+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development

Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development

Date post: 09-Jan-2016
Category:
Upload: werner
View: 39 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development. Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. Spring 2000-2001 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Popular Tags:
38
Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department of Economics Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. Spring 2000-2001 Email: [email protected]; WebPages: http://www.stanford.edu/~ljlau
Transcript
Page 1: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Economics 216:The Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.)Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development

Department of EconomicsStanford University

Stanford, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A.

Spring 2000-2001

Email: [email protected]; WebPages: http://www.stanford.edu/~ljlau

Page 2: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lecture 9The Role of Money and Finance

Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.)Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development

Department of EconomicsStanford University

Stanford, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A.

Spring 2000-2001

Email: [email protected]; WebPages: http://www.stanford.edu/~ljlau

Page 3: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

3

Why is Money Desirable?Money as a Facilitator of Transactions It lowers transactions cost (and hence makes possible productive

transactions that otherwise may not have taken place in the absence of an accepted medium of exchange)A common unit of account--a common numeraire Non-coincidence (lack of synchronization) of supply and demand—barters,

and successive barters, can only take place at a single time and place (e.g. Samuelson’s “exact consumption loan” model)

The effect of credit-worthiness and risk--lack of mutual trust requires cash on delivery (a future delivery on barter is risky)

The benefits and costs of anonymity (non-discrimination; illegal activities, the cash-in-advance constraint)

Private versus public issuance of money Currency substitution and the network externality--the more a form

of money is accepted, the more it is acceptable

Page 4: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

4

The Different Definitions of Money M0 = currency and coins in circulation M1 = M0 + demand deposits M2 = M1 + savings deposits The distinction between demand deposits and savings deposits has

become blurred in the United States (interest and non-interest bearing, withdrawal notice and penalty, money market funds at non-banking institutions)

Page 5: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

5

The Demand for Money Three traditional sources of demand for money (M1)

Transactions Demand Precautionary Demand Speculative Demand

Page 6: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

6

Transactions Demand (1) The types of market transactions requiring money balances

The monetization of previously non-market transactions (barter, home consumption, home services, in kind payments of rents and wages)

Inter-firm transactions (market) versus intra-firm transactions (non-market)--the organization of the economy (the degree of vertical integration; the degree of concentration (conglomerates), the degree of specialization and division of labor, the degree of self-sufficiency)

Transactions involving goods and services currently produced (thus generating current-value added) and transactions involving existing physical assets and inventories (which do not generate current value-added)

Real transactions versus financial transactions--purchases and sales of business assets versus purchases and sales of shares of common stock (securitization facilitates the trading of assets and hence increases the volume of transactions (reduces lumpiness and enhances liquidity)

The multiplier effect of financial transactions (financial deepening)--mutual funds, derivatives, holding companies

The volume of trade in existing assets, real or financial, depends on the level of wealth rather than the level of real GNP or GDP

Page 7: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

7

Transactions Demand (2) The role of institutions, customs and practices

(e.g., the frequency of settlement (a higher frequency requires more money, other things being equal), the use of credit and debit cards (increases the GDP/Money Supply ratio), the use of sweep accounts (increases the GDP/Money Supply ratio), the demand for money under central planning)

The cost of holding money for transactions purposes is the time value of money (the real rate of interest)

Page 8: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

8

The Quantity Theory of Money (Friedman):MV = PT For the four variables, only M and P can be directly observed V cannot be directly observed, but is measured as PT/V T actually stands for the total real volume of transactions in the

economy but in general cannot be directly observed either T is frequently identified with real GDP (value added), Y and is

typically assumed to be proportional to Y (real GDP), T=Y, where t is a constant

The velocity of money, defined as V=PT/M, is in general assumed to be an increasing function of the real rate of interest (the velocity is so-to-speak “the number of times money needs to change hands in order to support the given volume of transactions”)

V is in general not constant, even with the rate of real interest constant—V tends to rise with innovations in finance and transactions technology; e.g., a shift from the use of cash or checks to credit cards and debit cards reduces the money balances required to support a given volume of transactions and hence increases V

Page 9: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

9

The Measurement of the Velocity of Money V as defined cannot be measured because T is not directly observed Instead, one can define an alternative velocity variable V*=PY/M in terms of observable

variables, which is referred to as velocity* V*= PT/M x Y/T = V x Y/T = V/ The variable =T/Y the ratio of the total real volume of all transactions T to real GDP Y

is not a constant but changes over time The volume of transactions relative to real GDP (T/Y) tends to rise in the process of economic

development T/Y also rises with financial deepening T/Y rises with rising volume of trade with the same trade surplus/deficit

For most developing economies, especially in the early stages of their economic development, T is likely to rise much faster than Y, and hence is increasing over time; for developed economies, is likely to be more stable .

Since both V and tend to rise over time and with economic development and growth—what is likely to happen to V*?

At the beginning phase of economic development, V, which depends on financial and technological innovation, is likely to increase very slowly, whereas is likely to increase quite rapidly, leading to a fall in V*; as an economy matures, Increases in V become much more important, and becomes relatively more stable, and V* is likely to rise

Page 10: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

10

The Velocity of Money:China and the United States of America

The Velocity of Money, China and U.S.A.(International Monetary Fund Data)

-0.5

0.5

1.5

2.5

3.5

4.5

5.5

6.5

7.5

8.5

1959 1962 1965 1968 1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998

Year

GD

P/M

on

ey

GDP/M1 China

GDP/M2 China

GDP/M1 US

GDP/M2 US

Page 11: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

11

The Implications of the Quantity Equation of Money: MV* = PY

Differentiating the quantity equation with respect to t, we obtain:

dM dV* dP dTV* M T P . Dividing both sides by MV, we obtain:

dt dt dt dtdM dV* dP dT dY dT

/M /V* /P /T. Substituting /Y for /T, dt dt dt dt dt dt

and

rearranging, we obtain:

dP dM dV* dY/P /M /V*- /Y. In other words, the rate of inflation

dt dt dt dtmay be written as difference of the rate of growth of the money supply

and the rate of growth of real o

utput, assuming that the velocity* of money

remains constant.

Page 12: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

12

The Rate of Change of Velocity*

V* = V/τ;

dV* dV dτ dV dτThus, /V* /V - /τ. Both /V and /τ are likely to be

dt dt dt dt dtpositive so that the rate of change of velocity* is likely to be indeterminate

in sign. However, the presumption is tha

dV*t for developed economies, /V*

dtdV*

is likely to be positive and for developing economies, /V* is likely to bedt

negative. Thus, in developed economies, if the rate of growth of the money

supply exceeds the rate of growth of real GDP, there is likely to be inflation,

whereas in developing economies, the rate of growth of money supply can

exceed the rate of growth of real GDP significantly without necessarily

causing inflation.

Page 13: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

13

The Usefulness of the Quantity Equation of Money: MV* = PY The usefulness of the quantity equation of money is greatly

diminished if the velocity* of circulation of money is variable For most developing countries, especially those without a history of

high or hyper-inflation, the rate of growth of money supply can be significantly higher than the rate of growth of real GDP without necessarily causing additional inflation

This is because the velocity* of money, defined as PY/M, has, on the whole, been declining (a given level of real GDP requires more money balances to support over time)

Page 14: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

14

The Velocity of Money andReal GDP per Capita

Velocity of Money and Quasi-Money

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

14.0

10.0 100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per capita

GD

P/M

oney

Sup

ply

Page 15: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

15

The Rate of Growth of Money Supply andReal GDP per Capita

Average Annual Rate of Growth of Money Supply, 1985-1995

0.1

1.0

10.0

100.0

1,000.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cent

per

ann

um

Page 16: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

16

The Rate of Inflation andReal GDP per Capita

Average Annual Rate of Inflation, 1985-1995

0.1

1.0

10.0

100.0

1000.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cent

per

ann

um

Page 17: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

17

Precautionary Demand Availability of social (or even private) insurance (e.g., retirement,

survivor, health care, unemployment, inflation)--degree of completeness of markets

Availability of credit (households and firms) The time value of money (the rate of interest)

Page 18: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

18

Speculative Demand Money balances maintained for the exploitation of unexpected

opportunities The time value of money (the rate of interest)

Page 19: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

19

The Degree of Monetization andGrowth of Real GDP The degree of monetization increases with economic development Measured GDP may grow faster than true GDP especially at the

early stage of economic development Examples

Marketization of barter transactions Marketization of household work Growth of financial transactions--financial deepening

Page 20: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

20

Seigniorage and Inflation Tax The central bank (or private banks) issuing the currency in

circulation has seigniorage to the extent that money balances are held solely for the purpose of transactions or as a store of value

In developing economies, inflation is sometimes deliberately used as an instrument of taxation

Page 21: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

21

The Role of Finance (Credit) as a Facilitator of Transactions The “Cash-in-Advance” Constraint There are transactions that would not have taken place in the absence

of finance or credit, formal or informal Asymmetric information between savers and entrepreneurs/investors Transfer of risks from savers and producers to financiers (e.g. letter of credit) Economies of scale

Maturity transformation Pooling of resources (lumpiness of investments) Pooling of risks across borrowers Transaction costs Specialization in information acquisition and monitoring Amelioration of exchange rate risk

Lack of alternative investment instruments for savers

Page 22: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

22

Explicit or Implicit Deposit Insurance Enhances confidence in and hence stability of the financial system Reduces the probability of bank failure due to illiquidity as opposed to

insolvency Reduces the spillover (contagion) effect of bank failure Levels the playing field between large and small banks (a large number

of small banks is not as efficient as a small number of large banks because of the intrinsic economies of scale in banking; however, the political economy may favor a large number of small banks)

Encourages moral hazard on the part of both depositors and owners of financial institutions

Prudential regulation and supervision are therefore required A high reserve ratio as a substitute for ineffective prudential regulation

and supervision

Page 23: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

23

Moral Hazard and Financial Institutions The capital requirements (e.g., the Bank for International Settlement

(BIS) standard of 8%) are generally too low to discourage moral hazard on the part of the owners of the financial institutions

Government-directed credit and the doctrine of “too big to fail” encourage moral hazard on the part of the borrowers (as well as lenders)

Explicit or implicit deposit insurance encourage moral hazard on the part of savers and depositors in their choices of depository institutions for their deposits

Informal credit markets (the lack of anonymity which limits moral hazard) Mutual credit associations Grameen banks

Page 24: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

24

The Rate of Interest on Savings Deposits and Real GDP per Capita

The Deposit Rate and Real GDP per Capita

0.1

1.0

10.0

100.0

1000.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cen

t p

er a

nn

um

Page 25: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

25

The Rate of Interest on Loans and Real GDP per Capita

The Lending Rate and Real GDP per Capita

0.1

1.0

10.0

100.0

1000.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cen

t p

er a

nn

um

Page 26: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

26

The Interest Rate Spread andReal GDP per Capita

The Interest Rate Spread, 1995

0.1

1.0

10.0

100.0

1000.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cent

per

ann

um

Page 27: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

27

The Interest Rate Spread andReal GDP per Capita

The Interest Rate Spread, 1995

-50.0

0.0

50.0

100.0

150.0

200.0

250.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cent

per

ann

um

Page 28: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

28

The Interest Rate Spread andReal GDP per Capita

The Interest Rate Spread, 1995

-10.0

10.0

30.0

50.0

70.0

90.0

100.0 1000.0 10000.0 100000.0

Real GDP per Capita

Per

cent

per

ann

um

Page 29: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

29

The Rate of Interest on Savings Deposits and the Lagged Rate of Inflation

The Deposit Rate (1998) and the Lagged Rate of Inflation (1997)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

-10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70

The Lagged Rate of Inflation %

Th

e D

ep

os

it R

ate

%

Page 30: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

30

The Rate of Interest on Loans and the Lagged Rate of Inflation

The Lending Rate (1998) and the Lagged Rate of Inflation (1997)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

-10 10 30 50 70 90 110

The Lagged Rate of Inflation %

Th

e L

en

din

g R

ate

%

Page 31: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

31

The Rate of Inflation and the Rate of Economic Growth (1970-1998)

The Rate of Economic Growth and the Rate of Inflation(1970-1998)

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160

Average Annual Rate of Growth of GDP (%)

Average Annual Rate of Inflation (%)

Page 32: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

32

The Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Setting the basic or reference rate of interest (e.g., the federal funds

rate, the rediscount rate) Setting the capital requirement (BIS standard) Setting the reserve ratio Inflation targeting Open market operations (the lack of a deep and liquid bond market)

Page 33: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

33

Financial Repression Is there financial repression in developing economies? Is financial repression desirable or undesirable?

Page 34: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

34

The Benefits and Costs of a Currency Board System (Dollarization) True dollarization (Panama) and quasi-dollarization (Hong Kong,

Argentina) True dollarization implies that the U.S. dollar will be legal tender for all

obligations and contracts can be denominated in U.S. dollars Hong Kong and Argentina with a fixed U.S.$ peg are not quite truly dollarized

but is very close to being so Indonesia considered adopting a currency-board system in the midst

of the East Asian currency crisis

Page 35: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

35

The Benefits and Costs of a Currency Board System (Dollarization) Benefits:

Insulation of economy from exchange rate volatility Credible pre-commitment to non-interventionist monetary policy, in particular,

non-inflationary financing of government expenditures Implicit commitment to a low rate of inflation (a rate of inflation similar to

that of the United States)—lowers inflationary expectations if credible The rate of interest and the rate of inflation will be at U.S. levels if credible Promotes long-term FDI as well as foreign portfolio investment Facilitates foreign trade

Costs: No more monetary policy (neither money supply nor interest rate can be

independently controlled) Fiscal policy constrained by the ability to issue local currency or US$

denominated government notes and bonds Loss of seigniorage from currency issuance under true dollarization

Page 36: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

36

The Currency Board System Adequate foreign exchange reserves, in excess of M0, will still be

required Even a completely cashless society, which implies M0 = 0, will still require

foreign exchange for the smooth and orderly conduct of business Flexibility (especially downward) of prices and wage rates is

essential for prompt and successful adjustment to external shocks Low stock of external (especially short-term) debt denominated in

foreign currency relative to foreign exchange reserves

Page 37: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

37

Outstanding Issues of Dollarization Outstanding issues

Is there a lender of last resort (to domestic financial institutions)? Can the seigniorage be shared (true dollarization)? Coordination, if any, of monetary policy with the U.S. (e.g., monetary union)?

The U.S. benefits from seigniorage, both direct and indirect

Page 38: Economics 216: The  Macroeconomics of Development

Lawrence J. Lau, Stanford University

38

Voluntary Virtual Dollarization In economies with a high rate of inflation and a continuously

depreciating currency, it is quite common for transactions (e.g., loans and interest) to be denominated in U.S. dollars but settled in terms of the local currency in accordance with the exchange rate (either the official market rate or the black market rate, as specified by prior agreement)

Example 1: A firm may place an order in terms of U.S. dollars and upon delivery will settle in local currency in accordance with the market exchange rate on the date of delivery

Example 2: A firm may borrow money in terms of U.S. dollars. It will be given the proceeds in terms of the local currency in accordance with the market exchange rate on the date of the loan draw down. Upon maturity, it will repay in terms of the local currency in accordance with the exchange rate on the date of maturity.


Recommended