+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Customers and Retail GrowthCustomers and Retail Growth Liran Einav, Stanford and NBER Pete Klenow,...

Customers and Retail GrowthCustomers and Retail Growth Liran Einav, Stanford and NBER Pete Klenow,...

Date post: 25-Jan-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
47
Customers and Retail Growth Liran Einav, Stanford and NBER Pete Klenow, Stanford and NBER Jonathan Levin, Stanford and NBER Raviv Murciano-Goroff, Boston University April 2021 University of Houston Macro Seminar 0 / 46
Transcript
  • Customers and Retail Growth

    Liran Einav, Stanford and NBERPete Klenow, Stanford and NBER

    Jonathan Levin, Stanford and NBERRaviv Murciano-Goroff, Boston University

    April 2021

    University of Houston Macro Seminar

    0 / 46

  • What we do

    1 Quantify the role of customer growth in the growth of retail merchants and storesusing Visa, Inc. data in the U.S. from 2016–2019

    2 Trace aggregate retail sales changes to merchants with rapidly-growing vs.rapidly-shrinking numbers of customers

    3 Model firm growth through innovation and customer acquisition to see how thecustomer margin might affect aggregate growth

    1 / 46

  • Some related papers

    ModelsI Arkolakis (2010, 2016)I Perla (2019)

    EvidenceI Foster, Haltiwanger and Syverson (2008, 2016)I Hottman, Redding and Weinstein (2016)I Fitzgerald and Priolo (2018), Fitzgerald, Haller and Yedid-Levi (2019)I Baker, Baught and Sammon (2020)

    BothI Gourio and Rudanko (2014)I Eslava, Tybout, Jinkins, Krizan and Eaton (2015)I Bornstein (2018)I Bernard, Dhyne, Magerman, Manova and Moxnes (2019)I Afrouzi, Drenik and Kim (2020)

    2 / 46

  • Visa data

    Transaction amount and day

    Unique card identifiers (credit and debit)

    Unique merchant identifiers (firms with one or more stores)

    Store industry (3-digit NAICS)

    Store location (address)

    January 2016 through December 2019

    No detail on items bought or prices paid

    Cannot tie multiple card numbers to single households

    3 / 46

  • Visa data confidentiality

    All results have been reviewed to ensure that no confidential information about Visamerchants or cardholders is disclosed.

    Cards are anonymized, and we report no data on individual cards. Cardholder informationis based solely on the card’s transactions.

    We report no data on specific merchants or recent months (nothing from 2020 onward).

    4 / 46

  • Visa summary statistics

    U.S. annual averages from 2007 through 2019

    430 million cards

    32 billion transactions

    24% of all consumption

    60% credit, 40% debit

    5 / 46

  • Visa samples

    All NAICS

    Retail (+ restaurant) NAICS

    Offline retail (card present transactions) – our baseline sample

    “Named” merchants back to 2007 (instead of just 2016–2019)

    6 / 46

  • Decomposing sales

    Sales ≡ Cards · TransactionsCards

    · SalesTransactions

    For merchants, we can further decompose cards:

    Cards ≡ Stores · CardsStores

    7 / 46

  • Sales regressions

    We take logs and regress each RHS variable on the LHS (log of Sales).

    Coefficients decompose sales:

    Across merchants in 2019 (with NAICS fixed effects)

    Across stores within merchants in 2019 (with merchant fixed effects)

    Over time within stores/merchants 2016–2019 (store/merchant and year fixed effects)

    8 / 46

  • Decomposing sales across merchants in 2019

    Each entry is from a single univariate log-log regression on Sales

    Dep. var. → Cards Trans/Cards Sales/Trans # obs.

    All NAICS 0.743 0.037 0.221 2.18m

    Online 0.673 0.073 0.254 606k

    Offline 0.813 0.031 0.159 1.79m

    Offline retail 0.812 0.035 0.166 954k

    The coefficients in each row add up to 1 by construction.

    9 / 46

  • Decomposing sales in offline retail

    Dependent variable→ Cards Trans/Cards Sales/Trans # obs.

    Across merchants in 2019 0.812 0.035 0.166 954k

    Within merchants 2016–2019 0.844 0.101 0.055 3.91m

    Across stores within merchants 2019 0.843 0.079 0.078 2.02m

    Within stores 2016–2019 0.818 0.137 0.045 8.19m

    10 / 46

  • Decomposing 2019 merchant sales growth, by NAICS

    11 / 46

  • Decomposing store growth over time (by store age)

    Cards Trans/Cards Sales/Cards

    Age 1-2 years 0.736 0.080 0.184(0.001) (

  • Ventile Figures

    For each variable, subtract any fixed effects in logs

    Sort observations (merchant-years or store-years) into 20 groups based on their sales

    For each variable, compute its average within each ventile

    Exponentiate the average in each ventile, and normalize the lowest ventile to 1

    13 / 46

  • Across merchants in 2019

    14 / 46

  • Within merchants over time, 2016–2019

    15 / 46

  • Stores vs. cards per store across merchants in 2019

    16 / 46

  • Stores vs. cards per store over time within merchants, 2016–2019

    17 / 46

  • Across stores within merchants in 2019

    18 / 46

  • Within stores over time, 2016–2019

    19 / 46

  • Growth in spending per returning customer, merchants 2016–2019

    20 / 46

  • Merchant contributions to aggregate sales changes, 2016–2019

    21 / 46

  • Cumulative merchant contributions, 2016–2019

    22 / 46

  • Merchant contributions to sales changes over 2016–2019, by NAICS

    23 / 46

  • The importance of customers in the tails

    A merchant’s sales changes can be decomposed as:

    ∆Sit ≡ ∆Nit · S/N it + ∆(S/N)it ·N it

    whereN it ≡

    Nit +Ni,t−12

    and

    S/N it ≡Sit/Nit + Si,t−1/Ni,t−1

    2

    Use this to gauge role of customers for sales growth of top and bottom firms

    24 / 46

  • Customers vs. sales/customer and firm sales changes, 2016–2019

    25 / 46

  • Visa patterns and a model

    1 The number of customers drive Visa merchant growth

    2 Rapid-growers and shrinkers dominate aggregate Visa sales changes

    Motivates a model with these features:

    1 Heterogeneous firm innovation

    2 The number of customers responds strongly to innovation

    26 / 46

  • Consumer preferences

    A unit mass of customers have the following preferences over consumption:

    U =

    ∞∑t=0

    βtC

    1−1/σt

    1− 1/σ

    Consumption is an aggregate of varieties:

    Ct =

    (∫ 10nit (qitcit)

    θ−1θ di

    ) θθ−1

    .

    Note the fixed unit mass of varieties i ∈ [0, 1], with variety i having quality qit.nit ∈ [0, 1] is the probability that a consumer has the option to purchase variety i.cit is the quantity of variety i purchased by each consumer with access to i.

    27 / 46

  • Customer demand and the aggregate price index

    Per customer demand conditional on access to variety i:

    cit =

    (pitPt

    )−θqθ−1it Ct

    Resulting ideal price index

    Pt ≡(∫ 1

    0nit

    (pitqit

    )1−θdi

    ) 11−θ

    .

    Total demand facing firm j, summed across its customers:

    yit = nit · cit

    28 / 46

  • Production, customer acquisition, and static profit maximization

    Each firm uses production labor lit to produce its single variety:

    yit = lit

    It uses marketing labor mit to reach fraction nit of customers:

    nit =

    φ· mitMt

    )1/γwhere γ > 1 and Mt ≡

    ∫ 10mitdi.

    Normalizing the nominal wage to 1, the firm’s static profit maximization problem is:

    maxpit,mit

    (pit − 1) yit −mit

    29 / 46

  • Firm pricing and relative quality

    Through monopolistic competition, firms choose pricing:

    pit =θ

    θ − 1 ≡ µ

    Aggregate quality and relative quality:

    Qt ≡(∫ 1

    0q

    Γ(θ−1)it di

    ) 1Γ(θ−1)

    where zit ≡qitQt

    and Γ ≡ γγ − 1

    30 / 46

  • Customers and variable profits

    nit = min

    (γzΓ(θ−1)

    φ

    ) 1γ

    , 1

    πit =z

    Γ(θ−1)it

    Γ(θ − 1) · Lt

    31 / 46

  • Innovation

    A firm with absolute quality qit and relative quality zit that hires research labor sit sees itsquality follow a controlled binomial process with probability xit ∈ [0, 1]:

    qit+1 =

    {qite

    ∆ w/ prob. xitqit w/ prob. 1− xit

    and sit = λ log(

    1

    1− xit

    )zζit

    ∆, λ and ζ are all strictly positive

    32 / 46

  • Firm value and growth

    A firm’s value function is given by:

    Vt (z) = πt (z) + maxx∈[0,1]

    {R−1t

    [xVt+1

    (ze∆−gt

    )+ (1− x)Vt+1

    (ze−gt

    )]− st (z, x)

    }

    The growth rate of this economy is:

    1 + gt =

    (∫x(z)zΓ(θ−1)

    (e∆Γ(θ−1) − 1

    )dF (z) + 1

    ) 1Γ(θ−1)

    33 / 46

  • Recap on firm decisions

    In each period, a firm makes the following ordered decisions:

    1. Hire marketing labor m(z) to access customers n(z)

    2. Hire production labor l(z) to sell to their customers

    3. Hire research labor to achieve a probability of research success x(z) ∈ [0, 1]

    34 / 46

  • Labor market clearing

    Lt =

    ∫lt (z) dFt (z)

    Mt =

    ∫mt (z) dFt (z)

    St =

    ∫st (z) dFt (z)

    Lt +Mt + St = 1

    35 / 46

  • Aggregates

    Lt =γ (θ − 1) (1− St)γ (θ − 1) + 1

    Mt =1− St

    γ (θ − 1) + 1

    Ct = (γ/φ)1

    γ(θ−1) · Lt ·Qt

    36 / 46

  • Parameter values

    Symbol Parameter Value Target

    σ IES 0.5 Hall (2009)

    θ CES between varieties 3 Aghion et al. (2019)

    β Discount factor 0.992 Farhi and Gourio (2018)

    φ Scale of marketing costs 3.57 ·1037 Largest firms have n = 0.5γ Markeing cost elasticity 1.25 Visa sales decomposition

    ∆ Quality step size 0.06 Twice average growth

    λ Linear research cost 0.094 2.9% BLS growth rate

    ζ Convex research cost 10.04 Top 1% contribution in Visa

    37 / 46

  • Intensive and extensive margin elasticities

    The elasticity of sales with respect to quality is the sum of the elasticity of customers andthe elasticity of spending per customer with respect to quality:

    ξy,q = ξn,q + ξc,q =θ − 1γ − 1 + θ − 1

    With our calibration (γ = 1.25 and θ = 3), the customer share of the sales elasticity is80%, which matches our finding in the Visa data.

    38 / 46

  • Steady state values of endogenous variables

    Symbol Variable Baseline No customers

    g Growth rate 2.90% 3.22%

    r Interest rate 6.70% 7.38%

    L Production labor 67.9% 93.3%

    M Marketing labor 27.2% 0.0%

    S Research labor 4.9% 6.7%

    39 / 46

  • Törnqvist growth decomposition

    Baseline No customers

    True growth rate 2.90% 3.22%

    Approximated growth rate 2.95% 3.26%

    First order term 2.49% 3.17%

    Second order term 0.46% 0.09%

    40 / 46

  • Customers and firm quality

    1000 2000 3000 4000 5000z

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    n

    Baseline

    No customers

    41 / 46

  • Customers and firm value

    −1.0 −0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0log(z)

    −10

    −5

    0

    5

    10

    log(V)

    Baseline

    No customers

    42 / 46

  • Customers and firm innovation

    0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0z

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    x

    Baseline

    No customers

    43 / 46

  • The distribution of sales

    1 2 3 4z

    0.00

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    0.06

    f (y)

    Baseline

    No customers

    44 / 46

  • Firm contributions to aggregate sales changes

    B1 B5 B10 B25 T25 T10 T5 T1Firms grouped by sales changes

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    %Baseline

    No customers

    45 / 46

  • Conclusion

    We looked at Visa debit and credit card data on transactions at all offline retailmerchants from 2016–2019

    We documented a dominant role for the customer extensive margin in the dispersionof sales and sales growth across merchants

    In a simple growth model, the customer margin stimulates innovation and marketingby large firms but actually reduces overall innovation and growth

    46 / 46


Recommended