+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Econ 240C

Econ 240C

Date post: 24-Jan-2016
Category:
Upload: nura
View: 23 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Econ 240C. Lecture 16. Part I. VAR. Does the Federal Funds Rate Affect Capacity Utilization?. The Federal Funds Rate is one of the principal monetary instruments of the Federal Reserve Does it affect the economy in “real terms”, as measured by capacity utilization. Preliminary Analysis. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Popular Tags:
60
Econ 240C Lecture 16
Transcript
Page 1: Econ 240C

Econ 240C

Lecture 16

Page 2: Econ 240C

2

Part I. VAR

• Does the Federal Funds Rate Affect Capacity Utilization?

Page 3: Econ 240C

3

• The Federal Funds Rate is one of the principal monetary instruments of the Federal Reserve

• Does it affect the economy in “real terms”, as measured by capacity utilization

Page 4: Econ 240C

4

Preliminary Analysis

Page 5: Econ 240C

5The Time Series, Monthly, January 1967through May 2003

Page 6: Econ 240C

6Federal Funds Rate: July 1954-April 2006

Page 7: Econ 240C

7Capacity Utilization Manufacturing:

Jan. 1972- April 2006

Page 8: Econ 240C

8Changes in FFR & Capacity Utilization

Page 9: Econ 240C

9Contemporaneous Correlation

Page 10: Econ 240C

10Dynamics: Cross-correlation

Page 11: Econ 240C

11Granger Causality

Page 12: Econ 240C

12Granger Causality

Page 13: Econ 240C

13Granger Causality

Page 14: Econ 240C

14

Estimation of VAR

Page 15: Econ 240C

15

Page 16: Econ 240C

16

Page 17: Econ 240C

17

Page 18: Econ 240C

18

Page 19: Econ 240C

19

Page 20: Econ 240C

20

Page 21: Econ 240C

21

Page 22: Econ 240C

22

Page 23: Econ 240C

23

Estimation Results

• OLS Estimation

• each series is positively autocorrelated– lags 1 and 24 for dcapu– lags 1, 2, 7, 9, 13, 16

• each series depends on the other– dcapu on dffr: negatively at lags 10, 12, 17, 21– dffr on dcapu: positively at lags 1, 2, 9, 10 and

negatively at lag 12

Page 24: Econ 240C

24Correlogram of DFFR

Page 25: Econ 240C

25Correlogram of DCAPU

Page 26: Econ 240C

26We Have Mutual Causality, But

We Already Knew That

DCAPU

DFFR

Page 27: Econ 240C

27

Interpretation

• We need help

• Rely on assumptions

Page 28: Econ 240C

28

What If

• What if there were a pure shock to dcapu– as in the primitive VAR, a shock that only

affects dcapu immediately

Page 29: Econ 240C

Primitive VAR

(1)dcapu(t) = dffr(t) +

dcapu(t-1) + dffr(t-1) + x(t)

+ edcapu(t)

(2) dffr(t) = dcapu(t) +

dcapu(t-1) + dffr(t-1) + x(t)

+ edffr(t)

Page 30: Econ 240C

30The Logic of What If• A shock, edffr , to dffr affects dffr immediately,

but if dcapu depends contemporaneously on dffr, then this shock will affect it immediately too

• so assume is zero, then dcapu depends only on its own shock, edcapu , first period

• But we are not dealing with the primitive, but have substituted out for the contemporaneous terms

• Consequently, the errors are no longer pure but have to be assumed pure

Page 31: Econ 240C

31

DCAPU

DFFR

shock

Page 32: Econ 240C

32Standard VAR

• dcapu(t) = (/(1- ) +[ (+ )/(1- )] dcapu(t-1) + [ (+ )/(1- )] dffr(t-1) + [(+ (1- )] x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))/(1- )

• But if we assume

• thendcapu(t) = + dcapu(t-1) + dffr(t-1) + x(t) + edcapu(t) +

Page 33: Econ 240C

33

• Note that dffr still depends on both shocks

• dffr(t) = (/(1- ) +[(+ )/(1- )] dcapu(t-1) + [ (+ )/(1- )] dffr(t-1) + [(+ (1- )] x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))/(1- )

• dffr(t) = (+[(+ ) dcapu(t-1) + (+ ) dffr(t-1) + (+ x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))

Page 34: Econ 240C

34

DCAPU

DFFR

shock

edcapu(t)

edffr(t)

Reality

Page 35: Econ 240C

35

DCAPU

DFFR

shock

edcapu(t)

edffr(t)

What If

Page 36: Econ 240C

36EVIEWS

Page 37: Econ 240C

37

Page 38: Econ 240C

38Interpretations• Response of dcapu to a shock in dcapu

– immediate and positive: autoregressive nature

• Response of dffr to a shock in dffr– immediate and positive: autoregressive nature

• Response of dcapu to a shock in dffr– starts at zero by assumption that – interpret as Fed having no impact on CAPU

• Response of dffr to a shock in dcapu– positive and then damps out– interpret as Fed raising FFR if CAPU rises

Page 39: Econ 240C

39

Change the Assumption Around

Page 40: Econ 240C

40

DCAPU

DFFR

shock

edcapu(t)

edffr(t)

What If

Page 41: Econ 240C

41Standard VAR• dffr(t) = (/(1- ) +[(+ )/(1-

)] dcapu(t-1) + [ (+ )/(1- )] dffr(t-1) + [(+ (1- )] x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))/(1- )

• if

• then, dffr(t) = dcapu(t-1) + dffr(t-1) + x(t) + edffr(t))

• but, dcapu(t) = ( + (+ ) dcapu(t-1) + [ (+ ) dffr(t-1) + [(+ x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))

Page 42: Econ 240C

42

Page 43: Econ 240C

43Interpretations• Response of dcapu to a shock in dcapu

– immediate and positive: autoregressive nature

• Response of dffr to a shock in dffr– immediate and positive: autoregressive nature

• Response of dcapu to a shock in dffr– is positive (not - ) initially but then damps to zero– interpret as Fed having no or little control of CAPU

• Response of dffr to a shock in dcapu– starts at zero by assumption that – interpret as Fed raising FFR if CAPU rises

Page 44: Econ 240C

44Conclusions• We come to the same model interpretation

and policy conclusions no matter what the ordering, i.e. no matter which assumption we use, or

• So, accept the analysis

Page 45: Econ 240C

45Understanding through Simulation

• We can not get back to the primitive fron the standard VAR, so we might as well simplify notation

• y(t) = (/(1- ) +[ (+ )/(1- )] y(t-1) + [ (+ )/(1- )] w(t-1) + [(+ (1- )] x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))/(1- )

• becomes y(t) = a1 + b11 y(t-1) + c11 w(t-1) + d1 x(t) + e1(t)

Page 46: Econ 240C

46

• And w(t) = (/(1- ) +[(+ )/(1- )] y(t-1) + [ (+ )/(1- )] w(t-1) + [(+ (1- )] x(t) + (edcapu(t) + edffr(t))/(1- )

• becomes w(t) = a2 + b21 y(t-1) + c21 w(t-1) + d2 x(t) + e2(t)

Page 47: Econ 240C

47

Numerical Example

y(t) = 0.7 y(t-1) + 0.2 w(t-1)+ e1(t)w(t) = 0.2 y(t-1) + 0.7 w(t-1) + e2(t)

where e1(t) = ey(t) + 0.8 ew(t)

e2(t) = ew(t)

Page 48: Econ 240C

48

• Generate ey(t) and ew(t) as white noise processes using nrnd and where ey(t) and ew(t) are independent. Scale ey(t) so that the variances of e1(t) and e2(t) are equal

– ey(t) = 0.6 *nrnd and

– ew(t) = nrnd (different nrnd)

• Note the correlation of e1(t) and e2(t) is 0.8

Page 49: Econ 240C

49

Analytical Solution Is Possible

• These numerical equations for y(t) and w(t) could be solved for y(t) as a distributed lag of e1(t) and a distributed lag of e2(t), or, equivalently, as a distributed lag of ey(t) and a distributed lag of ew(t)

• However, this is an example where simulation is easier

Page 50: Econ 240C

50Simulated Errors e1(t) and e2(t)

Page 51: Econ 240C

51Simulated Errors e1(t) and e2(t)

Page 52: Econ 240C

52Estimated Model

Page 53: Econ 240C

53

Page 54: Econ 240C

54

Page 55: Econ 240C

55

Page 56: Econ 240C

56

Page 57: Econ 240C

57

Page 58: Econ 240C

58

Y to shock in w

Calculated

0.8

0.76

0.70

Page 59: Econ 240C

Impact of a Shock in w on the Variable y: Impulse Response Function

Period

Imp

act

Mult

iplier

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Calculated

Simulated

Impact of shock in w on variable y

Page 60: Econ 240C

Impact of a Shock in y on the Variable y: Impulse Response Function

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Period

Impac

t M

ultip

lier

Calculated

Simulated


Recommended