+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Date post: 10-Feb-2017
Category:
Upload: duongkiet
View: 220 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
25
Discussion Paper No. 0142 Adelaide University Adelaide 5005 Australia Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for Labour-intensive Goods Matthias Busse December 2000
Transcript
Page 1: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Discussion Paper No. 0142

Adelaide University

Adelaide 5005 Australia

Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for Labour-intensive

Goods

Matthias Busse

December 2000

Page 2: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC STUDIES

The Centre was established in 1989 by the Economics Department of the Adelaide University to strengthen teaching and research in the field of international economics and closely related disciplines. Its specific objectives are:

• to promote individual and group research by scholars within and outside the Adelaide University

• to strengthen undergraduate and post-graduate education in this field

• to provide shorter training programs in Australia and elsewhere

• to conduct seminars, workshops and conferences for academics and for the wider community

• to publish and promote research results

• to provide specialised consulting services

• to improve public understanding of international economic issues, especially among policy makers and shapers

Both theoretical and empirical, policy-oriented studies are emphasised, with a particular focus on developments within, or of relevance to, the Asia-Pacific region. The Centre’s Director is Professor Kym Anderson ([email protected]) and Deputy Director is Dr Randy Stringer ([email protected]) Further details and a list of publications are available from: Executive Assistant CIES School of Economics Adelaide University SA 5005 AUSTRALIA Telephone: (+61 8) 8303 5672 Facsimile: (+61 8) 8223 1460 Email: [email protected] Most publications can be downloaded from our Home page: http://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/ ISSN 1444-4534 series, electronic publication

Page 3: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

CIES DISCUSSION PAPER 0142

Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for Labour-intensive Goods

Matthias Busse

Centre for International Economic Studies and School of Economics University of Adelaide

[email protected]

November 2001

Page 4: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage?

Evidence for Labour-intensive Goods

Matthias Busse

November 2001

Abstract

This paper focuses on the question of whether labour standards can affect comparative

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods, and thereby influence trade flows. Using a

Heckscher-Ohlin framework, the effects of low labour standards depend on the type of

standard: Forced and child labour lead to an increase in the endowment of unskilled labour,

and hence improve comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods; the opposite

occurs with discrimination against females; and with basic trade union rights, the outcome is

ambiguous. The empirical results confirm the theoretical outcome, but also show that weaker

union rights are associated with a stronger comparative advantage.

JEL Classification: F1, F14

Key Words: Comparative Advantage, Trade, Labour Standards

Contact: Matthias Busse Hamburg Institute of International Economics Hamburg, Germany Email: [email protected]

Page 5: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

I. Introduction

The debate over whether labour standards should be imposed in international trade has come

to the forefront of the international trade policy agenda in recent years. It has attracted not

only interest from economists, governments and trade policy agencies, but also a large public

audience, including humanitarian organisations, partly due to concerns about the increasing

globalisation of the world economy. Unlike the more recent disputes about environmental

standards, the discussion about labour standards has been on and off the policy agenda since

the late nineteenth century. In 1890, for example, the United States banned the entry of

foreign goods manufactured by convict labour. Seven years later, the British Parliament

prohibited imports of goods produced in “any foreign prison, gaol, house of correction or

penitentiary” (quoted in Charnovitz, 1987, pp. 569-70).

More recently, during the Uruguay Round of GATT talks, the United States and France tried

unsuccessfully to put labour standards on the agenda. The next attempts, at the WTO

conferences in Singapore in 1996 and in Seattle in 1999, again failed. Unlike its predecessor,

the current Bush administration seems to have lost interest in international labour standards.

As a consequence, the United States, previously one of the main supporters of labour

standards within the framework of the WTO, is not driving the matter forward as before.

The European Union, on the other hand, is still calling for discussion of links between trade

and fundamental workers' rights and brought the issue forward at the WTO conference in

Doha in November 2001. This attempt was rejected by developing countries, which fear that

rich nations will seek to justify protectionist measures against foreign competition by alleging

their rivals abuse workers' rights. It has been agreed that the issue of labour standards remain

in the sphere of influence of the International Labour Organisation (ILO). The WTO has been

asked, however, to “take note of work under way in the ILO on the social dimension of

globalisation” (WTO, 2001) and will hold talks on an expert level about labour standards.

Since trade unions, human right activists, and some governments of developed (high standard)

countries show an ongoing interest in the matter, it is highly likely that labour standards will

appear on the agenda of future international trade talks again and remain an important issue of

international trade policy.

Page 6: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

The international discussion of the relationship between labour standards and international

trade consists basically of two issues: (1) Whether countries can improve their

competitiveness, and therefore increase production and exports of labour-intensive goods with

lower labour standards, and (2) whether there might be, partly as a result of the first issue,

“social dumping” and a “race to the bottom” on such standards. To ensure a “level playing

field”, advocates of labour standards then go on to favour effective import barriers against

products imported from countries with low labour standards, preferably within the WTO.

This paper concentrates on the first issue and focuses on the question of whether countries can

derive comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods from low labour standards,

and thereby influence trade flows. Since the impact of labour standards is likely to be felt

most strongly in unskilled-labour-intensive goods, only these goods are considered in the

analysis. Apart from discussing the underlying theoretical aspects, the paper consists of an

empirical test of the influence of labour standards on exports of unskilled-labour-intensive

goods.

Accordingly, the paper is structured as follows: After a brief introduction to different concepts

of labour standards in the next section, previous empirical work is reviewed in Section III.

Sections IV and V consider the trade and welfare effects of labour standards and changes in

factor endowments from a theoretical point of view. Section VI presents the estimation results

and finally, some concluding remarks as well as a summary of the major results are found in

Section VII.

II. Definition and Scope of Labour Standards

Partly as a result of the lack of agreement on a definition or a common list of labour

standards, the discussion about any effects on trade and comparative advantage has become

increasingly confusing. Obviously, labour standards vary from country to country, depending

on the income level as well as cultural, political, and social preferences and conditions

(Brown et al., 1998). As the choice of labour standards will definitely influence empirical

results, it is necessary to outline carefully the set of labour standards used. For the purposes of

analysing the effects on comparative advantage and trade, and for more clarity, the distinction

between “core” and other labour standards is crucial. Core (or fundamental) labour standards

Page 7: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

focus on important human rights and include basic union rights, freedom from forced labour,

equal opportunity in employment, and the abolition of child labour.

Other standards, like minimum wages or safety and health standards in the workplace, are

related to actual labour market and working conditions. These other labour standards,

sometimes called “acceptable conditions of work”, are highly controversial, whereas core

labour standards receive almost universal acceptance. This can be seen from the fact that more

than 130 countries have ratified three United Nations acts on core labour standards

(UN, 2001).1

Apart from the United Nations acts, the ILO conventions on core labour standards come close

to an internationally agreed set of standards. The ILO was created in 1919 primarily for the

purpose of adopting international standards to cope with the problem of labour conditions

involving "injustice, hardship and privation" (ILO, 2001a). Even though the ILO standard

setting mandate was broadened in 1944 to include more general, but related, social policy and

human and civil rights matters, core labour standards remained one of the most important

issues. International labour standards are essentially expressions of international tripartite

agreement on these matters. The tripartite representatives consist of workers’ and employers’

organisations and governments. Since its foundation, the ILO has adopted more than 180

conventions, which are international treaties subject to ratification by ILO member states, and

more than 190 recommendations, which are purely advisory and non-binding instruments. As

the ILO does not have any enforcement power, it relies on voluntary compliance and monitors

the carrying out of the ratified conventions.

There are eight ILO conventions on core labour standards. These include two conventions,

each on union rights, forced labour, child labour, and discrimination (see Table 1). The total

number of ratifications varies, but they are in the range of 140 to 160, but for those two on

child labour. Even though there is widespread agreement on the principles of these

conventions, only 63 countries have ratified all eight. In some cases, the exact wording or the

interpretation of these conventions might be incompatible with national laws or regulations

(OECD, 1996). Partly for this reason, the United States, for example, has ratified only two

conventions on core labour standards. On the other hand, the ratification of a particular 1 The three United Nations acts are (1) the Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, (2) the Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, and (3) the Convention on the Rights of the Child; see UN (2001) for details.

Page 8: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

convention is not necessarily a good indicator for enforcement of that convention. Rwanda,

for instance, has ratified all eight conventions, but few would argue that it has higher labour

standards than the United States.

Table 1: Ratification of ILO Fundamental Labour Standards (as of November 2001)

ILO Convention Number of countries having

ratified the convention

Union Rights (1) Freedom of Association and Protection of the Right to Organise Convention,

1948 (No. 87)

138 (2) Right to Organise and Collective Bargaining Convention, 1949 (No. 98)

150

Forced Labour (3) Forced Labour Convention, 1930 (No. 29)

159

(4) Abolition of Forced Labour Convention, 1957 (No. 105)

157

Child Labour (5) Minimum Age Convention, 1973 (No. 138)

115

(6) Worst Forms of Child Labour Convention, 1999 (No. 182)

106

Discrimination (7) Equal Remuneration Convention, 1951 (No. 100)

154

(8) Discrimination (Employment and Occupation) Convention, 1958 (No. 111) 152

Source: ILO (2001b).

III. Previous Studies of Comparative Advantage, Trade and Labour Standards

Several authors have empirically explored the relationship between the observance of certain

labour standards and comparative advantage and/or export performance.2 Aggarwal (1995)

examined growth rates of imports in the United States and the observed adherence to core

labour standards of ten developing countries. She found no positive correlation between the

two variables. Rather the opposite seems to occur, as she noted that it is common in

developing countries for labour standards to be higher in export-oriented sectors than in less

export-oriented or non-traded sectors. In addition, developing countries with higher labour

standards do not have lower import-penetration rates in the United States than countries with

lower standards.

2 See OECD (2000) and Brown (2000) for more thorough reviews. Apart from trade and comparative advantage, most of the studies mentioned in this section have also examined the interaction between labour standards and other economic variables like wages or foreign direct investment. For the purpose of this paper, only their results with respect to trade and comparative advantage are reported.

Page 9: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

The OECD (1996) focused on the relationship between two core labour standards, freedom of

association and collective bargaining rights, and measures of export performance, both in the

aggregate and for labour-intensive goods.3 They examined 78 OECD and non-OECD

countries, but found no evidence of a correlation between the observance of these union rights

and overall export performance. Furthermore, US imports of labour-intensive textile products,

where intensive competition from lower-labour-standard developing countries could be

expected, indicate that high standard countries have a large share of the US market. They

summarised their findings by concluding that the degree of observance of labour standards

has little effect on exports or patterns of specialization.

Van Beers (1998) suggested a possible negative relationship between the level of labour

standards and trade performance. Focusing on 18 OECD countries and other labour standards,

he used a combined index of standards that includes employment protection rights, fixed term

contracts, working time, minimum wages, and employees’ representation rights. He found

that higher (stricter) labour standards are negatively associated with exports of labour and

capital-intensive commodities produced with relatively more high-skilled labour.

In another study, Mah (1997) regressed export shares of GDP on the ratification of core ILO

conventions for 45 developing countries. He found that export shares are negatively

correlated with union rights like freedom of association and collective bargaining rights, but

also non-discrimination in employment and abolition of forced labour.

In his empirical work on comparative advantage and labour standards, Rodrik (1996) included

84 countries in his study and focused on the ratio of textile and clothing exports to total

exports (excluding fuels). He used control variables like the population-land ratio for the

relative labour endowment and average years of schooling for human capital as the natural

determinants of comparative advantage. As measures for the level of labour standards, he

used the number of ratifications of ILO conventions, a democracy indicator, incidence of

child labour, statutory hours worked, days of paid annual leave, and union density. Although

the variables for labour standards have the expected sign, he did not find any statistically

significant relationship. The statutory hours worked (in manufacturing) is the only exception. 3 The OECD measured export performance as the change in percentage of the change of a country’s exports in world markets over the period 1980-1990 (OECD, 1996, p. 93).

Page 10: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

A longer working week is positively associated with an improved comparative advantage in

textiles and clothing.

To improve the overall fit of the equation, Rodrik then divided his sample into poor and rich

countries, setting the cut-off point at US$ 6,000 per capita GDP in 1985. By concentrating on

poor countries, not only was the fit of the benchmark equation increased (from R2 = 0.10 to

R2 = 0.22), but also the child labour variable became statistically significant in some of his

regressions. A lack of child labour legislation or a weaker enforcement of the existing

legislation would lead to a higher comparative advantage in textiles and clothing.

IV. Trade and Welfare Effects

Since this paper concentrates on the effects of core labour standards on comparative

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods, the choice of a Heckscher-Ohlin framework as

an appropriate model is relatively straightforward. Because it is based on different relative

factor endowments, this standard trade model has particular strengths in analysing changes in

these endowments. There are, of course, other factors that influence comparative advantage,

such as differences in technologies or consumer preferences. Yet, as will be demonstrated

below, core labour standards could particularly change relative factor endowments of a

particular country. Furthermore, the Heckscher-Ohlin model allows differentiating between

skilled and unskilled labour as the factors of production.4 This enables us to focus on

comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods.

In its basic version, the Heckscher-Ohlin model comprises two goods (X, Y), two factors

(skilled, unskilled labour) and two countries (H, F). Production technologies are assumed to

be identical with constant returns to scale in both countries, preferences are identical and

homogeneous, and there are no market distortions. The defining characteristic of the model is

a difference in relative factor endowments. Country H (home) has a proportionally larger

unskilled labour force than country F (foreign). Good X (e.g. toys) is assumed to be unskilled-

labour-intensive and good Y (e.g. software) is skilled labour-intensive. Each country produces

both goods by using both factors. 4 This approach to modelling inter-industry trade or “North-South” trade has been increasingly used: for example, see Krugman (1995) and Golub (1997).

Page 11: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Suppose both countries trade with each other and fully respect labour standards in the initial

situation.5 In Figure 1a, the production possibility frontier PPF1 shows the maximum outputs

of the two goods if all resources of country H are used efficiently (PPF3 for country F in

Figure 1b). At an equilibrium price ratio P = PX/PY, where PX and PY indicate the prices for

goods X and Y, respectively, country H will produce at point Q1, consume at C1, reaching the

highest possible indifference curve U1. Since the home country (H) is assumed to be

unskilled-labour abundant, it will export good X and import good Y. The equivalent

production and consumption points for the foreign country (F) are Q4 and C4, respectively.

Now consider a decline in labour standards in country H only, using, say, unskilled prison

labour. The number of additional workers will increase the endowment of unskilled labour in

H and the PPF shifts outwards to PPF2, with a bias towards the unskilled-labour-intensive

good X.6 Since the production of X increases relative to that of Y, country H improves its

comparative advantage in the production of X. The enhanced (export) supply of X causes PX

and hence P to fall to P’, which represents a decline in the terms of trade of the home country.

The economy reaches a new equilibrium production point at Q3 (or Q2 if we had assumed a

small open economy at unchanged world market prices P), a new consumption point C3 (C2),

and a higher welfare level U3 (U2).7 Furthermore, exports of X and imports of Y increased.

Country F, on the other hand, will see only a change in the relative price level, that is, an

improvement in its terms of trade. This makes country F better off, and, hence, allows it to

reach a higher welfare level (U5). Note, however, that the fall in the production of good X is

caused by the fall in the price of the unskilled-labour-intensive good (PX). This will make its

production less profitable compared to that of good Y. Due to the decline in labour standards

in country H, the foreign country will shift its resources towards the production of Y.

5 The analysis of labour standards presented here is similar to that of Brown et al. (1996). 6 Modelling the impact of labour standards as the accumulation of production factors is merely an application of the techniques from the literature started by Rybczynski (1955). 7 Note that the deterioration in the terms of trade could offset the welfare gains from the growth in the unskilled labour force, thereby making the economy worse off. This phenomenon is called immiserizing growth (Bhagwati, 1958).

Page 12: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Figure 1: Trade and Welfare Effects of Labour Standards

(a) Country H

Y C2 U2 C3 PPF2 C1 U3 PPF1 U1

Q3 Q1 Q2 P’ P P X

(b) Country F Y PPF3 Q5 Q4 C5 C4 P’ U5 P U4 X

An interesting result is the observance of an increase in consumption, trade, and welfare

levels in both countries due to declining labour standards in the home country.8 Obviously,

this result is due to the set-up of the model, as the use of prison labour will increase

8 Again, this result holds only if the possibility of immiserizing growth in country H is neglected.

Page 13: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

production possibilities. Labour standards themselves are not included in the utility function

(OECD, 1996). Besides the fact that such an approach would complicate the analysis to a

large extent, it is also beyond the main focus of this paper, which is the effects on trade and

comparative advantage, and therefore not included in the analysis.

V. Labour Standards and Changes in Factor Endowments

In the previous section, the effects of prison labour, as an example of forced labour and

declining labour standards, have been considered. As has been shown, prison labour increases

the total factor endowment of unskilled labour, and the country improves its comparative

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods. But what about the other core labour

standards? Similar to forced labour, a lowering of the minimum age for employment, that is

the use of (more) child labour, will also increase the unskilled labour endowment. Since the

employment of children accounts for over ten per cent of the workforce in some developing

countries, the quantitative effect of child labour can be quite substantial (Shelbourne, 2001).

Besides the labour-augmenting effect, an increase in use of child labour is detrimental to

development, since it is likely that future generations of workers are less skilled and hence

less productive.9 These effects, however, are not considered in this paper.

Unlike forced and child labour, discrimination against, say, females in employment can be

expected to reduce the labour endowment. Two common types of employment discrimination

are restrictions on female work in certain sectors of the economy, like in some Islamic

countries, and lower salaries relative to male workers, even if females are as productive. Both

types will reduce the labour endowment, as females either are forced to or will voluntarily

reduce their labour supply. Whether discrimination against females will affect the relative

endowment of unskilled labour is less clear. There is, however, evidence that the educational

attainment level of females in developing countries is lower than that of males (UNDP,

2000).10 An increase in the discrimination against females will then lead, at least in the short

run, to a lower relative endowment of unskilled labour.

9 The empirical evidence is contradictory on this point. There are studies that suggest the opposite outcome. For example, Patrinos and Psacharopoulos (1997) found that child labour in Peru ensures school enrolment of children from some families. In addition, a few hours of work a day and schooling seemed rather to be complementary than mutually exclusive. 10 This evidence might be, of course, due to discrimination against females in schooling and training.

Page 14: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Finally, basic trade union rights like freedom of association and collective bargaining have

ambiguous effects on labour endowments. The outcome depends on the motives and

intentions of trade unions and can be summarised in three points.11 First, unions might be in a

better position to protect basic workers rights and to ensure that workers are not exploited. In

these cases, a violation of basic union rights can be associated with a similar outcome to the

three above-mentioned labour standards, that is, either a rise or fall in the endowment of

unskilled labour.

Second, unions might introduce further distortions in the labour market. They could try to

raise wages for unionised workers above market levels. As firms are likely to hire fewer

workers at higher wage rates, this policy option would lead to a fall in the number of

employed workers.12 And third, there might be productivity gains due to labour union

activities, since workers may be more motivated and hence productive (OECD, 2000). This

effect, which could be enhanced if union activity leads to better social relationship between

workers and employers, would shift the PPF outwards, but not necessarily with a bias towards

the production of the unskilled-labour-intensive good. Depending on the relative size of these

three effects, the endowment of unskilled labour could either rise or fall.

To sum up, from a theoretical point of view, the effects of a decline in labour standards

depend on the type of labour standard. Forced and child labour would lead to a increase in the

endowment of unskilled labour, and hence improve comparative advantage in unskilled-

labour-intensive goods, the opposite would occur with discrimination against females, and

with basic trade union rights the outcome is ambiguous.

VI. Empirical Evidence

Before presenting the empirical results, let us first have a look at the data used. Comparative

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods is measured as the ratio of unskilled-labour-

11 See Booth (1995) for a more thorough survey on the effects of trade unions. 12 This effect will occur only if there are no further distortions like, say, a monopsony in the labour market. With monopsony power of a firm, a higher wage rate would lead to higher employment levels. See Maskus (1997) and Martin and Markus (2001) for a discussion of the effects with different labour market distortions.

Page 15: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

intensive exports to total exports of goods (the variable is labelled EXLAB98).13 The focus is

on manufactured goods only. But what are unskilled-labour-intensive manufactured goods?

The classification is based on two determinants: technology and labour intensity. Among all

manufacturing industries, included in the analysis are those commodities that involve both

low technology and high labour intensity. Data on technology intensity was obtained from the

OECD (2001) Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard,14 whereas labour intensity is

based on value added per worker.15 Included in the analysis are exports of commodity

categories such as textiles, clothing, footwear, and toys (see Appendix A for a complete list).

Comparative advantage is determined foremost by relative factor endowments. Consequently,

for relative labour endowments two control variables are used: first, the total labour force

divided by the land area (LABDENS), which is expected to be positively associated with

EXLAB98; and, second, the educational attainment index (EDU) of the United Nations

Development Programme, which is based on average years of schooling in the above-25

population and the illiteracy rate. This index is used as a proxy for the skill level of the labour

force and is expected to be negatively associated with EXLAB98.16

As a measure of core labour standards, five indicators are used:

(1) LABFEM for the degree of discrimination against women in working life, representing

the female labour force activity rate, which is the percentage of female population ages

15-64 that are working.17

(2) CHILD as an indicator for the prevalence of child labour, defined as the percentage of

children ages 10-14 who are not working.18 13 Section III showed the theoretical effects, using a 2x2x2 Heckscher-Ohlin model. The graphical representation of the model has been limited to this simple case to show the basic trade and welfare effects. The model can be extended to, say, four goods, including two export and two import goods. Comparative advantage can then be interpreted in terms of export structure, or the ratio of unskilled labour-intensive exports to total exports. 14 According to the OECD (2001), the three determinants of technology intensity are the ratio of research and development (R&D) expenditures to value added, R&D expenditures divided by production and R&D expenditures plus technology embodied in intermediate and investment goods divided by production. 15 The commodity classification of labour-intensive goods is based on the work of Tyres at al. (1987). 16 See Appendix B for data sources of all variables. Included in the analysis were all 83 countries reporting export data for the considered commodity categories but Singapore, which is a city-state and has an unusually high labour force-to-land ratio. 17 Due to differences in the male labour force activity rate across countries, one might argue that variances in this indicator do not represent discrimination against females in all cases. However, neither the sign nor the significance of the estimation results, represented below, change if differences between the two activity rates are used instead.

Page 16: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

(3) CIVIL, the civil liberties indicator of the Freedom House (2000) for forced labour. This

non-governmental organisation monitors fundamental democratic and human rights in all

countries. Apart from political rights, it rates civil liberties separately on a scale from 1 to

7, with 1 representing the least free and 7 the most free.19 Even though the Freedom

House checklist for civil liberties covers a large range of issues, it also deals with forced

labour. However, we have to keep in mind that there are other labour standards like union

rights included in the checklist as well, and the interpretation of this indicator is less

straightforward.

(4) UNION for basic union rights like freedom of association and collective bargaining. This

is the OECD (1996, 2000) indicator for union rights. Based on reports from international

trade union organisations and the ILO, the OECD graded countries on a scale from

1 (union rights practically non-existent) to 4 (union rights guaranteed in law and

practice).20

(5) CONVEN for the number of ratifications of the eight ILO conventions on core labour

standards.

In Table 2, the estimation results for six regressions are reported, based on data for the year

1998. In the benchmark regression, reported in the first column, the two explanatory variables

having the expected signs are both statistically significant at the 1 per cent level. In the

remaining columns, the coefficients for the five indicators for labour standards are reported.

LABFEM, CHILD and CIVIL have all the expected signs and are statistically significant at

the 1 per cent or 5 per cent level.21 A higher level of discrimination against females, that is, a

decline in labour standards, is associated with a declining endowment of unskilled labour and,

hence, a weaker comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods.

18 Note that this indicator measures the non-prevalence of child labour. To simplify the interpretation of the results, a higher number in any of the five indicators always implies a higher labour standard. 19 Again, the scale has been reversed. 20 The scale from 1 to 4 has been defined exactly opposite to that of the OECD to ensure an easier interpretation of the following results 21 Unfortunately, there is evidence of multicollinearity between the educational attainment index EDU and CHILD, CIVIL and UNION. Since LABDENS has a stronger relative influence on EXLAB98 than EDU and, in one of the regressions, CHILD is likely to be a substitute for EDU, the educational attainment index in these three regressions has been omitted.

Page 17: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

The opposite occurs for child and forced labour: Lower standards lead to an increase in the

labour force and a stronger comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods. For

example, a decline in the number of children that are not working (that is, an increase in child

labour) by one percentage point, would lead to a rise in the ratio of unskilled-labour-intensive

exports to total exports by 0.43 percentage points.

Table 2: Comparative Advantage and Core Labour Standards Independent Variables

Dependent Variable: EXLAB98

Constant 0.455*** (0.092)

0.432*** (0.090)

0.502** (0.198)

0.244*** (0.056)

0.250*** (0.058)

0.411*** (0.104)

LABDENS 0.843*** (0.186)

0.709*** (0.188)

0.906*** (0.199)

1.048*** (0.192)

1.051*** (0.183)

0.849*** (0.186)

EDU -0.428*** (0.104)

-0.544*** (0.112)

-0.443*** (0.106)

LABFEM 0.355** (0.145)

CHILD -0.429** (0.203)

CIVIL -0.031*** (0.010)

UNION -0.058*** (0.017)

CONVEN 0.008 (0.009)

R2 0.36 0.41 0.27 0.31 0.46 0.37 N 82 82 82 82 56 82

Notes: See Appendix B for data sources; standard errors, which have been checked for heteroskedasticity, are reported in parentheses; *** significant at 1% level; ** significant at 5% level; * significant at 10% level.

Whereas the effects of declining basic union rights are ambiguous on theoretical grounds, the

sign for UNION is negative and the parameter is highly significant at the 1 per cent level.

Hence, in the case of the 82 countries included in the analysis, weaker union rights are

associated with an improving comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods.

The number of ratifications of the fundamental eight ILO conventions appears not to

significantly affect comparative advantage in exports of labour-intensive goods. CONVEN is

just above zero and not statistically significant. In addition, as can be seen from Table 3, the

number of ratifications is a poor measure of the level of labour standards. The partial

correlations between the number of ratifications for each of the four core labour standards

(CONDISC for discrimination and the number of ratifications of Conventions No. 100 and

Page 18: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

No. 111, CONCHILD for child labour (No. 138 and No. 182), CONFORCE for forced labour

(No. 29 and No. 105) and CONUNION for union rights (No. 87 and No. 98)) and my

equivalent indicators are all at or below 0.2. The partial correlation for the discrimination

against females is even (slightly) negative.

Table 3: Ratifications of Fundamental ILO Conventions and Level of Labour Standards

Variables Partial Correlation

LABFEM / CONDISC -0.02

CHILD / CONCHILD 0.07

CIVIL / CONFORCE 0.19

UNION / CONUNION 0.20

See Appendix B for data sources.

Based on these results, one might argue that, by lowering some labour standards, a developing

country can easily improve its comparative advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods.

Even though the first four measures of labour standards have a statistically significant impact

on the variations of exports, the results have to been seen in the perspectives of their relative

impact. In all regressions, the relative labour endowment and the educational attainment level

have a stronger influence on comparative advantage.22 Nevertheless, labour standards can still

have an impact on comparative advantage.

VII. Concluding Remarks

The main argument of this paper has been that labour standards can affect comparative

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods. It has been shown that once all commodity

categories of unskilled-labour-intensive goods and control variables are included in the

analysis, a (negative) statistical significant relationship between comparative advantage and

the level of core labour standards can be found for the 82 countries included in the analysis.

The empirical results do not, however, point in the same direction. Whereas forced and child

labour would increase the endowment of unskilled labour, and enhance comparative 22 The relative influence of a variable can be measured by standardised coefficients (beta). The results are reported in Appendix C.

Page 19: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods, discrimination against females would lead to

the opposite result. The effects of basic trade union rights are ambiguous in theory, but the

empirical results show that weaker union rights are associated with a stronger comparative

advantage in unskilled-labour-intensive goods.

A final observation concerns the fundamental relation between labour standards and

comparative advantage as well as the question of whether there might be “a race to the

bottom” on such standards. In the previous literature and in this paper, it has been assumed

that labour standards can be determined exogenously. It is quite clear that other labour

standards like working conditions (i.e. wages, working hours, days of paid leave) are

generally determined endogenously. One might argue that the same holds for core labour

standards. Even though legislation and enforcement of core labour standards are more easily

set by national governments, they could still be determinant endogenously to a certain degree.

If this is the case, all results with respect to causation should be interpreted cautiously and

concerns over unfair advantages due to low standards could be seen from a different

perspective. Nevertheless, it underlines the need for further research in this area.

Page 20: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

References

Aggarwal, Mita (1995), International Trade, Labor Standards, and Labor Market Conditions: An Evaluation of Linkages, US International Trade Commission, Office of Economics Working Paper No. 95-06-C, June.

Bhagwati, Jagdish N. (1958), “Immiserizing Growth: A Geometric Note,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 25, pp. 201-205.

Booth, Alison L. (1995), The Economics of the Trade Union, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Brown, Drusilla K. (2000), International Trade and Core Labour Standards: A Survey of the Literature, OECD Labour Market and Social Policy – Occasional Papers No. 43, Paris: OECD.

Brown, Drusilla K.; Deardorff, Alan V. and Stern, Robert M. (1996), “International Labor Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis”, in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert Hudec (eds.), Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. 1 Economic Analysis, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press, pp. 227-280.

Brown, Drusilla K.; Deardorff, Alan V. and Stern, Robert M. (1998), “Trade and Labor Standards”, Open Economies Review, Vol. 9, pp. 171-194.

Charnovitz, Steve (1987), “The Influence of International Labour Standards on the World Trading Regime: A Historical Overview”, International Labour Review, Vol. 126, No. 5, September-October, pp. 565-584.

Freedom House (2000), Freedom in the World: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties 1998-1999, Internet posting: http://www.freedomhouse.org.

Golub, Stephen S. (1997), “International Labor Standards and International Trade,” IMF Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, pp. 94-110.

ILO (2001a), About the International Labour Organization, Internet posting: http://www.ilo.org.

ILO (2001b), Ratifications of the ILO Fundamental Conventions, Internet posting: http://webfusion.ilo.org/public/db/standards/normes/appl/appl-ratif8conv.cfm?Lang=EN.

ITC (2000), Trade Analysis System PC-TAS 1994-1998, ITC (International Trade Center) and United Nations Statistics Division, Trade Data on CD-ROM.

Krugman, Paul R. (1995), Technology, Trade, and Factor Prices. NBER Working Paper No. 5355.

Mah, Jai S. (1997), “Core Labor Standards and Export Performance in Developing Countries”, The World Economy, Vol. 20, No. 6, September, pp. 773-785.

Martin, Will and Maskus, Keith (2001), “Core Labor Standards and Competitiveness: Implications for Global Trade Policy”, Review of International Economics, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 317-328.

Maskus, Keith (1997), Should Core Labor Standards be Imposed Through International Trade Policy? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1817.

Page 21: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

OECD (1996), Trade, Employment and Labour Standards: A Study of Core Workers’ Rights and International Trade, Paris: OECD.

OECD (2000), International Trade and Core Labour Standards, Paris: OECD.

OECD (2001), OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard: Towards a Knowledge-based Economy, Paris: OECD.

Patrinos, Harry A. and Psacharopoulos, George (1997), “Family Size, Schooling and Child Labor in Peru”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 10, No. 4, pp. 387-405.

Rodrik, Dani (1996), “Labor Standards in International Trade: Do They Matter and What Do We Do About Them”, in Robert Z. Lawrence, Dani Rodrik and John Whalley (eds.), Emerging Agenda For Global Trade: High States for Developing Countries, Washington Overseas Development Council Essay No. 20, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 35-79.

Rybczynski, Tadeusz M. (1955), “Factor Endowment and Relative Commodity Prices”, Economica, Vol. 22, pp. 36-41.

Shelbourne, Robert C. (2001), “An Explanation of the International Variation in the Prevalence of Child Labour”, The World Economy, Vol. 24, No. 3, March, pp. 359-377.

Tyres, Rodney; Phillips, Prue and Findlay, Christopher (1987), “ASEAN and China Exports of Labor-intensive Manufactures: Performance and Prospects”, ASEAN Economic Bulletin, Vol. 3. No. 3, March, pp. 339-367.

UN (2001), Treaty Bodies Database, United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights, Internet posting: http://www.unhchr.ch/tbs/doc.nsf.

UNDP (2000), Human Development Report 2000, Geneva: UNDP.

Van Beers, Cees (1998), “Labour Standards and Trade Flows of OECD Countries”, The World Economy, Vol. 21, No. 1, January, pp. 57-73.

World Bank (2001), World Development Indicators, Data on CD-ROM.

WTO (2001), WTO Ministerial Declaration, Doha, Qatar, November 14, 2001, Internet posting: http://www-svca.wto-ministerial.org.

Page 22: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Appendix A: Low Technology and Labour-intensive Goods

Commodity SITC, Rev. 3

Textile yarn and fabric 65

Glass, glassware and pottery 664-666

Furniture and bedding 82

Travel goods and handbags 83

Apparel 84

Footwear 85

Baby carriages, games, toys, and sporting goods 894

Sources: OECD (2001), Tyres et al. (1987) and own assembly; see text for explanation.

Appendix B: Definition of Variables and Data Sources

Variable Definition Source

EXLAB98 Exports of unskilled-labour-intensive manufactured goods divided

by total exports of goods, 1998 ITC (2000)

LABDENS Total labour force divided by land area (1,000 sq km of land), 1998 World Bank (2001)

EDU Educational attainment index, based on average years of schooling in the above-25 population and illiteracy rate, index from 0-1, 1998

UNDP (2000)

LABFEM Female labour force activity rate, ages 15-64, 1998 World Bank (2001)

CHILD Percentage of children ages 10-14 who are not working, 1998 World Bank (2001)

CIVIL Civil liberties, scale from 1-7, 1998-99 Freedom House (1999)

UNION Freedom of association and collective bargaining rights of unions, scale from 1-4, 1999

OECD (1996, 2000)

CONVEN Number of ratifications of the eight fundamental ILO conventions, Nov. 2001

ILO (2001b)

CONDISC Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO conventions on discrimination No. 100 and No. 111, Nov. 2001

ILO (2001b)

CONCHILD Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO conventions on child labour No. 138 and No. 182, Nov. 2001

ILO (2001b)

CONFORCE Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO conventions on forced labour No. 29 and No. 105, Nov. 2001

ILO (2001b)

CONUNION Number of ratifications of the two fundamental ILO conventions on basic union rights No. 87 and No. 98, Nov. 2001

ILO (2001b)

Page 23: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

Appendix C: Standardised Coefficients (Beta) of Regression Results

Independent Variables

Dependent Variable: EXLAB98

LABDENS 0.412 0.346 0.443 0.512 0.576 0.415EDU -0.372 -0.473 -0.384LABFEM 0.238 CHILD -0.205CIVIL -0.281UNION -0.343CONVEN 0.083

Page 24: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

CIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES The CIES Discussion Paper series provides a means of circulating promptly papers of interest to the research and policy communities and written by staff and visitors associated with the Centre for International Economic Studies (CIES) at the Adelaide University. Its purpose is to stimulate discussion of issues of contemporary policy relevance among non-economists as well as economists. To that end the papers are non-technical in nature and more widely accessible than papers published in specialist academic journals and books. (Prior to April 1999 this was called the CIES Policy Discussion Paper series. Since then the former CIES Seminar Paper series has been merged with this series.)

Copies of CIES Policy Discussion Papers may be downloaded from our Web site at http://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/ or are available by contacting the Executive Assistant, CIES, School of Economics, Adelaide University, SA 5005 AUSTRALIA. Tel: (+61 8) 8303 5672, Fax: (+61 8) 8223 1460, Email: [email protected]. Single copies are free on request; the cost to institutions is US$5.00 overseas or A$5.50 (incl. GST) in Australia each including postage and handling.

For a full list of CIES publications, visit our Web site at http://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/ or write, email or fax to the above address for our List of Publications by CIES Researchers, 1989 to 1999 plus updates.

0142 Busse, Matthias, “Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for Labour-Intensive Goods”, November 2001.

0141 Stringer, Randy and Glyn Wittwer, “Grapes, Wine and Water: Modelling Water Policy Reforms in Australia”, November 2001.

0140 Damania, Richard , Randy Stringer, K. Ullas Karanth, and Brad Stith, “The Economics of Protecting Tiger Populations: Linking Household Behaviour to Poaching and Prey Depletion”, November 2001.

0139 Damania, Richard and Erwin H. Bulte, “The Economics of Captive Breeding and Endangered Species Conservation”, October 2001.

0138 James, Jennifer S and Julian M Alston, “Taxes and Quality: A Market-Level Analysis”, October 2001.

0137 Rajan, Ramkishen, “Adopting an appropriate exchange rate regime: fixed or floating?”, October 2001. (Paper prepared for Malaysian Economic Outlook 2001, organized by the Malaysian Institute for Economic Research, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia).

0136 Anderson, Kym, Dimarana, Betina, Francois, Joseph, Hertel, Tom, Hoekman, Bernard, and Martin, Will, “The Cost of Rich (and Poor) Country Protection to Developing Countries”, September 2001. (Forthcoming in Journal of African Economies 2002.)

0135 Rajan, Ramkishen and Chung-Hua Shen, “Are Crisis-Devaluations contractionary?”, September 2001.

0134 Shapiro, Perry and Petchey, Jeffrey “Internationally Mobile Factors of Production and Economic Policy in an Integrated Regional Union of States”, August 2001.

0133 Rajan, Ramkishen and Graham Bird, Still the Weakest Link: the Domestic Financial System and Post-1998 Recovery in East Asia”, July 2001. (Since published in Development Policy Review, 19 (3), pp.355-66, 2001

Page 25: Do Labour Standards Affect Comparative Advantage? Evidence for ...

0132 Rajan, Ramkishen and Bird, Graham, “Banks, Maturity Mismatches and Liquidity Crises: a Simple Model”, July 2001.

0131 Montreevat, Sakulrat and Rajan, Ramkishen, “Financial Crisis, Bank Restructuring and Foreign Bank Entry: an Analytic Case Study of Thailand”, June 2001.

0130 Francois, Joseph F. “Factor Mobility, Economic Integration and the Location of Industry”, June 2001.

0129 Francois, Joseph F. “Flexible Estimation and Inference Within General Equilibrium Systems”, June 2001.

0128 Rajan, Ramkishen S., "Revisiting the Case for a Tobin Tax Post Asian Crisis: a Financial Safeguard or Financial Bonanza?" June 2001. (Paper prepared for presentation at a United Nations Meeting on Resource Mobilisation for Development, New York, June 25-26, 2001.)

0127 Rajan, Ramkishen S. and Graham Bird, "Regional Arrangements for Providing Liquidity in a Financial Crisis: Developments in Asia", June 2001.

0126 Anderson, Kym and Shunli Yao, "China, GMOs, and World Trade in Agricultural and Textile Products", June 2001. (Paper prepared for the Fourth Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis, Purdue University, West Lafayette 27-29 June 2001.)

0125 Anderson, Kym, "The Globalization (and Regionalization) of Wine", June 2001. (Paper for the National Academies Forum’s Symposium on Food and Drink in Australia: Where Are We Today? Adelaide, 5-6 July 2001.) (Forthcoming in Australian Agribusiness Review 2002.)

0124 Rajan, Ramkishen S., "On the Road to Recovery? International Capital Flows and Domestic Financial Reforms in East Asia", May 2001.

0123 Chunlai, Chen, and Christopher Findlay., "Patterns of Domestic Grain Flows and Regional Comparative Advantage in Grain Production in China", April 2001.

0122 Rajan, Ramkishen S., Rahul Sen and Reza Siregar, "Singapore and the New Regionalism: Bilateral Economic Relations with Japan and the US", May 2001.

0121 Anderson, Kym, Glyn Wittwer and Nick Berger, "A Model of the World Wine Market", May 2001. (Forthcoming in Economic Modelling, 2002)

0120 Barnes, Michelle, and Shiguang Ma, "Market Efficiency or not? The Behaviour of China’s Stock Prices in Response to the Announcement of Bonus Issues," April 2001.

0119 Ma, Shiguang, and Michelle Barnes, "Are China’s Stock Markets Really Weak-form Efficient?" April 2001.

0118 Stringer, Randy, "How Important are the 'Non-traditional' Economic Roles Agriculture in Development?" April 2001.

0117 Bird, Graham, and Ramkishen S. Rajan, "Economic Globalization: How Far and How Much Further?" April 2001. (Since published in World Economics, 2 (3), pp.1-18, 2001.)

0116 Damania, Richard, "Environmental Controls with Corrupt Bureaucrats," April 2001. 0115 Whitley, John, "The Gains and Losses from Agricultural Concentration," April 2001. 0114 Damania, Richard, and E. Barbier, "Lobbying, Trade and Renewable Resource

Harvesting," April 2001. 0113 Anderson, Kym, " Economy-wide Dimensions of Trade Policy and Reform," April

2001. (Forthcoming in Handbook on Developing Countries and the Next Round of WTO Negotiations, Washington DC: World Bank, 2002.)


Recommended