+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Do small businesses still prefer community banks?

Do small businesses still prefer community banks?

Date post: 31-Dec-2016
Category:
Upload: tara
View: 212 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
35
Accepted Manuscript Do small businesses still prefer community banks? Allen N. Berger, William Goulding, Tara Rice PII: S0378-4266(14)00099-5 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.03.016 Reference: JBF 4390 To appear in: Journal of Banking & Finance Received Date: 19 June 2013 Accepted Date: 10 March 2014 Please cite this article as: Berger, A.N., Goulding, W., Rice, T., Do small businesses still prefer community banks?, Journal of Banking & Finance (2014), doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.03.016 This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.
Transcript

Accepted Manuscript

Do small businesses still prefer community banks?

Allen N. Berger, William Goulding, Tara Rice

PII: S0378-4266(14)00099-5

DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.03.016

Reference: JBF 4390

To appear in: Journal of Banking & Finance

Received Date: 19 June 2013

Accepted Date: 10 March 2014

Please cite this article as: Berger, A.N., Goulding, W., Rice, T., Do small businesses still prefer community banks?,

Journal of Banking & Finance (2014), doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.03.016

This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a service to our customers

we are providing this early version of the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, and

review of the resulting proof before it is published in its final form. Please note that during the production process

errors may be discovered which could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain.

Do small businesses still prefer community banks?

Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina

Wharton Financial Institutions Center CentER – Tilburg University

[email protected]

William Goulding Massachusetts Institute of Technology

Sloan School of Management [email protected]

Tara Rice

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System [email protected]

February 2014

Abstract We formulate and test hypotheses about the role of bank type – small versus large, single-market versus multimarket, and local versus nonlocal banks – in banking relationships. The conventional paradigm suggests that “community banks” – small, single-market, local institutions – are better able to form strong relationships with informationally opaque small businesses, while “megabanks” – large, multimarket, nonlocal institutions – tend to serve more transparent firms. Using the 2003 Survey of Small Business Finance (SSBF), we conduct two sets of tests. First, we test for the type of bank serving as the “main” relationship bank for small businesses with different firm and owner characteristics. Second, we test for the strength of these main relationships by examining the probability of an exclusive relationship and main bank relationship length as functions of main bank type and financial fragility, as well as firm and owner characteristics. The results are often not consistent with the conventional paradigm, perhaps because of changes in lending technologies and deregulation of the banking industry. JEL Classification Numbers: G21, G28, G34 Keywords: Banks, Relationships, Small business, Government policy. The authors thank an anonymous referee, Rebel Cole, Bob DeYoung, Leora Klapper, Sole Martinez Peria, Paula Tkac, and participants in the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta conference on Small Business, Entrepreneurship and Economic Recovery and the CEPR/ECB/Kelley School of Business/ Review of Finance Conference on Small Business Financing for helpful comments and suggestions and Michael Carlson, Michael Donnelly, Michael Levere, and Raluca Roman for valuable research assistance. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors only, and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, its staff, or the Federal Reserve System.

1

1. Introduction

Banks are critical sources of funding for small firms, providing about 60% of debt financing to small

businesses (Survey of Small Business Finance, 2003). Small business lending is also important to banks. Both

small and large banks extend significant amounts of small business loans. Despite the importance of the banks

to small businesses and vice versa, surprisingly little is known about the characteristics of banks and small

businesses and their relationships with each other. In this paper, we examine bank types and their relationships

with small businesses.

Banks often extract proprietary information from strong relationships and use this information to set

contract terms and make credit underwriting decisions. The extant research suggests that small businesses

benefit from relationships in terms of credit availability, credit terms, and firm performance. Yet strong

relationships, particularly when they are exclusive, may also involve costs associated with a hold up problem –

extraction of rents from a captured firm – or with the potential for premature withdrawal of services if the bank

becomes financially distressed or fails. Exclusive relationships with certain types of banks may also be

inherently more fragile if these types are more likely to sever small business relationships or withdraw credit

than other types. Firms often bear the duplicative costs of multiple banking relationships to mitigate these

problems.

Arguments in the literature suggest that small banks are better able to form strong relationships with

informationally opaque small businesses, while large banks tend to serve more transparent firms because dealing

with opaque firms requires the use of soft information and such information is difficult to quantify and transmit

through the communication channels and layers of management of large organizations (e.g., Berger and Udell

2002, Stein 2002). Much of the early empirical literature provides support for this conventional paradigm (e.g.,

Haynes, Ou, and Berney 1999, Cole, Goldberg, and White 2004, Scott 2004, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan,

and Stein 2005).1 By extension, the arguments about the difficulties of large banks in dealing with the soft

information of opaque small firms may apply to multimarket and nonlocal banks as well. Thus, it is expected

under the conventional paradigm in the literature that opaque small businesses would be best served by small,

single-market, local banks, while large, multimarket, nonlocal institutions would tend to serve more transparent

firms.

1 Also consistent with the conventional paradigm, Gilje (2012) finds that a higher local market share for small banks increases the number of establishments in industries most dependent on external finance when local deposits increase.

2

If this conventional paradigm is correct, banking industry consolidation may have significant

consequences for the effectiveness of banking relationships with small businesses. Small banks, single-market

banks, and local banks may more often function as “community banks” that use soft information gathered from

relationships with the firm, its owner, and local community, while large banks, multimarket banks, nonlocal

banks may act more as “megabanks” with weaker community ties that base their relationships primarily on hard

information about the firm. Bank consolidation may also affect the competitiveness of local banking markets,

which may alter the strength of relationships and the benefits and costs of these relationships to small

businesses.

The large banks, multimarket banks, and nonlocal banks created by consolidation may be disadvantaged

in relationships based on soft information and may be more likely to sever relationships or withdraw credit than

the small, single-market, and local institutions they replace. During the financial crisis of 2007-2009, small

businesses saw their bank borrowing contract precipitously. Numerous reports cite small business owners’

difficulty in obtaining access to credit over the crisis period, particularly from large banks.2

Recently, however, a number of articles challenge the conventional paradigm and allow for the

possibility that technological progress and deregulation has made it easier for large, multimarket, and nonlocal

banks to to serve small, opaque firms.. Berger and Udell (2006) suggest that large banks may be able to serve

opaque firms well using hard-information technologies, such as credit scoring and lending against fixed asset

collateral (real estate, motor vehicles, or equipment) with values that are relatively easy to assess. A number of

empirical articles suggest that very large banks are able to increase their lending to opaque small businesses

using credit scoring technology (e.g., Frame, Srinivasan, and Woosley 2001, Frame, Padhi, and Woosley 2004,

Berger, Frame, and Miller 2005) and two studies suggest that small business credit scoring is responsible for an

increase in lending distance over time (Frame, Padhi, and Woosley 2004, DeYoung, Frame, Glennon, and Nigro

2011). Empirical results in Berger, Rosen, and Udell (2007) do not suggest a significant net advantage or

disadvantage for large banks in small business lending overall, or in lending to informationally opaque small

businesses in particular. Rather, the relative convenience of large banks, represented by their local market share

of deposits, appears to be most important variable in determining lender size. Berger and Black (2011) find that

2 Testimony of Governor Elizabeth A. Duke before the Committee on Financial Services and Committee on Small Business, U.S. House of Representatives, Washington, D.C., February 26, 2010 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/duke20100226a.htm) and National Federation of Independent Businesses, Small Credit in a Deep Recession, February 2010.

3

large banks tend to lend to both the smallest and the largest small businesses, with small banks specializing in

lending to medium-sized small firms. Canales and Nanda (2011) find that large banks with decentralized

decision making lend more to small businesses and respond more to local market competition, consistent with

behavior typically associated with small banks that make relationship loans. Berger and Black (2011) and

Berger, Cowan, and Frame (2011) find that small banks also use hard-information technologies, fixed asset

lending and credit scoring, respectively, in addition to relationship lending. De la Torre, Martinez Peria, and

Schmukler (2010) find that both large and small banks cater to small firms. Finally, one paper finds that the

conventional paradigm held for recent startups in the mid-2000s – in that a higher local market share of offices

owned by small banks resulted in more bank credit to startups – but did not hold for these firms in the recent

financial crisis (Berger, Cerqueiro, and Penas 2013).3

Despite these important issues and the recent controversy over the conventional paradigm, surprisingly

little empirical effort has been devoted to investigating the type of bank that tends to serve as the main

relationship bank with opaque small businesses and which types of main banks tend to be associated with

stronger relationships with these firms. The objective of this paper is to expand the literature along these lines.

For our purposes, we define a firm’s “main” relationship bank as the “primary” financial institution identified by

the firm. We test hypotheses about the role of main bank type – small versus large, single-market versus

multimarket, and local versus nonlocal banks – in banking relationships. In effect, we expand the conventional

paradigm about the roles of small banks to single-market and local banks and the roles of large banks to

multimarket and nonlocal banks, and test the conventional paradigm. Specifically, we test whether

“megabanks” (large, multimarket, nonlocal) less often serve as the main relationship bank than “community

banks” (small, single-market, local) for opaque small businesses, and whether the main bank relationships of

megabanks are weaker than those of “community banks.” Our application matches U.S. small business data

from the 2003 Survey of Small Business Finance (SSBF) to the Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income

for U.S. Banks (Call Reports) on the banks that provide them with credit and other services, and the Summary of

Deposits data on the conditions in their local banking markets.

We conduct two sets of tests. First, we test for the type of bank serving as the main relationship bank

identified by small businesses. Prior analyses of U.S. data typically do not focus on main banking relationships

3 In a related paper, Durguner (2012) shows that the importance of small business lending relationships in determining loan contract terms has diminished over time. Consistent with this, van Ewijk and Arnold (2013) find that U.S. banks have shifted from relationship-oriented models towards transactions-oriented models over time.

4

– they usually examine the relationship for a single loan at a time, and often do not match the loan to the bank

type.4 We include exogenous variables measuring firm characteristics (e.g., firm size and age, ownership type,

and industry), principal owner characteristics (e.g., if owner is also manager, has majority share, has had

personal financial problems), and local banking market conditions (e.g., concentration, market shares of large

and multimarket banks, bank offices per capita, state banking restrictions). We test the hypothesis from the

conventional paradigm that relatively opaque firms – measured by firm size, age, owner involvement, and

several other characteristics – tend to have their main banking relationship with small, single-market, and local

banks. Under the paradigm, these banks are expected to have advantages in soft-information-based relationships

relative to large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks, respectively. More transparent small businesses that rely

more on hard-information-based relationships are expected to have their main relationships more frequently at

large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks. In contrast, based on the recent literature, it could be the case

technological progress and deregulation have made it easier for large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks to serve

small, opaque firms, and small, single-market, local banks no longer have a comparative advantage in serving as

the main banks for these firms.

Second, we test for the strength of these main relationships by examining the probability of an exclusive

relationship versus multiple banking relationships and the length of a relationship as functions of the main bank

type and its financial fragility, as well as firm, owner, and market characteristics. Under the conventional

paradigm, relatively small, young firms with more “important” principal owners (i.e., owner-managers with

large stakes in their firms) and otherwise opaque small businesses tend to have stronger, more exclusive

relationships to deal with their soft information problems, whereas larger, more mature, firms with less

“important” principal owners may more often engage in multiple banking to reduce hold up and financial

distress concerns. Larger firms may also more often have multiple banks because a single bank cannot provide

all the financial services they need. In addition, under the conventional paradigm, it is expected that – even after

conditioning on firm and owner characteristics – relationships with small, single-market, and local banks or

“community banks” are likely to be stronger and more exclusive than those with large, multimarket, and

nonlocal banks or “megabanks” because the former relationships are more likely to be based significantly on

4 Studies of German hausbanks are exceptions in which main banking relationships are examined. Hausbanks are found to provide liquidity insurance to their customers (e.g., Elsas and Krahnen 1998). Hausbanks are also found to have better access to information, more influence on borrower management, and to provide relatively high shares of borrower debt (Elsas 2005).

5

soft information. In addition, firms may avoid single relationships with “megabanks” because of the fragility of

these relationships. These banks may have weaker ties to the local community and may be more likely to sever

small business relationships or withdraw soft-information-based credit than “community banks.” However,

some of the recent literature suggests to the contrary that “megabanks” may be able to use hard information to

have stronger and less fragile relationships with small, opaque businesses.

By way of preview, our empirical results are often not consistent with the predictions of the

conventional paradigm. In the first test, we find that opaque small businesses are not more likely to have a

community bank as their main bank. In the second test, we find mixed evidence on whether opaque small

businesses have stronger relationships with their main banks, but the evidence is clearer that strength does not

depend on the type of bank.

We conjecture that the conventional paradigm may not hold because of two important changes in the

banking industry over time: 1) changes in lending technology, specifically the introduction of credit scoring in

small business lending, and 2) changes in bank regulation (such as the Riegle Neal Interstate Banking and

Branching Efficiency Act of 1994 (IBBEA)) that allows large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks to integrate

offices across state lines.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the relevant literature on

banking relationship strength and associated research and policy issues. Section 3 discusses the data set and

provides summary statistics. Section 4 presents the empirical methodology. Section 5 presents the empirical

results, and Section 6 concludes.

2. Brief review of the relationship strength literature and associated issues

Relationship strength

Relationship strength is generally measured by the length or breadth of the relationship, or whether the

bank is the exclusive provider of financial services. Strong relationships may often be needed to extract

proprietary soft information and to lend to small firms without sufficient hard information on which to base

credit decisions. Firms of all types may also benefit from strong banking relationships in which the bank is able

to “reuse” hard and soft information garnered over the course of the relationship from loans, deposits, or other

services to set contract terms or make credit underwriting decisions. As will become clear, the literature

suggests that different types of banks – small versus large, single-market versus multimarket, and local versus

6

nonlocal – may have different abilities to maintain strong relationships with small businesses.

Benefits from strong relationships

Most empirical studies find benefits to borrowers from strong relationships. The research often finds

that stronger relationships are associated with better credit availability, as measured by a higher loan application

acceptance rate, less dependence on expensive trade credit, or fewer collateral requirements (e.g., Petersen and

Rajan 1994, 1995, Berger and Udell 1995, Cole 1998, Elsas and Krahnen 1998, Harhoff and Korting 1998,

Machauer and Weber 2000, Moro and Fink 2013). Studies of U.S. small businesses typically also find lower

loan interest rates when relationships are stronger (e.g., Berger and Udell 1995, Bharath, Dahiya, Saunders, and

Srinivasan 2011), although European studies often yield no significant effects of relationship strength on rates

(e.g., Elsas and Krahnen 1998, Harhoff and Korting 1998, Machauer and Weber 2000, Degryse and Cayseele

2000). Some studies also discover favorable effects of strong relationships on firm performance. Specifically,

one study of publicly traded U.S. companies finds that strong relationships increase the likelihood of success of

moderately financially distressed firms (Rosenfeld 2011), another study finds that relationships aid in resolution

of Chapter 11 bankruptcy proceedings (Dahiya, John, Puri, and Ramirez 2003), and a study of Italian

manufacturers yields a positive association between relationship strength and innovation by borrowing firms

(Herrera and Minetti 2007).5

Costs to strong relationships that may result in multiple banking

Strong relationships – particularly when they are exclusive – may also involve costs. The private

information generated by an exclusive banking relationship may give the bank market power over the firm,

yielding a hold up problem and extraction of rents from the firm (e.g., Sharpe 1990, Rajan 1992). Firms may

bear additional costs to engage in multiple relationships to mitigate the rent extraction (e.g., Von Thadden 1992,

Boot 2000, Farinha and Santos 2002, Elsas, Heinemann, and Tyrell 2004).6

Firms may also bear the duplicative costs of multiple banking instead of a single strong banking

relationship to protect themselves from premature withdrawal of services if their main bank becomes financially

distressed or fails. Thus, firms may be more likely to have multiple banking relationships when their main bank

is financially fragile and likely to become distressed or fail. The empirical literature on this topic is mixed, with

5 One study also documents some of the benefits to lenders from relationships in terms of increased future profitable lending opportunities (Bharath, Dahiya, Saunders, and Srinivasan 2007). 6 The extraction of rents may also make it profitable for banks to lend to some additional firms with marginal credit quality, improving the credit availability of these marginal firms (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 1995).

7

studies in some cases finding positive, negative, and/or no consistent effect of bank fragility on the probability

of multiple banking (e.g., Detragiache, Garella, and Guiso 2000, Ongena and Smith 2000, Berger, Klapper, and

Udell 2001, Berger, Klapper, Martinez Peria, and Zaidi 2008).7

The concept of relationship fragility may also be extended to apply to bank type if some types of banks

are more likely to sever relationships or withdraw critical services, independent of the bank’s financial

condition. In this regard, there is no literature on small versus large, single-market versus multimarket, or local

versus nonlocal banks on relationship severance. However, there are related studies on the effects of domestic

versus foreign banks – an extreme form of local versus nonlocal banks. One study of Indian banking suggests

that foreign banks have weaker ties to the country and may be more likely to sever relationships with local firms

than state-owned banks with mandates to serve local firms (Berger, Klapper, Martinez Peria, and Zaidi 2008).

A related literature finds that foreign banks generally reduced lending more than domestic banks during crisis

periods (Klein, Peek, and Rosengren, 2002, Claessens and Van Horen, 2011, de Haas and Lelyveld, 2011,

Popov and Udell, 2012, Ongena, Peydró, and van Horen, 2012).8 In the present context, it may be analogously

expected that large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks have weaker ties to the local community and may be more

likely to sever small business relationships or cut off credit than small, single-market, and local institutions,

respectively.

Finally, firms may more often bear the duplicative costs of multiple banking when one bank cannot

provide all of their financial service needs. This is likely to occur for some of the largest of the small businesses

studied here, which may be geographically dispersed, requiring services in more markets than are served by the

firm’s main bank. Multiple banks may similarly be needed if the firm requires international services or

specialized investment products not provided by the firm’s main bank. Empirical research typically finds that

larger firms are associated with multiple banking (e.g., Houston and James 1996, Machauer and Weber 2000,

Ongena and Smith 2000, Berger, Klapper, and Udell 2001, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005,

Berger, Klapper, Martinez Peria, and Zaidi 2008).9

Strong relationships and bank consolidation issues

7 A possible issue with these studies is that they typically do not measure the fragility of the main bank, but rather the fragility of one lending bank or all of the firm’s banks. We argue that the fragility of the main bank is the most logical choice, based on the assumption that the main bank is determined first. 8 However, it is possible that the major reason for the observed decrease in lending during the crisis is the decrease in firms’ demand for credit. For example, Kremp and Sevestre (2013) find that despite the stronger standards used by banks when granting credit, small businesses in France do not appear to have been strongly affected by credit rationing since 2008. 9 Other motives for multiple banking relationships are discussed in Berger, Klapper, Martinez Peria, and Zaidi (2008).

8

Some research and policy issues concern the effects of bank consolidation on relationships. Much of

the relationship lending literature focuses on the effects of bank size, hypothesizing that larger banks are

disadvantaged in relationships to small firms based on soft information due to difficulties in processing and

transmitting soft information through the communication channels of large organizations (e.g., Stein 2002),

agency problems within large organizations with more layers of management because the loan officer is the

main repository of soft information (e.g., Berger and Udell 2002), and/or organizational diseconomies of dealing

with using hard-information-based technologies for some firms along with soft-information-based technologies

for other firms (e.g., Williamson 1988). Large banks may have a comparative advantage in relationships with

larger firms due to economies of scale in processing and transmitting hard information.

Some empirical research is consistent with these expectations that large banks are less likely than small

banks to lend to or have strong relationships with small, young firms with little hard information available and

conversely for relationships with large, mature firms with more hard information available (e.g., Haynes, Ou,

and Berney 1999, Cole, Goldberg, and White 2004, Scott 2004, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein

2005). Thus, bank consolidation may have unfavorable implications for firms relying on relationships that make

primary use of soft information and conversely for firms relying on relationships based primarily on hard

information.10

Presumably, arguments similar to those based on bank size apply to the geography of banks – single-

market and local banks are more likely to have a comparative advantage in relationships based on soft

information, and multimarket and nonlocal banks are more likely to have a comparative advantage in hard-

information-based relationships. Some industrial organization research on banking focuses on differences in

competitive behavior and efficiencies of multimarket versus single-market banks and their effects on small

businesses and consumers, but does not examine the role of relationships (e.g., Hannan and Prager 2006, Berger,

Dick, Goldberg, and White 2007, Cohen and Mazzeo 2007, Berger and Ostromogolsky 2009). Similarly, there

has been research showing that lending distances have increased over time, with more small businesses

borrowing from nonlocal lenders (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 2002, Hannan 2003, Brevoort and Hannan 2006).

This literature also usually does not focus on relationships, despite the likely role of soft information in local

10 However, some research finds that market reactions may offset some of these consequences. Some studies of bank mergers and acquisitions find that small business lending appears to decline at consolidating institutions, but may be offset by increased lending supplies by other banks in the market or through increased market entry of newly chartered banks (e.g., Berger, Saunders, Scalise, and Udell 1998, Avery and Samolyk 2004, Berger, Bonime, Goldberg, and White 2004).

9

relationships and hard information in nonlocal relationships. Thus, the consolidation of the banking industry

may be expected to shift resources from small, single-market, and local banks to large, multimarket, nonlocal

institutions, with potentially significant consequences for banking relationships and their benefits to small

businesses.

Consolidation may also affect the competitiveness of local banking markets. Mergers and acquisitions

(M&As) within markets likely reduces competitiveness and M&As across markets likely increase

competitiveness. Relationship strength and its consequences may be greater when banking markets are less

competitive, because firms have fewer potential alternatives in the future event that their main bank tightens

contract terms dramatically. Empirical studies of the effects of concentration and other restrictions on

competitiveness on measures of credit availability, activity, and general economic performance find both

favorable effects (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 1995, Cetorelli and Gambera 2001, Bonaccorsi di Patti and

Dell’Ariccia 2004, Cetorelli 2004) and unfavorable effects (e.g., Black and Strahan 2002, Berger, Hasan, and

Klapper 2004, Karceski, Ongena, and Smith 2005, Cetorelli and Strahan 2006, Chong, Lu, and Ongena 2013).

3. Data and Summary Statistics

We combine data from the SSBF with the Call Reports. The SSBF is a survey by the Federal Reserve

of the financial condition of firms with fewer than 500 full-time-equivalent employees. The survey was first

conducted in 1987 and repeated in 1993, 1998, and 2003. It contains details on small businesses’ income,

expenses, assets, liabilities, and characteristics of the firm, firm owners, and the small businesses’ financial

relationships with financial service suppliers for a broad set of products and services. The sample is randomly

drawn but stratified to ensure geographical representation across all regions of the United States. The SSBF also

oversamples relatively large firms (conditional on having fewer than 500 workers). Given the above data, we

can measure assets, liabilities, profits, firm age, and the length of time firms have established relationships with

banks and other lenders. We also know the location of firms, so we can control for local market conditions.

Petersen and Rajan (1994) and Berger and Udell (1995) are among the first to use the data from the

1987 survey. These papers both find that banking relationships expand credit availability for small firms. Other

authors also use later waves of these data to study whether bank size affects credit allocation decisions (e.g.,

Cole 1998, Jayaratne and Wolken 1999, Cole, Goldberg, and White, 2004, Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and

10

Stein 2005, Berger and Black 2011). Our paper is the first to use these data to test role of bank type – small

versus large, single-market versus multimarket, and local versus nonlocal banks – in banking relationships.

The SSBF data contain information on up to 20 financial services firms with which a small business

may have a relationship, including the firm’s “primary” or main bank.11 We match the small businesses’ main

banks with the Call Reports, which contain financial statement and structure data on all U.S. commercial banks.

We exclude a number of firms from the sample. Of the 4240 firms in the SSBF, 3350 are in metropolitan

markets. We restrict our study to metropolitan markets because lending practices vary greatly between

metropolitan and rural markets, and the sample of rural banks would be too small to analyze. DeYoung,

Glennon, Nigro, and Spong (2012) find fundamental differences between small rural and metropolitan business

borrowers and conclude that divergent lending practices made necessary by these differences may result in a

greater number of small rural commercial banks than would be expected.

Of the 3350 metropolitan firms, 2846 identified a commercial bank as their primary institution. We

drop the other 504 firms from the sample that either did not have a commercial bank as a primary institution or

provided an incomplete response to the question, leaving the identity of the main institution uncertain. Another

232 firms could not be matched to the Summary of Deposits data to gather information on their local market

conditions, and another 4 firms were eliminated because their industry perfectly predicted whether it had its

main bank relationship with a multimarket institution, leaving 2,610 observations that could be used in our

regressions of main bank type (described below). We lose another 27 observations, leaving a total of 2,583, for

our regressions of relationship strength because we did not have the requisite 8 quarters of prior data to compute

one of our bank risk measures, the Z-score.

Table 1 Panel A reports the definitions of the variables used in the analyses taken from the 2003 SSBF

matched with the Call Reports. The firm characteristics include measures of firm size, minority ownership, age,

risk, and industry, and if the firm has a bank loan. For firm size, we specify dummies for small, medium, and

large firms, with total assets ≤ $100,000, $100,000 - $1 million, and over $1 million, respectively, with small

firms excluded as the base case in the regressions. Note that these are relative sizes within the broader category

11 Unfortunately, it is not possible to identify a “Second Main Bank Type,” as no priority is given to the other institutions that provide financial services.

11

of small businesses that are in the SSBF, and do not include the largest firms in the nation. Prior research finds

significant differences across these three size classes in the comparative advantages of large and small banks in

using different lending technologies (Berger and Black 2011). For firm age, we simply specify the natural log

of age. Age is a measure of opacity and has been found to affect the likelihood of borrowing from large banks

in prior research (e.g., Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005, Berger, Rosen, and Udell 2007). For

firm risk, we include a measure of credit score, leverage, and a dummy that equals 1 if the business has been

delinquent in the past three years. We also control for industry type with a set of dummies for one-digit SIC

codes (not shown in tables for brevity).

The owner characteristics include measures of organizational form and the involvement or “importance”

of the principal owner in the life of the firm. Organizational form includes dummies for whether the firm is a

corporation, partnership, or proprietorship, as these forms offer the firm different protections of assets in the

event that they do not repay their bank credit and may also reflect the need for soft information in their banking

relationships. We include variables measuring whether the principal owner of the firm is also the manager, and

whether the firm is owned exclusively by a single family. When the owner is also the manager and/or has a

large stake in the firm, it is more likely that the main relationship with the firm will require significant collection

of soft information about the owner. Thus, when the owner is more “important,” the firm may be more likely to

have a main relationship with a small, single-market, or local bank to deal with the soft information under the

conventional paradigm. Alternatively, when the owner is more “important,” large, multimarket, or nonlocal

banks may be more likely to have the main relationship because credit scoring is mostly based on the consumer

information on the owner, which may be more important when the owner is more important to the firm.

Turning to main bank characteristics, we use a size cutoff of $1 billion in gross total assets (GTA) to

distinguish between small and large banks following prior research on the empirical definition of “community

banks” (e.g., DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell 2004). Also following prior research and anti-trust guidelines, we

define a single-market bank as one in a single metropolitan market – a Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) or

New England County Metropolitan Areas (NECMA) in which the small business is located. All banks with

branch offices in two or more metropolitan or rural markets are defined as multimarket banks. Main banks that

do not have a banking office in the firm’s local market are designated as nonlocal. In some specifications, we

replace the main bank size dummy with the log of bank assets and the multimarket dummy with the number or

log of the number of markets in which the main bank has offices. In some specifications, we also account for

12

the financial fragility of the main bank by including its equity to gross total assets (GTA) ratio, its ratio of

nonperforming loans to total loans, a measure of its illiquidity (liquidity creation to GTA ratio, taken from

Berger and Bouwman 2009), its ratio of fee income from deposits to total revenues as an inverse measure of

nontraditional activities (similar to Lozano-Vivas and Pasiouras 2010 and DeYoung and Torna 2013), and its Z-

score computed over the prior 12 quarters (or 8-11 quarters if 12 quarters are unavailable), similar to Laeven and

Levine 2009 and Mercieca, Schaeck, and Wolfe 2007.

Banking relationship variables include a dummy for an exclusive bank-firm relationship. We also use a

measure of length of the relationship with the main bank.

Turning to local market characteristics, in the small bank versus large main bank estimation (described

more in Section 4 below), we also include a variable to measure the share of local market offices owned by large

banks. This is included as a proxy for the relative convenience to large banks. It is expected that firms are more

likely to have their main relationship at a large bank if the market presence of this bank type is greater, all else

equal.12 Similarly, we include multimarket bank share of local market offices in the single-market versus

multimarket bank equation to account for the relative convenience of multimarket banks. In the local versus

nonlocal bank equation, we include local bank offices per capita as an indicator of the relative convenience of

local banks. In all the regressions, we include a control for the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index of local banking

market concentration (HHI), which may or may not be an inverse indicator of competition (Berger, Demirguc-

Kunt, Levine, and Haubrich 2004). We also include an interstate branching index to control for regulatory and

competitive conditions (Rice and Strahan 2010).

Summary statistics on these variables are shown in Table 1 Panel B. We briefly discuss some of these

here. On average, firms in our sample are about 17 years old, and 69 percent are organized as corporations. The

leverage ratio debt-to-asset ratio of the average firm is 33 percent, and about half of the firms have a bank loan.

Less than one percent of firms in our sample have declared bankruptcy in the past 7 years. These firms are

largely family owned and operated – 81.5 percent of firms are family owned and 88 percent are owner-managed.

Over three-quarters of the firms in our sample have large banks as their main banks, and over 60 percent

12 Prior research finds that the local market share of large banks is a powerful predictor of lending bank size (e.g., Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005, Berger, Rosen, and Udell 2007).

13

have multimarket or nonlocal banks as their main banks.13 The majority of firms (57 percent) in the sample

state that they have only one bank and the average main bank relationship is 11 years. The high proportion of

firms that have large, multimarket or nonlocal banks as their main bank suggests, at least at first blush, that the

conventional paradigm does not strongly hold – most of our small-firm sample do not have community banks as

their main banks.

4. Empirical Methodology

Determinants of main bank type

Our first model examines the effects of firm, owner, and local market characteristics in determining the

firm’s main bank type:

Main bank type = f{Firm and owner characteristics, Local market characteristics} (1)

The dependent variables are dummies which equal 1 if the main bank is the given type and 0 otherwise.

We distinguish between small and large banks, between single-market and multimarket banks, and between

local and nonlocal banks. We estimate binomial logit models specifying the probability of the main bank being

large, multimarket, or nonlocal, leaving small, single-market, or local as the excluded base case, respectively.

Our primary tests in equation (1) are based on the discussion above concerning the effects of firm size

and age, and the “importance” of principal owner to the firm. We test the hypotheses under the conventional

paradigm that “community banks” (small, single-market, and local banks) tend to serve as the main bank for

more opaque firms – i.e., smaller, younger firms, with more “important” owners – and “megabanks” (large,

multimarket, or nonlocal banks) tend to have their strongest relationship with more transparent firms – i.e.,

larger, more mature firms, with less “important” owners.

Determinants of relationship strength

Our second model investigates the determinants of relationship strength. We use logit estimations to

study the probability that a firm has an exclusive banking relationship using a dummy for the dependent

variable. We also estimate an OLS model using robust standard errors to test for the length of the relationship

13 The mean size of the main bank is quite large – over $140 billion in gross total assets – much larger than the mean bank in the nation. This is because the observations are by the small business relationships rather than by banks, and the largest banks tend to have many more small business relationships than the smallest banks. Similarly, mean number of markets of the main bank is very large at 129 because the banks with the most markets tend to have many more small business relationships than the banks with the fewest markets.

14

(where length is defined as the log of (1+ length of firm-bank relationship in years)). We assume that

relationship strength is a function of firm, local market, and main bank characteristics as shown in equation (2):

Relationship Strength = g{Firm and owner characteristics, Local market characteristics, Main bank type and fragility } (2)

The firm, owner, and local market characteristics in equation (2) are identical to those in equation (1), except

that we include all three convenience variables – large bank branch share, multimarket bank branch share, and

local market bank offices per capita together in each version of Equation (2), whereas these entered in different

versions of Equation (1). The main bank characteristics include measures of the type and financial fragility of

the main bank. For main bank type, we simply specify dummies for large bank, multimarket bank, and nonlocal

bank, excluding dummies for small, single-market, and local banks as the base case. As discussed above, for

financial fragility, we include the main bank’s equity to gross total assets (GTA) ratio, its nonperforming loan

ratio, a measure of its illiquidity, an inverse measure of its nontraditional activities, and its Z-score.

Using equation (2), we first test the effects of firm size, age, and “importance” of the principal owner on

main bank relationship strength. Specifically, we test the hypotheses that smaller, younger firms, with more

“important” principal owners are more likely to have exclusive relationships and longer relationships to deal

with their soft information problems, while relatively large, more mature firms with less “important” principal

owners may more often engage in multiple banking relationships and shorter relationships.

Second, we test hypotheses regarding the strength of the relationship with the main bank type.

Specifically, we test the hypotheses that large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks have weaker ties to the local

community, and may be more likely to sever small business relationships or withdraw soft-information-based

credit than small, single-market, and local institutions, respectively. Therefore, it is expected that firms that

have these bank types are more likely to protect themselves against the fragility of their main banking

relationship by engaging in multiple banking or having shorter relationships.

Third, we test the effects of main bank financial fragility on the probability that the firm has multiple

banking relationships or short relationships to protect themselves from premature withdrawal of services if their

main bank becomes financially distressed or fails. Thus, conditional on the firm and owner characteristics, we

15

expect that multiple relationships are more likely and relationships are shorter when the main bank has a low

capital ratio, high nonperforming loan ratio, high illiquidity, low deposit fee income ratio, and low Z-score.14

5. Empirical results

Tables 2 and 3 show our regression results for the determinants of main bank type (Table 2), and

relationship strength (Table 3). Each table shows multiple specifications of the equations to illustrate the

robustness of the findings. Most of the regressions have the logit form, so we present the estimates as odds

ratios which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. For example, in the logit regressions

in Table 2 with the probability of a large, multimarket, or nonlocal bank as dependent variable, an odds ratio of

one on a firm being medium-sized would indicate that being a medium firm does not affect the probability of

having a “megabank” as its main bank. An odds ratio greater/less than one on a right-hand-side variable would

indicate that an increase in the variable increases/decreases the probability of a main bank being a large,

multimarket or nonlocal bank, as appropriate. We report the z-statistics for testing equality to one in

parentheses under the odds ratios in all tables. For the relationship strength regressions and one of the

robustness checks with the log of main bank assets as the dependent variable, we estimate by OLS and report

standard coefficients and t-statistics for testing equality to zero in parentheses under the coefficients.

Determinants of main bank type

Table 2 reports the results of our first set of tests that small, single-market, and local banks tend to serve

as the main bank for more opaque firms – i.e., smaller, younger firms, with more “important” owners – and

large, multimarket, and nonlocal banks tend to have their strongest relationship with more transparent firms –

i.e., larger, more mature firms, with less “important” owners. Columns 1-3 of Panel A report these regressions

for the main bank being a large bank, multimarket bank, or nonlocal bank, respectively. We find that most of

the key exogenous variables have odds ratios that are statistically insignificantly different from one; that is, we

do not find evidence that smaller, younger firms, with more “important” owners have their strongest

relationships with small, single-market and local banks. In column 1, the odds ratios on three variables are

14 Some studies of multiple banking in other nations use two different models of choice: 1) to have multiple banks, and 2) the number of banks, given multiple banking (e.g., Detragiache, Garella, and Guiso 2000, Berger, Klapper, Martinez Peria, and Zaidi 2008). We argue that such an approach is not appropriate for our sample of U.S. small businesses, which rarely have many more than two relationships.

16

statistically significantly different from one. Firms with a high percentage of minority ownership are more

likely than others to have a large main bank. This is not one of the variables that we necessarily associate with

firm opacity, but to the extent that minority-owned firms may be more informationally opaque, the result runs

contrary to the conventional paradigm. The odds ratio on the large bank share of the market offices is also

greater than one and statistically significant in the first regression in column 1, suggesting that small businesses’

choice of large banks is, in part, motivated by the convenience of having a large share of offices of that type of

bank in the area. As well, the odds ratio on HHI is significantly greater than one. In column 2, the odds ratio on

minority ownership is again significantly greater than one, possibly inconsistent with the conventional

paradigm. Analogous to column 1, the coefficient on multimarket share of offices in column 2 is significantly

greater than one, indicating that convenience of these banks plays a role. The odds ratio on partnership is also

significantly greater than one, but the odds ratio on corporation is not, yielding the mixed result that partnerships

are more likely than proprietorships with have a multimarket main bank, but corporations are not. In the third

regression in column 3, the odds ratio on the total number of bank offices in each market per capita, our proxy

of local bank office presence, is less than one, suggesting that small businesses’ choice of a local bank is driven

partly by the convenience of having more local offices in the market. Firms that have been bankrupt and firms

in more concentrated banking markets are also less likely to have nonlocal main banks.

Panels B-E of Table 2 test the robustness of these results. In Panel B, we repeat the three logit

regressions leaving out the controls for the banking market. Consistent with the main results in Panel A, the

odds ratios for the variables measuring the effects of firm size, age, and the “importance” of the principal owner

are all statistically insignificantly different from one, contrary to the predictions of the conventional paradigm.

In Panel C, we instead leaving out the controls for the owner characteristics. Again the odds ratios for

firm size and age are insignificantly different from one (the “importance” of the principal owner cannot be

determined in these regressions without the owner characteristics).

In Panel D, we add the other two dependent variables to each of the three main logit regressions. That

is, in the Main bank is large bank regression, we add the indicators for multimarket and nonlocal, and so forth.15

Not surprisingly, the odds ratios on these additional variables are statistically significantly greater than one in all

cases – these megabank properties often go together. More importantly, the odds ratios on the key right-hand-

side variables are again generally not statistically significantly different from one. The only exception is Firm

15 This is similar to the inclusion of distress in a regression model of bank failure in DeYoung and Torna (2013).

17

age in the large main bank regression, but the odds ratio of 1.014 is not economically significantly different

from one.

In Panel E, we rerun the regressions for large main bank and multimarket main bank replacing the

dummy indicators with continuous variables. That is, we replace the dependent variable for large main bank

with the log of bank gross total assets and the dependent variable for multimarket main bank with the number of

main bank markets. In columns 1-3, we use OLS to regress log of main bank’s gross total assets on right-hand-

side variables, both excluding and including variables for multimarket main bank and nonlocal main bank. In

columns 2-3, we alternate the variable for multimarket main bank between the indicator dummy and the log of

the number of main bank markets. In columns 4-6, we use ordered logit for the number of main bank markets

using the categories 1, 2-5, 6-20, and over 20 markets. We again run the regressions with and without variables

for large and nonlocal main bank, and alternate between the large bank dummy and the log of large bank assets

in columns 5-6.16 As in the earlier reported results, the measures of firm opacity and owner “importance” are

nearly all statistically insignificant or in the case of firm age, economically insignificant. Also as reported

earlier, all the main bank size, multimarket, and nonlocal variables on the right-hand-side all indicate that the

three megabank indicators are positively related. Thus, the main results are again found to be robust.

Determinants of relationship strength

Table 3 reports the results of our second set of regressions, which tests the effects of firm size, age, and

“importance” of the principal owner, as well as the main bank type and financial fragility, on the strength of the

main relationship. The main results are in columns 1-2. Column 1 reports the results of equation (2) estimated

as a logit model using the exclusive relationship indicator as the endogenous variable, while column 2 reports

the results of equation (2), estimated as an OLS model with robust standard errors and using the log of one plus

the length of the relationship with the main bank as the endogenous variable. Columns 3-4 repeat these

regressions using the megabank dummy on the right-hand-side in place of the our three main bank dummies.

Columns 5-6 use the log of main bank gross total assets in place of the large main bank dummy and the log of

the number of markets of the main bank in place of the multimarket main bank dummy.

We see in column 1 using the exclusive relationship dummy that the odds ratios for the medium and

large firm indicators are below one and statistically significant, that is, these firms are less likely than small

16 In unreported results, running OLS regressions for the log of main bank markets yields consistent findings.

18

firms to have exclusive relationships with their main banks. This could indicate that small firms have stronger

relationships with their main banks. This is consistent with the predictions of the conventional paradigm, or it

could reflect the fact that larger firms demand a larger array of financial services over a greater geographic area,

which may require multiple banks. We turn to the regression results for relationship length below to determine

which of these explanations is more likely. Notably, the odds ratios on partnership and corporation are

statistically significantly greater than one, indicating that proprietorships (in which the owner’s and firm’s

finances are intertwined) are less likely to have exclusive relationships. This is inconsistent with the

conventional paradigm in which more “important” principal owners are likely to have stronger relationships.

The odds ratios on whether the main bank is large, multimarket, or nonlocal are all insignificantly different from

one – inconsistent with the conventional paradigm, which would predict stronger relationships with “community

banks.” The odds ratios on the equity to asset ratio and the Z-score of the main bank are statistically

significantly less than one (although the Z-score is economically close to one), suggesting that firms with riskier

main banks are more likely to have exclusive relationships, which runs counter to the prediction that firms

choose multiple banks to avoid the risk of a fragile main bank.

The OLS regression in column 2 using the log of one plus the length of the relationship shows that small

firms are no more likely than medium or large firms to have a longer relationship with their banks, inconsistent

with the predictions of the conventional paradigm (recall that these are OLS coefficients that are tested against

the null of zero). The estimated coefficients on the age and riskiness of the firms indicate that older and safer

firms are more likely to have longer relationships with their banks. The age coefficient may reflect a

mechanical association, given that older firms have more years available to have longer relationships, while the

risk coefficient may suggest that banks prefer to keep relationships with safer firms. Finally, firms whose main

bank is large or multimarket tend to have longer relationship with their banks, contrary to the predictions of the

conventional paradigm.17

The regressions in columns 3-4 using the megabank dummy in place of the three indicator dummies are

almost identical to those in columns 1-2. The same key variables are statistically significant and the megabank

dummy has a positive, statistically significant coefficient in column 4, consistent with the positive coefficients

on the large and multimarket dummies in column 2.

17 The coefficient on family owned is positive, consistent with the prediction of the conventional paradigm that more “important” owners are likely to have stronger relationships with their main bank, but the coefficient is relatively small and statistically significant only at the 10% level.

19

The regressions in columns 5-6 with continuous indicators of main bank asset size and number of

markets are virtually identical with the main results in columns 1-2, except that in column 6, the nonlocal

coefficient is negative and statistically significant, consistent with the expectation that relationships with

nonlocal banks are shorter.

6. Conclusions

Bank researchers have traditionally argued that “community banks” – institutions that are small and

operate locally in a single market – tend to have the strongest relationships with the smallest, most

informationally opaque small businesses. The argument frequently cited is that community bankers are superior

at processing “soft” qualitative information about their customers and local communities that is difficult to

quantify and transmit over distances and through the communication channels of other banks. “Megabanks” –

institutions that are large, multimarket, and provide services from outside the local market – in contrast are

better at serving larger, more transparent firms using “hard” quantitative information and that may be more

easily communicated within these organizations. There are reasons to believe that this conventional paradigm

may have lost hold to some degree over time as technological progress and deregulation have made it easier for

megabanks to serve small, opaque firms.

Some of the recent literature has challenged the conventional paradigm, finding that large banks do lend

to small, opaque firms using hard-information technologies such as small business credit scoring and fixed-asset

technologies. However, the literature has not to date spent much effort testing other predictions of the

conventional paradigm regarding which type of bank serves as a small business’ “main” relationship bank and

the strength of the main bank relationship.

In this paper, we test some of these predictions using data from the 2003 SSBF. Specifically, we

conduct two sets of tests. First, we test for the type of bank serving as the “main” relationship bank. We find

that opaque small businesses are not more likely to have a community bank as their main bank. Second, we test

for the strength of these main relationships by examining the probability of multiple relationships and length of

the relationship as functions of main bank type and financial fragility, as well as firm and owner characteristics.

We find mixed evidence on whether opaque small businesses have stronger relationships with their main banks,

20

but the evidence is clearer that strength does not depend on the type of bank.18

18 To further address this issue, we tried to apply our analysis to the 1993 SSBF survey to compare to our main results, since 1993 was before the widespread use of small business credit scoring (the first FICO model for small business credit scoring was made available in 1995) and the passage of IBBEA in 1994 (which allowed large, multimarket and nonlocal banks to integrate offices across state lines). However, the quality of the data prevented us from doing so. In early survey years, a large number of firms were not matched or improperly matched to their main financial institutions. Correct matching of firm to financial institution has been a persistent issue that the survey designers have worked to address more fully with each survey round. In the 1993 survey, only 70% of firms were matched with their main institution, but by 2003, this had improved to 88%. The issue in the early years stems from the survey firm incompletely filling out the name of the institution (for example, “union bank” or “first national bank”) when hundreds of such banks had similar names. In later years, the survey design was improved to eliminate errors of this sort. Moreover, the unmatched banks in the earlier year appear to be the smaller banks. Thus, the 1993 survey would leave us with a small sample size, biased towards large firms.

21

References

Avery, R.B., and Samolyk, K.A., 2004. Bank consolidation and the provision of banking services: Small commercial loans, Journal of Financial Services Research 25, 291-325.

Beck, T., Degryse, H., De Haas, R., and van Horen, N., 2013. When Arm’s Length Is Too Far. Relationship

Banking over the Business Cycle, Tilburg University Working paper. Berger, A.N., and Black, L.K., 2011. Bank Size, Lending Technologies, and Small Business Finance, Journal of

Banking and Finance 35, 724-735. Berger, A.N., Bonime, S.D., Goldberg, L.G., and White, L.J., 2004. The dynamics of market entry: The effects

of mergers and acquisitions on entry in the banking industry, Journal of Business 77, 797-834. Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H.S., 2009. Bank liquidity creation, Review of Financial Studies 22, 3779–3837.

Berger, A.N., Cerqueiro, G., and Penas, M.F., 2013. Market size structure and small business lending: Are crisis times different from normal times?, University of South Carolina working paper.

Berger, A.N., Cowan, A.M., and Frame, W.S., 2011. The surprising use of credit scoring in small business lending

by community banks and the attendant Effects on credit availability, risk, and profitability, Journal of Financial Services Research 39, 1-17.

Berger, A.N., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Levine, R., and Haubrich, J.G., 2004. Bank Concentration and Competition:

An Evolution in the Making, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36, 433-451. Berger, A.N., Frame, W.S., and Miller, N., 2005. Credit Scoring and the Availability, Price, and Risk of Small

Business Credit, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 37, 191-222. Berger, A.N., Hasan, I., and Klapper, L.F., 2004. Further evidence on the link between finance and growth: An

international analysis of community banking and economic performance, Journal of Financial Services Research 25, 169-202.

Berger, A.N., Klapper, L.F., and Udell, G.F., 2001. The ability of banks to lend to informationally opaque small

businesses, Journal of Banking and Finance 25, 2127-2167. Berger, A.N., Klapper, L.F., Martinez Peria, M.S., and Zaidi, R. 2008. Bank Ownership Type and Banking

Relationships, Journal of Financial Intermediation 17, 37-62. Berger, A.N., Miller, N.H., Petersen, M.A., Rajan, R.G., and Stein, J.C., 2005. Does function follow

organizational form? Evidence from the lending practices of large and small banks, Journal of Financial Economics 76, 237-269.

Berger, A.N., and Ostromogolsky, P, 2009. The Effects of Banks on ‘Debt-Sensitive’ Small Businesses, Journal

of Financial Economic Policy 1, 44-79. Berger, A.N., Rosen, R.J., and Udell, G.F., 2007. Does market size structure affect competition? The case of

small business lending, Journal of Banking and Finance 31, 11-33. Berger, A.N., Saunders, A., Scalise, J.M., and Udell, G.F., 1998. The effects of bank mergers and acquisitions

on small business lending, Journal of Financial Economics 50, 187-229. Berger, A.N., and Udell, G.F., 1995. Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance, Journal of

22

Business 68, 351-381. Berger, A.N., and Udell, G.F., 2002. Small business credit availability and relationship lending: The importance

of bank organizational structure, Economic Journal 112, 32-53. Berger, A.N., and Udell, G.F., 2006. A More Complete Conceptual Framework for SME Finance, Journal of

Banking and Finance 30, 2945-2966. Bharath, S., Dahiya, S., Saunders,.A., and Srinivasan, A., 2007. So What Do I Get? The Bank’s View of

Lending, Journal of Financial Economics 85, 368-419. Bharath, S., Dahiya, S., Saunders, A., and Srinivasan, A., 2011. Lending Relationships and Loan Contract

Terms. Review of Financial Studies 24, 1141-1203. Black S.E., and Strahan, P.E., 2002. Entrepreneurship and bank credit availability, Journal of Finance 57, 2807-

2833. Bonaccorsi di Patti, E., and Dell’Ariccia, G., 2004. Bank competition and firm creation, Journal of Money,

Credit, and Banking 36, 225-251. Boot, A.W.A., 2000. Relationship banking: What do we know?, Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 7-25. Brevoort, K.P., and Hannan, T.H., 2006. Commercial Lending and Distance: Evidence from Community

Reinvestment Act Data, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 38, 1991-2012. Canales, R., and Nanda, R., 2012. A Darker Side to Decentralized Banks: Market Power and Credit Rationing in

SME Lending, Journal of Financial Economics 105, 353-366. Cetorelli, N., 2004. Bank concentration and competition in Europe, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36,

543-558. Cetorelli, N., and Gambera, M., 2001. Banking market structure, financial dependence and growth: International

evidence from industry data, Journal of Finance 56, 617-648. Cetorelli, N., and Strahan, P.E., 2006. Finance as a barrier to entry: Bank competition and industry structure in

local U.S. markets, Journal of Finance 61. Chong, T., Lu, L., and Ongena, S., 2013. Does banking competition alleviate or worsen credit constraints faced

by small- and medium-sized enterprises? Evidence from China, Journal of Banking and Finance 37, 3412-3424.

Claessens, S., and Van Horen, N., 2011. Trends in foreign banking: A database on bilateral foreign bank

ownership, Dutch Central Bank Working Paper Cohen, A., and Mazzeo, M. J., 2007. Market Structure and Competition among Retail Depository Institutions,

Review of Economics and Statistics 89. Cole, R., 1998. The importance of relationships to the availability of credit, Journal of Banking and Finance 22,

959-977. Cole, R. A., Goldberg, L.G., and White, L.J., 2004. Cookie-cutter versus character: The micro structure of small

business lending by large and small banks, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 39, 227-251.

23

Dahiya, S., Kose, J., Manju, P., and Gabriel, R., 2003. Debtor-in-possession financing and bankruptcy resolution: Empirical evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 259-280.

de la Torre, A., Martinez Peria, M.S., and Schmukler, S.L. 2010. Bank involvement with SMEs: Beyond

relationship lending, Journal of Banking and Finance 34, 2280-2293. Degryse, H., and Van Cayseele, P., 2000. Relationship lending within a bank-based system: Evidence from

European small business data, Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 90-109. Detragiache, E., Garella, P., and Guiso, L., 2000. Multiple versus single banking relationships: Theory and

evidence, Journal of Finance 55, 1133-1161. de Haas, R., and Van Lelyveld, I., 2011. Multinational banks and the global financial crisis: Weathering the

perfect storm, Dutch National Bank Working paper No. 322. DeYoung, R., Frame, W.S., Glennon, D., and Nigro, P., 2011. The information revolution and small business

lending: The missing evidence, Journal of Financial Services Research 39, 19-33. DeYoung, R., Hunter, W.C., and Udell, G.F., 2004. The Past, Present, and Probable Future for Community

Banks, Journal of Financial Services Research 25, 85-133. DeYoung, R., Glennon, D., Nigro, P., and Spong, K., 2012. Small Business Lending and Social Capital: Are

Rural Relationships Different?, University of Kansas Center for Banking Excellence Research paper # 2012-1.

DeYoung, R., and Torna, G., 2013. Nontraditional banking activities and bank failures during the financial

crisis, Journal of Financial Intermediation, v. 22, p.397-421. Durguner, S., 2012. Effects of changes in borrower-lender relationships on small business loan contract terms

and credit availability, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Working paper. Elsas, R., 2005. Empirical determinants of relationship lending, Journal of Financial Intermediation 14, 32–57. Elsas, R., Heinemann, F., and Tyrell, M., 2004. Multiple but Asymmetric Bank Financing: The Case of

Relationship Lending, CESifo Working Paper Series No. 1251. Elsas, R., and Krahnen, J.P., 1998. Is relationship lending special? Evidence from credit-file data in Germany,

Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1283-1316. Farinha, L.A., and Santos, J.A.C., 2002. Switching from single to multiple bank lending relationships:

Determinants and implications, Journal of Financial Intermediation 11, 124-151. Frame, W.S., Padhi, M., and Woolsey L., 2004. The Effect of Credit Scoring on Small Business Lending in

Low- and Moderate Income Areas, Financial Review 39, 35-54. Frame, W.S., Srinivasan, A., and Woosley, L., 2001. The Effect of Credit Scoring on Small Business Lending,

Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 33, 813-825. Gilje, E., 2012. Does Local Access To Finance Matter?: Evidence from U.S. Oil and Natural Gas Shale Boom,

Boston College working paper. Hannan, T. H., 2003. Changes in Non-Local Lending to Small Business, Journal of Financial Services Research

24, 31-46.

24

Hannan, T. H., and Prager, R.A., 2006. The profitability of small, single-market banks in an era of multimarket

banking, Finance and Economics Discussion Series (FEDS) 2006-41. Harhoff, D., and Korting, T., 1998. Lending relationships in Germany – Empirical evidence from survey data,

Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 1317-1353. Haynes, G.W., Ou, C., and Berney, R., 1999. Small business borrowing from large and small banks, In: Blanton,

J.L., Williams, A., Rhine, S.L.W. (Eds.), Business Access to Capital and Credit. Federal Reserve System Research Conference, pp. 287-327.

Herrera, A.M., and Minetti, R., 2007. Informed finance and technological change: Evidence from credit

relationships, Journal of Financial Economics 83, 223-269. Houston, J.F., and James, C.M., 1996. Bank information monopolies and the mix of private and public debt

choices, Journal of Finance 51, 1863-1889. Jayaratne, J., and Wolken. J., 1999. How important are small banks to small business lending? New evidence

from a survey of small firms, Journal of Banking and Finance 23, 427–458. Karceski, J., Ongena, S., and Smith, D., 2005. The impact of bank consolidation on commercial borrower

welfare, Journal of Finance 60: 2043–2082. Klein, M., Peek, J., and Rosengren, E., 2002. Troubled banks, impaired foreign direct investment: The role of

relative access to credit, American Economic Review 92, 664-682. Kremp, E., and Sevestre, P., 2013. Did the crisis induce credit rationing for French SMEs?, Journal of Banking

and Finance 37, 10, 3757-3772. Laeven, L., and Levine, R., 2009. Bank governance, regulation and risk taking, Journal of Financial Economics

93, 259-275. Lozano-Vivas, A., and Pasiouras, F., 2010. The impact of non-traditional activities on the estimation of bank

efficiency: International evidence, Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 1436-1449. Machauer, A., and Weber, M., 2000. Number of bank relationships: an indicator of competition, borrower

quality or just size?, Johan Wolfgang Goethe-Universitat Center for Financial Studies Working Paper No. 2000/06.

Mercieca, S., Schaeck, K., and Wolfe, S., 2007. Small European banks: Benefits from diversification?, Journal

of Banking and Finance 31 (7), 1975-1998. Moro, A., and Fink, M., 2013. Loan managers’ trust and credit access for SMEs, Journal of Banking and

Finance 37, 927-936. Ongena, S., Peydró, J., and van Horen, N., 2012. Shocks abroad, pain at home? Bank-firm level evidence on

financial contagion during the recent financial crisis, Tilburg University Working paper. Ongena, S., and Smith, D., 2000. What determines the number of bank relationships? Cross-country evidence,

Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 26-56. Petersen, M.A., and Rajan, R.G., 1994. The benefits of lending relationships: Evidence from small business

data, Journal of Finance 49, 3-37.

25

Petersen, M.A., and Rajan, R.G., 1995. The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships,

Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 407-443. Petersen, M.A., and Rajan, R.G., 2002. The Information Revolution and Small Business Lending: Does

Distance Still Matter?, Journal of Finance 57, 2533-2570. Popov, A., and Udell, G.F., 2012. Cross-border banking, credit access, and the financial crisis, Journal of

International Economics 87, 147-161. Rajan, R.G., 1992. Insiders and outsiders: The choice between informed and Arm’s-length debt, Journal of

Finance 47, 1367-1400. Rice, T. and Strahan, P.E., 2010. Does credit competition affect small-firm finance?, Journal of Finance 65, 861-

889. Rosenfeld, C.M., 2011. The Effect of Banking Relationships on the Future of Financially Distressed Firms,

College of William and Mary working paper. Scott, J.A., 2004. Small business and value of community financial institutions, Journal of Financial Services

Research 25, 207-230. Sharpe, S.A., 1990. Asymmetric information, bank lending, and implicit contracts: A stylized model of

customer relationships, Journal of Finance 45, 1069-87. Stein, J.C., 2002. Information production and capital allocation: Decentralized vs. hierarchical firms, Journal of

Finance 57, 1891-1921. U.S. Small Business Administration, Office of Advocacy, 2010. Frequently Asked Questions about Small

Business Finance. Washington: Small Business Administration. Van Ewijk, S., and Arnold, I., 2013. How bank business models drive interest margins: Evidence from US bank-

level data, Nyenrode Business Universiteit working paper. Von Thadden, E., 1992. The commitment of finance, duplicated monitoring, and the investment horizon, CEPR

Working Paper No. 27. Williamson, O., 1988. Corporate finance and corporate governance, Journal of Finance 43, 567-91.

Variable DescriptionFirm characteristics

Indicator if small firm Equals one if firm has assets less than or equal to $100,000, zero otherwise.

Indicator if medium firm Equals one if firm has assets greater than $100,000 and less than or equal to $1 million, zero otherwise.

Indicator if large firm Equals one if firm has assets greater than $1 million, zero otherwise.Percent minority owned Percentage of firm ownership that is non-white.

Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments Equals one if firm has been 60 or more days delinquent on business obligations at least once within the past three years, zero otherwise.

Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) Firm's credit score as obtained from Dun and Bradstreet.Leverage ratio of firm Ratio of firm debt to equity.Indicator if firm has a bank loan Equals one if firm has any type of bank loan, zero otherwise.

Firm age How many years ago was the firm established/purchased/acquired by the current owners.

Indicator if firm has declared bankruptcy Equals one if the firm has declared bankruptcy within the last seven years, zero otherwise.

Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager Equals one if owner is responsible for day-to-day management of the business, zero otherwise.

Indicator if family owned Equals one if the firm was owned exclusively by members of the same family, zero otherwise.

Indicator if proprietorship Equals one if the firm is a sole proprietorship, zero otherwise.Indicator if partnership Equals one if the firm is a partnership, zero otherwise.Indicator if corporation Equals one if the firm is a S or C corporation, zero otherwise.

Main bank characteristicsIndicator if main bank is large Equal one if the main bank has assets greater than $1 billion, zero otherwise.

Indicator if main bank is multimarket Equals one if the main bank has offices in multiple (metropolitan or rural) markets, zero otherwise.

Indicator if main bank is nonlocal Equals one if the main bank does not have an office in the firm's local market, zero otherwise.

Indicator if main bank is megabank Equals one if the main bank is large, multimarket, and nonlocal.Gross total assets of main bank ($ thousands) Shown here in levels but used in logs in regressions.

Number of markets of main bank The number of Metropolitan Statistical Areas in which the main bank has operations.

Equity to asset ratio of main bank Ratio of equity to total assets of main bank.NPL ratio of main bank Ratio of non-performing loans to total loans of main bank.

Illiquidity of main bank Berger and Bouwman's (2009) preferred liquidity creation measure divided by gross total assets of the main bank.

Fee income from deposits divided by total revenue of main bank Ratio of service charges on deposit accounts to total revenue.

Z-score of main bank

[Average (ROA) + Average (Equity/Gross Total Assets)]/Standard deviation of ROA, where the means of ROA and Equity/GTA as well as the standard deviation of ROA are computed over the previous 12 quarters. For banks with less than 12 consecutive quarters, we construct a Z-score using data using 8-11 quarters.

Main banking relationship characteristicsIndicator if firm has exclusive relationship with main bank Equals one if firm has a relationship with only main bank, zero otherwise.Length of relationship with main bank (years) Shown here in levels but used in logs in regressions.

Market controls

Large bank share of offices (percent)Percentage of offices with gross total assets greater than $1 billion in the market, where the market is the Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) or New England County Metropolitan Areas (NECMA).

Multimarket bank share of offices (percent) Percentage of offices in banks with offices in multiple (metropolitan and rural) markets.

Local bank offices per capita Offices per 1000 population in the local market.

Market concentration (HHI) Sum of the squared shares of deposits held by all banks in the firm’s local market.

Branching restriction indexRice and Strahan's (2010) time-varying index capturing state-level differences in regulatory constraints between 1994 and 2005, which takes the values between 0 and 4, with 0 being the least restrictive (most open).

Table 1Panel A: Variable descriptions

This panel reports variable names and descriptions.

26

Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev.Firm characteristics

Indicator if small firm 2,610 0.383 0.486Indicator if large firm 2,610 0.297 0.457Indicator if medium firm 2,610 0.321 0.467Percent minority owned 2,610 0.132 0.339Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 2,610 0.165 0.371Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) 2,610 3.893 1.468Leverage ratio of firm 2,610 0.328 0.388Indicator if firm has a bank loan 2,610 0.505 0.500Firm age 2,610 16.645 12.250Indicator if firm has declared bankruptcy 2,610 0.008 0.091

Owner characteristicsIndicator if owner is manager 2,610 0.884 0.320Indicator if family owned 2,610 0.815 0.389Indicator if proprietorship 2,610 0.263 0.440Indicator if partnership 2,610 0.050 0.218Indicator if corporation 2,610 0.687 0.464

Main bank characteristicsIndicator if main bank is large 2,610 0.763 0.425Indicator if main bank is multimarket 2,610 0.634 0.482Indicator if main bank is nonlocal 2,610 0.606 0.489Indicator if main bank is megabank 2,583 0.456 0.498Gross total assets of main bank ($ thousands) 2,610 1.41E+08 2.04E+08Number of markets of main bank 2,610 129.445 161.119Equity to asset ratio of main bank 2,583 0.090 0.026NPL ratio of main bank 2,583 0.013 0.010Illiquidity of main bank 2,583 0.442 0.144Fee income from deposits divided by total revenue of main bank 2,583 0.086 0.038Z-score of main bank 2,583 42.809 32.818

Main banking relationship characteristicsIndicator if firm has exclusive relationship with main bank 2,583 0.570 0.495Length of relationship with main bank (years) 2,583 11.229 10.122

Market controlsLarge bank share of offices (percent) 2,610 79.240 14.758Multimarket share of offices (percent) 2,610 0.492 0.238Local bank offices per capita 2,610 0.093 0.157Market concentration (HHI) 2,610 0.137 0.061Branching restriction index 2,610 2.093 1.298

Table 1Panel B: Summary Statistics

This panel reports summary statistics. Data from most of the variables are from the 2003 Survey of Small Business Finance (SSBF) combined with the 2003:Q4 Bank Call Reports and June 2003 Summary of Deposits. The Z-score variable is from the 2001:Q1 - 2003:Q4 Bank Call Reports.

27

(1) (2) (3)

Main bank is large bank

Main bank is multimarket

bankMain bank is nonlocal bank

Firm characteristicsIndicator if medium firm 1.028 1.050 0.981

(0.180) (0.381) (-0.151)Indicator if large firm 0.869 0.853 0.853

(-0.686) (-0.854) (-0.863)Percent minority owned 1.781*** 1.619*** 1.237

(2.658) (2.929) (1.352)Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 0.896 1.000 1.141

(-0.601) (-0.000) (0.840)Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) 1.007 1.054 1.026

(0.140) (1.300) (0.626)Leverage ratio of firm 0.836 0.844 1.140

(-1.037) (-1.193) (0.918)Firm age (log years) 1.009 1.001 1.002

(1.296) (0.153) (0.450)Indicator if firm declared bankruptcy 0.540 0.674 0.331**

(-1.204) (-0.740) (-2.032)Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager 1.076 1.371 0.732(0.268) (1.296) (-1.270)

Indicator if family owned 0.919 0.954 0.996(-0.407) (-0.273) (-0.025)

Indicator if partnership 1.280 1.998** 1.027(0.715) (2.420) (0.099)

Indicator if corporation 0.977 1.089 0.816(-0.143) (0.642) (-1.535)

Market controlsLarge bank share of offices 1.059***

(11.998)Multimarket share of offices 3.676***

(5.287)Local bank offices per capita 0.065***

(-3.502)Market concentration (HHI) 17.053** 1.488 0.061***

(2.172) (0.416) (-2.834)Branching restriction index 1.000 0.946 1.025

(0.000) (-1.248) (0.571)

Observations 2,610 2,610 2,610Pseudo R2 0.1300 0.0299 0.0350

Robust z-statistics of the hypothesis that the odds ratios equal one are given in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 2Panel A: Determinants of main bank type (main results)

Regressions are weighted by survey weights to account for disproportionate sampling and nonresponse, and include a constant term and a set of one-digit SIC indicator variables to control for industry effects (not shown). We present estimates as odds ratios, which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. An odds ratio of one would indicate that the regressor has no effect on the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. An odds ratio greater/less than one indicates that an increase in the regressor increases/decreases the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one.

28

(1) (2) (3)

Main bank is large bank

Main bank is multimarket

bankMain bank is nonlocal bank

Firm characteristicsIndicator if medium firm 0.964 1.042 0.997

(-0.258) (0.331) (-0.022)Indicator if large firm 0.852 0.873 0.892

(-0.814) (-0.746) (-0.631)Percent minority owned 1.996*** 1.611*** 1.216

(3.238) (2.895) (1.257)Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 1.034 0.999 1.159

(0.195) (-0.009) (0.939)Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) 1.027 1.057 1.033

(0.598) (1.359) (0.807)Leverage ratio of firm 0.767* 0.856 1.157

(-1.685) (-1.125) (1.055)Firm age (log years) 1.007 1.001 1.001

(1.049) (0.195) (0.161)Indicator if firm declared bankruptcy 0.376* 0.669 0.379*

(-1.866) (-0.738) (-1.752)Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager 0.934 1.333 0.745(-0.262) (1.223) (-1.264)

Indicator if family owned 0.963 0.973 1.029(-0.194) (-0.165) (0.176)

Indicator if partnership 1.427 2.055*** 0.940(1.110) (2.600) (-0.226)

Indicator if corporation 1.010 1.105 0.756**(0.064) (0.759) (-2.141)

Market controlsLarge bank share of offices

Multimarket share of offices

Local bank offices per capita

Market concentration (HHI)

Branching restriction index

Observations 2,610 2,610 2,610Pseudo R2 0.0226 0.0149 0.0135

Robust z-statistics of the hypothesis that the odds ratios equal one are given in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 2Panel B: Determinants of main bank type (no market controls)

Regressions are weighted by survey weights to account for disproportionate sampling and nonresponse, and include a constant term and a set of one-digit SIC indicator variables to control for industry effects (not shown). We present estimates as odds ratios, which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. An odds ratio of one would indicate that the regressor has no effect on the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. An odds ratio greater/less than one indicates that an increase in the regressor increases/decreases the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one.

29

(1) (2) (3)

Main bank is large bank

Main bank is multimarket

bankMain bank is nonlocal bank

Firm characteristicsIndicator if medium firm 1.030 1.057 0.960

(0.202) (0.449) (-0.339)Indicator if large firm 0.877 0.851 0.853

(-0.715) (-0.950) (-0.962)Percent minority owned 1.779*** 1.586*** 1.251

(2.646) (2.822) (1.408)Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 0.888 0.990 1.119

(-0.653) (-0.065) (0.722)Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) 1.006 1.057 1.016

(0.123) (1.379) (0.392)Leverage ratio of firm 0.838 0.864 1.101

(-1.062) (-1.053) (0.689)Firm age (log years) 1.008 0.999 1.004

(1.260) (-0.122) (0.746)Indicator if firm declared bankruptcy 0.554 0.693 0.339**

(-1.169) (-0.704) (-2.031)Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager

Indicator if family owned

Indicator if partnership

Indicator if corporation

Market controlsLarge bank share of offices 1.059***

(11.993)Multimarket share of offices 3.683***

(5.265)Local bank offices per capita 0.060***

(-3.640)Market concentration (HHI) 17.540** 1.601 0.063***

(2.198) (0.497) (-2.783)Branching restriction index 0.999 0.947 1.022

(-0.028) (-1.236) (0.498)

Observations 2,610 2,610 2,610Pseudo R2 0.1300 0.0258 0.0326

Robust z-statistics of the hypothesis that the odds ratios equal one are given in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 2Panel C: Determinants of main bank type (no owner characteristics)

Regressions are weighted by survey weights to account for disproportionate sampling and nonresponse, and include a constant term and a set of one-digit SIC indicator variables to control for industry effects (not shown). We present estimates as odds ratios, which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. An odds ratio of one would indicate that the regressor has no effect on the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. An odds ratio greater/less than one indicates that an increase in the regressor increases/decreases the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one.

30

(1) (2) (3)

Main bank is large bank

Main bank is multimarket

bankMain bank is nonlocal bank

Firm characteristicsIndicator if medium firm 0.924 1.079 0.986

(-0.400) (0.522) (-0.098)Indicator if large firm 0.914 0.905 0.880

(-0.390) (-0.496) (-0.519)Percent minority owned 1.865** 1.371* 0.854

(2.236) (1.893) (-0.832)Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 0.839 0.960 1.173

(-0.845) (-0.240) (0.827)Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) 0.969 1.050 1.003

(-0.503) (1.073) (0.068)Leverage ratio of firm 0.781 0.871 1.491**

(-1.149) (-0.877) (2.328)Firm age (log years) 1.014* 0.998 1.000

(1.748) (-0.293) (0.013)Indicator if firm declared bankruptcy 0.873 1.152 0.392*

(-0.257) (0.194) (-1.867)Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager 1.204 1.581* 0.630*(0.668) (1.776) (-1.699)

Indicator if family owned 0.828 0.961 0.991(-0.819) (-0.224) (-0.047)

Indicator if partnership 1.295 2.152*** 0.765(0.643) (2.807) (-0.855)

Indicator if corporation 1.217 1.180 0.755*(0.986) (1.134) (-1.762)

Market controlsLarge bank share of offices 1.069***

(10.740)Multimarket share of offices 2.073***

(2.650)Local bank offices per capita 0.007***

(-4.902)Market concentration (HHI) 144.435*** 0.472 0.004***

(3.000) (-0.771) (-5.007)Branching restriction index 1.010 0.982 1.078

(0.144) (-0.370) (1.429)Additional right hand side controls

Indicator if main bank is large 5.977*** 14.560***(11.025) (14.318)

Indicator if main bank is multimarket 5.451*** 2.725***(10.155) (6.959)

Indicator if main bank is nonlocal 15.674*** 2.192***(13.570) (5.561)

Observations 2,610 2,610 2,610Pseudo R2 0.436 0.176 0.272

Robust z-statistics of the hypothesis that the odds ratios equal one are given in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 2Panel D: Determinants of main bank type (additional right hand side controls)

Regressions are weighted by survey weights to account for disproportionate sampling and nonresponse, and include a constant term and a set of one-digit SIC indicator variables to control for industry effects (not shown). We present estimates as odds ratios, which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. An odds ratio of one would indicate that the regressor has no effect on the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. An odds ratio greater/less than one indicates that an increase in the regressor increases/decreases the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one.

31

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Log of main bank's total assets

Log of main bank's total assets

Log of main bank's total assets

Ordered logit of main bank's number of

markets of operation

Ordered logit of main bank's number of

markets of operation

Ordered logit of main bank's number of

markets of operation

Firm characteristicsIndicator if medium firm -0.098 -0.157 -0.082 0.996 1.037 1.185

(-0.609) (-1.322) (-0.970) (-0.035) (0.184) (0.714)Indicator if large firm -0.345 -0.221 -0.152 0.812 0.904 1.215

(-1.553) (-1.469) (-1.568) (-1.154) (-0.395) (0.802)Percent minority owned 0.752*** 0.470*** 0.328*** 1.430** 1.093 0.718

(4.085) (3.684) (3.373) (2.211) (0.470) (-1.378)Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 0.019 -0.011 0.177 0.966 0.759 0.505**

(0.096) (-0.079) (1.548) (-0.216) (-1.133) (-2.108)Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) -0.016 -0.049 -0.015 1.002 0.973 0.960

(-0.311) (-1.376) (-0.579) (0.042) (-0.473) (-0.548)Leverage ratio of firm -0.292 -0.314*** -0.130 0.793* 0.711* 0.894

(-1.613) (-2.633) (-1.516) (-1.654) (-1.781) (-0.446)Firm age (log years) 0.010 0.008** 0.007** 1.004 1.001 0.996

(1.459) (2.001) (2.424) (0.750) (0.136) (-0.467)Indicator if firm declared bankruptcy -0.208 0.406 -0.356 0.892 6.797* 9.280*

(-0.278) (0.887) (-1.629) (-0.229) (1.933) (1.771)Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager 0.069 0.029 0.203 0.649* 0.541* 0.500*(0.243) (0.177) (1.549) (-1.710) (-1.939) (-1.824)

Indicator if family owned -0.187 -0.177 -0.119 1.012 1.039 1.590*(-0.872) (-1.362) (-1.174) (0.071) (0.200) (1.841)

Indicator if partnership 0.403 0.083 0.227 0.817 0.592* 0.283***(1.127) (0.369) (1.333) (-0.727) (-1.706) (-2.771)

Indicator if corporation -0.141 -0.022 0.060 0.896 0.981 1.002(-0.841) (-0.187) (0.761) (-0.823) (-0.097) (0.007)

Market controlsLarge bank share of offices 0.069*** 0.046*** 0.032***

(13.747) (12.899) (12.118)Multimarket share of offices 6.054*** 2.235** 2.715**

(7.310) (2.352) (2.313)Market concentration (HHI) -0.512 1.389* -2.107*** 31.497*** 62.653*** 242.776***

(-0.440) (1.818) (-3.314) (3.181) (3.140) (3.671)Branching restriction index 0.159*** 0.109*** -0.075*** 1.022 1.159** 1.175**

(2.916) (2.798) (-3.077) (0.491) (2.361) (2.433)Additional right hand side controls

Main bank is large bank 38.600***(12.366)

Gross total assets of main bank (log $ thousands) 2.633***(14.815)

Main bank is multimarket bank 2.523***(21.784)

Number of markets of main bank (log) 1.127***(50.678)

Main bank is nonlocal bank 2.435*** 0.220* 9.409*** 4.986***(19.596) (1.877) (13.291) (7.221)

Observations 2,610 2,610 2,610 2,610 2,610 2,610R2 0.144 0.593 0.798Pseudo R2 0.0461 0.4549 0.6407

Robust z-statistics of the hypothesis that the coeffiecients equal zero (cols. 1-3) or odds ratio equal zero (cols. 4-6) are given in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 2Panel E: Determinants of main bank type (using bank assets instead of large bank dummy and number of markets instead of multimarket dummy)

The regressions in columns 1-3 use the log of main bank assets as the dependent variable in an OLS regression and the regressions in columns 4-6 are ordered logit models of the main bank's number of markets of operation using the categories 1, 2-5, 6-20, and over 20 markets. Regressions are weighted by survey weights to account for disproportionate sampling and nonresponse, and include a constant term and a set of one-digit SIC indicator variables to control for industry effects (not shown). We present OLS coefficients in columns 1-3. In columns 4-6 we present estimates as odds ratios, which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. An odds ratio of one would indicate that the regressor has no effect on the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. An odds ratio greater/less than one indicates that an increase in the regressor increases/decreases the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one.

32

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Firm has exclusive relationship

Length of relationship

Firm has exclusive relationship

Length of relationship

Firm has exclusive relationship

Length of relationship

Firm characteristicsIndicator if medium firm 0.480*** 0.042 0.482*** 0.046 0.483*** 0.049

(-5.726) (1.012) (-5.677) (1.102) (-5.655) (1.183)Indicator if large firm 0.346*** 0.048 0.347*** 0.050 0.348*** 0.052

(-5.954) (0.815) (-5.929) (0.846) (-5.950) (0.886)Percent minority owned 0.781 -0.029 0.786 -0.020 0.771 -0.041

(-1.549) (-0.671) (-1.517) (-0.460) (-1.627) (-0.945)Indicator if firm is delinquent on payments 0.809 0.016 0.804 0.008 0.806 0.014

(-1.312) (0.283) (-1.357) (0.141) (-1.342) (0.264)Firm risk rating (6 is safest; 1 is riskiest) 0.970 0.050*** 0.970 0.050*** 0.971 0.051***

(-0.737) (3.400) (-0.732) (3.378) (-0.706) (3.469)Leverage ratio of firm 0.371*** -0.058 0.369*** -0.066 0.373*** -0.050

(-6.910) (-1.239) (-6.947) (-1.403) (-6.851) (-1.057)Firm age (log years) 0.998 0.034*** 0.998 0.034*** 0.998 0.034***

(-0.363) (15.397) (-0.368) (15.403) (-0.391) (15.403)Indicator if firm declared bankruptcy 1.274 0.249 1.275 0.249 1.261 0.226

(0.460) (1.344) (0.462) (1.367) (0.437) (1.206)Owner characteristics

Indicator if owner is manager 0.885 0.059 0.889 0.068 0.884 0.061(-0.560) (0.961) (-0.540) (1.085) (-0.565) (0.989)

Indicator if family owned 0.796 0.089* 0.797 0.090* 0.800 0.095*(-1.309) (1.697) (-1.304) (1.685) (-1.282) (1.801)

Indicator if partnership 1.721* -0.082 1.722* -0.075 1.717* -0.082(1.754) (-0.843) (1.759) (-0.766) (1.754) (-0.841)

Indicator if corporation 1.296** -0.063 1.297** -0.061 1.300** -0.061(1.968) (-1.462) (1.973) (-1.402) (1.989) (-1.414)

Main bank characteristicsIndicator if main bank is large 1.149 0.158***

(0.804) (2.793)Indicator if main bank is multimarket 1.070 0.090**

(0.498) (2.050)Indicator if main bank is nonlocal 0.993 -0.042 0.965 -0.099**

(-0.048) (-0.932) (-0.228) (-2.050)Indicator if main bank is megabank 1.120 0.090**

(0.879) (2.189)Gross total assets of main bank (log $ thousands) 1.046 0.040***

(0.994) (2.794)Number of markets of main bank (log) 0.989 0.013

(-0.167) (0.652)Equity to asset ratio of main bank 0.003** 0.622 0.002** 0.338 0.006* 1.161*

(-2.200) (1.022) (-2.325) (0.556) (-1.916) (1.784)NPL ratio of main bank 0.034 -3.329 0.037 -3.224 0.022 -4.030

(-0.632) (-1.064) (-0.613) (-0.997) (-0.714) (-1.319)Illiquidity of main bank 0.586 -0.113 0.600 -0.079 0.586 -0.114

(-1.404) (-0.872) (-1.354) (-0.609) (-1.425) (-0.885)Fee income from deposits divided by total revenue of main bank 1.844 0.282 1.855 0.338 1.625 -0.051

(0.375) (0.515) (0.383) (0.641) (0.286) (-0.091)Z-score of main bank 0.996** -0.000 0.996** -0.000 0.997* 0.000

(-2.061) (-0.257) (-2.044) (-0.346) (-1.906) (0.268)Market controls

Large bank share of offices 1.006 -0.002* 1.007* -0.001 1.005 -0.003**(1.417) (-1.739) (1.806) (-0.640) (1.241) (-2.183)

Multimarket share of offices 0.815 -0.108 0.790 -0.140 0.819 -0.112(-0.792) (-1.207) (-0.908) (-1.562) (-0.771) (-1.247)

Local bank offices per capita 0.590 -0.100 0.621 -0.036 0.593 -0.099(-1.291) (-0.799) (-1.195) (-0.291) (-1.326) (-0.849)

Market concentration (HHI) 0.678 0.200 0.740 0.300 0.722 0.214(-0.357) (0.659) (-0.276) (0.976) (-0.293) (0.700)

Branching restriction index 1.171*** 0.010 1.169*** 0.009 1.166*** 0.003(3.501) (0.706) (3.466) (0.581) (3.393) (0.230)

Observations 2,583 2,583 2,583 2,583 2,583 2,583R2 0.263 0.257 0.269Pseudo R2 0.0743 0.0740 0.0746

Robust z-statistics of the hypothesis that odds ratio equal one (cols. 1, 3 and 5) or coefficients equal zero (cols. 2, 4 and 6) are given in parentheses.*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Table 3Determinants of main bank relationship strength

The regressions in columns 1-2 are our main results for relationship strength; the regressions in columns 3-4 replace the three dummies for main bank type with a megabank dummy, which equals one if the main bank is large, multimarket, and nonlocal, and zero otherwise; and the regressions in columns 5-6 use the log of the main bank's assets in place of the main bank large dummy and log of the main bank's markets of operation in place of the main bank multimarket dummy. Regressions are weighted by survey weights to account for disproportionate sampling and nonresponse, and include constant term and a set of one-digit SIC indicator variables to control for industry effects (not shown). We present estimates of the logit specification in columns 1, 3 and 5 as odds ratios, which are obtained by exponentiating the original logit coefficients. An odds ratio of one would indicate that the regressor has no effect on the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. An odds ratio greater/less than one indicates that an increase in the regressor increases/decreases the probability that the dependent variable takes a value of one. We present estimates of the OLS specification in columns 2, 4 and 6 as coefficients.

Main resultsMegabank dummy replacing main bank

type dummies

Log of assets replacing main bank dummy and log of number of markets

replacing multimarket dummy

33


Recommended