+ All Categories
Home > Documents > ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the...

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the...

Date post: 06-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: dinhanh
View: 213 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
38
1/1 ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality David Ros´ e Queen’s University February 7, 2018
Transcript
Page 1: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

1/1

ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems ofInequality

David Rose

Queen’s University

February 7, 2018

Page 2: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

2/1

Last class...

I Top income share in Canada- Veall (2012)

I Income inequality in the U.S. - Piketty & Saez (2003)

Today ...

I The Top 1 Percent in an International and Historical Perspective

I Income Inequality and Progressive Taxation in China and India

Page 3: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

3/1

Page 4: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

4/1

Remember that time we talked about technology...

Across developed counties we see two distinct patterns in the topincome shares:

1. The “U-shape”: Anglo-Saxon countries

2. The “L-shape”: France, Germany, Japan, etc.

Page 5: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

5/1

Page 6: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

6/1

Page 7: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

7/1

Sps. skills biased technological change (SBTC) is the main event:

Canucks and Aussies adopt cutting edge U.S. technology but thecontinental Europeans and Japanese don’t?

I Hard to understand why countries on the tech. frontier would seedifferent trends if this was the driving force

Why are these Anglo-Saxon countries so “special”?

I Institutions? Culture?

Page 8: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

8/1

Alvaredo et al. think something else is going on ...

Traditional story:

I Rising income inequality in the U.S. due to increasing skillpremium

1. globalization2. skill-biased technological change

Some Stranger Things going on:

I Lots of the action at very topI S & D for skills probably aren’t a good explanation for this

I Need to look beyond earned incomes

Page 9: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

9/1

“You have to pay them in Iraq, you can pay them as a VAT”

- not Dr. Seuss

Taxation probably has a role in the 1% share:

I U.S., France, U.K, Germany all saw declines in top marginal taxrates after 1970

I The U.S. super-sized its cuts

Page 10: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

10/1

Exhibit A:

Page 11: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

11/1

Exhibit A: the remix

Page 12: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

12/1

Page 13: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

13/1

Observations:

I Strong negative correlation between change in the top 1% share ofincome and the change in the top marginal tax rate

I Recall: correlation 6= causation ... this is just descriptive

Page 14: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

14/1

Story time: Top Marginal Tax Rates and the 1 PercentShare

1. Slemrod (1996): fall in tax rate decreased the incentives for topearners to engage in “tax avoidance”I Cost benefit calculation for hiding income, now the benefit is lower

I Alvaredo et al. are not swayed:

I This can’t explain a long-run surge

I Same story when we include capital-gains (much easier to hide thisincome)

Page 15: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

15/1

2. Lindsey (1987) and Feldstein (1995): lower taxes created moreincentive for talented people to work harder, greaterentrepreneurship, etc.

Taking this seriously:

I The standard optimal tax formula implies, with an elasticity oftaxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top taxrate would be 57 percent (Diamond and Saez 2011).

Page 16: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

16/1

What if we don’t (take the plain-vanilla labour market model seriously)?

Search and Matching Literature

3. Workers and firms find each other and decide to have a relationship(i.e. match)I This produces some amount of surplus that they bargain over

I Often Nash Bargaining is used in these models (not our focus here)

I Key: β represents the worker’s share of surplus and (1− β) is thefirm’ share

I β high =⇒ the worker has high bargaining power

Page 17: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

17/1

Intuition for the Bargaining Story:

Page 18: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

18/1

Why bargaining models of wage determination matter:

When top marginal tax rates fell, high earners started bargaining moreaggressively to increase their compensation.

It does not follow that the 1%’s higher share is followed by increasedoutput ... it doesn’t reflect higher economic growth.

Taking this seriously:

I Top tax rate could potentially be set as high as 83 percent (Piketty,Saez,and Stantcheva 2011).

Piketty, Saez, and Stantcheva (2011) find no apparent correlationbetween cuts in top tax rates and growth rates in real per capita GDP

Page 19: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

19/1

4. What if there’s no causal link between the observation that the top1% share increased while top tax rates were being cut? Maybe it’smerely a coincidence.

Keep in mind that we are trying to rationalize a correlation.

Page 20: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

20/1

Another Candidate Explanation:

Intergenerational wealth accumulation is getting easier.

Piketty (2011): A number of countries are witnessing a return ofinheritance as a major factor

I slower economic growth

I lower rates of taxation of capital

I lower rates of taxation on inheritance and gifts

Need to consider bequests (at time of death) and inter vivos gifts.

I Very hard to collect data on this

Page 21: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

21/1

Page 22: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

22/1

Takeaways:

I Top income shares evolved differently between English speakingand non-English speaking developed countries

I Unlikely that technological progress can account for all of the risein English-speaking countries

I Changes in top marginal tax rates may help explain some of theincrease in the top 1% share

I It’s hard to pin-down the mechanism

Page 23: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

23/1

Piketty and Qian (2009)

Motivation:

I Lots of policy reform for LDCs is about improving effectiveness ofservices, making institutions market friendly, liberalizing trade, etc.

I Little attention is paid to the need for modern income tax systems

Page 24: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

24/1

Why we should think about tax systems:

1. LDCs often rely of very distortionary tax tools - e.g. taxes on tradeor specific consumption goods

2. Can potentially raise the tax revenues needed to provide publicgoods

3. Progressive taxation is one of the least distortionary tools forcontrolling the rise from inequality

Page 25: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

25/1

Page 26: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

26/1

Page 27: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

27/1

Page 28: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

28/1

Real per capita GDP increased by almost 200 percent in China between1986 and 2003 and by slightly less than 80 percent in India

I 6.4 percent per year in China and 3.3 percent per year in India

The top 1%’s income grew even faster! (hence the growing share)

Page 29: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

29/1

China’s Income Tax System

Pre-reform: all Chinese workers worked for the state and paid animplicit tax (from their wages).

Expansion of the private sector by the market reforms decreased thegovernments ability to tax in this manner

I Individual taxation introduced officially in 1980

I Gov’t very clever: to avoid upsetting people they set the deductibleamount very high!I Almost nobody paid tax in 1980

I Fairly steady individual tax system since then

Page 30: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

30/1

Page 31: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

31/1

India’s Income Tax System

A different story:

I Introduced by the British in 1922

I Underwent a lot of changes (almost constant changes) during the1988-2008 period

I The exemption has almost kept pace with nominal income growthI tweaking of tax rates for different bracketsI increases in the personal exemption amount

Page 32: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

32/1

Page 33: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

33/1

The differing taxation policies have resulted in large differences in thedevelopment of their tax bases:

Page 34: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

34/1

Page 35: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

35/1

Page 36: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

36/1

Let me help you plan your weekend:

Midterm: Things we’ve covered

Tools:

1. Poverty Measures: Notes & Ch 3 and 4 of the World BankHandbook on Poverty and Inequality, Low Income Lines, 2011-2012.

2. Inequality Measures: Notes & Ch 6 of the WB Handbook onPov & Ineq.

3. Taxes and Transfers: Notes & Ch 15 of the WB Handbook onPov & Ineq.

Page 37: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

37/1

Main papers we have covered:

1. Osberg, Lars and Kuan Xu (1999). Poverty Intensity: How Well DoCanadian Provinces Compare?

2. Osberg, Lars (2000). Poverty in Canada and the United States:Measurement, Trends, and Implications.

3. The Developing World is Poorer Than We Thought, but No LessSuccessful in the Fight Against Poverty.

4. Fortin, Nicole, Green, David A., Lemieux, Thomas, Milligan, Kevinand W. Craig Riddell (2012). Canadian Inequality: RecentDevelopments and Policy Options.

5. Chawla, Raj K. (2004). Wealth Inequality by Province.

Page 38: ECON 361: Income Distributions and Problems of Inequality · taxable income of 0.5, that the revenue-maximizing top tax rate would be 57 percent ... Progressive Income Taxation in

38/1

6. Ravallion, Martin (2014). Income Inequality in the DevelopingWorld.

7. Veall, Michael R. (2012). Top Income Shares in Canada; RecentTrends and Policy Implications.

8. Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez (2003). Income Inequality inthe United States.

9. Alvaredo, Facundo, Atkinson, Anthony B., Piketty, Thomas, andEmmanuel Saez (2013). The Top 1 Percent in International andHistorical Perspective

10. Piketty, Thomas and Nancy Qian (2009). Income Inequality andProgressive Income Taxation in China and India, 1986-2015


Recommended