+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND...

Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND...

Date post: 10-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
36
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE A CBO PAPER OCTOBER 2003 Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales © Digital Vision
Transcript
Page 1: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATESCONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE

A

CBOP A P E R

OCTOBER 2003

Economic Issuesin Taxing

Internet andMail-Order

Sales

© D

igita

l Vis

ion

Page 2: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should
Page 3: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

CBOA

P A P E R

Economic Issues in TaxingInternet and Mail-Order Sales

October 2003

The Congress of the United States O Congressional Budget Office

Page 4: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should
Page 5: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

Preface

The collection of state and local sales and use taxes when individuals purchase items overthe Internet or from other remote sources is an issue that is now before the Congress. TheInternet Tax Freedom Act of 1998 established an Advisory Commission on ElectronicCommerce to make recommendations about Internet taxation, including whether to requireretailers to collect sales taxes on Internet purchases. But the commission made no formalrecommendations, and the issue has remained unresolved. This Congressional Budget Office(CBO) paper—prepared at the request of the Senate Finance Committee—uses an economicframework to evaluate the various arguments that have been advanced by proponents andopponents of remote collection of sales taxes. In keeping with CBO’s mandate to provideobjective analysis, the report makes no recommendations.

Dennis Zimmerman of CBO’s Tax Analysis Division prepared the paper under the supervisionof G. Thomas Woodward and Roberton Williams. The paper benefited from comments byreviewers outside of CBO, including Thomas Neubig of Ernst & Young and William Fox ofthe University of Tennessee. Within CBO, Robert Dennis, Theresa Gullo, Roger Hitchner,Arlene Holen, Deborah Lucas, David Moore, Robert Murphy, Jennifer Smith, and JohnSturrock provided helpful suggestions.

Leah Mazade edited the manuscript, and Christine Bogusz proofread it. Denise Jordan-Williamsand Simone Thomas typed early drafts of the paper. Lenny Skutnik produced the printed copies,and Annette Kalicki prepared the electronic versions for CBO’s Web site (www.cbo.gov).

Douglas Holtz-EakinDirector

October 2003

Page 6: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should
Page 7: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

Contents

Summary vii

An Overview of the Remote Sales Taxation Issue 2States’ Inability to Collect Tax on Remote Sales 2The Growth of E-Commerce 3The Magnitude of Uncollected State and Local Use Tax Revenue 4The Debate: Whether to Require Remote Sellers to Collect Use Taxes 6

The Economic Trade-Off That Remote Collection Presents 7Nonneutral Taxation of Commodities 8Administrative and Compliance Costs 9Current Efforts to Reduce Compliance Costs 11

Other Economic Issues in the Remote Collection Debate 13Network Externalities and Market Failures 14The Size of the Public Sector 16International Considerations 18Remote Collection and Fairness 18Fiscal Autonomy of States and Local Governments 20

Page 8: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

vi ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

Tables

1. State and Local General Sales Tax Rates andState General Sales Tax Revenue 4

2. Sales Tax Revenue for Selected Local Governmentswith Populations of 200,000 or More, 2000 6

Boxes

1. Origin-Based Versus Destination-Based Sales Tax Systems 13

2. Taxing Digital Goods 14

Page 9: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

Summary

A ll of the 45 states, as well as the District ofColumbia, that levy retail sales taxes on purchases madewithin their borders (local sales) also impose an equiv-alent “use” tax on their residents’ purchases of items outof state (remote sales). Local governments also imposesales and sometimes use taxes. (However, because statesin many cases administer those taxes, the generaldiscussion that follows uses “states” for simplicity’s saketo mean both states and local governments.) Previously,those out-of-state purchases were mainly catalog andtelephone sales. But the growth of on-line, or “e”(electronic), commerce over the past several years hasincreased remote sales by billions of dollars.

States rely on retailers to collect sales taxes from consum-ers on their local purchases and to remit them to thestates, an approach with relatively low administrativecosts and a relatively high rate of collections. But deci-sions by the Supreme Court have established that statesdo not have the authority to require out-of-state sellersto collect and remit use taxes on remote sales unless theseller has established a connection, or “nexus,” with thepurchaser’s state—in this instance, a physical presence(an office or other place of business, property, or anagent). As a result, states rely on the use tax, which ispaid directly by purchasers and whose administrativecosts are relatively high and rate of collections quite low.Estimates of uncollected use taxes from all remote salesin 2003 range from $2.5 billion to $20.4 billion. Pro-jections for 2011 of uncollected taxes from on-line com-merce also vary widely, ranging from $4.5 billion to$54.8 billion.

In addition to its holding on nexus, the Court stated thatthe Congress could permit states to require remote sellersto collect use taxes, a conclusion that has led manyjurisdictions to look to the federal government to conferthat authority on them. A federal advisory committeestudied the question but was unable to reach a consensus

and thus issued no formal recommendations. Opponentsand proponents of granting such authority to states haveadvanced a variety of arguments; however, the centraleconomic issue is the magnitude of two kinds of costsrelated to taxation: the distortions (referred to as excessburden) that come from taxing goods unevenly and theadministrative and compliance costs of collectingrevenue.

Remote-seller collection of use taxes would eliminate theuneven taxation of identical goods purchased from alocal seller and a remote seller and thereby reduce the lossof national income that results when such tax differen-tials cause people to make purely tax-motivated decisionsabout consumption and production. Consumers may bewilling to purchase a good remotely even if the total costof production and delivery exceeds the comparable in-state cost because the money they save in taxes compen-sates them for the money they pay in shipping costs.Similarly, producers may be willing to construct facilitiesin locations where production and shipping costs arehigh to avoid nexus and the need to charge their custom-ers sales taxes. The more unevenly a tax is applied, themore producers and consumers waste resources in effortsto avoid it—thereby reducing economic efficiency. Andif a greater fraction of sales escapes taxation over time,states may seek to maintain the same level of receipts byraising tax rates, which would increase the tax system’sexcess burden.

While taxing remote sales could permit lower overall taxrates and reduced administrative costs, it is also likely toincrease the burden of compliance costs imposed onretailers doing business in many states compared with theburden borne by local sellers doing business in one state.In addition to the 45 states that impose sales taxes, localgovernments in most of them may impose such levies.A firm engaged in business nationwide could thus bedealing with more than 6,000 tax regimes, many with

Page 10: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

viii ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

different tax bases (the goods and services to which thetax applies), tax rates, and rules about who is subject totax. Evidence suggests that the cost of complying withthat multiplicity of tax systems, particularly for smallerfirms, will exceed compliance costs for local sellersdealing with a single sales tax system.

Those two economic costs arising from taxation—distortion costs and compliance costs—represent a lossto society. That loss constitutes the social costs of taxa-tion (costs in excess of the revenue collected). Requiringremote sellers to collect and remit use taxes would haveunclear effects on social costs: distortion costs wouldprobably be reduced, but compliance costs would prob-ably increase. The decision by policymakers to eithergrant or withhold from states the authority to collect usetaxes on remote sales involves a trade-off between thosetwo costs. Several proposals to grant that authority havebeen introduced in the 108th Congress.

Federal action is not the only source of policy changes thatcould affect that trade-off. As of August 2003, more than30 states had developed and 20 adopted the StreamlinedSales and Use Tax Agreement (SSUTA). The SSUTA isintended to reduce the compliance costs imposed onremote sellers by implementing three strategies: (1)adopting computer technology and institutional arrange-ments to enable vendors to comply more cheaply withmultiple tax laws and taxing authorities; (2) adoptingcommon tax-base definitions for categories of con-sumption, similar tax bases, and similar tax-filing andaudit procedures; and (3) compensating vendors for thecompliance costs that remain after the first two strategieshave been implemented.

Proponents and opponents of remote collection raise otherissues as part of the debate. Opponents have argued thateffectively exempting Internet purchases from sales taxesis a means of inducing more people to use the Internetand stimulating the growth of e-commerce. The growthof Internet use is desirable because the Internet exhibits“network externalities”—a person’s joining the networkbenefits not only him- or herself but also other par-ticipants, by adding to the total number of participantsin the network. Too few people use the Internet whenthose external benefits are not reflected in the price of

access to it. Providing a subsidy would thus increase useof the Internet and benefit society.

Network externalities, however, exist mainly in the earlystages of a network’s growth. For that reason, it is difficultto justify incentives for a network such as the Internet,which was used by 56 percent of the U.S. populationabove the age of eight in 2001. And even if such exter-nalities are present, not collecting use taxes on remotepurchases is an indirect and unevenly targeted means ofencouraging more people to use the Internet (and in statesthat have no sales tax, no incentive at all). Thus, such anapproach may not increase overall efficiency, whereas amore direct incentive for Internet use or access might. Some opponents of remote-seller use tax collection agreethat nonneutral, or uneven, taxation of commodities canlead to higher tax rates and excess burden. But they alsoargue that collecting use taxes on remote sales will none-theless increase the social costs of taxation if, as somepeople believe, governments have an inherent tendencyto be too large. If taxes are costly to collect, that cost canhelp constrain government spending. Reducing the costsof collecting use taxes, therefore, may not result in lowerrates on other taxes and a lessening of distortion costs butinstead will encourage larger government and increase thesocial costs of taxation. Those analytic possibilities not-withstanding, the empirical evidence regarding such claimsis mixed. And regardless of the issue of remote collection,concerns about the magnitude of government spendingcould be addressed through the political process as wellas with a variety of tax and spending controls that havebeen adopted by some states and local governments.

Tax equity, another issue in the remote collection debate,has been used as the basis for some proponents’ argu-ments. They contend that not collecting use taxes violatesprinciples of fairness in that two individuals who purchaseidentical goods may pay different taxes because one ofthem buys the good over the Internet. Proponents furthermaintain that because Internet access—as well as the useof credit cards and other instruments typically used toshop on-line—tends to rise with income, the effectiveexemption of e-commerce from taxation causes state salestax systems to be more regressive than they would bewithout such an exemption.

Page 11: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix

Both arguments represent value judgments about howtaxes should be levied. As a result, one cannot evaluate theeffect that the violation of those equity norms has oneconomic well-being as one can evaluate the effect ofviolating the efficiency standard. Consumers who buy thesame goods through different channels choose to do soand in other ways are not identical; comparing them toassess fairness is thus problematic. As for the differentialeffects on consumers with different income, the potentialfor e-commerce to make the sales tax more regressivediminishes as Internet access becomes more nearlyuniversal.

Opponents of requiring remote sellers to collect use taxesraise a different fairness issue—one related to businessesthat receive no benefits or services from a jurisdictionbecause they are located elsewhere. Those opponents arguethat such businesses should not have to pay taxes insupport of those benefits and services. But the “tax” inquestion is a levy on consumers that is merely collectedby firms, and any impact on those businesses appears ascompliance costs, a burden that could be lightened bycompensation. To the extent that issues of tax equity arise,

they are centered on the effects on residents of a taxingjurisdiction who purchase goods and services remotely.

Another concern expressed by opponents of remote-sellertax collection is the question of states’ fiscal autonomy.Granting the authority to collect use taxes on remote salesin exchange for simplifying sales tax regimes, they argue,would limit states that have sales taxes in tailoring theirtax to their citizens’ preferences. To the extent that stateschoose well on behalf of their residents, those choicespresumably increase well-being. As a general matter,however, the issue is beyond the scope of economicanalysis.

Of the various arguments related to efficiency and fairness,nonneutral taxation and compliance costs appear to becentral to the issue of remote sales tax collection. However,even the gains from eliminating nonneutral taxation woulddepend on the degree to which international differencesin taxing remote sales persisted and the ability to trackand tax digital goods (for example, digitized music). Thegains from reducing compliance costs have yet to bedemonstrated.

Page 12: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should
Page 13: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

Economic Issues in TaxingInternet and Mail-Order Sales

States and local governments that levy taxes onretail sales have long faced the issue of the cost ofcollecting that revenue when their residents purchase itemsby mail or telephone from retailers that are located outof their jurisdictions—so-called remote sellers. Retail salesover the Internet, known as electronic, or “e,” commerce,have boosted remote sales and increased states’ and localgovernments’ interest in collecting taxes on those pur-chases. The uncollected revenue from the e-commerceshare of such sales is expected to continue to increase, butprojections of its magnitude vary widely—for example,for 2011, they range from $4.5 billion to $54.8 billion.1

States and local governments require merchants to collectsales taxes at the point of sale and remit them to the gov-ernment. That system works well when the sale takesplace within the taxing jurisdiction (local sales). Butthose governments have limited authority to requiresellers outside their jurisdictions to collect tax onpurchases made by their residents. As a result, all of thestates that levy sales taxes have adopted a companion“use” tax, to be collected from residents, that applies togoods purchased from out-of-state vendors that are“used” at home. The use tax is intended to reduce theincentive for residents to purchase goods from retailerslocated in lower-tax (or no-tax) jurisdictions. But theadministrative costs of collecting use taxes are relativelyhigh. As a result, governments tend to avoid those costsand rely primarily on residents to voluntarily pay the

taxes. Relatively little revenue is collected, however.2

Consequently, the underlying economic issue is notwhether sales over the Internet (or by mail or telephone)are to be subject to tax—they already are. The issue israther the cost of collecting such taxes.

Under the Constitution, the Congress could reduce theadministrative costs of collecting sales and use taxes bygiving states and local governments the authority torequire remote sellers to collect them. Such a require-ment would eliminate some tax differentials amongcommodities and reduce the loss of national income thatresults when that uneven taxation causes people to decidewhether to consume or produce something on the basisof the taxes that apply. The costs arising from the “dis-tortion” of those decisions are sometimes referred to asexcess burden. But the requirement would also imposehigher compliance costs on remote sellers, who wouldhave to keep track of a complex system of tax bases (seethe discussion below) and rates imposed by the 45 statesand thousands of local jurisdictions that levy sales anduse taxes.

Those two effects—distortion costs and compliance costs—represent a loss to society and constitute the socialcosts of taxation (costs in excess of the revenue collected).A decision to require remote sellers to collect and remit

1. The lower estimate appears in Peter A. Johnson, A CurrentCalculation of Uncollected Sales Tax Arising from Internet Growth (NewYork: Direct Marketing Association, March 11, 2003); the higherestimate is from Donald Bruce and William F. Fox, State and LocalSales Tax Revenue Losses from E-Commerce: Updated Estimates (Knox-ville, Tenn.: Center for Business and Economic Research, Univer-sity of Tennessee, September 2001).

2. Enforcement of the use tax is practical only for consumer goods(such as automobiles and boats) that must be registered in a stateand for purchases made by businesses that are otherwise subjectto audit. The use tax accounts for about 10 percent of total salesand use tax collections, according to John F. Due and John L.Mikesell, Sales Taxation: State and Local Structure and Admin-istration (Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 1994), p. 246.Most of that use tax revenue comes from business-to-business salesthat are subject to compliance review (unlike most business-to-consumer sales).

Page 14: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

2 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

use taxes would have conflicting effects on social costs:it would reduce excess burden but increase administrativeand compliance costs. As a result, federal policymakersface a difficult choice. In the Internet Tax Freedom Actof 1998 (Public Law 105-277), the Congress establishedthe Advisory Commission on Electronic Commerce todevelop recommendations about taxation related to theInternet, including recommendations on expanding theduty of retailers to collect taxes on remote sales. But thecommission was unable to reach a consensus and issuedno official recommendations.

Thus, the Congress still faces the question of whether toact on this issue and, if so, what action to take. ThisCongressional Budget Office paper examines in moredetail the trade-off between distortion costs and adminis-trative and compliance costs.3 It also evaluates severalother claims that have been advanced as part of thedebate about whether to grant states the power to requireremote sellers to collect use taxes. Those claims concernthe effect of that power on the growth of the Internet andon the growth of government. In addition, the claimsraise issues of fairness (who pays taxes) and of states’ fiscalautonomy (the freedom to determine their tax policywithout interference from the federal government).

An Overview of the RemoteSales Taxation IssueGeneral sales taxes were first adopted in the 1930s.Today, 45 states, the District of Columbia, and manylocal governments levy sales and use taxes, imposing theirown tax rates and choosing their own definitions of the“base”of goods and services to which the tax applies.Sales taxes were originally conceived as a levy on all retailsales with sellers acting as collection agents; however, thebase of the tax in most jurisdictions is neither compre-

hensive nor uniform. For example, sales tax basestypically exclude most services and intangible products,such as medical, legal, financial, and education services.Many jurisdictions also exempt some categories oftangible goods, such as food and medicine, to lighten theburden of the tax on lower-income taxpayers. In contrast,the base includes a substantial amount of goods pur-chased by businesses—which means that those commod-ities are effectively taxed twice under the sales tax, onceas an input in a production process and once as part ofthe final good that is produced.4

The general sales tax finances a substantial portion ofstates’ public services, accounting in 2002 for 33.5 per-cent of states’ total tax revenue (see Table 1 on pages 4and 5). Among the states, that share varies considerably:it accounts for more than 50 percent of tax revenue inArizona, Florida, Nevada, South Dakota, Tennessee,Texas, and Washington and, as expected, for none of therevenue in the five no-sales-tax states—Alaska, Delaware,Montana, New Hampshire, and Oregon. Thirty-fivestates also allow local governments to levy sales taxes.(However, in many cases, the states administer thoselocal taxes.)

Sales tax revenue is a far smaller part of the finances oflocal governments, accounting for about 12.2 percent oftotal local tax revenue in 2000. That average masks con-siderable variation, however. Sales tax revenue accountedfor 18.1 percent of total tax revenue in 2000 for localgovernments whose population exceeded 200,000 andthat levied a general sales tax (see Table 2 on page 6).

States’ Inability to Collect Tax on Remote SalesAs mail-order businesses have expanded, states havesought ways to maintain their revenue base in the face of

3. The “optimal tax” framework for commodity taxes with an explicittrade-off between excess burden and administrative and compliancecosts is developed in Shlomo Yitzhaki, “A Note on OptimalTaxation and Administrative Costs,” American Economic Review,vol. 69, no. 1 (1979), pp. 475-480. An analysis of the optimaltax literature and electronic commerce is presented in DonaldBruce, William F. Fox, and Matthew Murray, “To Tax or Not toTax? The Case of Electronic Commerce,” Contemporary EconomicPolicy, vol. 21, no. 1 (2003), pp. 25-40.

4. Raymond L. Ring Jr., in his article “Consumers’ Share andProducers’ Share of the General Sales Tax” (National Tax Journal,vol. 52, no. 1, 1999, pp. 79-90), estimated that 41 percent of thesales tax base in 1989 entailed purchases by businesses, govern-ments, and nonprofit organizations. Ring could not estimatespecific shares for each category, however. Double taxation doesnot occur in cases in which taxable purchases are inputs fornontaxable services. Information also is not available to determinewhether the share of the tax base that is made up of purchases bybusinesses, governments, and nonprofit organizations has changedover the past decade.

Page 15: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 3

a growing volume of out-of-jurisdiction purchases. Inthat pursuit, they tested their authority to require remotesellers to collect the use tax applicable in the customer’sstate. But the Supreme Court invalidated those statutesas unconstitutional constraints on interstate commercein cases in which the remote sellers had an insufficientconnection to the taxing states.

For instance, in 1967, in National Bellas Hess, Incorpo-rated, v. Department of Revenue for the State of Illinois,the Court struck down an Illinois statute that requiredremote sellers to collect use taxes on their sales to Illi-nois customers.5 National Bellas Hess was a Missourimail-order business whose only connection with cus-tomers in the state of Illinois was through the U.S.Postal Service or common carriers (for example, UnitedParcel Service). The Court held that under the Consti-tution’s commerce and due process clauses, the firmlacked the requisite physical presence in Illinois—or“nexus” with the state—either to justify the burden thatthe statute imposed on interstate commerce or to over-come the statute’s “offense” to due process.6

The Court used the firm’s costs for complying withsuch statutes to illustrate the burden that the Illinoisstatute imposed on interstate commerce. It concludedthat if the Illinois statute was upheld, the decisioncould potentially subject National Bellas Hess’s inter-state business to the tax rates, exemptions, and record-keeping requirements of every political subdivision inthe country. The result, according to the Court, wouldbe to “entangle National’s interstate business in a vir-tual welter of complicated obligation to local jurisdic-tions who would have no legitimate claim that theywere imposing ‘a fair share of the cost’ of government.”

In a more recent case, the Court signaled its view ofwhere resolution of the issue of remote sales taxationmight be pursued. In Quill Corporation v. North Dakota,the Court was again faced with a state statute that re-quired remote sellers to collect use taxes on their sales toout-of-state customers.7 The Quill Corporation, a Dela-ware-based remote seller, was connected to customers inNorth Dakota only by common carrier or the mail. TheCourt found that Quill’s “minimum contacts” with thestate satisfied the requirements of due process but thatthe firm nevertheless lacked what the judges now termeda “substantial nexus” with the state as required under thecommerce clause. The Court thus upheld the standardit had expressed in National Bellas Hess and concludedthat Quill lacked the requisite physical presence in NorthDakota to justify the burden that the state statute im-posed on interstate commerce. The Court noted that theunderlying issue of taxing remote sales was “not only onethat Congress may be better qualified to resolve but alsoone that Congress has the ultimate power [under theConstitution] to resolve.”

The Growth of E-CommerceDetermining the rate of growth of e-commerce overmore than a few years is difficult. The federal govern-ment first published complete data on total e-commercefor 1999. The value of Internet sales grew by more thanhalf over the next two years, rising from $660 billion in1999 to just over $1 trillion in 2001. More than 93 per-cent of that latter amount was attributable to business-to-business transactions for “manufacturing shipments” and“merchant wholesale trade sales,” categories of economicactivity that the Bureau of the Census uses in its e-com-merce surveys.8 Business-to-consumer transactions appearin two other categories: “retail trade sales” and “servicerevenue.” (The term “total e-commerce” covers bothbusiness-to-business and business-to-consumer transac-tions.)

5. National Bellas Hess, Incorporated, v. Department of Revenue for theState of Illinois, 386 U.S. 753 (1967).

6. In due process jurisprudence, the relevant inquiry is framed aswhether a defendant has had minimum contacts with thejurisdiction “such that the maintenance of the suit does not offendtraditional notions of fair play and substantial justice.” SeeInternational Shoe Co. v. Washington, 326 U.S. 310 (1945), quotingMilliken v. Meyer, 311 U.S. 457 (1940).

7. Quill Corp. v. North Dakota, 504 U.S. 298 (1992).

8. The Census Bureau’s e-statistics are available at www.census.gov/eos/www/ebusiness614.htm.

Page 16: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

4 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

Table 1.

State and Local General Sales Tax Rates and State General Sales Tax Revenue

State TaxRate, 2003(Percent)

Top Combined Stateand Local Tax Rate,

2003 (Percent)

Total State TaxRevenue, 2002

(Millions of dollars)

State General Sales Tax Revenue, 2002In Millionsof Dollars

As a Percentage ofTotal State Taxes

Alabamaa 4 11 6,879 1,747 25.4Alaskaa 0 7 1,090 0 0Arizonaa 5.6 8.6 8,477 4,289 50.6Arkansasa 5.125 9.875 5,034 1,918 38.1Californiaa 6 8.5 77,755 23,793 30.6Coloradoa 2.9 7.9 6,923 1,904 27.5Connecticut 6 6 9,033 3,044 33.7Delaware 0 0 2,174 0 0Floridaa 6 7.5 24,816 14,418 58.1Georgiaa 4 7 13,772 4,834 35.1Hawaii 4 4 3,421 1,611 47.1Idahoa 5 8 2,271 795 35.0Illinoisa 6.25 9.25 22,460 6,424 28.6Indiana 6 6 9,995 3,798 38.0Iowaa 5 7 5,006 1,747 34.9Kansasa 5.3 8.3 4,808 1,798 37.4Kentucky 6 6 7,975 2,313 29.0Louisianaa 4 9.5 7,346 2,329 31.7Maine 5 5 2,627 835 31.8Maryland 5 5 10,821 2,694 24.9Massachusetts 5 5 14,820 3,690 24.9Michigan 6 6 21,864 7,784 35.6Minnesotaa 6.5 7.5 12,936 3,739 28.9Mississippia 7 7.25 4,729 2,341 49.5Missouria 4.225 8.35 8,679 2,855 32.9Montana 0 0 1,443 0 0Nebraskaa 5.5 7 2,993 1,069 35.7Nevada 6.5 7.25 3,945 2,071 52.5New Hampshire 0 0 1,884 0 0

(Continued)

Retail sales statistics give some indication of the growthof e-commerce over the past decade. The Census Bureaucollects time-series data on the retail component of totale-commerce in its “Monthly Retail Survey”; the category“electronic shopping and mail-order houses”covers allremote retail sales (mail order, telephone, and e-com-merce). Those sales have grown rapidly, rising from$35.1 billion in 1992 to $109.7 billion in 2001 and$116.6 billion in 2002. The e-commerce share of thosesales cannot be identified for 1992, but data for 1999 to2001 show the share almost doubling, from 16.6 percentto 31.3 percent.

The Magnitude of Uncollected State andLocal Use Tax RevenueThe concerns of states and local governments aboutuncollected use tax revenue (from both business-to-consumer and business-to-business transactions) predatethe rise of sales on the Internet. Uncollected revenuefrom remote sales in 1994 reached $3.3 billion accordingto the Advisory Commission on IntergovernmentalRelations, or 2.5 percent of states’ sales and use tax col-

Page 17: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 5

Table 1.Continued

State TaxRate, 2003(Percent)

Top Combined Stateand Local Tax Rate,

2003 (Percent)

Total State TaxRevenue, 2002

(Millions of dollars)

State General Sales Tax Revenue, 2002In Millionsof Dollars

As a Percentage ofTotal State Taxes

New Jersey 6 6 18,329 5,994 32.7New Mexicoa 5 7.25 3,628 1,339 36.9New Yorka 4 8.5 43,262 8,609 19.9North Carolinaa 4.5 7.5 15,535 3,216 20.7North Dakotaa 5 7.5 1,117 335 30.0Ohioa 5 7 19,617 6,395 32.6Oklahomaa 4.5 9.85 6,053 1,531 25.3Oregon 0 0 5,139 0 0Pennsylvaniaa 6 7 22,136 7,327 33.1Rhode Island 7 7 2,128 732 34.4South Carolinaa 5 7 5,749 2,334 40.6South Dakotaa 4 6 977 524 53.6Tennesseea 7 9.75 7,798 4,679 60.0Texasa 6.25 8.25 28,662 14,560 50.8Utaha 4.75 7 3,925 1,499 38.2Vermonta 5 6 1,534 215 14.0Virginiaa 3.5 4.5 12,781 2,799 21.9Washingtona 6.5 8.9 12,629 7,906 62.6West Virginia 6 6 3,552 963 27.1Wisconsina 5 6 11,814 3,698 31.3Wyominga 4 6 1,094 445 40.7

Memorandum:United States n.a. n.a. 533,435 178,939 33.5

Source: Congressional Budget Office using rates and revenue figures from the Federation of Tax Administrators, available at www.taxadmin.org.

Note: n.a. = not applicable.

a. States in which local governments also levy sales taxes.

lections and 0.8 percent of their total tax revenue.9

Perhaps because many observers expected evolvingcomputer technology to increase remote sales and uncol-lected use tax revenue, the policy debate is often de-scribed as being about taxation of sales over the Internet.But, as noted earlier, the relevant issue is the cost ofcollecting tax revenue from all remote sales rather thanthe increase in such uncollected revenue caused by e-commerce. Any policy requiring remote sellers to collectand remit use taxes levied on e-commerce would proba-

bly be applied to mail-order and telephone sales as well(assuming that all types of remote sellers would bearsimilar compliance costs).

The General Accounting Office in 2000 projected upperand lower bounds for uncollected revenue from remotesales for 2003.10 Its upper-bound estimate was $20.4 bil-lion, or 7.9 percent of projected state and local generalsales tax revenue of $256.4 billion, and its lower-boundestimate was $2.5 billion. Those projections are probablytoo high because they predated the recent recession (total

9. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, Taxationof Interstate Mail-Order Sales: 1994 Revenue Estimates (1994). Thecommission’s original report on mail-order sales, State and LocalTaxation of Out-of-State Mail-Order Sales (May 1986), discussesthe related economic issues more fully.

10. General Accounting Office, Sales Taxes: Electronic CommerceGrowth Presents Challenges; Revenue Losses Are Uncertain, GAO/GGD/OCE-00-165 (June 2000).

Page 18: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

6 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

Table 2.

Sales Tax Revenue for Selected Local Governmentswith Populations of 200,000 or More, 2000

Local GovernmentSales Tax Revenue

(Thousands of dollars)Total Tax Revenue

(Thousands of dollars)Sales Tax as a Percentage

of Total Tax

Albuquerque, N.M. 96,367 200,847 48.0Anaheim, Calif. 57,343 159,718 35.9Bakersfield, Calif. 37,582 69,764 53.9Chicago, Ill. 181,834 1,910,382 9.5Denver, Colo. (City and county) 361,349 649,534 55.6Houston, Tex. 313,864 1,072,223 29.3Kansas City, Mo. 141,243 512,680 27.5Los Angeles, Calif. 442,148 2,300,418 19.2Montgomery, Ala. 58,778 110,280 53.3New Orleans, La. 133,490 359,037 37.2New York, N.Y. 3,525,610 22,547,398 15.6Norfolk, Va. 24,321 273,002 8.9Oklahoma City, Okla. 204,073 272,439 74.9Philadelphia, Pa. 104,328 1,918,632 5.4Phoenix, Ariz. 278,731 618,214 45.1San Diego, Calif. 372,785 855,886 43.6San Francisco, Calif. (City and county) 270,274 1,511,562 17.9St. Paul, Minn. 11,049 129,068 8.6Tampa, Fla. 11,402 158,761 7.2Tulsa, Okla. 202,108 246,359 82.0Washington, D.C. 640,212 3,215,766 19.9

Source: Congressional Budget Office based on unpublished data from the Census Bureau’s “2000 Annual Survey of State and Local Government Finances.”

sales tax revenue for the year ending June 2003 was only$228 billion). But the wide range of the estimates reflectsthe uncertainty arising from shortcomings in the dataavailable to quantify uncollected revenue from remotesales. Factors that must be estimated include the rate ofgrowth of e-commerce; the proportion of e-commercethat is not part of the sales tax base; the share of e-com-merce that is part of the tax base but that representspurchases by exempt entities; and the proportion oftaxable e-commerce on which tax is already being col-lected and that replaces other forms of remote sales. Aseries of assumptions must be made to adjust for thosefactors in estimating total sales over the Internet.

More-recent estimates of uncollected tax revenue fromall remote sales are not available. But two forecasts ofsuch revenue from the e-commerce share of remote salesfor 2006 and 2011 assign different values to each of thefactors contributing to overall uncertainty and conse-quently reach very different conclusions. According to

one set of estimates, uncollected state and local revenuewould be $45.2 billion in 2006 and $54.8 billion in2011, losses that would represent 5.6 percent of state taxrevenue in 2006 and 5.4 percent in 2011.11 The share oflocal tax revenue lost would be 1.8 percent in both years.Another set of estimates is considerably lower—$3.2billion in 2006 and $4.5 billion in 2011, or less than1 percent of state and local tax revenue in both years.12

The Debate: Whether to RequireRemote Sellers to Collect Use TaxesThe potential loss of revenue stemming from states’ andlocal governments’ inability to efficiently collect use taxeson remote purchases has generated a policy debate over

11. Bruce and Fox, State and Local Sales Tax Revenue Losses from E-Commerce.

12. Johnson, A Current Calculation of Uncollected Sales Tax Arising fromInternet Growth.

Page 19: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 7

whether vendors should be required to collect use taxesin their stead. The Supreme Court’s decision in QuillCorporation v. North Dakota makes it clear that only theCongress can give states the authority to require remotesellers to collect use taxes. In fact, that policy role is thefederal government’s only stake in the Internet sales taxdebate; the issue has no direct federal budgetary implica-tions.

The proponents and opponents of such regulation callon principles related to economic efficiency, fairness, andstates’ fiscal autonomy to support their respective posi-tions. According to one side or the other in the debate,requiring remote sellers to collect use taxes will:

# Have opposing effects on the social costs of taxa-tion—decrease the loss of national income thatresults when the differential taxation of commodi-ties causes tax-motivated decisions about consump-tion and production (excess burden) and increasethe compliance costs that would be imposed onremote sellers to collect and remit use taxes;

# Increase the size of government and eliminate a taxadvantage that is helping the Internet grow to itseconomically desirable size;

# Distribute the burden of sales taxes more equitablyand treat people in equal circumstances equally;

# Impose a tax burden on remote sellers who, unlikelocal sellers, receive no compensating public servicebenefits (for example, fire and police protection);or

# Compromise the fiscal autonomy of states and localgovernments, which is guaranteed by the Constitu-tion, if standardization of tax bases and rates is re-quired to reduce compliance costs.

Faced with competing demands involving e-commerce,the Congress considered legislation in 1998 to tax In-ternet access (the fees paid to be connected to theInternet) and require remote sellers to collect taxes onInternet sales. Policymakers eventually enacted theInternet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA), which allowed exist-ing taxes on Internet access to remain in effect but im-

posed a three-year moratorium on new federal, state,and local access levies. In addition, it allowed existingtaxes on sales over the Internet to remain in effect andpermitted governments to impose new taxes on suchsales as long as they applied equally to sales made byother means, but it prohibited discriminatory taxes onInternet sales. The law did not give states and local gov-ernments the authority to require that remote sellerscollect sales taxes.

The ITFA, as noted earlier, also established the Advi-sory Commission on Electronic Commerce, which wasto report to the Congress in April 2000 with recom-mendations about Internet taxation, including salestaxes. However, the commission was unable to achievethe two-thirds majority (13 of 19 members) required toissue official findings and recommendations about re-mote sellers’ expanded duty to collect sales taxes.13

Policymakers were split into two major camps: thosewho would make the Internet a tax-free zone and thosewho would allow collection of use taxes on remote salesprovided state and local governments met certain re-quirements for simplifying and standardizing their taxbases or rates (or both). In November 2001, a compro-mise of sorts was reached by policymakers’ extension ofthe ITFA for two years. The extension’s pending expi-ration in 2003 makes it likely that the current Congresswill address the issue.

The Economic Trade-Off ThatRemote Collection PresentsIn general, the economic issue involved in collectinguse taxes on remote sales (in short, remote collection) isfairly straightforward, notwithstanding the variety ofeconomic arguments advanced by both sides in the pol-icy debate. Remote collection reflects a trade-off be-tween two kinds of social costs that arise from taxation:the loss of national income from nonuniform taxationand the loss from incurring administrative and compli-ance costs for collection. The desirability of remote col-lection depends on the magnitudes of those two kindsof costs.

13. See Advisory Commission on Electronic Commerce, Report toCongress (April 2000).

Page 20: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

8 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

Nonneutral Taxation of CommoditiesVirtually all taxes impose costs in the form of reducedeconomic efficiency. That is, the loss to taxpayers pay-ing the tax is greater than the value of the taxes col-lected because taxes distort decisions about private con-sumption and production and lead to less efficient useof national economic resources. Research indicates thatto raise a given amount of tax revenue, those distor-tions, or excess burden, can be minimized by taxing allcommodities uniformly up to the point that taxing anadditional commodity will increase the costs of admin-istering the tax by more than it reduces excess burden.14

Within that framework, a larger public sector will re-quire a higher tax rate to raise more revenue. Becausethe loss of economic well-being from a tax increasesmore than proportionately with the rise in the tax rate,the outcome will be added inefficiency from the higherrate on taxed goods.

It is the violation of the standard of uniform tax ratesthat supporters of remote-seller tax collection cite aspart of their concern about e-commerce. Under currentarrangements, the tax-inclusive price that a consumerpays for a good varies depending on whether the con-sumer purchases it locally and pays tax on it or buys itover the Internet without complying with the use tax.That kind of price differential causes some decisionsabout both consumption and producers’ locations to bemotivated by taxes rather than by the cost of the re-sources used to produce and sell the good.

For example, a consumer might choose to purchasebooks over the Internet for $100 inclusive of the ship-ping cost, pay no sales tax, and fail to comply with theuse tax rather than purchase the same books at a localbookstore for $102 inclusive of a local $5 sales tax. Thereal resource cost of the books (including profit) pur-

chased from the Internet seller is $100; that is, the“market” values the resources that are used to produceand deliver those books at $100. The real resource costof the same books (including profit) available for salefrom the local bookseller is $97; the portion of thebooks’ cost that is sales tax ($5) is a transfer from theconsumer to the government and uses no resources.Thus, the tax differential that results from the con-sumer’s noncompliance with the use tax causes thisconsumer to make a choice that increases the produc-tion cost of books by $3. That money represents a lossof economic well-being to society because those $3worth of resources could have been used to produce $3worth of other goods or services.

The same circumstances can be used to show how a taxdifferential may affect decisions about production. Sup-pose the Internet bookseller located its East Coast dis-tribution center in jurisdiction A, a small state that hasfew potential customers and in which distribution costsfor the book order discussed above are $10, rather thanin jurisdiction B, a large state that has many potentialcustomers and in which distribution costs are $7. Thebookseller made that decision because by choosing ju-risdiction A, it avoided a physical presence in jurisdic-tion B and the requirement to collect jurisdiction B’s$5 sales tax from customers who live there. The book-seller thus uses $10 of resources for distribution andcharges a jurisdiction B customer $100 (with no salestax) rather than using $7 of resources for distributionand charging $102 (inclusive of sales tax).

Regardless of whether the effect comes through deci-sions about consumption or production, the potentialfor distortion costs arises when differing taxation causesthe price of a good to vary according to whether it ispurchased locally or remotely. In addition, empiricalwork confirms that tax differentials do matter. Studieshave shown that retail prices rise when a sales tax is im-posed;15 research also indicates that differences in salestax rates along state borders cause consumers to switch

14. Were individuals’ preferences known, tax rates could be set to varyamong commodities according to how closely each good’s use wastied to leisure and other activities that cannot be taxed and howsensitive consumers were to a change in the good’s price. Butindividuals’ preferences cannot be known, and policymakers havesettled instead for establishing uniform tax rates across commoditiesas a way to minimize excess burden. For a discussion of the historyof that policy process, see Joel Slemrod, “Optimal Taxation andOptimal Tax Systems,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 4,no. 1 (1990), pp. 157-178.

15. James M. Poterba, “Retail Price Reactions to Changes in State andLocal Sales Taxes,” National Tax Journal, vol. 49, no. 2 (1996),pp. 165-176; and Timothy J. Besley and Harvey S. Rosen, “SalesTaxes and Prices: An Empirical Analysis,” National Tax Journal,vol. 52, no. 2 (1999), pp. 157-178.

Page 21: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 9

their purchases from the higher-tax to the lower-taxjurisdiction.16 Some evidence even suggests that taxingtangible goods but not services may have contributed togrowth in the consumption of services relative togoods.17 Other research shows that reduced economicwell-being can result when consumers alter theirchoices of what to buy because of differential taxes oncommodities.18

In sum, avoiding a situation in which residents of agiven state face differential taxation on the same goodtends to minimize distortions. Not collecting use taxeson e-commerce amplifies the differential taxation thatis already occurring through mail-order, telephone, andcross-border sales. Short of eliminating all sales taxes,policymakers cannot correct the losses from such non-neutral taxation by adopting an alternative approach.

Administrative and Compliance CostsEvery tax system must be administered; tax laws mustbe enforced, and taxpayers—both individuals and busi-nesses—must spend time and money to comply withthose laws. Administrative costs can be thought of asthe expenses incurred by the tax authorities, the stateand local agencies charged with collecting taxes. Com-pliance costs are borne by others, typically those whopay a tax, such as the individual taxpayer in the case ofan income tax. In the case of the general sales tax, how-ever, those costs fall not on consumers directly butrather on retailers who must collect the tax and remit itto the state or to the local government. Of course, some

compliance costs may be passed on to the consumer inthe form of higher prices for retailers’ goods.19 (As dis-cussed later, consumers would also bear compliancecosts indirectly in their role as taxpayers if tax authori-ties compensated retailers for those costs out of col-lected revenue.)

Administrative and compliance costs, therefore, repre-sent the other major social cost of taxation. Like distor-tion costs, they are a cost above and beyond what iscollected and transferred from the private sector to gov-ernments for public use. Consequently, all else beingthe same, it is desirable to minimize the costs of admin-istering and complying with a tax. Although preciseinformation on such costs for different taxes is largelyunavailable, states and local governments nonethelessappear to design their tax structures to account forthem. For example, some services are excluded from theexisting sales tax base because they are thought to entailhigher-than-usual administrative costs per dollar ofrevenue collected.20

High administrative costs help explain why states andlocal governments seldom enforce use taxes for mostbusiness-to-consumer remote sales. Consider the exam-ple of Connecticut’s Operation Equity program. Theprogram pays other states 50 percent of the first year’suse tax that Connecticut collects as a result of informa-tion provided by those states’ sales tax audits. The sizeof that percentage suggests that the cost of achievingcompliance by other means—for example, by pursuingindividual Connecticut taxpayers—is high.

16. William F. Fox, “Tax Structure and the Location of EconomicActivity Along State Borders,” National Tax Journal, vol. 39, no. 4(1986), pp. 387-440; and Michael J. Walsh and Jonathan D. Jones,“More Evidence on the ‘Border Tax’ Effect: The Case of WestVirginia, 1979-84,” National Tax Journal, vol. 41, no. 2 (1988),pp. 261-265.

17. David Merriman and Mark Skidmore, “Did Distortionary SalesTaxation Contribute to the Growth of the Service Sector?” NationalTax Journal, vol. 53, no. 1 (2000), pp. 125-142.

18. Charles L. Ballard and John B. Shoven, “The V.A.T.: TheEfficiency Cost of Achieving Progressivity by Using Exemptions,”in Michael J. Boskin, ed., Modern Developments in Public Finance:Essays in Honor of Arnold Harberger (Oxford, England: BasilBlackwell, 1985), pp. 109-129, Table 6.7.

19. When general sales taxes differ across products or locations, whichis the situation with respect to e-commerce, consumers in the high-tax jurisdiction are likely to reduce their purchases from localretailers and cause those retailers to bear some of the cost of thetax.

20. The role of administrative costs in the structure of sales and usetaxes is discussed in John L. Mikesell, “The Future of AmericanSales and Use Taxation,” in David Brunori, ed., The Future of StateTaxation (Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 1998), pp. 15-32. See Joel Slemrod, “Optimal Taxation and Optimal TaxSystems,” for a more general discussion of how the considerationof administrative costs can change policymakers’ judgments aboutthe optimal tax system.

Page 22: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

10 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

One way to reduce administrative costs is for the fed-eral government to give states the authority to requireremote sellers to collect use taxes on those sales and re-mit them to the purchaser’s state of residence, a man-date that would eliminate costly collection efforts bythe states. From the perspective of state authorities,such a policy would unambiguously reduce the socialcosts of taxation—administrative costs and perhaps dis-tortion costs as well. From the perspective of federalpolicymakers, the effect on social costs is less certain.Under that approach, the reduction in a state’s or localgovernment’s administrative costs would be accompa-nied by an increase in remote retailers’ compliancecosts. Those costs would probably be higher for remotesales than for local sales. Vendors making remote saleswould be dealing with the varied tax bases, rates, andaudit procedures of as many as 45 states (those that levysales taxes) and an unknown number of local jurisdic-tions that impose their own sales tax and do not rely onthe state to administer it. In contrast, vendors makingonly local sales usually face one definition of the base towhich the sales tax applies and at most two rates (onestate and one local).21

Thus, the size of vendors’ compliance costs relative tothe distortion costs of sales taxes appears to be centralto the question of whether it is efficient to require re-mote sellers to collect use taxes. Yet few data exist formeasuring those costs. A recent analysis for the state ofWashington found that compliance costs ranged from0.97 percent of the state’s sales tax revenue collected bylarge firms (defined as having at least $1.5 million inannual gross sales) to 6.47 percent of the revenue col-lected by small firms (firms with at least $150,000 butless than $400,000 in annual gross sales).22 Robert J.

Cline and Thomas S. Neubig, in a study for Ernst &Young, used Washington’s figures to estimate the com-pliance costs that remote sellers would incur for collect-ing and remitting the use tax in three cases: one state,15 states, and 45 states plus the District of Columbia.23

They concluded that compliance costs as a share of rev-enue collections would rise as the number of states inwhich a firm did business increased and the size of thefirm decreased; their estimates of costs ranged from1 percent of tax revenue for a large firm collecting taxesin one state to 48 percent or 87 percent of revenue for amedium-sized or small firm doing business in 45 states.Lorrie Jo Brown, the author of the Washington statestudy, has suggested that those adjustments to theWashington state estimates grossly overstate the likelycompliance costs, but she has provided no comparableestimate for multistate retailers.24

Despite the lack of specific estimates, the availableevidence taken as a whole suggests that the compliancecosts from collecting use taxes will constitute a substan-tially greater burden for vendors’ remote sales than thecosts attached to local sales. Moreover, such costs figureprominently in the opposition to remote collection.Opponents of requiring vendors to collect use taxes onremote sales suggest that those increased costs wouldoutweigh the reduction of distortion costs from eliminat-ing differential taxation. Consequently, federal policythat is focused on reducing the social costs of taxationmust consider compliance costs carefully, and state taxauthorities must find a way to reduce those costs if theyare to obtain the authority to collect taxes remotely.

21. The available data indicate that more than 7,500 jurisdictions levya sales tax. However, as of 1994, state and local tax bases werevirtually identical within each of the 29 states that administer thetax for local governments. Even in the states that allow localadministration, local governments tend to follow the broad outlinesof the state tax bases. See Due and Mikesell, Sales Taxation: Stateand Local Structure and Administration, pp. 279-292.

22. Washington State Department of Revenue, Retailers’ Cost ofCollecting and Remitting Sales Tax (December 1998). For a discus-sion of the conceptual framework that the state used in measuringthe costs of tax compliance, see Bin Tran-Nam and others, “Tax

Compliance Costs: Research Methodology and Empirical Evidencefrom Australia,” National Tax Journal, vol. 53, no. 2 (2000),pp. 229-252.

23. Robert J. Cline and Thomas S. Neubig, Masters of Complexity andBearers of Great Burden: The Sales Tax System and Compliance Costsfor Multistate Retailers (Washington, D.C.: Ernst & Young,September 8, 1999).

24. See Lorrie Jo Brown, “Sales Tax Compliance Costs for E-TailersRevisited: A Critique of the Ernst and Young Study,” State TaxNotes, vol. 18, no. 4 (January 24, 2000), pp. 315-317.

Page 23: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 11

Current Efforts to Reduce Compliance CostsFederal legislation to permit states and local govern-ments to collect use taxes on remote sales would imposehigh compliance costs on remote sellers, costs thatwould tend to offset the gains in economic efficiencyfrom reducing distortion costs. However, states andlocal governments are working to lower those compli-ance costs, specifically through the Streamlined SalesTax Project (SSTP), set up in 2000. More than30 states have joined together to design a voluntarysales and use tax system. By encouraging businesses tovoluntarily collect use taxes, the project may help statesand local governments increase their revenue even inthe absence of federal legislation. The system is in-tended to demonstrate how tax simplification, theadoption of computer technology, and compensationcan reduce costs and thereby increase the likelihood ofCongressional action to require remote collection.

By November 2002, 34 states and the District of Co-lumbia had agreed on the administrative characteristicsof such a system and submitted the Streamlined Salesand Use Tax Agreement (SSUTA) to states for adop-tion by their legislatures and governors.25 The agree-ment was to go into effect for adopting states when itwas enacted by at least 10 states that together consti-tuted at least 20 percent of the total population of thestates imposing a sales tax. Both thresholds wereachieved by August 2003; at that point, 20 states hadenacted legislation that aligned their sales tax systemswith the provisions of the agreement.26 Most of thosechanges are to take effect by July 1, 2004.

The states adopting the SSUTA will now review eachstate’s law to ensure that it complies with the agree-

ment. Once the 10-state and 20-percent-populationthresholds have been verified, the agreement will gointo effect, and a governing board with one vote perstate will be established. That board, which will includeparticipation by businesses, will respond to questionsand resolve disputes, judge states’ compliance with theagreement, and consider amendments to it.

Under the SSUTA, remote sellers’ compliance costswould be reduced in several ways. The agreementwould lessen the complexity and diversity of the salestax structures faced by sellers by simplifying bases andrates and imposing uniform sourcing rules (for identi-fying the purchaser’s residence). It would require theuse of computer technology to simplify the process bywhich sales and use taxes are computed, remitted, andaudited. And it would require states to compensate re-mote sellers for many of the remaining compliancecosts.

Although states’ compensation of retailers’ costs forcollecting sales and use taxes would remove a principalobjection to requiring remote collection, compensationis not a substitute for the other two cost-reducing op-tions. Instead of diminishing the resources devoted tocollecting taxes that would result from improvementsin technology and simplification, compensation wouldshift those costs from retailers and consumers to thestate’s taxpayers. From a federal policy perspective,compensation would not reduce the social costs of taxa-tion.

Simplifying Sales Tax Bases and Rates and HandlingOther Administrative Matters. The SSUTA would sim-plify but not standardize the structures of the variousstates’ sales taxes, allowing considerable differences intax bases among but not within the states that imposesuch taxes. Under the system, the states would jointlydefine the items included in major categories of goodsand services (for example, food, clothing, automobiles,and service groups) that were subject to sales taxation,and each state would compose its base from amongthose categories. Local governments that levied salestaxes would have to use the same base as the state’s. Theresult would be a system that was currently limited to46 tax bases (assuming that all states with existing salestaxes plus the District of Columbia adopted it); the

25. The Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Agreement was adopted onNovember 12, 2002, and is available at www.geocities.com/streamlined2000/.

26. Three of the 20 adopting states have made changes in theagreement, which may cause them to be judged as not being inconformance with it. Texas and Washington would continue tohave vendors remit sales tax on local purchases to the jurisdictionof the origin of the sale rather than to the jurisdiction of theresidence of the purchaser. Minnesota has chosen an alternativedefinition for food. The population threshold would still be meteven if the three states were judged not to be in compliance.

Page 24: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

12 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

bases would differ by the sales categories they included,but for any given category, the items it covered wouldbe identical among all the states.

Under the terms of the SSUTA, all items in a state’s taxbase would be subject to the same sales tax rate—withthe exception of food and drugs, to which a differentrate (possibly zero) might apply. The agreement wouldpermit no more than one local rate, and all local salestaxes would be administered by the state. The SSUTAwould establish uniform rules for the frequency of taxfilings and for changes to tax bases and rates, andwould simplify the procedures by which purchaserscould obtain tax exemptions. It would also shift theresponsibility for validating those exemptions from theseller to the state. Furthermore, the agreement wouldimpose uniform sourcing rules that relied first on thedestination of the good—the purchaser’s location—which would be determined by using shipping in-structions or an address gleaned from the seller’s busi-ness records (including the address associated with thepurchaser’s payment instrument, such as a credit card).If that information was lacking, sourcing would revertto the origin of the good, determined by the addressfrom which tangible property was shipped or, in thecase of a digital good, the location at which it was firstavailable for transmission. (Box 1 discusses origin-basedversus destination-based sales taxes and the social costsof taxation.) Devising a reliable and simple system forsourcing digital goods remains a thorny issue for statesand local governments (see Box 2).

Simplifying the Process of Computing and RemittingTaxes. The very force that has increased uncollected usetax revenue from e-commerce—rapid technologicalgrowth in the computer industry—may also have cre-ated tools to reverse that trend. Software purchased byvendors or operated at off-site centralized computercenters could significantly reduce remote sellers’ costsof coping with the complexity of numerous tax bases,rates, and auditing procedures. Those programs coulddetermine, in real time (during the transaction), thesales tax status of a product on the basis of the state andlocal tax law in the purchaser’s jurisdiction. Informa-tion on the amount of the tax and the jurisdiction towhich it was to be remitted could be stored (again, onor off site) in an audit file set up for each remote seller.

Under the computer strategy spelled out in the SSUTA,remote sellers could choose to contract with a certifiedservice provider (CSP) that would handle all the seller’ssales and use tax functions, including filing all tax re-turns and being the focal point for audits. CSPs wouldbe certified by the states and would have to use a certi-fied automated system (CAS) for those functions. (Thestates would certify that the software met all require-ments for identifying the taxable status of the pur-chaser, the tax base and rate, the good’s source, andother necessary factors.) Remote sellers could also dealwith their sales and use taxes on their own, using aCAS. Alternatively, sellers with sales in at least fivestates and totaling a minimum of $500 million coulduse their own system for that task, provided that it hadbeen approved by the project’s member states.

Compensation. Simplifying tax structures and adoptingcomputer technology would each reduce compliancecosts to some degree, although estimates of those reduc-tions are not available.27 Regardless, under the SSUTA,some compensation would be provided for those costs.A CSP’s costs would be paid from the sales tax revenueit collected. In addition, the CSP would receive a bonuseach year for two years based on a percentage of the taxrevenue generated by a seller, with the expectation thatthe CSP would share that revenue with the seller as aninducement to participate in the system. Sellers whodecided to handle their own sales and use tax functionsby employing a CAS or proprietary software would re-ceive a percentage of the revenue collected for a periodof two years plus any compensation currently providedby the seller’s state. After two years, compensationwould come only from the seller’s state.

27. As of 1998, 26 of the 45 states levying sales taxes compensatedvendors at least to some degree for their compliance costs. Howthat compensation compares with actual compliance costs in moststates is not known; however, the state of Washington estimatedthat a large firm is compensated for 65 percent of its compliancecosts and a small firm, for 11 percent. See Washington StateDepartment of Revenue, Retailers’ Cost of Collecting and RemittingSales Tax (December 1998), pp. 39-40. The SSTP has begun astudy of the SSUTA’s potential for reducing compliance costs.

Page 25: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 13

Box 1.

Origin-Based Versus Destination-Based Sales Tax SystemsUse taxes on remote sales are difficult to collect be-cause sales and use tax systems are “destination based.”That is, a state imposes its tax on the basis of thedestination of the purchased item; if the purchaserresides in the state, the tax is incurred. By contrast, inan “origin-based” system, the tax is levied at the sourceor origin of the item being sold; if the seller is in thestate, the tax is incurred. Thus, under an origin-basedsales and use tax system, the difficulty of collectingtaxes on remote sales does not arise because remotesales are not taxable.

Some observers have argued that shifting to an origin-based system could improve sales tax compliance.1 Formerchants, the advantage of an origin-based system isthat retailers deal only with the sales tax system in thejurisdiction in which their firm is located. The advan-tage for states and local governments is that an origin-based system does not depend as heavily as a destina-tion-based system does on the voluntary complianceof individuals; under an origin-based framework, all

1. An origin-based system is discussed in Aaron Lukas, Tax Bytes:A Primer on the Taxation of Electronic Commerce (Washington,D.C.: Cato Institute, December 17, 1999), pp. 19-20; andWade Anderson and Andrew Wagner, “Guidelines forEstablishing an Origin-Based Sales Tax,” State Tax Notes,vol. 18, no. 12 (March 20, 2000), pp. 915-918. The articleby Anderson and Wagner suggests using an interstate revenue-sharing agreement to distribute the revenue collected inconformance with a destination-based tax.

the use taxes paid under a destination-based systemwould be collected as sales taxes by vendors whosebusinesses would all lie within the taxing jurisdiction.

The effect on states’ and local governments’ revenue ofmoving to an origin-based system would vary byjurisdiction. A jurisdiction would lose the revenuefrom remote sales to its residents but gain the revenuefrom sales by its merchants to out-of-state buyers. Asa result, implementing an origin-based system couldincrease interstate tax competition. Lower-tax stateswould have some advantage in attracting retailers whomarketed their goods and services in other, higher-taxstates. However, the net consequences for efficiency arenot clear. Tax competition could tend to reduce juris-dictions’ revenue from the sales tax relative to whatthey would derive from a destination-based system, anoutcome that would affect either the composition ofrevenue or the jurisdiction’s overall spending, or both.

Under an origin-based system, consumers could avoidsales taxes by buying from an out-of-state merchant.Merchants thus would have incentives to locate inplaces that allowed their customers to avoid the salestax. The overall economic efficiency that resultedwould depend on the efficiency of the sales tax relativeto the efficiency of the kind of tax that replaced anyreduction in sales tax revenue, and on the overall sizeof the public sector. How retailers reacted to thedifferences in taxes and how states and local govern-ments responded to retailers’ decisions about where tolocate their businesses would help determine an origin-based system’s impact in each state.

An industry monitoring group, the Council on StateTaxation (COST), has praised the SSUTA as a move inthe right direction.28 However, COST suggests that theagreement lacks enforcement provisions, is vague abouthow closely compensation would be tied to actual com-

pliance costs, and is missing a federal monitoring mecha-nism that should be incorporated before the authority torequire remote sellers to collect and remit use taxes isprovided by the Congress.

Other Economic Issues in theRemote Collection DebateBoth opponents and proponents of remote collection citeadditional economic considerations beyond distortion

28. Council on State Taxation, Report Card on the Streamlined SalesTax Implementing States’ Agreement (Washington, D.C.: Councilon State Taxation, October 11, 2002).

Page 26: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

14 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

Box 2.

Taxing Digital GoodsIf states are given the authority to require remote sellersto collect and remit use taxes, each sale must be“sourced”; that is, the seller must determine where thegood will be used. (Most often, in the case of a pur-chase by a consumer, that use will occur at the resi-dence of the buyer.) For tangible goods, sourcing is amanageable problem. The good must be shipped to alocation, which is a reasonable approximation of whereit will be used, and the opportunities for businesses andconsumers to behave in ways that minimize their taxesare not that great. A buyer located on the border of twostates with very different tax rates might be able to havethe purchase shipped to the lower-tax jurisdiction(using a post office box, for example, or the address ofa friend or relative) and not incur costs for transporta-tion that exceeded what he or she saved in taxes. Thattype of strategy would be particularly useful for expen-sive goods, but such opportunities are limited.

Digital goods are not subject to similar constraints. Forexample, Apple Music’s iTunes Music Store does notcollect use tax on its on-line sales of digitized music.Even if the sellers of such goods decided to collect it,buyers (particularly consumers, whose purchases are lesseasily tracked than businesses’ purchases) could con-

ceivably have the digital product “shipped” to a com-puter in any location and pay for the product with acredit card whose billing address listed a state withouta sales tax. Indeed, the possibility of avoiding a destina-tion-based tax on digital goods appears to be substan-tial. One approach proposed by the Streamlined Salesand Use Tax Agreement would be to revert to origin-based taxation (as described in Box 1, a tax assessed onthe basis of the seller’s location) in cases in which ashipping address and the customer’s financial informa-tion were not adequate to to determine the customer’sresidence for a transaction. Of course, the digital natureof the goods makes it entirely possible that the identifi-able seller’s location may be chosen to minimize salesand use taxation.

The taxing of digital goods thus presents difficulties,and no technical solution grounded in current technol-ogies appears to be imminent. As a result, requiringremote sellers to collect and remit use taxes is likely togenerate less revenue from digital goods than manypeople expect. To the extent that taxes on such goodswere avoided or minimized, the gains and losses in ef-ficiency discussed in this analysis would be moderated.

costs and administrative and compliance costs in theirarguments—in particular, network externalities, the sizeof government, horizontal and vertical equity, unfairtaxation of remote sellers, and states’ fiscal autonomy. Ingeneral, however, reflection suggests that those issues areless central to the debate over remote collection of usetaxes than are social costs.

Network Externalities and Market FailuresOne argument advanced by opponents of remote collec-tion is that excluding Internet sales from taxation pro-vides a desirable stimulus to the growth of the Internetand e-commerce. Underlying that contention is thenotion that the Internet is characterized by “externalities”that cause too few people to become part of the networkand that leave it at less than its desirable (that is, efficient)size. Such a contention is consistent with economictheory but does not appear to be consistent with people’s

current use of the Internet. More than 136 million of the241 million people in the United States above the age ofeight (56 percent) used the Internet in 2001.29 Thatdegree of use suggests that the Internet and e-commercehave probably expanded beyond the network’s critical-mass phase (see the discussion below).

Externalities occur when a transaction imposes economiceffects on third parties that are not reflected in the priceestablished between the buyer and seller of a good. Nottaking those effects into account leads to the incorrectamount of the good being bought and sold—or, moreaccurately, to the incorrect amount of the external effect

29. See Department of Commerce, A Nation Online: How AmericansAre Expanding Their Use of the Internet (February 2002), Table 2-2,p. 26.

Page 27: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 15

being provided. If there are positive externalities, anincentive that reduces the price of a good by an amountequal to the external benefit that society receives from thetransaction will increase output to a level that morenearly reflects both the benefits received by privatecitizens (the buyers and sellers) and the external benefitsreceived by all citizens. In that case, the market’s failureto take all benefits into account would be corrected.

In the context of taxing purchases made over theInternet, opponents of such taxes have cited “networkexternalities” as part of the rationale for their position.30

The Internet is, of course, a communications networkand, like all such structures, tends to be characterizedby network externalities; that is, when a person joins anetwork, he or she receives benefits from being able tocommunicate with its other members. If the network’sservices are provided competitively, the price that a newmember pays accurately reflects the value of those bene-fits. But the other members of the network each receivea benefit as well—that of being able to communicatewith the new participant. Because potential membersdo not take those network (external) benefits into ac-count when deciding whether or not to join, the possi-bility arises that too few people will participate and thenetwork will be too small. The market in that case is in-efficient because the benefits derived from adding moremembers to the network still exceed the cost of the re-sources that would be expended to add them. Oppo-nents of requiring remote sellers to collect use taxes ar-gue that exempting e-commerce from that collectionresponsibility is desirable because it acts as an incentivethat can help correct that inefficiency.

Any economic advantage from providing a tax-basedsubsidy, or preference (in this instance, the “preferen-tial” treatment of not collecting use taxes), to e-com-

merce sales depends, among other things, on the extentof the network’s development relative to its optimalsize.31 No network can exist until the price of joining itfalls to a level that induces a critical mass of people topurchase the network’s services. Those initial partici-pants tend to be “high-demand individuals” who notonly value the services highly but whose intense interestin the technological wizardry of the new network makesthem provide high levels of benefits (in the form of ad-vice and troubleshooting) to the network’s other partic-ipants. As costs continue to fall over time, people withsuccessively less demand for network services and pos-sessing less technological expertise are induced to join.Those new entrants generate ever-smaller benefits forother participants, for two reasons.

First, the probability that existing network memberswill communicate with one more entrant decreases;even if each new member is just as technically compe-tent as those who came before, the new entrant’s valueas a communications partner falls because so many oth-ers are already available. Second, the new entrant’s de-creased technological ability relative to previous en-trants makes him or her less valuable as a source of ad-vice. A network reaches an economically efficient sizewhen the cost of joining exceeds the value placed onparticipating in the network by those who have yet tojoin. Those always-potential entrants would have pro-vided relatively few benefits to other participants—andthey might have imposed costs in the form of conges-tion on a network that had become stable in size.

An incentive during the early stages of the Internet’sdevelopment and the rise of e-commerce could argu-ably have increased economic efficiency. But perma-nently exempting e-commerce from sales taxation whenmore than 50 percent of the population who conceiv-ably might use the Internet already does so risks provid-ing an incentive in exchange for few or no offsettingexternal benefits, thereby increasing rather than reduc-30. The discussion here concentrates on direct network externalities;

also relevant but not discussed are indirect network externalitiesand learning network externalities. The reasoning behind thediscussion of direct network externalities is basically identical tothat underlying the others. See George R. Zodrow, “NetworkExternalities and Indirect Tax Preferences for Electronic Com-merce,” International Tax and Public Finance, vol. 10, no. 1 (2003),pp. 79-97. Zodrow concludes that network externalities provideno justification for not taxing remote sales.

31. The time path is discussed in Nicholas Economides, “TheEconomics of Networks,” International Journal of IndustrialOrganization, vol. 14, no. 6 (1996), pp. 673-699; and Zodrow,“Network Externalities.”

Page 28: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

16 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

ing a distortion.32 Even if external benefits from newentrants remained significant, the object of an incentivewould be to stimulate the growth of the network, notof e-commerce per se.33

Opponents of remote collection proffer another argu-ment to support their position: that it is not the size ofthe network that needs to be subsidized but rather thee-commerce business model. In effect, the argumenthere is that e-commerce is an infant industry and needsto be subsidized to enable it to compete with traditionalforms of commerce until its scale increases to a size thatallows its production costs to decline enough to make itcompetitive. Yet the industry’s sales exceeded $1 trillionin 2001 (including both business-to-business andbusiness-to-consumer sales), and more and more so-called bricks-and-mortar firms are expanding their useof e-commerce to complement their traditional modeof selling. The e-commerce model thus hardly seemsendangered. Furthermore, a standard problem withsubsidizing an infant industry is knowing when toeliminate the subsidy. Unless a clearly articulated casecan be made for the future benefits that will be offeredby a mature industry, the passage of time becomes anargument for eliminating the subsidy, whether or notthe industry is competitive. (If the industry is not com-petitive, then subsidization was not successful; if it is,then subsidization was successful but is no longer nec-essary.)

The Size of the Public SectorThe basic principles of efficiency and neutral taxationthat guide tax policy partly depend on the propositionthat the size of the government is independent of deci-sions about how to collect taxes—that is, overall gov-

ernment spending is constant. But that is not necessar-ily the case if the difficulty or ease of collecting taxesinfluences the size of the public sector. Public-sectorgoods and services—the output of government—arelike other goods and services. The incentives to providethem can become distorted, resulting in the productionof too many or too few goods and services and, as aconsequence, a reduction in economic well-being.Some analysts suggest that the incentives confrontingelected officials and bureaucrats cause the political pro-cess to provide more public services than taxpayers de-sire.34 If that depiction accurately describes the func-tioning of governments, a dollar that was reallocatedfrom the private to the public sector would generatepublic consumption whose value was less than the valueof the private consumption that it replaced. That out-come would mean a loss of economic well-being forsociety, even if it were possible to collect taxes withoutimposing efficiency costs.

Some opponents of requiring remote sellers to collectuse taxes argue that it might lead to a larger public sec-tor and a loss of economic well-being. Their argumentis essentially that the cost of collecting taxes influenceshow much in total taxes will be collected and thereforehow big the government will be (or how much inpublic-sector goods the government will provide). Theissue of collecting use taxes from remote sellers is rele-vant to the total cost of collecting taxes and the publicsector’s size in two ways.

First, the difficulty of getting purchasers to complywith the use tax on remote sales raises the cost of col-lecting sales taxes. It raises that cost directly, throughthe administrative costs associated with collecting taxes

32. In fact, the Internet in its infancy did receive an incentive. But thesubsidy was not given directly to users; it took the form of federalfinancing for development of the giant supercomputers that actas the highway for the Internet. That subsidization reduced coststo a level that enabled a critical mass of high demanders to starta network.

33. Users of the Internet receive an incentive if they use a telephoneline to connect to it because the price of local phone access issubsidized. See Robert W. Crandall and Leonard Waverman, WhoPays for Universal Service? When Telephone Subsidies BecomeTransparent (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press,2000), p. 157.

34. Those relationships are developed in Geoffrey Brennan and JamesBuchanan, The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a FixedConstitution (Cambridge, England, and New York: CambridgeUniversity Press, 1980), and have come to be referred to as the“Leviathan” model. An overview of the public-choice theory andliterature and its relationship to tax policy appears in a three-article“Symposium on Public Choice” in the National Tax Journal(vol. 51, no. 2, 1998). See, specifically, Randall G. Holcombe, “TaxPolicy from a Public Choice Perspective,” pp. 359-371; Stanley L.Winer and Walter Hettich, “What Is Missed If We Leave OutCollective Choice in the Analysis of Taxation?” pp. 373-389; andJames M. Poterba, “Public Finance and Public Choice,” pp. 391-396.

Page 29: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 17

on remote sales, and indirectly, through higher tax rateson other tax bases (to finance the government’s spend-ing decisions) and therefore through the economic effi-ciency costs that must be imposed to garner a givenlevel of receipts. As those costs mount, states and localgovernments may find it difficult to raise as much reve-nue as they could have otherwise, and their growth maybe constrained.

Thus, rapid growth in the share of remote sales makesthe sales tax less and less effective in generating revenue.From the perspective of overall efficiency, the very factthat effectively exempting some activities from taxationcauses inefficiency could be an advantage if it kept thegovernment from spending more resources on less-valuable output from the public sector. That view cor-responds to the notion that it is worth imposing someefficiency costs in order to create incentives to reduceother efficiency costs. Which inefficiency effect waslarger would depend on how state and local officialsresponded to increased revenue from a use tax, as wellas on whether an inherent bias toward a larger-than-optimal public sector really exists in the first place.

In sum, both opponents and proponents of remotesales tax collection may agree that e-commerce is signif-icantly increasing uncollected revenue from use taxesand making it more costly—in terms of economic effi-ciency—to raise a given amount of revenue. Propo-nents of remote collection focus on that inefficiency asharmful, whereas opponents who argue that the publicsector is too large regard that same inefficiency as bene-ficial because it creates incentives that help reduce an-other form of inefficiency.

A second way in which mandated collection of usetaxes is relevant to the issue of the public sector’s size isthat it may reduce fiscal competition in which statesessentially use lower taxes to bid for taxpayers.35 Be-cause states and local governments can have differenttax systems, they can compete to attract economic ac-tivity. That competition raises the cost of collectingrevenue by imposing a penalty on jurisdictions that levy

higher taxes than their neighbors do—a penalty thattakes the form of lost tax base and less tax revenue asretailers move their activities to lower-tax states.

The findings of the literature on tax competition areambiguous.36 Clearly, if the move to simplify sales anduse taxes meant pushing states to impose the samerates, it would undoubtedly reduce the potential scopeof interstate tax competition. But the thrust of currentsimplification efforts is to require states to have simi-larly defined bases, leaving jurisdictions free to competeon the basis of rates. The SSUTA is directed at basesbecause the greatest concerns about compliance costshave focused on multiple and divergent bases and basedefinitions.37

To summarize, remote collection could influence thesize of the public sector by reducing the cost of collect-ing taxes. However, if the authority to collect use taxeswas granted to the states, other means of constrainingthe public sector’s size would still be available throughthe political process. Competition could also proceedon the basis of other taxes, such as those on income andproperty, and explicit fiscal restraints could be adoptedto produce lower levels of spending or taxes. Such re-straints include enacting more-effective balanced bud-get requirements, limiting taxes or spending (or both),requiring supermajorities for the enactment of tax in-

35. See Aaron Lukas, Tax Bytes: A Primer on the Taxation of ElectronicCommerce (Washington, D.C.: Cato Institute, December 17,1999), pp. 10-11.

36. The effect of fiscal centralization (and tax competition) on the sizeof state and local governments has been a subject of considerableempirical interest. A series of articles on the topic appeared in theAmerican Economic Review: see Wallace E. Oates, “Searching forLeviathan: An Empirical Study,” vol. 75, no. 4 (1985), pp. 748-757; and Jeffrey S. Zax, “Is There a Leviathan in YourNeighborhood?”; Kevin F. Forbes and Ernest M. Zampelli, “IsLeviathan a Mythical Beast?”; and Wallace E. Oates, “Searchingfor Leviathan: A Reply and Some Further Reflections,” all invol. 79, no. 3 (1989), pp. 560-583.

37. Cline and Neubig, Masters of Complexity and Bearers of GreatBurden, pp. 9-10. The authors illustrate that complexity withflowcharts of the tax status of nine types of groceries and11 categories of shoes in a sampling of states.

Page 30: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

18 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

creases, and instituting voter referenda for bond is-sues.38

International ConsiderationsRemote sales include not only purchases from mer-chants in other states but also purchases from sellers inother countries. A concern raised by opponents of re-mote collection is that if remote sellers are required tocollect use taxes, they will lose business to foreign sellersthat are beyond the reach of states’ taxing authorities.Parties interested in the issue of remote collection havecalled on policymakers to ensure that any alteration incollection authority takes into account the need to ex-pand the approach to an international context.

To the extent that foreign sellers gain an advantage overU.S. retailers because use taxes cannot be collected ontheir sales, virtually all the same economic issues thatare part of the current domestic debate are raised. Theeffective exemption of purchases abroad would tend togenerate additional uncollected use taxes and reduceeconomic efficiency.

The prospect of international sales generating theseproblems raises questions about the degree to whichthey can be resolved by remote collection within theUnited States. Essentially, international sales provide apossible venue for avoiding the use tax, even if states aregranted the authority to collect it from remote sellers,because that authority might not extend to vendorsabroad.

The amount of uncollected use taxes that might be gen-erated by buying from foreign firms is difficult to as-sess. For many goods, the shipping costs from suchgreat distances will exceed the avoided sales taxes. Butin the case of digital goods moving over the Internet,shipping would not be a factor. The other aspect of theissue is the states’ inability to influence the cost of col-

lecting use taxes from abroad. Those costs depend ontreaties, which are negotiated by the federal govern-ment.

Worth noting, however, is the European Union’s(EU’s) treatment of sales of digital goods. Specifically,on July 1, 2003, the EU imposed on non-EU remotesellers a more costly compliance system for collectingand remitting the value-added tax (VAT) on digitalgoods than it imposes on EU remote sellers. A remoteseller established within the EU collects and remits theVAT under an origin-based system, thus treating theseller as a U.S. state treats a local seller. U.S. remotesellers who have established a company within the EUare entitled to be treated as an EU company; those whohave not done so must collect the VAT on the basis of acustomer’s residence and remit the tax to one EUmember state, which then distributes the revenueamong the other EU states. (As an alternative, a remoteseller can register separately with each EU country andcomply with each country’s national VAT legislation.)At this point, the EU appears to be relying on volun-tary compliance for enforcement.

Remote Collection and FairnessBoth opponents and proponents of remote collectionhave raised the issue of fairness in the debate overwhether to grant states that authority. Opponents arguethat it is unfair to require merchants to pay taxes tostates from which they receive no benefits. Proponentscontend that to exempt out-of-jurisdiction sales fromuse taxes favors people who are economically better offand who are more likely to have Internet access, andtreats otherwise equivalent consumers differently on thebasis of the means by which they purchase identicalgoods.

Those arguments derive from two distinct perspectiveson fairness, or tax equity. One view calls for distribut-ing the tax burden according to each taxpayer’s abilityto pay; the other would distribute the tax burden ac-cording to the benefits each taxpayer received. Any dis-cussion of fairness that focuses on a single tax inevitablysuffers from considering that tax in isolation, sincewhatever one’s standard for fairness may be, it mustultimately be applied to the distribution of the burdenfrom all taxes.

38. Therese J. McGuire, in “Proposition 13 and Its Offspring: ForGood or for Evil?” National Tax Journal, vol. 52, no. 1 (1999),pp. 129-138, reviews the literature on property tax limitations andfinds that they have been effective in changing fiscal decisions.James M. Poterba, in “Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Policy:Evidence from the States,” National Tax Journal, vol. 48, no. 3(1995), pp. 329-336, reviews the literature on state balanced budgetrules, which appear to affect public spending.

Page 31: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 19

The Ability-to-Pay Principle. The equity principlebased on a taxpayer’s ability to pay breaks down furtherinto two dimensions: horizontal and vertical equity.Horizontal equity is the standard that people in equalcircumstances should be taxed equally. Vertical equitysays that people in better circumstances—usually mea-sured in terms of income—should be taxed moreheavily than those whose situations are less advanta-geous. Both concepts represent value judgments abouthow taxes should be levied. As a result, one cannot eval-uate the effect that the violation of those equity normshas on economic well-being as one can evaluate the ef-fect of violating the efficiency standard.

A mechanical application of the horizontal equity prin-ciple suggests that Internet sales should be treated thesame way that non-Internet sales are treated—either byeliminating the sales tax, enforcing the use tax, or hav-ing remote sellers collect the use tax. Otherwise, twoconsumers who purchase the same items, one on-lineand one from bricks-and-mortar establishments, aretreated differently. Yet the proper measurement of hori-zontal equity is problematic. By definition, if both con-sumers have equal access to the Internet, they arechoosing to not purchase the same “bundle” of goodsand services. Presumably, each consumer has reasonsfor his or her choice of shopping arrangements, leadingtheir equivalent situations to produce different out-comes. Whether horizontal equity, properly measured,is violated is not immediately obvious.

Vertical equity expresses society’s value judgmentsabout how people in unequal circumstances should betaxed, and it is usually measured in terms of the distri-bution of the tax burden among income groups. A re-gressive tax extracts more tax—as a proportion of cur-rent income—from lower-income taxpayers than fromhigher-income ones. A progressive tax takes moretaxes—as a proportion of current income—as incomerises.

Access to computers (whether at home, school, work,or the library) and the Internet is directly related to in-come. Proponents of requiring remote sellers to collectuse taxes argue that not collecting taxes benefits peoplewho are better off and makes the sales tax more regres-sive. In 1997, 9.2 percent of individuals with family

income below $15,000 used the Internet, comparedwith 44.5 percent of those with income exceeding$75,000. However, over the next several years, Internetuse grew among people in all income groups; in 2001,it was 25 percent and 78.9 percent, respectively, forthose in the lowest and highest income categories. Be-cause the rate of growth of Internet use has been higherfor people in the lower-income groups, access to theInternet is becoming more evenly distributed overtime.39

Some observers believe that the issue of vertical equityin remote sales taxation goes beyond the ownership anduse of computers and the Internet. Purchases over theInternet (as well as over the phone) often require creditcards. If lower-income groups have limited access tothose payment media, some vertical inequity from nottaxing remote sales might persist unless cash on deliverybecame a generally available payment option.

There are several other ways to overcome such inequityif lower-income groups continue to find themselveslimited in their access to the Internet for retail pur-chases or if the types of goods they generally buy arenot sold on the Internet. Policymakers could fashionother tax policies to achieve the desired after-tax distri-bution of income—for example, by adjusting the struc-ture of state income tax rates or providing income-tested refundable sales tax credits for the state incometax.40

The Benefit Principle. The benefit principle of equityin taxation requires that the tax burden be distributedin accordance with the benefits each taxpayer receives

39. Department of Commerce, A Nation Online, Table 2-2, p. 26. Thecoefficient of inequality in Internet use by income category hasdeclined substantially, from .309 in 1998 to .270 in 2001. (Acoefficient of zero would indicate that each income group’sproportion of Internet users was identical to its proportion of allfamily income.) See Table 9-1, p. 89.

40. In the executive summary of its report, the Advisory Commissionon Electronic Commerce suggested a less direct and less reliableapproach to compensation. The commission recommended in itsmajority proposals that surpluses in the Temporary Assistance forNeedy Families fund be spent “to provide needy families accessto computers and the Internet, and to provide training in computersand Internet use” (p. 4).

Page 32: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

20 ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES

from public spending. Some opponents of requiringremote sellers to collect use taxes argue that in-state sell-ers that collect sales tax revenue receive benefits in theform of public services in exchange for collecting thetax. In contrast, if remote sellers were required to col-lect and remit use taxes to another state, they would notbe compensated with such benefits.41 Thus, opponentsargue, taxing e-commerce would be inconsistent withthe benefit principle of taxation.

The equity of a tax on retail sales is not usually evalu-ated on the basis of the benefit principle, for two rea-sons. First, the benefit principle is generally applied tothe financing of spending programs whose beneficiariesare an identifiable subset of the population—for exam-ple, airports that are financed through taxes assessed oneach airline ticket. Second, governments usually assessthe tax on those identifiable beneficiaries as a functionof their use of the service—hence the tax’s commonname of “user charge.” Sales tax revenue fits neither ofthose circumstances. Many of the programs it financesprovide mostly collective consumption (that is, of pub-lic services) that benefits everybody rather than an iden-tifiable subset of the population. In addition, the salestaxes a person pays are related to his or her consump-tion of private, not public, services.

The concern of opponents to remote-seller tax collec-tion is not relevant to the tax itself but rather to the lackof compensation for the compliance costs that sellersincur in their role as collection agents. Many states ei-ther do not compensate retailers for those costs or com-pensate them inadequately, in effect shifting part of thesocial costs of taxation to retailers who may be unablein turn to shift their compliance costs to consumers inthe form of higher prices. Some observers might be lessconcerned about the lack of compensation for local sell-ers, who receive some public service benefits, than forremote sellers, who do not—although that concernmay find no abatement if local sellers are paying forthose benefits through other business taxes.

Fiscal Autonomy of States and Local GovernmentsA final concern raised by opponents of remote collec-tion arises less from the task itself than from compro-mises associated with the process’s simplification,which are necessary for remote collection authority tobe granted. They argue that the fiscal autonomy ofstates and local governments will be diminished by thechanges in the tax system that may be required to ob-tain that authority.

The federal system of government gives almost totalfreedom to states and local governments to determinetheir tax systems. The only major constraint on thatautonomy is that state and local taxes may not impedeinterstate commerce, which generally means that taxesmust not discriminate according to a taxpayer’s state ofresidence or a good’s place of production. A state maynot impose an import tariff on clothing, for example,but it can impose an excise tax that applies uniformlyto sales of clothing within the state—whether the cloth-ing is produced by in-state or out-of-state firms.

State and local governments have chosen to structuretheir general sales and use taxes to conform to a varietyof policy objectives and voter preferences. Some gov-ernments make a considerable effort to exclude itemsfrom the tax base to distribute the burden of sales anduse taxes in a particular way (usually to soften their im-pact on lower-income groups); other jurisdictionschoose to use a broader tax base and achieve distribu-tional objectives through the structure of the incometax. Some states include a considerable amount ofbusiness-to-business sales in the base. Some include avariety of services. And some governments compensatesellers for at least a portion of the costs they incur ascollection agents.

The issue before the Congress is whether to grant stateand local governments the authority to require remotesellers to collect use taxes. As discussed earlier, that au-thority might impose substantial compliance costs onremote sellers. If applying enhanced computer technol-ogy to the process of collecting taxes cannot by itselfreduce those costs to a level acceptable to the Congress,then resolution of the issue of whether to collect usetaxes on Internet sales may require states and local gov-ernments to simplify their sales tax bases or rates (or

41. “When a business . . . remits sales taxes to the state in which it islocated, there is a plausible linkage among the taxes paid, theservices provided, and legislative representation . . . [t]he remoteseller does not benefit from most of the services that distant stateor those local governments provide” (Lukas, Tax Bytes, p. 13).

Page 33: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES 21

both)—that is, essentially give up some of their fiscalautonomy.

Opponents of e-commerce taxation argue that the fed-eral government will compromise that autonomy if itspecifies the changes in tax structure to be made (toreduce compliance costs) in exchange for the authorityeffectively to collect taxes on remote sales.42 Much ofthat concern focuses on the political and social conse-quences that might result from rearranging the delicatebalance of power that now exists between the federaland state and local levels of government. However,states that have voluntarily embraced such a solutionare willing to trade reduced fiscal autonomy for the au-thority to require remote collection.

Fiscal autonomy is not just a roadblock to those favor-ing the requirement for remote-seller tax collection.The current moratorium on new Internet access taxesalso diminishes fiscal autonomy, as would the proposalput forward by the Advisory Commission on ElectronicCommerce (but not adopted in the renewal of theInternet Tax Freedom Act), which calls for states toexempt from sales taxation the intrastate sale of digitalproducts (for example, music) and their tangible coun-terparts (CDs).

In the end, economic analysis can do little to evaluatetrade-offs involving fiscal autonomy. It remains forstate and local policymakers to judge the costs of trad-ing that autonomy for the potential benefits identifiedin the preceding discussion of economic effects. And itis left to federal policymakers to judge whether thechanges states make to obtain those benefits satisfy theirconcerns about compliance costs.

42. See Adam Thierer, The Governors’ Misguided Plan to Tax theInternet and Create a New National Sales Tax, Heritage FoundationBackgrounder (Washington, D.C.: Heritage Foundation, January 3,2000), p. 12.

Page 34: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should
Page 35: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should
Page 36: Economic Issues in Taxing Internet and Mail-Order Sales...ECONOMIC ISSUES IN TAXING INTERNET AND MAIL-ORDER SALES ix Both arguments represent value judgments about how taxes should

This publication and others by CBOare available at the agency's Web site:

www.cbo.gov


Recommended