+ All Categories
Home > Documents > DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf ·...

DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf ·...

Date post: 15-Mar-2018
Category:
Upload: vannhu
View: 215 times
Download: 3 times
Share this document with a friend
31
DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú DT DECON DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE SUPPLY IN PERU Nº 448 Luis García Erika Collantes DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA
Transcript
Page 1: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del PerúDEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍAPontificia Universidad Católica del Perú

DEPARTAMENTO DEECONOMÍA

DTDECON

DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO

EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE SUPPLY IN PERU

Nº 448

Luis GarcíaErika Collantes

DEPARTAMENTO DEECONOMÍA

Page 2: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448

EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY IN PERU

Luis García Erika Collantes

Diciembre, 2017

DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA

DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO 448 http://files.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf

Page 3: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

Effect of the Juntos social program on female labor supply in Peru Documento de Trabajo 448 © Luis García y Erika Collantes (autores) Editado e Impreso: © Departamento de Economía – Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú,

Av. Universitaria 1801, Lima 32 – Perú. Teléfono: (51-1) 626-2000 anexos 4950 - 4951 [email protected]

http://departamento.pucp.edu.pe/economia/publicaciones/documentos-de-trabajo/

Encargado de la Serie: Jorge Rojas Rojas

Departamento de Economía – Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú,

[email protected]

Primera edición – Diciembre, 2017.

Tiraje: 50 ejemplares

Hecho el Depósito Legal en la Biblioteca Nacional del Perú Nº 2017-17638

ISSN 2079-8466 (Impresa)

ISSN 2079-8474 (En línea)

Se terminó de imprimir en diciembre de 2017.

Page 4: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

1

Effect of the Juntos social program on female labor supply in Peru

Luis García1 and Erika Collantes2

Abstract

Over the last ten years, the Peruvian conditional transfer program, Juntos, has expanded

significantly. The objective of this program is to promote school attendance, reduce

child labor, and monitor the growth and development of children in impoverished areas.

Although improvements in these indicators have been appreciated, there may be

unforeseen impacts on the households receiving the transfers. In this study, we focus

on the program’s impact on the working hours of women in recipient households.

According to the standard theory (Becker, 1965), transfers could reduce the labor supply

by assuming leisure to be a normal good. According to theories of family economics,

transfers to one member can affect the allocation of resources to all members of the

household (Chiappori, 1992). The international empirical literature is inconclusive,

pointing to non-existent, negative, and even positive effects (Alzúa, Cruces and Ripani,

2012; Gassman and Trindade, 2016). In the Peruvian case, the most similar study is that

of Fernández and Saldarriaga (2014), who study the impact of the closeness of the

program payment date on female labor supply, finding a negative effect during the week

of payment. Our study goes further, in that: (i) we consider that transfers could result in

a reallocation of resources within the household; (ii) we quantify the changes in working

hours from one year to the next as a result of the program; (iii) in the light of structural

econometric models, we control the main biases (unobservable heterogeneity, selection

bias, and endogeneity), since it is not possible to apply an experimental design. Using

the panel component of Peru’s National Household Survey (Encuesta Nacional de

Hogares del Perú), we find that the Juntos program reduces the paid work of women in

beneficiary households by nine hours per week.

Keywords: Conditional transfer programs, Juntos program, unforeseen impacts,

selection bias, unobservable heterogeneity.

JEL codes: C23, I38, J22

1 Department of Economics, Pontificia Universidad Catolica del Peru ([email protected]) 2 Department of Economics, Pontificia Universidad Catolica del Peru ([email protected]) * A preliminary version of this paper was presented at the conference of the Latin American Studies Association (LASA 2017). The authors are grateful to the participants for their comments.

Page 5: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

2

Resumen

En los últimos diez años, el Perú ha experimentado una importante expansión del

programa de transferencias condicionadas Juntos. El objetivo de este programa es

incentivar la asistencia escolar, reducir el trabajo infantil y seguir el crecimiento y

desarrollo de los niños en zonas de pobreza. Se han observado mejoras en estos

indicadores; sin embargo, pueden existir impactos no previstos en el hogar que recibe

la transferencia. Este estudio se enfoca en el impacto sobre las horas de trabajo de las

mujeres de hogares beneficiarios. Según la teoría estándar (Becker, 1965), las

transferencias pueden reducir la oferta laboral asumiendo al ocio como un bien normal.

Según las teorías de la economía familiar, las transferencias a un miembro pueden

afectar la asignación de recursos de todos los miembros dentro del hogar (Chiappori,

1992). La literatura empírica internacional no es concluyente, mostrando efectos nulos,

negativos o inclusive positivos (Alzúa, Cruces y Ripani, 2012; Gassman y Trindade, 2016).

En el caso peruano, el estudio más cercano es el de Fernández y Saldarriaga (2014),

quienes estudian el impacto de la proximidad de la fecha de pago del programa Juntos

en la oferta laboral femenina, encontrando un efecto negativo. Nuestro estudio va más

allá porque: (i) considera que las transferencias pueden ocasionar una reasignación de

los recursos dentro del hogar; (ii) cuantifica los cambios en las horas de trabajo de un

año a otro como consecuencia del programa; (iii) a la luz de modelos econométricos

estructurales, controlamos los principales sesgos (heterogeneidad inobservable, sesgo

de selección y endogeneidad), dado que no se puede aplicar un diseño experimental.

Utilizando la Encuesta Nacionales de Hogares Panel del Perú de 2011-2013,

encontramos que el programa Juntos reduce 9 horas semanales el trabajo remunerado

de las mujeres de hogares beneficiarios.

Palabras Clave: Programas de transferencias condicionadas, programa Juntos, Impactos

imprevistos, sesgo de selección, heterogeneidad inobservable.

Códigos JEL: C23, I38, J22

Page 6: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

1

Effect of the Juntos social program on female labor supply in Peru

Luis García and Erika Collantes

1. Introduction

In recent years, there has been a significant global expansion in social programs oriented

towards the poorest. Peru has been running a conditional transfer program called Juntos

since 2005, covering the population living in poverty. The objective of this program is to

ensure that school-aged children attend school and undergo periodic health checks. The

transfer is paid to mothers, conditional upon fulfillment of the stipulated program

commitments.

There is a wealth of empirical literature to support the contention that conditional

transfer programs have made a clear impact on school attendance, reducing child labor,

and certain improvements in the field of health and nutrition (Fiszbein and Shady, 2009;

Manley, Gitter and Slavchevska, 2013). However, the doubt remains about whether the

design of such programs might have unforeseen impacts that could either increase and

strengthen household welfare or harm it in some way. One such unforeseen impact is

that on the labor supply of women from beneficiary households.

Standard economic theory predicts that a cash transfer to individuals will decrease their

willingness to work, both in terms of labor participation and hours worked. Family

economics extends the model to propose that transfers may cause a reallocation of

resources, with the impact possibly depending on the bargaining power of individual

household members. As such, we are interested in determining whether the Juntos

program that has been massively implemented over the last decade has made any

impact on the working hours of women from beneficiary households. The female

population is important because of the well-known gender inequality of labor

participation, whereby women participate less than men on the job market and the

elasticity of the female labor supply tends to be greater than the male equivalent given

their traditional role in the household (Kumar and Liang, 2016).

The international empirical literature on this subject is inconclusive, pointing to null,

negative, and even positive effects (Alzúa, Cruces and Ripani, 2012; Gassman and

Trindade, 2016). In the Peruvian case, the closest study to ours is that by Fernández and

Saldarriaga (2014), who analyze the impact of closeness to the program payment date

on the female labor supply and find a negative effect during the week of payment.

Our study goes further than that of Fernández and Saldarriaga (2014), because: (i) we

consider that transfers could result in a reallocation of resources within the household

Page 7: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

2

including time spent working; (ii) we use the available data to quantify the changes in

working hours from one year to the next as a result of the program; (iii) in the light of

structural econometric models, we control the main biases (unobservable

heterogeneity, selection bias, and endogeneity); this is because it is not possible to apply

an experimental design, as the program’s allocation was not random but targeted ad

hoc at certain regions and geared towards populations living in poverty. Thus, we will

quantify the causal effect by way of a structural econometric study, because of the lack

of experimental data and because the structural model takes into account decisions

within the households as well as causal relationships, unlike impact evaluation studies

which do not usually feature such analysis (Gaarder et al., 2010).

In this study, we center on the impact on paid work of women. Remunerated work is

known to mean working outside the house, and there are studies that propose that

conditional transfer programs could be encouraging unpaid participation in family

businesses or housework (Streuli, 2012; Escobal and Benites, 2012; Jones et al. 2007).

Thus, it would be interesting to study the impact of these programs on remunerated

work, given the implications of women leaving the job market.

Based on the theoretical literature, we hypothesize that the impact of the Juntos

program on remunerated working hours is negative. The results of our study show that

this impact has indeed been negative and significant, providing evidence of the income

effect on remunerated working hours given an increase in unearned income, or in the

monetary transfer. In this study we do not make a value judgement on whether the

effects we find are good or bad in terms of welfare; we simply present the evidence we

encounter.

The paper is organized as follows: In Section 2 we present a review of the theoretical

and empirical literature on the subject. In Section 3 we set out the econometric

methodology, in which we discuss the main economic problems we come up against and

solve. In Section 4 we define the variables and present a brief analysis of the sample

data. In Section 5 we show the main results. Finally, in Section 6 we conclude.

2. Theoretical framework

2.1. Theoretical literature

Economic literature abounds with studies on the impact of government transfers and

social programs on the labor supply. In this section we break down the theoretical

studies into those in which the decision to work is made on an individual basis (one-

person households); and those in which a person’s labor supply interacts with that of

other members of the household (multi-person households).

Page 8: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

3

2.1.1. The individual labor supply model

This concerns a basic neoclassical model of labor supply in a single period (see, for

example, Blundell and McCurdy, 1999) in which an person decides between two goods,

one a consumption good and the other leisure time, both of which provide individual

welfare. This person faces two restrictions; one is time-related, where the total amount

of time available is divided between leisure time and time spent in paid work. The other

restriction is budget-related, and corresponds to the spending limit on the consumer

good, which is financed through earned income (hours worked multiplied by wage

earned) plus an unearned income. The microeconomic theory shows that an increase in

unearned income will result in a reduction in the labor supply (Becker, 1965, p. 501).

This model was extended by Gronau (1976), who considered domestic work to be an

additional activity to leisure and work outside the house. Gronau’s model proposes that

given an increase in unearned income, there will be a reduction in hours worked due to

the increase in leisure hours, without affecting domestic work. In the case of individuals

who do not work (that is, those who only engage in domestic work and leisure), the

aforementioned increase will entail an increase in leisure time at the expense of time

spent on domestic work.

However, when it comes to welfare programs, as Moffitt (2002) points out, the outlook

is a little more complex than the basic neoclassical model proposes. First, welfare

programs can take a variety of forms, including conditional or unconditional monetary

transfers, tax relief, and in-kind transfers. Second, these programs are usually applicable

to lower-income population groups. That is, individuals are eligible for programs if they

demonstrate that they meet the requirements for participation, which include having a

low income (mean-tested programs). Moreover, if the earnings of these individuals

increase over time, they may no longer be eligible to participate in these programs. This

creates the possibility that individuals could make decisions to ensure program

eligibility, at their convenience. An important fact that is not taken into account in the

basic model is that many individuals who are eligible for programs may not wish to

participate in them. According to Moffitt (2002), there are two possible rationalizations

for this behavior. One is that there may be a certain degree of stigma attached to

participating in the program, which could reduce individual utility. The other is that

there are costs associated with taking part in these programs (time, effort, “hassle”

costs, etc.), which could discourage individuals from participating.1

In this model, if the monetary transfer to the eligible group is increased, the labor supply

could decrease, because: (a) there could be individuals who decide to work less to

reduce their income in order to become eligible for the program; (b) some who are

already on the program could reduce their working hours due to a pure income effect;

1 In addition, there could be non-convexities in the budgetary restrictions, precisely in the area in which the person could change their eligibility status.

Page 9: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

4

and (c) eligible individuals who did not previously wish to join the program could change

their minds if any increase in the transfer exceeded the costs of being on the program

(Moffitt, 2002, p.2417).

2.1.2. The family labor supply model

A number of studies have extended the standard one-person model of labor supply to

reflect the fact that there may be more than one member of a household who is willing

to supply working hours on the job market. The simplest way to approach the family

economy is through a family utility-family budget model in which the function of

household utility is a single entity, and depends on the aggregate consumption of all

members and the number of hours worked by each. Moreover, this model assumes that

the income generated through the work of household members goes into a common

purse, used to fund family purchases. Any financial transfers to individual members

would end up forming part of this common purse.

However, various studies have shown that this model is not suitable for the study of

family decisions, whether theoretical or empirical (Chiappori, 1992; Quisumbing and

Maluccio, 1999). For this reason, other models assume different and separate utility

functions for the head of household and his or her spouse, with budgetary restrictions

that are not necessarily common, and family decisions may be influenced by the

individual with the most bargaining power in the household. This has given rise to a

strand known as “collective” whose models contribute to an explanation of how the

allocation of resources are determined within the household. Chiappori (1992) finds a

sharing rule that is endogenously determined in the model, depending on the earnings

of each individual and on non-labor income. This sharing rule determines how a transfer

received can be distributed among the members of a household.

In the light of these models, a cash transfer disbursed to mothers would not necessarily

have the same effect as in the case of the one-person model, since it is possible that a

fraction of the amount transferred will end up in the hands of other household

members. This fraction will depend on the bargaining power of the mother in the

household. It is worth mentioning that the theoretical literature and the empirical

evidence show that the cash transfers received by mothers can alter their

empowerment (Haddad et al., 1997; Barrientos and DeJong, 2004).

2.2. International empirical evidence

In this section we present some international empirical evidence on the impact that

welfare programs have on labor supply. Hoynes (1996), in a study on the United States,

finds that the cash-transfer welfare program Aid to Families with Dependent Children-

Unemployed Parent (AFDC-UP) has a negative effect on labor supply and other work

incentives. For the same country, Krueger and Meyer (2002) evaluate the effects of the

Page 10: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

5

social security program on labor supply. Specifically, they focus on workers’

compensation insurance, and find that these programs tend to reduce employees’

working hours.

Gassmann and Trindade (2016) analyze the impact on labor supply of a monetary

assistance program for the neediest in the Kyrgyz Republic. They find that the effect

differs between heads of household and their spouses, the sign being negative for the

former and unclear for the latter (primarily women). The impact on wives varies

depending upon the region of the country and the quarter of the year in which the

questionnaire was conducted.

Among the studies on conditional cash transfer programs, Alzúa, Cruces and Ripani

(2012) investigate the effect of these social programs on incentives to work and the

adult labor supply in three developing countries (Mexico, Nicaragua, and Honduras). To

this end, they use a differences-in-differences technique since they have experimental

data sets from those programs. The results show the effect of these social programs on

the adult labor supply has been negative for the most part, but small and non-significant.

However, in the case of the Mexican program Progresa, they find a small and positive

impact on the number of hours worked by recipient mothers.

The literature on conditional cash transfers also includes that of Molyneux (2007) who,

after studying Mexico’s Progresa/Oportunidades, proposes that such programs, rather

than empowering women, limit their traditional role as homemaker, childcarer, and

administrator of household spending, while their male partners retain their role as

breadwinner.

2.3. Description of the Juntos program

Before presenting the literature review on the Peruvian case, it is important to introduce

the Juntos program. Since 2005, Peru has been part of the group of countries that has

implemented conditional cash transfer programs to benefit children. The Juntos

program consists fundamentally of the disbursement of a cash transfer (200 soles

bimonthly, approximately 60 American dollars) to women with young children,

conditional upon their attendance of school and on growth and development checks.

The program began in the deprived region of Ayacucho, which was the cradle of the

political violence that plagued Peru during the 1980s and part of the 1990s.

Then, throughout 2005, the program was rolled out in just five impoverished regions of

the country. In the subsequent years it was extended to most of Peru, with coverage in

21 of its 26 political regions by 2017. Expansion has been gradual and the program does

not cover these regions in their entirety, focusing primarily on deprived rural areas.

Internally, in each region the program has reached the provinces and districts with the

Page 11: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

6

highest levels of poverty and need. According to statistics from the third quarter of 2017,

the program contains 742,094 registered households, of which 674,607 receive the

transfer regularly. In these households, there are 1,599,582 beneficiary children.

A notable fact about this program is that no base line data was collected prior to

implementation. Moreover, the initial selection of beneficiary districts was not based

solely on poverty criteria, but also included those districts that were affected by the

internal armed conflict. In subsequent years beneficiary selection was sequential,

focusing primarily on the regions with the highest poverty levels in certain districts;

within these districts, the Household Targeting System conducted a joint assessment

with the local authorities to determine the recipient households.

This methodology meant that the information obtained from the program was far from

being an experimental design. In the first place, the beneficiary selection was not

random but determined by the authorities of the day, without a statistically comparable

control group. Moreover, the participation of local authorities in the implementation

and selection of beneficiaries introduced specific characteristics of each region (for

example, preferences and acceptance of state policies by the population) to the

selection process. Finally, the participation of each household in the program is

voluntary, not compulsory. This fact creates a self-selection process which is based on

subjective criteria (costs and benefits of taking part). All of these considerations suggest

the existence of relevant information on individual participants that is not normally

available to program evaluators. Therefore, given the nature of the data, measurement

of the effect of Juntos requires statistical and econometric techniques that take into

account the possible biases stemming from the program’s design and the omitted

variables.

2.4. Empirical evidence in Peru

In a qualitative study on the effects of the program in the Ayacucho region, Streuli

(2012) finds similar results to those of Molyneux (2007) regarding the traditional rule of

women, but she also points to evidence of empowerment of beneficiary women in terms

of their self-esteem and social image. Moreover, she proposes that some beneficiary

women could use the funds to undertake or bolster habitual agricultural activities.

Moreover, because participating children spend more time at school, mothers reallocate

their time to domestic activities.

In a qualitative analysis, Escobal and Benites (2012) use a differences-in-differences

matching method to find that the Juntos program has had an impact on the allocation

of time to child labor. According to their calculations, which draw on the “Young Lives”

database, the number of minutes per day that children assign to remunerated activity is

reduced slightly, while the minutes allotted to unpaid work increase. The authors infer

from this that the program is fostering adult work (non-remunerative for the mothers)

Page 12: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

7

in family businesses. Jones et al. (2007) reach similar conclusions about the increase in

the workload of women in agricultural and domestic activities.

In another study, Fernández and Saldarriaga (2014) attempt to estimate the impact of

Juntos on hours worked through the effect that closeness to the payment date might

have. Using the differences between the Juntos payment dates and those of the

interview for the National Household Survey (Encuesta Nacional de Hogares, ENAHO)

within a single municipality, they find that the Juntos program reduces the number of

hours worked by between six and ten hours during the week following the cash transfer

date. The authors attribute this impact on hours worked to the time it takes to access

the money from the transfer, the time allocated to spending it, and a possible income

effect. This is likely to be a very short-term impact, as it only considers the week that

immediately follows each payment date. This drop in working hours is greater for

married women and for mothers with children below the age of five. Moreover, they do

not find a significant effect on workforce participation in remunerated activities, nor on

the labor supply of the husbands of married women.

Finally, Alencastre and Del Pozo (2017) estimate the impact of Juntos on labor

participation. Using a linear and non-linear double differences model, they do not find

statistically significant evidence of changes to labor participation in the years 2004 and

2014. In another study, Del Pozo and Guzmán (2010), employ quasi-experimental

designs to find that Juntos is encouraging agricultural production activities in rural

households, from which they infer that if might affect remunerated working hours.

3. Econometric methodology

We will assess the impact of the Juntos conditional transfer on the female labor supply

through an econometric model that considers working hours as the endogenous

variable, and has participation in the Juntos program as the main regressor. In addition,

to control for the influence of other factors, the regression includes control variables.

As has been established in the literature on labor participation, econometric variables

of this type can be subject to selection bias, and occurs in this case when the hours

worked and wages are only observable for women who have opted to work. If this

phenomenon were to materialize, the model could not be estimated using ordinary least

squares (OLS), as this would present bias or inconsistency in the estimators, but using

maximum likelihood estimation (MLE), following the model proposed by Heckman

(1979).

Another econometric problem occurs when the error in the equation presents an

unobserved heterogeneity component, such as individual tastes and presences related

Page 13: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

8

to work, that is correlated to the decision to participate in the program. If this were to

occur, estimation using the Heckman method would be biased and inconsistent. On the

other hand, if a panel data is employed, the bias due to unobservable heterogeneity

could be eliminated through a fixed effects approach, since the first difference or the

within groups estimator would eliminate this component. However, the fixed effects

model generally does not eliminate selection bias unless the conditional expectation of

the error given participation on the labor market remains constant over time, which

need not necessarily be the case.

A third econometric problem arises if the regressor of interest is endogenous, or if there

are omitted variables that change over time, or this regressor has been measured with

error. As a consequence, a correlation between the regressor and the idiosyncratic error

is produced, which makes it necessary to use an alternative based on the instrumental

variables method. Any other method could give rise to estimations with endogeneity

bias. In the case of Juntos, this problem is likely to exist given that participation in the

program is not random but voluntary and subject to the policy decisions of the program

administrators and local authorities.

Fortunately, there are techniques that allow these biases to be controlled for. To go into

these techniques in detail, we employ the following sample selection model with panel

data,

𝑦𝑖𝑡∗ = 𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 + 𝛼𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡 (1)

𝑑𝑖𝑡∗ = 𝑧𝑖𝑡𝛾 + 𝜂𝑖 + 𝑢𝑖𝑡 (2)

𝑑𝑖𝑡 = 1[𝑧𝑖𝑡𝛾 + 𝜂𝑖 + 𝑢𝑖𝑡 > 0] (3)

𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝑑𝑖𝑡 ∙ 𝑦𝑖𝑡∗ (4)

Equation (1) 𝑦𝑖𝑡∗ represents the desired working hours of each individual 𝑖 at the moment

𝑡 and is a latent variable that is unobserved in the entire sample. In Equation (2), 𝑑𝑖𝑡∗ is

another continuous latent variable that determines the participation of an individual 𝑖

in the labor market. This latter variable is unobservable, as there is only a dummy

variable that takes the value of 1 for the individual 𝑖 at the moment 𝑡 if the right side of

Equation (2) is positive and 0 if the opposite occurs (Equation [3]). Finally, Equation (4)

shows that the observed hours worked 𝑦𝑖𝑡 coincide with the desired hours if they are

strictly positive, and equal to 0 otherwise. In equations (1) and (2), the unobserved

heterogeneity error components are 𝛼𝑖 and 𝜂𝑖, which do not vary over time, and capture

elements specific to the individuals that do not usually change over time, such as tastes,

preferences, habits, customs, etc. Meanwhile, the idiosyncratic errors 𝜀𝑖𝑡 and 𝑢𝑖𝑡

behave like typical errors in linear regression models. Finally, the vectors 𝑥𝑖𝑡 and 𝑧𝑖𝑡

contain variables that determine the above-mentioned endogenous variables.

Page 14: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

9

This is a model with sample selection if there is some kind of covariance between the

idiosyncratic errors in equations (1) and (2) – that is, 𝐶𝑜𝑣(𝜀𝑖𝑡, 𝑢𝑖𝑡) ≠ 0, and hence

Equation (1) cannot be estimated using OLS. On the other hand, if the unobservable

heterogeniety term 𝛼𝑖 has a correlation with our main regressor included in the

vector 𝑥𝑖𝑡, 𝐶𝑜𝑣(𝛼𝑖 , 𝑥𝑖𝑡) ≠ 0, then the OLS and Heckman estimations in Equation (1) will

present bias. Finally, endogeneity bias will arise if 𝐶𝑜𝑣(𝑥𝑖𝑡 , 𝜀𝑖𝑡) ≠ 0.

Below we present the three estimators proposed in the literature to resolve these

problems.

3.1. The Kyriazidou's estimator

It was developed in Kyriazidou (1997), and the objective of this estimator is to eliminate

bias due to unobserved heterogeneity and selection bias in a single procedure. As

mentioned, the differentiation procedures that eliminate the heterogeneity bias do not

necessarily eliminate the sample selection bias. However, according to Kyriazidou’s

strategy, if one person participates in two consecutive periods, the magnitude of this

selection effect is very similar in both periods if 𝑧𝑖𝑡 does not change over time. Let 𝜆𝑖𝑡 be

this effect2. Then, Equation (1) can be rewritten as

𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 + 𝜆𝑖𝑡 + 𝛼𝑖 + 𝑣𝑖𝑡 (1’)

where 𝑣𝑖𝑡 ≡ 𝜀𝑖𝑡 − 𝜆𝑖𝑡, which has zero mean. The term 𝜆𝑖𝑡 in (1’) is the equivalent of the

term of correction introduced in the sample selection models (inverse Mills ratio), but it

is not constant in time, so the first differences estimator does not eliminate it.

Nevertheless, under an assumption called “conditional exchangeability” and assuming

𝑧𝑖1𝛾 = 𝑧𝑖2𝛾 it will be the case that 𝜆𝑖1 = 𝜆𝑖2. Then, the calculation of the first difference

will also eliminate the effect of selection bias. In empirical terms, (a) it is most probable

that 𝛾 will be unknown, and, (b) in general, 𝑧𝑖1𝛾 ≠ 𝑧𝑖2𝛾. To resolve (a), Kyriazidou’s

method estimates equations (2) and (3) using a conditional logit fixed effects model,

obtaining �̂� and 𝑧𝑖𝑡�̂� for 𝑡 = 1, 2. For (b), Kyriazidou assigns higher weights (kernel

weights) to those observations for which 𝑧𝑖𝑡�̂� ≅ 𝑧𝑖𝑡−1�̂�, and estimates equation (1’) in

first differences using weighted least squares for the case of 𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑑𝑖𝑡−1 = 1. When the

panel has more than two periods, the differences between two contiguous periods or

with more years of difference can be calculated. This will be the case of our estimator,

since our 3-year-panel database is balanced. Let �̂�𝑖𝑛 be the estimated weight, then the

expression of the estimator is

2 Formally, 𝜆𝑖𝑡 ≡ 𝐸[𝜀𝑖𝑡|𝑑𝑖1 = 1, 𝑑𝑖2 = 1] = 𝐸[𝜀𝑖𝑡|𝑢𝑖1 > −𝑧𝑖1𝛾 − 𝜂𝑖, 𝑢𝑖2 > −𝑧𝑖2𝛾 − 𝜂𝑖].

Page 15: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

10

�̂� = [∑ ∑ �̂�𝑖𝑛(𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝑥𝑖𝑠)′(𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝑥𝑖𝑠)𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑑𝑖𝑠

𝑠<𝑡

𝑛

𝑖=1

]

−1

× [∑ ∑ �̂�𝑖𝑛(𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝑥𝑖𝑠)′(𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝑥𝑖𝑠)𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑑𝑖𝑠

𝑠<𝑡

𝑛

𝑖=1

]

Kyriazidou (1997) calculates the variance-covariance matrix, which differs from that

obtained using ordinary least squares. One advantage of this method is that it does not

require a specific distribution of the errors to be assumed, but its main defect is that it

rests on the assumption of “conditional exchangeability,” which implies

homoscedasticity in the idiosyncratic error. This assumption has been criticized in the

literature for being unrealistic (Dustmann and Rochina-Barrachina, 2006; Semykina and

Wooldridge, 2010).

3.2. The Rochina-Barrachina’s estimator

Unlike the Kyriazidou’s estimator, Rochina-Barrachina (1999) takes Equation (1) and use

temporary differences to eliminate the unobserved heterogeneity component 𝛼𝑖, as in

the case of fixed effect estimators. Let 𝑡 and 𝑠 be two different periods, and if the

individual participates in the labor market in both (in which case, 𝑦𝑖𝑡 and 𝑦𝑖𝑠 will be

observed), the differentiation will result in Equation

𝑦𝑖𝑡 − 𝑦𝑖𝑠 = (𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝑥𝑖𝑠)𝛽 + (𝜀𝑖𝑡 − 𝜀𝑖𝑠) (5)

However, because of the sample selection problem, it will be the case that

𝐸[𝜀𝑖𝑡 − 𝜀𝑖𝑠|𝑥𝑖 , 𝑧𝑖 , 𝑑𝑖𝑡 = 1, 𝑑𝑖𝑠 = 1] ≠ 0 where 𝑥𝑖 and 𝑧𝑖 are the vectors of the exogenous

variables in both periods. The strategy of Rochina-Barrachina is similar to that of

Heckman in the case of the cross-sectional model, where the conditional expectation of

𝜀𝑖𝑡 − 𝜀𝑖𝑠 is calculated under the assumption of joint normality of 𝜀𝑖𝑡 − 𝜀𝑖𝑠 and the errors

of the selection equation in periods 𝑡 and 𝑠. Then, Equation (5) is written as

𝑦𝑖𝑡 − 𝑦𝑖𝑠 = (𝑥𝑖𝑡 − 𝑥𝑖𝑠)𝛽 + ℓ𝑡𝑠𝜆𝑖𝑡𝑠 + ℓ𝑠𝑡𝜆𝑖𝑠𝑡 + 𝑒𝑖𝑡𝑠. (6)

In which the terms 𝜆𝑖𝑡𝑠 and 𝜆𝑖𝑠𝑡 are the selection bias correction terms and are a function

of the exogenous variables from Equation (2) in both periods and of the respective

parameters.3 The empirical strategy of Rochina-Barrachina involves estimating, in a first

stage, the joint decision of labor participation in the periods 𝑡 and 𝑠 using a bivariate

probit model, which takes the vectors 𝑧𝑖𝑡 of all periods as regressors. These estimations

are used to construct the estimations �̂�𝑖𝑡𝑠 and �̂�𝑖𝑠𝑡, which are introduced in (6). Then,

this equation is estimated using OLS, and in our case we estimate the standard

deviations using the bootstrap technique. It is worth noting that this technique entails

estimations taking the periods two-by-two. Using a T-period panel sample, (𝑇2

) =𝑇!

2!(𝑇−2)!

3 See Rochina-Barrachina (1999) for the exact formulas.

Page 16: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

11

estimations are produced. In our case, we work with a three year panel so have three

estimations that can be integrated into a single more efficient result by using a distance

minimization procedure, with the variances-covariance matrix as a weighting matrix.

3.3. The estimator of Semykina and Wooldridge (2010)

The previous two estimators may not be suitable if the regressor of interest in 𝑥𝑖𝑡 is

correlated to the idiosyncratic error 𝜀𝑖𝑡. As we explained earlier, if this occurs with the

Juntos program, the estimators of Kyriazidou and Rochina-Barrachina would be biased

and inconsistent. Semykina and Wooldridge (2010), extending the model of Woodridge

(2005), propose an instrumental variables estimator to estimate this kind of model, in

which there is unobserved heterogeneity correlated to the regressor of interest,

selection bias, and endogeneity of the regressor of interest.

The Semykina and Wooldridge’s model is in the spirit of Mundlak's (1978) correlated

random effect model, which obtains the fixed-effect estimations of Equation (1), by

adding time averages of a vector of variable 𝑧𝑖𝑡. This vector includes the exogenous

regressors in the vector 𝑥𝑖, plus other valid instruments that are included in Equation (2)

but not in (1). Then, Equation (1) is converted into

𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 + 𝑧�̅�𝜔 + 𝐸[𝑣𝑖𝑡1|𝑧�̅�, 𝑑𝑖𝑡] + 𝑒𝑖𝑡

where 𝛼𝑖 = 𝑧�̅�𝜔 + 𝑐𝑖, and 𝑣𝑖𝑡1 = 𝑐𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡. Defining 𝑣𝑖𝑡2 = 𝜂𝑖 + 𝑢𝑖𝑡, under the typical

assumption4 that 𝑣𝑖𝑡1 is a linear function of 𝑣𝑖𝑡2 of the form 𝐸[𝑣𝑖𝑡1|𝑣𝑖𝑡2] = 𝛾𝑣𝑖𝑡2, it

follows that 𝐸[𝑣𝑖𝑡1|𝑧�̅�, 𝑑𝑖𝑡] = 𝛾𝐸[𝑣𝑖𝑡2|𝑧�̅�, 𝑑𝑖𝑡], in which 𝐸[𝑣𝑖𝑡2|𝑧�̅�, 𝑑𝑖𝑡] = 𝜆𝑖𝑡 is the

equivalent of the inverse Mills ratio as a selection bias term of correction. Then,

Semykina and Wooldridge estimate the model

𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝑥𝑖𝑡𝛽 + 𝑧�̅�𝜔 + 𝛾𝜆𝑖𝑡 + 𝑒𝑖𝑡 (7)

using two-stage least squares for pooled data. In the first stage, 𝜆𝑖𝑡 is estimated through

probit for each period. Then, �̂�𝑖𝑡 is used in (7), which is estimated using as instrumental

variables the valid instruments from Equation (2), 𝑧�̅� and �̂�𝑖𝑡. The standard deviations

are calculated using the bootstrap technique.

4. The data and the variables

We estimate the model primarily through the ENAHO panel for the years 2011-2013.

This survey has nationwide coverage, including both urban and rural areas, and collects

detailed information about household characteristics, members, and primary economic

activities (job, education, healthcare, social programs, etc.). We selected the afore-

4 This assumption is met when the joint distribution of errors is normal.

Page 17: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

12

mentioned years because the Juntos panel was expanded considerably between 2011

and 2013, and these variations are captured in the survey.

Because we are interested in the labor behavior of women, we consider only those aged

14 or over. In the three years selected, it can be observed that some of these women

can opt not to participate in the labor market during a given year. Some interesting

patterns are discerned in this regard, in that the work engaged in by the women may

involve dependent or independent activities; moreover, it is common in Peru for some

women to dedicate time to unpaid work in family businesses.

Taking the above into account and discarding certain inconsistent data in the panel

dataset,5 the total sample from the 2011-2013 ENAHO Panel survey is 5,632 women

observed over the three years. Under the methodologies of Kyriazidou and Rochina-

Barrachina, the estimations are limited to the case of women working during at least

two of the three periods, so the number of observations may decrease. In the case of

the Semykina and Wooldridge estimator, those women in the sample who have worked

at least one out of the three years are taken into account, so the size is somewhat larger.

The endogenous variable of the main equation is hours engaged in a remunerated

economic activity in the last seven days.6 This variable assigns a value of 0 to those

individuals who undertake unpaid work or do not participate in any economic activity.

The endogenous variable in the selection equation is a dummy variable that represents

participation in the remunerated labor market, and takes a value of 1 if the individual

presents a positive number of hours worked over the last seven days, and of 0 otherwise.

Meanwhile, the regressor of interest is a dummy variable that indicates whether the

household participated in the Juntos program at the time of the survey. In addition,

some control variables are added to the model.

Some of the variables taken from the ENAHO survey and used in the model are:

Household income: The annual income of the household in soles.

Years of schooling: The years of education completed by the individual.

Age: The age of the person in years.

Number of children: The number of children below the age of six in the

household.

Married: A dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the woman is married,

and 0 otherwise.

5 Fundamentally, these were consistencies in relation to age and sex. 6 It should be noted that a sizable percentage of female workers in Peru engage in unremunerated economic activities. For example, according to our calculations using cross-sectional ENAHO data from 2011, of the total female participants in the survey that year who engaged in some type of economic activity, the main pursuit of 32.57% was unpaid family work. On the other hand, in that same year just 12% of men in the survey undertook unpaid work as their main activity.

Page 18: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

13

Chronic illness: Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the individual suffers

some form of chronic illness, and of 0 if the individual does not suffer from any

illness.

Pregnancy: Dummy variable equal to 1 if the woman received pregnancy checks

over the last 12 months, and of 0 otherwise.

Illness of a member: Dummy variable equal to 1 if a household member

experienced a serious illness or accident, and of 0 otherwise.

Desertion by head of household: Dummy variable equal to 1 if the head of

household deserted the household, and of 0 otherwise.

Crime: Dummy variable equal to 1 if the household was victim to any form of

crime (theft, assault, etc.), and to 0 otherwise.

Natural disaster: Dummy variable equal to 1 if the household was victim to any

form of natural disaster (drought, storm, plague, etc.), and to 0 otherwise.

Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics of the main endogenous variable, working

hours in the primary paid activity. The table shows that an average of 17 hours per week

were allotted to paid work for the three years from 2011 to 2013. This average also takes

into account the zero hours of non-working women; if only working women are taken

into account, the average number of hours per week increases to 36. This is because the

sample is approximately halved when only working women are factored in, in

comparison with the sample that includes both women who work and those who do not

work. It is also noteworthy that in both samples there is variability between individuals

and over time.

Table 2 sets out the descriptive statistics of the other variables used in the estimations.

As can be seen in the table, female labor participation in remunerated activities

fluctuated around 48% in the years 2011-2013. It is also notable that just 11% of women

participated in Juntos over the same period. Another striking result is that 49% of

women in the sample report having or suffering from a chronic illness. Moreover, 45%

of women were found to live in households with children below the age of six, while the

Table 1 Hours worked in main remunerated activity

(Average for 2011-2013)

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Observations

Hours overall 17.277 23.537 0 98 N = 16.896

between 19.738 0 98 n = 5632

within 12.823 -41.057 82.610 T3

Hours (if hours>0) overall 35.953 21.940 1 98 N = 8119

between 19.543 1 98 n = 3736

within 11.143 -22.047 90.953 T-bar = 2.17318

Source: ENAHO PANEL 2011-2013

Compilation: authors.

Page 19: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

14

percentage of married women was just 33%. Also interesting is that 4% of women were

pregnant at the time they were surveyed during one of the three sample years. It should

be noted that 11% of those surveyed suffered some kind of natural disaster at some

point over the period 2011-2013.

As a general comment regarding the standard deviations, it can be stated that all

variables selected in the model contain intragroup, or within group, variability, based

on what can be inferred from the standard deviation values (except for the case of the

household desertion variable, which has a standard deviation of close to 0). This

variability in time favors the use of fixed-effect techniques.

Page 20: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

15

Table 2 Descriptive statistics of the other variables used in the estimations

(Average for 2011-2013)

Variable Mean Std. Dev.

Variable Mean Std. Dev.

Participation in remunerated activities

overall 0.481 0.500

Pregnancy overall 0.041 0.198

between

0.411

between

0.134

within

0.284

within

0.146

Juntos program overall 0.107 0.310

Criminal offense (theft, assault, etc.)

overall 0.032 0.177

between

0.283

between

0.112

within

0.126

within

0.138

Household income

overall 2494.4 2429.4

Serious illness or accident

overall 0.092 0.289

between

2181.9

between

0.199

within

1068.5

within

0,.16

Number of children < 6 years of age

overall 0.458 0.715

Desertion of head of household

overall 0.006 0.080

between

0.641

between

0.059

within

0.318

within

0.061

Chronic illness overall 0.490 0.500

Natural disasters overall 0.109 0.311

between

0.399

between

0.227

within

0.301

within

0.209

Married overall 0.334 0.472

Proxy meanscore overall 0.264 0.233

between

0.459

between

0.224

within

0.110

within

0.063

Source: ENAHO PANEL 2011-2013

Compilation: authors.

Of the afore-mentioned methods, that of Semykina and Wooldridge requires the use of

instrumental variables, since the Juntos variable is considered as endogenous. As we

know, these variables must meet the condition of being correlated with the endogenous

regressor Juntos, but not correlated with the error of Equation (7). To this end, we

selected the following variables as instruments:

HDI: The human development index, as calculated by the United Nations

Development Programme (UNDO) at district level. We use the HDI with a lag of

one year – that is, for 2010, 2011, and 2012.7

Percentage that completed secondary education: Percentage of the population

that has completed secondary school in the district, in the year prior to the

ENAHO survey. We also obtained this variable from the UNDP database, for the

years 2010, 2011, and 2012.

7 Available at: http://www.pe.undp.org/

Page 21: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

16

Proxy meanscore: A continuous indicator that measures the household income

and consumption, and it is calculated on a set of observable characteristics of

the household and its members. This indicator is usually employed to determine

whether a household is eligible for social support. We have calculated this

indicator using the standard World Bank methodology (see World Bank [2007]).

The selection of these variables is justified because the program has been targeted from

the outset to districts with high poverty levels, which is related to a low human

development index, even if this relationship is not perfect (García, 2017). In our case,

we use this index with a lag of one year, allowing that the selection of the districts may

be related to the index from the previous year. In addition, we do not expect there to

be a direct relationship between the previous year’s HDI and the change in women's

working hours from one year to the next. A similar argument applies to the second

instrumental variable selected – the percentage of people in the district who have

completed secondary education, as of the previous year. This is an indicator of the level

of human development in the district, which could also be related to the selection of

districts where the Juntos program was applied. Likewise, we do not expect this lagged

structural indicator to be related to the changes in women's working hours from one

year to the next. Finally, the method requires a third complementary instrumental

variable, for which we have selected the “proxy mean score” variable. We also expect

this variable to be related to the household’s participation in the Juntos program, since

the index seeks to identify potentially eligible households in a similar manner to the

Household Targeting System. Table 3 shows the correlations between these

instrumental variables and the Juntos variable. Although these correlations are high, in

the estimation of the Semykina and Wooldridge method, statistical tests are performed

to prove the validity of the estimates.8

Table 3 Correlations between instruments and the Juntos variables

HDI

Percentage with secondary education Proxy meanscore

-0.4602 -0.3915 0.3729

Source: ENAHO PANEL 2011-2013 Compilation: authors.

5. Econometric results

8 It is worth mentioning that the estimation of the “proxy meanscore” variable is not an excluded variable per se, so we do not consider it into the evaluation of the validity of the excluded variables. See Semykina and Wooldridge (2010), page 378 for an explanation of its function. The only variables taken into account are the HDI, percentage with higher education, and the respective averages in time.

Page 22: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

17

As stated in the methodology section, we perform the estimation of the working hours

model following the approaches of Kyriazidou (1997), Rochina-Barrachina (1999), and

Semykina and Wooldridge (2010) for the Juntos program.

The estimations of the working hours model for Juntos using the standard “within

groups” fixed-effects method, as well as the three above-mentioned methods, are set

out in Table 4. The results show that the impact of Juntos on women’s working hours in

Peru is negative and significant for 2011-2013, which is consistent with the economic

theories. Under the Kyriazidou and Rochina-Barrachina methods, Juntos reduces the

remunerative activities of women over the age of 14 by an average of between three

and four hours per week. However, the impact is greater under the method of Semykina

and Wooldridge, which does take into account the problems of exogeneity associated

with the Juntos variable. Under this method, it is estimates that Juntos reduces

participation in remunerated activities by 9.4 hours per week, on average. It is possible

that the Kyriazidou and Rochina-Barrachina methods are subject to an attenuation

effect since they do not control the exogeneity of Juntos.

As stated in earlier sections, the international literature has also reported negative

effects of cash transfers on hours worked (for example, Hoynes, 1996; Krueger and

Meyer, 2002), and those results differ from the findings of Alzúa et al. (2012) regarding

conditional transfers. If we take the estimation of an effect of 9.4 hours less hours

worked as the most accurate, this impact is close to that found by Fernández and

Saldarriaga (2014), calculated at between six and ten hours, although the impact of

these authors is very short term. In our work, the calculation can be understood as a

change from one year to the next, and thus implies readjustments in internal household

resources, which would explain the slightly greater impact. On the other hand, this

negative impact is consistent with that cited by other authors, such as Escobal and

Benites (2012), who point out that in the case of children, remunerated work decreases

in favor of more time spent on unremunerated activities. In our study, a decrease is also

observed in the remunerated work of women. There is also consistency with the findings

of the qualitative study by Streuli (2012), who demonstrates that the Juntos transfer is

occasionally used to strengthen family businesses in which women perform unpaid

work, but also notes that there may have been an increase in the time spent on non-

laboral activities. Moreover, the effect identified is also consistent with the hypothesis

that sending children to school results in a loss of unremunerated hours spend in the

family business. These unpaid working hours would have to be covered by other

household members, in this case by women, which would lead to a drop in their time

spent in remunerated work. Our results are also consistent with the findings of Del Pozo

and Guzmán (2010), who find that the Juntos program has a positive impact on

household production, which could serve to reduce women’s participation in paid work

outside the house.

Page 23: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

18

As to the other control variables, in the estimation it can be observed that the pregnancy

variable presents a negative and significant sign under the Semykina-Wooldridge

method, such that if a woman is pregnant, the number of hours worked per week

reduces by four; this effect is reasonable. Curiously, under the Kyriazidou method, a

positive sign is presented, which is counter-intuitive, and under Rochina-Barrachina the

impact is non-significant. On the other hand, the estimations show that the variable for

the number of children aged less than six presents a negative sign across all methods,

but is only significant under the Kyriazidou and Semykina-Wooldridge approaches. It is

notable that this effect is relatively small; remunerated work is reduced by one hour and

a half for each additional small child in the household. Meanwhile, if a woman suffers

from some form of chronic illness, her working hours will decrease slightly, although the

effect proves to be significant only under the Kyriazidou method. Similarly, if a member

of the household suffers from a serious illness, the number of working hours will

decrease, but on this occasion the impact is only significant, to 10%, under the method

of Semykina-Wooldridge. Moreover, if the head of household deserts the household,

the average number of hours women spend working increases by almost nine, though

this effect is only significant under the Kyriazidou method. Finally, there is a marked

difference in the hours spent in paid activities among women who live in rural areas

versus their urban counterparts.

Page 24: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

19

Table 4

Estimation of impact of Juntos program on hours worked in remunerated activities (Panel 2011-2013)

Variable

Fixed effects conditioned

to d=1

Kyriazidou

(1997)

Rochina-Barrachina

(1999)

Semykina –Wooldridge

(2010)

Juntos -3.798 ** -3.846 *** -3.076 * -9.471 **

(1.819) (1.009) (1.773) (4.108)

Family income 38.27x10-5 ** 173.63x10-5 *** 43.42x10-5 85.34x10-5 ***

(18.15x10-5) (29.43x10-5) (40.06x10-5) (29.29x10-5)

# Children < 6 years of age -0.488 -1.157 ** -0.800 -1.595 *

(0.671) (0.586) (1.050) (0.842)

Chronic illness -0.795 -1.008 *** -1.222 -0.813

(0.639) (0.404) (0.993) (0.826)

Marital status 1.495 -0.913 3.188 1.433

(1.736) (2.535) (2.048) (2.531)

Pregnancy -2.488 9.666 *** -0.209 -4.630 **

(1.798) (3.096) (2.249) (2.165)

Desertion 1.293 8.874 *** 3.550 3.478

(2.793) (2.720) (2.666) (3.528)

Crime victimhood 0.952 0.490 1.113 0.035

(1.392) (0.844) (1.401) (1.738)

Serious illness of household member -0.603 -0.852 -0.792 -1.999 *

(0.952) (0.584) (1.124) (1.206)

Natural disaster -0.704 -0.175 -0.999 -0.998

(1.112) (0.585) (1.239) (1.249)

Rural=1, Urban=0 -16.660 * -19.636 *** -14.444 *** -17.447 **

(9.675) (3.234) (5.267) (7.937)

Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***=sig. at 1%, **=sig. at 5%, *=sig. at 10%. Note 1: Rochina-Barrachina and Semykina-Wooldridge estimations use bootstrap standard errors. Note 2: The selection bias terms of correction in the Rochina-Barrachina and Semykina-Wooldridge regression do not prove to be significant (not shown in the table). Compilation: authors.

It is worth noting the results of the validity of the instruments. For this, we have opted

for the well-known F-test for the strength of the instruments, the Sargan test for

overidentifying restrictions, and the Hausman test for the pertinence of using the

instrumental variables method based on evaluation of the endogeneity of the Juntos

regressor. These tests only apply to the regression with instrumental variables under

Semykina and Wooldridge’s method. Table 5 shows the validity test for the instruments.

As can be seen the chosen instruments meet the required conditions. As to the strength

of the instruments, the F statistic applied to the excluded instruments is equal to 116.1,

exceeding the known “golden rule” that sets the minimum threshold at ten units.

According to the Sargan test for overidentifying restrictions, the null hypothesis is not

Page 25: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

20

rejected, so it is correct to exclude the afore-mentioned instruments from the

regression. Finally, the Wu-Hausman test of endogeneity in the Juntos variable indicates

that the null hypothesis of non-endogeneity is rejected for this variable; thus, the

estimation by instrumental variables is preferred to an estimation using ordinary least

squares.

Table 5 Assessment of instrument validity

Edogeneity Instrument weakness Restrictions on identifiers

H0: Exogenous regressors H0: Weak instruments H0: Instruments correctly excluded from the main

equation

Wu-Hausman 4.351 Strength of excluded variables

116.141 Sargan 2.587

P-value 0.037 P-value 0.000 P-value 0.460

Compilation: authors.

Finally, we evaluate the interaction of the program’s impact with some of the regressors.

To this end, we have performed separate estimations for each population subgroup. We

present these results in Table 6. First, we see clearly that there is a considerable

difference in the program's impact depending on women's marital status. Thus, for the

group of married women, Juntos has no appreciable significant effect on remunerated

working hours, while for unmarried women, if a member of their household is a Juntos

beneficiary, this will reduce their engagement in paid work by 15 hours per week.

Another striking result is the difference found according to the age of the women. For

women below the age of 40, the Juntos program reduces their working time by almost

18 hours per week, while there is practically no effect for those over the age of 40. This

result suggests that younger women are more sensitive in their labor participation,

perhaps because they are involved in other alternative activities, or because they have

less economic responsibilities within the household. As to the other variables in Table 6,

there are practically no differences in subpopulations, or the estimations are not entirely

reliable since the instruments do not achieve validity in these subpopulations.

Page 26: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

21

Table 6 Impact of Juntos on hours worked per week, by

population groups

Juntos coefficient P-value

Unmarried -15.451 0.002

Married 3.308 0.684

Without children < 6 years -7.746 0.180+

With children < 6 years -10.637 0.078

Age <40 -16.630 0,003

Age > 40 -0.834 0.896

No chronic illness -10.085 0.053

Chronic illness -9.436 0.218

Rural -6.179 0.060+

Urban -17.770 0.250 + Instruments do not prove valid

6. Conclusions

In this study we investigated the impact of the Juntos program on the number of hours

that women in Peru spend in remunerated work. Economic theory holds that this effect

should be negative due to the income effect that cash transfers bring about. Because

the Juntos program does not yield experimental data and the quasi-experimental

techniques do not control all biases, it is necessary to employ a structural econometric

model that controls for unobserved heterogeneity biases, selection bias, and regressor

endogeneity. We used techniques developed specifically to control for these biases,

such as those of Kyriazidou (1997), Rochina-Barrachina (1999), and Semykina and

Wooldridge (2010).

Our results for Peru show that the impact of the Juntos conditional cash transfer

program on hours spent in remunerated activities has been negative and significant,

evidencing the income effect on working hours in the case of a cash transfer.

We found an average estimated impact of 9.4 hours per week less remunerated work

for those women whose households are recipients on the Juntos program. These results

are close to those found for the very short term by Fernández and Saldarriaga (2014),

and to other authors who present negative results. However, the effect found in this

paper is not a short-term effect, but interpreted as an annual change. Our results are in

keeping with the theories on intra-household resource allocation. Moreover, we find

Page 27: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

22

significant differences in impact based on women’s marital status and age, with the

impact greater in the case of young and of unmarried women.

The results leads us to assert that the Juntos program should not be seen purely as a

program to benefit children, but one that also has implications for other household

members, principally on women, given the reallocation of time and other household

resources. Whether the program is expanded or continued, these collateral effects

should be kept in mind, and the results should also be considered alongside other

studies that have evaluated unforeseen or indirect effects of the program for an overall

evaluation of its positive and negative aspects.

7. References

Alzúa, María Laura, Guillermo Cruces and Laura Ripani (2012). “Welfare Programs and

Labor Supply in Developing Countries: Experimental Evidence from Latin America”. IZA

Discussion Paper No. 6959.

Alencastre, L. and C. Del Pozo (2017). “¿Beneficios o perjuicios para las mujeres? Cómo

el Programa Juntos afecta a las mujeres usuarias en el Perú”. Third final report.

Consorcio de Investigación Económica y Social (CIES) and Centro de Estudios Regionales

Andinos Bartolomé de las Casas (CBC).

Barrientos, A. and J. DeJong (2004) Child Poverty and Cash Transfers, CHIP Report No. 4,

London: Childhood Poverty Research and Policy Centre.

Becker, Gary (1965). “A theory of allocation of time”. The Economic Journal, Vol. 75, No.

299, pp. 493-517.

Blundell, Richard and Thomas McCurdy (1999). “Labor supply: a review of alternative

approaches”. Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. (3), pp. 1560 – 1618.

Chiappori, Pierre-André (1992). “Collective labor supply and welfare”. Journal of Political

Economy, Vol. (100), pp. 437-467.

Del Pozo, César and Esther Guzmán (2010). “Efectos de las transferencias monetarias

condicionadas en la inversión productiva de los hogares rurales en el Perú”. Lima:

Consorcio de Investigación Económica y Social – CIES.

Dustmann, C. and M. Rochina-Barrachina (2006). “Selection correction in panel data

models: An application to the estimation of females’ wage equations”. Econometrics

Journal, Vol (10), pp. 263-293.

Page 28: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

23

Escobal, Javier and Sara Benites (2012). “Algunos impactos del programa JUNTOS en el

bienestar de los niños: Evidencia basada en el estudio Niños del Milenio”. Lima: Niños

del Milenio; Young Lives. Boletín de políticas públicas sobre infancia, 5.

Fernández, Fernando and Víctor Saldarriaga (2014). “Do benefit recipients change their

labor supply after receiving the cash transfer? Evidence from the Peruvian Juntos

program”. IZA Journal of Labor & Development 2014, Vol. 3, No. 2.

Fiszbein, A. and N. R. Schady (2009). Conditional cash transfers: reducing present and

future poverty, Washington DC: World Bank Publications.

Gaarder, M., A. Glassman and J.E. Tood (2010). “Conditional cash transfers and health:

unpacking the causal chain”. Journal of Development Effectiveness, Vol (2), 1, pp. 6-50.

García, Luis (2017). “The consumption of household goods, bargaining power, and their

relationship with a conditional cash transfer program in Peru”. Journal of International

Development, 29, 500-519. DOI: 10.1002/jid.3272

Gassmann, Franziska, and Lorena Zardo Trindade (2016). “The effect of means-tested

social transfers on labour supply: heads versus spouses – An empirical analysis of work

disincentives in the Kyrguz Republic”. UNU-MERIT Working Paper No. 2016-030.

Gronau, Reuben (1976). “Leisure, home production and work–the theory of the

allocation of time revisited”. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. (85), pp. 1099 – 1124.

Haddad, L., J. Hoddinott, and H. Alderman (1997). Intrahousehold Resource Allocation

in Developing Countries. London: John Hopkins University Press.

Heckman, James (1979). “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error”. Econometrica,

Vol. 47, pp. 153-161.

Hoynes, Hillary (1996). “Welfare transfers in two-parent families: labor supply and

welfare participation under AFCD-UP”. Econometrica, Vol. 64, No. 2, pp. 295-332.

Jones, N., R. Vargas and E. Villar (2007). “El programa Juntos y el bienestar de la

infancia”. In: Relaciones con condiciones: El Estado Peruano frente a su infancia. Lima:

Niños del Milenio.

Krueger, Alan and Bruce Meyer (2002). “Labor supply effects of social insurance”.

Handbook of Public Economics. NBER Working Paper No. 9014.

Kumar, Anil and Liang Che-Yuan (2016). “Declining Female Labor Supply Elasticities in

the U.S. and Implications for Tax Policy: Evidence from Panel Data”. FRB of Dallas

Working Paper No. 1501.

Page 29: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

24

Kyriazidou, Ekaterini (1997). “Estimation of a panel data sample selection model”.

Econometrica, Vol. (65), pp. 1335-1364.

Manley, J., S. Gitter and V. Slavchevska (2013). “How Effective are Cash Transfers at

Improving Nutritional Status?”. World Development Vol. 48, pp. 133-155.

Moffitt, Robert (2002). “Welfare programs and labor supply”. Handbook of Public

Economics, Vol (3), pp. 2394-2427.

Molyneux, Maxine (2007). “Change and Continuity in Social Protection in Latin America

Mothers at the Service of the State?”. Gender and Development Programme Paper

Number 1. Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social Development.

Mundlak, Y. (1978). “On the pooling of time series and cross section data”.

Econometrica. Vol. 46, pp. 69-85.

Quisumbing, A. and J. Maluccio (1999). “Intrahousehold allocation and gender relations:

new empirical evidence”. Policy research report on gender and development. Banco

Mundial Working paper series No. 2.

Rochina-Barrachina, María Engracia (1999). “A new estimator for panel data sample

selection models”. Annales d'Économie et de Statistique No. 55/56, pp. 153-181.

Semykina, Anastacia y Jeffrey Wooldridge (2010). “Estimating panel data models in the

presence of endogeneity and selection”. Journal of Econometrics, Vol. (157), pp. 375-

380.

Streuli, Natalia (2012). “Children’s Experiences of Juntos, a Conditional Cash Transfer

Scheme in Peru”. Young Lives Working paper No. 78.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey (1995). “Selection corrections for panel data models under

conditional mean independence assumptions”. Journal of Econometrics, Vol (68), pp.

115-132.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey (2005). “Simple solutions to the initial conditions problem in

dynamic, nonlinear panel data models with unobserved heterogeneity”. Journal of

Applied Econometrics, Vol (20), pp. 39-54.

World Bank (2007). Protección Social en el Perú. ¿Cómo mejorar los resultados para los

pobres?". Lima: World Bank.

Page 30: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

ÚLTIMAS PUBLICACIONES DE LOS PROFESORES DEL DEPARTAMENTO DE ECONOMÍA

Libros Adolfo Figueroa

2017 Economics of the Anthropocene Age. Palgrave Macmillan. Adolfo Figueroa y Richard Web 2017 Distribución del ingreso en el Perú. Lima, Instituto de Estudios Peruanos. Alfredo Dammert y Raúl García 2017 Economía de la energía. Lima, Fondo Editorial, Pontificia Universidad Católica del

Perú. Mario D. Tello 2017 La productividad total de factores agregada en el Perú. Nacional y Departamental.

Lima, Instituto Nacional de Estadística e Informatica. Félix Jiménez 2017 Veinticinco años de modernización neocolonial: Críticas de las políticas neoliberales

en el Perú. Lima, Instituto de Estudios Peruanos. Carlos Contreras y Elizabeth Hernández (editores) 2017 Historia económica del norte peruano. Señoríos, haciendas y minas en el espacio

regional. Lima, Banco Central de Reserva del Perú e Instituto de Estudios Peruanos. José Rodríguez y Pedro Francke (editores) 2017 Exclusión e inclusión social en el Perú. Logros y desafíos para el desarrollo. Lima,

Fondo Editorial, Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. Iván Rivera 2017 Principios de Macroeconomía. Un enfoque de sentido común. Lima, Fondo Editorial,

Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. Ismael Muñoz, Marcial Blondet y Gonzalo Gamio (Editores). 2017 Ética, agencia y desarrollo humano. V Conferencia de la Asociación Latinoamericana

y del Caribe para el Desarrollo Humano y el Enfoque de Capacidades. Lima, Fondo Editorial, Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú.

Waldo Mendoza y Janneth Leyva 2017 La economía del VRAEM. Diagnósticos y opciones de política. Lima, USAID-CIES. Félix Jiménez 2017 Macroeconomía. Enfoques y modelos. Lima, Editorial Macro. Máximo Vega-Centeno 2017 Ética y deontología. Lima, Fondo Editorial, Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú.

Page 31: DOCUMENT O DE TRAB AJO - files.pucp.edu.pefiles.pucp.edu.pe/departamento/economia/DDD448.pdf · DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO N° 448 EFFECT OF THE JUNTOS SOCIAL PROGRAM ON FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY

Documentos de Trabajo No. 447 “El derecho a la educación intercultural bilingüe y la política fiscal en Perú”. Luis

García y Erika Collantes, Noviembre, 2017. No. 446 “Cambio técnico en el sector regulado de la microfinanzas peruanas: 2003-2015”.

Giovanna Aguilar y Jhonatan Portilla. Octubre, 2017. No. 445 “Teaching Modern Macroeconomics in the Mundell-Fleming Language: The IS-

MR-UIP-AD-AS Model”. Waldo Mendoza Bellido. Setiembre, 2017. No. 444 “La experiencia de la Banca de Desarrollo en el Perú: 1990-2015”. Oscar

Dancourt Masías y Renzo Jiménez Sotelo. Agosto, 2017. No. 443 “Teaching Modern Macroeconomics in the Traditional Language: The IS-MR-AD-

AS Model”. Waldo Mendoza Bellido. Julio, 2017. No. 442 “Has the Gender Wage Gap been Reduced during the ‘Peruvian Growth Miracle?’

A Distributional Approach”. Juan Manuel del Pozo Segura. Julio, 2017. No. 441 “Crecimiento y desindustrialización prematura en Perú. Un análisis Kaldoriano”.

Félix Jiménez. Junio, 2017. No. 440 “La economía de PPK. Promesas y resultados: la distancia que los separa”. Waldo

Mendoza Bellido y Erika Collantes Goicochea. Mayo, 2017. No. 439 “¿Es la educación un mecanismo de salida hacia mejores ocupaciones para las

trabajadoras del hogar?” Cecilia Garavito. Mayo, 2017. Materiales de Enseñanza No. 2 “Macroeconomía: Enfoques y modelos. Ejercicios resueltos”. Felix Jiménez.

Marzo, 2016. No. 1 “Introducción a la teoría del Equilibrio General”. Alejandro Lugon. Octubre, 2015.

Departamento de Economía - Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú Av. Universitaria 1801, Lima 32 – Perú.

Telf. 626-2000 anexos 4950 - 4951 http://departamento.pucp.edu.pe/economia/


Recommended