+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Eapen Krishnan Paper

Eapen Krishnan Paper

Date post: 04-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: enescu-george
View: 226 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 51

Transcript
  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    1/51

    0

    Transferring tacit know-how through licensing or joint venture: Is

    opportunism really redundant?

    Alex EapenThe University of Sydney Business School

    Discipline of International BusinessNSW 2006, Australia

    Tel: + 61-2-903 66435Email:[email protected]

    Rekha KrishnanSimon Fraser University

    Department of International Business8888 University Drive

    Burnaby, BC V5A 1S6, CanadaTel: +1-604-291-3047

    Email:[email protected]

    Version: Mar, 2012

    We thank Aks Zaheer, Anand Nandkumar, Anita McGahan, Anoop Madhok, HarbirSingh, Kannan Srikanth, Klaus Meyer, Peter Liesch, Rajiv Krishnan, Sarah Kaplan,and seminar participants at the Indian School of Business and the University ofSydney, for helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    2/51

    1

    Transferring tacit know-how through licensing or joint venture: Is opportunism

    really redundant?

    Abstract

    Transaction cost economics scholars argue that firms exist due to failure of markets,

    a main stimulus of which is opportunism. On the contrary, proponents of the

    knowledge based view claim that the opportunism assumption is redundant in

    explaining why firms exist. A key feature of this debate, however, is that despite

    competing causal mechanisms, predictions of both theories are identical. We see this

    lack of predictive uniqueness as the prime bottleneck in resolving the question of

    whether opportunism matters, and contribute to the debate in two ways: (1) we

    exploit the contingency logics inherent in knowledge based and transaction cost

    approaches to build distinctive predictions from both theories, and (2) we

    empirically test their competing logics, bringing empirical evidence to the debate

    which has this far been largely on conceptual turf. Our results, based on an analysis

    of tacit know-how transfer in strategic alliances between foreign and local firms in

    India, and subject to certain caveats we discuss in the paper, indicate that

    opportunism matters.

    (165 words)

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    3/51

    2

    INTRODUCTION

    A key debate in the theory of the firm is on the role of opportunism. Some scholars, primarily

    from a transaction cost economics (TCE) standpoint, argue that firms exist due to market

    failure, a main stimulus of which is opportunism (Hennart, 1982; McFetridge, 1995;

    Williamson, 1985; 1991; 1993). Others maintain that the opportunism assumption is

    redundant, that is, the existence of the firm can be explained without the notion of

    opportunism (Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Kogut & Zander, 1993;

    Madhok, 2006). Yet another group suggests that opportunism may be relevant, but not to the

    encompassing extent that TCE portrays (Madhok, 2006), nor always directed by guileful self-

    interest seeking (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009). Conceptual disagreement aside, empirical

    evidence on whether opportunism is critical to explaining the boundaries of the firm is also

    very scant. Even within the huge body of empirical research on TCE (David & Han, 2004;

    Macher & Richman, 2008), scholars usually assume but omit testing the underlying

    opportunism assumption (Tsang, 2006; Verbeke & Griedanus, 2009).

    A specific context in which this debate has gained significant play in recent years is

    the international strategy literature on the implications of ownership advantages of firms on

    their boundaries. Examining how firms transfer their knowledge-based advantage into new

    countries, Kogut & Zander (1993) suggest that firms, as social communities with superior

    cooperation and coordination mechanisms, are simply better vehicles to transfer know-how.

    Transferring knowledge across borders, particularly when it is tacit, is hence more likely to

    occur within the firm than on the market. This is a key prediction of the knowledge-based

    view (KBV) of the multinational enterprise. Transaction cost theorists agree that tacit

    knowledge is more efficiently transferred within the firm, but emphasize that this is because

    contracting for tacit knowledge on the market is rendered inefficient by opportunism-related

    hurdles (McFetridge, 1995; Hennart, 1982). Within firms, on the other hand, members have

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    4/51

    3

    fewer incentives to behave opportunistically (Williamson, 1985). Thus, unlike KBV, the

    transaction cost theory of the multinational enterprise turns on the notion of opportunism.

    This debate in the international strategy literature has witnessed passionate arguments from all

    sides (Kogut & Zander, 1993; McFetridge, 1995; Love, 1995; Verbeke, 2003) and little sign

    of being settled (e.g., Fransson, Hakanson, & Liesch, 2011).

    We seek to advance the literature surrounding the opportunism debate in both

    conceptual and empirical ways. Our starting point is the observation that despite

    fundamentally different views from KBV and TCE on the relevance of opportunism, both

    sides arrive at the same prediction that tacit know-how is more efficiently transferred

    internally than on the market. In other words, while the causal mechanisms differ, predictions

    from transaction cost and knowledge-based views are identical. This lack of predictive

    uniqueness poses a key conceptual bottleneck in this debate1

    We seek to get around these conceptual and empirical issues in this paper.

    Conceptually, we exploit the contingency logics inherent in KBV and TCE to build distinctive

    predictions from both theories. Contingency propositions also better represent the causal

    mechanisms underpinning both theories (cf. Rajan & Zingales, 1998). Our theoretical strategy

    involves identifying situations where opportunism is likely to be a concern, and then

    . A second critical gap, given that

    the debate has been largely on conceptual turf (e.g., Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Foss, 1996a;

    1996b; Kogut & Zander, 1992; Fransson et al., 2011), is the lack of empirical evidence on

    whether or not opportunism matters. There is indeed abundant empirical research on KBV and

    TCE, but as Verbeke & Greidanus (2009) rightly say, very few studies assess directly

    whetheropportunism is actually instrumental [or not] to governance choices (p.1476). The

    question of whether opportunism is critical to understanding the boundaries of the firm, yet, is

    ultimately an empirical one (Tsang, 2006).

    1 The predictive similarity of TCE and KBV in spite of their different theoretical mechanisms has beenhighlighted by scholars in other contexts as well (e.g., Poppo & Zenger, 1998; Sampson, 2004).

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    5/51

    4

    examining whether the likelihood of internal transfer of tacit know-how increases in those

    circumstances. In other words, we test whether the potential for opportunism makes any

    difference to how tacit know-how is transferred. We expect tacit know-how, in general, to be

    transferred internally, but if the effect of tacitness on transfer through hierarchical means

    increases with the level of opportunism faced by transferor and recipient, this could be the

    smoking gun to suggest that opportunism matters. On the contrary, if the effect of tacitness

    on the mode of transfer is insensitive to the potential for opportunism, then perhaps as KBV

    suggests, opportunism is not so crucial for the theory. So the difference in the magnitude of

    the effect of tacitness under conditions of low and high opportunism serves as our litmus test

    for whether opportunism matters. To obtain a complete picture, we also frame a contingency

    argument for KBV. We argue that while the likelihood of internal transfer increases with the

    tacitness of know-how, this effect is weaker when the transferor and unaffiliated recipient

    have similar routines. That is, when routines are similar, transferring tacit know-how should

    be easier, even to unaffiliated firms. Any evidence for this would corroborate the KBV view

    that ease of transfer (and not opportunism) is what drives firms proclivity to internal transfer.

    Empirically, we test these notions using unique data from a survey of technology

    transfer arrangements between foreign and domestic firms in India. We surveyed licensing

    contracts, which are closer to a market transaction, as well as joint ventures, which have

    overtones of hierarchy or internal transfer (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hennart, 1988; Osborn &

    Baughn, 1990; Oxley, 1997; Phene & Tallman, 2012). We collected detailed micro-level data

    on the nature of know-how transferred such as its tacitness, importance to the recipient, and

    the extent of specific investments required to be made by the recipient for its implementation.

    As we argue below, the latter two variables are reasonably good indicators of potential

    opportunism. We also measured the similarity between transferor and recipient in this case,

    between foreign and domestic partners in their routines and culture. Employing logistic

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    6/51

    5

    regression analyses, we find that tacit know-how is more likely transferred through joint

    venture than through licensing. This is consistent with prior literature. However, we also find

    that the effect of tacitness on the choice of joint venture is stronger under conditions of high

    potential opportunism, i.e., when the know-how being transferred is central to the recipient, or

    when the recipient needs to make specific investments. But we do not find the effect of

    tacitness varying with whether or not the recipient has routines similar to that of the

    transferor. Subject to certain caveats we discuss later on, we interpret these results to mean

    two things firstly, that opportunism is relevant to understanding the boundaries of the firm,

    and secondly, that opportunism is the likely causal mechanism behind the often observed

    empirical link between tacitness of know-how and its internal transfer. These conceptual and

    empirical observations, as we discuss later on in the paper, have fairly significant implications

    for the debate over opportunism and the theory of the firm, and for issues related to the

    question of what firms really do (cf. Kogut & Zander, 1992).

    BACKGROUND

    The assumption of opportunism has received a significant amount of attention and

    commentary in the organization, strategy, and international business literatures. Not all of it

    has been positive. While there is seldom any disagreement over the need to carefully identify

    the nature of human beings that underlies their behavior (Simon, 1985; Verbeke & Greidanus,

    2009; Williamson, 1993), scholars have attacked opportunism, inter alia, as being an under-

    socialized and narrow view of human behavior (Donaldson, 1990; Granovetter, 1985), of little

    normative value (Ghoshal & Moran, 1996), and irrelevant to understanding why firms exist

    (Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Hodgson, 1998; Kogut & Zander, 1992; 1996; Love, 1995). This

    critical commentary has been reciprocated in equal measure with extensions (Rugman &

    Verbeke, 2003), elaboration (Wathne & Heide, 2000), and reconceptualization of the

    opportunism construct (e.g., Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009).

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    7/51

    6

    In the international strategy literature, the study of how tacitness of know-how

    influences the boundaries of the MNE has turned out to be a duelling ground for this debate.

    By questioning the need for the opportunism assumption, Kogut and Zander (1993) reshaped

    the way scholars understood the MNE and its boundaries (Tallman, 2003; Verbeke, 2003).

    Until Kogut and Zander (1993), the existence of the MNE was largely attributed to the failure

    of markets for critical intermediates such as knowledge, raw materials, and distribution

    (Hennart, 2001). According to proponents of this approach, whether the cross-border transfer

    of a firm's ownership advantage, e.g., its proprietary knowledge, occurs on the market or

    through hierarchical modes such as joint ventures or wholly-owned subsidiaries depends on

    whether or not there is a viable market for that advantage (Buckley & Casson, 1976; Hennart,

    1982; Rugman, 1981). In some instances, markets fail for reasons related to opportunism

    (Williamson, 1985), necessitating the internalization of that transfer. Kogut and Zander (1993)

    took issue with this explanation and argued that it is overdetermined with its reliance on

    opportunism. In building their case, they introduced the concept of tacitness of knowledge to

    the literature which until then considered knowledge as a public good that is easy to transfer

    but hard to protect. By bringing tacitness of knowledge into the picture, they established that

    the transfer of tacit knowledge, due to the difficulty in describing and teaching it, may not be

    easy even among willing parties. However, because routines, values, and assumptions are

    shared within the firm, it turns out less costly to transfer tacit knowledge internally. Hence,

    according to Kogut and Zander (1993), the existence of the MNE, or more precisely, the

    transfer of tacit knowledge across borders through hierarchical modes can be attributed

    simply to the efficiency of firms in transferring knowledge internally. The notion of

    opportunism is redundant.

    Kogut and Zanders thesis received a lot of support (e.g. Love, 1995; Tallman, 2003),

    but also provoked a series of critiques (Foss, 1996a; 1996b; McFetridge, 1995), rebuttals

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    8/51

    7

    (Kogut & Zander, 1995), and reflections (Kogut & Zander, 2003). Like Kogut and Zander,

    Love (1995) too asserts that opportunism is not necessary to explain the existence of the firm.

    But unlike them, Love (1995) maintains that firms exist because of market failure, but a

    different class of it that comes not from opportunism but from genuine unbridgeable

    differences in routines. Madhoks (1996) argument is similar and largely consistent with

    Kogut & Zanders. From a transaction cost perspective, on the other hand, McFetridge (1995)

    argued that the reason firms transfer tacit knowledge internally is because the potential for

    opportunism is subdued when transactions are organized through hierarchical modes. Kogut

    and Zanders finding that MNEs transfer tacit knowledge internally rather than externally,

    thus, is entirely consistent with transaction cost reasoning that is based on opportunism

    (McFetridge, 1995). Several other scholars too have weighed in on this issue of whether

    opportunism matters (e.g., Foss, 1996a; 1996b; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996), and the debate

    continues (e.g., Fransson et al., 2011), but largely on conceptual terrain. Empirical evidence

    for whether or not opportunism matters is rare, not only in the TCE literature that rests on the

    notion of opportunism (Tsang, 2006), but also in the KBV literature that refutes it.

    THEORY

    Theoretical Strategy

    As we have indicated, a key bottleneck in the opportunism debate as it has played out in the

    international strategy literature is that predictions from TCE and KBV regarding the transfer

    of tacit know-how are identical. Hence, what would help make progress, in our view, is a way

    to draw and empirically test distinctive predictions based on the 'with opportunism' and

    'without opportunism' logics of both theories. As we demonstrate below, this can be done by

    means of contingency arguments. Furthermore, contingency arguments are native to the key

    logics of both KBV and TCE, so portraying them as such is really just more precise

    articulation.

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    9/51

    8

    Take the KBV for example. Kogut and Zander (1993) argue that firms are social

    communities that specialize in the creation and internal transfer of knowledge. Firms are

    simply better at transferring tacit knowledge. And this is largely because they are a

    ...repository of social knowledge that structures cooperative action... (p.627). In other

    words, firms naturally beget the cooperation and coordination necessary to transfer tacit

    knowledge. The reverse argument then is also true; the key hurdle in transferring knowledge

    to unaffiliated firms is that transferor and recipient lack a common social fabric. When

    unaffiliated firms lack the same routines, structures, and identity as the transferor, extra effort

    needs to go into teaching the recipient, and transfer becomes costly. Herein lies the key

    contingency in the knowledge based view. Tacitness of know-how, per se, is not the real

    barrier to its transfer. Tacit knowledge can be transferred (it is transferred within the firm,

    after all), but less easily so, when the recipient lacks similar routines. Kogut and Zander do

    emphasize that differential routines between transferor and recipient are what matter (p.630),

    a point that Love (1995) too nicely summarizes: ...the boundaries of the firm are

    determined...by differential 'embedded capabilities' that exist between creators of knowledge

    and its users (p.400). By embedded capabilities, Love essentially means routines. Although

    there is a bit of confusion over which side of the debate Teece (1986) stands (cf., Love, 1995:

    402), his statement that trying to transact tacit knowledge may ...fail if it must take place

    between unaffiliated enterprises with different internal cultures (and) codes of

    communication... (Teece, 1986: 29) also attests to the point we are making. Transferring tacit

    knowledge is problematic only to the extent that the recipient lacks the appropriate routines.

    This contingency argument is inherent in the knowledge based view of the firm.

    Let us move on to TCE. An important rebuttal from TCE to Kogut and Zander's

    thesis is that the relationship between tacitness and internal transfer can easily be explained by

    transaction cost theory (McFetridge, 1995). Firms are indeed relatively efficient in

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    10/51

    9

    transferring tacit knowledge but this is because the market for tacit knowledge fails. And

    according to TCE theorists, opportunism is what drives this failure. The key implication of

    this argument is that contracting for tacit knowledge on the market becomes a problem only to

    the extent that conditions of opportunism exist. One such condition, for example, is when

    transaction specific investments are needed. Transaction specific investments and the resulting

    lock-in problems are a breeding ground for opportunism related contractual problems

    (Williamson, 1985). So tacitness could pose a problem to contractual exchange, but more so

    in the presence of transaction specific investments. McFetridge (1995: 410) clarifies this and

    says: if there were no transaction-specific investments and hence no lock-in, (tacitness) need

    not burden market and unified governance differentially. It is also widely acknowledged in

    the TCE literature that uncertainty coupled with asset specificity begets contractual problems

    (Leiblein & Miller, 2003; Williamson, 1985). In our context of know-how transfer,

    uncertainty arises from the difficulty in defining and specifying tacit knowledge. And

    whenever assets are specific in nontrivial degree, [an increased] degree of uncertainty makes

    it more imperative that the parties devise a machinery to 'work things out' (Williamson,

    1985: 60). In other words, the combination of uncertainty and asset specificity is what

    necessitates hierarchical solutions. So the kernel of transaction cost theory too is a

    contingency argument. Tacitness matters only to the extent that transferor and recipient face

    circumstances that beget opportunism concerns.

    Phrasing our KBV and TCE predictions as contingency statements, thus, is consistent

    with the conceptual core of both theories. There are also empirical benefits of employing

    contingency arguments in the KBV-TCE debate. They bring sharper focus to the terms of

    disagreement by better capturing the underlying causal mechanisms of both theories (cf.

    Rajan & Zingales, 1998), and in turn, allow us to test the competing logics. The first set of

    contingency arguments we propose below are on how the effect of tacitness varies with the

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    11/51

    10

    potential for opportunism, and the second, on how it varies with similarity of routines and

    culture between transferor and recipient.

    Hypotheses Development

    As a baseline, and as TCE and KBV scholars in the international strategy field have

    suggested, we maintain that tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through

    hierarchical modes than on the market (Kogut & Zander, 1993; McFetridge, 1995). So our

    baseline hypothesis is that the more tacit the know-how, the more likely it will be transferred

    through hierarchical modes than on the market. However, in order to accurately portray and

    test TCE and KBV predictions relating to how tacit know-how is transferred, in the following

    sections we frame propositions as contingency statements.

    Tacitness, opportunism, and internal transfer. Contracting on the market works well

    when the buyer and seller have a fairly good understanding of what is being exchanged

    (Arrow, 1962; Barzel, 1989; Mayer & Nickerson, 2005). And for this reason, transacting any

    kind of knowledge on the market is inherently difficult because the buyer does not completely

    know what he is buying (Arrow, 1962; Hennart, 1982) and the seller cannot describe it to the

    buyer because in doing so he reveals it free of charge. This problem only gets compounded

    when the knowledge is tacit as well. This information asymmetry between buyer and seller is

    the first contributor to market failure for knowledge. The second, is opportunism. When it is

    difficult to clearly specify the details of the knowledge being transferred, the seller has

    sufficient room to behave opportunistically. And so, the buyer maybe concerned, ex-ante, that

    the seller is exploiting the information asymmetry and quoting a higher price, or that, ex-post,

    the seller will not deliver what was promised. With room for such opportunistic manoeuvres,

    it is unlikely that the buyer will consent to a market-based contractual transfer of the

    knowledge. The safeguards and opportunism-mitigation inherent in hierarchy (Hennart, 1988;

    Oxley, 1997; Sampson, 2004) become necessary. The seller too may have similar opportunism

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    12/51

    11

    concerns, but mainly around whether or not he/she will be able to fully appropriate rents on

    the knowledge (Oxley, 1997). If the buyer uses the knowledge ex-post in ways not covered by

    the contract, the seller may lose access to rents that are legally due to him/her. Tacit

    knowledge, by definition, is not patentable, and so the ability to prevent such

    misappropriation is weak. The market for tacit know-how thus fails under conditions of

    opportunism. And given the opportunism-mitigating properties of hierarchy (Hennart, 1988;

    Oxley, 1997; Sampson, 2004), such know-how is likely to be transferred through hierarchical

    modes.

    However, the threat of opportunism is not uniform across all transactions. Some

    conditions beget greater opportunism concerns than others. We focus on two such conditions

    when the know-how is of central importance to the recipient, and when it requires specific

    investments by the recipient.

    When the know-how being transferred is central to the recipient, this raises the

    sceptre of opportunism for both the transferor and recipient. Recall that from the recipient's

    perspective, the key concern is that the transferor may misrepresent the value of the know-

    how, or not deliver as promised. These are always concerns for the recipient when contracting

    for know-how, but arguably, more of a concern when the know-how being purchased is

    critical to its operations. The stakes are higher since the recipient has more to lose from the

    poor performance of know-how related to its core operations. Consequently, he/she will be

    particularly wary about the transferor being opportunistic and misrepresenting the value or

    defaulting on the delivery of the know-how. From the transferor's side too, the stakes are high.

    Everything else constant, the potential for the recipient to misappropriate know-how that is

    central to its operations is higher because the recipient may have better ability and incentive to

    do so. It is likely that recipients are more capable of misusing technologies in the areas of

    operation they are most familiar with. And the gains from doing so are higher. Thus from both

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    13/51

    12

    the recipient's and transferor's perspectives, concerns over opportunism are likely to be higher

    when the know-how is central to the recipient.

    Putting these arguments together, it becomes clear that transferring tacit know-how

    on the market is likely to fail, but more so when it is central to the recipient. In such cases,

    both parties are likely to take recourse to transfer through more hierarchical modes, where the

    incentives to act opportunistically are drastically reduced (Hennart, 1993; McFetridge, 1995;

    Williamson, 1985). It is perhaps useful to reiterate our key point that from the TCE point of

    view, the market failure for tacit know-how, and the need to replace markets with internal

    transfer, is not due to tacitness per se, but because of associated opportunism concerns. By

    specifying the following contingency hypothesis we directly capture this underlying causal

    mechanism.

    Hypothesis 1: Tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes

    (e.g., through joint ventures) than on the market (e.g., through licensing), but more so when

    the know-how is central to the recipient's operations.

    As we briefly alluded to earlier, another situation likely to give rise to opportunism

    concerns is when the recipient is required to make specific investments to implement the

    know-how (Shelanski & Klein, 1995). The problems associated with asset specificity and how

    it yields room for opportunism concerns have received a lot of commentary in the TCE

    literature (for the sake of brevity we do not repeat them here). And as mentioned earlier, the

    combination of asset specificity with uncertainty raises significant transaction costs

    (Williamson, 1985).

    Again, as discussed above, a key concern for the recipient in attempting to contract

    for tacit know-how is that the transferor may change terms of the contract ex-post and not

    deliver as promised. This is always a concern but a greater one when the recipient has

    invested heavily in specific investments. The cost to the recipient of the transferor

    opportunistically reneging on the contract is immensely higher. Thus:

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    14/51

    13

    Hypothesis 2: Tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes

    (e.g., through joint ventures) than on the market (e.g., through licensing), but more so when

    the recipient needs to make specific investments to implement the know-how.

    Tacitness, similarity of routines and culture, and internal transfer. The knowledge-

    based view of the MNE contends that it is not opportunism but the difficulty in effectively

    coordinating with third parties that prevents firms from transferring tacit knowledge on the

    market. If that is indeed the case, then firms should be more likely to transfer tacit knowledge

    externally when routines and organizational culture of the recipient are similar to their own 2

    Tacit knowledge is not easy to describe and makes systematic transfer cumbersome

    (Nonaka, 1994). Codifying tacit knowledge in order to make it teachable requires extensive

    communication and coordination between source and recipient. In the context of knowledge

    transfer, prior research suggests that similarity in management styles between the source and

    recipient results in similarity of work expectations, operating procedures and interpretation of

    strategic issues (Olk, 1997; Park & Ungson, 1997; 2001; Simonin, 1999). Compared to their

    culturally distant counterparts, organizations that share similar expectations and

    .

    Culture is typically considered a set of cognitions shared by members of a social unit [such

    as an organization] (OReilly et al., 1991:491; Scott, 2001; Smircich, 1983). Such shared

    cognition, which involves translating events consistently and developing shared meanings and

    conceptual schemes (Daft & Weick, 1984; Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994), guide the behavior

    of organizational members (Rousseau, 1990; Schein, 1985) and allows them to develop

    common interpretations (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994). Scholars argue that shared mental

    models held by organizational members result in effective coordination (Klimoski &

    Mohammed, 1994; Srikanth & Puranam, 2011).

    2The need for articulating the knowledge based view as a contingency argument is evident in commentary by

    Fransson et al. (2011: 430) that ...it cannot be assumed that firms are always better attransferring...knowledge in house than through market transactions,...there may be conditions, as yet

    unspecified, when this might be the case. The only disagreement we have is that the conditions are notunspecified. The key condition under which firms are better at transferring knowledge, as we argue, is when

    potential recipients have a culture and routines dissimilar routines to those of the transferor.

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    15/51

    14

    interpretations need to expend less effort and energy in devising compatible inter-

    organizational routines. This in turn facilitates better communication between them (Park &

    Ungson, 1997; 2001) and reduces knowledge exchange costs (Jensen & Szulanski, 2004).

    Therefore, when an unaffiliated knowledge recipient shares similar values and cognitions with

    the transferor, that similarity facilitates better communication and effective coordination. In

    turn, this should encourage the transfer of tacit knowledge on the market rather than through a

    more hierarchical mode, such as joint venture.

    Second, because tacit knowledge is firmly embedded in context, it is important to

    understand the context in which knowledge is stored and retrieved (Nonaka, 1994). In

    knowledge-exchange, scholars have argued that an organizations culture represents its history

    and is therefore considered one of the facilities where the organizations memory is retained

    for future reference (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994; Walsh & Ungson, 1991). Thus, an

    organizations culture, besides providing a framework for information processing, enables it

    to store knowledge (Brief & Downey, 1983; Busenitz & Lau, 1996; Gray, Bougen, &

    Donnellon, 1985; Harris, 1994; Shaw, 1990). Accordingly, organizations that are culturally

    similar tend to organize and store knowledge in a mutually understandable manner (Schneider

    & Angelmar, 1993) as well as retrieve knowledge from their memory in similar ways

    (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994). Their framework for decision-making, problem-solving,

    information and knowledge processing tends to be comparable as well (Mitchell et al., 2000).

    Thus, a recipient that is similar to the transferor in terms of organizational culture is more

    likely to understand the context in which the transferors knowledge is embedded, which

    makes the transfer of tacit knowledge easier.

    Taken together, these arguments suggest that the relative efficiency of internal

    transfer of tacit knowledge reduces when the knowledge recipient shares the same (or similar)

    routine and culture as the transferor. Hence:

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    16/51

    15

    Hypothesis 3: Tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes

    (e.g., through joint ventures) than on the market (e.g., through licensing), but less so when the

    transferor and recipient are similar in their organizational routines and culture.

    METHODS

    Empirical Context

    We test these hypotheses using data from a survey of technology recipients in joint

    ventures and technology licensing arrangements between foreign and domestic firms in India.

    Our choice of the survey method and the target population of licensing and joint ventures (as

    opposed to, say, wholly-owned subsidiaries), as well as our decision to survey the recipient

    and not the transferor were deliberate. Scholars in the past have relied on secondary data to

    study licensing and joint ventures (Gulati, 1995; Oxley, 1997). But with secondary data, as

    those very scholars admit, ...it is very difficult to obtain data on aspects of technology

    transferred...such as tacitness or age... (Oxley, 1997: 394). Hence, to get at the attributes and

    details of the technology transferred, a survey is more appropriate. Our decision to survey the

    technology recipient is rather unique but necessary in our case for two reasons. First, some of

    the moderating variables we propose in our hypotheses, e.g., centrality of know-how to the

    recipient and the extent of specific investments it needed to make, are obviously best

    measured by surveying the recipient. Secondly, and perhaps more importantly, it seems to us

    appropriate to measure tacitness of the technology being transferred through the eyes of the

    recipient. Whether a technology is perceived as tacit or not, depends on the experience and

    repertoire of capabilities of the recipient. What might seem simple or codifiable technology to

    the transferor may appear complex and unclear to a recipient who lacks the relevant

    experience or capabilities. So the recipient's perception of tacitness is at least equally (and

    perhaps even more) relevant to the choice of mode of transfer. Surveying the recipient

    automatically precludes foreign wholly-owned subsidiaries from our sampling frame because

    in wholly-owned operations there is no unaffiliated recipient. Our empirical focus is thus on

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    17/51

    16

    licensing and joint ventures and on the choice between them, considering licensing closer to a

    market contract and joint ventures closer to a hierarchical solution to knowledge transfer

    (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hennart, 1988; Oxley, 1997; Phene & Tallman, 2012).

    Surveying only licensing and joint ventures, if anything, makes our empirical tests

    more conservative. Compared to the differences between licensing and wholly-owned

    subsidiaries, the differences between licensing and joint venture are less distinctive. They do

    for sure differ in transaction cost mitigating and knowledge transfer properties (Oxley, 1997),

    but these differences are not as stark as between licensing and wholly-owned subsidiaries.

    Also, given that most tacit know-how is perhaps transferred through wholly-owned

    subsidiaries, which we do not observe, the variation in tacitness in our dataset is likely to be

    limited. All these factors militate against us in finding any significant results. Focussing on

    the choice between licensing and joint ventures thus only raises the bar for us, making it even

    harder to find any significant results.

    Data

    We used Capitaline, a secondary database, and member lists of various international chambers

    of commerce in India to identify a sample of 700 international licensing and joint venture

    agreements operating in India. Following Parkhe (1993) and Simonin (1999), we aimed to

    target respondents highly knowledgeable about the relationships. In our case these were

    mainly managing directors and chief executive officers. We obtained the names of these target

    respondents from Capitaline and chambers of commerce data.

    We designed our questionnaire and implemented our survey according to Dillmans

    (2000) 'Tailored Design Method', which suggests several ways to encourage response. Our

    measurement items were generated through a review of prior literature. We used university

    faculty and doctoral students to assess the content of the items and to ascertain whether the

    items tapped into the conceptual domain of the focal construct (DeVellis, 1991). This yielded

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    18/51

    17

    a set of fine-tuned questionnaire items that were used in personal interviews and early pre-

    tests with managing directors of Indian firms involved in international licensing and joint

    venture agreements. These steps allowed us to check for any item ambiguity.

    The first wave of questionnaires was sent to managing directors and senior

    executives of the 700 Indian firms we identified that had licensing and joint venture

    agreements with foreign firms. This was followed, four weeks later, by a second wave of

    survey mailings. Of the 700 managing directors and senior executives that received

    questionnaires, 126 responded, yielding an 18% response rate. This is comparable to surveys

    of such relationships in other emerging economies: e.g., 14.4% for China (Isobe, Makino &

    Montgomery, 2000), and 19% for Mexico (Robins, Tallman & Lindquist, 2002). All the

    responses to our survey came from individuals directly responsible for the relationships: 80

    came from chairpersons and managing directors of the alliances, 30 from presidents, vice

    presidents and general managers, and 16 from full-time directors. Nearly 75% of the

    respondents had been with the firm for more than five years, and of these almost 25% for

    more than 20 years. The foreign partners of Indian firms we surveyed were spread over 21

    countries. All relationships in our sample are dyadic, and belong to industries in the

    manufacturing sector where licensing and joint ventures are more prevalent (e.g., Parkhe,

    1993; Simonin, 1999). Tests of proportions show that the distribution of our responses

    according to their two-digit manufacturing SIC is not statistically different from that reported

    in two landmark studies by Harrigan (1988) and Ghemawat, Porter & Rawlison (1986). The

    top four industries in our sample rank in the same order as in these studies, and as others have

    also found (e.g. Parkhe, 1993), are relatively high-tech (industrial machinery and equipment,

    chemicals and allied products, electrical and electronic equipment, and transportation

    equipment).

    Some of our key measures were collected using the same survey instrument and from

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    19/51

    18

    a single respondent. Hence we undertook multiple procedural and statistical remedies to

    address the potential concern of common method bias and single informant bias. Specifically,

    we undertook procedural remedies such as protecting respondent anonymity, scale reordering,

    and reducing item ambiguity, as well as statistical remedies like Harmans (1967) one factor

    test. Based on these, we are confident that common method or single respondent bias is not a

    serious problem in our study.

    We checked the potential for non-response bias by comparing the characteristics of

    our respondents to those of the targeted population sample. T-tests for the size of the firms (p

    = 0.284) and age of the Indian firm (p = 0.344) revealed no significant differences between

    respondent and non-respondent groups. In line with Mohr & Spekman (1994) and Poppo &

    Zenger (2002), we also tested for non-response bias by comparing early and late respondents.

    Armstrong & Overton (1977) argue that late respondents are more representative of non-

    respondents. We found no significant difference between early and late respondents on

    characteristics such as number of employees of the Indian partner (p = 0.18) and relationship

    duration (p = 0.29).

    Dependent Variable

    We used a dummy variable to represent the mode of know-how transfer. This variable, JV,

    took the value 1 when know-how was transferred via joint venture, and 0 when it was through

    a licensing agreement. We carefully considered using on a more nuanced version of this

    variable based on the fact that an ideal test of transaction cost theory requires a dependent

    variable that captures finer aspects of safeguards built into the contract (Malhotra &

    Lumineau, 2011; Mesquita & Brush, 2008). Hierarchy is not the only solution to transaction

    costs; other safeguards such as contracts of longer duration (Crocker & Masten, 1988;

    Joskow, 1985; 1987), exclusivity (Gallick, 1984), or even relational assets (Madhok, 2006)

    could meet the same opportunism-mitigation purposes. So ideally, the extent of contractual

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    20/51

    19

    safeguards, irrespective of it source, should be our dependent variable.

    However, we stuck with the more conventional market hierarchy dichotomy measure

    for three reasons. Firstly, we needed our measure to be relevant to the debate we are

    contributing to. In other words, we needed a dependent variable that would be flexible enough

    to reflect both KBV and TCE mechanisms and thus appeal to both camps. While finer details

    of the contract would help in better capturing opportunism-mitigation elements of the

    governance structure, it is unclear how it would better represent the commonality of social

    fabric that, according to KBV, eases the cost of transfer. Secondly, the debate at the center of

    our work has primarily been around why firms are more efficient carriers of tacit know-how,

    or alternatively, why tacit know-how is transferred internally as opposed to on the market. For

    the sake of relevance to this question, we persisted with our dichotomous variable; it picks up

    whether the know-how transfer was within-firm or to an unaffiliated party. Thirdly, despite

    recent advances, the terrain of contract research where scholars micro-analyze contracts to

    capture their finer transaction cost mitigation characteristics still has teething problems.

    These include issues like which clauses of the contract to look at, whether sets of clauses still

    serve opportunism mitigation when they interact with each other, and indeed the definition of

    a contractual safeguard (Mayer, 2009). As a simple example, while Mesquita & Brush (2008)

    measure contract completeness with the number of contingency clauses included in the

    contract, Crocker & Reynolds (1993) consider those with fewer contingency clauses more

    complete because such contracts potentially cover broader areas of dispute. As TCE scholars

    duly acknowledge, contract research is an area where the enterprise as a whole needs to

    improve (Mayer, 2009). Without specific guidance from the literature on specific contract-

    based measures, and not to distract from the main goal of the paper, we decided to stick with

    our parsimonious measure. Our measure is not without precedent, though. Several other

    scholars both from KBV and TCE approaches have dichotomized the governance choice

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    21/51

    20

    into market or hierarchy (Colombo, 2003; Kogut & Zander, 1993; Mayer & Salomon, 2006;

    Nickerson & Silverman, 2003; Osborn & Baughn, 1990; Phene & Tallman, 2012; Sampson,

    2004)

    Independent Variables

    Our main independent variable is tacitness, and our moderator variables fall under two

    groups: the potential for opportunism and the commonality of social fabric across transferor

    and recipient.As we explain below, we conceptualized tacitness as tacitness of the know-how

    packagebeing transferred. We also used two indicators of potential opportunism - centrality

    of know-how to the recipient(for hypothesis 1) and size of specific investment(for hypothesis

    2). We captured the commonality in social fabric across transferor and recipient using a

    variable similarity of routines and culture (hypothesis 3).

    Tacitness. In measuring tacitness, we focussed on the tacitness of the know-how

    package being transferred. The know-how package refers to the entire package being

    transferred, and includes not only the core technology, but also the surrounding supporting

    skills. The know-how package thus varies with the range of supporting skills needed from the

    foreign partner by the recipient. Capable recipients need fewer skills and vice-versa. So to

    measure tacitness of the know-how package, we used a five-item measure that captured the

    recipients need for supporting skills to implement the core technology. Specifically, based on

    prior conceptual descriptions (Baranson, 1969; Hall and Johnson, 1970; Odagiri, et al., 2010),

    we operationalized this variable by asking recipients whether or not the marketing and

    production skills they possessed matched those required to produce and sell the product for

    which know-how is being sourced, and whether they required production process, marketing,

    management, and other technical assistance to implement the technology contributed by the

    transferor. The key insight underpinning this measure is that as the need for tacit skills such as

    marketing and management increases, so does the overall tacitness of the know-how package.

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    22/51

    21

    This measure had satisfactory reliability. An important consideration when using

    binary items in a scale, as we do, is that the traditional Cronbach alpha can be negatively

    biased; an ordinal alpha, based on tetrachoric or polychoric correlations, is more appropriate

    (Zumbo, Gadermann, & Zeisser, 2007). For our five items, the ordinal alpha was 0.68. We

    also conducted factor analysis to assess construct validity. Following an orthogonal rotation,

    we extracted one factor that had an eigenvalue greater than 1 and accounted for 85% of total

    variance. The last three out of the five items loaded well onto this one factor with loadings

    greater than 0.65 and the 0.40 cut-off normally prescribed (Ford, MacCallum, & Tait, 1986).

    For our main analyses we therefore chose to retain only the last three items in the scale.

    Redoing factor analysis with only the last three items returned factor loadings that were

    higher than 0.71. Also, the ordinal reliability alpha improved significantly from 0.68 to 0.79.

    To be sure though, we ran our regressions with both the three-item and the five-item index

    and obtained substantially similar results.

    Moderators. In capturing the potential for opportunism, we resorted to unobtrusive

    measures (Webb & Weick, 1979). As research on personality traits has shown, using direct

    survey questions to capture negative constructs such as narcissm (Chatterjee & Hambrick,

    2007), racism (Newman & Krzystofiak, 1979), or in our context, opportunism, is likely to

    elicit low response rates and social desirability bias. Hence, rather than trying to measure

    opportunism itself as some scholars have done (Anderson, 1988; Sako & Helper, 1998), we

    used unobtrusive indicators of opportunism (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Klein et al., 1978; Oxley,

    1997).

    We measured centrality of know-how to the recipient using a dummy variable. We

    asked the respondent who in our case was also the recipient whether the know-how was

    central to its operations, and coded the variable 1 if the answer was in the affirmative, and 0

    otherwise.

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    23/51

    22

    To measure size of specific investment, we asked the recipient to indicate the size of

    investment that had to be made specifically to implement the know-how, and was less relevant

    to other uses. This variable was coded in five bands: 1 for specific investments of less than

    US$10 million, 2 for investments between US$ 10 and 45 million, 3 for investments between

    US$45 and 110 million, 4 for investments between US$110 and 220 million, and 5 for those

    above US$ 220 million. Our contention is that higher values on this variable indicate greater

    levels of asset specificity (Dyer, 1996). This measure meets the three guidelines Mayer (2009)

    offers to increase construct validity of empirical measures of transaction-specific investments.

    That is, our item captures the specificity of the investment, the size (and not only the

    presence) of the investment, and we obtain this information from the firm making the

    investment and not from just any of the firms involved in the transaction.

    To measure similarity of routines and culture, we used a two-item measure to capture

    the extent to which there was overlap in the transferor's and recipient's organizational routines

    and culture. Specifically, we used five point likert type items to ask the respondents to what

    extent their business practices and operational mechanisms, and organizational culture and

    management style were similar to that of their foreign partner. This scale had an ordinal alpha

    of 0.80.

    Control Variables

    To control for alternative explanations for the relationship between our dependent

    and independent variables, we included controls for industry, age of the technology, cultural

    distance between home country of the foreign firm and India, and prior export experience of

    the foreign firm in India.

    Tacitness of a technology could be correlated with its age. As time wears on, details

    of the know-how become more established and well known. And it has been shown that older

    technologies are more likely to be transferred on the market (Davidson & McFetridge, 1985).

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    24/51

    23

    To rule out any correlation we observe between tacitness and choice of transfer mode being

    due to the common correlation with age of the technology, we specifically controlled for it.

    Age of technology was coded 1 when the respondent indicated that the core technology

    transferred (the technology stricto sensu) had been introduced in the transferors home

    country within the past year, 2 when it was two to three years old, 3 when it was three to five

    years old and 4 when its first introduction was more than five years ago.

    Cultural distance between the foreign and Indian firm could be correlated with both

    the latter's perception of tacitness and the mode of transfer. Whether a given technology

    appears tacit or not to a recipient could be partly a function of the cultural distance between

    the sender and recipient, and cultural distance has been shown to influence the choice between

    licensing and joint venture (Garca-Canal, Valds-Llaneza, & Snchez-Lorda, 2008). Hence

    we included cultural distance, measured using the Kogut & Singh (1988) index, as a control.

    A technology transferor who has been exporting to India in the past may be more

    willing to make greater resource commitments, i.e. to choose an EJV over a licensing

    agreement. To control for this, we included Prior Export, a dummy variable that was coded 1

    if the foreign firm had exported its products to India prior to the present collaboration and 0

    otherwise.

    Finally, to control for possible industry effects, we included industry dummies for

    chemicals, electronics, industrial machinery and transportation equipment industries. We are

    unable to include dummies for all industries in our data because the number of observations

    per industry is not large enough to justify that.

    RESULTS

    We report descriptive statistics and pair-wise correlations in table 1. Given the binary nature

    of our dependent variable, we used logistic regression to estimate the coefficients in our

    model. The results of our conventional logistic regression analyses are in table 2. To test our

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    25/51

    24

    hypotheses, we include in our models interaction terms between tacitness and each of our

    moderator variables. To attenuate problems related to multicollinearity, we mean-centered

    these variables before multiplying them to create the interaction terms. Model 1 includes only

    control variables, models 2 and 3 include the main independent variables, and models 4, 5,

    and 6 include interaction terms one at a time. Model 7 is the full model that includes all three

    sets of variables controls, independent variables, and the interaction terms. The main

    variables of interest, given our hypotheses, are the interaction terms. Looking at the

    coefficient estimates and their standard errors in model 7, we find support for hypotheses 1

    and 2, but not for hypotheses 3.

    --------------Please insert tables 1 and 2 about here-----------

    However, interpreting results in logistic regression models is notoriously difficult

    (Hoetkar, 2007). Unlike in linear regressions, estimates of coefficients in non-linear models,

    such as the logistic one, do not represent the actual marginal effect of independent variables.

    In the logistic case, the effect of each variable is non linear, and depends on its own values as

    well as on the values of other independent variables in the model. Interpreting interaction

    terms is even less straightforward. The coefficients of interaction terms are not equal to their

    marginal effect (Ai & Norton, 2003; Zelner, 2009) and conventional tests of statistical

    significance are wrong (Zelner, 2009).

    To make interpretation easy and to draw valid conclusions from logistic regressions,

    Zelner (2009) recommends computing differences in predicted probabilities () at different

    values of the independent variables. For example, we could calculate the predicted probability

    of joint venture () while holding tacitness at its minimum value and other independent

    variables at some theoretically interesting level. We could then repeat this, this time holding

    tacitness at its maximum value. The difference between these two predicted probabilities ()

    i.e., at low and high levels of tacitness - indicates the 'effect' of tacitness on the probability

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    26/51

    25

    to joint venture. To get a sense of the magnitude of interaction effects, we could calculate

    at different values of the moderating variable. That is, we could calculate and compare the

    effect of tacitness () when the know-how is central to the recipient as well as when it is not.

    This double difference (), the difference in the effect of tacitness () when know-how

    is central to the recipient and when it is not, represents the interaction effect. If we find that

    the effect of tacitness is different when the know-how transferred is central to the recipient

    and when it is not, this suggests an interaction effect. And if we find that the effect of tacitness

    on joint venture is stronger when know-how is central to the recipient, this supports

    hypothesis 1.

    While examining differences in predicted probabilities () and double differences

    () gives us a sense of the magnitude of the effects we are interested in, we still do not

    know if these magnitudes are statistically significant. To calculate statistical significance,

    Zelner (2009) recommends a simulation-based method drawn from the political science

    discipline (King, Tomz, & Wittenberg, 2000). Essentially here, confidence intervals for

    coefficients, differences in predicted probabilities, and double differences are computed by

    drawing several values of these estimates from a simulated distribution. Using these

    confidence intervals, we can make inferences about statistical significance. We implemented

    this procedure by using the clarify suite of programs written for Stata (Tomz, Wittenberg,

    & King, 2001). The results of these analyses are in tables 3 and 4.

    ---------------Please insert tables 3 and 4 about here-------------

    Table 3 shows the effect of tacitness () at minimum and maximum values of other

    variables. The predicted probability of joint venture at low levels of tacitness and when the

    know-how is central to the recipient is 0.30 (row 1(b), column 1 in table 3). This increases to

    0.96 in cases where the know-how transferred is highly tacit (row 1(b), column 2 in table 3).

    The effect of tacitness, when know-how is central to the recipient, is thus 0.66. In a similar

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    27/51

    26

    way, tacitness increases the probability of joint venture by 0.15 when the size of specific

    investment variable is held at its minimum (row 2(a); column 3), and by 0.96 when the size of

    specific investment is very high (row 2(b); column 3). We also compute the confidence

    intervals for these effects. Essentially, if the confidence interval contains 0, is insignificant,

    and vice-versa. An interesting result that is not revealed in the conventional logistic regression

    results is that the effect of tacitness varies in magnitude across values of other variables. Also,

    the effect of tacitness is significant only at higher levels of the other variables. This is

    suggestive of interaction effects.

    Based on Zelners (2009) recommendation, we also plot these results in figures 1, 2,

    and 3. Figure 1 depicts the estimated effect of tacitness () along with its 95 percent

    confidence intervals at various (mean-centered) values of centrality of know-how to the

    recipient. The line in the plot that is bounded by confidence intervals represents the effect of

    tacitness () at various levels of centrality of know-how to the recipient. The narrow

    vertical rectangles denote the confidence intervals associated with these estimates. Figures 2

    and 3 show the plots for size of specific investmentand similar routinesrespectively.

    -----------Please insert figures 1, 2, and 3 about here-----------

    The statistical test of the interaction hypotheses is essentially whether the effect of

    tacitness at low and high values of the moderator variables are significantly different. This is

    what we represent in table 4. As per Zelner's recommendation we compute double differences

    (). These are the differences between the effects of tacitness at lowest and highest values

    of the moderating variables. We also construct confidence intervals that allow us to run

    statistical significance tests.

    Table 4 shows that there are large differences in the effect of tacitness at various

    values of the moderator variables. We find that tacitness has a much stronger effect when

    know-how is central to the recipient and when the need for specific investment is high. These

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    28/51

    27

    two results are consistent with transaction cost theory. Contrary to the prediction from the

    knowledge based view though tacitness seems to lead to the choice of joint venture when

    transferor and recipient have similar routines.

    Sensitivity Analysis

    We tested if our results were sensitive to alternative measures of tacitness. We recoded

    tacitness of the know-how packageas a count measure that took values from 1 to 5 depending

    on the number of types of supporting skills required. We also ran our analysis with another

    measure of tacitness tacitness of the core technology a set of three items that tapped into

    the extent to which the technology being transferred could be codified and taught, again

    measured from the recipient's perspective. Specifically, the five point likert type items

    captured the extent to which the technology transferred could be described in a manual, the

    extent to which the recipient can learn to manufacture the product or implement the

    manufacturing process by looking at a set of blueprints, and the extent to which

    manufacturing the product and/or implementing the process requires the on-site guidance of

    employees of the know-how transferring firm. The ordinal alpha for this measure was 0.75,

    and all three items loaded well onto one factor. Our results are robust to the use of these two

    different measures of tacitness.

    A possible threat to internal validity in our study lies in our use of single-item

    measures for centrality of know-how to the recipient and size of specific investment. One

    argument, based on the literature on (psychometric) measurement is that single-item measures

    are prone to measurement error. Measurement error in single-item scales could arise out of not

    being able to capture the multiple dimensions of a construct, and by leaving respondents with

    greater ambiguity to interpret the item in their own way. Moreover, one cannot compute a

    reliability statistic such as the cronbach or ordinal alpha in a single-item measure (Hoeppner

    et al., 2011). Using multiple items on the other hand generally allows for averaging out

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    29/51

    28

    random measurement error, and better means of capturing a complex construct. In our study,

    however, measurement error is unlikely to be a significant problem given that our single-item

    variables centrality of know-how to the recipientand size of specific investment capture

    objective and not perceptual data. We are indeed interested in the potential for opportunism in

    each transaction, but we do not directly measure the perception of opportunism (e.g.,

    Anderson, 1988; Sako & Helper, 1998). Instead, for reasons mentioned before and as several

    others have done (e.g., Gulati & Singh, 1998; Klein et al., 1978; Oxley, 1997 etc.), we infer

    the potential for opportunism from certain objective characteristics of the transaction. And for

    such objective characteristics, single-item measures are usually sufficient (e.g., Sako &

    Helper, 1998: 396). Measurement error in our single-item measures, thus, is likely to be small.

    Nevertheless, we did some additional analysis to assess the resilience of our results to

    potential measurement error. Specifically, we employed regression calibration (Carroll &

    Stefanski, 1990; Hardin, Schmiediche, & Carroll, 2003) to check the sensitivity of our

    estimation to measurement error. Measurement error in independent variables generally poses

    two problems for regression estimates: (a) it reduces the power of the test, making it more

    difficult to detect significant effects (Anderson, 1988: 255; Carroll et al., 2006), and (b)

    induces bias in the coefficient estimates (Carroll, et al., 2006; Hardin et al., 2003). The first is

    likely not a problem for our study because for the interaction terms that include our two

    single-item variables centrality of know-how to the recipient and size of specific investment,

    we do find significant effects. In other words, we get significant effects even when

    measurement error should have made finding support for our TCE hypotheses more difficult.

    The latter problem of potentially biased coefficients, on the other hand, is something we

    would like to rule out. To do this, we estimated two sequences of regression calibration

    models, one for centrality of know-how to the recipient and the other for size of specific

    investment. In each sequence we progressively attributed a larger proportion of the total

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    30/51

    29

    variance in the (single-item) variable and its interaction term to measurement error. For

    example, in the sequence of regression calibration models for size of specific investment, we

    initially assumed that all the variance in size of specific investment and its interaction term is

    due to actual variance in the true measures (i.e., zero measurement error). In subsequent re-

    runs of the model, we progressively increased the proportion of total variance due to

    measurement error to five, ten, fifteen, twenty, and twenty-five percent. Regression

    calibration modelling takes these estimates of error variance into account, and produces

    unbiased coefficients (Hardin & Carroll, 2003; Hardin, et al., 2003). We find that as we

    assume greater levels of measurement error, the unbiased coefficient estimate of the

    interaction terms are much larger than what we report in our main results table. In other

    words, if measurement error were present in our data, what we will have, more likely than

    not, is attenuation bias; in the other words, the coefficients we report here are smaller than

    what they ought to be. This obviously is not very disconcerting. It is perhaps useful to also

    note that the interaction term with size of specific investment remains significant in the

    regression calibration models. The interaction term with centrality of know-how to the

    recipient has the correct sign, but is significant only in a one-tailed test. This is not cause for

    excessive concern, however, given the inherent tendency in regression calibration models to

    trade off variability of the coefficient estimates in favour of unbiasedness (Carroll et al.,

    2006).

    Finally, while our results show that firms use structural solutions, such as equity joint

    ventures, to mitigate opportunism concerns in the transfer tacit knowledge, there is a rich line

    of research on how firms can handle opportunism but through informal solutions, such as

    trust-based governance (Madhok, 1995; Carson et al., 2003; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996). Gulati

    (1995) shows that partners formed non-equity alliances instead of equity alliances when they

    had prior ties, which he argued indicates the presence of prior trust between partners. We

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    31/51

    30

    tested if our results held even after controlling for prior familiarity between partners. We

    included in our regressions a dummy variable that indicated whether or not the recipient and

    transferor had a licensing or joint venture relationship before the focal one. And the results

    were not different from what we report here.

    DISCUSSION

    Our study seeks to contribute to the KBV-TCE debate on the relevance of

    opportunism for the theory of the firm. Both TCE and KBV predict that tacit know-how is

    more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes than on the market, but TCE

    attributes this to market failure arising from opportunism concerns and KBV, to the difficulty

    in transferring tacit know-how owing to the absence of similar routines. We see this as the key

    bottleneck in the debate this far. While both theories disagree on the relevance of

    opportunism, they arrive at identical predictions for how tacit know-how is transferred. This

    lack of predictive uniqueness has also hindered empirical tests of the competing causal

    mechanisms.

    In this paper, we sought to move the KBV-TCE debate forward by crafting and

    testing contingency arguments from both theories. We examined whether opportunism matters

    to how tacit know-how is transferred. In testing contingency arguments from TCE, we

    predicted that the likelihood of tacit know-how being transferred through hierarchical modes

    will be stronger when opportunism inducing conditions are prevalenti.e., when know-how

    is core to the recipient firm in the host country and when the specific investments made by the

    recipient firm is high. Similarly, in testing contingency arguments from KBV, we predicted

    that the likelihood of tacit know-how being transferred through hierarchical modes will be

    weaker when the organizational culture and routines of the transferor and recipient are similar.

    Irrespective of our empirical findings, this theoretical approach confers several

    advantages. Framing arguments from KBV and TCE as contingency statements brings

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    32/51

    31

    distinctiveness to the predictions of both theories, and in the process, greater clarity to the

    debate. Contingency arguments also allowed us to tease out and isolate the different causal

    mechanisms in KBV and TCE and as a result, we conduct more direct tests of TCE and KBV

    positions (Tsang, 2006).

    We considered several candidate moderators of the relationship between tacitness

    and transfer mode to use in our study, but not all of them were useful for our purpose, viz.,

    separating TCE and KBV predictions. On the one hand, many potential moderators that signal

    opportunism concerns can also be argued to signal transfer costs, but more importantly, the

    moderators that will do the job for us are those that deliver distinctive predictions for TCE

    and KBV. This is what has primarily guided our choice of moderators. From a TCE point of

    view we argue that when know-how is core to the recipient, it is likely to trigger opportunism

    concerns among both partieswith the transferor being concerned about potential knowledge

    leakage and the recipient, about misrepresentation of knowledge. Our second moderator,

    specific investment by the recipient, closely mirrors the TCE emphasis on asset specificity.

    These two, in our view, are distinctively TCE hypotheses. They are useful for our purpose

    because it is difficult to come up with knowledge-based explanations that result in the same

    predictions. Similarly, our third moderator similarity in routines and culture closely relates

    to the conceptual mechanisms of the knowledge-based view. It is difficult to draw an

    opportunism-based explanation for why similarity in routines should make the transfer of tacit

    know-how any easier.

    Besides the novelty of our theoretical approach that is based on contingency

    arguments, the fact that we bring some empirical evidence to bear on this debate is also

    valuable because the literature surrounding the debate has so far been largely on conceptual

    turf alone. Except for Kogut and Zanders (1993) article, all the other articles critiquing or

    defending their contention (e.g., McFetridge, 1995; Madhok, 1996; Love, 1995; Fransson et

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    33/51

    32

    al., 2011) have been conceptual. Even Kogut and Zanders (1993) article, although empirical

    in nature, was not able to partition out the causal mechanisms underlying KBV. As Kogut &

    Zander (1993: 633) themselves indicate, ...this test is by no means fully specified. In

    particular, we do not look at the capabilities of the recipient. Our paper has taken an

    empirical step forward in this direction.

    Implications

    The key implication of our study is that opportunism matters. Several aspects of our

    findings lend robust credence to this conclusion. Firstly, we set up two separate tests

    hypotheses 1 and 2 for whether opportunism matters, and across both, we find consistent

    results that it does. The likelihood of tacit know-how being transferred through hierarchy is

    significantly greater, both in terms of magnitude and statistical significance, when the know-

    how is core to the recipient and when the recipient has made transaction specific investments.

    So opportunism necessitates recourse to hierarchy whenever the transferor seeks to transfer

    tacit know-how. Secondly, the robustness of this conclusion also comes from the fact that our

    results hold even when characteristics of our empirical test militate against finding any

    significant results. As discussed earlier, our test, based on only licensing and joint ventures, is

    very conservative. Thirdly, we do not find evidence that that transfers will be via licensing

    when transferor and recipient share the same routines and culture. In fact we find the opposite,

    although this result is not statistically significant. That is, we find that the likelihood of joint

    venture is higher when tacit know-how is transferred to recipients with similar routines and

    culture as the transferor. If we assume for a moment that similar routines reflect the ability of

    the recipient to compete back against the transferor, this result may also be considered

    additional support for TCE. When routines are similar, the transferor is likely to want better

    avenues for monitoring the use of know-how. And this is better afforded through JVs than

    licensing.

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    34/51

    33

    The second key implication of our results is that the causal mechanism underlying

    the often observed link between tacitness and hierarchical transfer modes is opportunism and

    not ease of transfer due to similar routines. As we have mentioned, an important point of

    contention in the KBV-TCE debate is that the link between tacitness and hierarchy is equally

    amenable to both KBV and TCE explanations. The way we set up our tests, we were able to

    directly test which of these two mechanisms is in play. There were three occasions in our

    empirical analysis for the KBV argument to receive support and show through. Had the effect

    of knowledge tacitness on transfer mode choice been insensitive to opportunism concerns (in

    hypotheses 1 and 2), that would have been sufficient to support the KBV contention.

    However, our results support the contention that opportunism matters. We also examined

    separate contingencies for KBV that transferring tacit knowledge hierarchically might be less

    likely if organizational culture and routines are similar. Finding this would have lent support

    to KBV that it is transfer costs and not opportunism that guides transfer mode choice. Our

    result for this prediction too was not significant. Across these three sets of results, we think it

    is fairly robust conclusion that, at least in our empirical context, opportunism and not

    similarity of routines is the relevant causal mechanism in play.

    A third important implication of our study is that it speaks to the question of what do

    firms do? This is a significant issue for the theory of the firm in general (Conner, 1991;

    Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Grant, 1996; Kogut & Zander, 1992; 1996; Foss, 1996a; 1996b),

    but also for the study of joint ventures (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hennart, 1988). The dominant

    view until recent times has been that the raison d'etre for firms is their ability to curb

    opportunism. By virtue of better monitoring and incentive-alignment mechanisms, hierarchy

    reduces the payoffs from opportunism for the members of a firm (Kale & Puranam, 2004;

    Wathne & Heide, 2000; Williamson, 1985). To this end, Williamson (1985:66) says:

    ...market contracting would be ubiquitous in the face of nonopportunism. Departing from

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    35/51

    34

    this emphasis on opportunism and transaction cost mitigation, other scholars have suggested

    that what firms offer, over and above markets, is superior coordination abilities (Grant, 1996),

    the origins of which are in the social community of voluntaristic action inherent in firms

    (Kogut & Zander, 1992: 384). A similar opportunism-mitigation versus coordination argument

    has played out in the strategic alliance literature as well. One view in this literature is that

    joint ventures mainly serve an opportunism reduction purpose, i.e., since partners in a joint

    venture share from the gains of the venture, their incentives are aligned and they are less

    likely to act opportunistically (Hennart, 1988; Kale & Puranam, 2004). An alternative view is

    that joint ventures are chosen because they facilitate better coordination between partners

    (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Kogut & Zander, 1993; Madhok, 1995; 2006; Phene & Tallman,

    2012). In recent times, however, scholars have converged on the notion that hierarchical

    governance mechanisms simultaneously serve both opportunism-mitigation and coordination

    functions (Kale & Puranam, 2004; Mesquita & Brush, 2008). In fact, TCE scholars in strategy

    and international business have not only highlighted the importance of coordination

    (Williamson, 1985; 1993), but even extended the transaction cost construct to include

    communication and coordination costs as well (Rugman & Verbeke, 2003; Phene & Tallman,

    2012).

    What still distinguishes TCE and other perspectives on the question of what firms do,

    however, is its view on where the coordination benefits of hierarchy come from. To TCE

    proponents, coordination comes from reduced incentives of members of a firm to act

    opportunistically; ex-post maladaptation problems are less likely to arise in firms due to the

    absence of opportunism (Williamson, 1993: 97). The knowledge based view on the other hand

    ascribes coordination benefits to higher-order organizing principles (Kogut & Zander, 1992),

    a shared identity among members of a firm, and common procedural rules (Kogut & Zander,

    1996). Somewhat similarly, Ghoshal & Moran (1996) suggest that coordination arises from a

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    36/51

    35

    sense of shared purpose. Contrasting the TCE view with theirs, they remark: the advantage

    of organizations over markets may not lie in overcoming human pathologies through

    hierarchy, but in leveraging the human ability to...cooperate (p. 42).

    So where do cooperation and coordination in firms really come from? Our view, which

    we think is reflected also in our empirical results, rests on the following three observations.

    Firstly, hierarchy need not automatically or always confer coordination benefits (Sako &

    Helper, 1998:391). Coordination, even within firms, is difficult unless specific mechanisms

    are in place (Bechky, 2003; Hansen, 1999; Mors, 2010). Hierarchy and superior coordination

    are thus not synonymous3

    3 To be fair, Kogut & Zander do allude somewhat briefly to the difficulty in transferring know-

    how between departments (1992: 389) and to the fact that firms differ in what they can do well(1996: 515). But their mainstream emphasis is on the coordination-enabling features of the firmsthrough shared identities and higher order organizing principles.

    . Secondly, there is no reason why coordination, with some effort,

    cannot be effected on the market as well. If this statement is true, then hierarchy may not be

    essential to generating coordination benefits. Foss (1996a) makes this very point: ...the gains

    from...being embedded in higher order organizing principles could be realized over the

    market. In other words, agents could simply meet under the same factory roof, own their

    own pieces of physical capital equipment or rent it to each other, and develop value-

    enhancing organizing principles among themselves, or in other ways integrate their

    specialized knowledge. Firms would not be necessary (Foss & Klein, 2008; italics added).

    This view resonates well with Mesquita & Brush's (2008) empirical results that contracts,

    with some embellishments, can facilitate hierarchy-like coordination between alliance

    partners while at the same time, they do not adequately safeguard from opportunism (p.803).

    Srikanth & Puranam (2011) find similar results showing that fairly intensive coordination can

    be effected even in arms-length (offshoring) contracts. Moreover, investigating the kinds of

    coordination mechanisms within and across firms, Srikanth & Puranam (2010) conclude that

    there is no unique coordination mechanism within firms that cannot be implemented in

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    37/51

    36

    contracts. Extrapolating from these results, one could argue that hierarchy is critical to

    curtailing opportunism but not to ensuring coordination. Thirdly, the argument that

    coordination arises from high-order organizing principles need not be inconsistent with an

    opportunism-based argument. Transaction cost theorists would suggest that ....the absence of

    opportunism that hierarchy may help to create stimulates the emergence of trust, cooperation,

    information exchange, and various sets of commitments, which is precisely what [is] packed

    into the concept of higher order organizing principles (Foss, 1996a: 473). Simply put, higher

    order coordination routines generally seen within firms could very well be because of the

    reduced payoffs from being opportunistic for members of the firm, and in that respect

    consistent with transaction cost theory.

    Taken together, these three observations suggest that the while the need for coordination

    is important in alliance governance, its role in driving the preference for hierarchy over

    market is not unequivocally clear. Coordination-benefits do not seem unique to hierarchy

    since firms can still suffer coordination problems, and effective coordination can occur on the

    market (Foss, 1996a; Srikanth & Puranam, 2011). What hierarchy really does is opportunism

    mitigation. And we think our results reflect this. In conditions were coordination is likely to

    be difficult, such as when routines and culture of partners are dissimilar, we do not find

    managers choosing joint venture over licensing. But on the other hand, the managers we

    surveyed chose joint ventures when opportunism concerns were high. So, what do firms do?

    They may very well facilitate coordination, but we think this is likely only because, as a first

    step, they mitigate opportunism. To be clear, we certainly do believe that coordination is

    crucial to transferring tacit knowledge (Nonaka, 1994), but not that this is what fundamentally

    distinguishes hierarchy and markets.

    There are, however, three important caveats to our story. Firstly, as we have said, our

    tests are very conservative. And despite that we find results supporting TCE. This strengthens

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    38/51

    37

    our confidence in the TCE results, but at the same time suggests that the insignificant findings

    for KBV do not indicate the theory is irrelevant or wrong. Our lack of support for KBV could

    simply be because our tests are too conservative to pick up those effects. Secondly, scholars

    have suggested that opportunism need not always be guileful. For example, Verbeke &

    Greidanus (2009) propose the concept of bounded reliability, taking into account that all

    failed commitments need not always be motivated by deceit. Our empirical analysis

    unfortunately does not distinguish between opportunism that is and isnt deceitful. And in that

    sense, Verbeke & Greidanuss (2009) concept of bounded reliability could very well be an

    alternative explanation to the conclusions we draw from our results. Thirdly, while we control

    for industry characteristics, we do not thoroughly explore whether our results are industry-

    dependent. It is plausible that the relevance of opportunism could vary by industry. For

    example, in biotechnology alliances, knowledge transfer concerns rooted in coordination

    concerns and not opportunism could be more relevant (Phene & Tallman, 2012).

    Nevertheless, and despite these limitations, our study makes a worthwhile contribution to the

    opportunism debate. Conceptually, we derive distinctive predictions that capture the

    mechanisms underpinning KBV and TCE views, and empirically, we bring a set of results to

    bear on the question of whether or not opportunism matters. So, is opportunism really

    redundant in explaining the boundaries of the firm? Based on our research and subject to the

    caveats we have just mentioned, we think not.

    REFERENCES

    Ai, C.R., & Norton, E.C. 2003. Interaction terms in logit and probit models. EconomicsLetters,80(1):123129.

    Anderson, E. 1988. Transaction costs as determinants of opportunism in integrated andindependent sales forces. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9(3): 247-264.

    Armstrong, S.J., & Overton, T.S. 1977. Estimating non-response bias in mail surveys.Journal of Marketing Research, 14: 396-402.

    Arrow, K., 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In Arrow, K.

    (ed.) The rate and direction of economic activity.Princeton: Princeton University Press.Baranson, J. 1969.Industrial technologies for developing economies.NY: Praeger.

  • 8/13/2019 Eapen Krishnan Paper

    39/51

    38

    Barzel, Y. 1989.Economic analysis of property rights.NY: Cambridge University Press.Bechky, B.A. 2003. Sharing meaning across occupational communities: The transformation of

    understanding on a production floor. Organization Science, 14(3): 312- 330.Brief, A., & Downey, H.K. 1983. Cognitive and organizational structures: A conceptual

    analysis of implicit organizing theories.Human Relations. 36 (12): 1065-1090.

    Buckley, P., J & Casson, M., 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise, London:Macmillan.

    Busenitz, L.W., & Lau, C.M. 1996. A cross-cultural cognitive model of new venture creation.Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice. Summer: 25-39.

    Carroll, R.J., & Stefanski, L.A. 1990. Approximate quasilikelihood estimation in models withsurrogate predictors.Journal of the American Statistical Association, 85: 652-663.

    Carroll, R.J., Ruppert, D., Stefanski, L.A., & Crainiceanu, C.M. 2006. Measurement error innonlinear models: A modern perspective.London: Chapman & Hall.

    Carson, S.J.


Recommended