+ All Categories
Home > Education > Coc volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Coc volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Date post: 01-Nov-2014
Category:
Upload: ahmed-al-baidhani-cpa-mba-phd-candidate
View: 188 times
Download: 13 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
The Effects of Corporate Governance on Bank Financial Performance in the Arabian Peninsula.
Popular Tags:
94
Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1 155 CORPORATE OWNERSHIP & CONTROL Postal Address: Postal Box 36 Sumy 40014 Ukraine Tel: +380-542-611025 Fax: +380-542-611025 e-mail: [email protected] [email protected] www.virtusinterpress.org Journal Corporate Ownership & Control is published four times a year, in September-November, December-February, March-May and June-August, by Publishing House “Virtus Interpress”, Kirova Str. 146/1, office 20, Sumy, 40021, Ukraine. Information for subscribers: New orders requests should be addressed to the Editor by e-mail. See the section "Subscription details". Back issues: Single issues are available from the Editor. Details, including prices, are available upon request. Advertising: For details, please, contact the Editor of the journal. Copyright: All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored or transmitted in any form or by any means without the prior permission in writing of the Publisher. Corporate Ownership & Control ISSN 1727-9232 (printed version) 1810-0368 (CD version) 1810-3057 (online version) Certificate № 7881 Virtus Interpress. All rights reserved. КОРПОРАТИВНАЯ СОБСТВЕННОСТЬ И КОНТРОЛЬ Почтовый адрес редакции: Почтовый ящик 36 г. Сумы, 40014 Украина Тел.: 38-542-611025 Факс: 38-542-611025 эл. почта: [email protected] [email protected] www.virtusinterpress.org Журнал "Корпоративная собственность и контроль" издается четыре раза в год в сентябре, декабре, марте, июне издательским домом Виртус Интерпресс, ул. Кирова 146/1, г. Сумы, 40021, Украина. Информация для подписчиков: заказ на подписку следует адресовать Редактору журнала по электронной почте. Отдельные номера: заказ на приобретение отдельных номеров следует направлять Редактору журнала. Размещение рекламы: за информацией обращайтесь к Редактору. Права на копирование и распространение: копирование, хранение и распространение материалов журнала в любой форме возможно лишь с письменного разрешения Издательства. Корпоративная собственность и контроль ISSN 1727-9232 (печатная версия) 1810-0368 (версия на компакт-диске) 1810-3057 (электронная версия) Свидетельство КВ 7881 от 11.09.2003 г. Виртус Интерпресс. Права защищены.
Transcript
Page 1: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

155

CORPORATE

OWNERSHIP & CONTROL

Postal Address:

Postal Box 36

Sumy 40014

Ukraine

Tel: +380-542-611025

Fax: +380-542-611025

e-mail: [email protected]

[email protected]

www.virtusinterpress.org

Journal Corporate Ownership & Control is published

four times a year, in September-November,

December-February, March-May and June-August,

by Publishing House “Virtus Interpress”, Kirova Str.

146/1, office 20, Sumy, 40021, Ukraine.

Information for subscribers: New orders requests

should be addressed to the Editor by e-mail. See the

section "Subscription details".

Back issues: Single issues are available from the

Editor. Details, including prices, are available upon

request.

Advertising: For details, please, contact the Editor of

the journal.

Copyright: All rights reserved. No part of this

publication may be reproduced, stored or transmitted

in any form or by any means without the prior

permission in writing of the Publisher.

Corporate Ownership & Control

ISSN 1727-9232 (printed version)

1810-0368 (CD version)

1810-3057 (online version)

Certificate № 7881

Virtus Interpress. All rights reserved.

КОРПОРАТИВНАЯ

СОБСТВЕННОСТЬ И КОНТРОЛЬ

Почтовый адрес редакции:

Почтовый ящик 36

г. Сумы, 40014

Украина

Тел.: 38-542-611025

Факс: 38-542-611025

эл. почта: [email protected]

[email protected]

www.virtusinterpress.org

Журнал "Корпоративная собственность и

контроль" издается четыре раза в год в сентябре,

декабре, марте, июне издательским домом Виртус

Интерпресс, ул. Кирова 146/1, г. Сумы, 40021,

Украина.

Информация для подписчиков: заказ на подписку

следует адресовать Редактору журнала по

электронной почте.

Отдельные номера: заказ на приобретение

отдельных номеров следует направлять Редактору

журнала.

Размещение рекламы: за информацией

обращайтесь к Редактору.

Права на копирование и распространение:

копирование, хранение и распространение

материалов журнала в любой форме возможно

лишь с письменного разрешения Издательства.

Корпоративная собственность и контроль

ISSN 1727-9232 (печатная версия)

1810-0368 (версия на компакт-диске)

1810-3057 (электронная версия)

Свидетельство КВ 7881 от 11.09.2003 г.

Виртус Интерпресс. Права защищены.

Page 2: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

156

CORPORATE OWNERSHIP & CONTROL Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

CONTENTS

DOES ANALYST FOLLOWING IMPROVE FIRM PERFORMANCE? EVIDENCE FROM THE MENA REGION 157 Omar Farooq, Harit Satt ENHANCING THE CORPORATE PERFORMANCE THROUGH SYSTEM DYNAMICS MODELLING 167 Mridula Sahay, Kuldeep Kumar THE EFFECT OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ON BANK FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM THE ARABIAN PENINSULA 178 Mohamed A. Basuony, Ehab K. A. Mohamed, Ahmed M Al-Baidhani DEBT, GOVERNANCE AND THE VALUE OF A FIRM 192 K. Rashid, S. M. N. Islam, S. Nuryanah LINK BETWEEN MARKET RETURN, GOVERNANCE AND EARNINGS MANAGEMENT: AN EMERGING MARKET PERSPECTIVE 203 Omar Al Farooque, Eko Suyono, Uke Rosita THE LIFECYCLE OF THE FIRM, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND INVESTMENT PERFORMANCE 224 Jimmy A. Saravia EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION, ORGANIZATIONAL CULTURE AND THE GLASS CEILING 239 Michael Dewally, Susan Flaherty, Daniel D. Singer

Page 3: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

157

DOES ANALYST FOLLOWING IMPROVE FIRM PERFORMANCE? EVIDENCE FROM THE MENA REGION

Omar Farooq*, Harit Satt**

Abstract

Given ineffective disclosure and governance mechanisms, are there any mechanisms that can help improve performance of firms in the MENA region? This paper aims to answer the above question by documenting the effect of analyst following on firm performance during the period between 2005 and 2009. Our results show that the extent of analyst following does positively affect firm performance. However, this beneficial impact exists only at high level of analyst following. At lower levels of analysts following, our results show negative relationship between the two. We argue that high levels of analyst following, it becomes hard for insiders to evade effective disclosure of firm value. It, therefore, leads to lower agency problems and, eventually, to better performance. We also show that high levels of analyst following, partly, improve the informativeness of reported earnings. However, it does not improve the informativeness to an extent that the information contained in reported earnings is positively reflected in stock prices. JEL classification: G32 Keywords: Analyst Following, Corporate Governance, Firm Performance, Earnings Informativeness, Emerging Markets * Department of Management, American University in Cairo, Cairo, Egypt Tel.: 20 102 376 0037 Email: [email protected] ** School of Business Administration, Al Akhawayn University in Ifrane, Ifrane, Morocco

1. Introduction

Information is the key to efficient functioning of the

stock markets. Securities get priced correctly when

the relevant information about firms get incorporated

into the prices. Financial analysts play an important

role in this process by bringing out new information

about firms. Under normal circumstances, stock

market participants view analysts’ research reports,

forecasts, and recommendations as relatively accurate

sources of information and use them in their

investment decisions. Jensen and Meckling (1976)

suggest that, as information intermediaries, financial

analysts are able to mitigate the agency problems

present within firms. Merton (1987) argues that the

market value of a firm is an increasing function of the

breadth of investor awareness. Conventional wisdom

suggests that one of the ways to increase awareness of

an investor regarding a certain firm is by increasing

the extent of analyst following. Chung and Jo (1996)

argue that the value of a firm is a positive function of

number of analysts following a firm. In addition to

increasing awareness, analyst following may also

effect firm valuation by reducing information

asymmetries and agency problems. Analysts perform

the task of discovering any information that firm

decides to hide. In doing so, they act as a device that

ensures that all information is presented to stock

market participants. As a result, they help reduce

information asymmetries and positively impact firm

valuation. Furthermore, greater the extent of analyst

following, greater is the amount of information that

gets discovered. The extent of analyst following,

therefore, should be an important determinant of the

relationship between analyst following and firm

valuation.

In this paper, we aim to extend the above strand

of literature by documenting whether the extent of

analyst following improves firm performance, an

important proxy for firm valuation, in the previously

unexplored region of the Middle East and North

Africa (MENA). To the best of our knowledge, this is

the first attempt to relate the two in the MENA region.

Given the ability of analysts to uncover new

information, it is intuitive to argue that they are able

to reduce information asymmetries between outsiders

and insiders. Reduction in information asymmetries

makes expropriation technology costly and results in

disciplining the managers by reducing agency

problems. Therefore, analyst following is an obvious

determinant of firm performance. Furthermore,

conventional wisdom suggests that greater is the

Page 4: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

158

extent of analyst following for a certain firm, higher is

the reduction in information asymmetries. As a result,

greater is the extent of analyst following, better

should be firm performance. Consistent with our

expectations, our results show that analyst following

does positively affect firm performance in the MENA

region (Morocco, Egypt, Saudi Arabia, United Arab

Emirates, Jordan, Kuwait, and Bahrain) during the

period between 2005 and 2009. However, this

positive impact exists only at high levels of analyst

following. At lower levels of analyst following, we

report a negative impact of analyst following on firm

performance – an unexpected finding. Our results are,

partly, consistent with prior literature that considers

any mechanism that helps resolve information

asymmetries between insiders and outsiders as value

relevant for stock market participants. As an example,

consider Lang et al. (2004) who document a positive

valuation effect of analyst following in emerging

markets. They argue that emerging markets have

scarcity of information, thereby enhancing the value

relevance of any mechanism that provides valuable

information to investors. Our results are partly

consistent because at the lower levels of analyst

following, our results show that the extent of analyst

following negatively impacts firm performance. This

is surprising because, at most, low analyst following

should result in no impact on firm performance.

Negative association between the two is counter

intuitive.

Another surprising finding of our analysis is the

negative relationship between firm performance and

earnings per share. This relationship is also robust

across different sub-samples. One reason for this

negative impact is the low information content of

reported earnings. Investors, aware of the fact that

firms in the emerging markets misreport information,

have little faith on reported information. Therefore,

they discount earnings per share. In order to see

whether the extent of analyst following improves the

infomativeness of reported earnings, this paper also

documents the impact of analyst following on the

informativeness of reported earnings. Our results

show that analyst following does improve the

informativeness of reported earnings, but it does not

completely offset the lower faith that investors have

on reported information. Our results show that the

magnitude of negative relationship between earnings

per share and firm performance reduce significantly

as the extent of analyst following goes up.

Our results are important for investors investing

in the MENA region. One of the main problems faced

by these investors is that it is almost impossible for

them to differentiate between good and bad firms.

However, our results show that investors can use

analyst following to infer which firm is expected to do

good and which firm is expected to do bad.

Furthermore, our results also indicate that analyst

following can also be used to improve the

informativeness of reported earnings. Our results

show that investors can complement accounting

information with analyst following to distinguish

between true and manipulated accounting

information. It is important to mention here that our

paper adds to the debate on the effectiveness of

alternate/external governance mechanisms in the

MENA region. Unlike the developed markets,

analysts are not considered very important monitoring

mechanisms in the MENA region. Farooq and Id Ali

(2012) show no value in analysts’ recommendation in

the MENA region. They consider lower demand for

analyst services and relatively low market for

reputation in the MENA region for their result.

However, our results indicate that analysts do have

some value for stock market participants. The

increased scrutiny provided by them helps in reducing

information asymmetries, thereby improving firm

performance.

The remainder of the paper is structured as

follows: Section 2 briefly discusses motivation and

background for this study. Section 3 summarizes the

data and Section 4 presents assessment of our

hypothesis. Section 5 discusses implications of our

findings and the paper concludes with Section 6.

2. Motivation and background

Prior literature characterizes emerging markets with

ineffective and weak corporate governance

mechanisms. Claessens and Fan (2003), for instance,

note that traditional governance mechanisms are weak

in emerging markets. In another related study, Farooq

and Kacemi (2011) document that an average firm in

the Middle East and North Africa is owned and

controlled by a single entity. They argue that

concentration of ownership in the hands of a few

gives rise to many of the agency problems. These and

numerous other studies argue that weak enforcement

of investor protection laws, presence of family

control, and lax implementation of anti-director rights

contribute to ineffectiveness of corporate governance

mechanisms in emerging markets. Prior literature

suggests that ineffective governance mechanisms

result in poor information disclosure. Leuz et al.

(2003), for instance, document that managers and

insiders do not disclose true information about their

firms in emerging markets. As a result, agency

problems are exacerbated, thereby causing adverse

impact on firm performance. Dowell et al. (2000)

argue that firms with no or little adaptation to global

governance standards have lesser market value. In

another related study, Black (2001) shows that

ineffective corporate governance mechanisms

adversely affect firm valuations in emerging markets.

This strand of literature argues that higher information

asymmetries in poorly governed firms provide

incentives to managers/controlling shareholders to

expropriate resources, thereby negatively affecting

firm performance.

Page 5: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

159

Given that financial analysts can help resolve

some of the inefficiencies in corporate governance

mechanisms, this paper argues that analyst following

is a value enhancing mechanism in emerging markets.

Analysts resolve inefficiencies in governance

mechanisms by bringing out new information to stock

market participants. Michaely and Womack (1999)

note that analysts are the agents that collect, interpret,

and disseminate public and private information to

stock market participants. By disseminating valuable

information, analysts are able to resolve information

asymmetries. Amir et al. (1999) also suggest that

analysts’ research mitigate information deficiencies

present in financial statements. This paper argues that

analysts’ role as information providers is of

paramount importance in emerging markets

(Claessens et al., 2002; Lins, 2003; Dyck and

Zingales, 2004; Nenova, 2003). Nenova (2003) argues

that investors discount firms with high information

asymmetries. Information asymmetries introduce

agency problems within firms and expose investors to

excessive risk. Therefore, any mechanism that can

help in reducing information asymmetries is of great

importance to stock market participants.

Our arguments are consistent with prior

literature that considers financial analysts to substitute

for corporate governance mechanisms in emerging

markets. Lang et al. (2004), for example, document

the substitution effect of analysts by showing that the

extent of analyst following mitigates the negative

effect of lower investor protection on valuation in

emerging markets. In another related study, Knyazeva

(2007) documents that analyst following improves

firm performance by substituting for corporate

governance. Main argument in this strand of literature

is that analysts’ role as information providers allow

investors to offset any information misreported by

firms. This strand of literature also argues that the

nature of analyst’s job is such that he has to make

every effort to bring to light any information

misreported or not disclosed by firms.1 Conventional

wisdom suggests that more is the number of analysts

looking out for information, greater is the chances that

no information remains misreported or undisclosed.

As a result, higher analyst following should affect

firm performance more than lower analyst following.

At a lower level of analyst following, the information

asymmetries are not resolved to an extent that analyst

following becomes valuable for stock market

participants. It, therefore, leads us to hypothesis a

positive but a nonlinear relationship between analyst

following and firm performance.

1 Plentiful of prior literature suggests that the compensation

of analysts depend on their accuracy (Stickel, 1992; Hong and Kubik, 2003). Therefore, it is intuitive to argue that analysts strive for gathering as much value relevant information as possible.

H1a: There is a positive, but nonlinear, relationship

between analyst following and firm performance in

emerging markets

However, a second school of thought contests the

value enhancing impact of analyst following in

emerging markets.2 This school of thought cites

several reasons behind no impact of analyst following

in emerging markets. Most important of them are: (1)

Lower market for reputation, (2) Less demand for

analyst services, and (3) Unscrupulous behavior of

brokerage houses. All of these factors are expected to

affect value enhancing role of analysts to a varying

degree.

The first issue that arises in emerging

markets is the absence of market for reputation.

Anecdotal evidence suggests that there are no rating

agencies like “Institutional Investor (publisher of All-

American Research Team)” or “The Wall Street

Journal (publisher of Best on the Street)” in most of

the emerging markets. Therefore, there is little

incentive for analysts to improve their rankings or

reputation. In the absence of market for reputation, it

is not entirely clear why analysts would compete for

quality. In addition, evidence also suggests lower

development of financial press or financial media in

these markets. For instance, there are no well-

developed TV channels are that specifically related to

financial news. If there were such TV channels, it

would have been possible for some analysts to

develop reputation of being accurate and it would

have pushed the others to be accurate as well. Lower

market for reputation should lower the pressures that

analysts may face to improve value of their research.

As a result, value enhancing role analysts is expected

to be less pronounced in emerging markets.

Another issue that often arises in emerging

stock markets is the lower demand for analyst

services. Prior literature suggests limited participation

of local populations in emerging stock markets.

Giannetti and Koskinen (2005), for example,

document that only 3.3% of Indian population invests

in stock market, while this statistics is 1.2% for

Turkey and 2.3% for Sri Lanka. They also show that,

in contrast to emerging markets, 40.4% of Australian

population, 26.0% of the US populations, and 31.0%

of New Zealand population invests in stock markets.

We argue that limited participation of local

populations in stock markets lowers the demand for

analyst services in emerging markets. Lower demand

of analyst services should reduce the incentives for

analysts to improve their research, thereby resulting in

a weaker relationship between analyst following and

firm performance.

2 There is not enough evidence on how valuable analyst

research is in most of the emerging markets. Erdogan et al. (2011), for instance, document that analysts are not able to distinguish well performing and poorly performing firms in Turkey. In another related study, Farooq and Ahmed (2013) report low value of analyst recommendations in Pakistan.

Page 6: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

160

In addition to the above two factors,

inadequate regulations pertaining to brokerage houses

may also result in lowering the value of analyst

research. Prior literature documents that brokerage

houses collude to manipulate stock prices in emerging

markets. Khwaja and Mian (2006) document that

“when brokers trade on their own behalf, they earn at

least 50 to 90 percentage points higher annual returns

and these abnormal returns are earned at the expense

of outside investors”. In another related study,

Khanna and Sunder (1999) argue that “brokers were

often accused of collaborating with the company

owners to rig share prices in pump and dump

schemes”. Farooq and Ahmed (2013) argue that one

of the channels via which brokerage houses

manipulate prices is by using financial analysts

employed by them. They explain a scenario where a

brokerage house starts accumulating stocks at a lower

price. It gradually pushes the stock price up until it

reaches a level where brokerage houses ask their

analysts to issue buy recommendations. Naive

investors, anticipating stock prices to go up further,

keep on buying in response to analysts’ buy

recommendations. At this high price, brokerage

houses start disposing off their accumulated stocks.

An outcome of such behavior is the decline in value

enhancing role analysts in emerging markets.

All of the above mentioned factors may result in

insignificant relationship between analyst following

and firm performance.

H1b: There is no relationship between analyst

following and firm performance in emerging markets

3. Data

This paper examines how the extent of analyst

following affects firm performance in the MENA

region. We select Morocco, Egypt, Saudi Arabia,

United Arab Emirates, Jordan, Kuwait, and Bahrain

as the representative stock markets for the MENA

region because of their relatively more development.

The sample period is between 2005 and 2009. The

following sub-sections will explain the data in greater

detail.

3.1 Analyst following

We define analyst following by the maximum number

of analysts issuing annual earnings forecasts in a

given year. Greater the number of analysts following

a firm, the better is its information environment and

lower is information asymmetry. Data for analyst

following is obtained from the I/B/E/S.3 Table 1

3 The Institutional Brokers' Estimate System (I/B/E/S) is a

database owned by Thomson Financials and provides data on analyst activities, such as earnings forecasts and stock recommendations issued by them. The IBES provides a data entry for each forecast and each recommendation announcement by each analyst whose brokerage house contributes to the database. Each observation in the file

documents the descriptive statistics for analyst

following during our sample period. Panel A presents

descriptive statistics for each year, while Panel B and

Panel C presents similar statistics for each country

and each industry respectively. Our results in Table 1,

Panel A, show that analyst following gradually

increased from 0.8497 in 2005 to 2.8732 in 2009. It

shows gradual improvement in analyst industry in the

MENA region. It also shows that maximum analyst

following that a firm generated was 11 analysts in

2005. It also gradually increased to 20 analysts by

2009. Furthermore, Table 1, Panel B, shows that firms

headquartered in United Arab Emirates, Morocco, and

Egypt have the highest level of analyst following in

the region. We report average analyst following of

1.6780 in United Arab Emirates, 1.6238 in Morocco,

and 1.3145 in Egypt. Table 1, Panel B, also reports

that firms headquartered in Kuwait have the least

level of analyst following in the region. The results in

Table 1, Panel C, show that firms belonging to

Telecommunication sector have the highest level of

analyst following. It is intuitive because most of

Telecommunication firms are large and very

profitable firms in the region.

Table 1 documents the descriptive statistics for

analyst following in the MENA region, i.e. Morocco,

Jordan, Bahrain, Egypt, Kuwait, United Arab of

Emirates, Saudi Arabia, and Qatar. The sample period

is from 2005 to 2009. Panel A document descriptive

statistics for each year, while Panel B and Panel C

document similar statistics for each country and each

industry respectively.

3.2 Firm performance

This paper measures firm performance by market-

adjusted returns (RET). We define RET as the

difference between stock returns and market returns.

Stock prices and market index are obtained from the

Datastream. The stock price data and the market index

data was obtained for the first and the last day of a

given year to compute RET.

3.3 Control variables This paper uses the following firm-specific

characteristics as control variables. The data for

control variables is obtained from the Worldscope.

SIZE: We measure size by log of market

capitalization. Conventional wisdom suggests that

large firms have lower agency problems due to

increased interest from stock market participants

(investors and analysts). Lower agency problems

should lead to better performance of large firms (Fang

represents the issuance of a forecast or a recommendation by a particular brokerage house for a specific firm. For instance, one observation would be a forecast or a recommendation by Brokerage House ABC regarding Firm XYZ.

Page 7: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

161

et al., 2009). Furthermore, Bhattacharyya and Saxena

(2009) argue that larger firms have more bargaining

power over their suppliers and competitors, thereby

improving their performance.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics for analyst following

Panel A. Analyst following in different years

Years Average Standard Deviation Maximum Minimum

2005 0.2621 0.8497 11 0

2006 0.4681 1.1791 13 0

2007 0.6909 1.4454 13 0

2008 1.0439 2.1206 14 0

2009 1.4015 2.8732 20 0

Panel B. Analyst following in different countries

Countries Average Standard Deviation Maximum Minimum

Bahrain 0.3095 0.6220 3 0

Egypt 1.3145 2.3932 14 0

Jordan 0.3102 0.7532 5 0

Kuwait 0.2415 0.9515 12 0

Morocco 1.6238 1.1392 8 0

Qatar 0.6487 1.8132 13 0

Saudi Arabia 0.6352 1.6066 14 0

United Arab of Emirates 1.6780 3.2715 20 0

Panel C. Analyst following in different industries

Industry Average Standard Deviation Maximum Minimum

Oil and Gas 0.3647 0.9238 5 0

Basic Materials 0.9000 1.5137 10 0

Industrials 0.7870 1.6066 14 0

Consumer Goods 0.4603 0.9242 5 0

Healthcare 0.6000 0.8329 3 0

Consumer Services 0.4240 1.4241 15 0

Telecommunication 4.7600 4.6319 14 0

Utilities 1.6285 1.7836 6 0

Financials 0.7851 1.9637 20 0

Technology 1.1428 2.3904 11 0

LEVERAGE: We measure leverage by total

debt to total asset ratio. High leverage exposes firms

to greater financial risk. High risk should result in

lower performance (Mitton, 2002).

EPS: This paper defines EPS as earnings per

share. EPS is an important variable that measures

investor interest in a firm (Chang et al., 2008). It also

measures accounting performance of a firm. Higher

investor interest and superior accounting performance

is expected to translate into better stock price

performance.

GROWTH: This paper measures GROWTH

by growth in earnings per share. Jegadeesh and Livnat

(2006) document that firms with higher growth have

better stock price performance.

PoR: It is defined as percentage of earnings

paid as dividends. Prior literature considers dividends

as a tool via which firms can reduce information

asymmetries (Grossman and Hart, 1980; Jensen,

1986; La Porta et al., 2000). Lower information

asymmetries should lead to better stock price

performance.

VOLATILITY: It is the measure of a stock's

average annual price movement to a high and low

from a mean price for each year. For example, a

stock's price volatility of 20% indicates that the

stock's annual high and low price has shown a

historical variation of +20% to -20% from its annual

average price. We expect firms with high volatility to

exhibit low stock price performance.

Table 2 documents the statistics for our control

variables during our sample period. Panel A

documents the descriptive statistics for control

variables used in our analysis and Panel B documents

the correlation between different control variables. As

is expected, Table 2, Panel A, shows that firms in the

MENA region pay low fraction of their earnings as

dividends. Our results show that the PoR is 30.3736%

for our sample firms. This observation is in contrast to

the PoR in the developed countries where almost 80%

of earnings are distributed to shareholders as

dividends. Table 2, Panel A, also shows that firms in

the MENA region have very low leverage. This

observation is consistent with prior literature that

Page 8: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

162

shows that firms in the MENA region rely on their

retained earnings for their long-term financial needs

(Achy, 2009). Furthermore, Table 2, Panel B, shows

low correlation between our control variables, thereby

allowing us to include these variables in regression

analysis.

The following table documents the statistics for

control variables used in regression. The sample

comprise of firms from Morocco, Jordan, Bahrain,

Egypt, Kuwait, United Arab of Emirates, Saudi

Arabia, and Qatar. The period of analysis is from

2005 to 2009. Panel A document descriptive statistics

for control variables, while Panel B document

correlation between different control variables.

Table 2. Statistics for control variables

Panel A. Descriptive statistics

Mean Median Standard Deviation

EPS 3.8409 0.1760 17.8059

SIZE 6.3646 6.3966 2.3453

LEVERAGE 18.7935 13.5730 18.6983

VOLATILITY 30.7110 29.9760 10.8343

PoR 30.3736 21.5045 29.0761

GROWTH 11.8849 7.6535 64.1726

Panel B. Correlation matrix

EPS SIZE LEVERAGE VOLATILITY PoR GROWTH

EPS 1.0000

SIZE 0.2425 1.0000

LEVERAGE 0.0337 -0.0086 1.0000

VOLATILITY -0.1553 0.3339 0.0135 1.0000

PoR 0.1398 0.0512 -0.0708 -0.1815 1.0000

GROWTH -0.0130 -0.0375 0.0062 -0.0827 -0.1560 1.0000

4. Methodology

This paper aims to document the effect of analyst

following on firm performance in the MENA region.

In order to test this hypothesis, we estimate a

regression equation with market-adjusted returns

(RET) as a dependent variable and two variables

representing analyst following (ANALYST) and

square of analyst following (ANALYST*ANALYST)

as independent variables. Furthermore, as mentioned

above, we also include a number of control variables

in our regression equation. These variables are

earnings per share (EPS), log of market capitalization

(SIZE), total debt to total asset ratio (LEVERAGE),

stock price volatility (VOLATILITY), dividend

payout ratio (PoR), growth in earnings per share

(GROWTH), and year dummies (YDUM). Our basic

regression takes the following form. It is important to

mention here that we use panel data regression with

fixed effects for our analysis. Hausman test was used

to decide between fixed effect and random effects.

εYDUMβGROWTHβPoRβ

VOLATILITYβLEVERAGEβSIZEβEPSβ

ANALYST*ANALYSTβANALYSTβαRET

Yr

Yr

87

6543

21

(1)

The results of our analysis are reported in Table

3. Our results show that the extent of analysts

following improves firm performance only at high

levels. We report significant and positive coefficient

of ANALYST*ANALYST. At low levels of analyst

following, our results indicate a negative relationship

between analyst following and firm performance. We

report significantly negative coefficient of

ANALYST. Our results indicate that high analyst

following is associated with lower information

asymmetries in the MENA region. Lower information

asymmetries lead to lower agency problems, thereby

positively influencing firm performance. However, at

low level of analyst following, information

asymmetries do not get resolved to an extent that it

influences firm performance positively. Surprisingly,

our results also show that there is a negative

relationship between earnings per share and firm

performance. We report significant and negative

coefficient of EPS. It indicates that stock market

participants do not value the reported earnings on

their face value.

Table 3 documents the effect of analyst

following on firm performance in the MENA region

(Morocco, Egypt, Saudi Arabia, United Arab

Emirates, Jordan, Kuwait, and Bahrain). The period of

analysis is from 2005 to 2009. The panel data

regression with fixed effects is performed using

Equation (1). The coefficients with 1% significance

are followed by ***, coefficient with 5% by **, and

coefficients with 10% by *.

Page 9: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

163

Table 3. Effect of analyst following on firm performance

Equation (1)

ANALYST -0.0901***

ANALYST*ANALYST 0.0069***

EPS -0.0150***

SIZE 0.6773***

LEVERAGE 0.0063

VOLATILITY -0.0296**

PoR 0.0022**

GROWTH 0.0026***

Year Dummies Yes

No. of Observations 974

F-Value 47.32

R2 within 0.4022

There may be concerns that the results obtained

above are confined to certain sub-sets of stocks. For

instance, smaller firms have higher information

asymmetries and analysts’ role to reduce these

asymmetries should be more pronounced in these

firms relative to larger firms. As a result, analyst

following should be more value relevant for small

firms. Lang et al. (2004) argue that increased analyst

following is associated with higher valuations,

particularly for firms likely to have higher

information asymmetries. In order to overcome these

concerns, we divide our sample into different groups

– large / small firms, firms with high / low debt, and

firms from common law / civil law countries. All of

these groups are characterized by different levels of

information asymmetries. Large firms, firms with

high debt, and firms from common law countries have

better information environment relative to small

firms, firms with low debt, and firms from civil law

countries, respectively. We re-estimate Equation (1)

for each group. Results of our analysis are reported in

Table 4. We report that our results hold true in both

civil law and common law countries. Interestingly,

our results also show that our results hold in a sub-

sample of large firms and in a sub-sample of firms

with high leverage. We report negative and significant

coefficient of ANALYST and positive and significant

coefficient of ANALYST*ANALYST for these

groups. Both of these groups have lower information

asymmetries. Larger firms enjoy more interests from

investors and analysts, while firms with high debt

command more scrutiny from creditors. As a result,

the incremental value of analysts should be less

pronounced in these sub-samples. We report

insignificant impact of analyst following in sub-

samples characterized by high information

asymmetries – small firms and firms with low debt.

This finding is in contrast with Lang et al. (2004) who

document that analyst following is more value

relevant in asymmetric information environments.

The following table documents the effect of

analyst following on firm performance in different

sub-samples (Large/Small, High Leverage/Low

Leverage, Common Law/Civil Law). The sample

comprise of firms from the MENA region (Morocco,

Egypt, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, Jordan,

Kuwait, and Bahrain). The period of analysis is from

2005 to 2009. The panel data regression with fixed

effects is performed using Equation (1). The

coefficients with 1% significance are followed by

***, coefficient with 5% by **, and coefficients with

10% by *.

Table 4. Effect of analyst following on firm performance in different sub-samples

Size Leverage Legal Traditions

Large Small High Low

Common

Law Civil Law

ANALYST -0.0875** -0.0614 -0.1017*** -0.0516 -0.0282 -0.0988**

ANALYST*ANALYST 0.0063** -0.0175 0.0071*** 0.0060 0.0041** 0.0065*

EPS -0.0167*** -0.1194*** -0.0110* -0.0167*** -0.0620*** -0.0066**

SIZE 0.719*** 0.6222*** 0.7515*** 0.7281*** 1.1338*** 0.3967***

LEVERAGE 0.0029 -0.0054** 0.0012 -0.0099 0.01410* 0.0031

VOLATILITY -0.0411** -0.0249** -0.0183 -0.0475** -0.0592*** 0.0038

PoR 0.0041*** -0.0008 0.0018 0.0025* 0.0038** 0.0015

GROWTH 0.0038*** 0.0011*** 0.0031*** 0.0018*** 0.0017** 0.0030***

Year Dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

No. of Observations 554 420 462 512 320 654

F-Value 41.10 19.61 17.24 37.45 65.80 16.33

R2 within 0.4518 0.3532 0.4208 0.4584 0.7128 0.3117

Page 10: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

164

5. Discussion of results

Our results have shown that high level of analyst

following has a positive impact on firm performance.

We argue that at high level of analyst following,

information asymmetries are reduced to a significant

level and therefore cause firm performance to

improve. One implication of our argument is that, at

high level of analyst following, firms should be

unable to manipulate their financial statements. As a

result, we should expect a positive impact of high

analyst following on the informativeness of reported

earnings. In order to test our conjecture, we introduce

two more variables in Equation (1). These variables

represent interaction between analyst following and

earnings per share (ANALYST*EPS) and interaction

between square of analyst following and earnings per

share (ANALYST*ANALYST*EPS). Our modified

equation takes the following form:

εYDUMβGROWTHβPoRβ

VOLATILITYβLEVERAGEβSIZEβ

EPS*ANALYST*ANALYSTβEPS*ANALYSTβEPSβ

ANALYST*ANALYSTβANALYSTβαRET

Yr

Yr

109

876

543

21

(2)

The results of our analysis are reported in Table

5. Contrary to our expectations, our results report

negative and significant coefficient of

ANALYST*EPS and of

ANALYST*ANALYST*EPS. However, we show

that the magnitude of coefficient of

ANALYST*ANALYST*EPS is significantly less

than coefficient of ANALYST*EPS. It shows that

higher level of analyst following does have, at least,

some beneficial impact on the informativeness of

reported earnings. However, the beneficial impact is

not to an extent that it results in completely restoring

the credibility of reported earnings. Our findings,

partly, support Farooq (2013) who document positive

impact of analyst following on informativeness of

reported earnings in the MENA region.

The following table documents the effect of

analyst following on informativeness of earnings in

the MENA region (Morocco, Egypt, Saudi Arabia,

United Arab Emirates, Jordan, Kuwait, and Bahrain).

The period of analysis is from 2005 to 2009. The

panel data regression with fixed effects is performed

using Equation (2). The coefficients with 1%

significance are followed by ***, coefficient with 5%

by **, and coefficients with 10% by *.

Table 5. Effect of analyst following on informativeness of earnings

Equation (2)

ANALYST -0.1044***

ANALYST*ANALYST 0.0087***

EPS -2.3700***

ANALYST*EPS -0.2419**

ANALYST*ANALYST*EPS -0.0005**

SIZE 0.6756***

LEVERAGE 0.0062

VOLATILITY -0.0300**

PoR 0.0023**

GROWTH 0.0027***

Year Dummies Yes

No. of Observations 974

F-Value 40.01

R2 within 0.4034

6. Conclusion

This paper documents the impact of analyst following

on firm performance in the MENA region during the

period between 2005 and 2009. The results of our

analysis show that higher analyst following, indeed,

leads to better performance. We argue that lower

information asymmetries that arise as a result of high

analyst following reduce agency problems and result

in improving stock price performance of firms. We

also show that our results hold across different sub-

samples characterized by different characteristics. For

instance, we show that our results are qualitatively the

same in the common law as well as the civil law

countries. We also show that our results hold in a sub-

sample of large firms and in a sub-sample of firms

with high leverage. Interestingly, in the sub-samples

where analysts are needed the most – small firms and

firms with low leverage – our results do not hold. We

report insignificant relationship between analyst

following and firm performance in these sub-samples.

These sub-samples are characterized by higher agency

problems and therefore incremental value of analysts

should be higher in these sub-samples. Surprisingly,

we also show that low level of analyst following is

associated with lower stock price performance. It

shows that lower analyst following does not resolve

information asymmetries and agency problems.

Our results also show negative association

between earnings per share and firm performance. It

indicates low informativeness of reported earnings.

Given that higher analyst following lowers

Page 11: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

165

information asymmetries, this paper also tests whether

analyst following improves informativeness of

reported earnings or not. Our results show that high

level of analyst following does improve the quality of

reported earnings, but not to a level that it is

positively reflected in stock prices. Our results have

implications for investors, regulators, and policy

makers in a way that we show misleading information

in reported earnings. Our results indicate that earnings

alone do not convey much information to stock

market participants. Only those reported earnings that

are complemented by high analyst coverage may have

some information value.

References 1. Amir, E., Lev, B., and Sougiannis, T., (1999). What

Value Analysts? Working Paper, The Recanati

Graduate School of Management, Tel Aviv.

2. Bhattacharyya, S. and Saxena, A., (2009). Does the

Firm Size Matter? An Empirical Enquiry into the

Performance of Indian Manufacturing Firms. MPRA

Paper No. 13029, Munich Personal RePEc Archive.

3. Black, B., (2001). The Corporate Governance

Behavior and Market Value of Russian Firms.

Emerging Markets Review, 2(2), pp. 89-108.

4. Chang, H-L., Chen, Y-S., Su, C-W., and Chang, Y-W.

(2008). The Relationship between Stock Price and

EPS: Evidence Based on Taiwan Panel Data.

Economics Bulletin, 3(30), pp. 1-12.

5. Chung, K. H. and Jo, H., (1996). The Impact of

Security Analysts’ Monitoring and Marketing

Functions on the Market Value of Firms. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31(4), pp. 493-

512.

6. Claessens, S. and Fan, J. P. H., (2003). Corporate

Governance in Asia: A Survey. International Review

of Finance, 3(2), pp. 71-103.

7. Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J. P. H., and Lang, L.

H. P., (2002). Disentangling the Incentive and

Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings, Journal

of Finance, 57(6), pp. 2741-2771.

8. Dowell, G., Hart, S., and Yeung, B., (2000). Do

Corporate Global Environmental Standards Create or

Destroy Market Value? Management Science, 46(8),

pp. 1059-1074.

9. Dyck, A. and Zingales, L., (2004). Private Benefits of

Control: An International Comparison. Journal of

Finance, 59(4), pp. 537-600.

10. Erdogan, O., Palmon, D., and Yesegel, A., (2011).

Performance of Analysts Recommendation in the

Istanbul Stock Exchange. International Review of

Applied Financial Issues and Economics, 3(3), pp.

491-503.

11. Fang, V. W., Noe, T. H., and Tice, S., (2009). Stock

Market Liquidity and Firm Value. Journal of

Financial Economics, 94(1), pp. 150-169.

12. Farooq, O., (2013). Does Analyst Following Improve

Informativeness of Earnings? Evidence from the

MENA Region. Forthcoming, International Journal of

Business Governance and Ethics, 8(2).

13. Farooq, O. and Ahmed, S., (2013). Do Governance

Reforms Increase Performance of Analysts’

Recommendations? Evidence from an Emerging

Market. International Journal of Business Governance

and Ethics, 8(1), pp. 69-92.

14. Farooq, O. and Kacemi, Y., (2011). Ownership

Concentration, Choice of Auditors, and Firm

Performance: Evidence from the MENA Region.

Review of Middle East Economics and Finance, 7(2),

pp. 1-17.

15. Farooq, O. and Id Ali, L., (2012). Should Investors

Follow Analysts’ Recommendations? Evidence from

the MENA Region. Working Paper, American

University in Cairo, Egypt.

16. Giannetti, M. and Koskinen, Y., (2005). Investor

Protection and the Demand for Equity. Research

Paper No. 64/2004, European Corporate Governance

Institute.

17. Grossman, S. and Hart, O., (1980). Disclosure Laws

and Takeover Bids. Journal of Finance, 35(2), pp.

323-334.

18. Hong, H. and Kubik, J. D., (2003). Analyzing the

Analysts: Career Concerns and Biased Earnings

Forecasts. Journal of Finance, 58(1), pp. 313–351.

19. Jegadeesh, N. and Livnat, J., (2006). Revenue

Surprises and Stock Returns. Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 41(1-2), pp. 147-171.

20. Jensen, M. C., (1986). Agency Costs of Free Cash

Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American

Economic Review, 76(2), pp. 323-329.

21. Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H., (1976). Theory of

the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and

Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics

3(4), pp. 305-360.

22. Khanna, T. and Sunder, S. (1999). A Tale of Two

Exchanges. Harvard Business School Case Study.

23. Khwaja, A. I. and Mian, A., (2006). Unchecked

Intermediaries: Price Manipulation in an Emerging

Stock Market. Journal of Financial Economics, 78(1),

pp. 203-241.

24. Knyazeva, D. (2007). Corporate Governance, Analyst

Following and Firm Behavior. Working Paper, New

York University.

25. La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and

Vishny, R. W., (2000). Agency Problems and

Dividend Policies around the World. Journal of

Finance, 55(1), pp. 1-33.

26. Lang, M. H., Lins, K. V., and Miller, D. P., (2004).

Concentrated Control, Analyst Following, and

Valuation: Do Analysts Matter Most When Investors

Are Protected Least? Journal of Accounting Research,

42(3), pp. 589-623.

27. Leuz, C., Nanda, D., and Wysocki, P. D., (2003).

Earnings Management and Investor Protection: An

International Comparison. Journal of Financial

Economics, 69(3), pp. 505-527.

28. Lins, K., (2003). Equity Ownership and Firm Value in

Emerging Markets. Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, 38(1), pp. 159-184.

29. Merton, R., (1987). A Simple Model of Capital

Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Information.

Journal of Finance, 42(3), pp. 483-510.

30. Michaely, R. and Womack, K., (1999). Conflict of

Interest and the Credibility of Underwriter Analyst

Recommendations. Review of Financial Studies,

12(4), pp. 653-686.

31. Mitton, T., (2002). A Cross-firm Analysis of the

Impact of Corporate Governance on the East Asian

Financial Crisis. Journal of Financial Economics,

64(2), pp. 215-244.

Page 12: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

166

32. Nenova, T., (2003). The Value of Corporate Voting

Rights and Control: A Cross Country Analysis.

Journal of Financial Economics, 68(3), pp. 325-351.

33. Stickel, S. E., (1992). Reputation and Performance

Among Security Analysts. Journal of Finance, 47(5),

pp. 1811–1836.

Page 13: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

167

ENHANCING THE CORPORATE PERFORMANCE THROUGH SYSTEM DYNAMICS MODELLING

Mridula Sahay*, Kuldeep Kumar**

Abstract

The aim of the current study is to improve the performance of corporate through application of System Dynamics (SD) methodology. The paper discusses the importance of system dynamics modelling in enhancing corporate performance and how it shows the dynamic behaviour of the system. For this purpose a system dynamics model for an Indian Steel company has been prepared. The paper also covers a brief introduction of the system dynamics modelling, a brief narration of Steel Sector and the process adopted in modelling. Some of the important corporate performance parameters such as market share, revenue, employee’s strength, number of shareholders, installed capacity have been taken to reflect corporate behaviour. The behaviour of these performance parameters over time is used for both validation of the model as well as for reflecting their future pattern. The paper concludes that the SD modelling approach has high potential in understanding corporate performance behaviour and their by gaining insight into the corporate functioning and taking appropriate remedial steps for improving its performance. Keywords: Corporate Performance, System Dynamics, Dynamics Behaviour * Associate Professor, Amrita Business School, Amrita University, India ** Professor, Faculty of Business, Bond University, Australia

1. Introduction

Corporate performance is a very actual output or

result of a corporation as measured against its

intended outputs, which can be reflected in many

ways. Corporate performances build the image of the

corporation in front of shareholders, investors,

funding agencies, competitors; fulfil the goal of the

company etc. It also effects on the image of the board

of the corporation and their governance. It’s related to

revenue, return on investment, overhead and

operational costs. Many companies strive to be the

best in their market and most never succeed. Many of

the ones that do, so only temporarily and subsequently

lose their position through misunderstanding how

they got there and what is needed to stay there. Very

few, as Collins (2001) has stated, are capable to going

from “good to great”.

Corporate performance is viewed from the

perspective of different stakeholders as businesses

respond to contemporary developments and broader

strategic, commercial and social consideration.

Dahya, et. al. (2002), In 1992, the Cadbury

Committee issued the Code of Best Practice which

recommends that boards of U.K. corporations include

at least three outside directors and that the positions of

chairman and CEO be held by different individuals.

The underlying presumption was that these

recommendations would lead to improved board

oversight. They empirically analyse the relationship

between CEO turnover and corporate performance.

CEO turnover increased following issuance of the

Code; the negative relationship between CEO

turnover and performance became stronger following

the Code’s issuance; and the increase in sensitivity of

turnover to performance was concentrated among

firms that adopted the Code.

Richard et al. (2009) states that organizational

performance encompasses three specific areas of firm

outcomes: (a) financial performance (profits, return

on assets, return on investment, etc.); (b) product

market performance (sales, market share, etc.); and (c)

shareholder return (total shareholder return, economic

value added, etc.

Beaver (2000) states that performance appraisal

is a serious business and not some academic fad that

will fade like so much of the indulgent language and

management tools and techniques currently in vogue

at its most fundamental. Performance appraisal is the

principal means for an organization to assess the

effectiveness of its decision making. In doing this,

judgements can be made about the success or failure

of its strategic management in the context of its

organizational paradigm. The notion of corporate

success is a natural derivative of a firm’s

achievements which is in turn a reflection of the

quality of its management decisions in relation of the

quality of its management decisions in relation to

strategic objectives, market and a whole range of

internal and external circumstances. Given the

Page 14: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

168

unpredictability of these circumstances, many of the

current methods of measuring corporate performance

effectively, realistically and consistently appear to be

facile and inappropriate and subject to imaginative

financial engineering and plain management abuse.

Based upon the explanation of Majumdar (1997)

whether larger firms are superior in performance to

smaller firms, or vice-versa and whether older firms

are superior in performance to younger firms, or vice-

versa, have generated large amount of theoretical and

empirical research in the economics, management and

sociology disciplines. Cheng (2008) provides

empirical evidence that firms with larger boards have

lower variability of corporate performance. The

results indicate that board size is negatively associated

with the variability of monthly stock returns, annual

accounting return on assets, Tobin's Q, accounting

accruals, extraordinary items, analyst forecast

inaccuracy, and R&D spending, the level of R&D

expenditures, and the frequency of acquisition and

restructuring activities. The results are consistent with

the view that it takes more compromises for a larger

board to reach consensus, and consequently, decisions

of larger boards are less extreme, leading to less

variable corporate performance.

Prasetyantoko and Parmono (2008) disused that

firm size is positively related to firm profitability, but

it is not related to market capitalization and ownership

factors matters on firm performance.

Wheelen & Hunger (2002) pointed that

businesses are tending to rely less on financial

measures (which are based on Accounting Standards)

such as, profit, return on investment, and return on

assets, alone to assess over all corporate performance

Wheelen and Hunger (2002), defined

performance simply as the end result of activity. At

one level, it maybe as simple and mundane as this

definition, although at another level the notion of a

general measure of performance is both intriguing yet

continually disappointing (Bonoma & Clark 1988).

Choosing a performance measure is one of the

most critical challenges facing organizations (Ittner &

Larcker 1998). It is common for corporations to have

numerous performance measures (Neely, Adams &

Kennerley 2002), though financial measures dominate

for Autralian, UK and US executives (Phillips &

Shanak 2002; Clark 1999; Kokkinaki & Ambler

1999).

Irala (2007) states that traditionally periodic

corporate performance is most often measured using

some variant of historical accounting income (eg. Net

Profit, EPS) or some measures based on the

accounting income (eg. ROI/ ROCE). And he also

examines whether Economic Value Added has got a

better predictive power relative to the traditional

accounting measures such as EPS, ROCE, RONW,

FCF, Capital Productivity (Kp) and Labor

Productivity (Lp)

Harols and Belen (2001) investigate the relation

between the ownership structure and the performance

of corporations if ownership is made multi-

dimensional and also is treated as an endogenous

variable.

Qi, Wu, Zhang (2000), investigate whether and

how the corporate performance of listed Chinese

firms is affected by their shareholding structure.

Adams et al (2005) develop and test the hypothesis

that firms whose CEOs have more decision-making

power should experience more variability in

performance. They suggest that the interaction

between executive characteristics and organizational

variables has important consequences for firm

performance

Joy et al (2007) has shown in their research that

women representation on board increase return on

equity (ROE), return on sales (ROS), return on

investment (ROI) corporate performance. Bryan

(2007) state that companies should redesign their

financial-performance metrics for this new age.

Normally companies focus far too much on measuring

returns on invested capital (ROIC) rather than on

measuring the contributions made by their talented

people. Times have changed. Metrics must change as

well.

During the 1990s and beyond, countries around

the world witnessed calls and/or mandates for more

outside directors on publicly traded companies' boards

even though extant studies find no significant

correlation between outside directors and corporate

performance. Dahya

et. al (2007) examine the

connection between changes in board composition

and corporate performance in the U.K. over the

interval 1989–1996, a period that surrounds

publication of the Cadbury Report, which calls for at

least three outside directors for publicly traded

corporations. They find that companies that add

directors to conform to this standard exhibit a

significant improvement in operating performance

both in absolute terms and relative to various peer

group benchmarks. They also find a statistically

significant increase in stock prices around

announcements that outside directors were added in

conformance with this recommendation. They do not

endorse mandated board structures, but the evidence

appears to be that such a mandate is associated with

an improvement in performance in U.K. companies.

Norburn, and Birley, (1998) tested the

relationship between the characteristics and

background of U.S. top executives, and measures of

corporate performance. Results were generally

positive: managerial characteristics not only predicted

performance variations within industries—the top

performers having significantly different managerial

profiles than poorly performing companies—but also

that the characteristics of managers within high-

performing companies were similar across the five

industries.

Firth et al. (2006) has examined the

compensation of CEOs in China's listed firms. First,

they discuss what is known about the setting of CEO

Page 15: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

169

compensation and then we go on to examine factors

that may help explain variations in the use of

performance related pay. In China, listed firms have a

dominant or controlling shareholder. Firth et al.

(2006) argue that the distinct types of controlling

shareholder have different impacts on the use of

incentive pay. We find that firms that have a State

agency as the major shareholder do not appear to use

performance related pay. In contrast, firms those have

private block holders or SOEs as their major

shareholders relate the CEO's pay to increases in

stockholders' wealth or increases in profitability.

However the pay–performance sensitivities for CEOs

are low and this raises questions about the

effectiveness of firms' incentive systems.

Above discussion shows that corporate

performance as a whole is missing. Most of them

have worked on composition of the committee,

financial aspect of the company etc., but corporate

performance as a whole like operational performance,

financial performance has not been combined

together. The purpose of this paper is to combine both

operational as well as financial performance together

to measures the performance of the company with

using management science tools like system dynamics

(SD).

2. System Dynamics: principles and concepts

The system dynamics (SD) has been developed as

industrial dynamics approach has at MIT by Prof. J.

W. Forrester in late sixties. It amalgamates ideas

developed in various system theories. It is a branch of

control theory, which deals with socio-economic

systems and also a branch of management science,

which deals with the problems of controllability. It is

a way of studying the behaviour of any systems to

show how policies, decisions, structure and delays are

inter-related to influence growth and stability. It

integrates the separate functional areas of

management – marketing, investment, research,

personnel, production, accounting etc. Each of these

functions is reduced to a common basis by

recognizing that any economic or corporate

(candidates, instructed) activities consists of flows of

money, orders, materials, personnel, and capital

equipment. These five flows are integrated by an

information network. Industrial dynamics recognizes

the critical importance of this information network in

giving the system its own dynamics characteristics.

It combines both qualitative and quantitative

aspects to explore, realize and communicate complex

ideas. The qualitative part entails the creation of

causal relationship, in which variables are mapped in

a cause and effect relationship pattern.

The quantitative aspect involves the

development of a computer model based upon a

“stock and flow diagram, and equations which depict

interrelated variables in the system. Stock variable

(rectangles) represents the state variables and are the

accumulations in the system. Flow variables (valves)

alter the stocks by filling or draining the stocks.

Arrows point the causal relation between two

variables and also reflects the flow of information

within the model structure.

System dynamics models, however, have two

important differences which are major advantages:

1. They allow for far more complex multiple

interrelationships of variables over time, and

outcomes of those relationships are calculated by the

model rather than being done externally and inputted

in advance.

2. They can include the impact of variables

which are not normally subject to quantification. This

is done by arbitrarily assigning a value of 1.00 to a

subjective variable, and allowing it to vary based on

the management group’s expectations of what would

happen under certain conditions.

System thinking and dynamics plays an

important role in understanding the relationship

between strategic choices and its outcomes. Five

decades ago, Jay Forrester, regarded as the father of

SD, started to advocate for the application of systems

and feedback theory to the formulation of

organizational and social policies (Forrester, 1961).

Peter Senge’s The Fifth Discipline (1990) has been an

important source for understanding system thinking

and dynamics to a wide audience. SD importance is

rooted on the decision-makers limitations to fully

understand their environment and business system

realities due to three main conditions: complexity,

uncertainty, and cognition limitations (Folke, 2006).

Rather than try to optimize for a solution, the

decision-maker choose for satisfying explanations.

This is the groundwork of Simon’s “theory of

bounded rationality”, the type of rationality that a

decision-maker draws on when the situation is too

complex relative to their limited rational abilities

(Simon, 1979). He reasons that decision-making in

practice challenge existing assumptions that

“…decision-makers pursuit optimal choices in all

conditions.” For the operational strategist this

discussion implies that he/she will be only somewhat

capable of retaining and manipulating sufficiently

representative information and structural relations

during the process of strategy formulation due to the

steering of intermediaries, which may be particularly

difficult to anticipate and control (Nobs, Minkus, &

Rummert, 2007).

In SD, a system is a way of understanding any

dynamic process and many complex relations in the

organizations. SD creates a representation of the

operations choices and studies their dynamics,

facilitating the understanding of the relation between

the behavior of a system over time and its underlying

structure and decision rules. Better performing

organizations attempted to gain an understanding of

the system structure before they proceeded to develop

strategies and take action. Concisely, SD is based on a

Page 16: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

170

structural theory that offers a panorama on operations

strategy issue

Rahdari and et.al (2007) discussed the model the

effects of fluctuations in world steel price on

stockprice of one of Iranian steel producers. They also

offer some policies to mitigate the global fluctuation

effects on stock price of steel-makers in Iran

Sahay (2011) highlighted an application system

dynamics methodology and develop a cause and

effect relationship model for corporate strategy, which

has potential of integrating board parameters/variables

significant in corporate strategy development.

Kumar and Vrat (1989) discussed the application

of system dynamics to simulate the production flow in

a steel plant. The feedback concepts underlying the

model of a production shop were discussed. Models

of various shops were assembled to construct the

entire flow of the steel production system. The

applications of the model in the area of corporate

planning were discussed.

Sahay (1984) stated that system dynamics model

validation is a systematic trial-search process. He

emphasized the use of both qualitative and

quantitative criteria for model validation followed by

sensitivity testing for monitoring information

economically for the purpose of exercising desired

controls in organizational functions to achieve its

goals.

King et al (1983) conceptualized an integrated

general model of business performance that combined

the individual management disciplines of industrial

economics, reenfield theory and business policy

within the framework of a dynamics feedback model.

Measures to assess the position of a company in its

business environment and the process of strategic

choice were discussed.

King et al (1983) conceptualized an integrated

general model of business performance that combined

the individual management disciplines of industrial

economics, organisation theory and business policy

within the framework of a dynamics feedback model.

Measures to assess the position of a company in its

business environment and the process of strategic

choice were discussed.

Brugnoli (1999) states that Trainers can improve

the evaluation-decision process of management

through improving its system thinking capabilities.

Gary et al (2008) have found that there is

opportunity for system dynamics research to develop

explanations for the observed longitudinal patterns of

performance differences among firms. Such work

addresses an important issue for policy makers,

shareholders, and general managers, and would make

enormous contributions to the strategy field.

3. Objectives of the Paper

Objective of this research paper is to prepare an

integrated dynamic model for improving the

performance of Indian steel company both in its

operational performance (installed capacity actual

production, market share, manpower involved etc.) as

well as financial performance (return on investment,

expenditure and revenue etc.). Authors have chosen

system dynamics techniques for developing a model

among the availability of number of management

science tools and techniques due to its effective and

dynamics behavioural pattern.

4. Steel Industry

Steel industry is a booming industry in the whole

world. The increasing demand for it was mainly

generated by the development project that has been

going on along the world, especially the

infrastructural works and real estate projects that has

been on the boom around the developing countries.

Steel industry was till recently dominated by the

United Sates of America but this scenario is changing

with a rapid pace with the Indian steel companies on

an acquisition spree.

Steel Industry has grown tremendously in the last one

and a half decade with a strong financial condition.

The increasing needs of steel by the developing

countries for its infrastructural projects have pushed

the companies in this industry near their operative

capacity.

The main demand creators for Steel industry are

Automobile industry, Construction Industry,

Infrastructure Industry, Oil and Gas Industry, and

Container Industry.

The Steel industry has enough potential to grow

at a much accelerated pace in the coming future due to

the continuity of the developmental projects around

the world. This industry is at present working near its

productive capacity which needs to be increased with

increasing demand.

It is common today to talk about "the iron and

steel industry" as if it were a single entity, but

historically they were separate products. The steel

industry is often considered to be an indicator of

economic progress, because of the critical role played

by steel in infrastructural and overall ("Steel

Industry". Retrieved 2009-07-12.)

The economic boom in China and India has

caused a massive increase in the demand for steel in

recent years. Between 2000 and 2005, world steel

demand increased by 6%. Since 2000, several Indian

and Chinese steel firms have risen to prominence like

Tata Steel (which bought Corus Group in 2007),

Shanghai Baosteel Group Corporation and Shagang

Group. ArcelorMittal is however the world's largest

steel producer.

In 2008, steel began trading as a commodity on

the London Metal Exchange. At the end of 2008, the

steel industry faced a sharp downturn that led to many

cut-backs. (Unchiselled, Louis (2009-01-01). "Steel

Industry, in Slump, Looks to Federal Stimulus". The

New York Times. Retrieved 2012-04-15)

Page 17: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

171

Iron and steel are used widely in the construction

of roads, railways, other infrastructure, appliances,

and buildings. Most large modern structures, such as

stadiums and skyscrapers, bridges, and airports, are

supported by a steel skeleton. Even those with a

concrete structure will employ steel for reinforcing. In

addition, it sees widespread use in major appliances

and cars. Despite growth in usage of aluminium, it is

still the main material for car bodies. Steel is used in a

variety of other construction materials, such as bolts,

nails, and screws (Ochshorn, Jonathan (2002-06-11).

"Steel in 20th Century Architecture". Encyclopedia of

Twentieth Century Architecture. Retrieved 2010-04-

26.) Other common applications include shipbuilding,

pipeline transport, mining, offshore construction,

aerospace, white goods (e.g. washing machines),

heavy equipment such as bulldozers, office furniture,

steel wool, tools, and armour in the form of personal

vests or vehicle armour (better known as rolled

homogeneous armour in this role).

Authors have chosen the field of steel sector for

the study because Indian Steel sector has large

contribution in development of economic base and

industrialization in India. The demand of steel is

growing day by day due to its need in rapid

development of infrastructure, Construction

Company, power sector, telecommunication,

railways, etc.

In India both public and private sector

companies are involved in producing steel. Steel

Authority of India (SAIL), Rashtriya Ispat Nigam Ltd.

(RINL), NMDC Ltd., Maganese Ore (India) Ltd.,

MSTC Ltd., Hindustan Steel works Construction Ltd,

MECON Ltd., Bharat Regrafactories Ltd., Sponge

Iron India Ltd., Kundremukh Iron Ore Company Ltd.

are the Indian government undertaking public sector’s

steel plants and Tata Steel Ltd., Essar Steel Ltd., JSW

Steel Ltd., Jindal Steel & Power Ltd., Spat Industries

Ltd. Bhusan Power & Steel Ltd., Monnet Ispat &

Energy Ltd., Sponge Iron Industry, Pig Iron Industry,

Electric Arc Furnace Industry, Induction Furnance

Industry, Hot Rolled Long Products Units, Steel Wire

Drawing Units, Hot Rolled Steel Sheets/Strips/Plates

Units, Cold Rolled Steel Sheets/Strips Units,

Galvanised and Color Coated Sheets/strips Units, Tin

Plate Units are private sectors companies

Steel production in India has increased by a

compounded annual growth rate (CAGR) of 8 percent

over the period 2002-03 to 2006-07. Going forward,

growth in India is projected to be higher than the

world average, as the per capita consumption of steel

in India, at around 46 kg, is well below the world

average (150 kg) and that of developed countries (400

kg). Indian demand is projected to rise to 200 million

tonnes by 2015. Given the strong demand scenario,

most global steel players are into a massive capacity

expansion mode, either through brownfield or

greenfield route. By 2012, the steel production

capacity in India is expected to touch 124 million

tonnes and 275 million tonnes by 2020. While

greenfield projects are slated to add 28.7 million

tonnes, brownfield expansions are estimated to add

40.5 million tonnes to the existing capacity of 55

million tonnes.

5. System Dynamics Modelling for Corporate Performance of Indian Steel Company

Improvement in corporate performance in traditional

way primarily made through the decision makers at

various levels such as board of the corporation and the

managers of the works based on comparing and

judging various identifies factors and the corporate

performance empirically; or through factor analysis

combining methods of investigating exceptions and

drawing commonality in the pattern of the outcome

and the behaviour; or using regression analysis/multi-

variant analysis or econometric model.

These approaches provide very broadly the

future course of action without understanding intrinsic

causes. They are piece meal approach and laps

coherence and system thinking and dynamics of the

system. The application of system dynamics

methodology attempts on improvement intervention

based on system thinking and has potential to solve

complex problem. Sector-wise simulated results are

discussed below.

5.1Demand and capacity

Here, demand of product and installed capacity are

considered as a level variable. Demand of product is

31000 MT and installed capacity is 3500 MT/year in

the reference year 2001.

Figure 1 show that demand of product is

increases with demand of product increasing rate and

demand of product increasing rate is calculated by

demand rising fraction multiply by demand of product

and divided by year. Installed capacity is depend on

installation time and additional capacity multiplier.

Market share is an auxiliary variable and it has

calculated by demand of product, sales and demand

fulfilling factor.

We can see in figure 2 that demand of product in

the country and installed capacity increases every

year. It has rise from 31000 MT to 51000 MT

(64.5%) and installed capacity of the company has

increased 3500 MT to 6000 MT (71.4%) in six year.

5.2 Revenue and Expenses

In this sector, manufacturing cost, other expenses,

loans & advances are considered as level variables.

Manufacturing cost changes over the time with the

help of increase in manufacturing cost rate and

manufacturing cost rate is effected and percentage

increase in manufacturing cost per year. Similarly

other expense also changes with other expenses

increasing rate and inflation rate of general

Page 18: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

172

commodity per year. loans & advances changes.

Revenue is calculated with sales and price per TMT

and for the calculation of price per TMT, selling price

in ref year, product mix factor and ratio of current

inflation index to normal index have taken.

Board members salary and compensation, salary of

employee, annual manufacturing cost, annual other

expenses, S&A expenses, interest payment have

considered to calculated expenditure.

5.3 Corporate Performance

In this sector, authors have assumed that desired

corporate performance level should be minimum 60 in

the reference year 2001 and for the result of corporate

performance index; they also have calculated total

corporate performance with market share, profit,

installed capacity, employee, shareholders etc. and for

each variables, there is some weigthages point.

5.4 Validated criteria for the developed model

For validation, very few selected performance

indicators for enhancing the performance of corporate

has taken like employee’s strength, no. of

shareholders, installed capacity, return on investment,

market share, expenditure, revenue etc.

The validation in the system dynamics

modelling means behaviour of the model is resembles

the actual behaviour of the system. This means from

the model, some important variables are chosen and

their simulated behaviour is compared with actual

values for the reference period.

The SD model with the data collected from the

company’s report of the reference year 2001 has been

simulated. The results are observed both in the tabular

and graphical form for important variables from each

sector. By modifying some of the structural

relationships, values of some multipliers and graph

functions and simulated till acceptable model output

is obtained.

Figure 1. Demand and Capacity Stock- flow diagram

MARKET SHARE

DEMAND RISING FRACTION

ACTUAL FUND AVAILABLE

FOR INVESTMENT

DEMAND OF PRODUCT

DEMAND OF PRODUCT

INCREASING RATE

INSTALLED CAPACITY

CAPACITY INCREASING RATE DECREASE IN INSTALLED

PRODUCTION

CAPACITY RATE

ACTUAL

PRODUCTION

DESIRED PRODUCTION

CAPACITY

UTILIZATION

ANTICIPATED MARKET SHARE

SALES

INCREASE IN INSTALLED

CAPACITY DESIRED

AVERAGE CAPACITY UTILIZATION

RETAINED EARNING FOR

INVESTMENT

YEAR

SALES

INCREASE IN INSTALLED

CAPACITY DESIRED

INSTALLATION TIME

INSTALLATION COSTPER TMT

RE USE FRACTION

DEMAND FULFILLING FACTOR

INVESTMENT NEED TO INSTALLE

ADDITIONAL CAPACITY

CAPACITY ADDITION

MULTIPLIER

LOANS & ADVANCES

PROCUREMENT RATE

FINALISATION OF

CAPACITY ADDITION

DEMAND FULFILLING FACTOR

PROFIT AFTER TAX

RE INVESTMENT FRACTION

PERIOD

NORMAL CU

LOANS &ADVANCES

REQUIRED

Page 19: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

173

Figure 2. Standard run of demand of product and installed capacity of the company

Figure 3. Demand and Capacity Stock- flow diagram

9:41 PM Tue, Oct 22, 2013

Untitled

Page 1

1.00 2.25 3.50 4.75 6.00

Years

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

30

45

60

3

5

6

1: DEMAND OF PRODUCT 2: INSTALLED CAPACITY

1

1

1

1

2

2

2

2

SALES

SALES

TOTAL CORPORATE

PERFORMANCE

CORPORATE PERFORMANCE

INDEX

WEIGHTAGE ON INSTALLED CAPACITY

DESIRABLE CORPORATE

PERFORMANCE

INSTALLED CAPACITY

~

CP POINT IN % DUE TO

INSTALLED CAPACITY

INSTALLED CAPACITY

WEIGHTED POINT ON CP

NO OF EMPLOYEE

~

CP POINT IN % DUE

TO EMPLOYEE

EMPLOYEE WEIGHTED

POINT ON CP

WEIGHTAGE ON NO

OF EMPLOYEE

NO OF SHAREHOLDERS

SHAREHOLDERS

WEIGHTED POINT ON CP

~

CP POINT IN %DUE

TO SHAREHOLDERS

WEIGHTAGE ON NO

OF SHREHOLDERS 2

PROFIT AFTER TAX

WEIGHTED POINT ON CP

PROFIT AFTER TAXMARKET SHARE

MARKET SHARE

WEIGHTED POINT ON CP

WEIGTHAGE ON

MARKET SHARE

~

CP POINT IN % DUE

TO MARKET SHARE

WEIGHTAGE ON PROFIT

AFTER TAX

~

CP POINT IN % DUE

TO PROFIT AFTER TAX

PERCENT INCREASE IN

MARKET SHARE

PROFIT AFTER TAX PER TMT

EMPLOYEE PER TMT

SHAREHOLDERS PER TMT

PERCENTAGE INCREASE

IN INSTALLED CAPACITY

IC IN RY

MS IN RY

Page 20: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

174

Figure 4. Standard run of demand of product and installed capacity of the company

The process of validation progresses after having

the initial run often, if modeller finds some erroneous

and implausible results, by modifying some of the

erroneous structural relationships included in the

model by mistake or wrong assumptions or assumed

values, of some multipliers, or graph functions etc

(taken earlier with some assumptions) The model is

run for simulation again and again incorporating some

modifications each time, till valid output is obtained.

An attempt has been made to compare the model

behaviour with that of the actual data for employee,

shareholders, installed capacity, production capacity,

revenue, expenditure, return on investment, market

share etc as depicted in figures they show close

resemblance.

In the reference year installed capacity of the

company is 3500 MT and it increases year by year.

This table shows the comparison of actual vs.

simulated result.

Figure 5. The comparison of actual vs. simulated result

9:43 PM Tue, Oct 22, 2013

Untitled

Page 1

1.00 2.25 3.50 4.75 6.00

Years

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

2500

5000

7500

1500

5000

8500

1: EXPENDITURE 2: PROFIT AFTER TAX

1

1

1

1

2

2

2

2

Page 21: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

175

5.5 Future Projection

For knowing the corporate performance in future

years say (2008 to 2017), reference year has been

changed to the year 2006-2007 and initial values of

variables and some other values taken accordingly,

keeping other values and relationships is structure of

the model unchanged for simulation. This means

without modify the structure of the model, the model

is run for simulation for next ten years.

The projected result shows for next ten years i.e.

2017, in 2007 installed capacity of the company is

6,000 MT/ year and it shall be double after 3 years

(2010) and in 2017 it shall be 22,950 MT. Even

company wants to double its capacity by 2010.

Demand of product in the country is shall be

from 51,000 MT to 110,000 MT from 2007 to 2017.

11th

Five Year Plan of India (ministry of steel) and

National Steel Policy of India indicated the demand

growth will be 121,000 MT by 2019.

Figure 6. Future projected result of demand of product, installed capacity and actual production of the

company

6. Conclusion

System Dynamics is a powerful method to gain useful

insight into situations of dynamic complexity and

policy resistance. It is increasingly used to design

successful policies in companies and public policy

settings. In this paper we reported an ongoing

research effort to study the performance of corporate.

iThink©

software has been extensively used to

develop a comprehensive system dynamics model of

corporate performance. We have also utilised the

computer simulation tools of the software to handle

the high complexity of the resulting feedback model.

System dynamics model for the corporate

performance developed has been put to generate

model behaviour by simulating using solution interval

1 year and 6 years as simulation run length with initial

values for the year 2001. For future projection,

solution interval is 1 and simulation length is 10 yrs

with initial value for the year 2007.

The performance of corporate lies not only in

having efficient plan but by implementing the plan

efficiently to enhance the desired performance

without much of deviations.

References

1. Beaver G. (2000), Strategy, performance and

governance: the sensitivity of remuneration, Journal of

Strategic Change 9(6): September/October, 327-331

2. Bonoma, T. V. & Clark, B. H., 1998, Marketing

Performance Assessment”, Harvaed Business School

Press, Boston.

3. Brayn, Lowell L. (2007) The new metrics of corporate

performance: Profit per employee, Mckinsey Quaterly

4. Brown D.Michael (1994) Measuring corporate

performance, Long Range Planning, Volume 27, Issue

4, August 1994, Pages 89–98

5. Brugnoli Carlo (1999), System Thinking and

Corporate Stagey, System Dynamics conference

Procedding, 1999

6. Cheng, Shijun (2008), Board size and the variability of

corporate performance, Journal of Financial Economics,

Volume 87, Issue 1, January 2008, Pages 157–176

7. Clark, B. H. 1999, “Marketing Performance Measures:

History and Interrelationships”, Journal of Marketing

Management, Vol. 15, pp. 711-732.

8. Collins, Jim (2001) Good to Great: Why Some

Companies Make the Leap...and Others Don’t,Random

House

9. Coyle R. G., (1972), The Dynamics of a Mining

Enterprise, 10th International Conference on decision

making in the Mineral Industry, Johannesburg.

10. Dahya, Jay; McConnell, John J.; Travlos, Nickolaos G.

(2002), The Cadbury Committee, Corporate

Performance, and Top Management Turnover, The

Journal of Finance, Volume 57, Issue 1, pages 461–483,

9:38 PM Tue, Oct 22, 2013

Untitled

Page 1

0.00 2.50 5.00 7.50 10.00

Years

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

3:

3:

3:

50

90

130

5

15

25

1: DEMAND OF PRODUCT 2: INSTALLED CAPACITY 3: ACTUAL PRODUCTION

1

1

1

1

2

2

2

2

3

3

3

3

Page 22: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

176

11. Dahya , Jay and McConnell, John J. (2007), Board

Composition, Corporate Performance, and the Cadbury

Committee Recommendation, Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, 42 : pp 535-564

12. Dangerfield B. C., (1986), System Dynamics as an aid

to the present day Corporate Strategic Policy Making,

2nd European Simulation Congress, Antwerp, Belgium.

13. Daqing Qi, Woody Wu, Hua Zhang (2000),

Shareholding structure and corporate performance of

partially privatized firms: Evidence from listed Chinese

companies, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal Volume 8,

Issue 5, Pages 587-610

14. Fey W. R., (1962), An Industrial Dynamics Case study,

Industrial Management Review, 4(1), PP 79-99.

15. Firth, Michael; Fung, Peter M.Y.; Rui Oliver M. (2006),

Corporate performance and CEO compensation in

China, Journal of Corporate Finance, Volume 12, Issue

4, September 2006, Pages 693–714

16. Folke, C. (2006). Resilience: The emergence of a

perspective for social–ecological systems analyses .

Global Environmental Change , 253-267 .

17. Forrester, J. (1961). Industrial Dynamics. Cambridge,

MA: MIT Press.

18. Gary, Michael Shayne; Kunc, Martin; Morecroft John

D. W. and Rockart, Scott F. (2008) System Dynamics

and Strategy, System Dynamics Review. 24, 407–429

19. Guest, David E.; Michie, Jonathan; Conway, Neil;

Sheehan, Maura (2003), Human Resource Management

and Corporate Performance in the UK, British Journal

of Industrial Relations, Volume 41, Issue 2, pages 291–

314,

20. Harold Demsetz and Belén Villalonga, (2001)

Ownership structure and corporate performance, Journal

of Corporate Finance, Volume 7, Issue 3, Pages 209-

233

21. http://steel.gov.in/overview.htm

22. http://steel.nic.in

23. http://steel.nic.in/dev2.htm

24. http://www3.inderscience.wiley.com/cgi-

bin/fulltext/85009266/PDFSTART

25. Irala, Lokanandha Reddy, Corporate Performance

Measures in India: An Empirical

26. Analysis, WP-2007/01/A available at

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=964

375

27. Ittner, C. D. & Larcker, D. F., 1998,”Innovations in

Performance Measurement: Trends and Research

Implication”, Journal of Management Accounting

Research, Vol. 10, pp. 205-238.

28. Joy, Lois; Carter, Nancy M; Wagner, Harvey M.; and

Narayanan Sriram (2007) The Bottom Line: Corporate

Performance and Women's Representation on Boards,

Catalyst Inc USA

29. Kalpan, R. S. & Norton, D. P., 1992, “The Balanced

Scorecard – Measures that Drive Performance”,

Harvard Business Review, January-February, pp. 71-79.

30. King P. D. A., Coyle R. G. and Wolstenholme E. F.,

(1983), A General System Model of Business

Performance, Proc. of the 1983, International System

Dynamics Conference, MIT, USA.

31. King P. D. A., Coyle R. G. and Wolstenholme E. F.,

(1983), A General System Model of Business

Performance, Proc. Of the 1983, International System

Dynamics Conference, MIT, USA.

32. Kokkinaki, F. & Ambler, T., 1999, “Marketing

Performance Assessment: An Exploratory Investigation

into current Practice and the Role of Firm Orientation”,

Marketing Science Institute, Working Paper, No. 99-

114.

33. Kumar R. and Vrat P., (1989), Using Computer Model

of Material Flow-Case of a Steel Plant, Proc.

International System Dynamics Conference, MIT, USA.

34. Legasto A. A and Maciariello J., (1980) System

Dynamics: A Critical Review, TIMS Studies in the

Management Science 14, PP 23-24.

35. Majumdar, S. (1997), “The Impact of Size and Age on

Firm-level Performance: Some Evidence from India”,

Review of Industrial Organization 112, 231-242

36. Mandal Purnendu, Love, Peter E. D., Gunasekaran, A.

(2002) , Towards a system dynamics modelling

framework for quality in manufacturing, International

Journal of Manufacturing Technology and Management

2002 - Vol. 4, No.3/4 pp. 333-343

37. Milling P. M., (1988), Subjective Knowledge Bases in

Corporate Policy Making, Proc. of the 1988

International Conference of System Dynamics Society,

La Jolla, CA.

38. Neely, A., Adams, C. & Kennerley, M. 2002, “The

Performance prim – the scorecard for measuring and

managing business success”, FT Prentice Hall, London.

39. Norburn, David; Birley, Sue (1998), The top

management team and corporate performance, Strategic

Management Journal, Volume 9, Issue 3, pages 225–

237,

40. Nobs, A., Minkus, A., & Rummert, A. (2007).

Implementing and Controlling an Operations Strategy in

Global Industrial Service Networks. In Advances in

Production Management Systems (pp. 19-26). Boston:

Springer

41. Perelman L.J., (1980), Time in System Dynamics,

TIMS Studies in Management Science 14, PP 75-89.

42. Phillillips, B. & Shanka, T., 2002, “Balanced Scorecard

(BSC) Measures in Small and Medium Enterprises

(SMEs) – An Exploratory Study”, in R. Shaw, S. Adam

& H. McDonald (eds.). Proceedings of the Australian

and New Zealand Marketing Academy Conference

(ANZMAC) 2002, Melbourne, Australia, pp. 2452-

2456.

43. Prasetyantoko, A. and Parmono, R. (2008),

“Determinants of Corporate Performance of Listed

Companies in Indonesia” from http://mpra.ub.uni-

mucnchen.de/6777/MPRA-paper-6777.pdf

44. Rahdari, Hossein; Forouzan, Alireza; Ramezankhani,

Atefeh; Foroughi Pouyan (2007), Analyzing the Effect

of Global Steel Price Fluctuation on Iran's Steel-Maker

Stock Prices: A System Dynamics Approach, retrieved (

may 2012) from

http://www.systemdynamics.org/conferences/2009/proc

eed/papers/P1137.pdf

45. Renée B. Adams, Heitor Almeida, Daniel Ferreira

(2005), Powerful CEOs and Their Impact on Corporate

Performance, Review of Financial Studies, Volume18,

Issue4, Pp. 1403-1432 available at

http://rfs.oxfordjournals.org/content/18/4/1403.short

46. Reserve Bank of India’s Report,

2001,2002,2003,2004,2005,2006,2007

47. Richard et al. (2009): Measuring Organizational

Performance: Towards Methodological Best Practice.

Journal of Management.

48. Roberts N., (1983), Computer Simulation using System

Dynamics, Adison-Wesley, Reading, Massachusetts.

49. Sahay, Mridula (2011) Corportat Strategy through

System Dynamics, System thinking and System

Page 23: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

177

Dynamics, System Thinking and System Dynamics,

Macmillan Publishers India Ltd., India pp. 64-75

50. Sahay S. S., (1984), Some Studies on a Comprehensive

Procedure for corporate Long Range Planning Using

System Dynamics and Goal Programming Techniques,

Ph. D. Thesis, Indian Institute of Technology,

Kharagpur.

51. Senge, P. (1990). The Fifth Discipline. Garden City,

NY: Doubleday Currency.

52. Sheth, J. N. & Sisodia, R. S., 1995, “Feeling the Heat”,

Marketing Management, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 8-23.

53. Simon, H. (1979). Rational Decision Making in

Business Organizations. The American Economic

Review , 493-513 .

54. Spencer R. S., (1966), Modeling Strategies for

Corporate Growth, Conf. of American Association for

the Advancement of Science, Washington D. C.

55. Sterman, J. D. 2003. Business Dynamics: Systems

Thinking and Modelling for a Complex World, McGraw

Hill

56. Steve Engelen, Hilda Meersman, & Eddy Van De

Voorde (2006), Using system dynamics in maritime

economics: an endogenous decision model for

shipowners in the dry bulk sector, Maritime Policy &

Management, Volume 33, Issue 2, pp 141-158

57. Vij A. K., Vrat P., Sushil, (1987), Application of

System Dynamics to Energy Modeling in the National

Economy – Conceptual Framework, Proc. Second

National Conference on System Dynamic Varanasi,

January 15-17, 1987.

58. Wheelen, T. L. & Hunger, D. J., 2002, “Startegic

Management and business policy” 8th Ed. Prentice Hall,

New Jersey.

59. Wiener N., (1948), Cybernetics on Control and

Communication in the Animal and Machine, MIT Press.

60. Wolstenholme E. F. and Coyle C. G., (1983), The

Development of System Dynamics as a Methodology

for System Description and Quantitative Analysis, Jr.

Operations Research Society, 34(7), PP 569-581.

61. Wright R. D., (1971), Industrial Dynamics

Implementation: Growth Strategies for a Trucking Firm,

Sloan Management reviews. 13(1), PP 71-86.

62. www.tatasteel.com

63. .World Steel Industry, Economic Watch June 2010,

retrieved from http://www.economywatch.com/world-

industries/steel-industry/?page=full on May 2012

Page 24: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

178

THE EFFECT OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ON BANK FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE: EVIDENCE FROM THE

ARABIAN PENINSULA

Mohamed A. Basuony*, Ehab K. A. Mohamed**, Ahmed M Al-Baidhani***

Abstract

This paper investigates the effect of internal corporate governance mechanisms and control variables, such as bank size and bank age on bank financial performance. The sample of this study comprises of both conventional and Islamic banks operating in the seven Arabian Peninsula countries, namely Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, and Yemen. Regression analysis (OLS) is used to test the effect of corporate governance mechanisms on bank financial performance. The results of this study reveal that there is a significant relationship between corporate governance and bank profitability. Board size, board activism, number of outside directors, and bank age significantly affect Tobin’s Q. Meanwhile, ROA and PM are affected by ownership concentration, audit committee, audit committee meetings, and the age & size of the bank. The results are consistent with previous literature that the correlation between corporate governance and firm performance is still not clearly established and that impact of corporate governance on bank financial performance in developing countries is still relatively limited. Keywords: Board Structure, Ownership Structure, Audit Committee, Corporate Governance Mechanisms, Bank Performance, GCC, Yemen * American University in Cairo, Egypt ** Professor of Accounting & Vice of Academic Affairs, Faculty of Management Technology, German University in Cairo, New Cairo, Post Code: 11835, Cairo, Egypt Tel.: 20 227590764 Fax: 20 227581041 Email: [email protected]*** German University in Cairo, Egypt

1. Introduction

Corporate governance has become one of the most

topical issues in the modern business world today.

Spectacular corporate failures, such as those of Enron,

Worldcom, Barlow Clows and Levitt, the Bank of

Credit and Commerce International (BCCI), Polly

Peck International and Baring Bank, have made it a

central issue, with various governments and

regulatory authorities making efforts to install

stringent governance regimes to ensure the smooth

running of corporate organizations, and prevent such

failures. A corporate governance system is defined as

a more-or-less country-specific framework of legal,

institutional and cultural factors shaping the patterns

of influence that shareholders (or stakeholders) exert

on managerial decision-making. Corporate

governance mechanisms are the methods employed, at

the firm level, to solve corporate governance

problems.

Corporate governance is viewed as an

indispensable element of market discipline (Levitt

1999) and this is fuelling demands for strong

corporate governance mechanisms by investors and

other financial market participants (Blue Ribbon

Committee 1999; Ramsay 2001). Regulators have

enacted corporate governance reforms into law in

many countries such as the USA (Sarbanes-Oxley

Act, 2002). In other countries such UK (Combined

Code of Corporate Governance, 2003) the corporate

governance codes are principles of best practice with

some indirect element of legislature operating through

the respective stock exchange listing rules. For the

banking sector, Basel II is widely adopted by

developing and emerging market economies to

enhance their CG codes.

Bank governance was altered tremendously

during the 1990s and early 2000s, principally due to

bank ownership changes, such as mergers and

acquisitions (Berger et al. 2005; and Arouri et al.

2011). The worldwide financial crisis of 2008, which

started in the United States, was attributable to U.S.

banks’ excessive risk-taking. Consequently, in order

to control such risk and draw people’s attention to the

agency problem within banks, there are statements

made by bankers, central bank officials, and other

related authorities, emphasizing the importance of

effective corporate governance in the banking

industry since 2008 and until now (Beltratti and Stulz

2009; and Peni and Vahamaa 2011). Therefore, any

Page 25: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

179

similar crisis occurred or may occur in the future

might be explained as a result of bank governance

failure. Few studies have focused on banks’ corporate

governance (see Macey and O’Hara, 2003; Levine,

2004; Adams and Mehran, 2005; Capiro et al. 2007;

Bokpin, 2013; Nyamongo and Temesgen, 2013).

This study focuses on banks operating in Yemen

and the GCC countries in order to provide empirical

evidence on the effects of corporate governance on

bank performance. The rest of the paper is organised

as follows: the following section provides a

theoretical background and hypotheses development.

The research methodology is provided in section 3,

followed by the findings and analysis in section 4; and

finally summary & conclusion are provided in

section 5.

2. Theoretical Background and Hypotheses Development

2.1 Background

Traditional finance literature has indicated several

mechanisms that help solve corporate governance

problems (Jensen and Meckling (1976); Fama (1980);

Fama and Jensen (1983); Jensen (1986); Jensen

(1993); and Turnbull (1997). There is a consensus on

the classification of corporate governance

mechanisms to two categories: internal and external

mechanisms. However, there is a dissension on the

contents of each category and the effectiveness of

each mechanism. In addition, the topic of corporate

governance mechanisms is too vast and rich research

area to the extent that no single paper can survey all

the corporate governance mechanisms developed in

the literature and instead the papers try to focus on

some particular governance mechanisms.

Jensen (1993) outlines four basic categories of

individual corporate governance mechanisms: (1)

legal and regulatory mechanisms; (2) internal control

mechanisms; (3) External control mechanisms; and

(4) product market competition. Shleifer and Vishny

(1997) concentrate on: incentive contracts, legal

protection for the investors against the managerial

self-dealing, and the ownership by large investors;

they point out the costs and benefits of each

governance mechanism. Denis and McConnell (2003)

use a dual classification of corporate governance

mechanisms (They use systems as synonym to

mechanisms) as follows: (1) internal governance

mechanisms including: boards of directors and

ownership structure and (2) external ones including:

the takeover market and the legal regulatory system.

Farinha (2003) surveys two categories of

governance (or disciplining) mechanisms, the first one

is the external disciplining mechanisms including:

takeovers threat; product market competition;

managerial labour market and mutual monitoring by

managers; security analysts; the legal environment;

and the role of reputation. The other category is the

internal disciplining mechanisms which include: large

and institutional shareholders; board of directors;

insider ownership; compensation packages; debt

policy; and dividend policy.

Despite the existence of different corporate

governance structures, the basic building blocks of the

structures are similar. They include the existence of a

Company, Directors, Accountability and Audit,

Directors’ Remuneration, Shareholders and the AGM.

Cadbury (1992), Greenbury (1995) and Hampel

(1998) called for greater transparency and

accountability in areas such as board structure and

operation, directors’ contracts and the establishment

of board monitoring committees. In addition, they all

stressed the importance of the non-executive

directors’ monitoring role. The relationship between

corporate performance and corporate governance is

measured using only one of the two variables:

ownership structure and board structure (Krivogorsky,

2006).

Much of the empirical findings on corporate

governance and performance in non-financial

institutions are also applicable to financial

institutions. However, the optimal designing of bank

governance structure is very complex and important

relative to unregulated, non-financial firms for several

reasons. Mullineux (2006) argues that good CG of

banks requires prudential risk-related regulation and

attention to conflicts of interest and competition

issues, particularly given the clear information

advantage of banks over their retail customers. Banks

are prudentially regulated and highly levered

compared to other companies and hence bank

governance deserves special attention (Adams and

Mehran 2003).

Moreover, the stakeholders’ interests at banks

extend beyond the shareholders’ interests since the

bank depositors, creditors, and regulators have stakes

in the banks as well. In addition to shareholders and

managers, depositors and regulators have a straight

stake in bank performance. Griffiths (2007) argues

that borrowers have a legitimate claim on banks by

entering in lending agreements, acquire power and

urgency through their cause being adopted by other

stakeholders such as regulators and consumer

organisations. These stakeholders enjoy all three of

Mitchell et al. (1997) stakeholder attributes: power,

legitimacy and urgency (Yamak and Su¨er, 2005;

Griffiths, 2007). Governments are also worried about

banks reputations, and consequently regulate their

governance, because a bank’s failure negatively

affects the respective country’s economy, and may

even spread globally, similar to what happened during

the 1997 Asian financial crisis (Pathan et al. 2008)

and the 2008 U.S. financial crisis (Peni and Vahamaa

2011).

Abu-Tapanjeh (2009) compares the OECD

corporate governance principles with principles from

Islam and declares them compatible; he points out

that Islam as applied to business is entirely

Page 26: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

180

compatible with corporate governance. Honesty and

trust that are key ingredients of an effective

governance framework (OECD, 2004) are also basic

to ethical behaviour in the Islamic Sharia (Gambling

and Karim, 1991; Tan, 2006; Taylor, 2008;

Mohammed, 2009). Hence the first research

hypothesis is:

H1: There is no difference in adopting CG

mechanisms between Islamic banks and

conventional banks.

2.2 Board Structure

The board of directors is typically the governing body

of the organization. Its primary responsibility is to

make sure that the organization achieves the

shareholders’ goal. The board of directors has the

power to hire, terminate, and compensate top

management (Johnson et al. 2008). Therefore, it

safeguards the organization’s assets and invested

capital. In addition to setting the bank’s objectives

(including generating returns to shareholders), the

board of directors and senior management affect how

banks run their daily operations, meet the obligation

of accountability to bank’s shareholders, and consider

the interests of other recognized stakeholders (Basel

Committee, 2004).

Nonetheless, there is a debate regarding the

effect of board composition on firm performance

(Dulewicz and Herbert, 2004; De Andres et al., 2005;

Ehikioya, 2009; Mohamed et al., 2013). Bhagat and

Black (2002) find a negative relationship between the

proportion of outside directors and corporate

performance. Moreover, Yermack (1996) reported

evidence that a higher percentage of independent

directors leads to worse performance. In addition,

Klein (2002) suggests that high percentage of outside

directors will have the same negative effect. On the

other hand, several studies do not show any evidence

of an existing relationship between the proportion of

non-executive directors and firm performance (Dalton

et al., 1998; Vafeas and Theodorou 1998; Laing and

Weir, 1999). Pi and Timme (1993) find that banks

cost efficiency and return on assets are not

significantly related to the proportion of inside

(outside) directors. While Alonso and Gonzalez

(2006) document a positive relation between the

proportion of non-executive directors and bank

performance.

Moreover, several studies reveal that there is

negative relation between the size of the board and

performance (Hermalin and Weisbach, 1991;

Eisenberg et al, 1998; Carline et al, 2002; Mak and

Yuanto, 2003). Larger boards seems to be less

efficient due to the slow pace of decision making and

the difficulty in both arranging board meeting and

reaching consensus. It is also argued that the CEO

seems to have more dominant power when the board

size is too large (Jensen, 1993; Yermack, 1996;

Eisenberg et al, 1998; Singh and Davidson, 2003;

Cheng, 2008). Staikouras et al. (2007) report ROA

and ROE are statistically significant and negatively

related to board size in European Banks. However,

Huang (2010) finds positive significant relationship

between the size of the board and bank performance

in Taiwan.

It is not only the size of the board that seems to

have a governing effect on firm performance, it is

argued that the board composition in terms of the

number of outside directors versus inside directors

results in better performance through better

monitoring. This argument is mainly based on the

agency theory (Fama 1980; Demsetz and Lehn, 1985).

Several studies find that the larger the number of

outside directors on the board, the better the firm

performance (Rosenstein and Wyatt, 1990; Weisbach,

1988; Huson, 2001; Mohamed et al., 2013). Huang

(2010) finds positive significant relationship between

the number of outside directors and bank performance

in Taiwan.

On the other hand, some argue that based on the

stewardship theory executive directors have a positive

effect on corporate R&D costs and better performance

based on improved strategic innovation (Donaldson,

1990; Kochar and David, 1996; Davis et al, 1997).

Several studies reveal negative relation between the

number of outside directors and firm performance

(Agrawal and Knoeber, 1996; Kochar and David,

1996; Bhagat and Black, 2002). Meanwhile, several

other studies find no significant relation between the

number of outside directors and corporate

performance (Hermalin and Weibach, 1991; Dalton et

al, 1998; Vafeas and Theodorou, 1998; Laing and

Weir, 1999; Lam and Lee, 2012). Further explanation

is provided by Adams and Ferreira (2007) who

suggest that CEOs may be reluctant to share

information with more independent boards, thereby

decreasing shareholder value.

Based on the agency perspective the separation

of the roles of CEO from chairman is another crucial

monitoring mechanism. CEO duality is problematic

from an agency perspective as the CEO seems to get

dominant influence on board decisions by chairing the

group of people in charge of monitoring and

evaluating his performance. This in effect results in

weakening the board's independency and may result

in ineffective monitoring of management. Therefore

good governance will occur when the two roles of

Chairman and CEO are separated (Baliga and Rao,

1996; Brickley et al, 1997; Coles and Hesterly, 2000;

Weir and Laing, 2001; William et al. 2003).

Rechner and Dalton (1989) find no significant

differences in firm performance between separated

leadership structure firms and combined leadership

structure firms over a five year period. However,

further study of the same sample reveal that firms

with separated leadership structure have higher

performance than the firms with combined leadership

Page 27: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

181

structure measured with ROE, ROI and profit margin

(Rechner and Dalton, 1991).

Saundaramurthy et al. (1997) provide evidence

that separating the positions will affect the

shareholder wealth positively. Moreover, Coles and

Hesterly (2000) find that firms that separate CEOs

and board chairs will have better stock returns than

firms that do not separate the two roles. On the other

hand, Baliga and Rao (1996) do not find sufficient

evidence to support a performance distinction

between separated and combined leadership firms

when the performance was measured using the market

value added (MVA) and economic value added

(EVA) as performance indicators.

Audit committees are identified as effective

means for corporate governance that reduce the

potential for fraudulent financial reporting (NCFFR,

1987). Audit committees oversee the organization’s

management, internal and external auditors to protect

and preserve the shareholders’ equity and interests.

To ensure effective corporate governance, the audit

committee report should be included annually in the

organization’s proxy statement, stating whether the

audit committee has reviewed and discussed the

financial statements with the management and the

internal auditors. As a corporate governance monitor,

the audit committee should provide the public with

correct, accurate, complete, and reliable information,

and it should not leave a gap for predictions or

uninformed expectations (BRC, 1999). The BRC

report provides recommendations and guiding

principles for improving the performance of audit

committees that should ultimately result in better

corporate governance. The importance of the audit

function in terms of the audit committee and audit

firm is further strengthened by the Sarbanes-Oxley

Act of 2002. The discussion above leads us to the

second research hypothesis:

H2: There is a significant relationship between board

structure and bank performance.

5.3 Ownership Structure

Cole and Mehran (1998) find that changes in

performance are significantly associated with changes

in insider ownership. They document that the greater

the increase in insider ownership, the greater the

performance improvement, which is consistent with

the alignment of interests hypothesis arising from a

larger insider ownership. Also consistent with that

hypothesis of Subrahmanyam et al (1997) who find

evidence, in a sample of successful bidders in bank

acquisitions, of a positive association between bidder

returns and the level of insider ownership when the

latter exceeds 6%.

Large shareholders and institutional investors

can be seen as potential controllers of equity agency

problems as their increased shareholdings can give

them a stronger incentive to monitor firm

performance and managerial behavior (Demsetz,

1983; Demsetz and Lehn 1985; and Shleifer and

Vishny, 1986; Shleifer and Vishny, 1997, La Porta et

al, 1998; La Porta et al, 1999; Claessens et al, 2000,

and Denis and McConnell, 2003). This potentially

helps to circumvent the free rider-problem associated

with ownership dispersion.

Equity agency costs can be reduced by

increasing the level of managers' stock ownership,

which may permit a better alignment of their interests

with those of shareholders. In fact, in the extreme case

where the manager's share ownership is 100%, equity

agency costs are reduced to zero (Jensen and

Meckling, 1976). As managerial ownership increases,

managers bear a large fraction of the costs of shirking,

perquisite consumption and other value-destroying

actions. Further, larger share ownership by managers

reduces the problem of different horizons between

shareholders and managers if share prices adjust

rapidly to changes in firm’s intrinsic value.

A limitation, however, of this mechanism as a

tool for reducing agency costs is that managers may

not be willing to increase their ownership of the firm

because of constraints on their personal wealth.

Additionally, personal risk aversion also limits the

extension of this monitoring device as the allocation

of a large portion of the manager's wealth to a single

firm is likely to translate into a badly diversified

portfolio (Beck and Zorn, 1982).

In accordance with the proposition that larger

managerial ownership reduce agency costs, Kaplan

(1989) finds that following large management

buyouts, firms experience significant improvements

in operating performance. He interprets this evidence

as suggesting that operating changes were due to

improved management incentives instead of layoffs or

managerial exploitation of shareholders through

inside information. Smith (1990) reports similar

results and notes that the amelioration observed in

operating performance is not due to reductions in

discretionary expenditures such as research and

development, advertising, maintenance or property,

plant and equipment. Macus (2008) argues that the

basic issue from an agency perspective is how to

avoid such opportunistic behaviour. Previous studies

suggest that corporate governance is an effective tool

to control the opportunistic behaviour of management

(Denis and McConnell, 2003; Bhagat and Bolton,

2008; Chen et al., 2009).

Research by Morck et al (1988), McConnell and

Servaes (1990) and Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) is

also consistent with the view that insider ownership

can be an effective tool in reducing agency costs,

although they report a non- monotonic relation. This

functional form has been related to the observation

that, within a certain ownership range, managers may

use their equity position to entrench themselves

against any disciplining attempts from other

monitoring mechanisms. Spong and Sullivan (2007)

reveal that boards of directors are likely to have a

Page 28: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

182

more positive effect on community bank performance

when directors have a significant financial interest in

the bank. However, some other studies find no

evidence of a positive relationship between insider

ownership and performance (see, for instance,

Demsetz and Lehn, 1985; Loderer and Sheehan, 1989;

Holderness and Sheehan, 1988; Denis and Denis,

1994; and Loderer and Martin, 1997).

A possible explanation for these mixed results is

that many of the studies do not properly distinguish

the possibility of alignment of interests across a

certain range of ownership values and of

entrenchment over another range. Furthermore, these

analyses usually do not take into account the

possibility that several different mechanisms for

alignment of interests can be used simultaneously,

with substitution effects with insider ownership. It is

quite conceivable that different firms may use

different mixes of corporate governance devices

(Rediker and Seth, 1995). These different mixes can,

however, all be optimal as a result of varying

marginal costs and benefits of the several monitoring

instruments available for each firm. If so, then one

would not be able to observe a relationship between

performance and any of these particular mechanisms.

It appears that the main conflict is between owners

and managers in common law countries due to the

existence of dispersed control and ownership

structures. While, in civil law countries the control

and ownership structures are concentrated, thus the

main governance problem arises between minority

and controlling shareholders. Therefore, ownership

structure has greater importance in civil law countries

where protection of shareholders right is weak (La

Porta et al., 1998; Beck et al., 2003). The situation is

more prevalent in developing countries where large

concentration of ownership is more evident while the

stock markets are weak. In those countries there is a

higher degree of economic uncertainties coupled with

weak legal controls and investor protection, and

frequent government intervention; all resulting in

poor performance (Ahunwan, 2002; Rabelo and

Vasconcelos, 2002; Tsamenyi et al; 2007).

Similar results are prevalent in the banking

sector in the GCC countries where most ownership

and control in substantial family corporate holdings

and boards of directors are largely dominated by

controlling shareholders, their friends and relatives.

There are few independent directors on boards and

shareholders dominate the decision-making process as

there is rarely any separation between ownership and

management. In most cases the chairman of the board

is also the CEO; and there is a general lack of

transparency and disclosure which leads to the

conclusion that a high concentration of corporate

ownership undermines the principles of good

corporate governance (The Union of Arab Banks,

2003; Yasin and Shehab, 2004). Based on the above

discussion, the third research hypothesis is:

H3: There is a significant relationship between

ownership structure and bank performance.

3. Research Methodology 3.1 The method

In order to test the hypotheses, quantitative method is

used to investigate the effects of corporate governance

mechanisms on bank performance. CG mechanisms

include (ownership concentration, director ownership,

duality, board size, board non-executives, board

activism, audit committee and audit committee

meetings), and other control variables, such as bank

size, age and type of banks. The bank performance is

measured by Tobin’s Q, ROA, and Profit Margin.

Bankscope database is used to select the country,

Yemen and six GCC countries, and selected the top

fifty banks from the above seven countries, as shown

in table (1). It is also used the respective banks’

websites and other websites to extract the relevant

financial and non-financial information about each

bank from its published audited financial statements,

annual reports, and other relevant information.

3.2 Sampling and data collection

The sample includes conventional and Islamic banks

operating in Yemen and the six GCC countries using

the data for the year 2011. Excluded from the sample

are banks that do not have audited financial

statements. Financing, insurance, or non-bank

institutions are excluded since they are different from

banks with respect to their specific characteristics,

management structures, accounting procedures, and

audit functions. Table (1) below shows the population

and samples selected per country.

The final sample consists of the largest 50

conventional and Islamic banks operating in Yemen

and the six GCC countries. The process of selecting

this sample is based on the values of these banks’

total assets and the consequent ranking stated by

Bankscope database. Any bank excluded due to any

of the above reasons has been replaced with the next

immediate bank in ranking. Table (2) summarizes the

sample selection.

3.3 Measurement of variables

For bank performance measurement, the dependent

variables used are Tobin’s Q, ROA, and Profit

Margin. Meanwhile, the independent variables used in

regard to corporate governance mechanisms are

ownership concentration, director ownership, duality,

board size, board non executive, board activism, audit

committee and audit committee meetings. Other

control variables include bank type, bank age, and

bank size. Table (3) shows the definition and

measurement of these variables.

Page 29: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

183

Table 1. Population and samples per country

Country Population* (Banks only) Sample Size Sample Size (%)

Bahrain 29 14 48%

Kuwait 10 7 70%

Oman 7 7 100%

Qatar 7 7 100%

Saudi Arabia 12 9 75%

United Arab Emirates 19 7 37%

Yemen 11 8 73%

Total 95 59 62% *Information from Bankscope Database

Table 2. Sample selection

Number of banks selected from Bankscope Database based on its ranking for 2011 and the number of

banks in each country

59

No annual reports available for 2011 (3)

No sufficient data about bank (6)

Final sample

Final sample (%)

50

53%

Table 3. Definition and measurement of variables

Variable Symbol Definition Measurement

Dependent Variables

TobinQ Tobin’s Q MVE + PS + Debt / TA (as per Chung and Pruitt,

1994)

ROA Return on Assets Net Income / Total Assets

PM Profit Margin Net Income / Revenues

Independent Variables

OwnCon Ownership Concentration Adding up all shareholding of 5% or more

DirOwn Director Ownership Director ownership = 1; otherwise = 0

Brdsize Board Size Total number of board members during 2011

Duality CEO Duality If the CEO and Chairman are the same person = 0;

otherwise = 1

BrdNonEx

Number of Non-Executives

on Board

Number of non-executive members on the board

during 2011

BrdActivism Board Activism Number of board meetings held during 2011

AC Audit Committee If Audit Committee exists = 1; otherwise = 0

ACmeetings Number of Audit Committee

Meetings per Year

Number of audit committee meetings during 2011

Control Variables

TYPE Bank Type Conventional bank = 1; Islamic = 0

AGE Age of Bank In years: 10 or more = 1; less than 10 = 0

SIZE Bank Size Natural log of total assets

4. Data Analysis and Discussion 4.1 Descriptive Analysis

Table (4) illustrates the minimum and maximum

values for the variables. The descriptive findings

show the central tendency and dispersion of the

indicators as shown in table (4). The study focuses on

conventional and Islamic banks operating in Yemen

and the six GCC countries.

Table (5) shows the frequency of the banks

based on the GCC countries and Yemen.

Figure (1) shows the description of the sample

based on number of banks on the six GCC countries

and Yemen.

Page 30: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

184

Table 4. Descriptive Statistics

Variables Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation

OwnCon 0.05 1.0000 .62 .28

DirOwn .00 1.00 .16 .37

Duality .00 1.00 .92 .27

Brdsize 6.00 19.00 9.48 2.22

BrdNonEx 4.00 13.00 8.46 2.04

BrdActivisim .00 9.00 4.96 1.67

AC .00 1.00 .86 .35

ACmeetings .00 11.00 4.08 2.41

Age 4.00 75.00 29.74 15.45

Size 6.21 11.33 8.91 1.52

TobinQ .1300 3.2600 .94 .38

ROA -.0090 .0491 .02 .01

PM -.3700 .7500 .37 .22

Table 5. Frequency of the sample

Country Frequency Percent Cumulative Percent

Bahrain 14 28.0 28.0

Kuwait 4 8.0 36.0

Oman 7 14.0 50.0

Qatar 6 12.0 62.0

KSA 9 18.0 80.0

UAE 7 14.0 94.0

Yemen 3 6.0 100.0

Total 50 100.0

Figure 1. Description of the sample

4.2 Hypotheses Testing

For testing the first hypothesis, two-independent

samples t-test is adopted. Finally, multiple regressions

models are used to test the second and third

hypotheses.

4.2.2 The difference between Islamic and

conventional banks in using CG mechanisms

This hypothesis is concerned with the difference

between CG practices in conventional and Islamic

banks.

The two groups that are used in this hypothesis

are: Islamic and conventional banks which use CG

mechanisms. The independent-samples T-test is used

to test this hypothesis as shown in table (6). For the

ownership concentration as a CG mechanism, the

interpretation of the independent t-test result is a two-

stage process. The first stage is to examine the

homogeneity of the variance between the two groups

using Levene’s Test for Equality of Variances, where

(F = 8.953, P = 0.004). This is considerably less than

0.01 (thus significant), indicating that equal variances

cannot be assumed. The second stage is to use the t-

test row of results labelled equal variance not

assumed. This provides the t-value (t = -.420), the

degree of freedom (df = 16.186), and the sig. (2-

Page 31: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

185

tailed) is .680, where (P > 0.05). Thus, the result is

not significant which means that Islamic banks are not

significantly different from conventional banks in

using CG mechanism as in table (6).

For the other CG mechanisms (director

ownership, duality, board size, board non-executives,

board activism, audit committee and audit committee

meetings), the interpretation of the independent t-test

result is a two-stage process. The first stage is to

examine the homogeneity of the variance between the

two groups using Levene’s Test for Equality of

Variances, where (P-value for F-test > 0.05). This is

considerably less than 0.05 (thus not significant),

indicating that equal variances can be assumed. The

second stage is to use the t-test row of results labelled

equal variance assumed. Where (P-value for T-test >

0.05) for director ownership, duality, board non-

executives, board activism, audit committee and audit

committee meetings. Thus, the result is not significant

except for board size where (P-value for T-test <

0.05) which means that there is a significant

difference. Finally, it can be said that Islamic banks

are not significantly different from conventional

banks in using CG mechanism except for board size

as in table (6). The results agree to great extent with

the findings of Al-Tamimi (2012) that there is no

significant difference between the UAE national

conventional and Islamic banks regarding CG

practices

Table 6. Independent-Samples T-test

F Sig. t df Sig.

(2-tailed)

OwnCon Equal variances assumed 8.953 .004 -.501 48 .618

Equal variances not assumed -.420 16.186 .680

DirOwn Equal variances assumed 2.286 .137 .798 48 .429

Equal variances not assumed .712 17.563 .486

Duality Equal variances assumed .009 .926 .047 48 .963

Equal variances not assumed .047 21.006 .963

Brdsize Equal variances assumed .007 .932 2.563 48 .014

Equal variances not assumed 2.163 16.330 .046

BrdNonEx Equal variances assumed .091 .764 .316 48 .753

Equal variances not assumed .294 18.675 .772

BrdActivisim Equal variances assumed .044 .835 -.865 48 .391

Equal variances not assumed -.807 18.749 .430

AC Equal variances assumed .105 .747 -.164 48 .870

Equal variances not assumed -.158 19.670 .876

ACmeetings Equal variances assumed .761 .387 -.402 48 .689

Equal variances not assumed -.356 17.335 .726

4.2.3 Testing the effect CG mechanisms on firm

performance

The second and third research hypotheses are

concerned with studying the effect of CG mechanisms

on firm performance.

Three equations are used to test these hypotheses are

presented in the formulars 1, 2, 3.

This hypothesis concerns with investigating the

effect of firm size, firm age, and CG variables on firm

performance by using OLS analysis. Table (7)

provides the results for the multivariate regression

models.

Tobin’s Q = α + β1 OwnCon +β2 DirOwn + β3 Duality + β4 Brdsize + β5 Brdnonex + β6

Brdativism + β7 Ac + β8 Acmeeting + β9 Age + β10 Size + ε (1)

ROA = α + β1 OwnCon +β2 DirOwn + β3 Duality + β4 Brdsize + β5 Brdnonex + β6 Brdativism

+ β7 Ac + β8 Acmeeting + β9 Age + β10 Size + ε (2)

PM = α + β1 OwnCon +β2 DirOwn + β3 Duality + β4 Brdsize + β5 Brdnonex + β6 Brdativism

+ β7 Ac + β8 Acmeeting + β9 Age + β10 Size + ε (3)

Page 32: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

186

Table 7. OLS regression results

*Statistically significant at the 0.10 level

** Statistically significant at the 0.05 level

*** Statistically significant at the 0.01 level

Model 1 investigates the relationships between

firm performance (Tobin’s Q) and the variables of

interest. The R2

is 0.474 and the model appears highly

significant (F = 3.508, p = 0.001). As regards our

variables of interest, firm age, board size and board

activism appear to have an effect on Tobin’s Q, where

the estimated coefficients are positive and statistically

significant at 10%, 1% and 5% respectively. These

results on board size are consistent with the results of

Huang (2010) in Banks in Taiwan, however they are

inconsistent with previous studies (Jensen 1993;

Yermack 1996; Eisenberg et al, 1998; Singh and

Davidson, 2003; Staikouras et al., 2007; Cheng,

2008). Board non-executives has an effect on Tobin’s

Q, where the estimated coefficient is negative and

statistically significant at 1% level. This result is

consistent with the finding of Agrawal and Knoeber

(1996), Kochar and David (1996) and Bhagat and

Black (2002). The variance inflation factor (VIF)

score was calculated for each independent variable, in

order to evaluate whether multicollinearity may be a

cause of concern. VIF scores higher than 10 are likely

to cause a multicollinearity problem (Gujarati, 2004).

The highest VIF obtained is 3.210.

Regarding model 2, it examines the relationships

between firm performance (ROA) and firm size, firm

age, and CG variables. The R2

is 0.376 and the model

appears significant (F = 2.345, p = 0.028). As regards

our variables of interest, audit committee appears to

have an effect on ROA, where the estimated

coefficients are positive and statistically significant at

5% level. Ownership concentration and audit

committee meetings have an effect on ROA, where

the estimated coefficient is negative and statistically

significant at 10% level. These results are consistent

with previous studies (Ahunwan, 2002; Rabelo and

Vasconcelos, 2002; Tsamenyi et al; 2007). It seems

that in GCC banks most ownership and control are in

substantial family holdings and boards of directors are

largely dominated by controlling shareholders. Thus

the effect of the weak professional control results in

poor performance. The highest VIF obtained is 3.210.

Regarding model 3, it examines the relationships

between profit margin (PM) and firm size, firm age,

and CG variables. The R2 is 0.423 and the model

appears significant (F = 2.853, p = 0.009). As regards

our variables of interest, only firm age and firm size

appear to have an effect on PM, where the estimated

coefficients are positive and statistically significant at

10% and 5% level respectively. The results are

consistent with the findings of Klapper and Love

(2004) and Odegaard and Bohren (2003). This result

may reflect an independent source of value creation,

possibly due to market power and economies of scale

and scope (Odegaard and Bohren, 2003). Moreover,

large banks in the Middle East have more resources

(e.g., more skilled managers) compared to medium

and small banks which may help them to be more

efficient and attract more investors and increase their

firms' values. The highest VIF obtained is 3.210.

5. Summary and conclusion This paper investigates the effect of corporate

governance mechanisms on bank financial

performance in seven Middle Eastern countries. The

Model 3

(Dependent Variable

PM)

Model 2

(Dependent Variable

ROA)

Model 1

(Dependent Variable Tobin Q)

t-statistics Coeff. t-statistics Coeff. t-statistics Coeff.

.205

1.847*

2.050**

-1.385

-1.047

-.317

-1.051

.435

1.103

1.162

-.825

2.853

0.009

0.423

0.274

3.210

.069

.004

.049

-.156

-.111

-.214

-.021

.009

.025

.146

-.016

.720

1.098

-.220

-1.940*

-.896

-.884

-.343

1.443

.567

2.167**

-1.754*

2.345

0.028

0.376

0.215

3.210

.012

.000

.000

-.011

-.005

-.007

.000

.002

.001

.014

-.002

.153

1.765*

-.102

-.649

.650

-.149

4.391***

-3.020***

2.119**

.239

-.716

.085

.006

-.004

-.120

.114

-.040

.141

-.103

.078

.049

-.023

3.508

0.002

0.474

0.339

3.210

Const.

Age

Size

OwnCon

DirOwn

Duality

BrdSize

BrdNonEx

Brdactivism

AC

ACmeetings

F-statistics

p-value for F- test

R-squared

adjusted R2

Max VIF

Page 33: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

187

paper provides an insight into the corporate

governance practices in 50 conventional and Islamic

banks operating in Yemen and the six GCC countries

and the effect of such practices on Tobin’s Q, ROA

and PM. Corporate governance of banks in emerging

economies is of crucial importance as banks hold an

overwhelmingly dominant position in the financial

systems of these countries. Moreover, banks are

extremely important engines of growth in such

countries as they are typically the most important

source of finance for the majority of firms, in addition

to playing a major role in the payment & saving

system. Therefore, bank governance is of crucial

importance as the reduced role of economic regulation

has resulted in the managers of banks having greater

freedom on how they run their banks.

Emerging economies are likely to require more

effective and stronger governance mechanisms than

their western developed counterparts if they are to

become equal, full, and active participants in the

global financial marketplace. The governments of

most GCC countries have taken the necessary actions

to have a strong financial sector based on well-

established financial companies, in order to keep pace

with international developments and enable the vision

of a solid economy that will be recognized

internationally. While the corporate governance codes

and regulations in the GCC might not be as elaborate

as corporate governance regimes in western countries,

they can be said to provide adequate coverage of the

key disclosure issues of relevance in a market with a

nascent disclosure culture. Nonetheless, policy

makers in GCC countries need to ensure that firms

implement effective corporate governance

mechanisms. This implementation should be

appropriate for the GCC business environment while

embracing international corporate governance

standards.

The results reveal that certain corporate

governance mechanisms have impact on market value

performance. Meanwhile, book value performance is

affected by different corporate governance

mechanisms. The study results are consistent with

previous literature that the correlation between

corporate governance and performance is still not

clearly established and that financial impact on

corporate governance on performance in emerging

economies is still relatively scarce. The results reveal

that corporate governance practices do not differ

between conventional and Islamic banks in the

Middle East.

References 1. Abu-Tapanjeh, A. (2009), “Corporate governance

from the Islamic perspective: a comparative analysis

with OECD principles”, Critical Perspectives on

Accounting, Vol. 20, pp. 556-67.

2. Adams, R, and Ferreira, D. (2007), "A theory of

friendly boards", Journal of Finance, Vol. 62 No. 1,

pp. 217–250.

3. Adam, R. and Mehran, H. (2003), “Is corporate

governance different for bank holding companies?”,

Economic Policy Review, Vol. 9, pp.123-142.

4. Agrawal, A. and Knoeber, R. (1996), "Firm

performance and mechanisms to control agency

problems between managers and shareholders",

Journal of Financial Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 31

No. 3, pp. 377-398.

5. Ahunwan, B. (2002), "Corporate governance in

Nigeria", Journal of Business Ethics, Vol. 3, pp.

6. 269-287.

7. Allen, L., and Cebenoyan, A. (1991), "Bank

acquisitions and ownership Structure: Theory and

evidence", Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 15,

pp. 425-448.

8. Alonso, P.A. and Gonzalez, E.V. (2006), ‘‘Corporate

governance in banking: the role of board of

directors’’, Working Paper 06/4, Department of

Business Economics, Universitat Autonoma de

Barcelona, Barcelona, June, available at:

http://selene.uab.es/dep-economia-

empresa/documents/06-4.pdf (Accessed on

15/03/2013).

9. Al-Tamimi, H. (2012) "The effects of corporate

governance on performance and financial distress:

The experience of UAE national banks", Journal of

Financial Regulation and Compliance, Vol. 20 No. 2,

pp.169-181.

10. Arouri, H., Hossain, M. and Muttakin, M. (2011),

“Ownership structure, corporate governance and bank

performance: evidence from GCC countries”,

Corporate Ownership and Control, Vol. 8, pp. 365-

370.

11. Bhagat, S. and Black, B. (2002), "The non-correlation

between board independence and long-term firm

performance, Journal of Corporation Law, Vol. 27,

pp. 231-273.

12. Bahgat, S. and Bolton, B. (2008), "Corporate

governance and firm performance", Journal of

Corporate Finance, Vol. 14, pp. 257-273

13. Baliga, M. and Rao, J. (1996), "CEO duality and firm

performance: What’s the fuss?", Strategic

Management Journal, Vol. 17 No.1, pp. 41-53.

14. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, and Bank

for International Settlements, (2004). International

convergence of capital measurement and capital

standards: a revised framework. Basel Committee on

Banking Supervision.

15. Beck, P., and Zorn, T. (1982), "Managerial incentives

in a stock market economy", Journal of Finance, Vol.

37, pp. 1151-1167.

16. Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., and Levine, R. (2003),

"Law and finance: why does legal origin matter?",

Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 31 No.4, pp.

653–675.

17. Beltratti, A. and Stulz, R. (2009), “Why did some

banks perform better during the credit crisis? A cross-

country study of the impact of governance and

regulation”, National Bureau of Economic Research

working paper No. w15180.

18. Berger, A., Clarke, G., Cull, R., Klapper, L., and

Udell, G. (2005). “Corporate governance and bank

performance: a joint analysis of the static, selection,

and dynamic effects of domestic, foreign, and state

ownership”, World Bank Research Working Paper

3632. Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=756948

(Accessed on 15/03/2013)

Page 34: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

188

19. Blue Ribbon Committee (BRC) (1999), Report and

Recommendations of the Blue Ribbon Committee on

Improving the Effectiveness of Corporate Audit

Committees, New York Stock Exchange, New York,

NY.

20. Bokpin, A. (2013), "Ownership structure, corporate

governance and bank efficiency: an empirical analysis

of panel data from the banking industry in Ghana",

Corporate Governance, Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 274-287.

21. Brickley, J., Coles, J. and Jarrell, G. (1997),

"Leadership structure: Separating the CEO and

chairman of the board", Journal of Corporate Finance,

Vol. 3, pp. 189-220.

22. Cadbury Committee (1992), Report of the Committee

on the Financial Aspects of Corporate Governance,

Gee Publishing, London.

23. Capiro, G., Leaven, L. and Levine, R. (2007),

‘‘Governance and banks’ valuations’’, Journal of

Financial Intermediation, Vol. 16, pp. 584-617.

24. Carline, N., Linn, S. and Yadav, P (2002), "The

influence of managerial ownership on real gains in

corporate mergers and market regulation of merger

partners: empirical evidence, EFA Berlin Meetings

Discussion Paper, Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=302606 (Accessed on

15/12/2012)

25. Chen, Y., Moroney, R., and Houghton, K. (2005).

"Audit committee composition and the use of an

industry specialist audit firm", Accounting & Finance,

Vol. 45 No. 2, pp. 217-239.

26. Cheng. (2008), "Board size and the variability of

corporate performance", Journal of Financial

Economics, Vol. 87, pp. 157–176.

27. Claessens, S., Djankov, S. and Lang, L.H.P. (2000),

"The separation of ownership and control in East

Asian corporations’’, Journal of Financial Economics,

Vol. 58, Nos 1/2, pp. 81-112.

28. Cole, R., and Mehran, H. (1998), "The effect of

changes in ownership structure on performance:

evidence from the thrift industry", Journal of

Financial Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 291-317.

29. Coles, J., and Hesterly, W. (2000), "Independence of

the chairman and board composition: Firm choices

and shareholder value", Journal of Management, Vol.

26 No. 2, pp. 195-214.

30. Dalton, D., Daily, C., Ellstrand, A. and Johnson, J.

(1998), "Meta-analytic reviews of board composition,

leadership structure, and performance", Strategic

Management Journal, Vol. 19, pp. 269–290.

31. Davis, J., Schoorman, F. and Donaldson, L. (1997),

"Towards a Stewardship Theory of Management",

Academy of Management Review, Vol. 22, pp. 20–

47.

32. De Andres, P., Azofra, V., and Lopez, F. (2005).

"Corporate boards in OECD countries: Size,

composition, functioning and effectiveness",

Corporate Governance: An International Review, Vol.

13 No. 2, pp. 197-210.

33. Demsetz, H. (1983), "The structure of ownership and

the theory of the firm", Journal of Law and

Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 301-325.

34. Demsetz, H., and Lehn, K. (1985), "The structure of

corporate ownership: causes and consequences",

Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93, pp. 1155-1177.

35. Denis, D. and Denis, D., (1994), "Majority owner-

managers and organizational efficiency", Journal of

Corporate Finance, Vol. 1, pp. 91-118.

36. Denis, D., and McConnell, J. (2003), "International

corporate governance", ECGI Working Paper Series

in Finance, No. 05/2003.

37. Donaldson, L. (1990), "the ethereal hand:

Organizational economics and management theory",

Academy of Management Review, Vol. 15, pp. 369-

381.

38. Dulewicz, V. and Herbert, P. (2004), ‘‘Does the

composition and practice of boards of directors bear

any relationship to the performance of their

companies?’’, Corporate Governance: An

International Review, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 263-80.

39. Ehikioya, B. (2009), "Corporate governance structure

and firm performance in developing economies:

Evidence from Nigeria", Corporate Governance, Vol.

9 No. 3, pp. 231-243.

40. Eisenberg, T., Sundgren, S. and Wells, M. (1998),

"Large board size and decreasing firm value in small

firms", Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 48, pp.

35-54.

41. Fama, E., (1980), "Agency problems and the theory of

the firm", Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, pp.

288-307.

42. Fama, E. and Jensen, M. (1983), "Separation of

ownership and control", Journal of Law and

Economics, June, pp. 301–325.

43. Farinha, J. (2003), "Corporate governance: a survey of

the literature", Universidade do Porto Economia

Discussion Paper, No. 11.

44. Gambling, T. and Karim, R. (1991), Business and

Accounting Ethics in Islam, Maunsell, London.

45. Glassman, C. and Rhoades, S. (1980), "Owner vs.

manager control effects on bank performance", The

Review of Economics and Statistics, No.62, pp. 263-

270.

46. Greenbury, R. (1995), Directors’ Remunerations:

Report of the Study Group, Chaired by Sir Richard

Greenbury, Gee Publishing, London.

47. Griffiths, M. (2007), ‘‘Consumer debt in Australia:

why banks will not turn their backs on profit’’,

International Journal of Consumer Studies, Vol. 31

No. 3, pp. 230-6.

48. Gujarati, D. (2004), Basic Econometrics, McGraw-

Hill, Boston.

49. Hampel Report (1998), Committee on Corporate

Governance, Final Report of Committee, Gee

Publishing, London.

50. Hermalin, B., and Weisbach, M. (1991), "The effects

of board composition and direct incentives on firm

performance", Financial Management, Vol. 20, pp.

101-112.

51. Holderness, C., and Sheehan, D. (1988), "The role of

majority shareholders in publicly held corporations",

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 20, pp. 317-346.

52. Huang, C.-J. (2010), “Board, ownership and

performance of banks with a dual board system:

evidence from Taiwan”, Journal of Management &

Organization, Vol. 16 No. 2, pp. 219-34.

53. Huson, M. (2001), "Internal monitoring and CEO

turnover: A long-term perspective", Journal of

Finance, Vol. 56 No. 6, pp. 2265-2297.

54. Jensen, M., (1993), "The modem industrial revolution,

exit and the failure of internal control systems",

Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, pp. 831-880.

55. Jensen, M. (1986), "Agency costs of free cash-flow,

corporate finance and takeovers", American

Economic Review, Vol. 76, pp. 323-329.

Page 35: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

189

56. Jensen, M., and Meckling, W. (1976), "Theory of the

firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and

ownership structure", Journal of Financial Economics,

Vol. 3, pp. 305-360.

57. Johnson, G., Scholes, K., and Whittington, R. (2008).

Exploring Corporate Strategy. Pearson Education

Limited, Essex, England.

58. Kaplan, S. (1989), "The effects of management

buyouts on operating performance and value", Journal

of Financial Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 217-254.

59. Klapper, L.F. and Love, I. (2004), “Corporate

governance, investor protection, and performance in

emerging markets”, Journal of Corporate Finance,

Vol. 10 No. 5, pp. 703-28.

60. Klein, A. (2002), "Audit committee, board of director

characteristics, and earnings management", Journal of

Accounting and Economics, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 375-

400.

61. Kochar, R. and David, P. (1996), "Institutional

investors and firm innovation: a test of competing

hypotheses", Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17,

pp. 73-84.

62. Krivogorsky, V. (2006), "Ownership, board structure,

and performance in Continental Europe", The

International Journal of Accounting, Vol. 41 No. 2,

pp. 176-197.

63. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. Shleifer, A. and

Vishny, R (1998), "Law and Finance", Journal of

Political Economy, Vol. 106, pp. 1113-1155.

64. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A.

(1999) , "Corporate ownership around the world", The

Journal of Finance, Vol. 54, pp. 471-517.

65. Laing, D. and Weir, C. (1999), "Governance

structures, size and corporate performance in UK

firms", Management Decision, Vol. 37 No. 5, pp. 457-

467.

66. Lam, T., and Lee, S. (2012), "Family ownership,

board committees and firm performance: evidence

from Hong Kong". Corporate Governance, Vol. 12

No. 3, pp. 353-2366.

67. Levine, R. (2004), ‘‘The corporate governance of

banks: a concise discussion of concepts and

evidence’’, working paper, World Bank Policy

Research, World Bank, Washington, DC.

68. Levitt, A. (1999), "Levitt plays up shareholder rights

to directors", Investor Relations Business, April 12, p

2.

69. Loderer, C., and Martin, K. (1997), "Executive stock

ownership and performance: tracking faint traces",

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 45, pp. 223-255.

70. Loderer, C., and Sheehan, D. (1989), "Corporate

bankruptcy and managers' self- serving behavior",

Journal of Finance, Vol. 44, pp. 1059-1075.

71. Macus, M. (2008), “Board capability: An interactions

perspective on boards of directors and firm

performance”, International Studies of Management &

Organization, Vol. 38 No. 3, pp. 98-116.

72. Macey, J. and O’Hara, M. (2003), ‘‘The corporate

governance of banks’’, Economic Policy Review,

Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York, NY,

pp. 91-107.

73. Mak, Y., and Yuanto, K. (2003), Board Size Really

Matters: Further Evidence on the Negative

Relationship Between Board Size and Firm Value,

Pulses by Singapore Stock Exchange

74. McConnell, J., and Servaes, H. (1990), "Additional

evidence on equity ownership and corporate value",

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 27, pp. 595-612.

75. Mitchell, R., Agle, B. and Wood, D. (1997), ‘‘Toward

a theory of stakeholder identification and salience:

defining the principle of who and what really counts’’,

Academy of Management Review, Vol. 22 No. 4, pp.

853-86.

76. Mohamed, E., Basuony, M. and Badawi, A. (2013),

“The impact of corporate governance on firm

performance in Egyptian listed companies”, Corporate

Ownership and Control, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 691-705.

77. Mohammed, A. (2009), “The concept of corporate

governance in Sharia”, European Business Law

Review, Vol. 20 No. 2, pp. 343-68.

78. Morck, R., Shleifer , A. and Vishny, R. (1988),

"Managerial ownership and market valuation",

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 20, pp. 293-315.

79. Mullineux, A. (2006), “The corporate governance of

banks”, Journal of Financial Regulation and

Compliance, Vol. 14 No. 14, pp. 375-382.

80. National Commission on Fraudulent Financial

Reporting (NCFFR) (1987), Report of the National

Commission on Fraudulent Financial Reporting,

AICPA New York.

81. Nyamongo, E. and Temesgen, K. (2013), "The effect

of governance on performance of commercial banks

in Kenya: a panel study", Corporate Governance, Vol.

13 No. 3, pp. 236 – 248.

82. Ødegaard, B., and Bøhren, Ø. (2003). “Governance

and performance revisited”, ECGI-Finance Working

Paper, Paper No. (28).

83. OECD (2004), OECD Principles of Corporate

Governance, Organization for Economic Co-operation

and Development, Paris.

84. Pathan, S., Skully, M. and Wickramanayake, J.

(2008), “Reforms in Thai bank governance: The

aftermath of the Asian financial crisis”, International

Review of Financial Analysis, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 345-

362.

85. Peni, E. and Vahamaa, S. (2011), “Did good corporate

governance improve bank performance during the

financial crisis?”, Available at

http://ssrn.com/abstract=1740547 (Accessed on

15/03/2013)

86. Pi, L. and Timme, S. (1993), ‘‘Corporate control and

bank efficiency’’, Journal of Banking and Finance,

Vol. 17, pp. 515-530.

87. Rabelo, F. and Vasconcelos, F. (2002), "Corporate

governance in Brazil", Journal of Business Ethics,

Vol. 3, pp. 321-335.

88. Ramsay, I. (2001), Ramsay Report: Independence of

Australian Company Auditors: Review of Current

Australian Requirements and Proposals for Reform,

available at http//www.treasury.gov.au (Accessed on

15/03/2013)

89. Rechner, P. L. and D. R. Dalton (1989). ‘The impact

of CEO as board chairperson on corporate

performance: Evidence vs. rhetoric’, Academy of

Management Executive, Vol. 3, pp. 141–143.

90. Rechner, P. L. and D. R. Dalton (1991). ‘CEO duality

and organizational performance: A longitudinal

analysis’, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 12 No.

2, pp. 155–160.

91. Rediker, K., and Seth, A. (1995), "Board of directors

and substitution effects of alternative governance

Page 36: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

190

mechanisms", Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 16,

pp. 85-99.

92. Rosenstein, S. and Wyatt, J. (1990), "Outside

directors, board effectiveness and shareholders

wealth", Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 26, pp.

175-191.

93. Sundaramurthy, C., Mahoney, J., and Mahoney, J.

(1997), "Board structure, anti-takeover provisions,

and stockholder wealth", Strategic Management

Journal. Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 231-245.

94. Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1986), Large

Shareholders and Corporate Control, Journal of

Political Economy, 94, pp 461-488.

95. Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1997), A Survey of

Corporate Governance, Journal of Finance 52, pp 737-

783.

96. Singh, M. and Davidson,W. (2003), "Agency costs,

ownership structures and corporate governance

mechanisms". Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol.

27, pp. 793–816.

97. Smith, A. (1990), "Corporate ownership structure and

performance: The case of management buyouts",

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 27, pp. 143-164

98. Spong, K.R. and Sullivan, R.J. (2007), ‘‘Corporate

governance and bank performance’’, available at:

99. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=10

11068 (Accessed on 15/03/2013)

100. Staikouras, P., Staikouras, C. and Agoraki, M. (2007),

‘‘The effect of board size and composition on

European bank performance’’, European Journal of

Law and Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 1-27.

101. Subrahrnanyam, V., Rangan, N. and Rosenstein, S.

(1997), "The role of outside directors in bank

acquisitions", Financial Management, Vol. 26, pp. 23-

36.

102. Tan, R. (2006), “The path to ethical returns”, Estates

Gazette, No. 616, April, pp. 138-40.

103. Taylor, M. (2008), “Sharia law protects investors”,

Money Management, Vol. 22 No. 5, p. 8.

104. Tsamenyi, T., Enninful-Adu, E and Onumah, J.

(2007), "Disclosure and corporate governance in

developing countries: Evidence from Ghana",

Managerial Auditing Journal, Vol. 22 No. 3, pp. 319-

334.

105. Turnbull, S. (1997), "Corporate governance: Its scope,

concerns and theories", Corporate Governance, Vol.

5, pp. 180-205.

106. Union of Arab Banks (2003), available at:

www.uabonline.org/book/book-index.php

107. Vafeas, N., and Theodorou, E. (1998), "The

relationship between board structure and firm

performance in the UK", British Accounting Review,

Vol. 30, pp. 383-407.

108. Weisbach, M. (1988), "Outside directors and CEO

turnover", Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 20,

pp. 431–460.

109. Weir, C. and Laing, D. (2001), "Governance

structures, director independence and corporate

performance in the UK", European Business Review,

Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 86-94.

110. William, Q., Naoumova I., and Koutzevol, N. (2003),

"Corporate governance and firm performance in

Russia: An empirical study", Journal of World

Business, Vol. 38, pp. 385–396.

111. Yermack, D. (1996), "Higher market valuation for

firms with a small board of directors", Journal of

Financial Economics, Vol. 40, pp. 185-211.

112. Yamak, S. and Su¨er, O. (2005), ‘‘State as a

stakeholder’’, Corporate Governance, Vol. 5 No. 2,

pp. 111-20.

113. Yasin, H. and Shehab, I. (2004), “Monitoring and

overseeing disclosure”, in Saidi, N. (Ed.),

paperpresented at the Corporate Governance in

MENA Countries: Improving Transparency and

Disclosure, the Second Middle East and North Africa

Regional Corporate Governance Forum, Beirut, June

3-5.

Page 37: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

191

Appendix 1. List of Banks

Bahrain: Kuwait: Oman: Qatar: Saudi

Arabia: UAE: Yemen:

1 Ahli United

Bank BSC

National

Bank of

Kuwait

S.A.K.

Bank

Muscat

SAOG

Qatar National

Bank

National

Commercial

Bank (The)

Emirates

NBD PJSC

Tadhamon

International

Islamic Bank

2

Albaraka

Banking

Group

B.S.C.

Al Ahli

Bank of

Kuwait

(KSC)

National

Bank of

Oman

(SAOG)

Commercial

Bank of Qatar

(The) QSC

Al Rajhi

Banking &

Investment

Corporation-

Al Rajhi

Bank

Natiional

Bank of Abu

Dhabi

Yemen Bank

for

Reconstruction

and

Development

3

Gulf

International

Bank BSC

Jordan

Kuwait

Bank

Bank

Dhofar

SAOG

International

Bank of Qatar

Q.S.C.

Riyad Bank Abu Dhabi

Commercial

Bank

National Bank

of Yemen

4 BBK B.S.C.

Industrial

Bank of

Kuwait

K.S.C.

Bank

Sohar

SAOG

Qatar

International

Islamic Bank

Banque Saudi

Fransi

First Gulf

Bank

5 Ithmaar

Bank B.S.C.

HSBC

Bank

Oman

Qatar

Development

Bank Q.S.C.C.

Saudi British

Bank (The)

Dubai

Islamic Bank

plc

6

National

Bank of

Bahrain

Oman

Arab

Bank

SAOG

Qatar First

Investment

Bank

Arab

National

Bank

Union

National

Bank

7

Al-Baraka

Islamic

Bank

Ahli Bank

SAOG

Islamic

Development

Bank

Mashreqbank

8 Arcapita

Bank

Saudi

Hollandi

Bank

9

Al-Salam

Bank

Bahrain

Bank Al-

Jazira

10 Investcorp.

Bank

11

Bahrain

Islamic

Bank

12 United Gulf

Bank

13 BMI Bank

14 Future Bank

Page 38: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

192

DEBT, GOVERNANCE AND THE VALUE OF A FIRM

K. Rashid*, S. M. N. Islam**, S. Nuryanah***

Abstract

This paper examines the role of debt in affecting the value of a firm in the developing and the developed financial markets. The study uses panel data of 120 companies for the years 2000 to 2003 from the selected financial markets. The paper extends the literature by performing a comprehensive analysis of the relationship between debt and the value of a firm, by using a correct proxy to value a firm. Furthermore, the results are interpreted by taking into account the foundations of the developing and developed markets and different financial theories are ranked on the basis of these results of the study. The findings of the study suggest that higher debt plays a negative role in affecting the value of a firm in the selected markets showing the effect of market imperfections in the developing market. The result supports the second trade off theory and the foundation of the developed financial market. An efficient regulatory authority improves the firm’s performance by defending the rights of shareholders and reducing principal and agent conflicts. Similarly, the dual leadership structure, investors’ confidence and optimal utilization of assets improve shareholders’ value in these markets. The results are valuable to academics and policy makers as these results suggest an optimal capital structure for the firms of the selected financial markets. Keywords: Corporate Governance, Debt, Firm Performance, Board Size and CEO Duality ** Department of Accounting, Faculty of Economics, Universitas Indonesia Email: [email protected]

Acknowledgements This paper is adapted from Rashid, K. and Islam, S. (2008) Corporate Governance and Firm Value: Econometric Modelling and Analysis of Emerging and Developed Financial Markets, Emerald, UK, and is reproduced with the permission of Emerald. The authors thank Emerald for giving permission to publish this paper. The authors are thankful to Ms Siti Nuryanah and Ms Margarita Kumnick for their help in proof reading the document.

1. Introduction

Debt is an important tool in minimizing the principal

(shareholder) and agent (manager) divergences and

improving the firms’ performance in a financial

market (Heinrich, 2002; Abor, 2005). Previous studies

have focused on the relationship between the debt and

equity structure in affecting the value of a firm, but

have overlooked the role of additional factors

affecting the nature of this relationship, particularly in

a developing financial market. Furthermore, the

results of these other studies were not interpreted by

taking into account the foundations of developing and

developed markets. Finally, the literature lacks a

comprehensive study based on a robust data set and a

correct proxy to value a firm, to test its relationship

with the role of debt in developing and developed

financial markets.

The literature concerning the role of debt in

affecting firms’ performance suggests a mixed

relationship between both the variables. Nerlove

(1968), Petersen and Rajan (1994) and Hutchinson

(1995) find a positive relationship between higher

debt and the value of a firm in the financial market.

Similarly, Taub (1975) advocates for a positive

relationship between the different measures of

profitability and the debt to equity ratio. The effective

role of debt in corporate governance and hence

increasing firm value are also confirmed in the current

studies conducted by Ivashina et al. (2009), Altan and

Arkan (2011), and Ben Moussa and Chichti (2011).

On the other hand, Fama and French (1998),

Gleason et al. (2000) and Hammes (2003) argue that

higher debt deteriorates the value of a firm in

financial markets. Similarly, Berger and Patti (2006)

in their research conducted on banking sector and

Majumdar and Chhibber (1999) in their study related

to the DVF relationship pertinent to an emerging

market, find that higher debt deteriorates the value of

a firm. Sarkar and Sarkar (2008) found that debt

cannot play its disciplinary role as a corporate

governance instrument. The current study conducted

by Sadeghian et al. (2012) confirms further that the

debt increase has a negative influence on the

company’s performance.

Page 39: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

193

In spite of the mixed results in the DVF

relationship, an advanced panel threshold regression

model conducted by Feng-Li and Tsangyao (2011)

shows that, for Taiwan case study, there are two

threshold effects between debt ratio and firm value,

which are 9.86% and 33.33%. Firm value will

increase much higher if the debt ratio is less than

9.86%. The increase will be slower as the debt ratio

increases up to 33.33% and finally if the debt ratio is

greater than 33.33% there will be no relationship

between debt ratio and firm value.

This paper argues that the mixed results in the

DVF relationship indicates the limitations of the

previous studies as, for example, the studies

conducted by Kyereboah-Coleman and Biekpe (2005)

and Chang and Mansor (2005) have tested the

relationship between the level of debt and the value of

a firm as a control variable in a developing market but

have not incorporated the important factors affecting

debt and the value of a firm (DVF) relationship.

Similarly, Myers and Majluf (1984), Zwiebel (1996),

Berglof (1997), Hadlock and James (2002), Suto

(2003) and Rashid and Islam (2009) have not

performed the study to test the role of debt in

combined markets (developing and developed

financial markets). This research addresses the above-

mentioned gap in the literature and extends the recent

paper by Rashid and Islam (2009) by using a correct

proxy to value a firm and by performing a

comprehensive study to analyze the role of debt in

affecting the firm’s performance. Based on the panel

data of 120 publicly listed companies, this paper

depicts that debt plays an unhealthy role in managing

the conflicts between shareholders and managers. On

the contrary, the external regulatory regime defends

the rights of shareholders in the selected markets.

Finally, the results for the control variables suggest

that dual leadership structure, efficient utilization and

investors’ confidence lead to the improved value of a

firm in these markets. The results of this study are

valid, as an additional test of robustness is also

performed.

Following the introduction, the paper is further

structured as follows. Section 2 presents the literature

review which is followed by the hypothesis

development in Section 3. Section 4 describes the

methodology for the model. Similarly, Section 5

discusses the econometric results for the study.

Section 6 presents the explanation of the results and

finally, Section 7 concludes the paper.

2. Literature review 2.1 Corporate governance

Corporate governance in the literature is defined as

the mechanism used to protect the interests and rights

of shareholders in the market (Gompers et al., 2003).

The concept of corporate governance is also related to

the fair returns on the investment made by the

shareholders, because they are the providers of capital

(funds) to organizations as defined by Shleifer and

Vishny (1997). Similarly, a corporate governance

framework defends the rights of different stakeholders

which include management, customers, suppliers,

creditors and other associated parties related to the

operations of a firm (Dallas, 2004; Black et al., 2006).

Financial markets can be divided into two types:

developing and developed markets. These markets are

categorized on the basis of the sophistication of the

financial instruments used in these countries. The

developing financial market uses less sophisticated

instruments compared to the developed market. These

instruments are used to manage risk by hedging the

investors’ portfolios, ultimately improving the returns

for shareholders in the financial market (Hunt and

Terry, 2005). Shareholders in a developed market

earn higher returns due to the developed instruments

used in this market.

The literature related to corporate governance

suggests that different mechanisms of corporate

governance incorporate democratic (investor friendly)

provisions in both developing and developed financial

markets (Black, 2001; Black et al., 2003). The

instruments of corporate governance mechanisms

include shareholders, managers, board, executive

management, suppliers, customers, regulatory

authorities and judiciary as argued by Morin and

Jarrell (2001) and Dittmar et al. (2003).

The two important types of corporate

governance mechanisms include external and internal

corporate governance instruments. The latter refers to

the internal corporate governance regime and includes

board, size of board, mix in the board, leadership

structure of a firm (CEO duality) and the role of debt

in financial markets (Nam and Nam, 2004). These

instruments can improve the level of corporate

governance as argued by Gompers et al. (2003) and

Bebchuk et al. (2004). On the other hand, the former

are the external regulators in the financial market and

include a regulatory authority, judiciary, central bank

and a securities and investment commission

(Ahunwan, 2003).

2.2 Theories about capital structure

Debt has an important role in affecting the value of a

firm. There are different theories related to this. The

first school of thought in this regard is the Modigliani

and Miller hypothesis (1958, 1963). This theory

suggests that capital structure or the debt equity mix

does not affect the shareholders’ value significantly.

Modigliani and Miller hypothesis further suggests that

a firm operates in a perfect market as there is no

interest rate, agency cost of debt and the cost of

financial distress which makes the debt and equity

structure irrelevant in the market.

The second theory, which deals with the role of

capital structure, discusses the trade-off that exists

between the advantages and disadvantages of debt.

Page 40: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

194

This is the trade-off theory and suggests that financial

benefits of debt are offset by the disadvantages such

as the agency cost of debt and the cost of financial

distress (Copeland et al., 2005). The theory further

suggests that the benefits of debt, such as reduction in

the individual’s tax payment, are offset by the

additional amount of tax paid by the corporation.

Another theory relevant to the role of capital

structure is the second trade-off theory and suggests

that benefits of debt such as minimizing the amount

paid by an individual is equalized by the cost of

bankruptcy and the agency cost between creditors and

managers in the market.

Finally, the theory relevant to the role of capital

structure in affecting the value of a firm is the pecking

order theory. This theory ranks the methods or modes

of financing available to the firm on the basis of the

cost related to the execution of an individual option of

financing. The theory suggests that the firm will use

the cheapest source of financing on a priority basis,

which makes internal equity a highly preferable

source (Brealey and Myers, 2000). The second option

of raising funds is by issuing debt. Finally, the firm

can acquire finances by using the option of an

external equity. The theory further suggests that

issuance of debt conveys a positive signal to investors

as they realize that the management of a firm invests

in healthy projects. Furthermore, it also shows that the

firm has higher investment opportunities compared to

internally generated finances. The management of a

firm meets this short fall by issuing additional debt.

3.3 Other corporate governance instruments which increase the value of a firm

In addition to debt, majority shareholders, as an

external monitor, can also play an important role in

checking the internal corporate governance

mechanisms by defending the shareholders rights in

the financial markets (Franks and Mayer, 1994;

Kaplan and Minton, 1994).

Similarly, an internal mechanism such as the

board mix is also important, as it can affect the

shareholders’ value in the market (Abdullah, 2002;

Coles et al., 2008). The composition of the board is

vital in reducing the agency cost from the market. The

board of directors consists of a combination of inside

and outside directors (Wei, 2003). Inside directors are

the employees of a firm and have related financial

interests with the firm’s performance. These directors

can pursue their own benefits at the expense of the

shareholders (principal). Inside directors also

command the flow of important financial and strategic

information in affecting the shareholders’ value

(Stiles and Taylor, 1993). The convergence of

interests between shareholders and inside directors

can push the insiders to improve the value of a firm in

the financial market.

On the contrary, outside (independent) directors

are not the employees of a firm and can monitor the

organization on an independent basis (Bhagat and

Jefferis, 2002). This can improve the shareholders’

value, as the chances of expropriation of the minority

shareholders are reduced due to their (shareholders)

lower level of conflicts with the independent

directors. The combination of inside and outside

directors can be optimal to improve a firm’s

performance (Nam and Nam, 2004).

Similar to the board mix, board size is an

important corporate governance instrument in

affecting shareholders’ value (Loderer and Peyer,

2002). There are two schools of thought in this regard.

Zahra and Pearce (1989) and Kyereboah-Coleman and

Biekpe (2005) argue that a bigger board is better for

the firm’s performance, as it provides higher level of

strategic, planning and conceptual skills. The larger

board also creates value, as it is difficult for the

independent CEO (dual leadership) to dominate the

rational decisions of a board. There are functional

conflicts (healthy divergences) among the members of

the board which reduces the agency cost of the firm

(Linck et al., 2008).

On the other hand, Mak and Kusnadi (2005)

suggest that the bigger board does not add value for

the shareholders due to unhealthy conflicts among the

board members. Furthermore, the members of a larger

board often do not monitor the firm properly and are

involved in delayed decision making and free riding.

Free riding refers to the phenomena where the board

members do not perform their fiduciaries, but depend

on the monitoring done by other members of the

board. This deteriorates the value of a firm in the

financial market (Jensen, 1993).

The management and the board of directors can

also force the CEO to work for the benefits of all the

shareholders (the minority and the majority), by

relating the incentives of the CEO with its

performance. The management, including the board,

can also give proper remuneration to the CEO when

he/she meets both the long and short-term goals of a

firm (Bhagat and Jefferis, 2002).

The role of leadership structure is an important

component of corporate governance. The two main

types of leadership structures include dual and non-

dual leadership. Dual structure refers to a single

person performing both the tasks of CEO and the

chairman (Lam and Lee, 2008). This leads to the

dominance of the CEO, hence threatening the

independence of the board, as the board members

cannot discipline the CEO who is also the chairman of

board (Higgs, 2003: 23). On the contrary, non-dual

leadership refers to two different individuals holding

the job of CEO and chairman. This leads to the

independence of decision making by the board, hence

safeguarding the shareholders’ rights in a market.

In addition to all the instruments above, efficient

utilization of assets, as for example proxied by return

to total assets is an important aspect of corporate

Page 41: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

195

governance, since it creates returns for shareholders

and stakeholders. Firms in financial markets should

optimally utilize their assets to create shareholders’

returns (Capulong et al., 2000). The assets of these

firms should not be over and under-utilized by the

management to derive private gains from the financial

market.

The next section deals with the discussion

related to the role of business and management

theories. The first theory in this regard is the

stewardship theory. This theory suggests that the

manager, as an agent, looks after the interests of

shareholders (Davis et al., 1997). On the contrary, the

second theory is the agency theory and suggests that

the manager, as an agent, does not create value for

shareholders, deteriorating the firm’s performance

(Jensen and Meckling, 1976).

The figure below shows that in the presence of

an effective regulatory regime, debt can be used as a

powerful tool to reduce the misuse of cash flow and

discipline management, which improves the value of

a firm in a financial market.

Figure 1. The Relationship between Debt, Governance and the Value of a Firm

3. Hypohesis development

Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Jensen (1986) argue

that capital structure is of vital importance in affecting

the value of a firm. The free cash flow at the

discretion of managers is reduced in the indebted

firm, because it is utilized as a debt re-installment to

the creditor. The free cash flow is usually misused in

the forms of under and over investment by the

managers in a market. Under investment occurs when

managers do not invest in the profitable opportunities,

as the creditors share the part of profit from the

valuable investments. On the contrary, over

investment takes place when managers have

incentives to invest in projects due to their related

private benefits attached to the success of these

projects (Bebchuk et al., 2004). Shareholders pay

higher costs in monitoring and disciplining the

managers who deteriorates the value of a firm.

As discussed, the role of debt is important in

reducing the agency conflicts between managers and

shareholders, as the free cash flow problem is

resolved. The debt, in combination with other

instruments such as majority shareholders, can also

improve the value of a firm (Berglof, 1997). The

literature suggests that the use of corporate

governance instruments resolves the agency conflicts,

but an excessive use of a single instrument also

creates an additional agency cost in the market. This

leads to the need for other instruments, which reduce

the marginal cost and improve the marginal benefits

of each other to create real value for shareholders. The

combination of these instruments is called Edgeworth

complements. An instrument is Edgeworth

complementary if the marginal benefit of using

combined complementary instruments improves by an

additional use of each instrument in combination

(Heinrich, 2002).

The foundation of the developing financial

market suggests that the agency cost between

creditors and managers is governed properly

compared to the same cost between the managers and

shareholders. This suggests that higher debt creates

value in developing markets due to a better

management of the agency cost between the relevant

players of corporate governance (Berglof, 1997). The

majority shareholders also act as a better debt monitor

in the developing market, due to their higher financial

stakes related to the firms’ performance, compared to

the minority shareholders.

On the contrary, the agency cost between

managers and equity holders is handled properly in

the developed financial market. This feature of the

developed market advocates for the lower level of

debt as the shareholding is dispersed in this market.

Dispersed shareholding also justifies lower debt,

because the majority shareholders as external

monitors are absent (Rashid and Islam, 2008). This

feature of the developed market restricts higher debt

to be used as a better option for the value creation of

shareholders.

The level of financial benefits derived by

creditors in developing markets can be magnified by

linking them with the incentives to management

(Heinrich, 2002). This will force management to work

for all the stakeholders in these markets. Higher debt

in the hybrid system controls the adverse actions of

managers as it introduces efficient monitors

(blockholders) in the market. On the contrary, greater

debt also triggers a bankruptcy risk in the system

(Copeland et al., 2005). These advantages and

disadvantages should be considered to make optimal

financing decisions in the financial market.

The majority shareholders can monitor the firm

as they have higher financial interests related to the

firms’ performance. This related financial interest can

also reduce the free riding and wasteful duplication of

efforts by all the shareholders. Free riding prevails in

dispersed shareholding, when all the shareholders do

not keep a check on the management of the firm

properly, as most of them prefer not to pay any

monitoring cost. Secondly, wasteful duplication of

External

Corporate

Governance

Instruments

Debt and Other Governance

Instruments (agency cost

between managers and

creditors)

Management (control

under and over

investment of the free

cash flow)

Value of a

Firm

Page 42: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

196

effort occurs in financial markets when the majority

of the shareholders waste their efforts in doing the

similar job of monitoring as performed by all of them

(Diamond, 1984).

There are additional imperfections (inflation,

political turmoil, under-resourced and rudimentary

regulatory institutions, and expropriation of minority

shareholders) in the developing financial market

(Ahunwan, 2003). Higher inflation leads to an intense

depreciation and a loss of investors’ confidence.

Similarly, the political unsteadiness makes the market

unstable, leading to the deteriorating performance of a

firm. The weak regulatory institutions cannot align

the interests of the principal and agent which results

in a higher agency cost in the developing market.

Finally, the rights of minority shareholders are not

safeguarded, as cash flow in the firm is not used in a

positive manner in this market. These imperfections

affect the strength of individual instruments in the

Edgeworth combination to improve the marginal

benefits of each other.

The abovementioned discussion related to the

role of debt in affecting the value of a firm can be

summarized by suggesting that lower debt is

beneficial for firms in the developed market due to an

absence of majority shareholders as external monitors.

Similarly, due to the presence of additional

imperfections in the developing market, the higher

debt in combination with blockholding is not

beneficial to firms of this market. This discussion

leads to the following hypothesis.

H1: There is a negative relationship between higher

debt and the value of a firm in the selected financial

markets.

4. Methodology

The current section consists of the data collection

methods, methodology of construction of the

variables, econometrics relevant for the study and a

multifactor model used to test the relationship among

the dependent and independent variables.

4.1 Data collection methods The data set for sixty companies from each market is

collected for the firms listed at Kuala Lumpur and

Australian securities exchanges and is secondary in

nature. The study used simple random sampling as the

sample companies for this study are selected purely

on random basis. The data for the study is collected

for control variables and external and internal

corporate governance instruments. The data for

control variables (CEO duality, board size, price to

book value ratio and return on total assets) is collected

by using an OSIRIS database. The collected data is

also crossed-checked with financial information

available on the websites of companies listed at

respective securities exchanges. The data for the

external corporate governance instrument (regulatory

authority and judicial efficiency index) is collected

from the World Bank and International Monetary

Fund websites. Finally, the data set for the internal

corporate governance instrument (debt to equity ratio)

is collected by using the stock exchanges books in

these financial markets.

4.2 Methodology of the variables

The dependent and independent variables used in this

study are listed in table 1 and their methodology of

construction is as follows. Tobin’s Q is used as a

dependent variable for the study (Bhagat and Jefferis,

2002; Gompers et al., 2003). The proxy for the

dependent variable (Tobin’s Q) in this study is

calculated by adding market capitalization and total

assets. In the second step, the shareholders’ fund is

subtracted from the added value calculated in the first

step. The residual value is divided by the total assets

to get the proxy for the Tobin’s Q. The calculation for

the proxy by using the above-mentioned methodology

contributes to the literature as the replacement value

of institutional debt does not comprise the formula to

calculate the proxy for Tobin’s Q. The correct proxy

to value a firm used in developing and developed

financial markets enables us to find the real

relationship between the independent variables and

the firms’ performance.

The independent variables relevant for the study

which are used to test their relationship with the value

of a firm are constructed as follows. The internal

corporate governance instrument on which the study

is based is the debt to equity ratio of firms

(Kyereboah-Coleman and Biekpe, 2005). The variable

is directly extracted from the balance sheets of the

companies listed at the securities exchanges of the

selected markets. We expect a negative relationship

between the variable and the value of a firm in these

markets.

The next independent variable in this study is the

role of board size in affecting the firm’s performance.

The board size in the model for DVF relationship is

calculated by counting the number of directors on the

board (Kyereboah-Coleman and Biekpe, 2005). We

expect a negative relationship between the board size

and the value of a firm as we support the agency

theory in the selected financial markets.

CEO duality is used in the model for DVF

relationship to testify the role of leadership structure

in affecting the value of a firm (Haniffa and Cooke,

2000). This variable is measured with the help of a

dummy variable. The value of this variable is 1 when

a single person holds both the positions of CEO and

chairman. On the contrary, the value of the variable is

0 when both the roles (CEO and chairman) are

separated i.e performed by two different persons

(Kyereboah-Coleman and Biekpe, 2005). We expect a

negative relationship between the CEO duality and

the value of a firm as a single person holding both the

Page 43: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

197

important positions is against the corporate

governance principles in the selected markets.

The role of the external corporate governance

instrument (regulatory authority efficiency) is

measured by regulatory efficiency index (Klapper and

Love, 2004). This index is constructed by taking into

account the time and cost involved in the settlement

of corporate disputes in the judicial system

.

Table 1. Variables used for DVF Relationship Model

Variables Proxied by Symbol Expected Sign

Dependent variable

Value of a firm Tobin’s Q Mkt Cap+ TA- ShF/TA TQ

Independent variables

Return on total assets Returns generated by all assets of firm ROTA Positive

Gearing Percentage of debt used to finance the firm Gr Negative

Size Number of directors in the board Log Size Negative

Duality Dummy variable: Can take the values

between 1 and 0

Duality Negative

Price to book value ratio Ratio between price and book value of the

assets of a firm

Pb Positive

Regulatory regime Procedures involved in the settlement of the

disputes

Log Pro Negative

Notes: Mkt Cap = Market capitalization.

TA = Total assets.

Sh F = Shareholders’ funds.

The higher value on the index shows more cost

and time consumed in a court depicting the

inefficiency of a regulatory regime. We expect a

negative relationship between the inefficient

regulatory authority and the value of a firm.

The next variable used in this study is the return

on total assets. The validity of the test related to the

relationship between return on total assets and the

value of a firm will show the role of allocation and

dynamic efficiency in affecting the firms’

performance (Chen et al., 2005).

Price to book value ratio in this study is used to

test the role of investors’ confidence in affecting the

shareholders’ value in developing and developed

financial markets. The positive value will depict that

the investors are willing to pay a higher premium for

the assets of the organization in the market creating

value for the shareholders.

4.3 Econometric testing Multiple regression analysis is used as a tool for

hypothesis testing and to analyze the relationship

between corporate governance instruments, control

variables and the value of a firm. The general

representation of the DVF relationship model is given

in the equation below.

Yt = C + 1t X1t + 2t X2t + ……….. + nt Xnt + Ut (1)

where:

Yt = dependent variable (value of a firm);

C = intercept;

t = slope of the independent variables of the model

(internal, external and control variables);

Xt = independent variables; and

Ut = error term (residual).

The ordinary least square (OLS) estimation will

be used to minimize the error terms of the DVF

relationship model. This type of estimation improves

the power of the sample regression function to explain

the major portion of the population regression

function (Cuthbertson, 1996).

4.4 Multifactor model

The multifactor DVF relationship model is used to

analyze the properties of the individual corporate

governance mechanism and testify its role in affecting

the value of a firm in developing and developed

markets.

The multifactor model for this study is shown as

follows:

Yt = C + 1t X1t + 2t X2t + 3t log X3t + 4t X4t +

5t X5t + 6 log X6t + Ut

(2)

where.

X1t = CEO duality;

X2t = Gearing ratio;

X3t = Regulatory authority efficiency index;

X4t = Price to book value ratio;

X5t = Return on total assets; and

X6t = Board size

The above-mentioned equation shows the

relationship between the value of a firm, corporate

governance instruments and control variables in the

selected markets.

5. Econometric Results

The discussion relevant for this section deals with the

regression analysis and a robustness test. The details

of these tests are presented below.

Page 44: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

198

5.1 Multiple regression analysis

As discussed, multiple regression analysis is

performed to testify the role of debt in affecting the

value of a firm. Models with varying functional forms

and alternative specifications are tried and the model

with the best functional form and strong diagnostics is

selected for the study. The variables in the selected

model are given an appropriate treatment by

transforming independent variables (price to book

value ratio, return on total assets and shareholders

concentration) into percentage form. Similarly, the

other independent variables such as the regulatory

authority efficiency and board size, are transformed

into non linear form by taking the natural logarithm,

removing the potential disorder of the OLS

assumptions. This treatment is similar to that of

Sridharan and Marsinko (1997) and Kyereboah-

Coleman and Biekpe (2005), in their studies related to

role of corporate governance in the financial market.

Furthermore, the OLS assumptions followed by

the estimators in the current model are endorsed by

giving the white diagonal treatment to the variables as

the variance of the error term of the model is unequal.

This unequal variance of the error term leads to the

existence of the heteroscedasticity (Gujarati, 2003).

White diagonal treatment corrected the variance of the

error term by transforming the ordinary least square

(OLS) method of estimation into the generalized least

square estimation method (GLS) (Maddala, 2001).

The results are also made robust by performing

the tests to detect multicollinearity in the model. The

results are presented in table 2 and include the tests

for variance inflation factors (VIF) for the variables

relevant for the selected financial markets. The value

(VIF) is calculated by making the independent

variables as the dependent variable and calculating the

value for the R squared. This calculated R squared is

subtracted from one and is lastly divided by one to get

the value for the variance inflation factor (Gujarati,

2003). The formula below is used to calculate the

value for variance inflation factor.

VIF = 1/1 - R2 (3)

The range of the values for the VIF for the

variables varies from 1.06 to 1.35, which shows the

absence of the multicollinearity from the model for

DVF relationship.

Table 2. Values for Variance Inflation Factor for the Selected Markets

Variables Variance Inflation Factor

Gearing 1.06

Procedures 1.35

CEO Duality 1.14

Return on Total Assets 1.19

Board Size 1.09

Price to Book Value Ratio 1.16

Table 3. Results of the Model for DVF relationship for the Selected Markets

Variables Model

Constant 0.54

(3.09)**

Log Board Size 0.20

(1.25)

CEO Duality 0.14

(2.72)**

Gearing -0.07

(-4.36)**

Price to Book Value Ratio 49.03

(13.56)**

Return on Total Assets 0.93

(1.78)*

Log Procedures -0.15

(-2.31)**

R-Squared 0.77

Mean Dependent Variable 1.42

F-Statistic (276.93)**

Notes: The values of the coefficients are in the first row.

Below are the values of T-Statistics in parenthesis.

Total number of observation for combined model= 480.

* Represents the significance of a variable at 10% significance level.

** Represents the significance of a variable at 5% significance level.

Page 45: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

199

5.2 Results of the model The quantitative form of the estimated model

presented in table 3 is explained below.

Yit = 0.54 + 0.14 Duality - 0.07 Gr - 0.15 Pro +

49.03 Pb + 0.93 Rota + 0.20 Size (4)

(3.09)** (2.72) ** (-4.36) ** (-2.31) ** (13.56) **

(1.78)* (1.25)

R2 = 0.77

In the equation above, the values for the

coefficients are in the first row. The values for t-

statistics are in the parenthesis below. The single

asterisk (*) and double asterisk (**) show that the

variable is significant at 10% and 5% level of

significance respectively.

The diagnostics of the model show that the value

for the R squared is 77%. This value shows that 77%

variation in the dependent variable is explained by the

independent variables of the model. The 23%

variation remains unexplained by these independent

variables. The value for the F-statistic is high (276.93)

and is significant depicting that the model is stable

and reliable. The mean value for the dependent

variable (Tobin’s Q) is 1.42, endorsing that firms in

the selected markets are healthy and create value for

shareholders.

5.3 Robustness test

The robustness test (factor analysis) in this study is

performed to confirm the validity of the alternate

hypothesis relevant for the model and is presented in

table 4 below. The result for the factor analysis shows

that price to book value ratio has the highest

correlation (loading) with the Tobin’s Q (0.87). This

result suggests that the higher investors’ confidence

leads to the improved value of a firm to a greater

magnitude. On the other hand, return on total assets

has a least correlation with the price to book value

ratio (0.33) showing that the optimal utilization of

assets does not lead to a significant change in the

willingness of the investors’ to pay a higher premium

in these markets.

Table 4. Factor Analysis: Results about Highly Correlated Variables in the Models

Variables of Cross-market Analysis Correlation Coefficient

PB and ROTA 0.33

TQ and AC 0.35

TQ and PB 0.87

MC and CF 0.49

AC and Log Pro 0.34

6. Explanation of the Results

The results of the model relevant for the study are

presented in table 3 and their detail is as follows. The

result explaining the role of debt in affecting the value

of a firm shows that there is a negative relationship

between the variable (gearing ratio) and the firms’

performance. This confirms our hypothesis (H1) for

the study. The result is consistent with the foundation

of the outsider system of corporate governance as

dispersed shareholding and lower debt reinforce the

positive effects of each other. Furthermore, the

agency cost between creditors and managers is not

handled properly in the selected financial markets.

Tunneling (under and over investment of the free cash

flow) takes place as the excessive cash flow is not

invested in the healthy projects improving the agency

cost in the firms of these markets. The detrimental

activities of agents limit the constructive role of the

majority shareholders to improve the marginal

benefits of higher debt in the developing market. The

government of the developing market does not make

tough regulations to reduce the agency cost of debt

and protect the rights of shareholders.

The result is consistent with the findings of

Zingales (1995) and Chang and Mansor (2005) as the

majority shareholders do not perform a healthy role of

monitoring the debt. Furthermore, the financial

advantages of debt in the selected markets are lower

compared to the potential disadvantages associated

with it. These benefits include the tax shield which

minimizes the amount of tax paid to the government

at both corporate and individual levels. Similarly, the

disadvantages associated with debt include the agency

cost between creditors and managers and the cost of

financial distress. The result supports the agency

theory and the second trade off theory in these

markets. On the contrary, the result contradicts the

Modigliani and Miller hypothesis (1958, 1963) as

debt and equity structure has relevance in the selected

markets (Copeland et al., 2005).

There is a positive relationship between the CEO

duality and the value of a firm with the value of

coefficient as 0.14. The result shows that dual

leadership structure creates value for shareholders in

developing and developed markets (Haniffa and

Cooke, 2000). The implication of the result suggests

that debt in the firm disciplines the CEO and makes

him a steward working for shareholders. Finally, the

representatives of creditors on the board converge the

interests of the CEO and shareholders, which also

improves the value of a firm in these markets. The

result is consistent with the findings of Brickley et al.

(1997).

Page 46: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

200

The role of external corporate governance

instrument in affecting the value of a firm is endorsed

at a 5% significance level with a value of coefficient

of -0.15. The value for coefficient shows that a 1%

increase in the regulatory authority inefficiency

decreases the value of a firm by 0.15 units.

Alternatively, regulatory authority efficiency

improves the firms’ performance by restraining the

majority shareholders and managers from tunneling in

the selected financial markets. The agency cost is

reduced by protecting the rights of shareholders in

these markets as suggested by Nenova (2003).

There is a positive relationship between the price

to book value ratio and the value of a firm. The value

for the coefficient is 49.03. This shows that higher

investors’ confidence leads to an intense level of

investment in the selected financial markets. The

highest coefficient of the variable among all the

independent variables reflects its relative importance

in the DVF relationship model.

Finally, a positive relationship between the

return on total assets and the value of a firm is

confirmed at a 10% significance level with the value

of coefficient being 0.93. The result shows that the

optimal utilization of assets leads to the improvement

in the value of a firm as found by Chen et al. (2005)

in their studies about corporate governance in the

financial market.

7. Conclusion

The current paper has investigated the role of debt in

affecting the firms’ performance in the developing

and developed financial markets. The result shows

that debt cannot be used as an effective tool to control

the free cash flow and reduce the agency cost between

creditors and managers in these markets. In addition,

majority shareholders do not govern the agency cost

of debt properly. Similarly, the laws concerning the

governance of debt do not address the incomplete

contracting improving the level of divergence of

interests among the different players of corporate

governance.

The firms of the selected financial markets

should consider alternate options to raise the funds

compared to debt financing. Due to additional

imperfections in the developing financial market, the

conflicts between creditors and managers are not

governed properly. The results related to the role of

control variables suggest that an efficient regulatory

authority, dual leadership structure, investors’

confidence and an effective utilization of assets

improve the value of a firm in these markets. In

future, these factors should be considered by

governments of these countries in making corporate

governance policies. The limitations of the study

suggest that the role of debt in disciplining the

principal and agent conflicts in the insider system of

corporate governance and under recession or boom in

the economy can give us a different nature of the

DVF relationship, with a new policy implication.

References 1. Altan, M & Arkan, F 2011, 'Relationship between Firm

Value and Financial Structure: A Study on Firms in Ise

Industrial Index', Journal of Business & Economics

Research, vol. 9, no. 9, pp. 61-5.

2. Abdullah, S. (2002), “Board of directors’ independence

among listed companies in an emerging economy”,

Utara Management Review, Vol. 3 No. 2, pp. 27-46.

3. Abor, J. (2005), “The effect of capital structure on

profitability: an empirical analysis of listed firms in

Ghana”, The Journal of Risk Finance, Vol. 6 No. 5, pp.

438-444.

4. Ahunwan, B. (2003), Globalization and Corporate

Governance in Developing Countries, Transnational

Publishers, New York.

5. Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A. and Ferrell, A. (2004), “What

matters in corporate governance?”, working paper,

Harvard Law School, Boston.

6. Ben Moussa, F & Chichti, J 2011, 'Interactions between

Free Cash Flow, Debt Policy and Structure of

Governance: Three Stage Least Square Simultaneous

Model Approach', Journal of Management Research,

vol. 3, no. 2, pp. 1-34.

7. Berger, A. and Patti, E. (2006), “Capital structure and

firm performance: a new approach to testing agency

theory and an application to the banking industry”,

Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 30 No. 4, pp.

1065-1102.

8. Berglof, E. (1997), “Reforming corporate governance:

redirecting the European agenda”, Economic Policy,

Vol. 12 No. 24, pp. 93-123.

9. Bhagat, S. and Jefferis, R. (2002), The Econometrics of

Corporate Governance Studies, MIT Press, Cambridge.

10. Bishop, S., Faff, R., Oliver, B. and Twite, G. (2004),

Corporate Finance, Prentice Hall, Sydney.

11. Black, B. (2001), “Does corporate governance matter?

A crude test using Russian data”, University of

Pennsylvania Law Review, Vol. 149 No. 6, pp. 2131-

2150.

12. Black, B., Love, I. and Rachinsky, A. (2006),

“Corporate governance indices and firm’s market

values: time series evidence from Russia”, Emerging

Markets Review, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 361-379.

13. Black, B., Jang, H. and Kim, W. (2003), “Does

corporate governance affect firms’ market values?

Evidence from Korea”, working paper No. 237,

Stanford Law School, Stanford.

14. Brealey, R. and Myers, S. (2000), Principles of

Corporate Finance, McGraw-Hill, New York.

15. Brickley, J., Coles, J. and Jarrell, G. (1997),

“Leadership structure: separating the CEO and chairman

of the board”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 3, pp.

189-220.

16. Capulong, V., Edwards, D., Webb, D. and Zhuang, J.

(2000), Corporate Governance and Finance in East

Asia: A Study of Indonesia, Republic of Korea,

Malaysia, Philippines, and Thailand, 1, Asian

Development Bank, Manila.

17. Chang, A. and Mansor, S. (2005), “Can good corporate

governance practices contribute to firms’ financial

performance? Evidence from Malaysian companies”,

International Journal of Business Governance and

Ethics, Vol. 1 No. 4, pp. 350-362.

Page 47: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

201

18. Chen, K., Elder, R. and Hsieh, M. (2005), “Corporate

governance and earnings management: the implications

of corporate governance best-practice principles for

Taiwanese listed companies”, working paper, National

Cheng Kung University, Taiwan. Available at:

http://scholar.google.com/scholar?hl_en&lr_&q_cache:

n7nAD1bUcNwJ:aaahq.org/audit/midyear/06midyear/p

apers/Chen%2520et%2520al_TWN_CG%2520and%25

20EM.pdf_Hsieh__chen_elder_corporate_governance_

2005_aaahq.org. (Accessed 15 February, 2007)

19. Cheng, S. and Shiu, C. (2007), “Investor protection and

capital structure: international evidence”, Journal of

Multinational Financial Management, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp.

30-44.

20. Claessens, S. and Djankov, S. (1999), “Ownership

concentration and corporate performance in the Czech

Republic”, Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 27

No. 3, pp. 498-514.

21. Coles, J., Daniel, N. and Naveen, L. (2008), “Boards:

does one size fit all?”, Journal of Financial Economics,

Vol. 87 No. 2, pp. 329-356.

22. Copeland, T., Weston, J. and Shastri, K. (2005),

Financial Theory and Corporate Policy, Addison-

Wesely, New York.

23. Cuthbertson, K. (1996), Quantitative Financial

Economics: Stocks, Bonds, and Foreign Exchange, John

Wiley and Sons, London.

24. Dallas, G. (2004), Governance and Risk: An Analytical

Handbook for Investors, Managers, Directors and

Stakeholders, McGraw-Hill, New York.

25. Davis, J., Schoorman, D. and Donaldson, L. (1997),

“Toward a stewardship theory of management”, The

Academy of Management Review, Vol. 22 No. 1, pp.

20-47.

26. Deesomsak, R., Paudyal, K. and Pescetto, G. (2004),

“The determinants of capital structure: evidence from

the Asia Pacific region”, Journal of Multinational

Financial Management, Vol. 14 No. 4, pp. 387-405.

27. Diamond, D. (1984), “Financial intermediation and

delegated monitoring”, The Review of Economic

Studies, Vol. 51 No. 3, pp. 393-414.

28. Dittmar, A., Mahrt-Smith, J. and Servaes, H. (2003),

“International corporate governance and corporate cash

holdings”, The Journal of Financial and Quantitative

Analysis, Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 111-133.

29. Donaldson, W. (2003), “Corporate governance”,

Business Economics, Vol. 38 No. 3, pp. 16-21.

30. Eisenberg, T., Sundgren, S. and Wells, M. (1998),

“Larger board size and decreasing firm value in small

firms”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 48 No. 1,

pp. 35-54.

31. Fama, E. and French, K. (1998), “Taxes, financing

decisions, and firm value”, The Journal of Finance, Vol.

53 No. 3, pp. 819-843.

32. Feng-Li, L & Tsangyao, C 2011, 'Does Debt Affect

Firm Value in Taiwan? A Panel Threshold Regression

Analysis', Applied Economics, vol. 43, no. 1, pp. 117-

28.

33. Franks, J. and Mayer, C. (1994), “Ownership and

control”, in H. Siebert (ed.) Trends in Business

Organization: Do Participation and Cooperation

Increase Competitiveness?, M Siebeck, Tubingen,

reprinted in Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol.

9, pp. 30-45, 1997.

34. Gleason, K., Mathur, L. and Mathur, I. (2000), “The

interrelationship between culture, capital structure and

performance: evidence from European retailers”,

Journal of Business Research, Vol. 50 No. 2, pp. 185-

191.

35. Gompers, P., Ishii, J. and Metric, A. (2003), “Corporate

governance and equity prices”, Quarterly Journal of

Economics, Vol. 118 No. 1, pp. 107-155.

36. Gujarati, D. (2003), Basic Econometrics, McGraw-Hill,

New York.

37. Hadlock, C. and James, C. (2002), “Do banks provide

financial slack?”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 57 No. 3,

pp. 1383-1419.

38. Hammes, K. (2003), “Firm performance, debt, bank

loans and trade credit: an empirical study”, working

paper, Department of Economics, Gothenburg

University, Gothenburg.

39. Haniffa, R. and Cooke, T. (2000), “Culture, corporate

governance and disclosure in Malaysian corporations”,

Paper presented at the Asian AAA World Conference,

Singapore.

40. Hartzell, J., Kallberg, J. and Liu, C. (2008), “The role of

corporate governance in initial public offering: evidence

from real estate investment trusts”, The Journal of Law

and Economics, Vol. 51 No. 3, pp. 539-562.

41. Heinrich, R. (2002), Complementarities in Corporate

Governance, Springer, Berlin.

42. Higgs, D. (2003), “Review of the role and effectiveness

of non-executive directors”, working paper, Department

of Trade and Industry, London.

43. Hofstede, G. and Hofstede, G. (2004), Cultures and

Organizations: Software of the Mind, McGraw Hill,

New York.

44. Hunt, B. and Terry, C. (2005), Financial Institutions and

Markets, Thomas Learning, Melbourne.

45. Hutchinson, R. (1995), “The capital structure and

investment decisions of the small owner-managed firm:

some explanatory issues”, Small Business Economics,

Vol. 7 No. 3, pp. 231-239.

46. Ivashina, V, Nair, VB, Saunders, A, Massoud, N &

Stover, R 2009, 'Bank Debt and Corporate Governance',

Review of Financial Studies, vol. 22, no. 1, pp. 41-77.

47. Jensen, M. (1986), “Agency costs of free cash flow,

corporate finance and takeovers”, American Economic

Review, Vol. 76 No. 2, pp. 323-329.

48. Jensen, M. (1993), “The modern industrial revolution,

exit, and the failure of internal control systems”, Journal

of Finance, Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 831-880.

49. Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976), “Theory of the

firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership

structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3 No.

4, pp. 305-360.

50. Kaplan, S. and Minton, B. (1994), “Appointments of

outsiders to Japanese boards: determinants and

implications for managers”, Journal of Financial

Economics, Vol. 36 No. 2, pp. 225-258.

51. Klapper, L. and Love, I. (2004), “Corporate governance,

investor protection and performance in emerging

markets”, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 1 No. 5,

pp. 703-728.

52. Kyereboah-Coleman, A. and Biekpe, N. (2005), “The

relationship between board size board composition,

CEO duality, and firm performance: experience from

Ghana”, working paper, University of Stellenbosch

Business School, Cape Town.

53. Lam, T. and Lee, S. (2008), “CEO duality and firm

performance: evidence from Hong Kong”, Corporate

Governance, Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 299-316.

Page 48: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

202

54. Linck, J., Netter, J. and Yang, T. (2008), “The

determinants of board structure”, Journal of Financial

Economics, Vol. 87 No. 2, pp. 308-328.

55. Lipton, M. and Lorsch, J. (1992), “A modest proposal

for improved corporate governance”, Business Lawyer,

Vol. 48 No. 1, pp. 59-77.

56. Loderer, C. and Peyer, U. (2002), “Board overlap, seat

accumulation and share prices”, European Financial

Management, Vol. 8 No. 2, pp. 165-192.

57. Maddala, G. (2001), Introduction to Econometrics,

Wiley, West Sussex.

58. Majumdar, K. and Chhibber, P. (1999), “Capital

structure and performance: evidence from a transition

economy on an aspect of corporate governance”, Public

Choice, Vol. 98 No. 3, pp. 287-305.

59. Mak, Y. and Kusnadi, Y. (2005), “Size really matters:

further evidence on the negative relationship between

board size and firm value”, Pacific Basin Finance

Journal, Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 301-318.

60. Matos, J. (2001), Theoretical Foundations of Corporate

Finance, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

61. Mayer, C. (1998), “Financial systems and corporate

governance: a review of the international evidence”,

Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol.

154 No. 1, pp. 144-176.

62. Mesquita, J. and Lara, J. (2003), “Capital structure and

profitability: the Brazilian case”, working paper,

Academy of Business and Administration Sciences,

Vancouver.

63. Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958), “The cost of

capital, corporation finance and the theory of

investment”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 48

No. 3, pp. 261-297.

64. Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1963), “Corporate

income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction”,

American Economic Review, Vol. 53 No. 3, pp. 433-

443.

65. Morin, R. and Jarrell, S. (2001), Driving Shareholders

Value: Value-Building Techniques for Creating

Shareholder Wealth, McGraw-Hill Publishers, Sydney.

66. Myers, S. (1984), “The search for optimal capital

structure”, Midland Corporate Financial Journal, Vol. 2,

pp. 6-16.

67. Myers, S. and Majluf, N. (1984), “Corporate financing

and investment decisions when firms have information

those investors do not have”, Journal of Financial

Economics, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 187-221.

68. Nam, S. and Nam, C. (2004), Corporate Governance in

Asia: Recent Evidence from Indonesia, Republic of

Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand, Asian Development

Bank Institute, Manila.

69. Nenova, T. (2003), “The value of corporate voting

rights and control benefits: a cross-country analysis”,

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 68 No. 3, pp. 325-

351.

70. Nerlove, M. (1968), “Factors affecting differences

among rates of return on investments in individual

common stocks”, The Review of Economics and

Statistics, Vol. 50 No. 3, pp. 312-331.

71. Petersen, M. and Rajan, R. (1994), “The benefits of

lending relationships: evidence from small business

data”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 3-37.

72. Rajan, R. and Zingales, L. (1995), “What do we know

about capital structure? Some evidence from

international data”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 50 No.

5, pp. 1421-1460.

73. Rashid, K. and Islam, S. (2008), Corporate Governance

and Firm Value: Econometric Modelling and Analysis

of Emerging and Developed Financial Markets,

Emerald, UK.

74. Rashid, K. and Islam, S. (2009), “Capital structure and

firm performance in the developed financial market”,

Corporate Ownership and Control, Vol. 7 No. 2, pp.

189-201.

75. Sadeghian, NS, Mehdi Latifi, M, Soroush, S &

Aghabagher, ZT 2012, 'Debt Policy and Corporate

Performance: Empirical Evidence from Tehran Stock

Exchange Companies', International Journal of

Economics & Finance, vol. 4, no. 11, pp. 217-24.

76. Sarkar, J & Sarkar, S 2008, 'Debt and Corporate

Governance in Emerging Economies Evidence from

India', Economics of Transition, vol. 16, no. 2, pp. 293-

334.

77. Schwartz, E. and Aronson, J. (1967), “Some surrogate

evidence in support of the concept of the optimal

financial structure”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 22 No.1,

pp. 10-18.

78. Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1997), “A survey of

corporate governance”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52

No. 2, pp. 737-783.

79. Sridharan, U. and Marsinko, A. (1997), “CEO duality in

the paper and forest products industry”, Journal of

Financial and Strategic Decisions, Vol. 10 No. 1, pp.

59-65.

80. Stiles, P. and Taylor, B. (1993), “Benchmarking

corporate governance: the impact of the Cadbury Code”,

Long Range Planning, Vol. 26 No. 5, pp. 61-71.

81. Suto, M. (2003), “Capital structure and investment

behavior of Malaysian firms in the 1990s: a study of

corporate governance before the crisis”, Corporate

Governance, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 25-39.

82. Taub, A. (1975), “Determinants of the firm’s capital

structure”, The Review of Economics and Statistics,

Vol. 57 No. 4, pp. 410-416.

83. Titman, S. (1984), “The effect of capital structure on a

firm’s liquidation decisions”, Journal of Financial

Economics, Vol. 13 No. 1, pp. 137-151.

84. Titman, S. and Wessels, R. (1988), “The determinants

of capital structure choice”, The Journal of Finance,

Vol. 43 No. 1, pp. 1-19.

85. Wei, Y. (2003), Comparative Corporate Governance: A

Chinese Perspective, Kluwer Law International,

London.

86. White, H. (1980), “A heteroscedasticity-consistent

covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for

heteroscedasticity”, Econometrica, Vol. 48 No. 4, pp.

817-838.

87. Yan, Y. (2005), Foreign Investment and Corporate

Governance in China, Macmillan, London.

88. Yermack, D. (1996), “Higher market valuation of

companies with a small board of directors”, Journal of

Financial Economics, Vol. 40 No. 2, pp. 185-211.

89. Zahra, S. and Pearce, J. (1989), “Boards of directors and

corporate financial performance: a review and

integrative model”, Journal of Management, Vol. 15

No. 2, pp. 291-334.

90. Zingales, L. (1995), “What determines the value of

corporate votes?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics,

Vol. 110 No. 4, pp. 1047-1073.

91. Zwiebel, J. (1996), “Dynamic capital structure under

managerial entrenchment”, The American Economic

Review, Vol. 86 No. 5, pp. 1197-1215.

Page 49: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

203

LINK BETWEEN MARKET RETURN, GOVERNANCE AND EARNINGS MANAGEMENT: AN EMERGING MARKET

PERSPECTIVE

Omar Al Farooque*, Eko Suyono**, Uke Rosita***

Abstract

This paper investigates the impact of earnings management on market return (by the proxies of discretionary accruals and earnings response coefficient/CAR regarded as accounting and market based earnings quality, respectively) along with a number of moderating (both governance and financial) variables in an emerging market context. Indonesia. Building on extant literature and using panel data approach, it examines 52 manufacturing firms listed on the Indonesia stock exchange during 2007 to 2010 periods. Applying Modified Jones Model to measure earnings management, our regression analysis reveals that earnings management has significant negative influence of market return. Of the moderating variables, board size, leverage and firm size are showing significant effects on market return, but not the institutional ownership. Again, observing the use of moderator effects on earnings management, our findings confirm that board size has more predictive power than institutional ownership in deterring earnings management and weaken the association between earnings management and market return. Similarly, leverage has strengthened the relation between earnings management and market return showing more exposure to earnings management while firm size showing a tendency to weakening earnings management, on the contrary. These results have enormous implications for Indonesian corporate sector and policy makers in adopting appropriate governance measures to constrain earnings management and improve quality of earnings. Keywords: Earnings Management, Earnings Quality, Corporate Governance, Indonesia. GEL Classification: G32, G34, M41, M48 * UNE Business School, University of New England, Australia Tel.: +61(0)2 67723920 Email: [email protected] **Faculty of Economics and Business, Jenderal Soedirman University, Indonesia Email: [email protected] *** Faculty of Economics and Business, Jenderal Soedirman University, Indonesia Email: [email protected]

1. Introduction

High quality earning whether market or accounting

oriented is important in modern corporate

environment in which equity ownership is separated

from control of corporate decisions. Agency theory

explains the conflict of interests which are the effect

of separation between ownership and control (Jensen

and Meckling, 1976 and Fama and Jensen, 1983b).

Moreover, the separation between ownership and

control also results in an asymmetric information

problem between executives and shareholders. An

information asymmetry usually appears when

information is not equally available to all participants.

In effect, managers have more information than

owners to pursue their own interests at the cost of

owners, and sometimes they prefer to distort

information in their interests. Gitman and Madura

(2001) contend that some executives may try to

access some information about the firm which makes

them getting more benefits than shareholders. As

agents, the executives prepare financial statements to

discharge their stewardship and principals reward the

agents using the information provided. Earning is one

of the important information in the financial

statement. Earning should represent actual condition

of the firm to increase or decrease economics value

for the investors. Moreover, earning is used as a tool

to predict the management performance in using

company resources and the future company prospect

as well. Therefore, the occurrence of earning

manipulation in the financial statement may arise to

protect the interest of the executives at the cost of the

firm. If earning as a part of financial statement does

not represent the real economics condition of the

company, earning quality whether accounting and

market based becomes weak to support investors’

decision making process. This is, however, considered

as a failure of financial reporting system to protect the

interest of investors and other stakeholders.

Page 50: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

204

Although stewardship theory suggests that

executives’ behaviour does not depart from the

interests of the principals even when the interests of

the executives do not coincide with the interests of the

owners (Davis et al., 1997), it is evident that the use

of financial information, such as earnings, in many

contractual agreements might provide the executives’

an incentive for earnings management which

ultimately leads to lower quality of earnings,

irrespective of market or accounting oriented.

Because, the usage of accrual based accounting

contributes to the propensity of earning management

as it does not require the physical evidence of cash in

recording the transactions (Sulistyanto, 2008). The

assumption that earnings management is an

opportunistic behaviour of managers as indicated in

Healy and Wahlen (1999) that when managers use

judgement in financial reporting and in structuring

transactions to alter financial reports to either mislead

some stakeholders about the underlying economic

performance of the company or to influence

contractual outcomes that depend on reported

accounting numbers, it can be argued in line with

agency theory that earnings management is an agency

cost detrimental to shareholders as well as other

stakeholders. To mitigate this problem and ensure that

alignment of interests exists between executives and

shareholders, significant monitoring mechanisms such

as corporate governance are installed within the firm

(Shleifer and Vishny, 1986). Because, corporate

governance is a set of mechanisms to monitor and

ratify managerial decisions and ensure the efficient

operation of a corporation on behalf of its

stakeholders (Donelly and Mulcahy, 2008). It is the

subset of a firm’s contracts that help align the actions

and choices of managers with the interest of

shareholders (Armstrong et al., 2011). Boediono

(2005) document that earning quality is influenced by

the occurrence of earning management and corporate

governance mechanisms, particularly managerial

ownership, institutional ownership and board size

mechanisms. Good corporate governance system is

very useful to protect the stakeholder interest in the

company which consists of institutional ownership

and board of director.

Given the above mentioned context, this study is

motivated to investigates the impact of earnings

management on market return along with a number of

moderating (both governance and financial) variables

in an emerging market context. Indonesia. In this

case, we use discretionary accruals and earnings

response coefficient/CAR as the proxies for,

respectively, earnings management and market return

(for market-oriented earnings quality). Our specific

research questions are whether earnings management

affect significantly market return (earning quality);

whether corporate governance mechanisms and firm

financials have significant impact on market return

(earning quality) and finally whether corporate

governance mechanisms and firm financials can

effectively mediate or not the effect of earning

management on market return (earning quality) by

constraining earnings management behaviour.

The remainder of this paper is divided into five

sections. Section 2 considers literature review,

conceptual framework and hypotheses development,

section 3 describes research method for data sources

and sample selection, variable measurement and

operation, and data analysis and model development.

Results and discussion are addressed in section 4 and

section 5 denotes conclusion and implication of the

study.

2. Literature Review and Hypotheses Development

The relationship between market return (i.e. earnings

quality), governance and earnings management can be

explained by agency theory. The agency relationship

contributes to the problems of conflict of interest for

the separation of ownership and control and

information asymmetry. Conflict of interest occurs

when an agent acts to fulfill their own personal

interest when making economic decisions while

ignoring the implications for shareholders. It is based

on the idea that managers who are not owners will not

watch over the affairs of a firm as diligently as the

owners (Chrisman, Chua, and Litz, 2004). Moreover,

the agents have the advantage of having more or

better information than the principal does (Ross,

1973). Information asymmetry represents the gap

between the amounts of information held by

management and that held by market participants

(Fields et al., 2001). Therefore, the degree of

information asymmetry will be higher if the quality of

information is low and stakeholders will be poorly

informed about the business. So, managers tend to

become involved in opportunistic behaviour (i.e.

earnings management and flawed disclosure) that

potentially increases a firm’s agency cost. In other

words, the asymmetric information between the agent

and principals give an opportunity to the managers

maximizing their interest by conducting earning

management. Eisenhardt (1989) stated that the agency

theory uses three human characteristic assumptions,

that is : (1) human has a self interest, (2) human has a

limited thought about the future perception (bounded

rationality), and (3) human generally tries to averse

the risk (risk averse). Healy and Palepu (2001) outline

several solutions to the agency problem, such as

appropriate contractual incentives, effective

monitoring function of the board of directors and

capital market players etc. to reduce conflict of

interests by controlling managerial behaviour. This

implies that both internal and external governance

processes are important in solving agency problems.

The extant literature emphasizes that the quality

of earnings is very important to users of financial

information because reported earnings are considered

to be the premier information in financial statements.

Page 51: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

205

Salvato and Moores (2010) confer that high quality

accounting information on attributes such as earnings

is essential for firms to access equity and debt

markets. The informative function of earnings means

that it is often used as a basis to describe the financial

performance of a firm. Earnings quality can be

observed where earnings are regarded as having high

in quality, i.e. the more accurate and timely that

reported earnings reflect expected future dividends,

the higher the quality of earnings. Dechow and

Schrand (2004) contend earnings to be high in quality

when they accurately reflect the company’s current

operating performance, are good indicators of future

operating performance and are a good summary

measure for assessing firm value. This is consistent

with the objectives of financial analysts and investors

to evaluate the performance of the company, to assess

the extent to which current earnings indicates future

performance and determine whether current stock

price reflects intrinsic firm value (Dechow and

Schrand, 2004). Again, financial information users

consider earnings quality as the absence of earnings

management, because intentional manipulation of

earnings by managers may distort the usefulness of

earnings to users. Managers may manage earnings for

a number of reasons relating to capital market

motivations, compensation and bonus as well as debt

contracts, which might result in low quality of

earnings. This implies earnings that are persistent and

predictable may not be of high quality if it is a result

of earnings management. That is, the lower the

earnings management, the higher the earnings quality

and vice versa. According to Schipper and Vincent

(2003), the importance of earning quality can be

explained from two perspectives, first, the contracting

perspective and second, investment perspective. From

the former perspective, low quality of earnings may

result in unintentional wealth transfers, i.e.

overcompensation to the managers if earnings are

overstated. From the latter perspective, poor quality of

earnings is problematic as it can mislead investors,

resulting in misallocation of resources (Myers et al.,

2003; Schipper and Vincent, 2003). Therefore, it is

very important for the reported earnings to be of high

quality. Because, prior literature documents that high

earnings quality would ultimately increase market

liquidity (Young and Guenther, 2003), attractiveness

of stocks to outside investors, lower cost of debt

(Salvato and Moores, 2010) and cost of capital (Leuz

and Verrecchia, 2000; Salvato and Moores, 2010).

2.1 Earning Management and Earning Quality

Within the framework of agency theory, earnings

management has been viewed as a form of agency

cost as it causes information asymmetry and reduces

principals’ understanding of a firm’s performance

which subsequently influences their investment

decisions (Davidson et al., 2004). It views earnings

management activity as a result of the misalignment

of interest between agent and principal that ultimately

leads to the agency cost (Davidson et al., 2004). Most

prior studies acknowledge that earnings management

is opportunistic rather than beneficial (e.g. Siregar and

Utama, 2008; Burgstahler and Dichev, 1997; Balsam

et al., 2002; Yu, 2008). To date, numerous examples

in the literature support the notion that earnings

management is opportunistic (e.g. Jones, 1991; Teoh

et al., 1998; Healy and Wahlen, 1999). Managers are

motivated to manipulate earnings for a number of

reasons as identified in prior literature, such as to

hype the stock price especially before initial public

offerings (Friedlan, 1994) and prior to seasoned

equity offerings (Jo and Kim, 2007; DuCharme et al.,

2004; Teoh et al., 1998; Rangan, 1998), to avoid

reporting losses (Bustaghlar and Dichev, 1997;

Degeorge et al., 1999; Charoenwong and Jiraporn,

2009), to smooth earnings volatility (Cormier et al.,

2000) and to influence contractual outcomes from

import relief (Jones, 1991). In contrast, a smaller body

of literature claims that earnings management is

beneficial because it is not harmful to a firm’s value

(e.g. Jiraporn et al., 2008). Prior literature argues that

inflated earnings potentially reduce the earnings

informativeness, impairing the earnings and stock

price correlation. Earnings management leads to

earnings mispricing by the market players and,

consequently, distorts the capital market’s

information and system. Given that the earnings are

correlated to the share price (Su, 2003; Easton and

Harris, 1991; Chan and Seow, 1996; Alford et al.,

1993; Easton and Zmijewski, 1989), inflating

earnings will result in an incremental increase in the

share price (Healy and Wahlen, 1999). Consequently,

investor’s decision making is influenced by inaccurate

earnings; stock price may be overvalued. Therefore,

most literature assumes that earnings management is

detrimental to firm value as well as earnings quality.

Some studies find that firms which alter discretionary

accruals before security offerings eventually suffer a

lower and abnormal stock return (e.g. Teoh et al.,

1998; Rangan, 1998).

Earning quality could be defined as the ability of

earning information in giving response to the market.

In other words, the reported earning has a response

power. The power of market reaction to the earning

information is reflected on the degree of earnings

response coefficients (ERC). High ERC means the

reported earning has high quality. In the context of

agency theory, managers choose certain accounting

methods to get the earning that is suitable to their

motivation. Of course, this condition affects the

quality of reported earning, because earning may not

necessarily reflect the real economic performance.

Thus, the first hypothesis is formulated as follow :

H1: Earnings management significantly affects

earning quality.

Page 52: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

206

2.2 Corporate Governance and Earning Quality

The importance of corporate governance to ensuring

effective monitoring has been widely discussed in the

prior literature. Corporate governance is the system

through which the behavior of a company is

monitored and controlled (Cheung and Chan, 2004).

Corporate governance structures aim to mitigate the

agency problem. Baek et al. (2009) point out that

sound governance processes are one of the

mechanisms that are potentially relevant to reducing

agency cost. John and Senbet (1998) state that

corporate governance encompasses a set of

mechanisms by which shareholders’ exercise control

over corporate insiders and management to protect

their interests. Corporate governance acts as a set of

controls that govern the behavior of managers, define

their discretionary powers, and serve to offset

potential losses due to the conflict of interest between

shareholders and managers (Bozec and Bozec, 2007).

According to Ho and Wong (2001), the adoption

of good governance mechanisms provides an

“intensive monitoring package” for a firm to reduce

opportunistic behaviors and information asymmetry

(Leftwich, Watts, and Zimmerman, 1981; Welker,

1995). Having good corporate governance promotes

transparency and accountability in the firm’s

information; which subsequently has a positive

impact on the level of earnings quality (Johnson et al.,

2002). Strong corporate governance is expected to be

able to protect stakeholders interests, curb agency

conflicts and limit agency costs (Haniffa and Hudaib,

2006). Bathala and Rao (1995) state that corporate

governance could act to reduce a manager’s self-

interest in the principal-agent relationship. Low self

interest will increase the likelihood of a manager

giving high quality disclosures to shareholders in

order to reduce information asymmetry

(Kanagaretnam et al. 2007).

There are numerous studies on earnings quality

and corporate governance in the academic journals.

Such studies become sufficiently robust corporate

governance to ensure high quality of corporate

financial reports. Prior studies document that low

quality of earnings is systematically related to

weaknesses in the oversight of management. A firm’s

governance attributes are supposed to be effective in

enhancing the quality of earnings as a monitoring

mechanism. To overcome the problem of earnings

management, some studies (e.g., Xie et al. 2003; Kent

et al. 2010) view internal corporate governance as a

credible tool for deterring earnings management.

Dechow, Sloan and Sweeney (1996) highlight that the

establishment of governance processes is essential to

maintain the credibility of firms’ financial statements

and safeguard against earnings manipulation. This

study assumes that as part of firm’s governance

practices, both internal and external monitoring

effects, respectively, by institutional ownership and

board of directors are effective in reducing earnings

management and improving earnings quality.

2.2.1 Institutional Ownership and Earning Quality

Institutional ownership has the ability to control

management through an effective monitoring process,

therefore it can constrain earning management by

supporting management to report the real financial

condition. Institutional monitoring process supports

the company to report good quality of income. The

percentage of stock ownership by institutions affects

the financial reporting process which enable the

management team making acrualistion in accordance

with their interest (Boediono, 2005).

Osma and Noguer’s (2007) find that institutional

investors are more influential in reducing earnings

management. Hashim (2004) find evidence that

institutional ownership affect eraning quality

positively. It implies that more concentrated

ownership in the hands of institutional investors has

more incentive to monitor company activities. The

involvement of institutional investor not only improve

good corporate governance practices, but also

contribute to the better quality of reporting

mechanism. Thus, the second hypothesis could be

formulated as follow:

H2a: Institutional ownership significantly affects

earning quality.

2.2.2 Board of Director Size and Earning Quality

The managers’ conflicts of interest are mitigated

through governance attributes, which have the

potential to control and monitor by the board. Boards

of directors play important roles in monitoring.

“Broadly speaking, the monitoring function requires

directors to scrutinize management to guard against

harmful behaviour, ranging from shirking to fraud”

(Linck et al., 2008, p. 311). According to García Lara

et al. (2007) strong corporate governance promotes

efficient monitoring by the board of directors, those

results in higher financial statement transparency and

lower accounting manipulation. The board of

directors receives authority over the internal control

of the firm from shareholders. They are responsible

for monitoring management to ensure that it acts in

the shareholders’ best interests. Although the board

delegates most decision and control functions to top

management, the board retains ultimate control

(Beasley, 1996). Thus, the board of directors plays an

important role in monitoring the quality of earnings

reported to the public.

Linck et al. (2008, p. 311) point out that “[a]

firm’s optimal board structure is a function of the

costs and benefits of monitoring and advising given

the firm’s characteristics, including its other

governance mechanisms”. The size of boards is

important in determining the effectiveness of board

Page 53: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

207

monitoring function. The board of directors should

carefully determine the optimum number of board

members to ensure that there are enough members to

discharge responsibilities and perform related duties.

The studies show that firms that report high quality

earnings are more likely to have smaller board

(Eisenberg, Sundgren, and Wells, 1998; Mak and

Kusnadi, 2005; Vafeas, 2000; Yermack, 1996).

Although some studies argue that larger boards are

better as they have greater capability to safeguard

shareholder interest (Zahra and Pearce II, 1989), a

broader range of experience (Xie et al., 2003), and

varied expertise (Rahman and Ali, 2006), there are

also empirical studies that show that smaller boards

are more effective than large boards ensuring higher

firm value (Eisenberg et al., 1998), more informative

(Vafeas, 2000), better communication and more

timely decision-making (Karamanou and Vafeas,

2005), more coordinating directors efforts (Eisenberg

et al., 1998; Jensen, 1993; Yermack, 1996).

The board of director is appointed by

stockholders as their representative to manage the

company. Board composition and size have relation

with earning management practice. It is because of the

earning management practice has relation with

financial statement that present useful earning for the

investors on investment decision making. Therefore,

in order to get the best decision, earning should be

qualified. Kao and Chen (2004) report that large

board size is associated with higher earnings

management, and small board size is associated with

lower earnings management. Ismail et al. (2008) find

evidence that board of director size positively affect

earning quality. It is because the board of director has

an important role to monitor the earning reporting

mechanism. Based on this finding, the third

hypothesis is formulated as follow :

H2b: Board of director size significantly affects

earning quality.

2.3 Firm-specific Attributes and Earning Quality

2.3.1 Financial Leverage and Earning Quality

Leverage is a ratio that is derived from total liabilities

devided by total assets. This ratio shows the amount

of company assets that is funded by liabilities. The

higher leverage, the higher is the risk for investors.

So, investors demand more return from highly levered

firms. Therefore, it can be concluded that higher ratio

of leverage tends to push to more practices in earning

management (Herawati, 2008). Moradi (2010)

document that the volatility of earning response

coefficient (ERC) as a proxy of earning quality,

depends on the volatiliy of financial leverage.

Financial leverage is assumed as a relevant

information on unpredicted market reaction to the

company earning. Thus, the fourth hypothesis could

be formulated as follow :

H2c: Financial leverage significantly affects earning

quality.

2.3.2 Company Size with Earning Quality

Company size is a basis that shows the company’s

ability in managing the business. The higher company

size is, the more capable the company is in managing

business activities. In relation to agency theory,

managers have more information than the owners.

Therefore, managers try to show good performance to

the owners to maintain their position. This condition

encourages managers to do more earning

management. Thus, high company size tends to push

to more earning management, in which will gear the

low earning quality.

Pagulung (2006) found that leverage has

significant relationship with 5 atributes of earning

quality. Then, sales and company size has significant

relationship with 5 atributes of earning quality. Other

variables, such as : operating cycle, performance, and

industries clasification show the atributes of earning

quality that has relationship with acrual quality,

iquidity, and factorial earning quality. Thus, the fifth

hypothesis could be formuleted as follow :

H2d: Company size significantly affects earning

quality.

2.4 Good Corporate Governance can Weaken the Effect of Earning Management on Earning Quality

Previous research supports the proposition that

corporate governance is beneficial in reducing

managers’ propensity to manipulate earnings. Bedard

et al. (2004) study reports that board size and

ownership by non-executive directors reduce

downward earnings management. Zhang et al. (2007)

report a positive association between blockholder

ownership and earnings management. Heflin and

Shaw (2000), however, document that both internal

and external blockholders are effective in reducing

information asymmetry and market liquidity in a firm,

thus suggesting that blockholders, regardless of type,

have the effect of improving disclosure quality.

It is widely believed that a small board is more

effective in monitoring a firm’s activity (Coles et al.,

2008). Board size is an important determinant of

earnings management in Taiwan (Kao and Chen,

2004), it has no significant effect in Malaysian firms

(Rahman and Ali, 2006). A higher number of board

members will stimulate a higher number of

independent directors on the board, with vast range of

experience and knowledge (e.g. Linck et al., 2008;

Xie et al., 2003; Dalton et al., 1999) and, thereby,

increase the board’s capability in constraining

Page 54: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

208

earnings management. On the contrary, Zhao and

Chen (2008) document that lower fraud and accruals

are associated with a staggered board (which is a

proxy for weak governance), thus suggesting that

strong board governance is not always effective in

constraining managers’ propensity to manipulate

earnings.

The qualified earning is an earning from

reporting mechanism that earning management does

not occur. Good corporate governance can minimize

the earning management practice in the company.

Chtourou and Bedard (2001) report that the

characteristic of board of director has an important

effect to the quality of financial statement. Basically,

experienced and independent board of director can

reduce the earning management practice. Beside that,

the institutional investor has a right to control the

company managers. This condition is expected to

improve the quality of reporting process on earning,

which in turn reduce the extent of earning

management (Moradi and Nezami, 2011). Thus, the

hypotheses could be formulated as:

H3a: Institutional ownership can weaken the effect

of earnings management on earning quality.

H3b: Board of director size can weaken the effect

of earning management on earning quality.

2.5 Firm-specific Attributes can Strengthen the Effect of Earning Management on Earning Quality performance

A financial statement is a tool for analyzing company

performance and result of operation. This information

is very useful to the user’s in decision making

process. From different types of information in the

financial statement, earning information is very

important for users (Beattie et al. 1994). Financial

statement analysis could be done by evaluating the

financial ratios to the earning quality. Pedwell et al.

(1994) argue that large company has more predictable

permanent earning process and has more resources to

make good estimation on high earning quality. Many

previous studies document evidence that there are

significant relationship between earning management,

estimation of earning quality and company size in

Australia (Anis, 2010). Astuti (2002) find that

financial leverage positively affect earning

management. According to Astuti (2002) managers

conduct earning management aiming to avoid breach

of debt covenant, which intern impacts on earning

quality. Therefore, high leverage tend to motivate

managers to engage in earning management which

ultimately affect earning quality. Thus, the

hypotheses could be formulated as:

H4a: Financial leverage can strengthen the effect of

earning management on earning quality.

H4b: Size of the company can strengthen the effect of

earning management on earning quality.

2.6 Conceptual Framework

The conceptual framework of this research is

displayed in the following 3 figures. The main

variables of interest are the relationship between

market return as the proxy for earning quality and

earning management. In this process, considering the

importance of corporate governance and firm-specific

attributes, moderating effects of them are taken into

account separately. Figure-1 shows the total structure

of the regression model while Figure-2 and Figure-3

indicate mediating effect of specific variables for

corporate governance and firm-specific attributes,

respectively. In regards to corporate governance,

institutional ownership and board of director size are

adopted in the model to observe their effects on

earning quality through earnings management

(Figure-2). Again, financial leverage and firm size are

considered as important firm-specific attributes to

detect their effects on earning quality through

earnings management (Figure-3).

Figure 1. Relationship between market return (i.e. earning quality), corporate governance, earning management

and firm-specific attributes

Earning management

Good corporate governance:

- Institutional ownership

- Board of director size

Firm-specific attributes:

- Financial leverage

- Company size

Market return

(Earning quality)

Page 55: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

209

Figure 2. Moderating good corporate governance in the effect of earning management on

earning quality

Figure 3. Moderating firm-specific attributes in the effect of earning management on earning quality.

3. Research Method 3.1 Sampling Method and Data Sources

The sampling method is purposive sampling with the

criteria as follow: (1) manufacturing firms listed on

the Indonesian Stock Exchange during the period of

2007-2010; (2) issue of audited annual report with 31

December year-end and (3) reported earning during

that period. In regards to data sources, this research

has used secondary data that could be accessed from

Indonesian capital market linked websites, such as:

www.idx.co.id., www.yahoofinance.com and

www.duniainvestasi.com.

3.2 Variables Operation and Measurement a. Dependent Variable (Y):

The dependent variable of this research is earning

quality. Scott (2003) explained that Earnings

Response Coefficient (ERC) could be proxy for

earning quality, which is a measurement of market

return based on available market data. ERC is a

coefficient gathered from the regression between the

proxy of stock price and accounting earning after

controlling annual return.

ERC is calculated with the formula as follow :

where:

: Commulative abnormal return of the company

i in 5 days after publication of accounting earning;

: Individual abnormal return of the company on

period t-day

where:

: Individual return of the company on period t-

day

: Individual actual return of the company on period

t-day

: Market return on period t-day

where:

: Individual actual return of the company on period

t-day

: Stock closing price of the company on period t-

day

: Stock closing price of the company on period t-

1 day

where:

: Market return on the day of t

: Composite stock price index on the day of t

: Composite stock price index on the day of

t-1

| |

where:

: Unexpected EAT of the company i at the eriod

of t

: EAT (Earning after tax) of the company i at

the eriod of t

Good Corporate Governance:

Institutional Ownership

Board of Director Size

Earning Quality Earning Management

Firm-specific Attributes:

Financial Leverage

Company Size

Earning Management

Earning Quality

Page 56: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

210

: EAT (Earning after tax) of the company i at

the eriod of t-1

where:

: Annual return of the company i at the period of

year t

: Stock closing price of the company i at the period

of year t

: Stock closing price of the company i at the

period of year t-1

where:

: Cummultive abnormal return of the company i

during 5 days before and after the publication of

financial statement

: Unexpected earnings on the company i on the

period of t

: Annual return of the company i on the period of

t

: The value of earning response coefficient (ERC)

b. Independent Variables (X):

1) Earning Management (X1)

Discretionary accruals as a proxy of earning

management was calculated by Modified Jones Model

(Dechow et al., 1995) with the formula as follow:

TAC = NIit – CFOit (1)

Total accrual (TA) that is estimated with Ordinary

Least Square as follow:

(

) (

) (

) (2)

With the regression coefficient as above,

nondiscretionary accruals (NDA) is as

follow:

(

) (

)

(

)

(3)

Then discretionary accruals (DA) could be calculated

as follow:

(4)

where:

Dait: Discretionary accruals of the company i at the

period of t

NDAit: Nondiscretionary accruals of the company i at

the period of t

TAit: Total acrual of the company i at the period of t

NIit: Net earning of the company i at the period of t

CFOit: Cash flow from operating activities of the

company i at the period of t

Ait-1: Total assets of the company i at the period of t-1

Revit: Income alteration of the company i at the

period of t

PPEit: Fixed assets of the company i at the period of t

Recit: Alteration of receivables company i at the

period of t

ε: Error term

c. Moderating Variables:

Moderating variable is a variable that strengthen or

weaken the relationship between one variable to

another variable. The moderating variables on this

research are:

a) )

a) Institutional ownership is a percentage of voting

right owned by the institutions. According to

Suyono (2011), institutional ownership is

measured by:

% Institutional Ownership

=

x 100%

b) Board of Director Size (X3)

Board of diretor size is measured by the number

of board of director members on the company

(Boediono, 2005).

c) Financial Leverage (X4)

Financial leverage is measured by Debt Ratio,

with the formula as follow:

Debt Ratio =

d) Company Size (X5)

Company size is an indication of the company

capabilities to manage the stockholders

investment by improving their welfare. The

logaritm of total assets can be used as a proxy

for company size (Pagulung, 2006).

Company Size = Ln_Total asstes

3.3 Data Analysis The data analysis is consisted of descriptive statistic

(i.e. mean, maximum, minimum, and deviation

standard of the variables), classical assumption test

for multiple regression (i.e. normality,

multicollinearity, heteroskedasticity and

autocorelation) and regression for moderation

absolute difference. The test of hypotheses 1 and 2 is

done with multiple linear regression, meanwhile

hypotheses 3 and 4 with regression for moderation

absolute difference.

Page 57: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

211

Regression equation model for hypotheses 1 and

2 is as follows:

where:

Y = Earning quality

α = Constant

EM = Earnings management

IO = Institutional ownership

BDS = Board of director size

FL = Financial leverage

CS = Company size

Regression equation model for hypothesis 3 is as

follows:

| | | |

Regression equation model for hypothesis 4 is as

follows:

| | | |

where:

Y1 = Earning quality

Y2 = Earning quality

α = Constant

EM = Earnings management

IO = Institutional ownership

BDS = Board of director size

FL = Financial leverage

CS = Company size

ZEM = Variable of earnings management from the

result of standard value

ZIO = Variable of institutional ownership from the

result of standard value

ZBDS = Variable board of director size from the

result of standard value

ZFL = Variable of financial leverage from the result

of standard value

ZCS = Variable company size from the result of

standard value | | = The different of absolute value

between institutional ownership and earnings

management (measured by absolute value from the

deviation between EM and IO)

| | = The different of absolute value

between board of director size and earnings

management (measured by absolute value from the

deviation between EM and BDS)

| | = The different of absolute value

between financial leverage and earnings management

(measured by absolute value from the deviation

between EM and FL)

| | = The different of absolute value

between company size and earnings management

(measured by absolute value from the deviation

between EM and CS)

4. Results and Discussion

4.1 Sampling Procedure and Statistical Descriptive

The purposive sampling of this research are based on

the following criterias: (1) the number of

manufacturing companies listed on Indonesian Stock

Exchange (IDX) in 2007-2010 periods were 145

companies, (2) 17 companies were delisted during

these periods, (3) 23 companies did not issue the

annual report for the year-end 31 December, (4) 45

companies did not report earning, and (5) 8

companies did not have sufficient data for this

research. Therefore, final sample size of the study

reduced to 52 companies or 208 firm years for 4-year

periods.

The result of descriptive analysis that includes

minimum value, maximum value, mean, standard

deviation of the variables of earning quality (ERC),

earnings management, institutional ownership, board

of director size, financial leverage, and company size

arepresented in Table 1 as follows:

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics

N Mean

Std.

Deviation Minimum Maximum

EM 208 0.1241 0.14003 -0.66 0.80

IO 208 0.7076 0.19775 0.03 0.98

BDS 208 4.7019 2.00425 2.00 10.00

FL 208 0.3981 0.19417 0.05 0.97

CS 208 27.6074 1.35027 24.85 31.49

EQ (ERC) 208 0.0701 0.10383 -0.17 0.77

Valid N

(listwise) 208

Page 58: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

212

Table-1 shows average earnings management in

Indonesian companies is around 12% which is much

higher than the developed economies, but similar to

other emerging countries in Asian region. Mean value

of market return (ERC) as proxy for earnings quality

is 7% which is quite low as compared to developed

economies. This implies that stock market in

Indonesia is not adequately developed yet to ensure

symmetric information flow in the market. As a

result, there remains incentive for company managers

to use information for their own interest as reflected

in high levels of earnings management, an indicator of

agency costs. In regards to governance variables,

average institutional ownership is 71% which indicate

high concentration of ownership and average board of

director size is 5 which a minimum of 2 and

maximum of 10 members. The mean value of

financial leverage is 40% indicating that firms are not

highly levered. Similarly, mean company size is 28%

(log of total assets) which suggest that Indonesian

companies are not large scale companies in size with

the exception of a few companies.

4.2 Classical Assumption Test for Multiple Regression

As mentioned earlier, these tests are consisted of

normality, heteroskedasticity, multicollinearity and

autocorrelation (These results are not shown here for

brevity, but will available from the authors when

requested. See Appendix 1). Normality test with the

value of asymp. sig. (2-tailed) for unstandardized

variable is 0.205, which is higher than (0.05),

therefore, all data in this research have normal

distribution. Heteroscedasticity test shows that the

significant value for all variables are higher that α

(0.05). This means that there are no heteroscedasticity

in this test. Multicollinearity test also shows that the

results of VIF for all variables are smaller than 10

meaning that there are no multicollinearity between

independent variables in this model. Finally,

autocorrelation test shows the value of Durbin-

Watson is 2.172, dU = 1.77, dL = 1.53. It implies that

the value of DW is between dU and 4 - dU, i.e., there is

no autocorrelation in this model.

4.3 Findings on Hypotheses Testing and Discussion

The regression results from the Table 2 above shows

that earning management affects negative

significantly market return (ERC) as the proxy for

earning quality, which implies that the higher is

earnings management, the lower is the earnings

quality or market return and vice-versa.

Table 2. Summary of Multiple Linear Regression Test

No. Variable Regress.

Coeff t statistic t tabel Sig.

1 Earning Management (X1) -0.156 -2.291 < -1.984 0.023

2 Institutional Ownership (X2) -0.065 -0.955 > -1.984 0.341

3 Board of Director Size (X3) 0.296 3.472 > 1.984 0.001

4 Financial Leverage (X4) 0.221 3.115 > 1.984 0.002

5 Company Size (X5) -0.170 -2.061 < -1.984 0.041

Constant = -0.00000000004

Adjusted R Square = 0.078

Fhitung = 4.503

Therefore, as per expectation the first hypothesis

is accepted, meaning that the earning is the principal

factor that an investor mainly consider in decision

making process. The amount of reported earning

could be an indication for earning management that

may reduce the earning quality and harm the

investors’ interest. In this case, investors should take

care to the earning management practices by not

relying straight on to the reported earnings. This

finding of the study is in-line with Boediono (2005)

that earning management negative significantly

affects earning quality.

The result of second hypotheses test (a) shows

that the institutional ownership does not significantly

affect earning quality. It means this hypothesis is

rejected. This result implies that the existence of

institutional ownership can not guarantee earning

quality that is reported by the company. It is because

the existence of institutions is in place formally, but

they give up the monitoring process to the board of

director. This finding is in accordance with the study

of Rachmawati and Triatmoko (2007).

The finding of second hypothesis test (b) showed

that board of director size has positive significant

effect on earning quality as per expectation. It means

this hypothesis is accepted. This signifies that

investors’ believe that the existence of board of

director can effectively monitor the management

activities, thus constrain the extent of earning

management practices and improve earning quality.

This finding is consistent with Ismail et al (2008) that

board of directors has an important role in monitoring

the reported earning quality.

Page 59: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

213

The result of second hypothesis test (c) confirms

that the financial leverage can positively influence

earning quality. It means this hypothesis is accepted.

Investors believe that debts are used to support the

operating activities in the best way, so the reported

earning provides relevant information in investment

decision making process. This finding is in-line with

Moradi et al, (2010), Jang and Sugiarto (2007) as well

as the trade-off theory in the capital structure stating

that leverage as a proxy of capital structure has

positive impact on earning quality.

The result of second hypothesis test (d) shows

that the company size has negative impact on earning

quality. It means this hypothesis is accepted. This

indicates that the bigger the company size, the less

possibility of getting more qualified information

relating to it’s activities including reported earnings.

In case of profit announcement when investors

consider that earning has low predictive power and/or

less useful to predict future earning, that may

implicate to low earning response coefficient (ERC).

This finding in-line with Collins and Kothari (1989)

that company size has negative relationship with

ERC.

The third hypotheses testing used regression for

moderating variables, and the result is as follow:

Table 3. Summary of Regression for Moderating Variables on the Impact of Good Corporate Governance to the

Relationship between Earning Management and Earning Quality

No. Variable Regress.

coefficient t statistic t table Sig.

1 Earning Management (X1) -0.124 -1.734 < -1.660 0.084

2 Institutional Ownership (X2) -0.050 -0.691 > -1.660 0.491

3 Board of Director Size (X3) 0.178 2.427 > 1.660 0.016

4 Moderate_1 (X1-X2) 0.024 0.285 < 1.660 0.776

5 Moderate_2 (X1-X3) -0.073 -0.812 > -1.660 0.481

Constant = 0.060

Adjusted R Square = 0.029

Fstatstic = 2.246

The result of third hypotheis testing (a) shows

that the institutional ownership does not adequately

weaken the relationship between earning management

and earning quality. It is because the value of tstatistic

moderate_1 (X1-X2) is smaller than ttable and the

significance value 0.776 is higher than (0.05). Thus,

this hypothesis is rejected. Institutional ownership

faces dificulties in getting information from the

company management to play a role in controlling

and detecting earning management. Another reason is

that institutional ownership is more focused on

current income (Porter, 1992; Mas’ud, 2003),

therefore, this condition allows company management

an opportunity to conduct earning management in the

short term.

The result of third hypothesis (b) shows that the

board of director size cannot adequately weaken the

relationship between earning management and

earning quality. This is because the value of tstatistic

moderate_2 (X1-X3) is higher than -ttable and the

significance value 0.481 is higher than (0.05). Thus,

this hypothesis is also rejected. Because the

effectiveness of the board of director is affected by

many factors, such as board of director size and

composition, equalitable appointment system, profile

of board members, competenccy and independence of

members. These factors are not owned by all

companies, so company management tends to do

earning management for their personal interest.

(Anand, 2008).

Although both hypotheses are rejected

individually based on the statistical criteria, it is,

however, evident that both governance variables have

some moderating effects, though not significant, on

constraining earnings management to affect earnings

quality. Because, Table-3 above reveals that earnings

management can negatively affect earning quality at

10% level of confidence, which is weaker than the

effect reported in Table-2. Given that there is no

change in the findings of institutional ownership and

board of director size in Table-2 and Table-3 in

influencing earning management (i.e. insignificant

relation with earnings quality), still there is significant

change in earnings management influencing earnings

quality in Table-2 (i.e. it has strong significant

negative relation with earnings quality at 5% level of

confidence) and Table-3 (i.e. it has either no

significant relation with earnings quality or weak

significant negative relation with earnings quality at

10% level of confidence). Therefore, it can be argued

that both institutional ownership and board of director

can jointly deter earnings management to some extent

that leads to improving earnings quality as reflected in

Table-3 comparing with Table-2. Thus, we conclude

that institutional ownership and board size have

weaken the association between earnings management

and earnings quality, indicating that corporate

governance variables can deterring constrain earnings

management. However, the weakening effect is much

higher for board of director size than institutional

ownership.

The forth hypotheses testing used regression for

moderating variables, and the result is as follow:

Page 60: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

214

Table 4. Summary of Regression for Moderating Variables on the Impact of firm-specific Attributes to the

Relationship between Earning Management and Earning Quality

No. Variable Regress.

Coeff. t statistic t table Sig.

1 Earning Management (X1) -0.169 -2.359 < -1.660 0.019

2 Financial Leverage (X4) -0.138 -1.942 < -1.660 0.053

3 Company Size (X5) 0.001 0.011 > 1.660 0.992

4 Moderate_3 (X1-X4) 0.090 1.014 < 1.660 0.312

5 Moderate_4 (X1-X5) -0.032 -0.372 > -1.660 0.710

Constant = -0.052

Adjusted R Square = 0.028

Fstatistic = 2.175

The result of fourth hypothesis (a) shows that

financial leverage cannot strengthen the relationship

between earning management and earning quality.

This is because the value of tstatistic moderate_3 (X1-

X4) is smaller than ttable and the significance value

0.312 is higher than (0.05). Thus, this hypothesis is

rejected. Because the investors may have assumption

when the company has big amount of debt that

company management use that fund in supporting

company operational activities. This activity tends to

reduce the possibility of earning management

practices.

The result of forth hypothesis testing (b) also

shows that firm size cannot strengthen the relationship

between earning management and earning quality.

This is because the value of tstatsitic for moderate_4

(X1-X4) is higher than -ttable and significance value

0.710 is higher than (0.05). Therefore, this

hypotheis is also rejected. This implies that investors

are very careful in making investment decision

making as they rely on both financial and non

financial information. That is, company size cannot be

used to evaluate the existence of earning management

practices that can reduce earning quality. This finding

is consistent with Sulistiyono ( 2010).

Again, similar to Table-3, although both

hypotheses are rejected individually based on the

statistical criteria, it is, however, evident that both

firm-specific variables have some moderating effects,

though not significant, on strengthening earnings

management to affect earnings quality. Because,

Table-4 above reveals that earnings management can

negatively affect earning quality at a slightly lower

level than in Table-2 at 5% level of confidence. Also

importantly, in Table-4 the findings of both financial

leverage and firm size are different from that of in

Table-2. It appears that the significant influence of

financial leverage on earnings quality has shifted from

positive to negative sign, in one hand, the significant

negative influence of firm size on earnings quality has

shifted to insignificant relation with positive sign, on

the other. This indicates that high financial leverage

may decorate earnings quality as managers may

engage in more earnings management not to violate

debt covenants. Again, increased firm size may keep

the firm in a position to disseminate information to

keep investors updated and contain reputation in the

market, but still have resource limitation to do so

adequately. As a result, firm size lacks its influence to

positively affect earnings quality. Thus, we conclude

that leverage has strengthened the relation between

earnings management and market return, implying

that high leverage is more exposed to earnings

management. On the other hand, firm size remains

indifferent in strengthened the relation between

earnings management and earnings quality although it

shows a tendency to weakening earnings management

with positive but insignificant relationship with

earnings quality.

5. Conclusion This study investigates the impact of earnings

management on earnings quality along with a number

of moderating (both governance and financial)

variables in an emerging market context - Indonesia.

We use discretionary accruals following Modified

Jones Model and earnings response coefficient/CAR

as the proxies for, respectively, earnings management

and earnings quality (i.e. for market return). It

examines 4 different types of hypotheses (9

hypotheses in total) on a sample of 52 manufacturing

firms listed on the Indonesia stock exchange during

2007 to 2010 periods. Our regression results in Table-

2 reveal that earnings management has significant

negative influence of market return, confirming

hypothesis 1 as expected. Of the moderating

variables, good corporate governance variables

proxied by institutional ownership and board of

director size and firm-specific attributes proxied by

financial leverage and company size also have

significant effect on earning quality, except

institutional ownership variable. This confirms

hypothesis 2 partially for corporate governance

variables and completely for firm-specific variables.

Again, observing the use of moderator effects on

earnings management, Table-3 rejects hypothesis 3

statistically, but denotes that while both institutional

ownership and board size have some weakening effect

Page 61: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

215

of the association between earnings management and

market return, board size has more power to deterring

earnings management than institutional ownership.

Similarly, Table-4 also rejects hypothesis 3

statistically, but indicates that leverage has

strengthened the relation between earnings

management and market return showing more

exposure to earnings management by changing sign of

significant influence from positive to negative

between Table-2 and Table-4, whereas firm size

remains indifferent showing a tendency to weakening

earnings management by changing level of

significance and sign from negative significant to

positive insignificant between Table-2 and Table-4.

The results of this study have several

implications for Indonesian corporate sector and

policy makers in adopting appropriate governance

measures to constrain earnings management, for

instance ineffectiveness of external monitoring by

institutional owners, effective monitoring of board

with small size, negative signal of leverage in the

market, and positive indication of firm size in

disseminating reliable financial information in the

market etc. Given that this type of study is new

showing the relationship between earnings

management and market return along with governance

and firm-specific moderating variables, the study

does, however, assumes a number of limitations, such

as small sample size and period of years undertaken, a

few variable in this model, low value of Adjusted R2

etc. It is expected that future research can overcome

these limitations by taking larger sample size and time

periods as well as adding more variables such as

board of director members’ appointment equality

system, competency and independency that could be

measured with secondary and questionnaire based

primary data (Anand, 2008).

References 1. Agus Sulistiyono. 2010. “The effect of company size,

capital structure and company growth to the earning

response coefficient / ERC on the manufacturing firm

listed on Indonesian Stock Exchange. Thesis from

State University of Semarang, Indonesia in

www.fe.unnes.ac.id/digital_library (all term in

indonesian language).

2. Alford, A., Jones, J., Leftwich, R. and Zmijewski, M.

(1993). The relative informativeness of accounting

disclosures in different countries, Journal of

Accounting Research, 31, pp. 183-223.

3. Andini Novianti, 2010. “The Effect of Corporate

Governance Mechanism to The Degree of Accounting

Conservatism”. Thesis of Economics Faculty,

University of Jenderal Soedirman.

www.fe.unsoed.ac.id

4. Andri Rachmawati and Hanung Triatmoko. 2007.

“Analysis of Factors Affecting Earning Quality and

Firm Value”. Proceeding of National Accounting

Symphosium X, Makasar, Indonesia.

www.sna10makasar.com

5. Anggraini Niken Susanti. 2010. “The Effect of

Corporate Governance Mechanism to the Firm Value

with Earning Quality as Intervening Variable in

Manufacturing Firm Listed on Indonesian Stock

Exchanhe for period 2004-2007”. Proceeding of The

National Symphosium of Finance, Surakarta,

Indonesia. www.si.uns.ac.id

6. Anis MNIF. 2010. “Corporate Governance and

Management Earnings Forecast Quality : Evidence

From French IPOS”. Author manuscript, published in

"La place de la dimension européenne dans la

Comptabilité Contrôle Audit, Strasbourg : France

(2009)".

7. Armstrong, C. S., Core, J. E., Taylor, D. J., &

Verrecchia, R. E. (2011). When Does Information

Asymmetry Affect the Cost of Capital? Journal of

Accounting Research, 49(1), 1-40.

8. Astuti, D., S., P. 2002. “Analysis of Factors Affecting

Earning Management Motivation around Right Issue”.

Thesys of Master Accounting, Gajah Mada

University, Indonesia retrived from

www.etd.ugm.ac.id/index/php at 21 February 2012.

9. Baek, H. Y., Johnson, D. R. and Kim, J. W. (2009)

Managerial ownership, corporate governance and

voluntary disclosure, Journal of Business & Economic

Studies, 15(2), pp. 44-61.

10. Balsam, S., Bartov, E and Marquardt, C. (2002)

Accrual management, investor sophistication and

equity valuation: Evidence from 10-Q Filings, Journal

of Accounting Research, 40(4), pp. 987-1012.

11. Bambang Sutopo. 2009. “Earning Management and

Earning Quality in Investment Decision” paper

retrived from

http://pustaka.uns.ac.id/?menu=news&option=detail&

nid=144 (at 14 november 2011).

12. Bathala, C. and Rao, R. (1995) The determinants of

board composition: An agency theory perspective,

Managerial and Decision Economics, 16, pp. 59-69.

13. Beasley, M. (1996). An empirical analysis of the

relation between the board of director composition

and financial statement fraud, The Accounting

Review, 71(4), pp. 443-65.

14. Beattie, V., S. Brown., D. Ewer., B. John., S.

Manson., D. Thomas., and M. Tuner. 1994.

“Extraordinary Item and Income Smoothing, A

Positive Accounting Approach”. Journal of Business

Finance and Accounting, Vol.21. September, 791-

811.

15. Bédard, J., Chtourou, S. M., & Courteau, L. (2004).

The effect of audit committee expertise,

independence, and activity on aggressive earnings

management. Auditing: A Journal of Practice &

Theory, 23(2), 13–35.

16. Boediono, G.S.B. 2005. “Earning quality : the impact

of good corporate governance and earning

management”. Proceeding of National Accounting

Symposium VIII, Solo, Indonesia.

17. Belkaoui Riahi Ahmed. 2004. Acconting Theory.

Jakarta: Salemba Empat.

18. Bozec, Y., & Bozec, R. (2007). Ownership

concentration and corporate governance practices:

Substitution or expropriation effects? Canadian

Journal of Administrative Sciences, 24(3), 182–195.

19. Burgstahler, D., & Dichev, I. (1997). Earnings

management to avoid earnings decreases and losses.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(1), 99–126.

20. Chan, K. C. and Seow, G. S. (1996) The association

between stock returns and foreign GAAP earnings

Page 62: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

216

versus earnings adjusted to U.S. GAAP, Journal of

Accounting and Economics, 21, pp. 139-158.

21. Charoenwong, C. and Jiraporn, P. (2009) Earnings

management to exceed thresholds; Evidence from

Singapore and Thailand, Journal of Multinational and

Financial Management, 19, pp. 221-236.

22. Cheung, S. Y. L., & Chan, B. Y. (2004). Corporate

governance in Asia. Asia-Pacific Development

Journal, 11(2), 1–31.

23. Chrisman, J. J., Chua, J. H., & Litz, R. A. (2004).

Comparing the agency costs of family and non-family

firms: Conceptual issues and exploratory evidence.

Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice, 28(4), 335–354.

24. Chtourou, S.M., Bedard.J., and Couteau,L. 2001.

“Corporate Governance and Earnings Management”.

Sosial Sience Research Network, retrived from

http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=275053. At 20

February 2012.

25. Coles, J. L., Daniel, N. D. and Naveen, L. (2008)

Boards: Does one size fit all?, Journal of Financial

Economics, 87, pp. 329–356.

26. Cormier, D., Magnan, M. and Morard, B. (2000) The

contractual and value relevance of reported earnings

in a dividend-focused environment, European

Accounting Review, 9(3), pp. 387−417.

27. Dalton, D., Daily, C., Johnson, J., Ellstrand, A. (1999)

Number of directors and financial performance: a

meta-analysis. Academy of Management Journal, 42,

pp. 674–686.

28. Darmawati, D. 2003. “Corporate Governance and

earning management: an empirical study”. Jurnal

Bisnis and Akuntansi, Vol. 5 (1), pp. 47-68.

29. Davidson, W. N., Jiraporn, P., Kim, Y. S. and Nemec.

C. (2004) Earnings management following duality-

creating successions: Ethnostatistics, impression

management and agency theory, Academy of

Management Journal, 47(2), pp. 267-275.

30. Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L.

(1997). Toward a stewardship theory of management.

Academy of Management Review, 22, 20–47.

31. Dechow, P.M., Sloan, R. G. and Sweeney, A. (1996)

Causes and consequences of earnings manipulation:

An analysis of firms subject to enforcement actions by

the SEC, Contemporary Accounting Research, 13, pp.

1-36.

32. Dechow, M. P., & Schrand, C. M. (2004). Earnings

Quality. New York: The Research Foundation of CFA

Institute.

33. Degeorge, F., Patel, J. and Zeckhauser, R. (1999)

Earnings management to exceed thresholds, Journal of

Business, 72(1), pp. 1−33.

34. Deni Darmawati. 2003. “Corporate Governance and

Earning Management : an Empirical Study”. Jurnal

Bisnis dan Akuntansi, Vol. 5 (1), pp. 47-68.

35. Dewi Saptantinah Puji Astuti. 2002. “Analysis of

Factors Affecting Earning Management Motivation

around Right Issue”. Paper University of Andalas,

Indonesia retrived from

www.ojs.unud.ac.id/index/php at 21 February 2012.

36. Dhaliwal, D. S., Salomon G. L., dan Smith, E. D.

1982. “The Effect of Owner Versus Management

Control on the Choice of Accounting Methods”.

Journal of Accounting and Economics, Vol.4. hal.41 -

53.

37. Diky Mardianto. 2009. “The Effect of Corporate

Governance to The Earning Management and Firm

Value on Manufacturing Firm Listed in Indonesian

Stock Exchange on Period 2005-2007)”. Thesys at

faculty of Economic, University of Jenderal

Soedirman, Indonesia. www.fe.unsoed.ac.id

38. Donnelly, R. and Mulcahy, M. (2008) Board

structure, ownership and voluntary disclosure in

Ireland, Corporate Governance: The International

Review, 16, pp. 416-429.

39. DuCharme, L. L., Malatesta, P. H. and Sefcik, S. E.

(2004) Earnings management, stock issues, and

shareholder lawsuits, Journal of Financial Economics,

71, pp. 27-49.

40. Easton, P. D. and Zmijewski, M. E. (1989) Cross

sectional variation in the stock market response to

accounting earnings announcements, Journal of

Accounting and Economics, 11, pp. 117-141.

41. Eisenhardt, Kathleem M. 1989. “Agency Theory: An

Assesment and Review”. Academy of Management

Review, 14, hal 57-74.

42. Eisenberg, T., Sundgren, S., & Wells, M. T. (1998).

Larger board size and decreasing firm value in small

firms. Journal of Financial Economics 48(1), 35–54.

43. Etty Murwaningsari. 2008. “Factors affecting

Earnings Response Coefficient (ERC)”. Doctorate

thesis on University of Indonesia, Jakarta.

www.fe.ui.ac.id

44. Fama, E. F. and Jensen, M. C. (1983) Separation of

ownership and control, Journal of Law and

Economics, 26, pp. 301-325.

45. Fields, T. D., Lys, T. Z. and Vincent, L. (2001)

Empirical research on accounting choice, Journal of

Accounting and Economics, 31(1-3), September, pp.

255–307.

46. Forum For Corporate Governance In Indonesia

(FCGI). 2003. Indonesia Company Law. Retrived

from www.fcgi.or.id. at 8 November 2011.

47. Friedlan, J. M. (1994). Accounting choices of issuers

of initial public offerings. Contemporary Accounting

Research, 11(1), 1-31.

48. Gagaring Pagalung. 2006. “Earnings Quality :

Determinant Factors and Economic Consequences”.

Proceeding of National Accounting Symphosium IX

Padang, Indonesia, accesable on

www.sna9padang.com .

49. García-Lara, J. M., García-Osma, B., & Neophytou,

E. (2009). Earnings quality in ex-post failed firms.

Accounting & Business Research, 39(2), 119–138.

50. Ghozali, I. 2005. The application of multyvariate

analysis with SPSS. Diponegoro University Publisher,

Semarang, Indonesia.

51. Gideon SB Boediono. 2005. “Earning Quality :

Empirical Study on The Effect of Corporate

Governance Mechanism and Earning management”.

Proceeding of national Symphosium of Accounting

III, Surakarta, Indonesia. Accesable at

www.sna8surakarta.com

52. Gitman, L. J. and Madura, J. (2001). Introduction to

Finance. ISBN: 0201635372, Publisher: Addison-

Wesley

53. Gujarati, Damodar. 1993. The Echonometrics.

Indonesian Edition by Sumarno Zain. Erlangga

Publisher. Jakarta.

54. Hafiza Aishah Hashim dan S. Susela Devi. 2004.

“Corporate Governance, Ownership Structure and

Earnings Quality : Malaysian Evidence”. Retrived

from

http://lby100.com/ly/200806/P0200806273268118812

21.pdf. at 19 February 2012.

Page 63: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

217

55. Haniffa, R. M., & Hudaib, M. (2006). Corporate

governance structure and performance of Malaysian

listed companies. Journal of Business Finance &

Accounting, 33(7/8), 1034–1062.

56. Hashim, H. A., and Devi, S.S. 2004. “Corporate

Governance, Ownership Structure and Earnings

Quality : Malaysian Evidence”. Retrived from

http://lby100.com/ly/200806/P0200806273268118812

21.pdf. at 19 Februari 2012.

57. Healy, P. and Wahlen, J. (1999) A review of the

earnings management literature and its implications

for standard setting, Accounting Horizons, December,

pp. 365-383.

58. Healy, P. M. and Palepu, K. G. (2001) Information

asymmetry, corporate disclosure and the capital

markets: A review of the empirical disclosure

literature, Journal of Accounting and Economics,

31(1-3), September, pp. 405-440.

59. Heflin, F. and K.W. Shaw. 2000. Blockholder

ownership and market liquidity. Journal of Financial

and Quantitative Analysis 35 (4): 621-633.

60. Herawaty, V. 2008. “Corporate governance as a

moderating between earning management and firm

value”. Proceeding of National Accounting

Symposium XI, Pontianak, Indonesia.

61. Ho, S. S. M., and Wong, K. S. (2001) A study of the

relationship between corporate governance structures

and the extent of voluntary disclosure, Journal of

International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation,

10(2), Summer, pp. 139–56.

62. Imam Ghozali. 2005. Multivariate Analysys with

SPSS. Semarang : University Diponegoro Publisher.

63. Ismail, W.A.W. 2008. “Earnings Quality and

Corporate Governance Following The Implementation

of Malaysian Code of Corporate Governance”.

Retrived from

http://www.af.polyu.edu.hk/jcae_af/2010/paper_p/Ses

sion%205.pdf. At 19 February 2012.

64. Jang, L., Sugiarto, B., and Siagian, D. 2007. “Factors

affecting earning quality in manufacturing frms listed

on Indonesian Stock Exchange”. Journal

Akuntabilitas. pg. 142-149, Pancasila University,

Indonesia

65. Jensen, Michael C. Dan W.H. Meckling. 1976.

“Theory of the Firm : Managerial Behavior, Agency

Cost and Ownership Structure”. Journal of Financial

Economic. Vol.3.

66. Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial

revolution, exit and the failure of internal control

system. Jounal of Finance, 48(3), 831–880.

67. Jiraporn, P., Miller, G. A., Yoon, S. S. and Kim, Y. S.

(2008) Is earnings management opportunistic or

beneficial? An agency theory perspective,

International Review of Financial Analyst, 17, pp.

622-634.

68. Jo, K. and Kim, Y. (2007) Disclosure frequency and

earnings management, Journal of Financial

Economics, 84, pp. 561-590.

69. John, K., and Senbet, L. (1998) Corporate governance

and board effectiveness, Journal of Banking and

Finance, 22, pp. 371-403

70. Johnson, V. E., Khurana, I. K., & Reynolds, J. K.

(2002). Audit-firm tenure and the quality of financial

reports. Contemporary Accounting Research, 19(4),

637–660.

71. Jones, J. J. (1991) Earnings management during

import relief investigations, Journal of Accounting

Research, 29, pp. 193-228.

72. Kanagaretnam, K., Lobo, G. J. and Whalen, D. J.

(2007) Does good corporate governance reduce

information asymmetry around quarterly earnings

announcements?, Journal of Accounting and Public

Policy, 26, pp. 497–522.

73. Karamanou, I., & Vafeas, N. (2005). The association

between corporate boards, audit committees, and

management earnings forecasts: An empirical

analysis. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(3), 453–

486.

74. Kao L., Chen A., (2004), « The effects of board

characteristics on earnings management. Corporate

Ownership and Control, vol. 1, n° 3, pp. 96-107.

75. Kent, P. Routledge, J and Stewart, J. (2010) Innate

and discretionary accruals quality and corporate

governance, Accounting and Finance, 50, pp. 171-

195.

76. Kristiany. 2011. “The Effect of Information

Assymetric and Corporate Governance to the earning

management in manufacturing firm listed on

Indonesian Stock Exchange. Thesys of Faculty of

Economics, University of Jenderal Soedirman,

Indonesia.

77. Leftwich, R., Watts, R.L., and Zimmerman, J.L

(1981) Voluntary corporate disclosure: the case of

interim reporting, Journal of Accounting Research.

19, pp. 50-77.

78. Leuz, C., & Verrecchia, R. E. (2000). The economic

consequences of increased disclosure. Journal of

Accounting Research, 38(3), 91–124.

79. Linck, J., Netter, J. and Yang, T. (2008) The

determinants of board structure, Journal of Financial

Economics, 87, 308-328.

80. Mak, Y. T., & Kusnadi, Y. (2005). Size really

matters: Further evidence on the negative relationship

between board size and firm value. Pacific-Basin

Finance Journal, 13(3), 301–318.

81. Midiastuty, Pratana P., and Mas’ud Machfoedz. 2003.

“Relationship between earning management and

earning quality”. Proceeding of National Accounting

Symposium 6, Surabaya, Indonesia.

82. Moradi, Mehdi. 2010. “A Study of the Effect of

Financial Leverage on Earnings Response Coefficient

through out Income Approach: Iranian Evidence”.

International Review of Accounting, Banking and

Finance. Vol. 2 No. 2 Page 104-116.

83. Moradi, M.A., and Nezami, A. 2011. “Influence of

Ownership Structure on Earning Quality in the Listed

Firms of Tehran Stock Exchange”. International

Journal of Business Administration. Vol. 2, No. 4.

84. Muh. Arief Ujiyantho and Bambang Agus Pramuka,

2007. “Corporate Governance Mechanism, Earning

Management, and Financial Performance in

Manufacturing Firm Listed on Indonesian Stock

Exchange. Proceeding of National Accounting

Symphosium X, Makasar, Indonesia. Accesable at

www.sna9makasar.com

85. Myers, J. N., Myers, L. A., & Omer, T. C. (2003).

Exploring the term of the auditor-client relationship

and the quality of earnings: A case for mandatory

auditor rotation? Accounting Review, 78(3), 779–799.

86. Nadia Sriherdiati. 2010. “The Effect of Company

Characteristic to Cost of Equity Capital with Earning

Management as Intervening Variable in

Page 64: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

218

Manufacturing Firm Listed on Indonesian Stock

Exchange. Thesys of Economics Faculty, University

of Jenderal Soedirman, Indonesia.

87. National Committee on Governance Policy (KNKG in

Indonesian term), 2006, Hand Book for Good

Corporate Governance in Indonesia, Jakarta.

88. Nur Indriantoro and Bambang Supomo. 2002.

Research Method for Business for Accounting and

Management. BPFE UGM Publisher, Yogyakarta,

Indonesia.

89. Osma, B., & Noguer, B. (2007). The effect of the

board composition and its monitoring committees on

earnings management: Evidence from Spain.

Corporate Governance, 15, 1413-1427.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2007.00654.x

90. Pagalung, G. 2006. “Earnings Quality : Determinant

Factors and Economic Consequences”. National

Accounting Symposium IX Padang, Indonesia.

91. Pedwell, K.; Warsame, H.; and Neu, D. 1994. The

accuracy of Canadian and New Zealand earnings

forecasts: A comparison of voluntary versus

compulsory disclosures. International Accounting,

Auditing and Taxation 3 (2): 221-236.

92. Rachmawati, A and Triatmoko, H. 2007. “The

Analysis of factors affecting the earning quality and

firm value”. Proceeeding of National Accounting

Simpossium X. University of Hasanuddin, Makasar,

Indonesia. Accesable in www.sna9makasar.com.

93. Rahman, R. A., & Ali, F. H. M. (2006). Board, audit

committee, culture and earnings management:

Malaysian evidence. Managerial Auditing Journal,

21(7), 783–804.

94. Rangan, S. (1998) Earnings management and the

performance of seasoned equity offerings, Journal of

Financial Economics, 50, pp. 101-122.

95. Ross, S (1973). The economic theory of agency: the

principal's problem. American Economic Review, 63,

pp. 134–139

96. Salvato, C., & Moores, K. (2010). Research on

accounting in family firms: Past accomplishments and

future challenges. Family Business Review, 23(3),

193–215.

97. Schipper, K., & Vincent, L. (2003). Earnings quality.

Accounting Horizons, 17(Supplement), 97–110.

98. Scott, R. William. 2003. Financial Accounting

Theory. Prentice Education Canada Inc. Toronto.

99. Sembiring, E.D. 2005. “Company Characteristic and

Social Responsibility Disclosure in The Companies

Listed on Indonesian Stock Exchange”. National

Accounting Symphosium VIII. Surakarta, Indonesia.

www.sna8surakarta.com

100. Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1986). Large

shareholders and corporate control. The Journal of

Political Economy, 94(3), 461–488.

101. Siregar, S.V.N.P and Siddharta, U. 2005. “The effect

of ownership structure, company size, and good

corporate governance to the earning

management”.Proceeding of National Accounting

Symposium VIII, Padang, Indonesia.

102. Siregar, S. V., & Utama, S. (2008). Type of earnings

management and the effect of ownership structure,

firm size, and corporate-governance practices:

Evidence from Indonesia. The International Journal of

Accounting, 43(1), 1–27.

103. Sonda Marrakchi Chtourou, Jean Bedard, and Lucie

Couteau. 2001. “Corporate Governance and Earnings

Management”. Sosial Sience Research Network.

http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=275053. at 20

February 2012.

104. Sony Warsono dkk. 2009. Corporate Governance

Concept and Model Perserving True Organization

Walfare. Penerbit Center Of Good Corporate.

Yogyakarta.

105. Su, D. (2003) Stock price reactions to earnings

announcements: Evidence from Chinese markets,

Review of Financial Economics, 12, pp. 271–286.

106. Sulistyanto, H.S. 2008. Earning management :

theoretical and empirical model, Gramedia

Widiasarana Inc, Indonesia.

107. Susanti, A. N. 2010. “The Effects of Corporate

Governance mechanism to the firm value and earning

quality on companies Listed in Indonesian Sock

Exchange”. Proceeding of National Financal

Accounting Sympossium I. Jakarta, Indonesia

108. Sutopo, B. 2009. “The role of earning management

and earning quality in investment decision making”.

Retrived from

http://pustaka.uns.ac.id/?menu=news&option=detail&

nid=144 at 14 november 2011.

109. Syaiful Iqbal. 2007. “Corporate Governance as a

control for Earnings Management practice”. Journal

Ventura, Vol. 10, No. 3, Desember.

110. Teoh, S. H., Welch, I., & Wong, T. J. (1998).

Earnings management and the underperformance of

seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Financial

Economics, 50(1), 63–99.

111. Ujiyantho, M.A., and Pramuka, B.A, 2007.

“Corporate governance, earning management and

financial performance in manufacturing firm listed on

Indonesian Stock Excnage ”. Proceeding of National

Accounting Symposium X, Makasar, Indonesia.

112. Vafeas, N. (2000). Board structure and the

informativeness of earnings. Journal of Accounting

and Public Policy, 19(2), 139–160.

113. Vinola Herawaty. 2008. “The Role of Corporate

Governance as a Moderating Variable in the effect of

Earnng Management to the Firm Value”. Proceeding

of National Accounting Symphosium XI, Pontianak,

Indonesia.

114. Wan Adibah Wan Ismail, dkk. 2008. “Earnings

Quality and Corporate Governance Following The

Implementation of Malaysian Code of Corporate

Governance”.http://www.af.polyu.edu.hk/jcae_af/201

0/paper_p/Session%205.pdf. Diakses tanggal 19

Februari 2012.

115. Welker, M. (1995) Disclosure policy, information

asymmetry, and liquidity in equity markets,

Contemporary Accounting Research, 11, Spring, pp.

801-827.

116. Welvin I Guna, and Arleen Herawati. 2010. “The

Effect of Good Corporate Governance Mechanism,

Auditor’s Independence, Audit Quality to The

Earning Management”. Journal of Business and

Accountancy, Vol.12, No.1, April, pp.53-68.

117. Xie, B., Davidson, W. N., and DaDalt, P. J. (2003)

Earnings management and corporate governance: The

role of the board and the audit committee, Journal of

Corporate Finance, 9, pp. 295–316.

118. Yermack, D. (1996). Higher market valuation of

companies with a small board of directors. Journal of

Financial Economics, 40(2), 185–211.

119. Young, D., & Guenther, D. A. (2003). Financial

reporting environments and international capital

Page 65: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

219

mobility. Journal of Accounting Research, 41(3),

553–579.

120. Yu, F. (2008) Analyst coverage and earnings

management, Journal of Financial Economics, 88(2),

pp. 245-271.

121. Zahra, S. A., & Pearce II, J. A. (1989). Boards of

directors and corporate financial performance: A

review and integrative model. Journal of

Management, 15(2), 291–334.

122. Zhao, Y. and K. Chen, ‘Staggered boards and earnings

management’, The Accounting Review 2008, 83:

1347 – 1381.

123. Zhong, K., Gribbin, D. W. and Zheng, X. (2007) The

effect of monitoring by outside blockholders on

earnings management, Quarterly Journal of Business

and Economics, 46(1).

Page 66: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

220

Appendix 1. Clasical Assumption Test for Multiple Regression

Figure 1. Normality test

Figure 2. Multicolinearity test

One-Sample Kolmogorov-Smirnov Test

208

.6933

.3518

.074

.074

-.058

1.067

.205

N

Mean

Std. Dev iat ion

Normal Parameters a,b

Absolute

Positive

Negativ e

Most Extreme

Dif f erences

Kolmogorov-Smirnov Z

Asy mp. Sig. (2-tailed)

Unstandardiz

ed Residual

Test distribution is Normal.a.

Calculated f rom data.b.

Page 67: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

221

Figure 3. Heteroscedasticity test

Regression

Page 68: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

222

Figure 4. Auto-correlation test

Durbin Watson

Page 69: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

223

Figure 5. Distribution of t

Page 70: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

224

THE LIFECYCLE OF THE FIRM, CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND INVESTMENT PERFORMANCE

Jimmy A. Saravia*

Abstract

According to firm lifecycle theory the agency costs of free cash flows are not transitory problems but are a persistent issue for mature firms. This paper extends the theory by suggesting that to neutralize the threat of takeover the controlling parties of maturing firms progressively deploy antitakeover provisions, and this allows them to overinvest safely and prevent retrenchment. Another contribution of this paper is to develop a new empirical index that permits the identification of mature corporations with governance problems due to agency costs of free cash flows. Empirical results show that as firms mature free cash flows increase, more antitakeover provisions are put into place and negative net present value projects are undertaken. JEL classification code: G31, G34 Keywords: Firm Life Cycle, Free Cash flows, Corporate Governance, Overinvestment Professor, Grupo de Investigación en Banca y Finanzas, School of Economics and Finance, Center for Research in Economics

and Finance (CIEF), Universidad EAFIT, Carrera 49 Número 7 Sur 50, Medellín, Colombia Tel: (574) 2619500 ext. 8771 Email: [email protected]

1. Introduction

According to Agency Theory (AT) when corporations

earn substantial free cash flows, growth maximizing

managements will tend to invest in projects that yield

returns which are lower than the firms’ cost of capital

(Jensen, 1986). Stated this way, the theory suggests

that any firm earning significant free cash flows will

likely overinvest in negative net present value

projects. However, from the perspective of the

lifecycle of the firm this formulation leaves out

important considerations such as the expectations,

held by insiders and outsiders alike, about the

company’s future funding needs and investment

opportunities.

In particular, according to the lifecycle theory of

the firm the agency costs of free cash flows are not

transitory problems, but a persistent issue once firms

reach a certain stage in their lifecycle (Mueller, 2003).

Specifically, as firms mature their cash flows increase

substantially while their investment opportunities

decline, and to prevent retrenchment, growth

maximizing managements find it necessary to invest

in negative net present value projects. However, too

much overinvestment leads to low firm valuation and

potentially a hostile takeover. It is this threat of

takeover that limits the amount of overinvestment

undertaken by the management of the firm. On the

other hand, firm lifecycle theory suggests that young

firms will not overinvest even if it earns free cash

flows at a particular point in time. This is because fast

growing young firms usually depend on outside

sources to finance their long term growth. If growth

maximizing managements of young firms expect that

the free cash flows will be a temporary phenomenon

they will not jeopardize future growth by

overinvesting in the present. Thus, firm lifecycle

theory implies that the free cash flows problem will

occur in mature firms but not in young corporations.

In this sense, one contribution of this paper is to

provide evidence on the investment performance of

corporations over the lifecycle of the firm that is

supportive of the lifecycle view.

Furthermore, this paper extends the lifecycle

theory of the firm by proposing that to neutralize the

threat of takeover, managements of maturing firms

and their boards of directors progressively deploy

more consequential antitakeover provisions which

allow them to overinvest safely and prevent a

pronounced decline in the size of their corporations.

That is, as firms mature and the free cash flow

problem becomes more pronounced, company

managements and their boards of directors put into

place progressively more antitakeover provisions to

accommodate the overinvestments while at the same

time maintaining a comfortable level of job security.

An additional contribution of this paper is to

develop a new empirical index that, based on the

financial characteristics of firms over their lifecycle,

permits the identification of mature corporations with

governance problems due to agency costs of free cash

flows. As discussed below, the derivation of the index

Page 71: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

225

gives a clearer perspective on the fact that the agency

costs of free cash flows are not a one-off problem, but

are a recurrent issue once firms reach a certain stage

in their lifecycle. Importantly, the latter is overlooked

in the empirical literature as researchers usually

employ measures of cash flows retained by

management in a given fiscal year normalized by

book assets (e.g. Chi and Lee, 2010; Lehn and

Poulsen, 1989) or cash levels at some point in time

normalized by book assets or sales (Harford et al.,

2008; Ditmar and Mahrt-Smith, 2007; Jovanovic and

Rousseau, 2002). Contrary to the empirical index

constructed in this paper, such measures imply that

the free cash flow problem can be present in a firm in

a given year and disappear in the next rather than

being a recurrent problem and a feature of the

lifecycle of the firm.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows:

section 2 discusses firm lifecycle theory and the

progressive deterioration of corporate governance

over the lifecycle of the firm as evidenced by an

increase in overinvestment and managerial

entrenchment. Section 3 discusses the theory behind

the empirical index proposed in this paper to separate

young from mature companies. Section 4 discusses

the econometric specifications to test the theory.

Section 5, describes the data and presents the

econometric results. Section 6 concludes.

2. The Lifecycle of the Firm and Corporate Governance Figure 1 illustrates some of the key aspects of the

lifecycle theory of the firm developed by Mueller

(2003). The situation faced by young firms is shown

on the left hand side of the figure. According to the

theory, young firms are characterized by rapid growth

and by the fact that the amounts needed to fund their

positive net present value investment opportunities

will generally exceed its internal cash flows (I* >

CF). Hence, for young firms the shareholder-wealth-

maximization policy is to procure outside capital and

invest until the firm’s marginal cost of capital equals

the firm’s marginal return on investment and pay no

dividends. In this situation, shareholders will clearly

be in favor of providing the means to the young firm

to increase the level of investments until all positive

net present value projects have been undertaken.

Conversely, growth maximizing managements of

young firms would not invest in negative net present

value projects since future profit would be reduced

and the effect would be to increase present growth at

the expense of the future growth of the firm. Thus, for

a young firm, managerial and stockholder interests

regarding investment policy and growth coincide.

This is also represented on the left hand side of Figure

1 where the growth of young firms is depicted by a

solid line. As can be seen, for young firms growth

takes place at a rate which is consistent with

shareholder wealth maximization.

Figure 1. Schematic representation of firm growth over its lifecycle.

Total

output of

the firm

(e.g. total

sales)

Growth-

maximizing

firm

Firm age (in years)

Shareholder-

wealth-

maximizing

firm

Page 72: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

226

On the other hand, the right hand side of Figure

1 illustrates the case of mature firms. According to

lifecycle theory, as firms become older their cash

flows increase enormously while their investment

opportunities decline as their industry matures. As a

consequence, for older firms the positive net present

value investment opportunities eventually become

smaller that its internal cash flows (I* < CF). Now, for

mature firms the shareholder-wealth-maximizing

policy would also be to continue investing until the

marginal rate of return of the firm is equal to its

marginal cost of capital. However, this would involve

the reduction in the size of the firm as shown by the

solid line in the figure. In order to prevent a reduction

in the size of the firm, firm lifecycle theory predicts

that growth-maximizing managements will tend to

reduce, but not totally suppress, dividend payouts as

these payments diminish the quantity of resources

available for growth. Instead, managements will

invest the funds in negative net present value projects.

Consequently, it is at this point in the lifecycle of the

firm that the key agency problem of free cash flows

takes place. This is depicted in Figure 1 by a dashed

line representing the fact that the growth of mature

firms will be higher than that of a hypothetical mature

shareholder-wealth-maximizing firm.

Nevertheless, the lifecycle theory of the firm

also points out that there exist mechanisms that

prevent managers from overinvesting too much in

negative net present value projects. The most

important of these mechanisms is the threat of a

takeover. If shareholder dissatisfaction with

management is too great the stock price may plunge,

and this may increase the likelihood of a takeover.

Now, it is clear that in the context of U.S. institutions

the managements of maturing firms and their boards

of directors can neutralize the takeover threat to a

certain extent by progressively deploying antitakeover

provisions. Thus, in this paper we extend the lifecycle

theory of the firm by suggesting that as firms mature

and the free cash flow problem becomes more

pronounced, company managements and their boards

of directors put into place progressively more

antitakeover provisions to accommodate the

overinvestments while at the same time maintaining a

comfortable level of job security. The implication is

that as firms mature corporate governance will tend to

deteriorate as reflected in managerial entrenchment

and overinvestment in negative net present value

projects.

In addition it is important to note that, as shown

in Figure 1, despite the fact that mature firms tend to

over-invest their rate of growth is much lower than

that of firms in their early years. This is a

consequence of reduced opportunities for internal

investment in mature industries as mentioned above.

Therefore, according to firm lifecycle theory it is not

the fastest-growing firms that tend to over-invest for

these are typically young firms with good investment

opportunities. Instead, over-investment problems are

likely to occur in mature firms, especially those with

entrenched managements. Faced with the prospect of

contracting hierarchies, reduced real salaries, lower

opportunities for promotion, and even unemployment

many managers will very likely look for ways to

make their companies grow. The upshot is that a

mature-growth-maximizing firm will undertake more

investment and pay a lower dividend than a

stockholder-wealth-maximizing firm with the

objective of preventing retrenchment.

Thus, it is readily apparent that the lifecycle

theory of the firm provides a wealth of predictions for

some of the key issues in the field of corporate

finance and corporate governance that range from

agency conflicts to funding and dividend policy. In

this paper we will concentrate on the following

testable propositions: (a) the agency costs of free cash

flows are a recurrent problem for mature firms but not

a characteristic problem of young firms, (b) as firms

mature progressively more antitakeover provisions are

put into place to accommodate overinvestment, hence

(c) corporate governance deteriorates as firms mature.

3. An Empirical Index to Separate Young from Mature Firms

We have seen that according to firm lifecycle theory

the cash flows of young firms are usually too small

when compared to the amounts required for

investment at the optimal level. Therefore, young

firms can be characterized as being dependent on their

outside sources of finance to fully exploit their

investment opportunities. In contrast, the cash flows

of mature firms are generally larger than the amounts

of cash required for investment at the optimal level.

Thus, mature firms can be considered to be financially

autonomous in the sense that they can fund all their

investments and at the same time return part of that

cash to investors in the form of dividends or stock

repurchases.

However, it is also important to take into

account that debt financing is not subject to the free

cash flow problem. Clearly, if the firm fails to pay

interest or capital it becomes bankrupt and can be

liquidated. It is only the equity-holders that suffer

losses from a policy of growth maximization through

overinvestment. Hence, the key issue regarding the

agency costs of free cash flows is to determine when a

firm is financially dependent on shareholders and

when is financially autonomous from its shareholders.

Accordingly, let us define firms that are

financially dependent on shareholders as those that on

most occasions have cash flows that are smaller than

their investments funded with equity and retained

cash flows, and consequently have to issue new shares

in order to undertake the investments. Conversely, let

us define firms that are financially autonomous from

shareholders as those that on most occasions have

internal cash flows which are greater than their levels

of investments funded with equity and retained cash

Page 73: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

227

flows. It is in these financially autonomous firms

where the agency costs of free cash flow can occur.

From the foregoing considerations, an autonomy

index or “A-index” can be constructed as follows:

over a number of past years immediately preceding

the year in question, add up the number of times a

given company has cash flows which are greater than

its investments funded using new equity plus retained

cash flows (CF > ΔE + CF - Dividends). Clearly,

financially dependent young firms will tend to issue a

substantial amount of new equity and pay no

dividends so that their CF will usually be smaller than

their level of investments using new equity and

retained cash flows. On the other hand, financially

autonomous mature firms will issue very little new

equity and will pay dividends, so that their CF will be

usually greater than their level of investments using

new equity and retained cash flows. Thus, firms that

are financially autonomous from their shareholders

will obtain a higher score in this index relative to

those that are financially dependent on their

shareholders.

Now, how long a period should we consider in

order to construct the A-index? Graham (2006, p. 319)

suggests that in analyzing firm financial statements

one should use a fairly long period in the past: 7 to 10

years “in order to iron out the frequent ups and downs

of the business cycle”… and to get “a better idea of

the company’s earning power.” Hence, the A-index

for a given company in a given year will be

constructed by adding one point for each year in

which a company has greater cash flows than

investments funded with equity plus retained cash

flows over the previous 7 years. Accordingly, the A-

index will range from 0 to 7.

Importantly, the A-index is designed to avoid a

problem present in empirical studies that measure

firm age in years. Specifically, the difficulty is that

some firms mature faster than average e.g. those

producing intermediate goods like transistors, while

others mature much more slowly e.g. those

manufacturing consumer products like Coca Cola

(Mueller and Yun, 1998). Hence, if one measures firm

age in years there is a danger that some young firms

will be classified as mature when their economic

characteristics indicate they are still young, or vice-

versa, mature firms could be classified as young when

in fact they present all the characteristics of a mature

company. This problem is illustrated in Figure 2

below.

As can be seen, the A-index represents a better

empirical index for the purpose of separating young

firms from mature companies than firm age. While

measuring firm age in years can lead to an erroneous

classification as some firms mature faster than others,

the A-index will classify young firms as financially

dependent as long as they retain their strong growth.

On the other hand, the A-index will classify mature

firms as financially autonomous due to their slow

growth (or even negative growth).

Figure 2. Schematic representation of two firms with lifecycles of different length

Source: author’s considerations

Total

output of

the firm

(e.g. total

sales)

Firm with

long

lifecycle

Firm age (in years)

Firm with

short

lifecycle

Page 74: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

228

4. Econometric Specification

4.1. The “marginal q” method To test the propositions stated above, in this paper we

will employ a procedure first proposed by Mueller

and Reardon (1993) (henceforth M&R) to measure

deviations from shareholder wealth maximization as a

consequence of overinvestment. In stating their

method, M&R start by defining It as the investment of

a firm in period t, CFt+j as the cash flow that the

investment generates in t+j, and it as the firm’s

discount rate in t. Thus, the present value of the

investment, PVt can be expressed as follows:

1 )1(jj

t

jt

ti

CFPV

(1)

Then, M&R take the PVt from Eq. (1) and the

investment It, and calculate the ratio of “the pseudo

permanent return rt to it,” a ratio usually labelled qmt

or “marginal q.”

tmt

t

ttt Iq

i

IrPV

(2)

That is, M&R argue that if the company had

invested It in a project that generated a permanent

return rt, this project would have produced the same

PVt as in Eq. (1). The ‘qmt’ ratio is the key statistic in

M&R’s analysis; it can measure overinvestment

problems of the type where free cash flows are

retained and invested in negative net present value

projects. Then, M&R define the market value of the

firm Mt as:

(3)

Where, δt is defined as the depreciation rate that

the capital market appraises for the firm’s total

capital, and μt is the error of the market in evaluating

the market value of the firm. M&R then subtract Mt-1

from both sides of Eq. (3), replace PVt with qmt It, and

finally divide both sides by Mt-1 and obtain:

111

1

t

t

t

tmtt

t

tt

MM

Iq

M

MM

(4)

M&R then argue that Eq. (4) can be used to

estimate δt and qmt. To estimate Eq. (4) M&R utilize

data on the market value of each firm and its

investments. They define Mt as the sum of the market

value outstanding shares of a company plus the

market value of its outstanding debt. And they define

investment as:

ADVDREDDividendsCFI &

(5)

Where CF are the cash flows of the firm defined as

the sum of income before extraordinary items and

depreciation, and ΔD and ΔE are defined as net

additions to investment funds from changes in

outstanding debt and equity respectively. Moreover,

M&R argue that although R&D and advertising

expenditures ADV are charged to expenses (as

opposed to be treated as investments in the company

accounts) they are also forms of investment that can

produce intangible capital which contributes to a

firm’s market value, and that for this reason they add

them to their measure of total investment.

Figure 3. The M&R model – an example of an overinvestment situation.

Source: adapted from Mueller and Reardon (1993)

tttttt MPVMM 11

0 It/Mt-1

(Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 Slope =1

111

1

t

t

t

tmtt

t

tt

MM

Iq

M

MM

1ˆ mtq

Page 75: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

229

Figure 3 exemplifies the M&R equation (Eq.

(4)) and its usefulness for measuring overinvestment.

A marginal q which is smaller than one indicates that

managements are investing below the firm’s cost of

capital. In such a case shareholders would clearly

prefer to receive the cash in the form of dividends or

stock repurchases rather than seeing it reinvested. If

managements are able to repeatedly invest below the

firm’s cost of capital, this would evidence the

investor’s inability to force the managements to pay

out the free cash flows.

4.2. Specification of the investment performance equation

Since the objective of the present econometric

investigation is to determine whether overinvestment

occurs as the firm matures, the following specification

for marginal q will be estimated:

tititititimt firmagedelawarefirmsizeEindexAindexq ,5,41,3,2,10 (6)

Where, A-index is the index of firm financial

autonomy developed above and E-index is an index of

managerial entrenchment developed by Bebchuk et al.

(2009). In this paper we will employ Bebchuk et al.’s

index since it is constructed using a more reasoned

approach than other indices available in the literature.

Instead of including every single anti-takeover

provision in their index, Bebchuck et al. base the

inclusion of each provision on discussions with

lawyers, their own personal analysis and the

examination of provisions that attract opposition from

institutional investors. In this way, Bebchuk et al.

identify six key governance provisions: staggered

boards, limits to amend by-laws, poison pills, golden

parachutes, supermajority requirements for mergers,

and supermajority requirements for charter

amendments. The E-index is created for a given firm

in a given year by assigning a point for each of the six

key provisions that the firm has. Thus, the E-index

ranges from 0 to 6. These two indices will be our key

corporate governance determinants of marginal q. As

can be seen, the coefficients have been entered in Eq.

(6) with their expected a priori signs according to

theory and previous research. The equation states that

marginal q declines as firm financial autonomy and

managerial entrenchment increase. This is because

lifecycle theory predicts that as firms become more

financially autonomous and more antitakeover

provisions are put in place overinvestment will tend to

occur and this will be reflected in a low marginal q.

Moreover, to control for other potential

determinants of qmt, additional variables are included

in Eq. (6). The first of the control variables, firmsize,

will be measured as the natural logarithm of the book

value of total assets at the end of year t-1. This

variable is expected to have a negative sign. This is

because traditionally (i.e. before the mid-1980s in the

U.S.) large firm size used to be considered enough to

allow managements to substantially over-invest and

yet feel secure to a large extent. However, from the

point of view of managements, following the hostile

takeover wave of the 1980s large firm size probably

has not been considered sufficient to provide security,

and therefore it is likely that this variable may be

insignificant for samples taken from more recent

periods. Nevertheless, it is possible that this variable

may still retain some of its explanatory power and for

this reason it is included in Eq. (6) as a potential

determinant of marginal q.

Secondly, a control variable which takes the

value of 1 if a firm is incorporated in delaware and

zero otherwise is included in Eq. (6). It is expected on

a priori grounds that this variable will have a positive

sign. The reason is that prior work, such as that by

Daines (2001), suggests that the institutional

environment for firms incorporated in the state of

Delaware may be more effective in restraining agency

problems, in which case marginal q should be higher.

Finally, following prior work on rates of return on

investment over the lifecycle of the firm, firm age is

included as a control variable in Eq. (6). This variable

will be measured as the natural logarithm of the

number of years since the company’s incorporation. It

is expected a priori and on the grounds of previous

empirical research that the variable will have a

negative sign (see in particular Mueller and Yun,

1998). However, it is also possible that this variable

could be insignificant given that different firms have

lifecycles of different length, and that consequently,

the A-index may be a better empirical indicator when

it comes to the task of distinguishing young firms

from mature companies.

Substituting Eq. (6) into Eq. (4), including time

and industry dummy variables, and simplifying the

following investment performance regression

equation is obtained:

1,

,1

1

,

1

11,

,,5

1,

,,4

1,

,1,3

1,

,,2

1,

,,1

1,

,0

1,

1,,

)()(

)()()(

ti

tiJ

j

jij

T

t

tt

ti

titi

ti

titi

ti

titi

ti

titi

ti

titi

ti

ti

ti

titi

MIndustryTime

M

Ifirmage

M

Idelaware

M

Ifirmsize

M

IEindex

M

IAindex

M

I

M

MM

(7)

Page 76: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

230

Where Timet, t = 1,…, T-1 are time dummy

variables, and industryi,j, j =1,…, J-1 are industry

dummy variables, while α is the intercept for the base

or benchmark category.

Petersen (2009) has recently examined the

empirical literature and provides guidance on the

appropriate methods to follow when using corporate

finance panel data sets. Following his work, Eq. (7)

includes time dummy variables to deal with time

effects. In addition standard errors clustered by firm

will be used in the next section to address firm effects.

Finally, since depreciation rates should vary across

companies depending on the type of investments in

capital assets they undertake, Eq. (7) includes industry

dummy variables by assigning each company to a two

digit SIC industry code (Mueller and Yurtoglu, 2000).

5. Data and Econometric Results 5.1 Sample selection The starting point our data collection is Bebchuk et

al.’s (2009) E-index database. Currently, the database

contains information for the years 1990, 1993, 1995,

1998, 2000, 2002, 2004 and 2006. To obtain a sample

of firms with reasonably long time series of data with

which to build the variables, the database was initially

inspected for companies with non-missing values for

the years 1990 and 20044. In this manner 586

companies were identified. Given that some of the

companies changed names and ticker symbols, the

information was matched using 8 digit CUSIPs in

order to make sure that the data referred to the same

company5. Then, a search for these 586 firms was

performed using Datastream and 556 firms were

found. Next, banks, financial companies and certain

service industries (SICs 6000 to 6999 and above

8100) were excluded because the nature of capital and

investment in these industries is fundamentally

different when compared to non-financial firms. This

reduced the sample by 81 companies from 556 to 475.

For this final group of 475 firms the usual practice of

researchers who utilize corporate governance

provision indices (e.g. Gompers et al., 2003; Bebchuk

et al., 2009) was followed and the observations for the

years in which IRRC does not publish governance

provisions data were filled in by assuming that the

provisions remain unchanged in the period between

IRRC publications. Given the information contained

in Bebchuk’s database at the time of the data

4 Bebchuk et al.’s database contains two sub-samples, a no

dual class stock sub-sample and a dual class stock sub-sample. Following prior research we exclude dual class stocks for the reason that in those companies “the superior voting rights may be sufficient to provide incumbents with a powerful entrenchment mechanism that renders the other entrenchment provisions relatively unimportant” (Bebchuk et al., 2009). 5 CUSIP is an acronym that refers to the 8 character

alphanumeric security identifier distributed by the Committee on Uniform Security Identification Procedures.

collection for this paper it was possible to assign

values for the 475 firm’s E-indices for a period of 19

years, comprising the years from 1990 to 2008.

Market prices and accounting data for these

companies were obtained from the Datastream

database as described in the Appendix.

5.2 Sample description and test of hypotheses for differences between means

Table 1 provides summary statistics for the empirical

variables employed in this paper. As can be seen the

firms in the sample contain substantial variation in

their age, size, financial autonomy, entrenchment and

other variables important for testing our hypotheses in

the context of firm lifecycle theory.

This table provides summary statistics for the

variables employed in this paper. A-index is a firm-

level index of financial autonomy computed by

adding one point for every year, in the previous 7

years, in which a given firm’s cash flows are greater

than its investment financed using equity and retained

cash flows. E-index is the entrenchment index created

by Bebchuk et al. (2009). (Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 is the

percentage change in the market value of the firm

between the end of year t-1 and the end of year t.

It/Mt-1 is the investment undertaken by a given firm

during year t divided by the market value of the firm

at the end of year t-1. logtotalassets is the natural

logarithm of the book value of total assets measured

at the end of year t-1 in US$. delaware is a dummy

variable that takes the value of 1 if a firm is

incorporated in Delaware and zero otherwise.

logfirmage is the natural logarithm of firm age

measured in years since the company’s incorporation.

To further describe the sample used in this paper

Table 2 below presents the values of the A-index and

E-index variables sorted by firm age. Moreover, for

each variable the table presents tests hypotheses for

differences between the means of the youngest firms

(0 to 15 years of age and 16 to 30 years age) and the

means of older firms in the other time buckets. This is

interesting because it helps elucidate whether mature

firms earn more free cash flows than younger

companies and if the managements of older firms are

more entrenched. The information in the table

suggests that both propositions are correct. As can be

seen, older firms have higher A-indices on average

than younger companies and the tests of differences

between means indicate that the differences are

significant at the 1% level. Moreover, the table

indicates that the E-index tends to increase with firm

age and that the differences between the means of the

variable for young and mature firms are also

statistically significant at the 1% level.

Page 77: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

231

Table 1. Summary Statistics

Variable N Mean Median Std. Dev. Min Max

A-index 8687 5.0199 6 2.1651 0 7

E-index 8687 2.6594 3 1.3638 0 6

(Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 8620 0.0807 0.0309 0.3454 -0.8363 4.5065

It/Mt-1 8639 0.1262 0.0942 0.1607 -0.7120 2.2021

logtotalassetst-1 8686 21.6287 21.5468 1.4726 17.2768 27.2513

delaware 8687 0.4649 0 0.4988 0 1

logfirmage 8687 4.0373 4.2195 0.6085 0.0000 5.0752

Table 2. Financial autonomy and managerial entrenchment over the lifecycle of the firm

Firm age

A-index E-index

N Mean Std.

Dev.

Diff. 0-

15yrs

Diff. 16-

30yrs N Mean

Std.

Dev.

Diff. 0-

15yrs

Diff. 16-

30yrs

0 to 15

years 358 2.5419 2.3933

358 2.0196 1.4151

16 to 30

years 997 3.5757 2.3800 -1.0338*

997 2.3019 1.3942 -0.2823*

31 to 45

years 1235 4.4121 2.3583 -1.8702* -0.8364* 1235 2.5870 1.3933 -0.5674* -0.2851*

46 to 60

years 1114 4.7271 2.1890 -2.1852* -1.1514* 1114 2.7136 1.3682 -0.694* -0.4117*

61 to 75

years 1471 5.4317 1.9390 -2.8898* -1.856* 1471 2.6139 1.3574 -0.5943* -0.312*

76 to 90

years 1560 5.9314 1.4570 -3.3895* -2.3557* 1560 2.7423 1.3393 -0.7227* -0.4404*

91 to 105

years 1198 5.7362 1.5470 -3.1943* -2.1605* 1198 2.9332 1.2421 -0.9136* -0.6313*

106 to 120

years 445 5.7371 1.5218 -3.1952* -2.1614* 445 3.0090 1.3237 -0.9894* -0.7071*

121 to 135

years 154 5.4545 1.9607 -2.9126* -1.8788* 154 2.9935 1.1289 -0.9739* -0.6916*

136 to 150

years 122 5.9508 0.9435 -3.4089* -2.3751* 122 2.7377 1.2779 -0.7181* -0.4358*

151 to 165

years 33 5.5758 1.1997 -3.0339* -2.0001* 33 2.8788 1.139 -0.8592* -0.5769*

Table 2 presents the means and standard

deviations of the A-index and E-index variables sorted

by firm age. The A-index is a firm-level index of

financial autonomy computed by adding one point for

every year, in the previous 7 years, in which a given

firm’s cash flows are greater than its investment

financed using new equity and retained cash flows.

The E-index is the entrenchment index created by

Bebchuk et al. (2009). Firm age is the company’s age

measured in years since its incorporation. In addition,

for the A-index and E-index variables, the table tests

hypotheses for differences between the means of the

youngest firms (0 to 15 years as well as 16 to 30 years

of age) and the means of older firms in the other time

buckets. * and ** indicate that the difference is

significant at the 1% and 5% level respectively (one

tailed t-tests).

From these results we can conclude that while

younger firms depend on outside shareholders to

finance investments, older firms earn free cash flows

on a continuing basis which makes them largely

independent from shareholders. In addition, compared

to young firms older firms have more consequential

antitakeover provisions put in place as measured by

the E-index. Both results taken together suggest that

mature firms use the free cash flows that they earn on

a ongoing basis to overinvest while, on the other

hand, young companies will not overinvest even if

they earn free cash flows on a given year since their

managements know they will have to come back to

the shareholders for additional funding in the future.

Finally, correlations between the empirical

variables are presented in Table 3. It is interesting to

note that the E-index presents positive and significant

correlations with the A-index and logfirmage. This

implies that as firms mature, and on average become

more financially autonomous, their managements tend

to deploy a larger number of consequential anti-

takeover provisions. On the other hand, Table 3

shows that the A-index presents significantly negative

correlations with (Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 and It/Mt-1. This

suggests that, consistent with firm lifecycle

arguments, companies with a low A-index (young

firms) invest relatively more, and have a higher rate of

increase in their market values when compared to

firms with a higher A-index (older companies). The

latter is reinforced by the fact that that logfirmage also

has negative and significant correlations with (Mt-Mt-

1)/Mt-1 and It/Mt-1.

Page 78: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

232

Table 3. Correlation matrix

Variable A-index E-index (Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 It/Mt-1 logtotal-

assetst-1

delaware logfirmage

A-index 1.0000

E-index 0.0503* 1.0000

(Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 -0.1224* -0.0698* 1.0000

It/Mt-1 -0.1419* 0.0095 0.5219* 1.0000

logtotalassetst-1 0.1014* -0.0790* -0.0844* -0.0945* 1.0000

delaware -0.1363* -0.1307* 0.0419* 0.0774* 0.0340* 1.0000

logfirmage 0.4158* 0.1533* -0.1231* -0.1145* 0.2344* -0.2388* 1.0000

This table presents the correlation matrix for the

variables employed in this paper. A-index is a firm-

level index of financial autonomy computed by

adding one point for every year, in the previous 7

years, in which a given firm’s cash flows are greater

than its investment financed using equity and retained

earnings. E-index is the entrenchment index created

by Bebchuk et al. (2009). (Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1 is the

percentage change in the market value of the firm

between the end of year t-1 and the end of year t.

It/Mt-1 is the investment undertaken by a given firm

during year t divided by the market value of the firm

at the end of year t-1. logtotalassets is the natural

logarithm of the book value of total assets measured

at the end of year t-1 in US$. delaware is a dummy

variable that takes the value of 1 if a firm is

incorporated in Delaware and zero otherwise.

logfirmage is the natural logarithm of firm age

measured in years since the company’s incorporation.

* and ** indicate that a correlation is significant at the

1% and 5% level respectively.

Moreover, table 3 shows that the A-index has a

positive and significant correlation with logtotalassets

and logfirmage. This implies that, consistent with firm

lifecycle theory, companies with a high A-index are

on average relatively larger and older. Finally, note

the negative and statistically significant correlation

between delaware and logfirmage. This suggests that

the positive relationship between incorporation in

Delaware and good firm performance reported by

Daines (2001) may reflect that firms incorporated in

Delaware are younger on average than firms

incorporated elsewhere and not any corporate

governance advantage of incorporating in that State.

Having elucidated that database contains firms

with sufficient variation in their age, sizes and other

variables for the purposes of testing the paper’s

hypotheses, the next subsection employs the

econometric methods discussed above to test for

overinvestment.

5.3 Econometric results Table 4 below presents the results from

estimating Eq. (7). Mueller and Yun’s (1998)

investigation regarding investment performance over

the lifecycle of the firm is replicated in Table 4

column 1. This column shows results obtained by (a)

specifying marginal q as equal to an intercept plus a

coefficient times the natural logarithm of firm age, (b)

substituting for marginal q in the basic M&R

investment performance regression equation (Eq. 4)

and finally (c) estimating the parameters by OLS.

Similar to Mueller and Yun’s findings, the results in

the table show a significantly positive intercept of

1.8002 and negative and significant coefficient for

logfirmage of -0.1810. These estimates for our

sample, pertaining to the time period 1990-2008,

imply that for the average firm marginal q falls below

1 (indicative of overinvestment) around 80 years after

its incorporation (qmt = 1.8 - 0.18 (ln(80)) = 1). Table 4 presents estimates of ‘marginal q’ for

firms in the paper’s database over the time period from 1990 to 2008. The technique employed was originally developed by Mueller and Reardon (1993). The estimation method is OLS. The dependent variable is (Mt-Mt-1)/Mt-1, which is the percentage change in the market value of the firm between the end of year t-1 and the end of year t. It/Mt-1 is the investment undertaken by a given firm during year t divided by the market value of the firm at the end of year t-1. A-index is a firm-level index of financial autonomy computed by adding one point for every year, in the previous 7 years, in which a given firm’s cash flows are greater than its investment financed using equity and retained cash flows. E-index is the entrenchment index created by Bebchuk et al. (2009). logtotalassetst-1 is the natural logarithm of the book value of total assets measured at the end of year t-1 in US$. delaware is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if a firm is incorporated in Delaware and zero otherwise. logfirmage is the natural logarithm of firm age measured in years since the company’s incorporation. The regressions include year dummy variables to pick up movements in stock market values which are common to all firms. Moreover, each company is assigned to a two digit SIC industry code and industry dummy variables are also included. * and ** indicate that the coefficient is significant at the 1% and 5% level respectively (one tailed t-test). Following Petersen (2009) standard errors clustered by firm are reported in parentheses.

Page 79: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

233

Table 4. Investment performance over the lifecycle of the firm

Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

It/Mt-1 1.8002* 1.5942* 1.7184* 2.5330* 2.4793*

(0.2679) (0.1146) (0.2409) (0.4451) (0.4514)

(logfirmaget )It/Mt-1 -0.1810* -0.0392 -0.0352

(0.0640) (0.0566) (0.0608)

(A-indext )It/Mt-1 -0.0740* -0.0694* -0.0664* -0.0690*

(0.0146) (0.0144) (0.0144) (0.0149)

(E-indext )It/Mt-1 -0.0616* -0.0586* -0.0636* -0.0630*

(0.0202) (0.0198) (0.0206) (0.0211)

(logtotalassetst-1)It/Mt-1 -0.0374** -0.0424*

(0.0218) (0.0201)

(delawaret )It/Mt-1 -0.0559

(0.0583)

Industry dummy variables? yes yes yes yes yes

Time dummy variables? yes yes yes yes yes

Adjusted R2 0.3523 0.3616 0.3616 0.3628 0.3626

Number of observations 8618 8618 8618 8618 8618

However, as discussed above, a specification in

which firm age is measured in years since firm

incorporation has some important drawbacks. The

most important is that, logically, different firms will

have lifecycles of different lengths when measured in

years. This is the reason why the A-index was

constructed. Moreover, while the presence of free

cash flows is a necessary condition for

overinvestment, it is not sufficient. The reason is that

if management overinvests the market value of the

firm may plunge and a hostile takeover may ensue

(Mueller, 2003). This is why it is important to include

an index of antitakeover provisions such as the E-

index to determine how insulated firm management is

from the takeover threat. Thus, Table 4 column 2

specifies marginal q as equal to an intercept plus a

coefficient times the A-index plus another coefficient

times the E-index. This specification is then

substituted in M&R investment performance

regression equation (Eq. 4) and finally the parameters

are estimated by OLS. As shown in Table 4 column 2,

there are significantly negative coefficients for both

the A-index and the E-index at the 1 percent level.

Importantly, this result is consistent with the

predictions of firm lifecycle theory as it signifies that

marginal q will tend to decrease as both the A-index

and the E-index increase.

Next, Table 4 column 3 presents the results of

running a regression equation which includes the

preceding two kinds of measures (i.e. years since firm

incorporation and firm characteristics as captured by

the A-index and E-index) as a means to detect

overinvestment problems. As can be seen, while both

the A-index and the E-index coefficients remain

negative and significant at the 1% level, the

coefficient for the natural logarithm of firm age

becomes insignificant at any conventional level. The

reason for this result is that, as mentioned earlier,

although it is logically to expect that firms will go

through a lifecycle there is no reason to expect that

the lengths of company lifecycles measured in years

will be similar for the diversity of firms. Different

companies produce different types of products and

operate under different business conditions. For this

reason this paper argues that is more effective to

measure firm characteristics such as financial

autonomy and managerial entrenchment directly as a

means to assess firm age, than to try to determine if a

firm is young or mature by using firm age measured

in years.

Further, Table 4 column 4 presents the results of

running a regression equation with additional control

variables. Specifically, column 4 presents the results

of estimating Eq. (7) where specific predictions for its

coefficients are formulated. As can be seen, in this

specification both the A-index and the E-index

coefficients are negative as predicted and are

significant at the 1% level. However, the coefficient

for logfirmage although negative as expected on a

priori grounds is insignificant at any conventional

level. Interestingly, the coefficient for logtotalassetst-1

is negative as predicted, and it is significant at the 5%

Page 80: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

234

level (one tailed t-test). This provides evidence in

favor of the proposition that large firm size gives

managements protection from the takeover threat, and

that consequently, the managements of larger firms

have more leeway to overinvest than those of smaller

companies. On the other hand, contrary to our

expectations the coefficient for delaware is negative

and insignificant at any conventional level. Thus, at

least for our sample we find no evidence that the

institutional environment for firms incorporated in the

State of Delaware may be more effective in

preventing agency problems as manifested by

overinvestment.

Finally, Table 4 column 5 presents the results of

running a more parsimonious regression equation in

which marginal q is specified as equal to an intercept

plus a coefficient times the A-index, plus another

coefficient times the E-index, and finally an additional

coefficient times logtotalassetst-1. As shown in the

table, for this specification the intercept is

significantly positive at the 1% level and the

coefficients for the A-index, E-index and

logtotalassetst-1 are significantly negative at the 1%

level.

The investment performance results are further

illustrated with the aid of Table 5. This table presents

values for marginal q implied by the estimates in

Table 4 column 5 for different combinations of the A-

index and the E-index (similar results are obtained if

the estimates in Table 4 column 4 are used instead).

Note that in the calculations logtotalassetst-1 is held at

its mean value of 21.6287. Hence, for example, the

estimates imply that the value of marginal q for the

average firm when the A-index = 1 and the E-index =

1 equals 1.4302 (qmt= 2.4793 -0.069(1) –0.063(1) –

0.0424 (21.6287) = 1.4302).

Table 5. Calculated qmts for different combinations of the A-index and the E-index

A-index

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

E-i

nd

ex

0 1.5622 1.4932 1.4242 1.3552 1.2862 1.2172 1.1482 1.0792

1 1.4992 1.4302 1.3612 1.2922 1.2232 1.1542 1.0852 1.0162

2 1.4362 1.3672 1.2982 1.2292 1.1602 1.0912 1.0222 0.9532

3 1.3732 1.3042 1.2352 1.1662 1.0972 1.0282 0.9592 0.8902

4 1.3102 1.2412 1.1722 1.1032 1.0342 0.9652 0.8962 0.8272

5 1.2472 1.1782 1.1092 1.0402 0.9712 0.9022 0.8332 0.7642

6 1.1842 1.1152 1.0462 0.9772 0.9082 0.8392 0.7702 0.7012

Table 5 presents values for marginal q implied

by the estimates in Table 4 column 5 for different

combinations of the A-index and the E-index. A-index

is a firm-level index of financial autonomy computed

by adding one point for every year, in the previous 7

years, in which a given firm’s cash flows are greater

than its investment financed using equity and retained

earnings. E-index is the entrenchment index created

by Bebchuk et al. (2009). Note that in the calculations

logtotalassetst-1, the natural logarithm of the book

value of total assets measured at the end of year t-1 in

US$, is held at its mean value of 21.6287.

The results in Table 5 show that the values of

marginal q for the average firm are substantially

higher than 1 when firm financial autonomy as

measured by the A-index is low and managerial

entrenchment as measured by the E-index is also low.

Specially, the table shows the highest value of

marginal q of 1.5622 when the A-index and the E-

index are both equal to zero. More generally, the table

shows that the values of marginal q decline

progressively as financial autonomy and

entrenchment become more important.

The results in Table 5 can be best interpreted

with the aid of Figure 4. Marginal q equals the area

under the marginal rate of return schedule (mrr)

between 0 and the level of investments divided by the

area under the cost of capital (i) between 0 and the

level of investments (Mueller and Yurtoglu, 2000).

Thus, an estimated marginal q that is greater than one

is consistent with the interpretation that firms are

maximizing shareholder value by equalizing their

marginal rates of returns to their marginal cost of

capital. For example, as shown in Figure 4, if a firm

invested I1 it would equalize its marginal rate of

return mrr to its marginal cost of capital i, and its

marginal q would equal the area under mrr from 0 to

I1, that is ‘a + b,’ divided by the area under the

marginal cost of capital curve, namely ‘b’, which is

clearly greater than one.

Page 81: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

235

Figure 4. Interpretation of marginal q results

Therefore, since the data indicates that marginal

qs are substantially greater than one for low values of

the A-index and the E-index, we conclude that there is

significant evidence in favor of the hypothesis that the

managements of financially dependent firms as

measured by the A-index who are not entrenched

using anti-takeover provisions as measured by the E-

index (i.e. young firms) will tend to invest in a

manner which is consistent with shareholder wealth

maximization as measured by marginal q.

In addition, the results in Table 5 show that the

values of marginal q for the average firm are close to

1 when firm financial autonomy as measured by the

A-index is high and managerial entrenchment as

measured by the E-index is low. For instance, the

table shows a value of marginal q of 1.0162 when the

A-index is equal to 7 and the E-index is equal to 1. In

general, the table shows values for marginal q which

are close to 1 in the upper-right hand region of

Table 5.

Now, an estimated qmt which is close to 1 can be

interpreted as an indication of “moderate”

overinvestment taking place. To see this suppose that

a firm invests I2 as shown in Figure 4, and moreover

assume that the areas labelled ‘a’ and ‘d’ in the figure

are approximately equal. In this case, marginal q

would equal the area under mrr, that is ‘a + b + c’,

divided by the area under the cost of capital curve, i.e.

‘b + c + d’. Given that ‘a’ and ‘e’ have approximately

equal areas, marginal q approximately equals 1 and,

as the figure shows, there is overinvestment taking

place as the marginal investment project has a rate of

return that is below its cost of capital.

Therefore, the estimates of marginal q presented

in Table 5 are consistent with the hypothesis that the

managements of financially autonomous firms as

measured by the A-index who are not entrenched

using anti-takeover provisions as measured by the E-

index will tend to over-invest moderately as measured

by marginal q. Note that overinvestment is

“moderate” for the case of these mature firms because

of the threat of takeover.

Furthermore, the results shown in Table 5

indicate that there is strong evidence of

overinvestment as measured by marginal q when both

the A-index and the E-index have high values. From

the previous discussion it is clear that no firm that

maximizes shareholder wealth would undertake

investment for which qmt < 1, for this unequivocally

implies overinvestment. Now, when the A-index = 7

and the E-index = 6 the marginal q implied by the

estimates of Table 4 column 5 equals 0.7012. This

suggests that on average for every dollar that firms

with these high levels of financial autonomy and

entrenchment invested during the period 1990-2008,

the market value of these firms increased by only

about $0.70. Consequently, the estimates of marginal

q presented in Table 5 are consistent with the

hypothesis that the managements of mature

financially autonomous firms as measured by the A-

index who are also entrenched using anti-takeover

provisions as measured by the E-index will tend to

over-invest substantially as measured by marginal q.

Finally, the results in Table 5 show that the

values of marginal q for the average firm are

substantially greater than 1 when firm financial

autonomy as measured by the A-index is low and

managerial entrenchment as measured by the E-index

is high. For instance, the table shows a value of

marginal q of 1.2472 when the A-index is equal to 0

I2

mrr

Cost of

capital ‘i’

mrr, i

0 I1 I

a

b c

d

Page 82: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

236

and the E-index is equal to 5. This suggests that on

average for every dollar that firms with these levels of

low financial autonomy and high entrenchment

invested during the period 1990-2008, the market

value of these firms increased by about $1.25. In

general, the table shows values for marginal q which

are greater than 1 in the lower-left hand side region of

Table 5. Hence, the estimates of marginal q presented

in Table 5 are consistent with the hypothesis that the

managements of financially dependent firms as

measured by the A-index who are also entrenched

using anti-takeover provisions as measured by the E-

index will tend to invest in a manner consistent with

shareholder wealth maximization as measured by

marginal q. In other words, if there are no free cash

flows there can be no overinvestment even though the

management of the firm is entrenched. However, this

does not rule out that there may be other agency

problems involved that cause the managements of

these firms to keep antitakeover provisions in place6.

6. Conclusions

The agency costs of free cash flows are a problem

which is characteristic of mature firms. As firms

mature their cash flows eventually become larger than

the amounts needed to fund all positive net present

value projects. If it is taken into consideration that

some mature firms need to retrench, it is not

surprising that their managements will employ some

of the free cash flows to mitigate the negative growth.

Faced with the option between over-investing and

firing workers, they will likely choose the more

popular route. The lifecycle theory of the firm and the

derivation of the A-index give a clearer perspective on

this fact.

The A-index contrasts with current

measurements of free cash flows in that it makes it

clear that the agency costs of free cash flows are a

recurrent problem for mature firms and a feature of

the lifecycle of the firm. The A-index compares the

size of the cash flows with the actual investments

undertaken using equity and retained earnings rather

than solely measuring the size of the retained cash

flows or the level of cash held by a corporation at

some point in time. In this sense, the contribution of

this paper has been to develop a new empirical index

that allows us to separate young from mature firms

more effectively than using chronological firm age.

Finally, firm lifecycle theory and the results in

this paper leads us to conclude that, assuming that the

objective of a policy maker is to improve corporate

governance in the sense that managers remain

responsive to the wishes of the shareholders, there is

only one effective policy to be implemented: to

6 I discuss and examine this issue empirically elsewhere. I

conclude that these companies are mature firms that have lost their financial autonomy but that would not remove their antitakeover provisions due to their prior investments in unrelated businesses which makes them potential hostile takeover targets (Saravia, 2010).

outlaw the deployment of anti-takeover provisions. If

this policy were implemented over-investment on the

part of mature corporations would be mitigated to a

moderate level. The reason is that if shareholder

dissatisfaction with management were to become too

great the stock price would plunge, and this would

increase the likelihood of a takeover. Thus,

management would be under increasing pressure to

pay out the funds to shareholders in the form of

dividends or stock repurchases rather than over-

investing.

References

1. Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., and Ferrel, A. (2009), “What

Matters in Corporate Governance?” The Review of

Financial Studies, Vol. 22, pp. 783-827.

2. Chi, J.D., and Lee, D.S. (2010), “The Conditional

Nature of the Value of Corporate Governance”, Journal

of Banking & Finance, Vol. 34, pp. 350-361.

3. Daines, R. (2001), “Does Delaware Law Improve Firm

Value?” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 62, pp.

525-558.

4. Dittmar, A., and Mahrt-Smith, J. (2007), “Corporate

Governance and the Value of Cash Holdings”, Journal

of Financial Economics, Vol. 83, pp. 599-634.

5. Gompers, P., Ishii, J. and Metrick, A. (2003),

“Corporate Governance and Equity Prices”, Quarterly

Journal of Economics, Vol. 118, pp. 107-155.

6. Graham, B. (2006), The Intellingent Investor, Collins

Business Essentials, New York, NY.

7. Harford, J., Mansi, S., and Maxwell. W.F. (2008),

“Corporate Governance and Firm Cash Holdings”,

Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 87, pp. 535-555.

8. Jensen, M. (1986), “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow,

Corporate Finance, and Takeovers”, American

Economic Review, Vol. 76, pp. 323-329.

9. Jovanovic, B., and Rousseau, P.L. (2002), “The Q-

Theory of Mergers”, American Economic Review, Vol.

92, pp. 198-204.

10. Lehn, K., and Poulsen, A. (1989), “Free Cash Flow and

Stockholder Gains in Going Private Transactions”

Journal of Finance, Vol. 44, pp. 771-787.

11. Mergent, Inc. (2004), Mergent Industrial Manual. Vol.

1 & 2. Mergent, New York, NY.

12. Mueller, D.C. (2003), The Corporation: Investments,

Mergers and Growth. Routledge, New York, NY.

13. Mueller, D.C., and Reardon, E.A. (1993), “Rates of

Return on Corporate Investment”, Southern Economic

Journal, Vol. 60, pp. 430-453.

14. Mueller, D.C., and Yun, S.L. (1998), “Rates of Return

over the Firm's Lifecycle”, Industrial and Corporate

Change, Vol. 7, pp. 347-368.

15. Mueller, D.C., and Yurtoglu, B. (2000), “Country Legal

Environments and Corporate Investment Performance”,

German Economic Review, Vol. 1, pp. 187-220.

16. Petersen, M. A. (2009), “Estimating Standard Errors in

Finance Panel Data Sets: Comparing Approaches”, The

Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22, pp. 435-480.

17. Saravia, J. A. (2010), An Investigation of the

Relationship between Corporate Governance and Firm

Performance, Unpublished PhD Thesis, University of

Surrey, Guildford, Surrey, U.K.

Page 83: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

237

APPENDIX

Table A.1 lists the sources of data used in this paper. The

first column of the table displays the data items used, while

the second column presents the data sources. Panel A

presents the data needed to compute the market value of a

firm at the end of year t (Mt), which in turn is required to

implement the Mueller and Reardon (1993) marginal q

method. Specifically, the table shows that Mt is computed

by adding the market value of common stock (wc05301 x P)

plus the book value of total debt (wc03255) and preferred

stock (wc03451). Where the market value common stock

is calculated by multiplying the end of fiscal year number of

shares (wc05301) times the end of fiscal year price per

share (P).

This table lists the main sources of data used in this

paper. Panel A shows the data items needed to compute the

market value of a firm at the end of year t. Panel B lists the

data items needed to calculate the investment of a firm over

year t. Panel C lists the sources of data for important items

such as Bebchuk et al.’s (2009) E-index, as well as date of

incorporation which is used to compute firm age.

Table A1. The main sources of data used in this paper

Panel A. Firm market value (Mt)

Data item Datastream datatype

Market value of common stock (wc05301 x P)

End of fiscal year number of shares wc05301

End of fiscal year price per share P

Book value of total debt wc03255

Preferred stock wc03451

Panel B. Investment (It)

Data item Datastream datatype/ other

Cash flow wc04201

Dividends wc04551

Net new debt = change in total debt during year change in wc03255

Net new equity = change in number of common shares

outstanding x average share price over year t

change in wc05301 x average P

R&D expenditures wc01201

Advertising expenses

Approximated by multiplying company sales by

advertising to sales ratios from the IRS reports on corporation

returns for 1995.

IRS reports on corporation returns. Table 6:

Balance sheets, income statements, tax and selected

other items. See Mueller and Yurtoglu (2000).

Total sales wc01001

Panel C. Other

Data item Datastream datatype/ other

Total assets wc02999

Date of fiscal period end wc05350

Consumer price index (CPI) World bank - world development indicators

Entrenchment index (E-index)

Available from Bebchuk’s webpage at http://

www. law.harvard.edu /faculty/ bebchuk/data.shtml Date of Incorporation (to compute firm age) Mergent Industrial Manual (Mergent, 2004)

Industry SIC codes ‘Eqy Sic Code’

(Bloomberg table wizzard)

State of incorporation ‘State Of Incorporation’

(Bloomberg table wizzard)

On the other hand, Panel B lists the data needed to

calculate the investment of a firm over year t (It) which is

also necessary to implement the M&R marginal q method.

In particular, It is calculated by first subtracting dividends

(wc04551) from cash flows (wc04201) and then adding net

new equity (the change in the number of shares wc05301

times average share price P over year t), net new debt (the

change in total debt wc03255 over year t), R&D

expenditures (wc01201), and advertising expenses

(estimated by multiplying total sales (wc01001) and

advertising to sales ratios taken from IRS reports on

corporation returns, see Mueller and Yurtoglu, 2000).

Moreover, Panel C lists the sources of data for Bebchuk et

al.’s (2009) E-index, the companies’ dates of incorporation

which is used to compute firm age, as well as the book

value of total assets.

The financial data utilized to compute the autonomy

index are also taken from Table A.1. As discussed

Page 84: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

238

previously, the A-index is calculated by adding one point

for each year in which a company has greater cash flows

than investments financed using equity and retained cash

flows during the previous 7 years. Investments in financed

using equity and retained cash flows (Ie) are measured as

follows:

EDividendsCFI e (A.1)

Where CF is the cash flow of the firm (wc04201),

Dividends are taken from Datastream (wc04551) and ΔE

stands for net new equity. Therefore, when calculating the

A-index for a given firm in year t, 1 point is added for every

year (from t-7 to t-1) in which CF > Ie. Finally note that

prior to the calculation of the M&R variables all items were

deflated by using the CPI (2000 = 1). The CPI data for the

U.S. were obtained from the World Bank, World

Development Indicators, ESDS International, and

University of Manchester.

Page 85: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

239

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION, ORGANIZATIONAL CULTURE AND THE GLASS CEILING

M. Dewally*, S. Flaherty**, D. Singer***

Abstract

This study examines the impact of organizational culture on executive compensation systems. Organizational culture is found to have a strong impact on the relationship between CEO equity compensation and organizational effectiveness. Compensation patterns found in traditional organizations are interpreted to reflect a Managerial Power Theory of executive compensation. In contrast, in positive organizations, the exercise of managerial power appears to be constrained by the internal values of that organization and the need for the leader to maintain his or her authenticity. Female executives who have penetrated the glass ceiling in both traditional and positive organizations are found to contribute to a culture in which executive compensation reflects an Optimal Contract approach to principle-agent relationships for CEOs and shareholders. Keywords: Organizational Culture, Executive Compensation, Managerial Power Theory Asst. Prof. of Finance, Towson University

Email: [email protected] ** Asst. Prof. of Finance, Towson University Email: [email protected] *** Prof., of Finance, Towson University Email: [email protected]

1. Introduction

This study examines the impact of organizational

culture on the effectiveness of executive

compensation systems. While Landsberg (2012)

suggested the importance of business culture in

determining executive compensation and a large body

of literature has focused on organizational culture and

organizational performance (Xiaomin and Junchen,

2012; Kotter, J. P. and J. L. Heslett, 2011), little

research has looked explicitly at the relationship

between culture and executive compensation in

organizations.

The purpose of executive compensation systems

is to increase organizational effectiveness.

Effectiveness may be interpreted as synonymous with

the goal of publicly held corporations to maximize

shareholder wealth subject to certain social

constraints (Freeman and Parmar, 2007). Executive

compensation systems are thus directed towards

aligning executive compensation systems with

shareholder wealth (Balachandran, Joos, and Weber,

2012; Lee and Widener, (2013). This frequently takes

the form of equity bonuses whose value depends on

the price of the firm’s stock (Chng, et. al., 2012).

2. Executive Compensation Theory

Research has found that higher equity compensation

levels for executives do not necessarily enhance

shareholder wealth. Martin, Gomez-Mejia, and

Wiseman, (2013) have shown that equity based pay

affects the risk behavior of executives. The risk

sensitivity of equity compensated executives may

manifest itself either in undue risk aversion or in

excessive and imprudent risk-taking, neither of which

outcomes necessarily maximize shareholder wealth.

The relationship between executive equity

compensation and firm strategy is seen as highly

nuanced and complex and dependent on a large of

array of institutional and contextual factors (Devers,

McNarama, Wiseman, and Arrfelt, 2008; Weisbach,

2007). While the current state of behavioral research

on executive equity compensation is inconclusive, this

study has focused on the outcome of executive

compensation on organizational effectiveness rather

than the behavioral factors which lead to that

outcome.

The popular and academic literatures on

executive compensation suggest that this

compensation is often both out of line with

organizational performance and outrageously high

(Lawler, 2012; Lin, et. al., 2013). A research study

by Bebchuk and Fried (2004) suggested that executive

compensation systems often fail to accomplish the

goal of aligning the corporate and personal interests

of executives. The thesis they hypothesized has come

to be known as The Managerial Power Theory of

executive compensation, which argues that current

corporate governance practices distort executive

Page 86: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

240

compensation goals because the executives

themselves exert direct and indirect influence over

their compensation practices (Schneider, 2013). A

large body of evidence suggests that executives do in

fact exert various types of influences on their

compensation packages (Balachandran, Joos, and

Weber, 2012; Chng, et.al. 2012; Bebchuk, Fried and

Walker, 2002).

Management Power Theory may be contrasted

with Optimal Contracting Theory which assumes an

arms-length relationship between top executives and

the Board of Directors (Dorff, 2005). Compensation

thus reflects an exogenous market judgment rather

than the endogenous use of personal influence.

Optimal Contracting Theory may be viewed from the

perspective of “Principle-Agent Theory” in which the

principles (shareholders) attempt to get the agents (top

executives) to act according to the principles best

interests (Allen and Winton, 1995). The basic

problem with Optimal Contracting Theory is that the

ability to align executive and shareholder interests

requires solving significant information and

coordination problems which are in fact, so complex

that current corporate governance protocols assume

away such coordination problems (Hermalin and

Weisbach, 2012). Thus, any contract resulting from

negotiations between the CEO and the board is, de

facto, an optimal contract (Cao and Wang, 2013;

Weisbach, 2007).

3. Organizational Effectiveness

This study uses Tobin’s q as a measure of

organizational effectiveness. While organizational

performance has many different facets, an exogenous

market-based value for measuring overall

organizational effectiveness is provided by Tobin’s q,

the ratio of enterprise value (shareholder wealth and

the market value of debt) divided by book value.

Bolton, Chen, and Wang, N. (2011) have shown that

the relationship between Tobin’s q at the margin

determines investment preferences subject to the

constraints of capital structure. From an investor’s

perspective a preference is shown for using Tobin’s q

consistently used as a good measure of firm

performance (Semmler and Mateane, 2012).

McFarland contrasted Tobin’s q with other measures

of corporate performance in a simulation and found

that Tobin’s q was better correlated with true

performance than the accounting rate of return

(Stevens, 1990; McFarland, 1988).

4. Organizational Culture While this study posits two polar organization

cultures, traditional and positive, it is recognized that

real world organizations frequently have

heterogeneous cultures, embracing elements of both

sets of shared values. Nevertheless, organizations

may be said to have distinct personalities reflecting a

greater or lesser degree of traditional and positive

cultures (Reigle, 2013; Bradley-Geist, and Landis,

2012; De Vries, Kets, and Miller, 1986). Differing

management styles between traditional and positive

organizations and have been found to reflect differing

assumptions about the behaviors and values of

organization members (Seligman, 2004; Hoffman, et.

al., 2011).

An organization may be said to have a

distinctive personality reflecting the shared values,

norms and ethics of its members. Cameron and

Quinn (2011) identify organization personalities

within a Competing Values Model that differentiates

among organization on the values attached to

collaboration, competition, controlling and creativity.

Within this context flexibility and control are seen as

two differentiated sets of values. Flexibility values

encourage individuals to be open to change, and

spontaneously adapt and respond to that change to

accomplish organizational objectives. Control values

presume a stable and predictable environment where a

formal adherence to rules and conformance to

precedent are the keys to organizational success.

French and Holden (2012) found the type of

organizational culture impacts both how organizations

communicate and how they respond to crisis.

Particularly relevant to executive compensation

patterns was the finding of a strong relationship

between risk preferences and organization culture

(Cooper, Faseruk, Khan, 2013). Kimbrough and

Componation, (2009) also found that traditional

(mechanistic) and positive (organic) cultures

influence enterprise risk management practices.

4.1 Traditional Organizations Culture in traditional organizations is task oriented

with decisions made using a technically rational

framework characterized by tight worker controls

accomplished through a rigid hierarchy, direct

supervision and a set of policies and rules designed to

limit worker discretion. The culture in traditional

organizations focuses directly on the tasks to be

completed to achieve productivity—indeed, Frederick

Taylor often advocated replacing the “Principles of

Scientific Management” with the “Principles of Task

Management” (Wrege and Hodgetts, 2000).

The concept of management control is

surprisingly amorphous, but as the concept has

evolved it may be described as systematically

approaching organizational objectives by constraining

the actions of individual organization members

(Bredma, 2011). The spirit of what control is all

about my be found in Frederick Taylor’s emphasis on

a systematic and detailed solutions to problems of

cost reduction (Taylor, 1911; Wrege and Hodgetts,

2000)

Walton (2005) found bureaucratic rule-making

relevant to the goals of modern corporations. In

bureaucratic organizations rules are more frequently

Page 87: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

241

violated when the context of the organization changes

and performance suffers (Lehman and Ramanujam,

2009). West and Raso (2013) found rule-making

activities intensified among government agencies

when outcomes were defined in economic terms. It is

axiomatic among organization theorists that a great

danger in traditional organizations is that of excessive

control or a mismatch of control mechanisms to the

organization’s environment can damage

organizational effectiveness (Liu, Liao, and Loi,

2012); Harris, Harvey, Harris, and Cast, 2013).

In traditional organizations behavioral controls

emphasize negative sanctions against undesirable

behaviors. Traditional organizations assume people

are inherently irresponsible, prefer to be directed, and

dislike responsibility (Kopelman, Prottas, and Falk,

2012). This perception of workers creates an

approach to management focusing on punishment and

limiting worker discretion. (Jacobs, 2004; Lehman

and Ramanujam, 2011). These assumptions may be

expressed in an autocratic management style which

seeks to control worker behavior through the use of

tangible rewards such as pay and bonuses as well as

through the avoidance of threats and discipline

(Bolino and Turnley, 2003). Autocratic leaders in

traditional organizations are feared (Liu, Liao, and

Loi, 2012; Harris, et. al., 2013).

4.2 Positive Organizations

The culture in positive organizations focuses on the

emotional state of the workers to accomplish the tasks

necessary to accomplish productivity. In positive

organizations the goal is to have engaged workers

flourish in an atmosphere of proactivity, creativity,

curiosity, compassion, hope, and self reliance

(Cameron and Spreitzer, 2012; Avey, Luthans, and

Jensen, 2009; Bono, Davies, and Rasch, 2012;

Seligman, 2011).

Positive organizations focus on developing

members who thrive in an environment that calls for

personal freedom vitality, self-reliance and creativity.

Glynn and Watkiss (2012) have noted the importance

of cultural symbols in affirming the behaviors of

individuals in a positive organization. Such symbols

may be said to have generative potency for

individuals that results in enriched collective

strengths, virtuous behavior and increased capability.

Schein (1988) has found compensation to be an

important tacit cultural symbol for determining

behavior. This implies that compensation systems in

positive organizations have a moral dimension which

is not necessarily present in traditional organizations.

Thus culture may be expected to influence

compensation systems in positive organizations.

A requirement for the creation of positive

organizations is “authentic leadership” (Luthans and

Avolio, 2003; Dhiman, 2011). Authentic leadership

has many facets but the essence of this type of

leadership appears to be a leader who is “true” to

himself or herself (Avolio and Mhatre, 2012). Such a

leader has genuine concern for the well-being of all

organization members and is never Machiavellian or

false. Authentic leaders are trusted (Mishra and

Mishra, 2012). If it may be assumed that individuals

are in fact, self-actualizing, then it may be inferred

that positive organizations will be perceived by such

individuals as good places to work.

4.3 The Impact of Organizational Culture

Recent research has found that the state of the

organization, as opposed to the traits of individuals in

the organization, can play a significant role in

promoting desirable outcomes (Kluemper, DeGroot,

and Choi, 2013). Barney (1986) suggests that

organization culture can be a source of sustained

competitive advantage. While it cannot be

unequivocally stated that positive organizations will

perform better than traditional organizations, the bulk

of behavioral research suggests this is so (Wright and

Quick, 2009). The most recent research finds that a

positive orientation in an organization increases

productivity and organizational success (Cheung,

Wong, and Lam, 2012). Mussel (2013) found that

curiosity, a trait outcome in positive organizations,

was positively related to job performance. Further

research suggests that when new organization entrants

perceive their relationship with the organization as

supportive, caring, and entailing positive social

exchanges they become increasingly committed to the

organization (Allen and Shanock, 2013). Rich,

Lepine, and Crawford, 2010) found the job

engagement of organization members to be an

important factor in job performance.

5. Methodology

Positive organizations in this study were identified

from a data base created to find the “100 Best

Companies to Work For” (Moskowitz, Levering,

Akhtar, Leahey, and Vandermey, 2013), which was

constructed by Fortune Magazine in partnership with

the Great Place to Work Institute (GPWI).

Inclusion in this database was based on a score

that derived from a company’s “Trust Index” and

“Cultural Audit” created by GPWI. Employees in

259 firms were randomly surveyed to create a “Trust

Index.” The survey asked questions related to their

attitudes about management's credibility, job

satisfaction, and camaraderie in the organization.

Two-thirds of a company's total score were based on

the results of the institute's “Trust Index” survey. The

other third was based on responses to the institute's

“Culture Audit”, which includes detailed questions

about pay and benefit programs and a series of open-

ended questions about hiring practices, methods of

internal communication, training, recognition

programs, and diversity efforts. For the purposes of

this study, the top 100 scoring firms by the Great

Page 88: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

242

Place to Work Institute were classified as positive

organizations. This universe was then paired down to

37 firms by excluding companies domiciled overseas

and companies that are not publicly traded

corporations.

A comparable group of organizations were then

surveyed to determine if they could be classified as

traditional organizations. This determination was

made through an examination of their current Annual

Report for statements that reflected a commitment to

a command and control hierarchical management

style. Thirty seven such comparable organizations

were then identified as traditional. (See Table 1

below.)

This study then further disaggregated traditional

and positive organizations by those organizations

identifying named female executives. Organizations

with female other named executives were selected for

further study because an organization having women

who have penetrated the glass ceiling may be

characterized by a differentiated set of cultural values.

SEC rules on compensation disclosure require

organizations to name specific executives as

organizational leaders in their 10-k reports.

6. Characteristics of Organizations Studied

As can be seen from Table 1, little difference in the

average performance characteristics of traditional and

positive organizations surveyed in this study can be

found. However the variance within both

distributions is large. For example, the range for

Tobin’s q in traditional organizations was -3.52 to

2.71 while the range for positive organizations was -

.45 to 1.51. It may be that systematic differences in

organizational effectiveness between the two types of

organizations exist apart from central tendencies.

Table 1. Study Organizational Characteristics

Similarly Table 2 shows little difference in the

average compensation levels between the two types of

organizations. As above, however, the variance

within the average is large. The standard deviation for

total compensation for CEOs in traditional

organizations was $14.939 million and $7.49 million

in traditional organizations. The larger variance for

CEO compensation in traditional organizations

compared to positive organizations may be interpreted

to suggest that compensation practices differ between

the two types of organization.

Table 2. CEO Compensation Patterns

Traditional and Possitive Organizations

Page 89: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

243

7. Analysis

In examining the relationship between executive

compensation and organizational effectiveness, we

hypothesize a negative relationship between CEO

compensation and organizational effectiveness,

consistent with most research on this topic (Bebchuk

and Fried, 2004:Weisbach, 2007; Dorff, 2005). We

will further hypothesize that this relationship does not

hold for positive organizations because the power of

the CEO in positive organizations is mitigated by an

internal value system that would consider excessive

compensation a violation of that culture (an internal

“outrage” effect).

The model utilized also contains a dummy

variable to control for the presence of founding CEOs

(1 if present, 0 if not). The reason for this is that

founding CEOs often own so much equity in the

company, that further compensation is

inconsequential. As a result, they take a nominal

salary or bonus.

Executive compensation can have a number of

different dimensions (Ozkan, Singer, and You, 2012).

While the literature distinguishes between fixed

compensation in the form of salary and equity

compensation resulting from the grant of stock or

stock options, this study has found the two measures

of compensation highly correlated in both traditional

and positive firms. As most of the controversy about

executive compensation centers over the equity

element of compensation, this study will focus on that

variable (Balachandran, Joos, and Weber, 2012; Cao

and Wang, 2013; Jensen, 1986).

Assuming the validity of the Management Power

Theory for traditional organizations, we hypothesize

that CEO equity compensation is negatively related to

organizational effectiveness. That is, CEOs in

traditional organizations are able to enhance their

compensation in spite of the lack of their positive

impact on organizational effectiveness. As founding

CEOs already have large equity holdings it may be

assumed that they are particularly committed to a goal

of organizational effectiveness. Consistent with the

literature we will also hypothesize that the size of the

firm (as measured by sales) will be positively related

to organizational effectiveness as a result of increased

market power and cost efficiencies consistent with

increased economies of scale ((Jensen, 1986;

Weisbach, 2007; Lin, Hsien-Chang, and Lie-Huey,

2013). The Return on Equity (ROE) will be used as a

variable to control for short-term performance issues.

Thus for traditional organizations:

H(1) Tobin q = a - b1(Founder CEO) –

-b1(CEO Equity Compensation) + b2(Size) +

+ b3(ROE)

H(1) is tested for traditional organizations in

Table 3 below. For traditional firms, the presence of

a founding CEO and the equity compensation of

CEOs exhibit a strong and significant negative

relationship to organizational effectiveness. Size was

also found to be significantly related to organizational

effectiveness, consistent with established research on

this topic. ROE was not found to be significantly

related to organizational effectiveness, suggesting that

this inherently short-term measure of performance is

not associated with the long-run performance of the

organization as judged by the market. Alternatively

an explanation of the absence of a significant

relationship between ROE and organizational

effectiveness may reflect a market judgment that the

earnings on which the ROE calculation have been

‘managed” and are not creditable (Louis and Sun,

2011).

These findings suggest that executive equity

compensation in traditional organizations is

frequently determined by the exercise of managerial

power rather than an arms-length principle-agent

transaction for all traditional firms.

Table 3. Determinants of Organizational Effectiveness in Traditional and Positive Cultures

Founder/ CEO Equity

Intercept CEO ROE Size Compensation R2 F Test

All Traditional .990 -.587* -.005 .359** -.310**

Firms (-4.336) (-.038) (2.603 (-2.144) .434 6.144

All Positive .617 .159 .403** -.047 .002

Firms (.959) (2.376) (-.268) (.011) .178 1.730 Linear regression with Tobin’s Q as the dependent variable. T values in parentheses.

* significant an p = .01, ** significant at p = .05, *** significant at p = .10, one-tailed test.

In contrast, it is hypothesized that the negative

relationship between CEO equity compensation and

organizational effectiveness will not hold for Positive

Organizations because concern with the emotional

state of organization members acts as a constraint on

CEO excesses and CEO compensation is an important

symbol of the authenticity of that CEO. It is further

hypothesized that ROE will be positively associated

with organizational effectiveness because the

relationship between short-run performance and long-

Page 90: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

244

run performance has more credibility in an

organization whose members are fully engaged and

personally committed to organizational goals. Size is

also expected to be a significant determinant of

organizational effectiveness as above.

Thus, for Positive Organizations

H(2) Tobin q = a + b1(Founder CEO) + b1(CEO

Equity Compensation) + b2(Size) + b3(ROE)

Table 3 shows that neither the presence of a

founding CEO or CEO Equity compensation in

positive organizations is significantly related to

organizational effectiveness. While this is not the

same thing as the expected significant positive

relationship between CEO equity compensation and

organizational effectiveness, the absence of the

significant negative relationship found in traditional

firms does suggest that positive organization culture

does exert a mitigating influence on executive power.

Table 3 also shows ROE to be significantly and

positively related to organizational effectiveness in

Positive Organizations. This is interpreted to reflect a

market belief in the validity of reported earnings in

organizations where individual members are not

passive automatons doing as directed, but actively

engaged individuals committed to organizational

goals. The absence of a significant relationship

between size and organizational effectiveness,

suggests that the gestalt found in a positive

organization is more important to organizational

effectiveness than the power conveyed by market

share or cost efficiencies contingent on size.

It may be concluded from the results of Table 3 that

the Managerial Power Theory of executive

compensation in traditional organizations provides a

more likely explanation of executive compensation

patterns than Optimal Contract Theory. It may also

be inferred from Table 3 that organizational culture in

positive organizations can act as a constraint on the

power of the CEOs to determine their compensation.

8. The Impact of Named Female Executives A further line of inquiry in this study is the impact of

named female executives in an organization on the

effectiveness of that organization. It is not

hypothesized that the mere presence of female

executives increase organizational effectiveness, but

that the presence of those named female executives

says something about the nature the organization’s

culture and how that culture affects organizational

effectiveness. If the presence of female named

executives reflects cultural characteristics of an

organization that enhance organizational effectiveness

it may also be expected that their presence impacts the

relationship between executive compensation and

organizational effectiveness because an organization’s

culture itself affects executive compensation patterns.

Therefore we hypothesize for traditional organizations

without named female executives:

H(3) Tobin q = a - b1(Founder CEO) – b2(CEO

Equity Compensation) + b3(Size) +

b4(ROE)

And for traditional organizations with named female

executives

H(4) Tobin q = a + b1(Founder CEO) + b2(CEO

Equity Compensation) + b3(Size) +

b4(ROE) + b5(Female Executive

Compensation)

These hypotheses are tested in Table 4 following.

Table 4. Determinants of Organizational Effectiveness

In Traditional Firms with and without Named Female Executives

Named female

Founder/ CEO Equity Equity

Intercept CEO ROE Size Compensation Compensation R2 F Test

Trad. Firms 1.292 -.767* -.421** .644** -.542** .610 8.598

W/O Named (-5.313) (-2.267) (3.612) (-3.348)

Female Exec.

Trad. Firms .820 1.267 .205 -.662 .789 .396 .820

With Named (1.633) (.118) (-.790) (.466)

Female Exec. Linear regression with Tobin’s Q as the dependent variable. T values in parentheses.

* significant an p = .01, ** significant at p = .05, *** significant at p = .10, one-tailed test

It can be seen from the results presented in Table

4, that even in traditional organizations the presence

of named women executives changes the relationship

between executive compensation patterns and

organizational effectiveness. In traditional

organizations without named female executives the

negative relationship between the presence of a

founder CEO and CEO equity compensation that was

Page 91: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

245

found in Table 3 continues, but the association or

ROE with organizational effectiveness is found to be

both strong and negative. This negative relationship

may reflect a market suspicion that earnings have

been managed. Size continues its positive association

with organizational effectiveness and ROE continues

to be negatively related to organizational

effectiveness. As above, this may be interpreted as a

strong confirmation of the Managerial Power Theory

because CEO compensation is able to rise above the

consideration of short term performance indications.

In testing H(5) when named female executives

are present in traditional organizations, the negative

relationship between CEO compensation and

organizational effectiveness disappears, as does the

relationship between organizational effectiveness with

size and ROE. Certainly, there is something about a

culture which sanctions the presence of named female

executives which constrain the exercise of CEO

power to influence their own compensation. One

interpretation of this state of affairs is that such a

culture is more rational than a culture without named

female executives. This would be because the market

is gender neutral with respect to executive ability and

the presence of females above the glass ceiling

testifies to that rationality. The absence of a

significant relationship between ROE and Size and

organizational effectiveness may provide further

evidence of that rationality. This may mean that

executive compensation is more reflective of Optimal

Contracting Theory in organizations with named

female executives present.

In testing H(5), for positive organizations

without named female executives the impact of

named female executives on the relationship between

organizational effectiveness and executive

compensation would be expected to be even greater

than found in the testing of H(4). Therefore we

hypothesize for Positive Organizations without named

female executives

H(5) Tobin q = a + b1(Founder CEO) + b2(CEO

Equity Compensation) + b3(Size) + b4(ROE)

This hypothesis is tested in Table 5. Table 5

confirms the results of Table 3 for positive

organizations without the presence of female named

executives. No systematic impact may be found

between organizational effectiveness and the presence

of a CEO founder, ROE, Size, or CEO Equity

Compensation. All of which may be interpreted if not

as support for the presence of an Optimal Contract

paradigm in the organization, the absence of a system

where executive compensation is self-determined.

Based on the above findings it would appear that

the strongest case for an Optimal Contracting Theory

of executive compensation would be made in positive

organizations with named female executives.

This hypothesis is tested in:

H(6) Tobin q = a + b1(Founder CEO) + b2(CEO

Equity Compensation) + b3(Size) + b4(ROE)

+ b5(Female Executive Compensation)

Table 5. Determinants of Organizational Effectiveness

In Positive Firms with and without Named Female Executives

Named Fmale

Founder/ CEO Equity Equity

Intercept CEO ROE Size Compensation Compensation R2 F Test

Positive .810 .119 .290 -.106 -.146 .150 .925

Firms (.563) (1.355) (-.508) ( -.705)

W/O Named

Female Exec.

Positive Firms -.185 .857* .912* -1.114** .526*** 1.096** .880 7.339

With Named (4.238) (4.468) (-2.964) (2.339) (3.052)

Female Exec.

Linear regression with Tobin’s Q as the dependent variable. T values in parentheses.

* significant an p = .01, ** significant at p = .05, *** significant at p = .10, one-tailed test

As can be seen in Table 5 above, the testing of

H(6) provides strong evidence for an Optimal

Contract Theory of executive compensation. Both the

presence of a founding CEO and CEO Equity

Compensation are significantly and positively related

to organizational effectiveness. The essence of

Optimal Contract Theory is that CEO compensation is

tied to organizational performance. In H(6) that

relationship is clearly seen. The fact that ROE is also

positively related to organizational effectiveness can

be taken as further evidence of the rationality which

pervades the positive organization. The negative

relationship between size and organizational

performance can be interpreted to mean that the

power of engaged, flourishing individuals who are

committed to the success of the organization are more

important to performance than any legacy attributes of

the organization.

Page 92: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

246

Conclusion

Executive compensation in an era of economic turmoil remains a socially contentious issue. The argument can

be made that executive pay merely reflects the market valuation of a scarce resource. What appears to be

excessive compensation for such executives is said to reflect the value of a very scarce resource. That executive

compensation represents an optimal contract between a CEO and the shareholders.

Alternatively, it can be argued corporate executives have effectively contravened the underlying

framework of corporate governance and unjustly enrich themselves through the exercise of their power at the

expense of shareholders and society. Under vthese circumstances, executive compensation can be explained by

the exercise of raw Managerial Power.

This study finds that organization culture can have a strong impact on executive compensation and the

conventions surrounding it. Executive compensation in traditional organizations is generally found to reflect the

exercise of managerial power. The culture of a positive organization is found to constrain the exercise of that

power and to create a more rational and market driven setting for compensation negotiations between a CEO and

the Board of

Directors which increases the possibility of creating an optimal contract between the CEO and the shareholders.

A further finding of this study is that the presence of named female executives reflects cultural attributes in both

types of organization that create a setting for an optimal contract between executives and shareholders.

Insofar as executive compensation is seen as a social problem that needs to be addressed, these finding

suggest that a top-down approach to executive compensation is unlikely to work as long as the values in the

organization are conducive to the exercise of unjust management power. In contrast, a bottom up approach,

beginning with the creation of a positive organization in which engaged and committed workers characterized by

tacit assumptions of fairness and ethical propriety will naturally limit the abusive exercise of management

power.

References 1. Allen, F., and A. Winton. (1995) Corporate financial

structure, incentives and optimal contracting, In

Handbooks in operations research and management

science, (9) R. Jarrow, V. Maksimo-vic, and W. T.

Ziemba, EDS.,. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 693–720 2. Allen, David G.; Shanock, Linda Rhoades (2013)

Perceived Organizational Support and Embeddedness as

Key Mechanisms Connecting Socialization Tactics to

Commitment and Turnover among New Employees,

Journal of Organizational Behavior, 34(3), 350-369. 3. Avey, James B.; Luthans, Fred; Jensen, Susan M.

(2009) Psychological capital: A Positive Resource for

Combating Employee Stress and Turnover, Human

Resource Management, 48(5), 677-693. 4. Avolio, B. J. and Mhatre, K.H. (2012) Authentic

Leadership, in The Oxford Handbook of Positive

Organizational Scholarship, K. S. in The Oxford

Handbook of Positive Organizational Scholarship, K.

Cameron and G. M. Spreitzer (eds), New York: Oxford

University Press, 773-83.

5. Balachandran, S.V., Joos, P. and Weber, J. (2012) Do

Voting Rights Matter? Evidence From the Adoption of

Equity-Based Compensation Plans, Contemporary

Accounting Research. 29(4), 1204-1236. .

6. Barney, J.B. (1986) Organization Culture: Can it be a

Source of Sustained Competitive Advantage, Academy

of Management Review, 11, 656-665.

7. Bebchuk, Lucian A., Jesse M. Fried and David I.

Walker (2002) Managerial Power and Rent Extraction

in the Design of Executive Compensation, University of

Chicago Law Review, 69, 751-846.

8. Bebchuk, Lucian A. and Jesse M. Fried (2004) Pay

without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of

Executive Compensation, Cambridge, MA.: Harvard

University Press.

9. Bolino, Mark C. and Turnley, William H. (2003)

Counternormative Impression Management, Likeability,

and Performance Ratings: the Use of Intimidation in an

Organizational Setting, Journal of Organizational

Behavior, 24(2), 237-250.

10. Bolton, P., Chen, H. and Wang, N. (2011) A Unified

Theory of Tobin's q, Corporate Investment, Financing,

and Risk Management, Journal of Finance, 66(5),

1545-78.

11. Bono, J.E., Davies, S.E., and Rasch, R.L. (2012) Some

Traits Associated with Flourishing at Work, in The

Oxford Handbook of Positive Organizational

Scholarship, K. S. Cameron and G. M. Spreitzer (eds),

New York: Oxford University Press, 125-37.

12. Bradley-Geist, Jill; Landis, Ronald (2012) Homogeneity

of Personality in Occupations and Organizations: A

Comparison of Alternative Statistical Tests, Journal of

Business & Psychology, 27(2), 149-159.

13. Bredma, Krister. 2012 The Meaning and Development

of the Concept of

14. Management Control: An Etymological Study,

International Journal of Management, 29(2)

15. Cameron, Kim and Spreitzer, G. M. (2012)

Introduction: What is Positive about Positive

Organizational Scholarship? in The Oxford Handbook

of Positive Organizational Scholarship, K. S. Cameron

and G. M. Spreitzer (eds), New York: Oxford

University Press, 1-16.

16. Cameron, Quinn S. and Quinn, Robert E. (2011)

Diagnosing and Changing Organizational Culture:

Jossey-Bass, N.Y., N.Y.

17. Cao, M. and Wang, R. (2013) Optimal CEO

Compensation with Search: Theory and Empirical

Evidence, Journal of Finance, 68(5), 2001-2058.

18. Chng, D., Han M., Rodgers, M., Shih, E., and Song, X-

B (2012) When does incentive compensation motivate

managerial behaviors? An experimental investigation of

the fit between incentive compensation, executive core

self-evaluation, and firm performance, Strategic

Management Journal. 33(12), 1343-1362.

Page 93: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

247

19. Cheung, S. O., Wong, P.S., and Lam, A. (2012) An

Investigation of the Relationship between

Organizational Culture and the Performance of

Construction Organizations, Journal of Business

Economics & Management, 13(4), 688-704.

20. Cooper, T, Faseruk, A., and Khan, S. (2013) Examining

Practitioner Studies to Explore ERM and Organizational

Culture, Journal of Management Policy & Practice,

14(1), 53-68.

21. Devers, C.E., McNamara, G., Wiseman, R.M., and

Arrfelt, M. (2008) Moving Closer to the Action:

Examining Compensation Design Effects on Firm Risk,

Organization Science, 19(4), 548-566.

22. De Vries, M., Kets, M.R., and Miller, D. (1986)

Personality, Culture, and Organization, Academy of

Management Review, 11(2), 266-279.

23. Dhiman, Satinder, (2011), Personal Mastery and

Authentic Leadership, Organization Development

Journal, 29(2), 69-83.

24. Dorff, Michael B. (2005) Does One Hand Wash the

Other? Testing the Managerial Power and Optimal

Contracting Theories of Executive Compensation,

Journal of Corporation Law, 30(2), 255-307.

25. French, S.L. and Holden, T.Q. (2012) Positive

Organizational Behavior: A Buffer for

26. Bad News, Business Communication Quarterly,

75(2),208–220

27. Freeman, R. E., Martin, K., & Parmar, B. (2007)

Stakeholder capitalism. Journal of Business Ethics,

74(4), 303-314.

28. Glynn, M.A. and Watkiss, L (2012) The Generative

Potency of Cultural Symbols, in Leaders in The Oxford

Handbook of Positive Organizational Scholarship, K. S.

Cameron and G. M. Spreitzer (eds), New York: Oxford

University Press, 617-28.

29. Harris, Kenneth J.; Harvey, Paul; Harris, Ranida B., and

Cast, Melissa (2013) An Investigation of Abusive

Supervision, Vicarious Abusive Supervision, and Their

Joint Impacts, Journal of Social Psychology, 153(1), 38-

50.

30. Hermalin, B. and Weisbach, M.S. (2012) Information

Disclosure and Corporate Governance, Journal of

Finance, 67(1), 195-234.

31. Hoffman, B., Bynum, B., Piccolo, R., and Sutton, A.

(2011) Person-Organization Value Congruence: How

Transformational Leaders Influence Work Group

Effectiveness, Academy of Management Journal, 54(4),

779-796.

32. Jacobs, David (2004) The Human Side of Enterprise in

Peril, Academy of Management Review, 29(2), 293-

296.

33. Jensen, Michael C. and Kevin J. Murphy (1990)

Performance Pay and Top-Management

34. Incentives, Journal of Political Economy, 98, 225-264.

35. Kimbrough, R. L., and Componation, P. J. (2009) The

Relationship Between Organizational Culture and

Enterprise Risk Management, Engineering Management

Journal, 21(2), 18-26.

36. Kopelman, Richard E.; Prottas, David. J.; Falk, David

W. (2012) Further Development of a Measure of

Theory X and Y Managerial Assumptions, Journal of

Managerial Issues, 24(4), 450-470.

37. Kotter, J. P. and J. L. Heslett (2011) Organization

Culture and Corporate Performance, New York: The

Free Press.

38. Kluemper, Donald H., DeGroot, Timothy; Choi,

Sungwon (2013) Emotion Management Ability:

Predicting Task Performance, Citizenship, and

Deviance, Journal of Management, 39(4), 878-905.

39. Landsberg, R. D. (2012) Executive Benefit Planning

and Compensation Management.

40. Journal of Financial Service Professionals, 66(2), 19-20.

41. Lawler, Edward E. (2012) Outrageous Executive

Compensation: Corporate Boards, Not the Market, Are

to Blame, Forbes, accessed at

http://www.forbes.com/sites/edwardlawler/2012/10/09/o

utrageous-executive-compensation-corporate-boards-

not-the-market-are-to-blame.

42. Lee, M. and Widener, S.K. (2013) Culture and

Management Control Systems in Today's High-

Performing Firms, Management Accounting Quarterly,

14(2), 11-18.

43. Lehman, D.W. and Ramanujam, R. (2011) Selectivity

in Organizational Rule Violations, Human Resource

Development Quarterly, 22(2), 127-152.

44. Lin, D., Hsien-Chang, K., and Lie-Huey, W (2013)

Chief Executive Compensation: An Empirical Study of

Fat Cat CEOs, International Journal of Business &

Finance Research, 7(2), 27-42.

45. Liu, Dong, Liao, Hui, and Loi, Raymond (2012) The

Dark Side of Leadership: A Three-Level Investigation

of the Cascading Effect of Abusive Supervision on

Employee Creativity, Academy of Management Journal,

55(5), 1187-1212.

46. Louis, Henock; Sun, Amy X. (2011) Earnings

Management and the Post-earnings Announcement

Drift, Financial Management, 40(3), 591-621.

47. Luthans, F and Avolio, B. 2003 Authentic Leadership

Development, in Positive Organizational Scholarship:

Foundations of a New Discipline, K.S. Cameron, J.E.

Dutton, R.E. Quinn (Eds), San Francisco: Brett-

Koehler Publishers, 241-258.

48. McFarland, Henry (1988) Evaluating q as an Alternative

to the Rate of Return in Measuring Profitability; Review

of Economics and Statistics, 70(4), 614-23.

49. Martin, G.P., Gomez-Mejia, L., and Wiseman, R.

(2013) Executive Stock Options as Mixed Gambles:

Revisiting the Behavioral Agency Model, Academy of

Management Journal, 56(2), 451-472.

50. Mishra, A.K. and Mishra, K.E. (2012) Positive

Organizational Scholarship and Trust in Leaders, in The

Oxford Handbook of Positive Organizational

Scholarship, K. S. Cameron and G. M. Spreitzer (eds),

New York: Oxford University Press, 449-461.

51. Moskowitz, M., Levering, R., Akhtar, O., Fry, E.,

Leahey, C., VanderMey, A. (2013) The 100 Best

Companies to Work For, Fortune, 167(2), 85-93

52. Ozkan, N., Singer, Z., and You, H. (2012) Mandatory

IFRS Adoption and the Contractual Usefulness of

Accounting Information in Executive Compensation,

Journal of Accounting Research, 50(4), 1077-1107.

53. Reigle, Ronda F. (2013) Organizational Culture

Assessment: Development of a Descriptive Test

Instrument, Ph.D. dissertation, University of Alabama in

Huntsville.

54. Rich, B.L., Lepine, J, and Crawford, E. (2010) Job

Engagement: Antecedents and Effects on Job

Performance, Academy of Management Journal, 53(3),

617-635.

55. Seligman, Martin E. P. (2011) Building Resilence,

Harvard Business Review, 89(4), 100-106.

56. Seligman. Martin, E.P. (2002) Authentic Happiness

Using the New Positive Psychology to Realize Your

Page 94: Coc  volume_11_issue_2_winter_2014_continued1_

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 11, Issue 2, 2014, Continued - 1

248

Potential for Lasting Happiness, N.Y., N.Y.: The Free

Press

57. Semmler, W and Mateane, L. (2012) Equity Market or

Bond Market-Which Matters the Most for Investment?

Revisiting Tobin's q Theory of Investment, Technology

& Investment, 3(4), 203-209.

58. Schein, Edgar H., (1996) Three Cultures of

Management: The Key to Organizational Learning,

Sloan Management Review, 38(1), 9-20.

59. Schneider, Paul J. (2013) The Managerial Power Theory

of Executive Compensation, Journal of Financial

Service Professionals, 67(3), 17-22.

60. Stevens , J.L. (1990) Tobin's q and the Structure-

Performance Relationship: Comment,

61. The American Economic Review, 80(3), 618-623.

62. Taylor, Frederick W. (1911) The Principles of Scientific

Management, New York: Harper and Brother.

63. Walton, Eric J. (2005) The Persistence of Bureaucracy:

A Meta-analysis of Weber's Model of Bureaucratic

Control. Organization Studies, 26(4) 569-600.

64. Weisbach, M.S. (2007) Optimal Executive

Compensation vs. Managerial Power: A Review of

Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried’s Pay without

Performance: The Unfilled Promise of Executive

Compensation, Journal of Economic Literature, 45(2),

419-428.

65. West, William F.and Raso, Connor (2013) Who Shapes

the Rulemaking Agenda? Implications for Bureaucratic

Responsiveness and Bureaucratic Control, Journal of

Public Administration Research & Theory, 23(3), 495-

519.

66. Wrege, C.D. & Hodgetts, R.M. (2000) Frederick W.

Taylor’s 1899 pig-iron observations: examining fact,

fiction, and lessons for the new millennium, Academy

of Management Journal, 43(6), 1283-1291.

67. Wright, T.A. and Campbell, J. (2009) The Emerging

Positive Agenda in Organizations: Greater than a

Trickle, but not yet a Deluge, Journal of Organizational

Behavior, 30, 147-159.

68. Wright, Thomas A. and Quick, James Campbell (2009)

The Emerging Positive Agenda in Organizations:

Greater than a Trickle, but Not Yet a Deluge, Journal of

Organizational Behavior, 30(2), 147-159.

69. Wren, Daniel A., (2011) The Centennial of Frederick

W. Taylor's The Principles of Scientific Management: A

Retrospective Commentary, Journal of Business &

Management, 17(1), 11-22.

70. Xiaoming, C. and Junchen. H. (2012) A Literature

Review on Organization Culture and Corporate

Performance, International Journal of Business

Administration, 3(2), 28-37.


Recommended