+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

Date post: 05-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: ban-dee-mee
View: 226 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 33

Transcript
  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    1/33

    Early settlement rebatesfurther analysis

    Summary

    1.

    2.

    3.

    4.

    This working paper sets out some further analysis of the implications for home credit

    of early settlement rebates and their regulation. It builds on the analysis contained in

    two earlier working papers published alongside Emerging Thinking.1

    We look first at the rebates paid for early settlement of home credit loans and

    whether the statutory minimum rebate, as required by the Consumer Credit (Early

    Settlement) Regulations 2004 (the 2004 Regulations), represents a fair value for

    home credit customers and lenders.

    We have seen no evidence that home credit lenders have failed to comply with the

    2004 Regulations.2 We note further that the 2004 Regulations were designed to

    apply to a wide range of consumer credit agreements and not just to home credit

    loans. The purpose of our analysis is not to assess whether home credit lenders are

    failing to comply with the 2004 Regulations, nor whether the 2004 Regulations are

    appropriate, in general, across the consumer credit sector. Rather our objective has

    been to evaluate the widespread practice by home credit lenders of offering rebates

    which comply with the minimum required by law, but are no more generous to

    customers than this.

    Our analysis suggests that there is little justification in either principle or in practice

    for home credit lenders to retain up to four or eight weeks charges as a result of the

    2004 Regulations permitting a deferred, rather than the actual date of settlement, to

    be used in the rebate calculation. We can see no justification for home credit lenders

    1Renewal Loansand The Consumer Credit (Early Settlement) Regulations 2004.

    2

    One home credit lender submitted an opinion from Counsel expressing the view that its current approach to rebates compliedwith the 2004 Regulations.

    1

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    2/33

    to retain a larger amount for loans of longer than one year, than for loans of less than

    one year. These findings are robust to a range of assumptions about the cost

    structure of home credit. By contrast, the unadjusted actuarial formula3 appears to

    fall within our illustrative range of possible underlying costs for the purposes of

    calculating a cost-based rebate.

    5.

    6.

    7.

    We then consider the degree to which this issue is relevant to a competition inquiry.

    In principle, low rebates could adversely affect competition by increasing switching

    costs and adding to incumbency advantages. However, it not clear that these effects

    are currently having a strong adverse effect on competition. Other incumbency

    advantages appear more substantial.

    Finally, we explore whether rebates might be higher if other advantages enjoyed by

    incumbent lenders were reduced or if price competition intensified. We conclude that

    they might, although we consider that price competition is more likely to focus on

    headline prices than on rebates. We also noted that, in these circumstances, better

    rebates might be paid when customers renew a loan with an existing supplier

    compared with when they settle a loan early in order to switch to a competitor.

    Section 1: Introduction

    A high proportion of home credit loans settle ahead of term. 4 Most customers who

    settle early will pay a higher ex post interest rate than the headline APR on the loan.

    In the working paper on renewal loans, we estimated that renewals account for over

    one-third of new loans issued. While some renewal loans take place on or after the

    3As set out in the 2004 Regulations, but treating the actual settlement date as the settlement date for the purposes of the

    calculation rather than some deferred date.4For example, Provident estimated that [] per cent of its home credit loans were settled early. Early settlement is also

    common in other consumer credit markets: for example research conducted by Mori for the DTI in 2003 found that 48 per cent

    of HP customers and 41 per cent of personal loan customers had paid off a previous agreement early. Source: Consumerawareness of credit issues: research study conducted for DTI, September 2003.

    2

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    3/33

    contractual term, the majority of renewals appear to take place before this date 5 and

    other loans are settled early without renewal. The total balances outstanding on

    early settlements are substantialwe estimate that between 150 million and

    200 million in outstanding balances are refinanced through renewal loans each

    year.

    8.

    9.

    Competition between home credit suppliers over the terms of rebates appears

    muted. Customers understanding and awareness of the detailed terms on which

    early settlement takes place are likely to be low, particularly when taking out an initial

    loan.6 There appears to be little incentive for suppliers to offer a better deal at early

    settlement than the rebates required by law and relatively few do. Only two of the

    large suppliers offer rebates that are more generous than the statutory minimum for

    customers who are renewing loans.7 To our knowledge, no large supplier offers

    more generous rebates than the statutory minimum to customers who settle a loan

    early for any reason other than renewals. Rebates offered by most suppliers are a

    small percentage of the balances outstanding at early settlement.8

    In the absence of vigorous competition over the terms of early settlement, the price

    paid by many customers for early settlement of home credit loans is set according to

    by the minimum rebates determined by statute. If this statutory minimum

    underestimates the fair value of a rebate, this will to result in harm to those

    consumers that settle early. If the statutory minimum rebate overestimates the fair

    value of a rebate, this will result in a cross-subsidy in favour those customers who

    5Renewal Loansworking paper, paragraph 56.

    6We note that under the Consumer Credit (Agreements) (Amendment) Regulations 2004, suppliers are now required to provide

    three examples of what an early settlement figure would look like at one-quarter, one-half and three-quarters of the way througha loan. This provides some additional information to customers at the outset of a loan about the likely size of an earlysettlement rebate, for loans redeemed at those stages.7Mutual offers a refinancing discount for customers who renew a loan with them. They told us that this did not bring them

    business benefits but was part of their organizational culture. [] uses the actuarial formula set out in the regulations but doesnot defer the settlement date by four weeks. Some smaller suppliers also offer better terms than the statutory minimum. We

    were told by one small supplier that they had on one occasion gained some extra custom by paying a larger rebate than others.8Renewal loansworking paper, paragraph 62.

    3

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    4/33

    settle early, as lenders seek to recover the cost from other customers or in other

    ways.

    10.

    11.

    12.

    13.

    The rest of this paper examines the implications of early settlement rebates and their

    regulation on home credit. Section 2 assesses the extent to which early settlement

    rebates represent a fair balance between home credit lenders and customers. In

    Section 3, we explore the extent to which any shortfall between rebates paid on early

    settlement of home credit loans and fair values of rebates can be considered to be

    either a cause or a consequence of a lack of competition.

    Section 2: Are rebates fair?

    In this section, we consider whether rebates paid by home credit suppliers represent

    a fair balance between borrowers and lenders. We start by discussing conceptual

    issues about what constitutes a fair rebate. We then discuss the statutory framework

    which specifies minimum rebates payable for early settlement of consumer credit

    agreements, including home credit. This is followed by a comparison of this

    minimum statutory rebate with estimates of the costs associated with early

    settlement, derived from cost models. We then consider how missed repayments

    should be considered in the context of rebates before drawing some conclusions.

    What is a fair rebate?

    Article 8 of the European Directive on Consumer Credit (87/102/EEC) requires that

    consumers should have an equitable reduction in the total cost of credit at early

    settlement.

    The concept of fairness implicit in this requirement may be summarized in the

    proposition that, at early settlement, customers should not have to pay costs that

    4

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    5/33

    have not actually been incurred by the lender.9 It is acknowledged that it would be

    impracticable to attempt to allocate costs with total precision in every possible case.

    Regulation of early settlement rebates aims to provide a reasonable approximation

    of the economic reality of the way costs are attributed throughout the loan contract.10

    14. The calculation of a fair rebate is based on an approximate allocation of costs

    through the life of a loan. If all costs associated with a loan are incurred in full at the

    start of a loan then it would generally be a fair allocation for the customer not to

    receive a rebate at all. Some costs will typically be avoided by the lender at early

    settlement. Costs can be regarded as broadly falling within the following three

    categories depending on their profile of expenditure during the term of the loan. We

    shall for convenience call these fixed costs, variable costs and interest costs as

    follows:

    Fixed costs. These are costs incurred in full at the start of the loan. An example

    would be the administrative costs in setting up the loan. A fair allocation would

    result in these costs being borne by the customer.

    Variable costs. These are costs incurred at a constant rate throughout the life of

    the loan. For example, in home credit, there are weekly costs associated with

    weekly collections. A fair allocation would be to share the costs pro-rata

    according to time left for the loan to run.

    Interest costs. These are costs that depend on the amount of the loan

    outstanding and decline at a rate derived by using an actuarial formula. An

    example could be the interest the lender pays to its provider of capital that is

    attributable to the loan to the customer. This would decline as a proportion of

    periodic repayments throughout the life of a loan. Other costs could have a

    9Thus, the DTI stated that [the right to early settlement] exists because otherwise consumers who settled early could pay

    interest and other charges under an agreement that have not actually been earned by lenders. Source: Tackling loan sharks

    and more!, DTI Consultation document CCP 002/02, paragraph 2.1.10Source: DTI Tackling loan sharksand more!, paragraph 2.29.

    5

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    6/33

    similar profile. A fair allocation of such costs can be derived by using the

    actuarial formula.11

    15.

    16.

    17.

    One issue that is open to debate is how much of its expected profit margin (ie the

    amount by which the revenue from a loan is expected to exceed costs) the lender

    should retain on a loan that settles early. One approach would be to treat the profit

    margin as a funding cost and allocate it in proportion to the costs of financing the

    loan. However, other methods of allocating this margin may be equally or more

    appropriate. For example, the profit margin could be allocated between periods in

    proportion to the total costs incurred in each period or could be treated in the same

    way as a variable cost, and rebated pro-rata to the customer.

    The 2004 Regulations

    The 2004 Regulations set a statutory minimum level of rebates. This statutory

    minimum rebate is determined by an actuarial formula, whereby the customer is

    entitled to receive as a rebate the interest remaining on the loan at the settlement

    date. The settlement date may be deferred by up to four weeks to allow both parties

    to organise for processing of the final payment12. For loans of more than one year,

    lenders can retain an extra months interest to help lenders cover any early

    settlement costs.13

    In developing the 2004 Regulations, which are generally more beneficial to the

    customer than the previous arrangements, DTI needed to take a sector-wide view.

    The 2004 Regulations were therefore designed to apply to a wide range of consumer

    credit agreements, including (with some exceptions) mortgages and personal loans

    11It is worth noting that the capital employed by a lender over the life of a loan is a combination of the original loan principle and

    the cash flows over the term of a loan (primarily the costs incurred and collections received). Where costs other than interestare significant, funding costs will not follow exactly the same profile as the actuarial formula.12

    Source: DTI Guidance notes on the 2004 Regulations(2004).13

    Source: DTI Guidance notes on the 2004 Regulations (2004). The lender may elect to make this 30 days instead of onemonth.

    6

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    7/33

    up to 25,000. The approach taken in the 2004 Regulations is consistent with the

    following three assumptions, which may provide a reasonable approximation of the

    cost structure of providing other forms of credit.

    18.

    Most of the costs of providing consumer credit are interest costs or can be

    approximated by applying the actuarial formula using the headline APR on the

    loan. There are few variable costs.

    It takes about one month to arrange for early settlement. Alternatively,

    customers can and do wait until the settlement date before obtaining their further

    advance.

    The costs associated with early settlement are equivalent to around one months

    interest for longer loans.14

    None of these assumptions appears appropriate to home credit:

    A high proportion of costs are incurred after issue. In particular variable weekly

    collection costs are highcommission payments to agents are generally

    between 8 and 10 per cent of the Total Amount Payableand some

    administrative costs are also variable.

    When loans are renewed, early settlement normally happens within a few days

    of the request being made, rather than the four weeks envisaged by the 2004

    Regulations.15

    The administrative costs of early settlement are small. The main additional cost

    is the calculation and payment of the rebate. In meetings with the DTI in 2003,

    the CCA estimated that, for the smaller and medium-sized trader, the

    administrative costs of early settlement would, on average be around 1.82 per

    14There are two aspects to this. First, there may be some costs which are only incurred if the loan is settled early. Second, with

    high fixed and low variable costs, an actuarial formula may understate the costs that have been incurred at settlement.15

    This point was noted by the OFT in its response to the DTI consultation on the Consumer Credit Act (paragraph 2.9). TheOFT suggested that the deferment period for weekly collected credit should be reduced to 13 days.

    7

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    8/33

    settlement.16,17 For large suppliers, administrative costs are considerably lower.

    For example Provident has estimated its administrative costs of early settlement

    to be around []p for each loan settled early.18 Set-up costs are also relatively

    low: Provident estimated average set-up costs to be around [] a loan.19

    19.

    The high headline APR of home credit loanscompared with the headline APRs

    on other credit productswhich arises in part from the cost structure of home

    credit, means that an actuarial formula calculated using headline APRs gives

    rise to low rebates during the later stages of a loan and that four weeks interest

    calculated using this formula is a large sum compared with the balance

    outstanding on the loan.20 All of these differences between the cost structure of

    home credit loans and the cost structure consistent with the 2004 Regulations

    will tend to provide low rebates for early settlement of home credit loans,

    compared with underlying costs.

    Provident analysis of early settlement rebates

    Provident have submitted that the minimum statutory rebates nonetheless offer a

    reasonable approximation to the costs avoided by the lender at early settlement and

    that rebates are more or less fair in practice. In support of this view, Provident

    submitted an analysis of early settlement rebates, which was prepared by LEK.

    16The CCA told us that different practices existed within the sector in terms of the way these settlements were physically

    handled. However, one normal system was to send the rebate by post. This helped the smaller and medium-sized trader(SME

    trader) ensure that the payment got to the customer and so performed an audit function, enabling them to prove they hadcomplied with the legal requirement to pay the rebate. The 1.82 figure supplied to the DTI comprised matters such as thetraders time, typing and printing, cost of the cheque, cost of the envelope and cost of the stamp. The CCA told us that this wasa conservative estimate and it was clear to the CCA that some traders would spend more. The difference between lenderswould turn on factors such as the degree of computerization.17

    The CCA said it estimated that SME traders served about 500,000 customers. Making the assumption that each of these tookout two or more agreements over the course of a year, the CCA said that it believed the 2004 Regulations would require,perhaps, an extra 200,000 or so early settlements to be processed each year. The CCA therefore estimated that the aggregateextra administrative cost for the SME traders would therefore be something in the region of 400,000 a year. This estimate didnot cover the position of the larger companies, nor did it include the increased costs to SME traders flowing from the removal ofthe deferment period.18

    Source: LEK model. Provident told us that its settlement costs were low because of the efficiency of its back office functions,resulting from significant investment in IT systems. This investment is treated by Provident as an overhead and is not reflectedin the []p figure.19

    Source: LEK model.20

    See paragraph 19 of the working paper on The Consumer Credit (Early Settlement) Regulations 2004for an example of the

    impact of a four-week deferment. See paragraph 62 of the working paper on Renewal Loansfor details of the size of rebatespaid compared with balances outstanding on renewal loans.

    8

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    9/33

    20.

    21.

    The approach taken in this analysis is to compare the revenue that a home credit

    lender would receive if a loan settled in any given weektaking the current level of

    rebates as givenwith typical level of costs incurred on the loan up to that point,

    including an allowance for a profit margin. This methodology bears some similarity to

    the avoidable cost approach outlined in paragraphs 13 to 15, though it starts from

    the perspective of the lender rather than the borrower.

    The starting point for the LEK analysis is a breakdown of PPCs costs and

    revenues,21 consistent with the companys management accounts. This is shown in

    Table 1. The two largest cost items for PPC are agent commissions and bad debt.

    Issue-related costs account for [] per cent of costs ([] per cent of total revenue)

    and the administrative costs of early settlement account for [] per cent of costs

    (less for total revenue). The overall profit margin for PPC (before interest and tax) is

    [] per cent.

    TABLE 1 Breakdown of PPC costs and revenue

    Item million % of costs% of

    revenue

    Total agent commissionsBad debt charge

    Other costsIssue relatedWeekly (excl commissions)Bad debt and arrears related(excl bad debt charge)

    Early settlement related (exclcommissions)Total costs

    PBITTotal Revenue

    Source: Provident.

    22. A cost profile for Providents 55 week and 31 week products was then developed,

    using the average loan size for each product, to allocate costs and profit margin

    according to the week on which loans are settled. It is worth noting here, that the

    LEK analysis of Providents bad debt costs suggests that its time profile

    21Provident submitted that the analysis would be similar if GPC were chosen instead.

    9

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    10/33

    approximates better to the profile of interest rather than to a flat weekly cost or to a

    one-off fixed cost.

    23.

    24.

    25.

    This cost allocation may then be combined with data on repayments to calculate an

    average weekly margin, calculated as a rate of return on investment during the life of

    the loan.22 The lender is considered to be indifferent to the timing of settlement if this

    weekly margin is unaffected by the date on which the loan is settled. Figure 1 shows

    the average weekly margin generated by the LEK model for Providents 55-week

    loan product.

    FIGURE 1

    Weekly return on investment for a 55-week loan

    []

    Source: CC estimates, using LEK model.

    If the loan settles on the contractual date, then Provident makes an average weekly

    return on investment of around [] per cent (considerably higher than home credit

    lenders funding costs of around 0.2 per cent a week). Loans that settle before week

    [] earn a higher weekly margin than this. Loans that settle after term earn a lower

    weekly margin, although they still appear to be profitable as long as they are

    eventually settled. LEK then reallocated PPCs total profit margin across all loans

    that settle to calculate a constant weekly return on investment (also [] per cent)

    irrespective of the week in which settlement took place.

    The results of LEKs analysis for a [] loan with Providents 55-week product are

    shown below in Figure 2.23 The top line shows the revenue that Provident would

    22Investment in this instance comprises capital outstanding and direct costs incurred over the duration of the loan, plus fixed

    and bad debt costs allocated to the loan less actual collections received.23All assumptions about this product are the same as in the earlier example.

    10

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    11/33

    earn if a loan was settled in any given week. This is equal to the total charge for

    credit on the loan ([]) less the minimum statutory rebate for early settlement

    calculated according to the 2004 Regulations. The shaded areas show the

    allocations of costs and profit margins between loans settled in different weeks.

    FIGURE 2

    LEK/Provident comparison of revenue against costs

    []

    Source: Provident.

    26.

    27.

    28.

    If we accept the underlying analysis, Figure 2 shows that loans that settle at week

    [] or earlier are between [] and [] more profitable for Provident than loans

    which run to term. Loans that settle in weeks [] to [] are between [] and

    [] more profitable than those which run to term. Loans that settle in weeks [] to

    [] are between [] and [] less profitable than those which run to term (despite

    the fact that no rebate is paid on early settlement).

    However, there are two core assumptions in the LEK model which have a substantial

    effect on the results.

    First, the LEK model allocates its profit margin between weeks on which settlement

    takes place to generate a margin calculated on a constant average weekly rate of

    return. Given the considerable difference between the average weekly return on

    investment and the costs of funding, it is not clear that the entire profit margin should

    be, in effect, treated as a funding cost (see paragraph 15). The size of the profit

    margin as a proportion of Providents revenue means that the results of this model

    are highly sensitive to assumptions made about how this margin is allocated. In

    addition, there is an element of circularity in using this approach to assess whether or

    11

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    12/33

    not a system of rebates is fair, in that the total margin allocated in this way is, itself a

    function of the rebates regime in question. Using this approach can tend to generate

    cost-based rebates that are similar to those allowed under the current regime,

    whatever that regime may be.

    Second, the LEK model treats commission paid by Provident at early settlement24 as

    a cost of early settlement, and hence a cost that should be recovered by the supplier

    rather than rebated to the customer at early settlement. This is open to question

    because the activity that gives rise to the cost (i.e. the collection) has not in practice

    taken place.25 Companies may choose to reimburse their agents for activities that

    they have not carried out, but this is not a cost that needs to be recovered from

    customers.

    29.

    30.

    31.

    32.

    Both of these assumptions tend to increase the estimates of the costs incurred for

    loans that settle early. If alternative assumptions were made, different conclusions

    may be reached about whether the statutory minimum rebate is at a fair value.

    In summary, the allocation of costs in the LEK model appears to be reasonable and

    this cost analysis is helpful in identifying costs that have been avoided through early

    settlement. However, the treatment of profit margin as a cost and the way in which

    margin is reallocated according to the week of settlement mean that the LEK model

    is only of limited usefulness in assessing whether the level of rebates are fair.

    CC analysis of cost-based rebates under different scenarios

    We estimated the amount of a cost-based rebate using a range of assumptions about

    cost structures. The product used for these calculations was Providents 55-week

    24Equal to around [] per cent of the amount collected at settlement. Companies differ in their policies for paying commission

    on early settlement.25

    We were told that agents face an element of hassle when administering an early settlement and that if agents were not paidcommission on early settlement, other aspects of the commission package would have to rise.

    12

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    13/33

    product, which has a TCC of 65 per 100 advanced. This is the most widely held

    home credit loan product in the UK. We considered early settlement rebates payable

    on a 400 loan26 at various stages of the loans life.

    33.

    34.

    35.

    36.

    At early settlement, a cost-based rebate would allow the lender to recover the capital

    sum advanced and all variable and interest costs that have been incurred up to that

    point. It would also allow the lender to retain the profits earned up to that point. The

    customer would receive as a rebate, those variable and interest costs that had not

    been incurred, and the profit that had not been earned, when settlement takes place.

    The administrative costs of early settlement (in the case of Provident, around []p)

    may be subtracted from this rebate.

    In calculating a cost-based rebate, we assumed that all costs could be categorized

    as fixed costs, variable costs or interest costs.27 We assume to start with that no

    repayments are missed during the life of the loan. Missed repayments will be

    discussed in paragraphs 42 to 45.

    Table 2 summarizes a range of assumptions about the split between fixed, variable

    and interest costs for this loan. A central scenario assumes fixed costs of 30 (just

    over one-tenth of the TCC) and variable costs are 66 (one-tenth of the total amount

    payable and around a quarter of the TCC). These are broadly consistent with the

    LEK analysis of Providents fixed and variable costs in Table 1.

    This central scenario estimates variable costs to be of the same order of magnitude

    as commission payments, and hence treats the entire profit margin as an interest

    26We understand this to be typical of the amounts borrowed on a loan of around one years duration. Providents average loan

    size for a 55-week product is [].27

    In categorizing costs as interest, we are making an assumption about the profile with which costs are incurred during a loan

    (ie that it can be approximated by the declining profile given by an actuarial formula). Not all interest costs in this sense will befunding costs.

    13

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    14/33

    cost. As discussed in paragraph 15, this assumption is open to question and the

    central scenario therefore errs on the side of allocating costs to interest, rather than

    to variable costs. A cost-based rebate calculated in this way will be lower than one

    which could be calculated if, for example, the profit margin were treated like a

    variable cost or were allocated in proportion to all costs.

    37. Nine scenarios are generated by allocating the TCC according to different

    combinations of fixed, variable and interest costs. These scenarios may be

    considered as reflecting differences between the cost structure of different providers

    and loans28 and as illustrating a range of assumptions about the allocation of the

    profit margin over the life of the loan. It is assumed that all costs apart from fixed and

    variable costs decline over the course of the loan and are treated as interest. The

    actuarial formula used in the 2004 regulations may be considered to be a special

    case of this more general model, in which all of the TCC is assumed to be interest.

    The last column calculates an implicit interest rate that is used to allocate the

    interest component of the loan over its life. This is less than the headline APR on

    the loan, as only a proportion of the price of the loan is assumed to constitute

    interest.

    28

    For example, the low variable cost scenarios may be thought of as reflecting the view that the customer should only berebated half of the commission payments that would have been paid, if the loan had run to term.

    14

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    15/33

    TABLE 2 Range of cost assumptions for a 400 loan with a TCC of 260

    Scenario

    Repayment ofcapital

    Fixedcosts

    Variable costs

    Interest costs

    HeadlineAPR

    %

    Rate used forallocating interest

    costs%

    Low fixed, lowvariable 400 15 33 212 177.0 134.5

    Low fixed, med

    variable 400 15 66 179 177.0 108.2Low fixed, highvariable 400 15 132 113 177.0 62.0

    Med fixed, lowvariable 400 30 33 197 177.0 122.2

    Med fixed, medvariable 400 30 66 164 177.0 96.9

    Med fixed, highVariable 400 30 132 98 177.0 52.6

    High fixed, lowvariable 400 60 33 167 177.0 99.1

    High fixed, medvariable 400 60 66 134 177.0 75.8

    High fixed, highvariable 400 60 132 68 177.0 34.9

    Actuarial

    formula 400 0 0 260 177.0 177.0

    Source: CC analysis.

    38. We then calculated a cost-based rebate for each scenario. This is equal to the sum

    of variable and interest costs that had not been incurred at early settlement. Table 3

    summarizes the difference between the statutory minimum rebates payable (in which

    the settlement date on a 55-week loan for the purposes of calculating the rebate is up

    to eight weeks after settlement takes placesee paragraph 16), the rebate

    suggested by the actuarial formula on the actual date of settlement and rebates

    based on costs avoided by the supplier at early settlement. Evidence from suppliers

    and customer surveys suggested that around half of renewals take place with eight

    weeks or less remaining.29

    29Renewal Loans working paper paragraphs 53 to 60.

    15

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    16/33

    TABLE 3 Difference between statutory minimum and cost-based rebates under range of scenarios

    Cost assumptionsWeek of settlement

    All interestActuarialformula

    High fixed, lowvariable

    Smallest difference

    Medium fixed, Mediumvariable

    Central scenario

    Low fixed, highvariable

    Largest difference

    0 61 1 31 465 57 7 35 51

    10 53 12 37 55

    15 49 17 39 5720 44 20 40 5825 39 22 39 5730 33 23 37 5435 26 21 33 4840 19 18 27 4045 11 12 18 2850 3 5 8 13

    Source: CC analysis.

    39. In each of the scenarios, the statutory minimum rebate (ie using the actuarial formula

    with an eight-week delay to the settlement date) is lower than a cost-based estimate

    throughout the entire life of the loan. This difference is greatest for loans which settle

    at around the midpoint of the loan and in the high variable cost scenarios. Apart from

    the last one to two weeks of a loan, the shortfall between the statutory minimum

    rebate and any of the cost-based estimates is of a different order of magnitude from

    the administrative costs of early settlement. Other than for loans settled very early

    on or near to term, rebates calculated according to the actuarial formula (but without

    the eight-week delay to the settlement) fall within our illustrative range of cost-based

    scenarios. This is shown in Figure 3.

    16

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    17/33

    FIGURE 3

    Comparison of statutory minimum rebates with cost-based scenarios

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54

    Week of settlement

    Amountofrebate

    Low f ixed, high var iable High f ixed, low var iable Actuar ia l formula Statutory minimum

    Source: CC analysis.

    40.

    41.

    This analysis suggests that while the actuarial formula falls within our range of

    possible approximations of underlying costs, the statutory minimum rebate is

    consistently below any plausible cost-based estimate.

    In Annex A, we developed an analysis intended to reflect more closely the situation

    of a typical smaller provider. The higher administrative costs associated with early

    settlement in this example imply that cost-based estimates of early settlement

    rebates for loans that settle in the last three weeks are close to zero. For loans that

    settle between weeks 4 and 25, the statutory rebate is lower than a cost-based

    rebate on all scenarios. For loans that settle with eight weeks remaining, the

    difference is in the range 4 to 11, compared with a statutory minimum rebate of

    2.37.

    17

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    18/33

    Treatment of missed repayments

    42.

    43.

    44.

    The analysis so far has assumed that customers make all their repayments on time.

    If a customer has missed some repayments before the settlement date, then the

    supplier is entitled to calculate any rebate payable either by reference to the amounts

    and times that repayments are required under the contract (contractual repayments)

    or by reference to actual repayments made.

    If actual repayments are used, then the impact of charging the customer compound

    interest on missed repayments at the headline APRs on the loan, mean that

    customers can face substantial reductions in rebates for missing a small number of

    repayments, particularly if these are missed early on during the loan.30 This does not

    bear any resemblance to the underlying economic reality for home credit. The

    reductions in rebate implied by the formula are considerably greater than the extra

    funding costs associated with a missed payment. This is because the headline APR

    on home credit loans is several times higher than suppliers cost of funds.

    Moreover missed repayments are a common and accepted feature of home credit.

    We have been told that a customer who makes two repayments out of three is

    generally considered to be a good payer. Provident estimated that at least one

    repayment is missed in over 95 per cent of its loans.31 The expectation of a certain

    number of missed repayments is factored into the price and there is an implicit

    understanding between lenders, agents and customers that occasional missed

    payments will not be penalized.32

    30Examples of the dramatic impact of missed repayments where rebates are calculated by reference to actual payments are

    provided in paragraphs 41 to 47 of the working paper on The Consumer Credit (Early Settlement) Regulations 2004.31

    Source: Provident response to market questionnaire Q46.32In part, because repayments may be missed for reasons related to the agent rather than the customer.

    18

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    19/33

    45.

    46.

    47.

    Using contractual repayments as a basis for calculating rebates is more appropriate

    to home credit. The analysis conducted above may therefore be considered as

    estimating a cost-based rebate for early settlement at a given stage in the contractual

    term. Most home credit suppliers are using contractual repayments as a basis for

    calculating early settlement rebates.

    Conclusion on the level of early settlement rebates

    Our analysis suggests that there is little justification in either principle or in practice

    for home credit lenders to retain four or eight weeks charges over and above that

    provided for in the actuarial formula in the 2004 Regulations. We can see no

    justification for home credit lenders to retain a larger amount for loans of longer than

    one year, than for loans of less than one year. These findings are robust to a wide

    range of assumptions about the cost structure of home credit. The model developed

    by LEK for Provident does generate a cost profile which is a closer approximation of

    the rebate formula. However, this result appears to be driven by the size of

    Providents profit margin in relation both to its revenue and its funding costs and the

    assumptions made about the way in which that margin is allocated over the course of

    a loan.

    By contrast, the unadjusted actuarial formula appears to fall within our illustrative

    range of possible underlying costs for the purposes of calculating a cost-based

    rebate. However, if refinancing was subject to effective competitive pressure, we

    might expect terms of early settlement to be more generous to customers than this

    amount. The set-up and bad debt risk costs associated with renewal loans are lower

    than for other home credit loans.33 In addition, the actuarial formula produces

    rebates that are towards the bottom end of our illustrative range during the latter

    stages of a loan when most early settlements take place.

    33See Renewal loansworking paper, paragraphs 20 and 21.

    19

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    20/33

    Section 3: The competitive impact of early settlement rebates

    48.

    49.

    50.

    51.

    We noted in paragraph 9 that competition between home credit suppliers over the

    terms of rebates is muted and that the price paid by many customers for early

    settlement of home credit loans is determined by the minimum rebates set out in

    legislation. The analysis in paragraphs 11 to 47 suggests that this statutory minimum

    may be less than a fair value. This indicates a degree of harm to home credit

    customers who settle loans early, whether renewing an existing loan or for any other

    reason. In this section, we consider whether any such harm to customers may be

    considered to be either a cause or a consequence of a lack of competition. The rest

    of this section is structured around the following two questions.

    Do low rebates prevent, restrict or distort competition?

    Would rebates be higher if competition were more intense?

    Do low rebates prevent, restrict or distort competition?

    A rebate is a payment from an incumbent lender to a customer at early settlement. If

    rebates were too low, early settlement would be highly profitable for incumbent

    lenders and expensive for customers. Conversely, as rebates increase, early

    settlement becomes less profitable for incumbent lenders and cheaper for customers.

    Rebates could distort competition if the amount of the rebate significantly alters the

    incentives of customers and/or lenders in ways that protected incumbent lenders

    from competition or otherwise reduced rivalry between firms. We consider the impact

    of rebates on customers and lenders incentives below.

    Impact on customer incentives

    The fundamental impact of low rebates on customers incentives is to reduce the

    attractiveness to customers of settling loans ahead of term.

    20

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    21/33

    52.

    53.

    54.

    One implication is that low rebates can weaken customer incentives to transfer the

    balance of an existing loan to another supplier mid-term. This is a common form of

    switching in other credit markets (eg mortgages and credit cards).34 However, if

    rebates are low, then the cost of early settlement could outweigh any benefits of

    switching in this way, even where a new supplier is offering substantially lower prices

    (see example at Annex B).

    The effect is to reduce the likelihood of customers switching suppliers in this way

    and to reduce the ability of other suppliers to attract customers to switch through

    lower prices. However, the example at Annex B also suggests that, even with higher

    rebates, large price differentials are required for it to be beneficial to customers to

    transfer the balance on short-term loans from one provider to another. In addition, it

    can be argued that customers have other ways of switching in home creditfor

    example at the end of a loan or by multi-sourcing and switching at the margin.35 As

    such, the competitive significance of this form of switching may be less for short-term

    home credit loans than for longer-term credit products, such as mortgages, in which

    transferring the balance of an account is likely to be a very important method of

    switching suppliers.

    Provided the same rebate is offered to all customers who settle early, the amount of

    the rebate should not affect customers perception of the relative attractiveness of

    refinancing a loan with different suppliers. Although it is rare for refinancing to take

    place with companies other than the incumbent supplier,36 it seems unlikely that this

    is because customers choices have been distorted by low rebates. Other, more

    34For example, in its report Switched on to switching, NCC found that 31 per cent of customers surveyed in 2005 had switched

    mortgage providers. Credit card providers frequently offer reduced interest rates to customers who transfer their balance fromanother provider.35

    See paragraph 42 of the CC working paper on Customer Turnover, Multi-sourcing and Switching published alongside

    Emerging Thinking.36See paragraphs 44 to 46 of the CC working paper on Customer Turnover, Multi-sourcing and Switching.

    21

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    22/33

    plausible, explanations for this pattern are incumbency advantages and differences in

    suppliers incentives to offer refinancing (see paragraphs 56 to 59).

    55.

    56.

    57.

    58.

    Customers choice between suppliers could be affected, if suppliers offered more

    favourable rebates to customers who are renewing a loan than to customers who

    settle early for any other reason. Mutual offers a refinancing discount for customers

    who renew a loan, but most suppliers offer the same rebates on all early settlement.

    We do not consider the practice of offering differential rebates for renewals to be

    intrinsically anti-competitiveindeed we might expect it to be a natural response of

    suppliers in a competitive environment (see paragraph 64). However, the impact of

    differential rebates on competition might be different if it were more widespread.

    Impact on supplier incentives

    The fundamental impact of low rebates on suppliers incentives is to increase the

    benefits to incumbents of customers settling early. Rebates do not have a direct

    effect on any other suppliers incentives, though they may have an indirect effect by

    affecting their likelihood of winning business.

    The amount of the rebate therefore affects incumbent lenders incentives to refinance

    loans with existing customers. In particular, if rebates are too low, incumbent lenders

    will have an additional incentive to refinance a loan arising from the windfall on early

    settlement of the first loan. This incentive is not shared by any other lender, as it is

    only the incumbent lender who benefits from early settlement.

    This has two potential implications for competition. First, it is a factor increasing the

    relative profitability of serving existing customers compared with new customers.

    This could reduce rivalry between suppliers. Second, the difference in incentives to

    offer refinancing between incumbents and other lenders may increases the likelihood

    22

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    23/33

    that incumbents win refinancing business with customersfor example, because

    they are able to pass on part of these incentives to their agents (or, in principle, to

    customers).

    59.

    60.

    It appears likely that these two effects are currently dominated by other factors.

    Better information about the credit risks of existing customers and, consequently,

    lower default risks and the ability to offer larger loans are likely to be more significant

    factors affecting the profitability of existing customers compared to new ones. Other

    incumbency advantages are likely to be more significant factors in determining that

    most refinancing takes place with incumbent lenders.

    What might happen in a more competitive environment?

    In paragraphs 51 to 59, we considered the impact of rebates on competition between

    home credit lenders under current competitive conditions. However, it is possible

    that competition between home credit lenders may not be working as well as it might.

    For example, in our Emerging Thinking, we found little price competition between

    providers compared with what might be expected in a competitive market 37 as well

    as incumbency advantages deriving, in part, from a lack of transparent, readily-

    available data about the creditworthiness of customers.38 In the rest of this section,

    we explore what might be the impact on rebates of more vigorous price competition

    and/or a lessening of incumbent advantages. It should be noted that the CCs

    assessment of price competition and incumbency advantages is ongoing. No

    inference should be drawn about the CCs view of these issues from the following

    analysis, the purpose of which is to help understand the role of rebates in the

    competitive process, by considering alternative scenarios.

    37

    Emerging Thinking paragraphs 71 to 74.38Emerging Thinking paragraph 54 and paragraphs 85 to 81.

    23

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    24/33

    More vigorous price competition

    61.

    62.

    63.

    If there were more vigorous price competition between home credit suppliers, this

    might be expected to have an impact on rebates, if customers and suppliers consider

    rebates to form part of the price of home credit. We consider that it would be rational

    for them to do so. Low rebates increase the effective APR paid by customers and,

    for those customers who regularly settle early and refinance their loans, the rebate is

    an important determinant of the actual amount the customer pays for credit. More

    broadly, in a market subject to intense price competition, levels of rebate might be

    one among many competitive variables used by lenders, even if not the most

    obvious. More vigorous price competition could affect the level of rebates in two

    ways.

    First, customers initial choice of a lender might be affected by the rebates on offer.

    Firms could compete for new business on the basis of offering favourable terms at

    early settlement alongside other aspects of their product (eg the headline APR and

    the length of loan). This would affect rebates paid on all early settlements. However,

    it could be argued that this mechanism would be weak, even in a more competitive

    market. It may not be realistic to expect new customers to focus on this aspect of

    price.

    Second, lenders may seek to offer better rebates to retain existing customers.

    Offering good value on rebates could become a way in which suppliers demonstrate

    good customer service and provide incentives for loyalty. The significance of rebates

    as part of the overall cost of borrowing is likely to be clearer to an existing customer

    than to a new customer. Existing customers are also likely to have a greater

    understanding than new customers of their likelihood of settling future loans early.

    24

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    25/33

    64.

    65.

    66.

    67.

    The extent to which competitive forces would affect the level of rebates may differ

    according to the reason for early settlements. Where a customer is renewing a

    loanor if a customer is settling a loan early but might wish to use the supplier again

    in the future39then lenders in a more competitive environment could have

    incentives to maintain goodwill by offering a higher rebate. Suppliers are less likely

    to seek to offer better rebates to customers who wished to repay a loan early, but

    had no intention to do any more business with them.

    Lessening of incumbent advantage

    If incumbency advantages were weakened, then we might see greater competition at

    the point of renewal. Customers wishing to refinance a loan might have a wider

    choice of lenders willing to offer the amount the customer wishes to borrow.

    In these circumstances, the difference in incentives between the incumbent and other

    lenders identified in paragraph 58 may become more relevant to competitive

    outcomes. Faced with increased competition at the point of renewal, incumbents

    might seek to restore an element of incumbency advantage by offering better rebates

    to customers who stay with them. If statutory rebates were too low, incumbents

    would be able to profitably offer a better rebate to customers who refinance a loan

    with them than the statutory rebate, which may continue to be offered to customers

    who wish to settle early and switch to another supplier. There appears to be little

    need for incumbent suppliers to do this at present.

    Counterarguments

    Various arguments have been put to us to suggest that competition between home

    credit suppliers is inherently unlikely ever to focus on rebates.

    39

    For example, a customer who took out a home credit loan due to a short-term shortage of funds and was in position to payback the loan ahead of term might be more inclined to use the same lender in similar circumstances in the future.

    25

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    26/33

    68.

    69.

    70.

    71.

    It has been put to us by several parties that the choices customers make are based

    much more on immediate prosaic factors (eg how much is this going to cost me a

    week; how much will it cost me overall; are there any extra charges if I miss) than

    on something as esoteric as an early settlement rebate.

    This argument is not without force. Price competition is most likely to focus on the

    most visible aspects of pricenotably the headline price of the loan. In this sense,

    low rebates are similar to hidden charges in other markets and may not be

    competed down to costs, even in a generally competitive market. An alternative

    scenario might be that, with more vigorous price competition, rebates would be

    unaffected, but that increased competition would manifest itself through lower

    headline prices. There would be a cross-subsidy between customers who settle

    early and those who do not, but the process of rivalry would bid overall prices down

    to competitive levels.

    It was also put to us that credit advertising law requires APR to be given more

    prominence than rebate and that this could reduce the likelihood that price

    competition for initial loans would focus on the rebate. This appears to place a

    disproportionate emphasis on the impact of these regulations.

    We were also told that for any trader to systematically compete on rebate they would

    (other things being equal) need to charge higher cash cost and APR than their

    competitors. To be more competitive on rebate they would have to be less

    competitive on price. We have not seen any evidence to suggest that suppliers who

    currently offer more favourable rebates have higher charges than those that offer the

    statutory minimum.

    26

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    27/33

    72.

    73.

    74.

    75.

    Finally, it was put to us that a lack of observed competition on rebates suggests that

    rebates are already at the right level. Home credit lenders have told us that they are

    generally happy with the approach taken to rebates in the 2004 Regulations.

    However, we do not consider that it would be correct to infer that the observed lack of

    variation between suppliers, of itself, demonstrates that rebates are set at a level that

    is fair to both consumers and suppliers.

    Conclusion on competitive impact of rebates

    Rebates may affect competition between home credit providers in three ways:

    low rebates reduce customers incentives to switch providers through

    transferring the balance from one supplier to another (see paragraph 52);

    differential loyalty rebates provide incentives for customers to refinance with

    their existing supplier and act as a barrier to switching (see paragraph 55); and

    low rebates create an additional incentive for incumbent suppliers to refinance

    customers loans compared with other lenders. This could reduce rivalry

    between suppliers and be used reinforce incumbency advantages (see

    paragraphs 57 and 58).

    Looking at the first of these effects, we note that there are other ways in which

    customers may switch between home credit suppliers and that, even with higher

    rebates, large price differentials are required for it to be beneficial to customers to

    transfer the balance on short-term loans from one provider to another.

    It is difficult to see that the second and third of these effects are currently having a

    strong adverse effect on competition. Only Mutual currently offers higher rebates on

    renewals than for other early settlements. At present, other incumbency advantages

    appear more significant than any additional incentive for incumbent suppliers to offer

    refinancing.

    27

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    28/33

    76.

    77.

    78.

    However, low rebates might be a symptom of a lack of competition in home credit or

    might have an adverse effect on competition, if other impediments to competition

    were removed. We therefore also considered what might happen to rebates in a

    hypothetically more competitive environment.

    One scenario is that more vigorous price competition between lenders could focus on

    headline prices, leaving rebates unaffected. It seems unlikely that suppliers would

    actively seek to compete on rebates for all customers, even if the market were more

    competitive. For this to be a rational strategy, customers would need to be well-

    informed about rebates at the point of taking out their initial loan. At this stage, the

    rebate may appear of little relevance to the cost of credit and customers may focus

    on other parts of the customer offering. In this sense, low rebates are similar to other

    hidden charges. This is, in essence, the market failure rationale for setting a

    statutory minimum level of early settlement rebates, even in markets which are

    generally competitive.

    However, with more vigorous price competition and a weakening of incumbency

    advantages, we might expect more suppliers to offer refinancing on better terms to

    existing loyal customers. A greater focus on the cost of borrowing (including the

    rebate) from existing customers, plus a more credible threat to switch elsewhere,

    could put more pressure on suppliers to seek to retain them by offering better rebates

    on refinancing. If rebates were too low to start with, they would be able to do this

    profitably. If rebates paid under other circumstances were unaffected, this could

    increase barriers to switching. Although the market would be more competitive in

    this scenario, low statutory rebates might, at this point, act as an impediment to

    further competition.

    28

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    29/33

    ANNEX A

    Alternative scenario for smaller provider

    1.

    2.

    3.

    The example developed in paragraphs 32 to 40 is based on Providents 55-week

    product. This is the most widely held home credit loan product in the UK. However,

    it is not typical of smaller providers, who tend to offer loans for repayment over a

    shorter term. The CCA also told us that smaller providers faced higher costs

    associated with early settlement. In meetings with the DTI in 2003, the CCA

    estimated that, for the smaller trader, the administrative costs of early settlement

    would, on average be around 1.82 per settlement.

    We developed an analysis intended to reflect more closely the situation of a typical

    provider. The product we considered was a 28-week loan, with a TCC of 40 on

    100. A typical loan size for a product of this duration would be 200, on which the

    customer was making an average weekly repayment of 10. As with the example in

    the main body of the text, we considered a range of cost scenarios. In the central

    scenario, we assume the fixed costs associated with this loan to be 14. Weekly

    variable costs in the central scenario are 28 (equivalent to 10 per cent of the Total

    Amount Payable or 1 a week). As with the example in the main body of the text, the

    remaining 38 is assumed to be incurred with a similar time profile as interest. The

    implicit interest rate used for allocating these costs between periods is 90.0 per cent,

    compared with a product APR of 258.6 per cent. In all scenarios we used the CCAs

    average cost of early settlement of 1.82.

    Table 4 shows the range of scenarios considered.

    29

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    30/33

    TABLE 4 Range of cost assumptions for a 200 loan with a TCC of 80

    Scenario

    Repayment ofcapital

    Fixedcosts

    Variable costs

    Interest costs

    HeadlineAPR

    %

    APR forallocating

    interest costs%

    Low fixed, lowvariable 200 7 14 59 258.6 163.1

    Low fixed, med

    variable 200 7 28 45 258.6 112.2Low fixed, highvariable 200 7 42 31 258.6 69.7

    Med fixed, lowvariable 200 14 14 52 258.6 136.5

    Med fixed, medvariable 200 14 28 38 258.6 90.0

    Med fixed, highvariable 200 14 42 24 258.6 51.3

    High fixed, lowvariable 200 21 14 45 258.6 112.2

    High fixed, medvariable 200 21 28 31 258.6 69.7

    High fixed, highvariable 200 21 42 17 258.6 34.5

    Actuarial

    formula 200 0 0 80 258.6 258.6

    Source: CC analysis.

    4.

    5.

    Using these assumptions, we calculated cost-based early settlement rebates for

    each week of settlement using the formula in Figure 4.

    FIGURE 4

    Formula for calculating cost-based early settlement rebates

    Rebate = Weekly costs avoided by customer settling early

    plusinterest costs avoided by customer settling early

    minusadministrative cost of early settlement (= 1.82)

    Source: CC.

    Table 5 calculates the difference between the statutory minimum rebates payable

    calculated using the actuarial formula subject to a four-week defermentand rebates

    30

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    31/33

    based on the costs avoided by the supplier at early settlement. The statutory

    minimum rebate payable is included as the final column.

    TABLE 5 Difference between statutory minimum and cost-based rebates under range of scenarios

    Difference from statutory minimum

    Cost assumptionsWeek

    All interestActuarialformula

    High fixed / lowvariable

    Minimum

    Med fixed, medvariable

    Central scenario

    Low fixed highvariable

    Maximum

    Rebate payableStatutory minimum

    0 19 4 3 10 60.875 16 1 7 14 40.02

    10 13 4 10 16 22.9815 10 5 10 15 10.2420 6 4 7 11 2.3725 1 0 2 3 0.00

    Source: CC analysis.

    6. In the high fixed cost scenarios, the statutory minimum is below the cost-based

    rebate for loans that settle in the first two to three weeks. The higher administrative

    costs associated with early settlement in this example also imply that cost-based

    estimates of early settlement rebates for loans that settle in the last three weeks are

    close to zero. For loans that settle between weeks 4 and 25, the statutory rebate is

    lower than a cost-based rebate on all scenarios. For loans that settle at week 20, the

    difference is in the range 4 to 11, compared with a statutory minimum rebate of

    2.37.

    31

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    32/33

    ANNEX B

    Impact of rebates on incentives to transfer outstanding balances

    1.

    2.

    Consider a customer who has taken out a 400 loan on a Providents 55-week

    product, which has a TCC of 65 per 100 advanced.

    Now suppose that, after making 27 repayments, the customer is approached by

    another supplier, offering a 28-week loan at a total charge for credit of 40 per 100

    advanced. The customer does not want to borrow any more at that stage, but is

    interested in switching away from her current lender. Table 6 shows the details of

    the first loan and the situation after 27 weeks.

    TABLE 6 Details of first loan and situation after 27 weeks

    Terms of first loanOriginal loan size () 400TCC per 100 () 65TCC () 260Total amount payable () 660No of weeks 55Weekly payment () 12

    Situation after 27 weeks

    No of weekly payments made 27Balance outstanding on first loan () 336TCC per 100 for new provider () 40

    Source: CC analysis based on Provident loan example.

    3.

    4.

    In order to illustrate the implications of rebates for the incentives to switch in this way,

    we consider four scenarios for the rebate. At one end of the spectrum, the customer

    receives no rebate. At the opposite end, the customer receives a rebate calculated

    at a flat rate (ie the customer is rebated 28/52 of the total charge for credit). In

    between are the rebate calculated using the actuarial formula with and without the

    retention of eight weeks interest.

    Table 7 shows the impact of different rebate regimes on incentives to switch. With

    the rebate calculated as a flat rate, the customer is 51 better off for switching. With

    32

  • 8/2/2019 Early Settlement Rebates-further Analysis

    33/33

    the actuarial formula, the customer is 22 worse off. The differential is larger still, if

    the incumbent supplier chooses to retain eight weeks interest.

    TABLE 7 Impact of rebates on incentives to transfer balances

    Rebate regime Flat rate Actuarial

    Actuarialless eight

    weeks No rebate

    Cost of paying off loan with incumbent 336 336 336 336Rebate 132 80 43 0Amount borrowed from new provider 204 256 293 336Total amount payable with new provider 285 358 410 470Customer saving / cost of switching 51 22 74 134

    Source: CC analysis.


Recommended