as real GDP per person

    6Economic Growth and Subjective Well-Being: Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox in Brookings Paper on Economic

    Activity (Spring 2008), 1-102.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    17/84

    17

    increases, life expectancy at birth increases suggesting that health outcomes actually improve as

    real GDP per person increases. Figure 5-5 shows the relationship

    Figure 5-5 Relationship between Real GDP per Person and Life Expectancy at

    Birth, 2007

    SOURCE: World Banks World Development Indicators

    Caption:There is a clear tendency for life expectancy to increase as GDP per person increases.

    When real GDP per person is $5,000 the life expectancy is 66.9 years and this rises to 74.1 years

    as real GDP per person increases to $15,000. However, if real GDP per person increases by

    another ten thousand dollars to $25,000 then life expectancy only increases to 77.4. Therefore,

    life expectancy increases at a decreasing rate with real GDP per person. Despite the pollution

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    18/84

    18

    costs associated with economic growth, the higher real GDP per person the longer the average

    person can expect to live.

    End Caption

    between life expectancy at birth and GDP per person for 185 countries in 2007. There is a clear

    tendency for life expectancy to increase as GDP per person increases. When real GDP per

    person is $5,000 the life expectancy is 66.9 years and this rises to 74.1 years as real GDP per

    person increases to $15,000. However, if real GDP per person increases by another ten

    thousand dollars to $25,000 then life expectancy only increases to 77.4. Therefore, life

    expectancy increases at a decreasing rate with real GDP per person. Despite the pollution costs

    associated with economic growth, the higher real GDP per person the longer the average person

    can expect to live.

    Part of the reason that pollution costs do not shorten life spans as real GDP per person

    increases is that a clean environment is a normal good, which means that individuals purchase

    more of it as their incomes increase. This idea lies behind the environmental Kuznets curve. The

    relationship depicted by the curve states that as an economy expands, pollution initially

    increases, reaches a maximum, and then begins to decline as individuals choose to spend more of

    their income on a cleaner environment. Therefore, rather than destroying the environment and

    reducing life expectancy, economic growth may improvethe environment and increase life

    expectancy. As real GDP per person increases, individuals can also purchase more health care

    which should also increase life expectancy.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    19/84

    19

    5.2 Use the Solow Growth Model to Explain the Effect of Capital Accumulation onLabor

    Productivity

    Labor productivity is the key determinant of real GDP per person and, therefore, the standard of

    living. In Chapter 4, we learned that capital accumulation and total factor productivity (TFP) are

    the primary determinants of the labor productivity. Therefore, if we want to understand why the

    standard of living increases over time, we need to understand capital accumulation and the

    determinants of total factor productivity. In this section, we discuss capital accumulation and

    assume that total factor productivity remains constant. Economists use the Solow growth model

    to explain how capital accumulation influences labor productivity. The model is named after

    Nobel Laureate Robert Solow of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology who developed the

    model during the 1950s.7 His work and this model has become the foundation for how

    economists think about economic growth. We work with the intensive form of the aggregate

    production function that we described in Chapter 4, in whichyis potential real GDP per worker

    hour and kis capital per worker hour. Economists also call kthe capital-labor ratio. As we saw

    in Chapter 4, potential real GDP per worker hour and the capital-labor ratio are related through

    the aggregate production function:

    (5.2)

    where is capitals share of income andAis total factor productivity. We learned in Chapter 4

    that for the United States capitals share ofincome equals 0.32 and that total factor productivity

    in 2007 was 9.4. Figure 5-6 shows:

    7Solow, Robert. A Contribution to theTheory of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, (February

    1956) pp.65-94.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    20/84

    20

    Figure 5-6 The Aggregate Production Function for the United States, 2007

    Caption:The capital-labor ratio for the United States was $144.94 per hour in 2007, and

    potential real GDP per worker hour was $46.36 per hour. The production function shows us

    what happens to labor productivity as the capital-labor ratio increases while keeping total factor

    productivity constant. If the capital-labor ratio increases to $174.94 per hour, then labor

    productivity increases to $49.24. The marginal product of the extra capital is $2.88 per hour. If

    the capital-labor ratio increases again by $30 to $204.94 per hour, then labor productivity also

    increases to $51.79 per hour. The marginal product of the extra capital is still positive but

    decreases to $2.56 per hour. Why does the marginal product of capital decrease? The marginal

    product of capital decreases due to diminishing marginal returns when total factor productivity is

    constant, so the contribution of capital accumulation to labor productivity growth eventually

    becomes zero. The fact that capital experiences diminishing marginal returns means that the

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    21/84

    21

    sustained increase in labor productivity and the standard of living that the United States and

    other countries have experienced must be due to factors other than capital accumulation such as

    total factor productivity growth. We will return to this issue later in the chapter.

    End Caption

    the aggregate production function for the United States. The capital-labor ratio for the United

    States was $144.94 per hour in 2007, and potential real GDP per worker hour was $46.36 per

    hour. The production function shows us what happens to labor productivity as the capital-labor

    ratio increases while keeping total factor productivity constant. If the capital-labor ratio

    increases to $174.94 per hour, then labor productivity increases to $49.24. The marginal

    product of the extra capital is $2.88 per hour. If the capital-labor ratio increases again by $30 to

    $204.94 per hour, then labor productivity also increases to $51.79 per hour. The marginal

    product of the extra capital is still positive but decreases to $2.56 per hour. Why does the

    marginal product of capital decrease? The marginal product of capital decreases due to

    diminishing marginal returns when total factor productivity is constant, so the contribution of

    capital accumulation to labor productivity growth eventually becomes zero. The fact that capital

    experiences diminishing marginal returns means that the sustained increase in labor productivity

    and the standard of living that the United States and other countries have experienced must be

    due to factors other than capital accumulation such as total factor productivity growth. We will

    return to this issue later in the chapter.

    Capital Accumulation and the Bath Tub Analogy

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    22/84

    22

    Labor productivity is the critical determinant of the standard of living. We learned in

    Chapter 4 that 41.7 percent of the labor productivity growth is due to capital accumulation. The

    Solow growth model helps explain capital accumulation. If you understand a bath tub, then you

    understand the essential elements of this model. Figure 5-7 shows a bath tub with water flowing

    into the tub through the faucet

    Figure 5-7 Capital Accumulation and the Bath Tub Analogy

    Caption:Understanding the basics of capital accumulation are as simple as understanding why

    the level of water rises and falls in a bath tub. Investment per worker hour is the water flowing

    into the bath tub and the amount of investment necessary to keep the capital-labor ratio constant

    is water flowing out of the bath tub. The level of water in the bath tub is the capital-labor ratio.

    End Caption

    and water flowing out of the bath tub through the drain. The level of water is a stock variable

    because we measure it at a point in time, while the water flowing into and flowing out of the tub

    Water flowing into the bath tub

    Water flowing out of the bath tu

    Level of water in the bath tub

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    23/84

    23

    are flow variables that are measuredper time period. When is the level of water in the bath tub

    constant? The answer is simple. The level of the water in the tub is constant when the water

    flowing into the bath tub is exactly equal to the water flowing out of the bath tub. How does the

    level of water in the tub change? The level of water in the tub increases when the water flowing

    into the tub is greater than the water flowing out of the tub, and the level of water in the tub

    decreases when the water flowing out of the tub is greater than the water flowing into the tub.

    To apply the bath tub analogy to labor productivity, we just need to identify the stock and

    flow variables in the Solow growth model. The capital-labor ratio is the stock variable because

    we measure it at a point in time as the amount of capital goods per worker. As a reminder, the

    capital-labor ratio is defined as:

    ,

    whereKis the stock of capital goods andLis the labor force. The capital-labor ratio can change

    for one two reasons: either the capital stock changes or labor force changes.

    Investment and Water Flowing into the Bath Tub

    The level of water in the bath tub increases when water flows into the tub, but what

    causes the capital-labor ratio to increase? The capital-labor ratio increases when the stock of

    machines, tools, buildings, and roads increases. In other words, when households, firms, or the

    government purchase investment goods. For simplicity, we assume that the investment rate of

    for the economy,s, is a constant ratio between zero and one. Investment per worker hour, i,

    equals:

    (5.3) .

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    24/84

    24

    Figure 5-8 shows the investment rate for the United States from 1949 to 2008. During this

    Figure 5-8 The Investment Rate for the United States, 1949 - 2008

    SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis and Congressional Budget Office

    Caption:the private sector conducts the vast majority of investment activity in the United

    States. From 1949 to 2008, private sector investment averaged 16.0 percent of potential GDP

    while government investment averaged just 4.1 percent of potential real GDP. You should also

    notice a distinct decrease in the rate of government investment after the 1960s, from 6.5 percent

    in 1953 to 3.4 percent in 2008.

    End Caption

    period, the investment rate averaged 0.201 of potential GDP, so:

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    25/84

    25

    i= 0.201y

    for the United States. Figure 5-9 shows that the private sector conducts the vast majority of

    investment activity in the United States. From 1949 to 2008, private sector investment averaged

    16.0 percent of potential GDP while government investment averaged just 4.1 percent of

    potential real GDP. You should also notice a distinct decrease in the rate of government

    investment after the 1960s, from 6.5 percent in 1953 to 3.4 percent in 2008. Remember that

    , so:

    , and

    for the United States,

    .

    Figure 5-9 shows how investment per worker hour changes as the capital-labor ratio increases.

    Figure 5-9 Investment per worker hour, Real GDP per worker hour, and the Capital-

    Labor Ratio

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    26/84

    26

    Caption:Notice that the investment function has the same general shape as the production

    function from Figure 4.6 (a) in Chapter 4. This similarity occurs because we have assumed a

    constant investment rate for the economy. Therefore, as the capital-labor ratio increases real

    GDP per worker hour also increases and that causes investment per worker hour to increase.

    However, because of diminishing marginal returns, the increase in investment per worker hour

    gets smaller and smaller as the capital-labor ratio increases.

    End Caption

    Notice that the investment function has the same general shape as the production function from

    Figure 4.6 (a) in Chapter 4. This similarity occurs because we have assumed a constant

    investment rate for the economy. Therefore, as the capital-labor ratio increases real GDP per

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    27/84

    27

    worker hour also increases and that causes investment per worker hour to increase. However,

    because of diminishing marginal returns, the increase in investment per worker hour gets smaller

    and smaller as the capital-labor ratio increases.

    The Role of the Financial Sector in Capital Accumulation

    Capital accumulation plays an important role in explaining labor productivity. But how

    do households, firms, and the government finance the purchase of new capital goods? This

    question highlights the importance of the financial sector because investment is often financed

    by funds obtained in financial markets. If Ford wants to build a new factory in the United States,

    then it is likely to obtain the funds in financial market by either borrowing or issuing new stock.

    Where do financial markets obtain the funds to finance Fords investment? Other individuals in

    the household, government, and foreign sectors have decided to save. When you save by putting

    some of your income in a savings account, this saving allows the bank to lend those funds toa

    household or a firm, like Ford, that wants to invest. Therefore, a well functioning financial

    market is essential for allowing households, firms, and the government to finance the investment

    expenditures that lead to higher labor productivity.

    Investment is the purchase of capital goods by households and firms, , and thegovernment, . Therefore, the total amount of capital goods purchased in aneconomy,I, is:

    .

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    28/84

    28

    The funds for purchasing these investment goods come from private savings, ,government savings, , and foreign sector savings, . Therefore, nationalsavings, S, is:

    .

    Private saving equals household disposable income minus consumption expenditures. Therefore,

    a tax increase, a decrease in income, or an increase in consumption all lead to less private

    savings. If government saving is positive then the government runs a budget surplus, but if

    government saving is negative then the government runs a budget deficit. A budget surplus, like

    the United States had in the late 1990s, leads to higher national saving, all else equal. In

    contrast, the large budget deficits that the government expects to run from 2010 to 2019 means

    that national saving is lower. Foreign sector saving is the sum of saving by foreign households

    and foreign governments. When individuals in these sectors save, then there is a larger pool of

    funds available to finance investment expenditures.

    When we discussed the loanable funds model in Chapter 3, we learned that saving equals

    investment, so:

    ,

    and

    .

    The results here are very similar to the results with the loanable funds model in Chapter 3. A

    budget deficit means government savings becomes negative. Unless private or foreign savings

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    29/84

    29

    increases to compensate, investment expenditures must decrease. Whether the budget deficit

    causes private or government investment expenditures to decrease depends on the circumstances.

    Similarly, if the household sector saves more and government and foreign savings remain

    constant, then investment expenditures must increase. Again, whether private or government

    investment expenditures increase depends on the circumstances.

    Break-Even Investment and Water Flowing out of the Bath Tub

    Break-even investmentis the level of investment necessary to keep the capital-labor ratio

    constant. When investment is greater than the break-even level, the capital-labor ratio increases

    and when investment is less than the break-even level, the capital-labor ratio decreases. Two

    factors determine the break-even level of investment. First, the capital stock depreciates over

    time. We assume that the depreciation rate, d, is a constant fraction of the capital-labor ratio and

    that the depreciation rate is between zero and one, so:

    .

    Second, the capital-labor ratio can decrease when the capital stock is constant and the number of

    workers increases. The capital-labor ratio decreases because the existing capital stock is spread

    across a larger labor force. You can think of this as the dilution of the existing capital stock. We

    use nto represent the growth rate of the labor force and ntakes a value between zero and one, so:

    .

    Therefore, we can think of break-even investment as:

    (5.4)

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    30/84

    30

    .

    Notice that break-even investment is just a constant fraction of the capital-labor ratio, so at

    higher levels of the capital-labor ratio the break-even investment is higher. For the United

    States, the growth rate of potential labor hours has averaged 1.2 percent or 0.012 per year from

    1949 - 2008. The depreciation rate depends on the type of capital good. For example, buildings

    can last for decades while computers may only be useful for a few years so computers depreciate

    much more quickly than buildings. However, a depreciation rate of 10 percent or 0.10 is a

    common value to use. Hence, break-even investment for the United States is:

    Break-Even Investment= (0.10 + 0.012)k= 0.112k.

    When we graph the break-even investment line in Figure 5-10, we see that it is a straight line

    with

    Figure 5-10 Break-Even Investment and the Capital-Labor Ratio

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    31/84

    31

    Caption: The break-even investment line has a slope equal to the sum of the depreciation rate

    and the labor force growth rate. At higher levels of the capital-labor ratio, more investment is

    required to keep the capital-labor ratio constant, so the break-even level of investment is also

    higher. An increase in the depreciation or labor force growth rates leads to a steeper break-even

    investment line, while a decrease in the depreciation rate or labor force growth rates leads to a

    flatter break-even investment line.

    End Caption

    a positive slope equal to (d+ n); at higher levels of the capital-labor ratio, more investment is

    required to keep the capital-labor ratio constant, so the break-even level of investment is also

    higher. An increase in the depreciation or labor force growth rates leads to a steeper break-even

    investment line, while a decrease in the depreciation rate or labor force growth rates leads to a

    flatter break-even investment line.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    32/84

    32

    Equilibrium and the Steady State

    The change in the level of water in the bath tub equals the water flowing into the bath tub

    minus the water flowing out of the bath tub. For the level of water in the bath tub to remain

    constant, the water flowing into the tub must equal the water flowing out of the tub. Think of

    this as the equilibrium for the bath tub. In terms of the Solow growth model, the level of water is

    the capital-labor ratio so equilibrium occurs when the capital-labor ratio is constant. Economists

    call this equilibrium asteady state. A steady stateis an equilibrium in which the capital-labor

    ratio and output per worker hour are constant, but capital, labor, and output are growing. The

    steady-state is the long-run equilibrium so if an economy is not at the steady-state then the

    economy will gradually move toward the steady state. To find the steady state, we first need to

    find an equation for the change in the capital-labor ratio and the change in the capital-labor ratio

    equals investment minus break-even investment:

    .

    We can express this relationship as,

    .

    If we plug in the relationship for investment per worker hour in equation (5.4) we get

    (5.5) .

    Equation (5.14) is the key equation for the Solow growth model because it tells us how the

    capital-labor ratio evolves over time and allows us to determine the equilibrium. We know that

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    33/84

    33

    in the steady state. We can plug this fact into equation (5.10) to solve for the steady-state capital-labor ratio k* as:

    (5.6) * +

    .

    Using the aggregate production function, the steady state real GDP per worker hour is:

    (5.7) * +

    .

    For the United States, the formula for the steady state values is

    * +

    and

    .

    (MD: Steady State An equilibrium in which the capital-labor ratio and output per worker hour

    are constant, but capital, labor, and output are growing. The steady-state is the long-run

    equilibrium so if an economy is not at the steady-state then the economy will gradually move

    toward the steady state.)

    Figure 5-11 shows both the investment and break-even

    Figure 5-11 Equilibrium in the Solow Growth Model

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    34/84

    34

    Caption:The investment curve and the break-even investment line intersect at pointA. In the

    steady state, the capital-labor ratio is constant, so that the change in the capital-labor ratio is zero.

    This point occurs where the investment line intersects the break-even investment line at pointA

    in Figure 5-12. At point A, the capital-labor ratio is $63.8 per worker hour and the levels of

    investment and break-even investment are $7.1 per worker hour. Suppose that the initial capital-

    labor ratio is $22 per worker hour which we label as in Figure 5-12. At that capital-laborratio, the level of investment, , is $5.1 per worker hour and is greater than break-eveninvestment, , of $2.5 per worker hour. According to equation (5.8), and thecapital-labor ratio increases toward the steady state capital-labor ratio, . Now suppose theinitial capital-labor ratio is $125 per worker hour which we label as in Figure 5-12. At thatcapital-labor ratio, the level of investment, , is $8.9 per worker hour and is greater than break-

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    35/84

    35

    even investment, , of $14.0 per worker hour. According to equation (5.8), and the capital-labor ratio decreases toward the steady-state capital-labor ratio, .

    End Caption

    investment lines. In the steady state, the capital-labor ratio is constant, so that the change in the

    capital-labor ratio is zero. This point occurs where the investment line intersects the break-even

    investment line at pointAin Figure 5-12. At point A, the capital-labor ratio is $63.8 per worker

    hour and the levels of investment and break-even investment are $7.1 per worker hour.

    The steady state at pointAis stable because there is a built-in tendency for the economy

    to move toward the equilibrium. For example, suppose that the initial capital-labor ratio is $22

    per worker hour which we label as in Figure 5-12. At that capital-labor ratio, the level ofinvestment, , is $5.1 per worker hour and is greater than break-even investment, , of$2.5 per worker hour. According to equation (5.8), and the capital-labor ratio increasestoward the steady state capital-labor ratio, . The increase in the capital-labor ratio is thevertical distance between the investment and break-even investment lines. Notice that this

    vertical distance decreases as the capital-labor ratio increases. Why does this happen? As the

    economy accumulates more capital goods per worker hour, capital goods become less productive

    because of diminishing marginal returns. As a result, the extra output and investment that the

    economy receives from additional capital decreases as the economy accumulates more capital.

    The increase in the capital-labor ratio continues until and that does not occur until thecapital-labor ratio equals .

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    36/84

    36

    Now suppose the initial capital-labor ratio is $125 per worker hour which we label as in Figure 5-12. At that capital-labor ratio, the level of investment, , is $8.9 per worker hourand is greater than break-even investment, , of $14.0 per worker hour. According toequation (5.8), and the capital-labor ratio decreases toward the steady-state capital-laborratio, . The decrease in the capital-labor ratio is the vertical distance between the investmentand break-even investment lines. Notice that this vertical distance decreases as the capital-labor

    ratio decreases due to diminishing marginal returns. Why does this happen? Once again it is due

    to diminishing marginal returns. As the economy reduces capital goods per worker hour, capital

    goods become more productive. As a result, the extra output and investment that the economy

    receives from additional capital increases as the economy reduces the capital-labor ratio. The

    decrease in the capital-labor ratio continues until and that does not occur until thecapital-labor ratio equals . So, the steady-state is the equilibrium for the economy. We willcome back to this point when we discuss the balanced growth path in the next section.

    The Investment Rate and Real GDP Per Worker Hour

    Now that we have an equilibrium model for the capital-labor ratio and real GDP per

    worker hour, we can ask what causes the equilibrium to change. Figure 5-12 shows what

    happens when the investment rate increases from 0.201, , to 0.302, . First,

    Figure 5-12 An Increase in the Investment Rate

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    37/84

    37

    Caption:An increase in the investment rate from 0.201 to 0.302 shifts the investment curve

    shifts upward from to , so the economy is now producing more investment goods for anygiven level of the capital-labor ratio. Next, the capital-labor ratio increases. The level of

    investment is now greater than the level necessary to replace depreciation and provide the new

    workers with just as much capital as the existing workers. As a result, the capital-labor ratio

    begins to rise from the original steady-state value of $63.8, , to the new steady-state value of$115.8, . Because the capital-labor ratio is one of the inputs of the production function, thehigher capital-labor ratio increases real GDP per worker-hour. So, the Solow growth model

    predicts that a higher investment rate will increase labor productivity from $35.5 dollars per

    worker hour, , to $43.0 dollars per worker hour, , and a higher standard of living. Noticethat the increase in real GDP per worker hour eventually decreases to zero due to diminishing

    marginal returns to capital goods.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    38/84

    38

    End Caption

    the investment curve shifts upward from to , so the economy is now producing moreinvestment goods for any given level of the capital-labor ratio. Next, the capital-labor ratio

    increases. The level of investment is now greater than the level necessary to replace depreciation

    and provide the new workers with just as much capital as the existing workers. As a result, the

    capital-labor ratio begins to rise from the original steady-state value of $63.8, , to the newsteady-state value of $115.8,

    . Because the capital-labor ratio is one of the inputs of the

    production function, the higher capital-labor ratio increases real GDP per worker-hour. So, the

    Solow growth model predicts that a higher investment rate will increase labor productivity from

    $35.5 dollars per worker hour, , to $43.0 dollars per worker hour, , and a higher standard ofliving. Notice that the increase in real GDP per worker hour eventually decreases to zero due to

    diminishing marginal returns to capital goods.

    [Box Begins]

    Macro Data: The American Reinvestment and Recovery Act and Real GDP Per Person

    Congress passed and President Obama signed into law the American Reinvestment and Recovery

    Act in February 2009. The Act is designed to stimulate the economy in the short run, but it may

    have a negative long-run effect on labor productivity and the standard of living. The

    Congressional Budget Office estimates that the Act will reducereal GDP by between 0.0 percent

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    39/84

    39

    and 0.2 percent in 2019.8 Why is that? The Act will increase the budget deficit by $787 billion

    dollars, which the government is likely to pay for by borrowing. In other words, the government

    will run a budget deficit and government savings will decrease. Because investment

    expenditures equal saving, the investment rate should fall and the decrease in the investment rate

    should lead to a lower capital-labor ratio and a lower level of potential real GDP per worker

    hour. Figure 5-13 shows the effect of the decrease in the investment due to the borrowing

    Figure 5-13 The Long-Run Effect of the American Reinvestment and Recovery Act

    8Estimated Macroeconomic Impacts of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009. Letter from

    Douglas Elmendorf Director of the Congressional Budget Office to Senator Charles E. Grassley (Iowa). March 2,

    2009. Available at:http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10008/03-02-Macro_Effects_of_ARRA.pdf.

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10008/03-02-Macro_Effects_of_ARRA.pdfhttp://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10008/03-02-Macro_Effects_of_ARRA.pdfhttp://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10008/03-02-Macro_Effects_of_ARRA.pdfhttp://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10008/03-02-Macro_Effects_of_ARRA.pdf
  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    40/84

    40

    Caption:The budget deficits will reduce government savings which will reduce the funds

    available to the private sector to invest. As a result the investment rate will decrease froms1tos2

    and the investment curve will shift downward froms1ytos2y. As a result, the steady-state

    capital-labor ratio will decrease from to and output per worker hour will decrease from to . Because workers will be less productive, potential real GDP will also decrease.

    End Caption

    associated with the American Reinvestment and Recovery Act. The budget deficits will reduce

    government savings which will reduce the funds available to the private sector to invest. As a

    result the investment rate will decrease froms1tos2and the investment curve will shift

    downward froms1ytos2y. As a result, the steady-state capital-labor ratio will decrease from to and output per worker hour will decrease from to . Because workers will be lessproductive, potential real GDP will also decrease. However, part of the funds from the Act will

    go to infrastructure and other investment projects for which the government is responsible. If

    the Act adds government investment dollars to balance off falling private investment dollars, the

    overall investment rate in the economy, and the investment curve, will shift down only slightly.

    The end result will be a relatively small decrease in potential real GDP per worker hour and

    potential real GDP.However, if the Act finances government consumption or investment

    projects with little or no value, then the investment rate for the economy will decrease and so

    will labor productivity and potential real GDP. The key point is that a deficit may reduce

    potential real GDP depending upon what the government does with the funds it borrows.

    See related problem XXX on page XXX.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    41/84

    41

    [End Box]

    Depreciation, Labor Force Growth Rate, and Real GDP per worker hour

    Figure 5-14 shows what happens when the depreciation rate decreases. First, the break-

    Figure 5-14 A Decrease in the Depreciation Rate

    Caption:A decrease in the depreciation rate flattens the break-even investment line. Next, the

    capital-labor ratio increases for the same reason as we found when the investment rate increases;

    the level of investment is now greater than the level necessary to replace depreciation and

    provide the new workers with just as much capital as the existing workers. As a result, the

    capital-labor ratio begins to rise from the original steady-state value of to the new steady-statevalue of . Because the capital-labor ratio is one of the inputs of the production function, thehigher capital-labor ratio increases potential real GDP per worker hour. Therefore, the Solow

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    42/84

    42

    growth model predicts that a lower depreciation rate will lead to higher productivity and higher

    standard of living.

    End Caption

    even investment line flattens. Next, the capital-labor ratio increases for the same reason as we

    found when the investment rate increases; the level of investment is now greater than the level

    necessary to replace depreciation and provide the new workers with just as much capital as the

    existing workers. As a result, the capital-labor ratio begins to rise from the original steady-state

    value of to the new steady-state value of . Because the capital-labor ratio is one of theinputs of the production function, the higher capital-labor ratio increases potential real GDP per

    worker hour. Therefore, the Solow growth model predicts that a lower depreciation rate will

    lead to higher productivity and higher standard of living.

    What about the growth rate of the labor force? Notice that the growth rate of the labor

    force and the depreciation rate both influence the slope of the break-even investment line in the

    same way. Therefore, a decrease in the labor force growth rate will have exactly the same effect

    on the standard of living as a decrease in the depreciation rate. Therefore, the Solow growth

    model predicts that a lower labor force growth rate will lead to higher productivity and higher

    standard of living.

    Solved Problem 5.1: A Decrease in the Labor Force Growth Rate and Real GDP per

    worker hour. According to the United Nations Population Division, the population growth rate

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    43/84

    43

    averaged 1.7 percent per year between 1950 and 2005. The following table shows the

    Population Division forecasts that the population growth rates for different regions in the world.

    Population Growth Rates across the World

    Period Africa Asia Europe North

    America

    South

    America

    World

    1950 to 2005 2.6 1.9 0.5 2.2 1.2 1.7

    2005 to 2050 1.7 0.6 -0.1 0.6 0.6 0.8

    Change in thePopulationGrowth Rate -0.9 -1.3 -0.6 -1.6 -0.6 -0.9

    SOURCE: United Nations Population Division. The calculations are based upon the Median

    Variant forecast.

    The slower population growth rate should also reduce the growth rate of the labor force. What

    effect will this reduction have on labor productivity and the standard of living in the world?

    Solving the Problem:

    Step 1: Review the chapter material. The problem asks you to determine the effect of a

    decrease in the labor force growth rate on labor productivity and the standard of living, so you

    may want to review the section Depreciation, Labor Force Growth Rate, and Real GDP per

    worker hour, which begins on page x.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    44/84

    44

    Step 2: Use a graph to determine how a decrease in labor force growth rate influences the

    Solow growth model.

    The Solow growth model consists of three curves: the aggregate production function, the

    investment curve, and the break-even investment line. To determine the effect of a decrease in

    the labor force growth rate, we must determine which, if any, of these curves the labor force

    growth rate influences. Earlier we learned that the break-even investment line is so theslope of the break-even investment depends on the depreciation rate and the labor force growth

    rate. When the labor force growth rate decreases, the slope of the break-even investment line

    will decrease and the line will flatten or pivot downwards. The equation for the aggregate

    production function is and equation the equation for the investment curve is then youwill see so that the labor force growth rate does not influence either of these curves. Therefore,

    the labor force growth rate influences only break-even investment. Your graph showing the

    effect of the decrease in the labor force growth rate should look like this:

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    45/84

    45

    Step 3:Determine the effect on the capital-labor ratio. The break-even investment line shifts

    downwards. At the initial capital-labor ratio,

    , the level of investment,

    is greater than the

    new level of break-even investment, . Equation (5.14) tells us how the capital-laborratio evolves over time. Using that equation and what we know about the current levels of

    investment and break-even investment:

    .

    As a result, the capital-labor ratio begins to increase towards the new steady-state capital-labor

    ratio, . The change in the capital-labor ratio is the vertical distance between the investmentcurve and the break-even investment line. The vertical distance gets smaller as the capital-labor

    ratio increases due to diminishing marginal returns, so the increase in the capital-labor ratio gets

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    46/84

    46

    smaller and smaller as the world approaches the new steady state. Growth stops when the

    economy reaches the new steady state at pointB. The steady state level of labor productivity has

    increased from to .

    Step 4: Determine the effect of the capital-labor ratio on the standard of living. Economists

    use real GDP per person to measure the standard of living, and equation (5.1) tells us that real

    GDP per person equals labor productivity multiplied by labor input. We measure labor input as

    average annual hours worked per person. If labor input remains constant, then the increase in

    labor productivity from to will increase the standard of living. The ultimate effect of thedecrease in the population growth rate is to increase the standard of living for the average person

    in the world.

    The United Nations predicts that the population growth rate will decrease during the 2005

    to 2050 period for all regions of the world. However, the table at the beginning of this Solved

    Problems shows that the decrease in the population growth rate will vary across regions of the

    world. For example, Africa is expected to have a population growth rate of 1.7 percent per year.

    Asia, North America, and South America are expected to have population growth rates of about

    0.6 percent per year, but Europe is expected to have a negativepopulation growth rate of -0.1

    percent per year. The largest decrease in the population growth rate will occur in North America

    so, all else equal, you should expect that labor productivity and the standard of living increases

    from slower labor force growth rates will be highest in North America.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    47/84

    47

    Your Turn:See related problem XXX on page XXX.

    **********************************************************************

    Table 5-3 summarizes how changes in the Solow growth model change the steady-state

    Table 5-3 Summary of Changes in the Steady-State

    An increase in will leading to and

    the investment rate shift the investmentcurve up

    an increase in thecapital-labor ratio

    increase potential realGDP per worker hour.

    the level of total

    factor productivity

    shift the investment

    curve up

    an increase in the

    capital-labor ratio

    increase potential real

    GDP per worker hour.

    the depreciation

    rate

    shift the break-eveninvestment live up

    a decrease in thecapital-labor ratio

    a decrease in potentialreal GDP per worker

    hour.

    the labor force

    growth rate

    shift the break-eveninvestment live up

    a decrease in thecapital-labor ratio

    a decrease in potentialreal GDP per worker

    hour.

    potential real GDP per worker hour. Increases in the investment rate and total factor productivity

    lead to higher real GDP per worker hour in the steady-state while increases in the depreciation

    rate and the growth rate of the labor force lead to lower real GDP per worker hour in the steady

    state.

    5.3 Explain how Total Factor Productivity Affects Labor Productivity

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    48/84

    48

    Total factor productivity measures the overall efficiency of the economy in transforming capital

    and labor into final goods and services that households can consume. Total factor productivity

    growth, along with capital accumulation are the two sources for increases in labor productivity.

    We just learned that increases in labor productivity from capital accumulation eventually

    decrease to zero due to diminishing marginal returns. As a consequence, total factor productivity

    is the ultimate source of labor productivity growth and, hence, the increase in the standard of

    living.

    Total Factor Productivity and Real GDP per worker hour

    Figure 5-15 shows the effect of an increase in total factor productivity for the United

    Figure 5-15 An Increase in Total Factor Productivity

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    49/84

    49

    Caption:For the United States in 2007, total factor productivity is initially 9.4 and the capital-

    labor ratio is $144.9 per hour so potential real GDP per worker hour is $46.4 and the economy is

    at pointAin Figure 5-16. If the capital-labor ratio remains constant and total factor productivity

    increases by one point to 10.4 then the production function shifts up and the economy is now at

    pointB, so that at any given capital-labor ratio, real GDP per worker hour increases to $51.3 per

    hour. In this example, an increase in total factor productivity has a similar effect as an increase

    in the investment rate. But there is an important difference. The marginal product of capital

    decreases as the economy accumulates more capital holding all else constant, but the extra output

    from increasing total factor productivity does not. If total factor productivity increases to by

    another point to 11.4 then the economy moves to point Cand potential real GDP per worker hour

    increases to $56.2. Therefore, each time total factor productivity increases by one point,

    potential real GDP per worker hour increases by $4.9. In contrast to capital goods, there are no

    diminishing marginal returns for total factor productivity. Therefore, there is no limit to growth

    from increases in total factor productivity and total factor productivity growth must be the

    explanation for increases in labor productivity and the standard of living.

    End Caption

    States in 2007 assuming that the capital-labor ratio equals $144.9 per hour. Total factor

    productivity is initially 9.4 so potential real GDP per worker hour is $46.4 and the economy is at

    pointAin Figure 5-16. If the capital-labor ratio remains constant and total factor productivity

    increases by one point to 10.4 then the production function shifts up and the economy is now at

    pointB, so that at any given capital-labor ratio, real GDP per worker hour increases to $51.3 per

    hour. In this example, an increase in total factor productivity has a similar effect as an increase

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    50/84

    50

    in the investment rate. But there is an important difference. The marginal product of capital

    decreases as the economy accumulates more capital holding all else constant, but the extra output

    from increasing total factor productivity does not. If total factor productivity increases to by

    another point to 11.4 then the economy moves to point Cand potential real GDP per worker hour

    increases to $56.2. Therefore, each time total factor productivity increases by one point,

    potential real GDP per worker hour increases by $4.9. In contrast to capital goods, there are no

    diminishing marginal returns for total factor productivity. Therefore, there is no limit to growth

    from increases in total factor productivity and total factor productivity growth must be the

    explanation for increases in labor productivity and the standard of living.

    New technology is one source of higher total factor productivity. If a new technology is

    discovered that increases the processing power of computers, then total factor productivity would

    increase fromA1toA2. The production function would shift upward and real GDP per worker

    hour would increase. Similarly, if a second technology is discovered that reduces congestion on

    the internet, then the productivity of all existing computers would increase so total factor

    productivity would increase fromA2toA3. The production function would again pivot upward

    and real GDP per worker hour would increase again.

    What effect does an increase in total factor productivity have on the steady-state values of

    the capital-labor ratio and potential real GDP per worker hour? Figure 5-16 shows the effect of a

    one-time

    Figure 5-16 A One-Time Increase in Total Factor Productivity

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    51/84

    51

    Caption:The one-time increase in total factor productivity shifts the production function from

    to. At the initial capital-labor ratio, investment,, is now greater thanbreak-even investment. As a result, the capital-labor ratio increases and this causes potential real

    GDP per worker hour to increase and the steady state to move from pointAto pointB.

    End Caption

    increase in total factor productivity. The one-time increase in total factor productivity shifts the

    production function from

    to

    . At the initial capital-labor ratio, investment,

    , is now greater than break-even investment. As a result, the capital-labor ratioincreases and this causes potential real GDP per worker hour to increase and the steady state to

    move from pointAto pointB.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    52/84

    52

    In fact, the growth rate of total factor productivity,gA, is the key determinant for labor

    productivity growth and the growth rate of the standard of living when labor inputs per person

    are constant. Table 5-4

    Table 5-4 Steady-State Growth Rates

    Variable Symbol Steady-State Growth Rate

    Capital-labor ratio (

    )

    Potential real GDP per worker hour (

    )

    Capital Stock ( ) Potential real GDP ( )

    shows the steady-state growth rates for the capital-labor ratio and potential real GDP per worker

    hour when the hours per person (labor input) is constant. The appendix at the end of the chapter

    shows the how to derive the steady-state growth rates. For the United States, capitals share of

    income, , is 0.32. TFP growth has averaged 0.0125 or 1.25 percent per year and the growth rate

    of potential labor hours, n, averaged 0.0121 or 1.21 percent per year. So, for the United States:

    or 1.84 percent per year,

    and

    or 3.05 percent per year.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    53/84

    53

    Labor productivity increases by about 1.84 percent per year, and if labor inputs per person are

    constant, then potential real GDP per person also grows at about 1.84 percent per year.

    Similarly, when labor inputs per person are constant, potential labor hours grow at about 1.21

    percent per year so potential real GDP grows at about 3.05 percent per year.

    What Explains Differences in TFP?

    Now that we know that TFP growth is the key factor behind labor productivity growth

    and the growth rate of the standard of living, we need to determine why TFP increases over time.

    Economists have spent a tremendous amount of time trying to answer this question. Although no

    single theory has emerged, economists have identified several important factors, which we

    discuss next.

    Research and Development and the Level of Technology

    As we mentioned in Chapter 4, total factor productivity measures the overall efficiency of

    the economy in transforming inputs into real GDP. One of the most important factors

    influencing total factor productivity is the stock of knowledge that the world possess and the

    associated level of technology. The invention of computers made workers more productive by

    giving them new and better types of capital goods to work with. For example, word processors

    allow one administrative assistant today to do work that would have taken a team of

    administrative assistants in 1949. Assembly line workers in automobile plants now operate and

    oversee robots rather than doing the manual labor themselves. As a result, one worker today can

    produce many more automobiles than a team of workers could in 1949. In both examples, the

    new capital goods has made labor more productive.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    54/84

    54

    New capital goods do not just appear out of thin air. Private firms and the government

    devote a significant amount of resources to research and development (R&D) activities to come

    up with ideas for new capital goods or new goods and services for consumption. A considerable

    amount of the economys resources are devoted to discovering and testing these new ideas. The

    Commerce Department calculates that the United States conducted $317 billion worth of R&D in

    2004, with the private sector responsible for $209 billion of R&D and the government

    responsible for the remaining $108 billion of R&D.

    [Begin Box]

    Research and Development Expenditures and Labor Productivity Differences between

    China and the United States

    On page xx we saw that labor productivity in the United States was 6.3 times higher than in

    China. Because of the higher labor productivity, the United States is able to maintain a higher

    standard of living. Part of the reason the United States has a higher level of labor productivity is

    that the United States devotes more resources to develop new technology and accumulate human

    capital. For example, in 2004 (the most recent year data is available for both countries) the

    United States devoted 2.6 percent of GDP to research and development while China devoted just

    1.2 percent and as recently as 1996 China devoted just 0.6 percent of GDP research and

    development. The higher level of investment in new technology helps increase knowledge and

    total factor productivity so U.S. workers remain more productive.

    SOURCE: World Development Indicators, the World Bank.

    [End Box]

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    55/84

    55

    H3: Quality of Labor

    The quality of labor, like the quality of capital goods, can change over time. Workers

    become more skilled as they acquire human capital. Human capitalis the accumulated

    knowledge and skills that workers acquire from education and training or from life experiences.

    There are two basic ways for workers to acquire human capital.

    (MD: Human Capital Theaccumulated knowledge and skills that workers acquire from

    education and training or from life experiences.)

    First, a worker can go to school for formal training to learn basic skills that are useful in

    the workplace. Students go to school to learn science, math, and other subjects that make them

    better workers. And as students learn and acquire new skills, their human capital increases, and

    they become more productive workers. Through this learning, education transforms low-skilled

    high school graduates into high-skilled engineers and scientists.

    Second, as Nobel Laureate Kenneth Arrow of Stanford University points out, workers

    can accumulate skills through learning by doing.9 Arrow argued that the more workers perform

    a task, the more they learn about how to do the task quicklythereby improving their

    productivity in doing the task. Arrow cited evidence from engineering studies showing that the

    amount of time it takes to build an airplane decreases as workers build more airplanes. This

    relationship emerges because the workers have acquired knowledge and skills through building

    the previous airplanes, making them more productive.

    9Economic Implications of Learning by Doing, The Review of Economic Studies(June 1962), pp.155-173.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    56/84

    56

    H3: Government and Social Institutions

    Nobel Laureate Douglass North of Stanford University and economist Robert Thomas of

    the University of Washington have emphasized the importance of government and social

    institutions in explaining differences in labor productivity and the standard of living across

    countries.10 North and Thomas, and many other economists, believe that markets and property

    rights are important institutions that lead to economic growth. Individuals and firms are unlikely

    to risk their own funds, and investors are unlikely to lend their funds to individuals and firms,

    unless they can keep the profits from risky investment projects. In other words, property rights

    must be secure to encourage investment and capital accumulation. In some countries, property

    rights are not secure due to government corruption because it is impossible for individuals and

    firms to start or expand businesses without paying bribes to at least one government official.

    Historical evidence suggests that government institutions and property rights do matter.

    After Germanys defeat in World War II and the onset of the Cold War between the United

    States and the Soviet Union, Germany was divided into West Germany which was a

    parliamentary democracy with a market economy and secure property rights and East Germany

    which was a communist dictatorship without a strong market or secure property rights. Both

    East and West Germany were devastated by World War II. The two countries were reunified

    into a single country in 1990 and at the time of reunification real GDP per person in then West

    Germany was 2.6 times the level of real GDP per person in East Germany. The case of North

    and South Korea provides a second example of the importance of government institutions. Japan

    had occupied the Korean peninsula during World War II, but after Japans surrender Soviet

    10The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge University Press (1973).

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    57/84

    57

    troops occupied what would become North Korea while U.S. troops occupied what would

    become South Korea. Just like East Germany, North Korea was a communist dictatorship

    without strong markets or secure property rights while South Korea had strong markets and

    secure property rights. While economic data for North Korea are unreliable because the North

    Korean government does not make official data available, the CIAFact Bookestimates that real

    GDP per person for South Korea was 14.4 times the level in North Korea in 2008.

    Economists Daron Acemoglu of MIT, Simon Johnson of MIT, and James Robinson of

    the University of California at Berkeley tried to find systematic evidence showing the effect of

    government and social institutions on real GDP per person.11 European countries colonized large

    regions of the world between the 1600s and the 1800s. In countries such as the United States,

    Australia and New Zealand, Europeans came as settlers and established institutions that enforced

    the rule of law. These favorable institutions encouraged investment which led to faster economic

    growth and higher real GDP per person. However, in Africa and other areas European countries

    did not come as settlers. Instead, the Europeans came to extract natural resources and so did not

    establish government institutions that favored investment. The areas of the world in which the

    Europeans established strong property rights are generally rich today while the regions in which

    Europeans did not establish strong property rights are generally not rich.

    The experiences of the Germany, Korea, and the former European colonies have

    convinced many economists that government institutions play a critical role in encouraging

    economic growth.

    11The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,American Economic Review

    (December 2001), pp. 1369-1401.

  • 8/11/2019 Ch05Revision_Long-Run Economic Growth3.29.10.docx

    58/84

    58

    Geography

    Not all economists today agree with the primary importance of institutions for explaining

    the standard of living. In fact, as long ago as Adam Smiths 1776 bookAn Inquiry into the

    Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, economists have pointed out that geography

    influences a nations natural resources. For example, access to navigable rivers and coast line

    makes trade easier and should increase labor productivity and the standard of living. For

    example, the United States has a large coast line and extensive navigable rivers while countries

    such as Bolivia and Tibet are landlocked and mountainous so transportation is difficult.

    However, Jeffrey Sachs of Columbia University argues that geography plays an important role in

    economic growth for another reason. Sachs, along with economists Andrew Mellinger and John

    Gallup, argues that tropical climates experience higher rates of infectious disease such as

    malaria.12 The countries that are poor today are often the countries with high rates of infe


Recommended