+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but...

Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but...

Date post: 04-Aug-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
35
Credit or Crime? The Effects of Online Lending on Crime This draft: May 13, 2018 PRELIMINARY - DO NOT CIRCULATE Abstract Frictions in credit markets impact social welfare. Using bank mergers as a shock to local credit market competitiveness and a matched difference-in-difference methodology, I show that house- holds turn to peer-to-peer (P2P) lending when local credit markets suffer from frictions. In turn, availability of P2P credit offsets between 2% to 26% of the incremental crime incidents due to a bank merger. The moderation in crime growth principally occurs in property-related crimes (e.g., thefts and burglaries) while growth in persons-related and societal crimes are not affected. Overall, the evidence suggests that P2P lending is an important new credit channel which can have real effects. Keywords: Consumer loans, household credit, peer-to-peer, social welfare.
Transcript
Page 1: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Credit or Crime? The Effects of Online Lending on

Crime

This draft: May 13, 2018

PRELIMINARY - DO NOT CIRCULATE

Abstract

Frictions in credit markets impact social welfare. Using bank mergers as a shock to local credit

market competitiveness and a matched difference-in-difference methodology, I show that house-

holds turn to peer-to-peer (P2P) lending when local credit markets suffer from frictions. In turn,

availability of P2P credit offsets between 2% to 26% of the incremental crime incidents due to

a bank merger. The moderation in crime growth principally occurs in property-related crimes

(e.g., thefts and burglaries) while growth in persons-related and societal crimes are not affected.

Overall, the evidence suggests that P2P lending is an important new credit channel which can

have real effects.

Keywords: Consumer loans, household credit, peer-to-peer, social welfare.

Page 2: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

1 Introduction

Well-functioning credit markets are important for economic vitality and social welfare. For

instance, consolidation among local banks increases credit market frictions which, in turn, leads

to rising crime (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006). Yet, a recent resurgence in financial technology

(FinTech) has focused on relieving credit market frictions through the creation of online peer-to-

peer (P2P) markets. While these platforms have expanded the depth of credit markets, it remains

unclear whether they have had real effects. I show that P2P lending impacts social welfare by

moderating crime growth when households’ local credit markets suffer from imperfections due to

bank mergers..

Local banking institutions are traditionally important sources of credit to households due to

information and agency considerations (Petersen and Rajan 1995; Black and Strahan 2002; Han

and Li 2011). For instance, Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2004) show that local financial devel-

opment is an important driver of local economic success even in environments with no frictions

to capital movements. Survey evidence from households and small businesses also indicates that

banking markets are still localized (Kwast, Starr-McCluer, and Wolken 1997; Petersen and Rajan

2002). Therefore, imperfections in households’ local lending channels can have real and social

impacts (Prager and Hannan 1998; Kahn, Pennacchi, and Sopranzetti 2005). Ultimately, the

evidence suggests that there should be benefits to improving credit markets through ameliorating

frictions.

P2P credit markets serve as alternative borrowing channels for households. By using on-

line platforms, these markets facilitate the direct matching of individuals seeking credit with

geographically-dispersed households willing to supply funds.1 The platforms also use technology

to assess and price credit risk. Importantly, individuals are increasingly using these new markets,

which are expected to continue growing, reaching nearly $150 billion per year by 2025 (Pricewa-

terhouseCoopers 2015).2 I posit that P2P loans can serve as an alternative credit source when

individuals’ local credit markets are subject to frictions.

1Institutions are also recently adopting lender roles on P2P platforms.2For context, the Center for Financial Services Innovation estimates that, in 2015, households spent $36.5 billion

on fees and interest for single payment credit products, such as payday loans, and $26.2 billion on fees and interestfor short-term installment loan products, which range from several months to two years in duration.

1

Page 3: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

If individuals adopt P2P credit in response to market frictions, there are likely to be real

effects. One channel through which P2P credit can influence welfare is through reducing crime.

For instance, the criminology literature suggests that insufficient cash to meet current expenses

is a primary driver of burglaries (Wright and Decker 1994). While the financial economics of

crime literature is limited, initial evidence suggests that credit market frictions spur crime growth

(Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can

relieve financial constraints and reduce crime (Morse 2011).

Overall, I focus on two core hypotheses. First, I posit that households seeking credit will

turn to P2P markets when their local, traditional credit channels suffer from frictions. Second, I

hypothesize that access to P2P credit will impact social welfare by moderating the appreciation

in crime growth that is related to credit market imperfections.

To empirically test my hypotheses, I obtain data from 2007 through 2015 on bank transfor-

mations from the Federal Reserve. I use mergers between two non-failing banks to identify local

credit markets which are likely to be affected by frictions.3 I also obtain loan data from Lending

Club, the largest P2P lending market in the United States, to measure demand for P2P loans

in response to a bank merger.4 Finally, I rely on crime data from the National Incident Based

Reporting System (NIBRS), a reporting system used by law enforcement agencies and under the

jurisdiction of the Federal Bureau of Investigation (FBI), to assess the social welfare implications

of bank mergers and P2P credit.

I test my first conjecture by examining whether P2P loan volume responds to a bank merger.

For this analysis, I estimate panel regressions where the dependent variable is the log of the total

annual P2P loan volume within each three-digit zip code.5 The primary independent variable is

an indicator variable which takes a value of one if a bank merger occurred in the prior year, and

zero otherwise. Consistent with my hypothesis, I find that loan volume significantly increases in

the year after a bank merger, rising by about 28.60% or $353,957. The appreciation in borrowing

3A substantial literature ties bank mergers to less competitive credit markets (Akhavein, Berger, and Humphrey1997; Prager and Hannan 1998). As a result, mergers have been used to study the effects of bank competition ona range of socio-economic outcomes, including small business lending (Berger, Saunders, Scalise, and Udell 1998),loan contracts (Sapienza 2002), and crime (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006).

4Lending Club loan data report borrowers’ location at the three-digit level. Therefore, references to zip codesare at the three-digit level throughout the paper.

5Lending Club reports borrowers’ locations at the three-digit zip code level. I use the terms three-digit zip Codeand zip code interchangeably.

2

Page 4: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

is not explained by variation in demographics, aggregate time trends, and unobservable time-

invariant local factors.

Given that households turn to P2P credit in response to bank mergers, I test my second

hypothesis, that crime growth due to a bank merger is moderated by access to P2P credit. To

do so, I employ two approaches. First, I conduct ordinary least squares (OLS) panel regressions

where the dependent variable is annual crime growth. The main independent variables are the

bank merger indicator variable and the log of the total annual P2P loan volume. I also interact

the merger indicator variable with P2P loan volume to capture the effects of P2P credit on crime

growth after a bank merger.

In line with my conjecture, the estimates from the baseline panel regressions show that crime

growth spikes after a bank merger, but P2P lending reduces the rise. Specifically, I find that a one

percent increase in loan volume offsets about 0.64 new crimes. The effect is robust to variation

in socio-economic factors, including gender, race, age, education, income, unemployment rates,

home values, and population size, as well as changes in the number of law enforcement agencies

participating in NIBRS. Overall, the collective evidence indicates that P2P credit markets can

reduce a negative externality due to frictions in traditional lending channels.

However, the panel regressions are subject to endogeneity concerns. For instance, expectations

of households’ future incomes may impact present-day decisions by local banks, households’ credit

demands, and crime. Yet, the empirical specification facilitates a counterfactual framework (Ney-

man 1923; Rubin 1974) to solve these econometric problems using a matching and differencing

approach (Heckman, Ichimura, and Todd 1997; Heckman, Ichimura, Smith, and Todd 1998). The

intuition being that difference-in-difference estimation provides unbiased effect estimates if, in the

absence of the treatment, the trend over time would have been the same between the treated

and control groups. A concern with this technique, however, is that the groups may differ in

ways related to their trends over time. Matching is employed to address this type of confounding

factor. This combined procedure has been adopted across a range of disciplines to identify causal

effects, including political science (Liberini, Redoano, and Proto 2017), ecology (Andam, Ferraro,

Pfaff, Sanchez-Azofeifa, and Robalino 2008), and financial economics (Malmendier and Tate 2009;

Morse 2011; Becker and Hvide 2017).

3

Page 5: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Extending this framework to my setting, the underlying modeling challenge is the evaluation of

the causal effects of bank mergers and P2P credit on crime growth. This requires a control zip code

where a bank merger did not occur and P2P credit is unavailable. To construct counterfactuals

for treated communities, those which experienced a bank merger and have access to P2P loans, I

identify zip codes which never experience a bank merger and exploit the restriction of access to

P2P credit in two states, Iowa and West Virginia. Residents of these states could not borrow in

the P2P market due to state regulatory restrictions related to security issuances. This plausibly

exogenous restriction of access allows me to construct counterfactuals for a portion of the treated

zip codes.

For communities which experience a bank merger, using the nearest-neighbor method with

replacement, I select a matched zip code from the pool of non-merger, non-lender communities. I

match based on socio-economic factors in the year prior to a bank merger to remove any economy-

wide fluctuations.6 I am able to match 164 lender communities which experienced a bank merger

to a counterfactual zip code. I then employ a difference-in-difference estimator on the matched

zip codes to isolate the causal effects P2P credit on crime growth.

Evidence from the difference-in-difference tests reinforce the findings from the panel regres-

sions, indicating that access to P2P impacts social welfare by moderating growth in crime following

a bank merger. Specifically, the estimates suggest that, following a merger, there are about 1,037

incremental incidents of crime. However, access to P2P loans mitigates a portion of the spike,

offsetting about 26.44% of the rise. Alternatively, a one percent increase in loan volume inhibits

about 0.52 new crimes.

In light of this primary evidence, I examine if the there are heterogeneous effects across

types of crime. I do so because the economics of crime literature suggests that economic factors

principally impact property-related crimes, as opposed to personal or societal crimes. I exploit

the depth of the NIBRS data to investigate the hypothesis that the moderation in crime growth

due to P2P access is driven by property crimes. To test this conjecture, I examine growth in

6The socio-economic variables underpinning the matching process include, house prices, per capita income, gen-der, the proportion of the residents which are African American, the percentage of residents whom are collegeeducated, the unemployment rate, and the size of the population. These variables are typically important deter-minants of economic conditions and households’ decisions (Campbell 2006), including P2P borrowing (Morse 2015;Bazley 2017) and crime (Freeman 1999).

4

Page 6: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

thefts, burglaries, and briberies, as these are property-related crimes. I also examine whether

assaults and homicides/manslaughters, both persons-related crimes, and weapon law violations,

a societal crime, are impacted. I re-perform both the panel regressions and matched difference-

in-difference tests using growth in each crime category as the dependent variable. Overall, I find

that growth in property-related crime and assaults increase after a bank merger but access to

P2P lending moderates the appreciation. Homicides/manslaughters and weapon law violations

are not consistently influenced by mergers or P2P credit.

While the findings are robust to known determinants of crime, a natural alternative hypothesis

could be that expected future crime increases may prompt present-day mergers and P2P credit

demand. This explanation implies that, if trending crime risks cause mergers and P2P borrowing,

future crime would be a reflection of the current crime trend. In essence, current crime growth

would spur contemporaneous bank mergers and P2P loan volume. First, I find that present-day

crime growth is significantly and positively correlated with crime growth in the next year. Given

this correlation, positive contemporaneous correlations between crime growth and mergers and

crime growth and P2P borrowing should exist under this alternative hypothesis. However, crime

growth does not significantly predict bank mergers during the same year. Crime growth also does

not significantly explain concurrent P2P loan volume. Overall, the evidence suggests that the

reverse causation theory is unlikely.

These findings contribute to several financial economics literatures, including an emerging

branch focusing on technology and financial innovation (Tufano 2003; Hauswald and Marquez

2003; Balyuk 2017). Peer-to-peer lending markets are a key innovation from the recent FinTech

revolution and their role in the U.S. financial system is subject to ongoing regulatory debate.

Foundational studies have principally focused on identifying determinants of borrowers’ funding

outcomes, including creditworthiness (Iyer, Khwaja, Luttmer, and Shue 2015), trustworthiness

(Duarte, Siegel, and Young 2012), and their local economic conditions (Ramcharan and Crowe

2013). I expand the literature by showing that P2P credit markets impact social welfare through

reducing crime growth in response to capital market frictions.

This paper also speaks to the financial economics of crime and criminology literatures. Build-

ing upon Becker’s (1968) descriptive model of crime, Lochner (2004) constructs a model in which

5

Page 7: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

human capital increases the opportunity cost of crime from foregone work and incarceration.

Empirical studies support the link between income and wage earning opportunities and crime

(Patterson 1991; Levitt 2001). Recent evidence also indicates that capital market outcomes im-

pact criminal behavior. For example, Huck (2015) suggests that rising equity returns can spur

crime due to envy and wealth inequality. This study shows that effective credit markets can

alleviate crime through reducing financial frictions.

More broadly, this paper links to the banking (Erel 2011), credit (Agarwal, Chunlin, and

Souleles 2007; Tufano 2009; Zinman 2014; Melzer 2011) and household finance (Gross and Souleles

2002; Campbell 2006; Guiso and Sodini 2013) literatures. The results show that P2P markets

fill a missing rung in the credit ladder. Further, a principal component of the household finance

literature investigates individuals’ adoption of new financial products (Campbell 2006). I deepen

this literature by showing that frictions in traditional financial markets influences households’

engagement with a new capital market.

2 Literature Review

In this section, I review related work examining the relationship between crime and financial

economic factors. I also characterize the emerging literature on peer-to-peer lending. Building

upon these literatures, I develop the primary hypotheses of the study.

2.1 Economics of Crime

The dynamics between economic factors and crime have received considerable attention. A

principal area of focus has been the influence of employment opportunities on crime. While the

literature has found a positive association between the two, the strength of the relationship is not

typically strong (Freeman 1999; Cullen and Levitt 1999). More recently, Levitt (2001) documents

that a 1% increase in the unemployment rate is associated with an increase in property-related

crimes in the range of 1.4 to 2.7%. In line with this evidence, Grogger (1998) and Gould, Weinberg,

and Mustard (2002) show that limited legal wage-earning opportunities spurs criminal activities.

Income is also an important factor in individuals’ decisions to commit crimes. That is, households

turn to crime when facing poverty (Patterson 1991) and when income inequality increases (Kelly

6

Page 8: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

2000; Fajnzylber, Lederman, and Loayza 2002). However, Dills, Miron, and Summers (2010) point

out that fully understanding the determinants of crime will require significant further study.

The links between crime and capital markets have received less attention. The core of the

literature has centered on capital markets’ and firms’ responses to corporate crimes, including

fraud (Karpoff, Lee, and Martin 2008a; Karpoff, Lee, and Martin 2008b), bribery (Zeume 2017),

and insider trading (Acharya and Johnson 2010). However, Huck (2015) shows that movements in

equity markets impact crime through envy forms of utility (i.e., habit preferences). He finds that

a one standard deviation increase in equity returns is associated with about a 22.8o basis point

increase in crime. An emerging literature shows that developments in credit markets impact crime

rates as well. Garmaise and Moskowitz (2006) provide evidence that frictions in households’ local

credit markets, due to bank mergers, lead to rising crime. However, access to alternative sources

of financing, such as payday loans, can mitigate crime growth when individuals face financial

distress (Morse 2011). Overall, the literature indicates that financial markets impact not only

the economic welfares of households, but also their social welfares. Importantly, the evidence also

suggests that abatement of capital market frictions could have positive externalities.

2.2 Peer-to-Peer Lending

P2P credit markets have experienced significant growth in the recent past and are expected to

continue growing (Fitch Ratings 2014; PricewaterhouseCoopers 2015). Research into the dynamics

of peer-to-peer platforms is also rapidly increasing (Morse 2015). Foundational studies have

focused on determinants of borrowing outcomes. Iyer, Khwaja, Luttmer, and Shue (2015) show

that P2P lenders exhibit sophistication in assessing borrowers’ creditworthiness from financial

data. Yet, social cues and borrowers’ personal characteristics play important roles (Galak, Small,

and Stephen 2011; Duarte, Siegel, and Young 2012; Ravina 2012; Freedman and Jin 2014).

Borrowers’ local economic conditions, such as appreciating home values, also impact lenders’ and

borrowers’ decisions in P2P markets (Ramcharan and Crowe 2013; Bazley 2017).

The implications of P2P markets for traditional credit providers is a growing area of study as

well. For instance, recent evidence suggests that P2P lending generates information spillovers for

banks (Balyuk 2017). On the other hand, whether the rise of P2P markets has had real effects

7

Page 9: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

remains an open question.

2.3 Hypotheses

In light of the established literature, I construct two core hypotheses. First, it is reasonable

to hypothesize that P2P lending can serve as an alternative channel through which households

can borrow when their local credit markets are impacted by frictions, such as when banks merge.

Specifically, I posit that demand for P2P loans will increase in response to bank mergers. Second,

given the social welfare implications of credit market frictions, I conjecture that access to P2P

credit will offset, at least in part, the deleterious effects of bank mergers. Specifically, I posit that

access to P2P loans will influence social welfare through mitigating rises in crime following bank

mergers.

3 Data and Summary Statistics

I draw data from a variety of sources for this study. I briefly describe the data and provide

summary statistics for the key variables.

3.1 P2P Data

Lending Club is the largest P2P credit market in the U.S. To apply for a loan, an individual

specifies the amount of funds desired, the loan term (three or five years), the reason for borrowing,

and other personal details. Lending Club verifies the information and subsequently assigns an

interest rate to the loan based on a proprietary algorithm. Once the loan application is approved,

it is listed on the online platform and becomes available for investors to fund.7 Once listed on

the platform, loans typically receive full funding.8

Importantly, Lending Club publicly releases its loan data. I use a sample of 197,294 individual

loans with a total volume of approximately $2.950 billion issued between 2007 and year-end 2015.

The data include borrowers’ traditional credit statistics, such as FICO scores, income, and debt-

to-income, as well as their location of residence (at the three-digit zip code level). The data also

7Lending Club restricts applications to individuals with at least a 640 FICO score and a bank account. Thesecond largest P2P lender, Prosper, relies on these same base requirements.

8On average, a listed loan receives over 99% of the requested amount (Bazley 2017).

8

Page 10: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

include information on borrowers’ loan details, including the amount, term, interest rate, and

repayments.

I measure annual demand for P2P credit using, P2P Loan Volume, the natural log of the total

loan volume within a zip code area. In Panel A of Table 1, I show that average yearly volume in

a zip code is about $1,237,613 based on about 83 loans. The average interest rate across loans is

about 12.84%. I include definitions of all variables in Table A1.

3.2 Crime Data

I rely on crime data from the National Incident Based Reporting System (NIBRS). The system

is under the jurisdiction of the Federal Bureau of Investigation (FBI) and is a voluntary system

used by U.S. law enforcement agencies for collecting and reporting crimes. NIBRS collects data on

each single incident and arrest within twenty-two offense categories composed of forty-six specific

crimes, termed Group A offenses. Each incident includes information on the type of offense,

victim, offender, location of the offense, date, and time.9 In Table A2, I examine whether law

enforcement agencies’ participation in NIBRS fluctuates over my sample period. Overall, I find

that participation is moderately increasing.

I utilize data from 2007 through 2015 spread across thirty-five states and 338 three-digit zip

code areas. To assess annual crime growth within each zip code area, I create a variable, Crime

Growth, which is the yearly growth in the total number of incidents across all forty-six Group A

categories. In Panel B of Table 1, I show that there are about 14,632 crimes each year in a zip

code area. Crime growth is also increasing in my sample, with about 42 additional crimes per year

within a zip code. I also separately examine growth across specific crime types, including thefts,

burglaries, incidents of bribery, assaults, homicides/manslaughters, and weapon law violations.

Thefts comprise the largest proportion of total crimes.

9In addition to the Group A offenses, the system includes eleven Group B offense categories for which only arrestdata are reported. Group B offenses include bad checks, loitering, disorderly conduct, driving under the influence,drunkenness, nonviolent family offenses, liquor law violations, peeping, trespassing, and a miscellaneous category.The estimates are not sensitive to including Group B offenses in the analysis.

9

Page 11: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

3.3 Bank Data

Building upon Garmaise and Moskowitz (2006), I use bank mergers to identify local credit

markets which are likely impacted frictions. I, therefore, obtain information on all bank trans-

formations from the Federal Reserve. To measure the effect of bank consolidation on P2P credit

demand and crime, I construct an indicator variable, Bank Merger, which takes a value of one if

a merger occurred within a zip code area during the year. I identify bank mergers as mergers be-

tween two non-failing banks where one bank’s FDIC certificate is surrendered. Overall, I identify

389 bank mergers during my sample period.

3.4 Control Data

The criminology literature generally suggests several determinants of crime, including gender,

race, employment, and education (Flowers 1989). To account for these factors in my empirical

tests, I obtain data from a variety of sources. First, I obtain population demographic characteris-

tics for each zip code from the U.S. Census Bureau, including population size, median per capita

income, and the proportion of individuals that are male, African American, and have a graduated

from college. Wage earning opportunities also play a role in households’ decisions to commit

crimes (Grogger 1998; Gould, Weinberg, and Mustard 2002). I, therefore, obtain data on yearly

unemployment rates within zip codes from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. I also obtain annual

house price data from Federal Housing Finance Agency to account for the impacts of housing

market developments on crime (Cui and Walsh 2015).

4 Bank Mergers’ Impact on P2P Credit Demand

To begin, I first examine whether P2P credit serves as a substitute channel through which

individuals can borrow following a bank merger. I posit that as frictions in local credit markets

increase following bank mergers, households seeking credit can turn to the online P2P market.

Ultimately, this will lead to increases in P2P lending volumes.

To test this conjecture, I perform ordinary least squares (OLS) panel regressions which esti-

mate the effects of bank mergers on P2P loan volume in the year following the merger. Specifically,

10

Page 12: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

I estimate:

P2P Loan V ol.i,t = α0 + β1Bank Mergeri,t−1 + θXi,t + ψi + ρt + εi,t (1)

where P2P Loan Vol.i,t is the natural log of the P2P loan volume within three-digit zip code i

during year t. Bank Merger i,t−1 is an indicator which takes a value of one when a bank merger

occurs within zip code i during year t-1, and zero otherwise. Bank Merger is the primary variable

of interest and β1 captures the effect of a merger on P2P loan volume in the following year.

The regressions also include a vector of zip code-level controls, Xi,t, to account for time-varying

determinants of credit demand, including house prices, per capita incomes, unemployment rates,

the population sizes, and the proportions of the populations that are male, African American,

and college educated. Additionally, I include year fixed effects, ρt, to account for aggregate

time trends. The estimation results may still be biased, however, if crime is driven by some

unobservable, local characteristics. I, therefore, rely on zip code fixed effects, ψi, to account for

selection on time-invariant differences across communities.

The evidence in Table 2 indicates that bank mergers significantly influence the dynamics of

the P2P credit market. The estimate from a univariate regression (Column 1) shows that, in

the year following a merger, P2P loan volume grows by about 32.10%. Including time-varying

economic and demographic controls (Column 2) does not subsume the effect of a merger. The

estimates in Column (3) indicate that the increase in borrowing is also not driven by aggregate

time trends. Using zip code fixed effects to look within a zip code area (Column 4), a merger is

associated with a 28.61% increase in loan volume the following year. In economic terms, this is

equivalent to an increase of $353,957 in loan volume based on an average volume of $1,237,613.

Overall, mergers between traditional financial institutions have implications for P2P credit

markets. Specifically, consolidation of local credit channels leads to a significant increase in

borrowing in P2P market. In turn, the heightened borrowing suggests that P2P lending may

impact social welfare through moderating, crime growth, a negative externality, associated with

bank mergers.

11

Page 13: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

5 Effects of P2P Credit on Crime

Since P2P borrowing increases following a bank merger, access to the market has the potential

to impact social welfare. I test this conjecture using two approaches. First, I perform panel

regressions to estimate the effects of mergers and P2P lending on crime. Then, to address potential

endogeneity concerns, I employ a matched difference-in-difference methodology.

5.1 Baseline Panel Regression Methodology

As a baseline, I test whether P2P credit mitigates crime following a bank merger by performing

OLS panel regressions. Specifically, I estimate:

Crime Growthi,t = α0 + β1Bank Mergeri,t−1 + β2P2P Loan V ol.i,t

+ β3Bank Mergeri,t−1 × P2P Loan V ol.i,t

+ θXi,t + ψi + ρt + εi,t

(2)

where Crime Growthi,t is the change in the number of crimes from the prior year within zip code i.

Bank Merger i,t−1 is, as before, an indicator which takes a value of one when a bank merger occurs

within three-digit zip code i during year t-1, and zero otherwise. P2P Loan Vol.i,t is the natural

log of the P2P loan volume within three-digit zip code i during year t. The primary variable of

interest is Bank Merger i,t−1 × P2P Loan Vol.i,t and β3 captures the effects of P2P borrowing on

crime growth after a bank merger. The regressions also include the socio-economic controls as

well as year and zip code fixed effects. I also include an additional control, Law Agencies, which

is the number of law agencies within the zip code area that participate in NIBRS. I include this

control to address potential concerns that fluctuations in participation may drive crime growth.

5.2 Baseline Results

To begin, the estimates in Table 3 show that crime growth increases following a bank merger.

This finding is in line with (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006). When accounting for time-varying

socio-economic factors (Column 2), bank mergers significantly increase crime growth. Time-

invariant unobservable variables do not drive the effect since the results are robust to including

12

Page 14: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

zip code fixed effects (Column 3). Accounting for aggregate time trends (Column 4) also does not

subsume the effect. For instance, the estimates suggest that crime growth increases by about 382

incidents after a merger.

While the estimates for P2P Loan Vol. in Columns (1) and (2) indicate that areas with more

P2P borrowing also have more crime, accounting for unobservable time-invariant factors subsumes

the effect (Column 3). Similarly, the estimate for P2P Loan Vol. from specification (4), which

accounts for aggregate time trends, is not statistically different from zero.

Importantly, following a bank merger, P2P lending is associated with a significant decline in

crime growth. That is, access to P2P credit offsets a portion of the rise in crime associated with

a merger. Specifically, the estimates in Column (4) indicate that, within a zip code area, that a

one percent increase in loan volume reduces crime growth by 0.64 incidents. Based on the average

P2P loan volume response to a bank merger, about a 28.6% increase, P2P borrowing offsets about

18 new crimes.

Overall, the panel regression estimates suggests that the P2P credit market has the potential

to counteract the social costs associated with frictions in traditional capital markets. Specifically,

P2P lending increases following a bank merger which moderates the subsequent rise in crime

growth.

5.3 Matched Difference-in-Difference Methodology

The initial evidence points towards the P2P credit market serving as an alternative credit

channel when lending is restricted at traditional financial institutions. In turn, access to P2P

credit impacts social welfare by offsetting a portion of the growth in crime which stems from a bank

merger. However, the preceding analysis is subject to endogeneity and omitted variable concerns.

For instance, expectations of households’ future incomes may impact present-day decisions by

local banks, households’ credit decisions, and crime.

Yet, Eq.(2) does facilitate a counterfactual framework to solve these econometric problems us-

ing a matching and differencing approach. The counterfactual framework was pioneered in statis-

tics and program evaluation research by Neyman (1923) and Rubin (1974). The design assesses the

effect of a treatment against an estimation of the counterfactual, which would be the outcome had

13

Page 15: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

the subject not been exposed to the treatment. Heckman, Ichimura, and Todd (1997) and Heck-

man, Ichimura, Smith, and Todd (1998) expand upon the matching-counterfactual framework by

incorporating difference-in-difference estimation. The intuition being that difference-in-difference

estimation provides unbiased effect estimates if, in the absence of the treatment, the trend over

time would have been the same between the treated and control groups. However, a concern with

this technique is that the groups may differ in ways related to their trends over time. Matching is

employed to address this type of confounding factor. This combined procedure has been adopted

across a range of disciplines to identify causal effects, including political science (Liberini, Re-

doano, and Proto 2017), ecology (Andam, Ferraro, Pfaff, Sanchez-Azofeifa, and Robalino 2008),

and financial economics (Malmendier and Tate 2009; Morse 2011; Becker and Hvide 2017).

Extending this framework to my setting, the underlying modeling challenge is the evaluation of

the causal effects of bank mergers and P2P credit on crime growth. This requires a control zip code

where a bank merger did not occur and P2P credit is unavailable. To construct counterfactuals

for treated communities, those which experienced a bank merger and have access to P2P loans, I

identify zip codes which never experience a bank merger and exploit the restriction of access to

P2P credit in two states, Iowa and West Virginia. Residents of these states could not borrow in

the P2P market due to state regulatory restrictions related to security issuances. This plausibly

exogenous restriction of access allows me to construct counterfactuals for a portion of the treated

zip codes.

For lender communities which experience a bank merger, using the nearest-neighbor method

with replacement, I select a matched community from the pool of non-merger, non-lender com-

munities. I match based on socio-economic factors in the year prior to a bank merger to remove

any economy-wide fluctuations.10 The socio-economic variables underpinning the matching pro-

cess include, house prices, per capita income, gender, the proportion of the residents whom are

African American, the percentage of residents who have graduated college, the unemployment

rate, a vector of age groups, and the size of the population. These variables are typically impor-

tant determinants of economic conditions and households’ decisions (Campbell 2006), including

P2P borrowing (Morse 2015; Bazley 2017) and crime (Freeman 1999).

10However, I retain year fixed to address any residual concerns about time effects.

14

Page 16: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

I match 164 lender communities which experienced a bank merger to a counterfactual zip code.

Table 4 presents the results of the matching. For each variable, I report differences in the means

and t-statistics for tests of the hypothesis that the difference between zip codes with access to the

P2P market, in the year prior to a bank merger, and those that are restricted from borrowing,

in the same year, are zero. Among the ten variables, none have a difference in means that is

significantly different from zero. This suggests that the matched pairs are similar on observable

dimensions. I also examine whether crime growth, in the year prior to a bank merger, varies

significantly between the treated community its matched-control zip code and find no significant

difference. Given the reasonable matching results, I employ a difference-in-difference estimator to

isolate the causal effects of bank mergers and P2P credit on crime growth.

5.4 Matched Difference-in-Difference Results

I report estimates from the difference-in-difference analysis in Table 5. Column (1) shows

that a community which experienced a bank merger has higher crime growth in the next year

relative to similar community which did not have a merger. On the other hand, the estimate for

P2P Area, an indicator variable which takes a value of one if the zip code has access to the P2P

credit market, is not statistically significant. This suggests that the availability of P2P loans is

not associated with higher crime growth. Importantly, the estimate for the interaction between

Bank Merger and P2P Area is negative and statistically significant, indicating that P2P market

access reduces crime growth following a merger.

While the matching results indicate that the aligned zip code pairs are similar, in Column

(2), I include control variables to adjust for any residual bias and increase efficiency. Including

the socio-economic controls does not materially impact the estimates. I find that a merger is

associated with about 1,037 incremental crime incidents while the net effect of access to P2P

lending inhibits about 275 incidents. This is a reduction of about 26.54% of the new incremental

crimes due to a merger.

To be consistent with the baseline tests, in Columns (3) and (4), I report estimates using

P2P Loan Vol. instead of the indicator variable, P2P Area. The principal conclusions remain the

same when using P2P Loan Vol. Crime growth increases following a merger, but P2P lending

15

Page 17: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

moderates the rise. That is, the cumulative effect of a one percent increase in volume reduces

crime growth by about 0.52% after a merger.

The collective evidence from the panel regressions and the difference-in-difference tests indi-

cates that bank mergers incite growth in crime. However, access to P2P credit has an offsetting

effect. That is, the P2P credit market impacts social welfare by moderating the growth in crime

due to frictions in traditional lending channels.

6 Additional Evidence

The evidence from the primary tests indicates that access to P2P credit markets have social

welfare implications. In light of the findings, several additional points warrant investigation.

6.1 Crime Types

The criminology literature suggests that there is heterogeneity in the determinants of crimes

across crime types. For instance, economic variables are generally linked to property crimes, such

as theft, as opposed to violent crimes, like homicides (Levitt 2001; Raphael and Winter-Ebmer

2001). In addition, Wright and Decker (1994) note that many burglars identify insufficient cash to

meet their current expenses, i.e., insufficient liquidity, as a principal driver of their crimes. In light

of this, I examine how property, personal, and societal crimes respond following a bank merger

and whether P2P lending has heterogeneous impacts across crime types. I posit that property

crimes will increase following a bank merger, but that access to P2P credit will moderate the

rise. Conversely, I expect personal and societal crimes to be little influenced by mergers and P2P

lending.

To test these conjectures, I examine growth across several types of crimes. I identify property-

related, personal, and societal crimes according to their Uniform (UCR) Offense Codes through

NIBRS.11 To measure property-related crimes, I construct three variables. First, Theft Growth

is the yearly growth in the number of pocket-picking, purse-snatching, and shoplifting crimes.

11Specifically, NIBRS classifies crimes into three categories: (i) property, (ii) persons, and (iii) societal. Accordingto NIBRS, crimes against persons are those whose victims are always individuals. The objective of crimes againstproperty is to obtain money, property, or some other benefit. Crimes against society represent society’s prohibitionagainst engaging in certain types of activity.

16

Page 18: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Second, Burglary Growth is the yearly growth in the number of burglary and breaking and entering

crimes. Finally, Bribery Growth is the annual growth in bribery crimes.

I also create three variables related to crimes against persons and society. Specifically, Assault

Growth is the annual growth in aggravated and simple assaults and intimidation crimes. Next,

Homicide/Manslaughter Growth is the yearly increase in murder/non-negligent manslaughter,

negligent manslaughter, and justifiable homicide crimes.12 Lastly, I calculate the annual growth

in weapon law violations as a measure of societal crimes.

I re-perform both the OLS panel regressions and the matched difference-in-difference tests

using the aforementioned crime growth variables as dependent variables. I report estimates for

property crimes in Panel A of Table 6. The principal conclusion from the estimates is that

property-related crime growth increases after a bank merger, but access to P2P lending markets

moderates the rise. Specifically, the estimates from both the OLS panel regressions and difference-

in-difference tests show that growth in thefts (Columns 1 and 2) increases in the year following a

bank merger. That is, the difference-in-difference estimate for Bank Merger in Column (2) shows

that about 129 additional thefts occur in the year after a bank merger.

Importantly, the estimate for the interaction term, Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol., is negative

and statistically significant, indicating that rising P2P borrowing counteracts the spike and offsets

a portion of the growth in thefts. Based on the average increase in borrowing after a merger, the

estimates imply that P2P lending offsets about 1.98% of the incremental thefts. I find similar

effects for growth in burglaries, where about 1.59% of the new crimes due a merger are offset.

Growth in briberies is also reduced but the effect is economically small.

In Panel B, I report estimates related to growth in personal and social crimes. Assaults signif-

icantly increase after a bank merger, with about 254 incremental incidents (Column 2). However,

about 1.52% of the new assaults are offset based on the average increase in P2P borrowing. This

finding is interesting in light of the limited evidence linking economic factors and personal crime.

However, given that assaults typically occur at home between individuals who know each other,

access to credit may moderate stress and other visceral factors (e.g., Card and Dahl (2011)),

ultimately, reducing assaults. On the other hand, the estimates for homicides/manslaughters and

12The results are not sensitive to excluding justifiable homicides.

17

Page 19: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

weapon law violations indicate that bank mergers and P2P borrowing have limited impact on

growth in these types of crimes.

Overall, the evidence points towards P2P lending principally offsetting growth in crimes related

to property. That is, P2P credit alleviates local capital market frictions and reduces growth in

crimes where the objective is to obtain money, property, or some other benefit. Conversely, access

to P2P credit has limited impact on severe personal and societal crimes.

7 Robustness

In this section, I perform additional tests to investigate the robustness of the primary findings.

7.1 Reverse Causality

I focus on mergers between non-failing banks to alleviate reverse causality concerns related to

crime, bank mergers, and P2P credit demand. Nevertheless, a hypothesis could be that expected

future crime increases may prompt present-day mergers and P2P credit demand. An implication

of this conjecture is that, if trending crime risks cause mergers and P2P borrowing, future crime

would have to be a reflection of the current crime trend. In sum, current crime growth would

spur contemporaneous bank mergers and P2P loan volume. First, I note that crime growth is

positively correlated with crime growth in the next year (estimate = 0.205; p-value < 0.001).

In light of this correlation, I should find positive contemporaneous correlations between crime

growth and mergers and crime growth and P2P borrowing under this alternative hypothesis.

In Table 7, I directly address whether contemporaneous crime growth impacts merger activity

and P2P borrowing by regressing Bank Merger (probit regressions) and P2P Loan Vol. on the

concurrent change in crime. In Columns (1) and (2), crime growth does not significantly predict

a bank merger during the same year. In Columns (3) and (4), crime growth also does not

significantly explain concurrent P2P loan volume. Collectively, the evidence suggests that the

reverse causation theory is unlikely.

18

Page 20: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

8 Conclusion

Imperfect credit markets impact households’ welfares. The recent rise in P2P lending markets

have the potential to further complete credit markets and alleviate traditional frictions. However,

the real effects of P2P markets remains unclear. I show that P2P lending impacts social welfare

by moderating crime growth when households’ local credit markets suffer from imperfections.

Using a matched difference-in-difference empirical methodology and mergers between non-

failing banks to identify local credit markets which are likely to be affected by frictions, my tests

indicate that households turn to P2P loans in response to a merger. More importantly, P2P lend-

ing offsets about 25% of the spike in crime growth which follows a merger. I also I find heteroge-

neous effects across types of crimes. Growth in property-related crime and assaults increase after

a bank merger but access to P2P lending moderates the appreciation. Homicides/manslaughters

and weapon law violations are not consistently influenced by mergers or P2P credit.

Overall, this paper contributes to a range of financial economics literatures, including an

emerging branch focusing on technology and financial innovation. I also shed light on the dy-

namics between financial markets and crime. Finally, the findings in this study have important

implications for the ongoing debate about the role of P2P financial markets in the economy.

19

Page 21: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

References

Acharya, V. V. and T. C. Johnson (2010). More insiders, more insider trading: Evidence fromprivate-equity buyouts. Journal of Financial Economics 98 (3), 500–523.

Agarwal, S., L. Chunlin, and N. Souleles (2007). The reaction of consumer spending and debtto tax rebates-evidence from consumer credit data. Journal of Political Economy 115 (6),986–1019.

Akhavein, J. D., A. N. Berger, and D. B. Humphrey (1997). The effects of megamergers onefficiency and prices: Evidence from a bank profit function. Review of Industrial Organiza-tion 12 (1), 95–139.

Andam, K. S., P. J. Ferraro, A. Pfaff, G. A. Sanchez-Azofeifa, and J. A. Robalino (2008).Measuring the effectiveness of protected area networks in reducing deforestation. Proceedingsof the National Academy of Sciences 105 (42), 16089–16094.

Balyuk, T. (2017). Financial innovation and borrowers: Evidence from peer-to-peer lending.Working Paper .

Bazley, W. J. (2017). House prices, household credit, and financial technology. Working Paper .

Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. In The Economic Di-mensions of Crime, pp. 13–68. Springer.

Becker, S. O. and H. K. Hvide (2017). Do entrepreneurs matter? Working Paper .

Berger, A. N., A. Saunders, J. M. Scalise, and G. F. Udell (1998). The effects of bank mergersand acquisitions on small business lending. Journal of Financial Economics 50 (2), 187–229.

Black, S. E. and P. E. Strahan (2002). Entrepreneurship and bank credit availability. TheJournal of Finance 57 (6), 2807–2833.

Campbell, J. Y. (2006). Household finance. Journal of Finance 61, 1553–1604.

Card, D. and G. B. Dahl (2011). Family violence and football: The effect of unexpected emo-tional cues on violent behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1), 103–143.

Cui, L. and R. Walsh (2015). Foreclosure, vacancy and crime. Journal of Urban Economics 87,72–84.

Cullen, J. B. and S. D. Levitt (1999). Crime, urbal flight, and the consequences for cities. TheReview of Economics and Statistics 81 (2), 159–169.

Dills, A. K., J. A. Miron, and G. Summers (2010). What do economists know about crime? InThe Economics of Crime: Lessons for and from Latin America, pp. 269–302. University ofChicago Press.

Duarte, J., S. Siegel, and L. Young (2012). Trust and credit: The role of appearance in peer-to-peer lending. Review of Financial Studies 25 (8), 2455–2484.

Ehrlich, I. (1975). On the relation between education and crime. In Education, income, andhuman behavior, pp. 313–338. NBER.

Erel, I. (2011). The effect of bank mergers on loan prices: Evidence from the United States.The Review of Financial Studies 24 (4), 1068–1101.

Fajnzylber, P., D. Lederman, and N. Loayza (2002). Inequality and violent crime. The Journalof Law and Economics 45 (1), 1–39.

20

Page 22: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Fitch Ratings (2014). Peer to peer lending (global industry overview). Special Report .

Flowers, R. B. (1989). Demographics and criminality: The characteristics of crime in America.Greenwood Press New York.

Freedman, S. and G. Z. Jin (2014). The signaling value of online social networks: Lessons frompeer-to-peer lending. NBER Working Paper (w19820).

Freeman, R. B. (1999). The economics of crime. Handbook of labor economics 3, 3529–3571.

Galak, J., D. Small, and A. T. Stephen (2011). Microfinance decision making: A field study ofprosocial lending. Journal of Marketing Research 48 (SPL), S130–S137.

Garmaise, M. J. and T. J. Moskowitz (2006). Bank mergers and crime: The real and socialeffects of credit market competition. The Journal of Finance 61 (2), 495–538.

Gould, E. D., B. A. Weinberg, and D. B. Mustard (2002). Crime rates and local labor marketopportunities in the United States: 1979–1997. Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (1),45–61.

Grogger, J. (1998). Market wages and youth crime. Journal of Labor Economics 16 (4), 756–791.

Gross, D. B. and N. S. Souleles (2002). Do liquidity constraints and interest rates matter for con-sumer behavior? Evidence from credit card data. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1),149–185.

Guiso, L., P. Sapienza, and L. Zingales (2004). Does local financial development matter? Quar-terly Journal of Economics 119 (3), 929–969.

Guiso, L. and P. Sodini (2013). Household finance: An emerging field. In G. Constantinides,M. Harris, and R. Stulz (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Volume 2B, pp.1397–1531. North-Holland.

Han, S. and G. Li (2011). Household borrowing after personal bankruptcy. Journal of Money,Credit and Banking 43 (2-3), 491–517.

Hauswald, R. and R. Marquez (2003). Information technology and financial services competi-tion. Review of Financial Studies 16 (3), 921–948.

Heckman, J., H. Ichimura, J. Smith, and P. Todd (1998). Characterizing selection bias usingexperimental data. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Heckman, J. J., H. Ichimura, and P. E. Todd (1997). Matching as an econometric evaluationestimator: Evidence from evaluating a job training programme. The Review of EconomicStudies 64 (4), 605–654.

Huck, J. (2015). Taking a beating on the stock market: Crime and stock returns. WorkingPaper .

Iyer, R., A. I. Khwaja, E. F. Luttmer, and K. Shue (2015). Screening peers softly: Inferringthe quality of small borrowers. Management Science.

Kahn, C., G. Pennacchi, and B. Sopranzetti (2005). Bank consolidation and the dynamics ofconsumer loan interest rates. The Journal of Business 78 (1), 99–134.

Karpoff, J. M., D. S. Lee, and G. S. Martin (2008a). The consequences to managers for financialmisrepresentation. Journal of Financial Economics 88 (2), 193–215.

Karpoff, J. M., D. S. Lee, and G. S. Martin (2008b). The cost to firms of cooking the books.Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43 (3), 581–611.

21

Page 23: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Kelly, M. (2000). Inequality and crime. Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (4), 530–539.

Kwast, M. L., M. Starr-McCluer, and J. D. Wolken (1997). Market definition and the analysisof antitrust in banking. The Antitrust Bulletin 42 (4), 973–995.

Levitt, S. D. (2001). Alternative strategies for identifying the link between unemployment andcrime. Journal of Quantitative Criminology 17 (4), 377–390.

Liberini, F., M. Redoano, and E. Proto (2017). Happy voters. Journal of Public Economics 146,41–57.

Lochner, L. (2004). Education, work, and crime: A human capital approach. InternationalEconomic Review 45 (3), 811–843.

Malmendier, U. and G. Tate (2009). Superstar ceos. The Quarterly Journal of Eco-nomics 124 (4), 1593–1638.

Melzer, B. T. (2011). The real costs of credit access: Evidence from the payday lending market.The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1), 517–555.

Morse, A. (2011). Payday lenders: Heroes or villains? Journal of Financial Economics 102 (1),28–44.

Morse, A. (2015). Peer-to-peer crowdfunding: Information and the potential for disruption inconsumer lending. Annual Review of Financial Economics 7, 463–482.

Neyman, J. (1923). On the application of probability theory to agricultural experiments. Essayon principles. Statistical Science (5), 465–472.

Patterson, E. B. (1991). Poverty, income inequality, and community crime rates. Criminol-ogy 29 (4), 755–776.

Petersen, M. A. and R. G. Rajan (1995). The effect of credit market competition on lendingrelationships. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (2), 407–443.

Petersen, M. A. and R. G. Rajan (2002). Does distance still matter? The information revolutionin small business lending. The journal of Finance 57 (6), 2533–2570.

Prager, R. and T. Hannan (1998). Do substantial horizontal mergers generate significant priceeffects? Evidence from the banking industry. The Journal of Industrial Economics 46 (4),433–452.

PricewaterhouseCoopers (2015, February). Peer pressure: How peer-to-peer lending platformsare transforming the consumer lending industry. PwC Consumer Finance.

Ramcharan, R. and C. Crowe (2013). The impact of house prices on consumer credit: Evidencefrom an internet bank. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45 (6), 1085–1115.

Raphael, S. and R. Winter-Ebmer (2001). Identifying the effect of unemployment on crime.The Journal of Law and Economics 44 (1), 259–283.

Ravina, E. (2012). Love and loans: The effect of beauty and personal characteristics in creditmarkets. Available at SSRN 1107307 .

Rubin, D. B. (1974). Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized and nonrandomizedstudies. Journal of Educational Psychology 66 (5), 688.

Sapienza, P. (2002). The effects of banking mergers on loan contracts. The Journal of fi-nance 57 (1), 329–367.

Tufano, P. (2003). Financial innovation. Handbook of the Economics of Finance 1, 307–335.

22

Page 24: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Tufano, P. (2009). Consumer finance. Annu. Rev. Financ. Econ. 1 (1), 227–247.

Wright, R. T. and S. Decker (1994). Burglars on the Job. Northeastern University Press Boston,MA.

Zeume, S. (2017). Bribes and firm value. The Review of Financial Studies 30 (5), 1457–1489.

Zinman, J. (2014). Household debt: Facts, puzzles, theories, and policies. Technical report,National Bureau of Economic Research.

23

Page 25: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics

The table presents summary statistics for the primary data sets used in the study. Panel A reports statistics forcrimes. Panel B presents statistics related to P2P loans. P2P Loan Volume is the natural log of the total loan volume withina zip code area in a year. Number P2P Loans is the natural log of the number of P2P loans within a zip code area in ayear. Panel C presents statistics describing the demographics and economic characteristics for the three-digit zip code areas.Definitions for all variables used in the analysis are included in Appendix I.

Panel A: P2P Credit Statistics

Mean St. Dev. Min. Median Max. N

Total P2P Loan Volume 1,237,613 3,541,534 0.00 57,900 73,347,104 2,383

P2P Loan Vol. 8.26 6.36 0.00 10.97 18.11 2,383

Total Number P2P Loans 82.79 204.49 0.00 6.00 4,309 2,383

Number P2P Loans 2.28 2.19 0.00 1.95 8.37 2,383

Interest Rate 12.84 1.84 0.00 12.978 23.63 2,383

Panel B: Crime Statistics

Mean St. Deviation Min Median Max N

Total Crimes 14,632 22,811 2.00 7,355 254,718 2,383

Total Crime Growth 41.55 2,892 -24,676 -39.00 77,989 2,383

Assault 3,027 5,222 0.00 1,374 58,071 2,383

Assault Growth 2.48 589.20 -5,095 -1.00 11,411 2,383

Bribery 0.55 1.60 0.00 0.00 37.00 2,383

Bribery Growth 0.02 1.49 -31.00 0.00 20.00 2,383

Burglary 1,526 2,719 0.00 657.00 31,054 2,383

Burglary Growth -18.78 439.59 -4,542 -4.00 9,610 2,383

Homicide/Manslaughter 10.40 29.61 0.00 3.00 456.00 2,383

Homicide/Manslaughter Growth 0.26 6.43 -95.00 0.00 100.00 2,383

Theft 953.80 1,410 0.00 476.00 13,042 2,383

Theft Growth 59.15 277.85 -2,479 13.00 6,808 2,383

Weapons Law Violations 116.42 230.29 0.00 44.00 2,888 2,383

Weapons Law Violations Growth 2.38 43.02 -345.00 0.00 864.00 2,383

Number Law Agencies 179.79 172.20 1.00 132.00 1,248 2,383

Panel C: Socio-economic Statistics

Mean St. Dev. Min. Median Max. N

African American 8.43 10.91 0.00 3.87 70.84 2,383

Age 15 - 24 13.64 2.40 9.53 13.18 27.40 2,383

Age 25 - 44 24.54 2.83 17.48 24.42 45.43 2,383

Age 45 - 64 27.70 2.45 19.18 27.17 37.01 2,383

College Educated 28.52 10.27 7.34 27.37 74.30 2,383

House Prices 130.58 21.72 62.26 128.65 238.83 2,383

Income 26,930 5,915 12,961 25,940 64,424 2,383

Male 49.25 1.05 46.23 49.14 55.02 2,383

Population 179.85 244.73 2.81 95.43 2,799 2,383

Unemployment Rate 7.32 2.78 1.27 6.86 21.50 2,383

24

Page 26: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 2: Effects of Bank Mergers on P2P Credit Demand

The table presents estimates from panel regressions of the effects of bank mergers on peer-to-peer credit demand.The dependent variable in the regressions is P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip codeduring the year. The main explanatory variable is Bank Merger, which takes a value of one during the year following a bankmerger, and zero otherwise. Other variables are defined in Appendix I. The estimates for Income have been multiplied by1,000 and the estimates for Population have been multiplied by 10,000. Standard errors are clustered by at the zip codelevel and t-statistics are presented in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels are denoted by *, **, and ***,respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Bank Merger 0.321** 0.315*** 0.302*** 0.286***

(2.34) (4.17) (4.12) (4.60)

African American 0.014*** 0.014*** 0.019***

(3.27) (3.29) (7.74)

Age 15 - 24 0.005 0.007 0.015

(0.17) (0.22) (0.91)

Age 25 - 44 0.019 0.025 0.042***

(0.65) (0.82) (2.63)

Age 45 - 64 -0.046 -0.042 -0.010

(-1.20) (-1.08) (-0.45)

College Educated -0.006 -0.006 -0.009*

(-0.84) (-0.86) (-1.90)

House Prices -0.007*** -0.006** -0.007***

(-2.67) (-2.37) (-5.62)

Income 0.001*** 0.069*** 0.077***

(4.51) (4.30) (8.14)

Male 0.063* 0.058* 0.040*

(1.78) (1.67) (1.80)

Population 0.000*** 0.010*** 0.008***

(5.96) (6.31) (8.04)

Unemployment Rate 0.018 0.016 0.010

(0.88) (0.74) (0.79)

Year FE N N Y Y

Zip Code FE N N N Y

N 2,383 2,383 2,383 2,383

Adj. R-sq. 0.008 0.135 0.688 0.691

25

Page 27: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 3: Effects of P2P Credit on Crime After a Bank Merger: Ordinary Least Squares

The table presents estimates from panel regressions of the effects of peer-to-peer credit on crime growth. The de-pendent variable in the regressions is the growth in total crimes. The main explanatory variable is Bank Merger × P2PLoan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year following a bank merger. The otherindependent variables include Bank Merger, which takes a value of one during the year following a bank merger, and zerootherwise, and P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year. Other variablesare defined in Appendix I. Standard errors are clustered by at the zip code level and t-statistics are presented in parentheses.Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels are denoted by *, **, and ***, respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Bank Merger 187.713 324.360* 434.512* 381.983*

(1.00) (1.70) (1.95) (1.72)

P2P Loan Vol. 25.232** 36.790*** 20.042 28.100

(2.33) (2.78) (1.50) (1.65)

Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol. -50.616** -58.006*** -74.915*** -63.755**

(-2.46) (-2.75) (-2.91) (-2.50)

African American -19.530** -14.853 -21.439

(-2.52) (-1.05) (-1.63)

Age 15 - 24 24.293 147.446 265.053

(1.19) (1.10) (1.23)

Age 25 - 44 39.424 237.689* 347.131

(1.33) (1.84) (1.54)

Age 45 - 64 32.331 189.197 337.363

(0.90) (1.07) (1.13)

College Educated -9.722 -20.108* -10.662

(-1.20) (-1.83) (-0.87)

House Prices 8.496** 6.420 -5.943

(2.51) (0.74) (-0.49)

Income 0.004 0.009 0.001

(0.25) (0.34) (0.05)

Male -49.744 -160.564** -140.692**

(-1.06) (-2.13) (-2.01)

Law Agencies 0.056 9.158 9.216*

(0.08) (1.24) (1.82)

Population -0.207 0.019 0.049

(-0.85) (0.07) (0.20)

Unemployment Rate -7.115 -46.258* -31.659

(-0.27) (-1.77) (-1.08)

ZIP Code FE N N Y Y

Year FE N N N Y

N 2,383 2,383 2,383 2,383

Adj. R-sq. 0.003 0.007 0.097 0.146

26

Page 28: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 4: Matching Results

The table presents results from the matching of lender communities which experienced a bank merger (treatment)with non-lender zip codes which did not experience a merger (control). Communities are matched in the year prior to amerger. Column (1) reports the difference in means between matched treatment and control communities. Column (2)presents t-statistics for difference in means tests between treatment and control communities. Significance at the 10%, 5%,and 1% levels are denoted by *, **, and ***, respectively. Definitions of all variables are presented in Appendix I.

(1) Difference (2) T -statistic N

African American 4.234 1.65 328

Age 15 - 24 -0.934 -1.16 328

Age 25 - 44 3.053 1.44 328

Age 45 - 64 0.087 0.17 328

College Educated -3.119 -1.18 328

House Prices 2.817 1.01 328

Income -30.043 -0.07 328

Male -0.247 -0.76 328

Population 5.010 1.42 328

Unemployment Rate 1.070 1.40 328

Crime Growth 86.525 0.28 328

27

Page 29: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 5: Effects of P2P Credit on Crime After a Bank Merger: Matched Difference-in-Difference

The table presents estimates from matched difference-in-difference regressions of the effects of peer-to-peer credit oncrime growth. The dependent variable in the regressions is Crime Growth, the annual growth in crime. Bank Merger isequal to one if a bank merger occurred within the zip code area in the prior year, and zero otherwise. In columns (1) and(2), the main explanatory variable is Bank Merger × P2P Area, which indicates the effect on crime growth of having accessto P2P credit in the year after a banker merger. Specifically, P2P Area takes a value of one if P2P loans are available inthe zip code, and zero otherwise. In columns (3) and (4), the main explanatory variable is Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol..P2P Loan Vol. is the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year. Columns (2) and (4) reportestimates from regressions which include the control variables used in Table 3. All regressions include year fixed effects andmatched pair-group fixed effects. Pair-group fixed effects are dummy variables specific to each matched set of communities.Standard errors are clustered by at the zip code level and t-statistics are presented in parentheses. Significance at the 10%,5%, and 1% levels are denoted by *, **, and ***, respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Bank Merger 1089.837*** 1037.159*** 1342.575*** 1326.055***

(4.74) (3.82) (4.34) (3.48)

P2P Area 92.127 299.124

(0.44) (1.11)

Bank Merger × P2P Area -642.756** -574.392*

(-2.02) (-1.89)

P2P Loan Vol. 29.772 29.233

(0.94) (0.93)

Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol. -88.646** -81.287**

(-2.18) (-2.07)

Controls N Y N Y

Pair FE Y Y Y Y

Year FE Y Y Y Y

N 644 644 644 644

Adj. R-sq. 0.252 0.285 0.266 0.297

28

Page 30: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 6: Effects of P2P Credit on Crime After a Bank Merger: Crime Types

The table presents regression estimates of the effects of P2P credit on growth in crimes across crime types. Thedependent variables in the regressions are the growth in crimes by type. The main explanatory variable is Bank Merger× P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year following a bank merger.The other independent variables include Bank Merger, which takes a value of one during the year following a bank merger,and zero otherwise, and P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year.The regressions also include the socio-economic controls used in Table 3. Columns (1), (3), and (5) report estimatesfrom OLS regressions which include year and zip code fixed effects. Columns (2), (4), and (6) report estimates fromdifference-in-difference regressions which include year and pair-group fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered by at thezip code level and t-statistics are presented in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels are denoted by *, **,and ***, respectively.

Panel A: Property Crimes

Theft Burglary Bribery

(1) OLS (2) D-i-D (3) OLS (4) D-i-D (5) OLS (6) D-i-D

Bank Merger 79.499** 128.612*** 95.097 318.023*** 0.347* 1.485***

(2.58) (3.71) (1.56) (3.74) (1.86) (3.00)

P2P Loan Vol. 3.447** 4.009 0.958 6.542 -0.006 0.109***

(2.00) (1.43) (0.37) (1.13) (-0.62) (3.64)

Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol. -9.439*** -12.921*** -11.503* -24.203*** -0.025* -0.131***

(-3.14) (-3.58) (-1.77) (-3.46) (-1.79) (-3.31)

Controls Y Y Y Y Y Y

Year FE Y Y Y Y Y Y

Zip Code/Pair FE Y Y Y Y Y Y

N 2,383 644 2,383 644 2,383 644

Adj. R-sq. 0.175 0.202 0.173 0.342 -0.135 0.234

Panel B: Personal and Societal Crimes

Assault Homicide/Manslaughter Weapons Law Violations

(1) OLS (2) D-i-D (3) OLS (4) D-i-D (5) OLS (6) D-i-D

Bank Merger 77.913 254.391*** -0.213 0.564 1.114 -5.794

(0.86) (3.95) (-0.18) (0.42) (0.26) (-1.06)

P2P Loan Vol. 5.525 4.437 0.032 -0.196* 0.409 -1.281***

(1.41) (0.54) (0.73) (-1.80) (1.37) (-2.72)

Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol. -16.859* -17.999** 0.054 0.115 -0.034 1.078

(-1.73) (-2.30) (0.45) (0.87) (-0.06) (1.56)

Controls Y Y Y Y Y Y

Year FE Y Y Y Y Y Y

Zip Code/Pair FE Y Y Y Y Y Y

N 2,383 644 2,383 644 2,383 644

Adj. R-sq. 0.194 0.262 0.074 -0.017 0.132 0.095

29

Page 31: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 7: Contemporaneous Crime Growth’s Impact on Mergers and P2P Volume

The table presents estimates of the effects of contemporaneous crime growth on bank mergers and P2P borrowing.Columns (1) and (2) report marginal effects from probit regressions where the dependent variable is Bank Merger. BankMerger is equal to one if a bank merger occurred within the zip code area during the year, and zero otherwise. Columns (3)and (4) present estimates from OLS panel regressions where the dependent variable is P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of theP2P loan volume within the zip code during the year. The primary independent variable in the regressions is Crime Growth,the yearly growth in total crimes during the year. The estimates for Crime Growth have been multiplied by 10,000. Thecontrol variables used in the regressions are the same as those in Table 3. Standard errors are clustered by at the zip codelevel and z -statistics or t-statistics are presented in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels are denoted by*, **, and ***, respectively.

(1) Bank Merger (2) Bank Merger (3) P2P Loan Vol. (4) P2P Loan Vol.

Crime growth 0.007 0.018 0.260 0.271

(0.26) (0.69) (1.28) (1.34)

Controls N Y N Y

Year FE N N Y Y

Zip Code FE N N Y Y

N 2,383 2,383 2,383 2,383

Pseudo/Adj. R-sq. 0.007 0.036 0.779 0.780

30

Page 32: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table 8: Effects of P2P Credit on House Prices After a Bank Merger - MAY NOT USE

The table presents regression estimates of the effects of P2P credit on growth in crimes across crime types. Thedependent variables in the regressions are the growth in crimes by type. The main explanatory variable is Bank Merger× P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year following a bank merger.The other independent variables include Bank Merger, which takes a value of one during the year following a bank merger,and zero otherwise, and P2P Loan Vol., the natural log of the P2P loan volume within the zip code during the year.The regressions also include the socio-economic controls used in Table 3. Columns (1), (3), and (5) report estimatesfrom OLS regressions which include year and zip code fixed effects. Columns (2), (4), and (6) report estimates fromdifference-in-difference regressions which include year and pair-group fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered by at thezip code level and t-statistics are presented in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels are denoted by *, **,and ***, respectively.

House Prices House Price Growth

(1) OLS (2) D-i-D (3) OLS (4) D-i-D

Bank Merger -1.542 -1.918 -1.471** -0.913

(-1.03) (-0.51) (-2.54) (-1.14)

P2P Loan Vol. 0.103 0.235 -0.009 -0.117

(0.94) (1.05) (-0.21) (-1.63)

Bank Merger × P2P Loan Vol. 0.080 0.028 0.097** 0.192***

(0.66) (0.11) (2.02) (2.65)

Controls Y Y Y Y

Year FE Y Y Y Y

Zip Code/Pair FE Y Y Y Y

N 2383 644 2383 644

Adj. R-sq. 0.866 0.394 0.515 0.488

31

Page 33: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Appendix I: Variable Definitions

This table describes the variables used in the empirical analysis.

Primary Dependent Variables Definition

Crime Growth The growth in the total number of crimes within the three-digit zip code

area during the year. The data are from the National Incident-based Re-

porting System.

Assault Growth The annual growth in aggravated assaults, simple assaults, and intimi-

dation crimes within a three-digit zip code area. The UCR codes are

131, 132, and 133, respectively.

Burglary Growth The yearly growth in burglary and breaking and entering crimes. The

UCR code is 220.

Bribery Growth The annual growth in bribery crimes. The UCR is 510.

Homicide/Manslaughter Growth The yearly increase in murder/non-negligent manslaughter, negligent man-

slaughter, and justifiable homicides. The UCR codes are 91, 92, and 93,

respectively.

Theft Growth The annual growth in the number of pocket-picking, purse-snatching, and

shoplifting crimes. The UCR codes are 231, 232, and 233, respectively.

Weapon Law Violation Growth The yearly growth in weapon law violations which are violations of laws

or ordinances prohibiting the manufacture, sale, purchase, transportation,

possession, concealment, or use of firearms, cutting instruments, explosives,

incendiary devices, or other deadly weapons. The UCR code is 520.

Key Explanatory Variables Definition

Bank Merger An indicator variable which equals one if a bank merger occurred within

the three-digit zip code area during the year, and zero otherwise.

Number P2P Loans The natural log of the number of loans issued within the three-digit zip

code during the year.

P2P Loan Volume The natural log of the total amount of loans issued within the three-digit

zip code during the year.

Control Variables Definition

African American The annual proportion of the three-digit zip code population that is Af-

rican American. Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

Age 15 - 24 The percentage of the three-digit zip code population that is between 15

and 24 years old. Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

Age 25 - 44 The percentage of the three-digit zip code population that is between 25

and 44 years old. Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

Age 45 - 64 The percentage of the three-digit zip code population that is between 45

and 64 years old. Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

College Educated The annual proportion of the three-digit zip code population that has

graduated from college. Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

House Prices The annual three-digit zip code-level All-transactions House Price Index-

es. The data are from the Federal Housing Finance Agency.

Income Median per capita income among households within the three-digit zip

code during the year. Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

32

Page 34: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Variable Definitions – Continued

Control Variables Definition

Male The annual proportion of the three-digit zip code population that is male.

Data are from the U.S. Census Bureau.

Number Law Agencies The number of law enforcement agencies within each zip code area that

participate in NIBRS during the year.

Population The annual, three-digit zip code-level population. The data are from the

U.S. Census Bureau and scaled by 1,000.

Unemployment Rate The annual, three-digit zip code-level unemployment rate. The data are

from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.

33

Page 35: Credit or Crime? The E ects of Online Lending on Crime€¦ · (Garmaise and Moskowitz 2006) but access to alternative lenders, such as payday lenders, can relieve nancial constraints

Table A1: NIBRS Participation

The table presents reports statistics for law enforcement agencies participation in NIBRS during my sample period.Number Zip Codes is the annual mean number of three-digit zip codes, within the corresponding state, during mysample period. Law Agencies is the annual mean number of law enforcement agencies participating in NIBRS withinthe corresponding state. Law Agencies Growth is the yearly average change in the number of law enforcement agenciesparticipating in NIBRS.

State Num. Zip Codes Law Agencies Law Agencies Growth

AL 1.00 12.00 0.00

CO 10.00 175.99 7.66

CT 7.00 127.62 2.29

DE 2.00 336.67 6.00

GA 1.00 12.00 0.00

IA 16.33 122.33 1.16

ID 5.00 243.51 0.09

IL 1.00 12.00 0.00

IN 11.00 59.68 25.68

KS 5.56 372.32 -3.44

KY 12.89 172.84 16.79

LA 9.00 36.36 0.98

MA 10.89 280.16 3.93

ME 4.67 43.05 2.43

MI 16.67 392.23 0.56

MO 3.44 26.16 3.29

MS 1.83 17.73 2.27

MT 5.78 126.37 0.79

ND 5.00 117.42 1.82

NH 8.89 206.25 4.35

OH 19.89 258.99 6.50

OK 7.00 212.90 17.51

OR 6.44 138.97 12.31

PA 6.00 53.67 9.83

RI 4.00 134.67 0.33

SC 8.22 393.73 -10.54

SD 3.00 179.78 4.85

TN 10.22 385.17 0.65

TX 22.78 29.47 0.02

UT 5.00 147.22 1.93

VA 17.78 131.41 0.49

VT 4.00 66.00 0.00

WA 9.33 163.95 25.79

WI 12.67 65.94 7.16

WV 7.11 194.36 -5.61

34


Recommended