+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Chapter 9

Chapter 9

Date post: 17-Nov-2014
Category:
Upload: naveen9622
View: 120 times
Download: 6 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Chapter 9 economic
Popular Tags:
29
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice eighth edition Chapter 9 Production & Cost in the Long Run
Transcript
Page 1: Chapter 9

McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Managerial Economics ThomasMauriceeighth edition

Chapter 9

Production & Cost in the Long Run

Page 2: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics2

McGraw-Hill/Irwin2

Production Isoquants

• In the long run, all inputs are variable & isoquants are used to study production decisions• An isoquant is a curve showing all

possible input combinations capable of producing a given level of output

• Isoquants are downward sloping; if greater amounts of labor are used, less capital is required to produce a given output

Page 3: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics3

McGraw-Hill/Irwin3

Typical Isoquants (Figure 9.1)

Page 4: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics4

McGraw-Hill/Irwin4

Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution• The MRTS is the slope of an isoquant

& measures the rate at which the two inputs can be substituted for one another while maintaining a constant level of output

K

MRTSL

MRTS

K LThe minus sign is added to make a positivenumber since , the slope of the isoquant, isnegative

Page 5: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics5

McGraw-Hill/Irwin5

Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution• The MRTS can also be expressed as

the ratio of two marginal products:

L

K

MPMRTS

MP

L

K

MPMP MRTSAs labor is substituted f or capital, declines &

rises causing to diminish

L

K

MPKMRTS

L MP

Page 6: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics6

McGraw-Hill/Irwin6

Isocost Curves

• Represents amount of capital that may be purchased if zero labor is purchased

( C ) ( w, r )

Show various combinations of inputs thatmay be purchased for given level ofexpenditure at given input prices

• K C r-intercept is

C w

K Lr r

•( w r )

Slope of an isocost curve is the negativeof the input price ratio

Page 7: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics7

McGraw-Hill/Irwin7

Isocost Curves (Figures 9.2 & 9.3)

Page 8: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics8

McGraw-Hill/Irwin8

Optimal Combination of Inputs

• Two slopes are equal in equilibrium• Implies marginal product per rupee spent on

last unit of each input is the same

Q

Q

Minimize total cost of producing bychoosing the input combination on the

isoquant for which is just tangent to anisocost curve

L L K

K

MP MP MPw

MP r w ror

Page 9: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics9

McGraw-Hill/Irwin9

Example

• Quantity to be produced 10,000 units

• Cost of labour w = Rs. 40 per unit• Cost of capital r = Rs. 60 per unit

Marginal rate of technical substitution = slope of isocost curve = w/r = 2/3

Page 10: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics10

McGraw-Hill/Irwin10

Optimal Input Combination to Minimize Cost for Given Output (Figure 9.4)

Page 11: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics11

McGraw-Hill/Irwin11

Optimization & Cost

• Expansion path gives the efficient (least-cost) input combinations for every level of output• Derived for a specific set of input

prices• Along expansion path, input-price

ratio is constant & equal to the marginal rate of technical substitution

Page 12: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics12

McGraw-Hill/Irwin12

Example

• 3 isoquant curves – 500, 700, 900 • Capital cost r = Rs. 20 / unit• Labour cost w = Rs. 10 / unit

• Slope of isocost curve = 1/2

Page 13: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics13

McGraw-Hill/Irwin13

Expansion Path (Figure 9.6)

Page 14: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics14

McGraw-Hill/Irwin14

Returns to Scale

• If all inputs are increased by a factor of c & output goes up by a factor of z then, in general, a producer experiences:• Increasing returns to scale if z > c; output goes up

proportionately more than the increase in input usage

• Decreasing returns to scale if z < c; output goes up proportionately less than the increase in input usage

• Constant returns to scale if z = c; output goes up by the same proportion as the increase in input usage

f(cL, cK) = zQ

Page 15: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics15

McGraw-Hill/Irwin15

Long-Run Costs

• Long-run total cost (LTC) for a given level of output is given by: LTC = wL* + rK* Where w & r are prices of labor & capital,

respectively, & (L*, K*) is the input combination on the expansion path that minimizes the total cost of producing that output

Page 16: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics16

McGraw-Hill/Irwin16

Long-Run Costs• Long-run average cost (LAC) measures the

cost per unit of output when production can be adjusted so that the optimal amount of each input is employed• LAC is U-shaped

• Falling LAC indicates economies of scale

• Rising LAC indicates diseconomies of scale

LTC

LACQ

Page 17: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics17

McGraw-Hill/Irwin17

Long-Run Costs• Long-run marginal cost (LMC) measures

the rate of change in long-run total cost as output changes along expansion path• LMC is U-shaped

• LMC lies below LAC when LAC is falling

• LMC lies above LAC when LAC is rising

• LMC = LAC at the minimum value of LAC

LTC

LMCQ

Page 18: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics18

McGraw-Hill/Irwin18

Derivation of a Long-Run Cost Schedule (Table 9.1)

Output LMCLACTotal cost

(w = R5, r = R10)

Capital (units)

Labor (units)

Least-cost combination of

100

500

600

200

300

400

700

LMC

10

4052

1220

30

60

7

2230

8

10

15

42

R120

420

560

140

200

300

720

R1.20

0.840.93

0.700.67

0.75

1.03

R1.20

1.201.40

0.200.60

1.00

1.60

Page 19: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics19

McGraw-Hill/Irwin19

Long-Run Total, Average, & Marginal Cost (Figure 9.9)

Page 20: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics20

McGraw-Hill/Irwin20

Long-Run Average & Marginal Cost Curves (Figure 9.10)

Page 21: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics21

McGraw-Hill/Irwin21

Various Shapes of LAC (Figure 9.11)

Page 22: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics22

McGraw-Hill/Irwin22

Constant Long-Run Costs

• When constant returns to scale occur over entire range of output• Firm experiences constant costs in

the long run• LAC curve is flat & equal to LMC at

all output levels

Page 23: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics23

McGraw-Hill/Irwin23

Constant Long-Run Costs (Figure 9.12)

Page 24: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics24

McGraw-Hill/Irwin24

Economies of Scope

• Exist for a multi-product firm when the joint cost of producing two or more goods is less than the sum of the separate costs of producing the two goods

• For two goods, X & Y, economies of scope are measured by:

C( X ) C(Y ) C( X ,Y )SC

C( X ,Y )

SCSC

Where is greater than zero when economies of scopeexist & is less than zero with diseconomies of scope

Page 25: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics25

McGraw-Hill/Irwin25

Relations Between Short-Run & Long-Run Costs• LMC intersects LAC when the latter is at its

minimum point

• At each output where a particular ATC is tangent to LAC, the relevant SMC = LMC

• For all ATC curves, point of tangency with LAC is at an output less (greater) than the output of minimum ATC if the tangency is at an output less (greater) than that associated with minimum LAC

Page 26: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics26

McGraw-Hill/Irwin26

Long-Run Average Cost as the Planning Horizon (Figure 9.13)

Page 27: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics27

McGraw-Hill/Irwin27

Restructuring Short-Run Costs

• Because managers have greatest flexibility to choose inputs in the long run, costs are lower in the long run than in the short run for all output levels except that for which the fixed input is at its optimal level• Short-run costs can be reduced by

adjusting fixed inputs to their optimal long-run levels when the opportunity arises

Page 28: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics28

McGraw-Hill/Irwin28

Recall previous example

• Units to be produced 10000• Labour cost = 40 per unit• Capital cost = 60 per unit

Page 29: Chapter 9

Managerial Economics29

McGraw-Hill/Irwin29

Restructuring Short-Run Costs (Figure 9.14)


Recommended