+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became...

Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became...

Date post: 09-May-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
32
Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL J. Ignacio Garc´ ıa P ´ erez Universidad Pablo de Olavide - Department of Economics BASIC REFERENCE: Cahuc & Zylberberg (2004), Chapter 2 December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 1/32
Transcript
Page 1: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

Chapter 5: EDUCATION ANDHUMAN CAPITAL

J. Ignacio Garcıa Perez

Universidad Pablo de Olavide - Department of Economics

BASIC REFERENCE: Cahuc & Zylberberg (2004), Chapter 2

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 1/32

Page 2: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION

A decent amount of education, certified by a recognized diploma, is often seen as abasic necessity for winning a well-paid job.

According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker(1964), education is an investment , producing knowledge acquisition and increasedproductivity, leading in turn to higher earnings.

Some economists, though, see this concept of education as very reductive.

Much of what is taught in primary, secondary, and post-secondary institutions bringsno immediate payoff in the labor market.

Others, however, take the view that the essential virtue of this type of learning is toselect individual students. From this perspective, first formulated by Spence (1973),the education system plays the role of a filter .

it selects individuals on the basis of their intrinsic efficiency, allowing them to signal

their abilities to potential employers.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 2/32

Page 3: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION

To enable us to grasp the exact role of education, and then if possible quantify it, wewill need a precise conceptual structure, capable of representing the consequences ofboth knowledge acquisition and selection.

This is what the economic analysis of education aims at.

Individual choices will be seen to be socially efficient if the labor market is competitiveand if education produces no externalities.

We will then see how, when information asymmetries on the labor market were takeninto account, Spence was led to emphasize the role played by the education system asa selection mechanism.

In this context, individual choices about education are generally socially inefficient, andmay lead, in certain circumstances, to over-education.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 3/32

Page 4: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION: Some Facts

Spending on educationOn average, OECD countries spend 6.2% of their GDP on education.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 4/32

Page 5: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION: Some Facts

Graduation ratesThe majority of the population in OECD countries has obtained a diploma signifyingthe completion of upper secondary education.

Figure 2 shows that the average percentage of the working-age population that hascompleted secondary schooling in 2010 is 74% for the OECD countries.

Educational levels are advancing: the proportion of the population with at leastsecondary schooling is higher in the age range 25-35 than it is in the age range 55-64.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 5/32

Page 6: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION: Some Facts

Graduation rates31% of people in the OECD have tertiary education in 2010.

The % of young individuals with tertiary education is 1.7 times that for old workers.

Here, as before, convergence is observable: the countries where tertiary educationhave advanced most rapidly are the ones where these rates were lower.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 6/32

Page 7: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION: Some Facts

Education and performance on the labor market

Higher levels of education are positively correlated to greater labor marketparticipation, and to better performance in this market.

Figure 4 shows that wages rise with educational level in all the countries considered.

On average, in 2010 a OECD worker with less than upper secondary level receives awage equal to 77% of the wage of a worker with upper secondary education.

Wage earners with a tertiary level diploma receive wages 54% higher than those withan upper secondary diploma.

This suggests that to acquire education is a way to elevate one’s wages.

As well, figure 5 shows that, on average, rates of unemployment fall off as educationallevel rises.

Persons with an educational attainment falling below upper secondary level have aprobability more than twice as large of experiencing unemployment as do those with atertiary diploma, since their unemployment rate is 12.5%.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 7/32

Page 8: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION: Some Facts

Education and Wages

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 8/32

Page 9: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

INTRODUCTION: Some Facts

Education and Unemployment

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 9/32

Page 10: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

The theory of human capital, inaugurated by Becker (1964), starts with the hypothesisthat education is an investment producing earnings in the future.

In this context, wage differentials are influenced by differences in individualproductivity, which are themselves influenced by investments in education.

To acquire competencies that the labor market will reward brings “training costs ”comparable to investments that will be sources of future earnings.

These costs include the expenses of study (fees to enrol in specialized establishments,costs of lodging and travel, purchase of materials, etc.), potential loss of earnings dueto the fact that time spent on study is not devoted to remunerated activity, and thepsychological costs arising from stress and possibly the sheer difficulty of studying.

Investments in education may pay off when they produce an accumulation ofcompetencies, “human capital” as it is called, which brings returns in the form of higherremuneration.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 10/32

Page 11: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

From Becker’s perspective, education can only be a source of future earnings if wagesreflect differences in productivity .

Now it is not at all self-evident that improved productivity on the part of a wage-earnerdoes lead systematically to an increase in her wage, even in a perfectly competitivelabor market in which firms have perfect knowledge of workers’ characteristics, andworkers and jobs are both perfectly mobile.

In reality, a worker who has acquired competencies and expertise that improve herproductivity can only make them pay off if she is able to play two or more employers offagainst one another.

A single employer would indeed have no reason to raise the wage of a worker whoseproductivity had improved if that worker could not credibly threaten to take abetter-paid job elsewhere.

This observation led Becker to adopt the distinction between general training , whichenhances the productivity of the individual concerned for all types of job, and specifictraining , which only enhances her productivity for one particular type of job.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 11/32

Page 12: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

The link between wages and human capital can be highlighted in a very simple twoperiod model in which the labor force is made up of a continuum of identical workers,the size of which is normalized to 1.

Each worker lives 2 periods.

First period life is devoted to education only and the second period to production.

There is no preference for the present: the discount rate is equal to zero.

If he has had the advantage of general training equal to i, he is capable of producing aquantity of goods y(i) in the second period if he occupies any job.

If he has had the advantage of specific training equal to i for a particular job, he iscapable of producing a quantity of goods y(i) if he occupies that job.

Whenever he is not holding a job, the worker obtains z units of goods.

The production function y(i) is assumed to be increasing, concave, and such thaty(0) ≥ z.

The amount of time needed to make an investment in training is assumed to be zero.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 12/32

Page 13: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

Competitive equilibrium with general training

In a situation of perfect competition, all suppliers of labor who have made aninvestment i in general training are employed if they want to be.

The condition of free entry into the market ensures that the profits of the entrepreneurswho employ trained individuals are zero, i.e. y(i) = w(i),.

In such a case, a worker cannot make a credible promise to share the fruits of aninvestment in general training with the first employer she encounters (the wage-earnerreceiving less than y(i) if the entrepreneur participates in the investment in training),for once the investment has been made, the worker has an interest in quitting thatemployer, knowing that she will immediately find another firm to offer her wage y(i).

The result is that suppliers of labor are the only real beneficiaries of investments ingeneral training, and so must bear the entire cost of it themselves.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 13/32

Page 14: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

Competitive equilibrium with general training

Optimal investment maximizes y(i)− i, and is thusdefined by relation:

y′(i) = 1(1)

This result signifies that each individual has aninterest in investing to enhance her general trainingas long as the marginal return y′(i) of this investment isgreater than its marginal cost, here equal to 1.

Employers have no incentive to finance this type oftraining, for every worker can obtain a wage increase byoffering her services to competing bidders as soon asher productivity increases.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 14/32

Page 15: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

Competitive equilibrium with specific training

By definition, when training is specific, workers can only make their training pay off in aparticular job.

Once trained, they are unable to demand wage increases from their employer bymaking him bid against other employers.

Hence employers may have an incentive to invest in this type of training.

This conclusion will emerge more clearly if we represent the decisions of the secondperiod life by a two-stage game:

In the first stage, employers freely enter the market and compete through thewages they offer to workers.

In the second stage, each employer chooses the level of investment in specifictraining that maximizes his profit.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 15/32

Page 16: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

Competitive equilibrium with specific training

Given wage w offered in the first stage, this profit iswritten y(i)− w − i.

Profit maximization then gives an investment i∗

satisfying y′(i∗) = 1.

Free entry in the first stage of the game entails zeroprofit, and thus wage w = y(i∗)− i∗.

As in the case of general training, workers obtain anincome equal to their productivity minus the cost ofinvestment in training.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 16/32

Page 17: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

The Social Optimum

Choices made by individuals within the framework of perfect competition lead to socialefficiency.

This can be verified by writing the problem of a planner seeking to determine optimalinvestment in training, whether general or specific.

Since y(0) ≥ z, the planner decides to assign all of them to the technology y(·) in usein the market rather than let them produce z domestically.

If the planner dedicates an amount i of resources to the training of an individual, hisproblem is written as follows:

Maxiy(i)− i(2)

The solution of this problem is again given by the equality (1). Thus, in a perfectlycompetitive economy, individual choices regarding training are socially efficient.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 17/32

Page 18: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

THE THEORY OF HUMAN CAPITAL

The Social Optimum

The theory of human capital suggests that the mechanisms of competition giveindividuals an incentive to become educated for the purpose of acquiring skills onwhich the market sets a premium.

Moreover, it shows that individual educational choices are socially efficient if the labormarket is perfectly competitive.

Evidently in reality markets are never perfectly competitive.

In this case, wages and productivity differ, and educational choices are no efficient.

For example, if wages are lower than productivity because firms dispose ofmonopsony power, the investment in human capital is less than the social optimum.

Thus, in the absence of competition, the incentives to invest so as to improveproductivity disappear.

For this reason it is generally firms that invest in specific training, which wage-earnerscannot exploit to increase their market value.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 18/32

Page 19: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The positive correlation, highlighted in figure 5, between duration of studies andearnings, does not prove the existence of a causal relationship between these twovariables.

It is not, in fact, beyond dispute that education permits the accumulation of directlyproductive knowledge.

On this basis, Spence (1973) put forward the idea that education also — and perhapseven primarily — serves to select individuals, without really influencing the productiveefficiency that they will display in their future professional lives.

The productive efficiency of a person is seen as a sort of intrinsic quality, which maycertainly depend on a wide range of factors over which education exerts little influence.

The premise of Spence’s theory is that those persons who perform most effectively inactive life are also the ones who perform best while studying.

If productive efficiency is not observable by potential employers, then success as astudent simply serves to signal the presence of such productive characteristics

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 19/32

Page 20: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

From this standpoint, a person pursues education in order to signal her efficiency,without her studies really modifying this efficiency.

If education serves only to signal intrinsic individual qualities, then the real significanceof the positive correlation between duration of studies and earnings is just that moreefficient individuals have higher earnings.

The standpoint of the theory of human capital is completely at odds with that ofsignaling theory.

Signaling theory arrives at very different conclusions concerning the efficiency ofinvestments in education.

Whereas the theory of human capital indicates that individual decisions with regard toeducation are socially efficient under perfect competition, Spence (1973) shows thatworkers have a tendency to over-educate themselves with respect to the standard ofsocial efficiency.

In this section, we present a model in which employers observe the productivity ofworkers imperfectly, but view a degree, or the length of time spent in schooling, as anindicator of potential productivity.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 20/32

Page 21: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

We here consider a labor market made up of a continuum of individuals whoseproductive abilities are different.

The size of the continuum is normalized to one.

A worker with ability h can produce h units of a good.

For simplicity, we will now assume that there are only two levels of personal ability,h+ and h− with 0 < h− < h+.

Workers have the possibility to achieve a level of education s ≥ 0 that is observed byemployers.

A level of education s bears a cost equal to s/h.

Thus, the weaker the productive abilities of workers are, the more it costs.

It should be noted that in this model education does not improve individual productivity;it can serve only to signal ability when it is not observed by employers.

Workers’ preferences are represented by a utility function u(R, s, h) = R− (s/h),

where R designates earnings, equal to wage w if the individual is employed and to 0

otherwise.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 21/32

Page 22: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

We assume that decisions unfold in the following sequence:

1. workers, knowing which of the two types they belong to, choose their level ofeducation s,

2. firms enter the labor market freely, observe the signals s, and make simultaneouswage offers to workers.

3. workers accept or refuse the offers made to them.

Let us first consider a situation of perfect competition in which individual characteristicsare perfectly observed.

The hypothesis of free entry entails w(h) = h, for h = h−, h+.

Since we have assumed that workers get zero earnings when they do not work andthat the disutility of working is zero, hypothesis h− > 0 entails that all workers areemployed independently of the signal s.

In consequence, in the first stage, no one has any interest in utilizing resources tosend a signal s > 0 and so they all choose a zero level of education.

This situation is efficient, for s > 0 does not augment productivity.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 22/32

Page 23: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

Equilibrium when ability is unobservable

When abilities are unobservable, the signal becomes a way for the most efficientworkers to bring themselves to the attention of firms.

To that end, it is sufficient for them to choose a level of education that is too costly forinefficient workers, given the wage differential w(h+)− w(h−).

In that case, firms are capable of distinguishing between the two types of workersaccording to their respective signals, and the equilibrium is called separatingequilibrium.

In this situation, the condition of free entry entails w(h) = h, for h = h−, h+, andworkers with low efficiency send the signal s = 0, since a positive signal brings themno gain.

For equilibrium actually to be separating, it must be verified that no person of type h−

has an interest in deviating by choosing a signal identical to that sent by more efficientpersons.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 23/32

Page 24: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

Equilibrium when ability is unobservable

By sending a zero signal, a worker of low efficiency obtains a utilityu[

w(h−), 0, h−

]

= h−, while by sending a signal s+ identical to that of efficientworkers, he obtains u

[

w(h+), s+, h−

]

= h+ − (s+/h−).

Hence a worker of low efficiency has no interest in sending a signal identical to that ofmore efficient workers if h+ − (s+/h−) ≤ h−, which is equivalent tos+ ≥ h−.(h+ − h−).

Knowing that, workers of type h+ have an interest in sending the weakest signalpossible, while workers of type h− have no interest in imitating.

This signal thus has the value s∗ = h−.(h+ − h−).

Evidently efficient workers prefer s = s∗ to s = 0, since workers of type h−, whosesignaling costs are greater, are indifferent between these two values of s.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 24/32

Page 25: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

Equilibrium when ability is unobservable

So in this economy there does exist a separating equilibrium in which workers of lowefficiency do not seek education and obtain a wage w(h−) = h−, and in whichefficient workers become educated to a level s∗ > 0 and obtain a wage w(h+) = h+.

It is important to emphasize that, even in this simple model, the separating equilibriumjust described is not the sole equilibrium possible.

In fact, the definition of equilibria in signaling games raises difficulties having to do withthe beliefs of agents.

In general, it is necessary to choose a very restrictive concept of equilibrium in order toeliminate outcomes which appear to have no relevance.

In our elementary model, we implicitly selected the most efficient separatingequilibrium, i.e. the one that corresponds to the smallest value of the signal that stillmakes it possible to distinguish between the two types of worker.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 25/32

Page 26: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The inefficiency of education as a signaling device

In the previous example, it is easy to show that education is a waste of resources thathas no social utility.

To reach that conclusion, it is enough to compare the allocations obtained with andwithout the opportunity to become educated when individual abilities are notobservable.

Let λ be the proportion of efficient workers, and let us begin by analyzing the situationin which education is absent and workers are indistinguishable.

Since the opportunity cost of labor is assumed to be zero, and since h+ > h− > 0,

everyone participates in the labor market and obtains an identical wage w given byw = E(h) = λh+ + (1− λ)h−.

Normalizing the number of workers to 1, total output is then equal to E(h).

Now let us introduce the opportunity to get an education.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 26/32

Page 27: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The inefficiency of education as a signaling device

At the separating equilibrium, in which the efficient workers get educated, overallproduction net of the costs of education is equal to the difference between grossproduction E(h) and the costs of education, equal to λs∗/h+

In this case, education is clearly a waste of resources, even having detrimentalredistributive effects for the least efficient individuals.

These obtain a utility equal to u(w, 0, h−) = E(h) or u[

w(h−), 0, h−

]

= h−, in theabsence and presence respectively of education.

Workers with low productivity are thus systematically disadvantaged by education.

On the other hand, education has an ambiguous effect on the welfare of the mostproductive persons, who obtain a utility equal to u(w, 0, h−) = E(h) oru[

w(h+), s∗, h+]

=[

(h+)2 − h+.h− + (h−)2]

/h+ in the absence and presencerespectively of education.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 27/32

Page 28: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The inefficiency of education as a signaling device

What this means is that education improves the situation of efficient workers if andonly if u

[

w(h+), s∗, h+]

> u(w, 0, h−), which is equivalent to λ < (h+ − h−)/h+.

Efficient workers thus benefit from education if their proportion is sufficiently small withrespect to the efficiency gap between them and the less productive workers.

So the model of Spence (1973) portrays the role played by education in a verynegative light:

all it serves to do is select workers according to their efficiency, without improving theallocation of resources.

This result is not a general one, however, and the model which follows offers a case inwhich signaling activity makes it possible, under certain circumstances, to improve theallocation of resources.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 28/32

Page 29: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The EFFICIENCY of education as a signaling device

For education to become an efficient signaling device, all we have to do is adjust thepreceding model at the margin by assuming that the opportunity cost of labor issomething other than zero.

The preferences of workers are now represented by the utility functionu(R, s, d, h) = R+ d− (s/h), where R designates earnings, equal to wage w if theindividual is employed and 0 otherwise, d is an indicator function amounting to 0 if theindividual is employed and 1 if not, and the signal s still stands for the level ofeducation.

Let us further assume that the individual characteristic h takes only two values, h−

and h+, such that 0 < h− < 1 < h+, with E(h) < 1.

Under these hypotheses, when abilities are not observable and there is no signalingactivity, nobody enters the labor market, since the wage compatible with free entry,w = E(h), is less than the opportunity cost of labor.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 29/32

Page 30: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The EFFICIENCY of education as a signaling device

Such a situation arises when the proportion of workers whose productivity h is lessthan the opportunity cost of labor is large.

The opportunity of using a costly signaling device may then allow the most efficientpersons to enter the market, and so improve the allocation of labor.

Let us take a closer look at this situation.

When the equilibrium is separating, workers with low efficiency stay out of the market,for their productive ability h− does not permit them to obtain a wage greater than theopportunity cost of labor (free entry dictates w(h−) = h− < 1) .

These workers therefore send a zero signal s, since a positive signal brings them nogain.

For equilibrium actually to be separating, it must be verified that individuals of lowefficiency have no interest in choosing a signal identical to that of more efficientworkers.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 30/32

Page 31: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The EFFICIENCY of education as a signaling device

By sending a zero signal, a low-efficiency worker attains utility u(0, 0, 1, h−) = 1.

By sending a signal s+ identical to that of efficient workers, he or she obtainsu[

w(h+), s+, 0, h−

]

= h+ − (s+/h−).

Consequently a low-efficiency person has no interest in sending a signal identical tothe one sent by an efficient person if h+ − (s+/h−) ≤ 1, which is equivalent tos+ ≥ h−(h+ − 1).

Knowing that, workers of type h+ have an interest in sending the smallest signal thatworkers of type h− have no interest in imitating.

This signal is given by s∗ = h−(h+ − 1).

As in the preceding model, it is clear that efficient workers prefer s = s∗ to s = 0, sinceindividuals of type h−, for whom signaling is more costly, are indifferent between thesetwo values of s.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 31/32

Page 32: Chapter 5: EDUCATION AND HUMAN CAPITAL...According to the theory of human capital which became popular following Becker (1964), education is an investment, producing knowledge acquisition

EDUCATION AS A SIGNALING DEVICE

The EFFICIENCY of education as a signaling device

This separating equilibrium dominates, according to the Pareto criterion, theequilibrium without signaling,

since the less efficient workers obtain the same level of gain in the two equilibria— equal to u(0, 0, 1, h−) = 1 —

while the more efficient workers obtainu[

w(h+), s∗, 0, h+]

=[

(h+)2 − h+h− + h−

]

/h+ in separating equilibrium,

which procures them a gain exceeding the opportunity cost of labor whenh+ > 1 > h−.

December 2013 LABOUR ECONOMICS J. Ignacio Garcia-Perez – p. 32/32


Recommended