+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis....

Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis....

Date post: 28-Sep-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
18
Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed Investments for the Upper Tana-Nairobi Water Fund A Technical Appendix to the Upper Tana-Nairobi Water Fund Business Case Benjamin P. Bryant The Natural Capital Project Stanford University Author contact: [email protected] March 2015
Transcript
Page 1: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed

Investments for the Upper Tana-Nairobi Water Fund

A Technical Appendix to the Upper Tana-Nairobi Water Fund Business Case

Benjamin P. Bryant

The Natural Capital Project

Stanford University

Author contact: [email protected]

March 2015

Page 2: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Contents Preface .......................................................................................................................................................... 3

Acknowledgments ......................................................................................................................................... 3

Introduction .................................................................................................................................................. 4

What question are we trying to answer? ................................................................................................. 4

A fundamental assumption regarding interpreting “the intervention” ................................................... 4

Model structure and documentation overview ............................................................................................ 5

Detailed documentation: Costs .................................................................................................................... 5

Investment costs ....................................................................................................................................... 6

Net additional costs .................................................................................................................................. 7

Detailed documentation: Benefits ................................................................................................................ 7

Sediment-related benefits over time ........................................................................................................ 8

Benefits to agricultural producers and value-chain members ................................................................. 8

Source of agricultural benefits .............................................................................................................. 8

Agricultural benefits over time ............................................................................................................. 9

Potentially omitted impacts on agricultural producers ...................................................................... 10

Benefits to KenGen ................................................................................................................................. 10

Changes in generation ........................................................................................................................ 10

Avoided dredging costs for small upstream dams .............................................................................. 14

Improved generation (or value capture) due to increased storage capacity ..................................... 14

Potential negative value of preserved storage capacity ..................................................................... 14

Nairobi City Water and Sewerage Company benefits ............................................................................ 15

Avoided flocculant costs and avoided electricity costs ...................................................................... 15

Net revenue from saved process water .............................................................................................. 17

Scaling up for meeting demand .......................................................................................................... 17

Drinking water for those outside municipal water supply service ......................................................... 17

Page 3: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Preface This appendix details the model and assumptions used to translate biophysical output from SWAT

modeling of RIOS portfolios into monetary units and other biophysical metrics of more direct

stakeholder interest. Agricultural yield benefits are primarily discussed in the FutureWater technical

appendix,1 though this document provides additional detail on how they were utilized within the

broader return-on-investment analysis.

This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and therefore does not

provide significant background on the Upper Tana context, nor does it recapitulate the modeling and

economic analysis results. Rather, the goal is to make the underlying modeling transparent and

reproducible. It is therefore oriented around the model itself and data sources, with important

contextual points and assumptions discussed or referenced where relevant.

Acknowledgments The author would like to thank Johannes Hunink of FutureWater for extensive discussions regarding

proper interpretation of the SWAT modeling results. Adrian Vogl and Stacie Wolnie of the Natural

Capital Project provided helpful guidance on proper interpretation of the RIOS portfolios. Thanks are

also due to Colin Apse of the Nature Conservancy, and many helpful individuals based in Kenya,

including Fred Kihara and George Njugi of the Nature Conservancy (Nairobi office), Heather Mason,

Mathews Murgor, Philip Githinji, and all members of the Water Fund Steering committee.

1 Hunink and Droogers (2015). Impact Assessment of Investment Portfolios for Business Case Development of the Nairobi Water Fund in the

Upper Tana River, Kenya. FutureWater Report 133.

2 TNC (2015). Upper Tana-Nairobi Water Fund Business Case. Version 2. The Nature Conservancy: Nairobi, Kenya.

Page 4: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Introduction

What question are we trying to answer?

The fundamental question this analysis seeks to answer is whether the benefits to watershed

investments that may be undertaken by a Water Fund are likely to outweigh the costs associated with

them. This provides an assessment of whether the fund is an economically “worthwhile” investment

from the social perspective. Secondary to this, we also seek to gain an understanding of how the

benefits will be distributed, as well as a sense of how completely we have captured benefits and what

potentially significant benefits are being omitted. Because the first question essentially requires

assessing whether total benefits are above a certain threshold, it is possible to answer it without

definitely answering the latter distributional questions.

Before proceeding further, please note that while this report covers the analysis provided in the

business case document, it is intended primarily to document and justify the detailed modeling choices

made, and does not provide sufficient context to serve as a standalone document. It is assumed that the

reader will have good familiarity with the “Benefits analysis” chapter of the Business Case, and

preferably the chapters leading up to it as well.

A fundamental assumption regarding interpreting “the intervention”

The economic value of the conservation investments under consideration are based on the difference in

outcomes between what would happen with the Water Fund and what would happen without. It is

assumed that the Water Fund will make investments guided by outputs of the Resource Investment

Optimization System (RIOS). Importantly, RIOS identifies suggested interventions to make at the pixel

level of a landscape – in this analysis, 15 meters. These interventions are defined at a generic level,

including activities such as “agroforestry” and “riparian management.” These activities are then

translated into changes in parameters at higher units (the Hydrologic Response Unit in SWAT -- “HRU”),

based on response curves in the literature, which are described in Section 2.3.2 of the FutureWater

companion report. The process of translating RIOS interventions at the pixel level into HRU parameters

involves a series of assumptions related to parameters describing particular land cover characteristics

(independent of spatial orientation), how land cover within the HRU is distributed, and how that

distribution of land cover translates to parameter changes.

Therefore, when making statements regarding the magnitude of benefits associated with implementing

RIOS portfolios, we are making an assumption that implementation will occur in a manner that produces

approximately equivalent biophysical changes at approximately equivalent costs – these may or may not

be the same exact interventions specified by the RIOS outputs, as the assumption is that on the ground

specialists will utilize the RIOS outputs as guidance for implementing the water fund. Deviation from the

RIOS outputs could result in higher or lower returns than those modeled here. Additional research will

explore this relationship more closely to assess relevant sensitivities in this complex link between model

outputs and implementation realities. For additional discussion see “Addressing uncertainty during

implementation” on page 24 of the main body report.

Page 5: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Model structure and documentation overview The ultimate assessment of overall cost effectiveness is completed in an Excel spreadsheet, drawing on

modeling outputs from multiple other sources (eg, SWAT, statistical models in R, and other data). Here,

we explain the model structure by working backward from the final summary outputs that are

presented in the report. The model references the Excel implementation, though every attempt has

been made to specify the model mathematically. In some cases this results in rather trivial equations

that add little beyond the verbal description, but this is done in part to serve assist in verification that

the model is implemented as specified. Notationally, bolded italics with complete names indicate a

conceptual variable, while similarly formatted abbreviated terms with underscores indicate named

variables in Excel (for example “exchange rate for investment” and “exrate_for_inv”).

We utilize Net Present Value as the main summary metric, contained on the “Summary” sheet which

assembles all the different benefit streams.

On the summary sheet, all costs and benefits are calculated in KSh, though may be summarized

elsewhere (and in the final summary lines) in M KSh or M USD. If units are not specified in the

spreadsheet, KSh should be assumed.

NPV summarizes net benefits over time, utilizing a discount rate, according to the following equation:

Net Present Value = ∑ [ (1/𝑟𝑡𝑇𝑡=1 ) × Investment cost in year t ]

Where T is the time horizon (assumed to be 30 years), and r is the real discount rate (assumed to be

5%). See Page 16 and Footnote 22 of the main business case document for justification of these values.

Net Annual Benefits are in turn simply defined as:

Net Annual Benefit in Year t = Annual Benefit in Year t – Annual Cost in Year t

We now step through the individual sources of costs, followed by the individual sources of benefits.

Detailed documentation: Costs Total cost is simply considered to be investment cost plus net additional cost, because all other benefit

streams are assumed to be net of costs borne by the beneficiaries.

Total cost in year t = Investment cost in year t + Net additional cost in year t

As discussed in the main business case (p23), net additional cost encompasses all additional costs and

benefits besides upfront implementation cost – the most obvious of these are any maintenance or

reinvestment costs required to preserve the biophysical benefits flowing from the change in land use.

There may also be additional costs in terms of labor or altered farming practices, and these costs may

also be offset by co-benefits (with fodder provision by Napier grass being a prime example).

Page 6: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Investment costs

In the analysis used to prepare the business case document, the user specifies an aggregate budget,

which is assumed to be disbursed evenly over a given number of years, which can also be specified by

the user. Formally, this is implemented according to the following rules:

If project year is less than or equal to total years to invest, then:

Investment cost in year t = [Exchange rate for Investment] ×

[Total investment cost in USD]/[years to invest]

Otherwise,

Investment cost in year t = 0

Total investment cost in USD (inv_total) is entered on the Dashboard sheet. As of v17 of the CBA

spreadsheet, changing investment cost does not adjust the benefits, it only varies costs independently.

Depending on needs in later analysis, the model could be adjusted with a switch to allow independent

variation of the cost, or one that appropriately scaled benefits by interpolating between benefits

produced by the different portfolios.

The default length of time to make the investments (inv_years) is taken to be 10 years. That is, spending

occurs evenly over 10 years, and there is no distinction between the type of benefits that arise. The

current (v17) implementation should be robust to specifying any timeline of investment between 1 and

30 years, subject to the caveat that benefits produced after the 30 year time horizon will not be

captured. Also, currently (v17) the agricultural benefits are only calculated appropriately up to a

maximum of 20 cohorts (see “Agriculture benefits over time.”)

The analysis is conducted in units of Kenyan shilling and converted back to US dollars for summary

purposes where convenient. Because almost all of the cost considered for the investment are

opportunity costs borne within the Kenyan economy, fluctuating exchange rates should not have a

significant impact on the economic viability of the project within Kenya, in terms of consumption

opportunities for Kenyan beneficiaries. Exchange rates do matter for how money is raised and managed

within the fund however, and this will need to be given attention by the governors of the Water Fund. It

will also matter for the agricultural yield benefits, which were based on economic water productivity

estimates developed for export values.

The exchange rate for investment (exrate_for_inv) is specified as a separate exchange rate from the

primary exchange rate used in the model because the portfolios were developed by converting per-area

costs in KSh at a particular point in time (February 2014) to USD. The exact rate used was 84.918

KSh:USD. Under the assumption that implementation costs are most accurately priced in local currency

(as they are mostly a function of local labor and local currency), a rise in the strength of the dollar

(above the ~85 that was used) implies that a given portfolio can be implemented today for fewer USD

than at the time the portfolio was developed. However, the default analysis for the March 2015

business case does not utilize a different exchange rate, out of the interest of conservatism, and

Page 7: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

pragmatism: Rather than assessing the exchange rate dependence of every parameter utilized in the

model and how it has changed from the date of estimation, we utilize a constant rate throughout. Other

values that may in fact be exchange-rate dependent include economic water productivity statistics

(which reference export values), and avoided generation costs for KenGen, which may depend on oil

prices and Kenya’s purchasing power.

Net additional costs

As implemented for the business case analysis, net additional cost is specified as a fraction of the

investment cost that has come before it, defined by the parameter maint_frac:

Net additional cost in year t =

Net additional cost as fraction of investment × ∑𝑡−11 Investment cost in year t

This formulation allows the manifestation of maintenance cost over time to accurately track changes to

the implementation timeline. One caveat is that the assumption of a constant scalar implies that the

average net additional costs are manifested immediately in the year after implementation. This would

not be the case if project implementation was front-loaded with particularly high or low maintenance

interventions, or if net additional costs included factors besides maintenance that took time to manifest

themselves. For example, for some interventions, immediate maintenance may be required, but co-

benefits not captured in other benefit streams may not manifest for multiple seasons or time-periods.

Detailed documentation: Benefits Monetized benefits are considered for four different sets of stakeholders, each of which has at least one

benefit stream, and sometimes more than one:

Agricultural producers (including others in the value chain)

Nairobi City Water and Sewerage Company (NCWSC)

KenGen

Household abstracters of raw water for drinking

Background on these stakeholders is given in the main body of the business case, so this text focuses

only on technical issues surrounding implementation of their benefit streams.

In the spreadsheet, annual benefits are first aggregated to the level of the stakeholder, and then the

stakeholder benefits are summed to identify the total benefits in a given year, according to the simple

summation (with an implied subscript for the year):

Annual benefit = Total ag benefits + NCWSC benefits + KenGen benefits + Raw water users benefits

Before discussing each individual beneficiary and benefit stream, we discuss some general points about

the manifestation of benefits over time.

Page 8: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Sediment-related benefits over time

Benefits related to the sediment retention (eg, sediment concentration benefits for the water supply,

and sediment deposition benefits for KenGen) depend on upstream interventions taking effect. A first

requirement for consistency in modeling the timing of benefits is to ensure that the model does not

allow benefits to materialize prior to interventions being made. A second requirement is to allow that

there may be some delay between undertaking an intervention and significant sediment retention (if,

for example, sediment retention depends on development of above ground vegetation and/or root

structure).

These requirements are enforced in the model by use of a year-specific sediment benefit scalar, which

scales down the steady-state benefits in a sediment-related benefit stream according to the following

formula:

sediment dependent benefit in year t = sediment benefit scalar in year t × long run benefit

Where:

sediment benefit scalar in year t = ∑𝑡−(1+𝑠𝑒𝑑 𝑏𝑒𝑛𝑒 𝑑𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑦)1 [investment costt ]/[Total investment cost]

(and zero if sed_bene_delay ≥ t).

Here, sed_bene_delay refers to the parameter sediment benefit delay, which indicates the number of

years between investment and realization of steady-state sediment retention benefits. (In the

spreadsheet this is implemented in two rows using the offset function in Excel.)

The default value for sed_bene_delay is taken to be three years, based on hydrologist judgment with an

intent to be somewhat conservative – however, the choice of this parameter is currently not informed

by specific data, and could vary significantly for different interventions (for example, benefits from

terracing may be near-immediate, while benefits that rely on tree cover and tree root structures could

take longer).

Benefits to agricultural producers and value-chain members

Source of agricultural benefits

The details of the modeling of agricultural benefits are described in the FutureWater technical appendix

(Chapter 6), with additional details of the economics considerations described in the main body of the

business case document. Briefly, the increase in yields is assumed to be derived from avoided soil losses,

which lead to higher soil productivity than would occur without the project. The effect of soil depth on

yields is modeled through the use of a productivity index function, which relates relative yields to soil

depth. Rather than using yields directly however, the approach estimates changes in revenue by

assuming an equivalent relative change in evapotranspiration, which is multiplied by published values of

crop-specific economic water productivity.

This approach was chosen for feasibility and data availability, though an alternative approach based on

yields and crop budgets would likely better track what fraction of the change in revenue is captured as

Page 9: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

profit by the farmer, captured as profit elsewhere in the export and domestic value chains, and what

fraction is used to cover costs associated with the increase in production. For the business case analysis,

we do not attempt to disentangle these distributional effects, except to recognize that there is a

difference between the true economic benefit and the modeled change in revenue. By default, we scale

down the benefits by 50% (Yield benefits scalar, named ag_bene_scalar in Excel), which is admittedly a

somewhat arbitrary point, grounded simply as the midpoint between the bounds of 0 and 100 percent.

In perfectly complete and competitive markets with all domestic consumption, the fraction of altered

revenue that would count as a benefit would be closer to zero, because resources to move products

through the value chain are close to fully employed, and therefore incur a higher opportunity cost. By

contrast, the more “excess capacity” exists in the value chain, the lower the marginal cost of marketing

the higher yields, which in turn means that a higher fraction of the revenue change is a true benefit.

Besides the yield benefits scalar, the only other spreadsheet parameters related to the agricultural

benefits regard the timing of how benefits are realized, discussed next. (There are of course many other

parameters involved, but these are described in the FutureWater technical appendix. The return on

investment analysis treats the outputs of the FutureWater modeling as inputs.)

Agricultural benefits over time

Agricultural yield benefits are distinct from most others (except hydro sedimentation) in that they are a

function of cumulative action: Sediment accumulates over time, which, accounting for soil productivity

dynamics, leads to a concave-down curve for yield increase over time. The FutureWater report provides

these values for years 5, 10 and 15 from the time of full sediment retention capability. As with the

sediment retention benefits, we allow for some delay between implementation and the beginning of

yield benefits. Essentially, the yield benefit trajectory is shifted back in time. Because there is a

trajectory associated with the implementation that occurs in each year, it is more appropriate to track

these by “cohort” and sum across cohorts in a given year to get the total ag benefits in that year. These

calculations are performed on the “Ag – cohorts” sheet of the Excel CBA workbook.

Specifically:

We first establish the reference trajectory of yield benefits over time, assuming benefits start

immediately, and are implemented for the entire portfolio. This is simply linear interpolation between

the values provided in the future water report. This is implemented mathematically as

𝑈𝐴𝐵�̂̂� = 𝑈𝐴𝐵̅̅ ̅̅ ̅̅𝑡− +

�̂� − 𝑡−

𝑡+ − 𝑡−× (𝑈𝐴𝐵̅̅ ̅̅ ̅̅

𝑡+ − 𝑈𝐴𝐵̅̅ ̅̅ ̅̅𝑡−)

Where “UAB” stands for Unscaled Ag Benefits (that is, the output of the FutureWater modeling),

overbar indicates outputs from FutureWater, the hat indicates time relative to implementation for that

cohort, and t+ and t- indicate the nearest time periods on either side of �̂� for which FutureWater provided

values (0, 5, 10 and 15 years).

We then identify unscaled benefits adjusted for the lag in implementation:

Page 10: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

𝑈𝐴𝐵𝑡 = 𝑈𝐴�̂�[�̂�=𝑡−𝐴𝐵𝐷]

Where UABt is the actual unscaled benefit in that year, and ABD stands for “ag benefits delay” –

assumed to be 3 years in the reference case. (in Excel, the time lag is implemented using the OFFSET

function).

Then, to identify the value in a given year for a given cohort, we scale down the unscaled benefits by

dividing by the years to implement.3

𝐴𝐵𝑡 =𝑈𝐴𝐵𝑡

𝑇𝑖𝑚𝑝𝑙𝑒𝑚𝑒𝑛𝑡

Where 𝐴𝐵𝑡 indicates “actual benefits,” 𝑇𝑖𝑚𝑝𝑙𝑒𝑚𝑒𝑛𝑡 is the years to implement (years_to_imp in Excel).

Finally, we delay each cohort’s benefits by one year per cohort, and sum for each of the cohorts. In

Excel, this lag is implemented by referencing the cell above and to the left. Mathematically, it is making

the statement that the value to be assigned to cohort i in year j is the value assigned to cohort (i-1) in

year (j-1). To estimate total ag benefits in a given year, the summation is performed across cohorts (by

row in the spreadsheet). In the spreadsheet, cohort-specific values are always calculated for 20 cohorts,

but the summation is adjusted to draw only the first years_to_imp cohorts.

Potentially omitted impacts on agricultural producers

In at least some regions of the world, irrigators actually benefit from nutrient and sediment content in

surface water that is applied to their fields. In theory, these irrigators could suffer impacts from reduced

sediment in the water. Our discussions with WRMA and other groups have not suggested that there

would be significant loss in this case. Furthermore, since most sediment is trapped in Masinga reservoir,

any potential negative impact of the interventions beyond Masinga can be assumed minimal.

Benefits to KenGen

Benefits to Kengen derive from avoided service interruptions and (more significantly) increases in water

yield. We also attempted valuing the change in Masinga reservoir storage, but challenges and

uncertainties involved in such valuation were quite high, and so that value stream was omitted from the

business case document, though some of the challenges are discussed below.

Changes in generation

As essentially all benefits are related to increased (or avoided losses of) generation, we focus on

estimating changes in generation for each benefit stream first, and then finally discuss issues of valuing

the increase in generation.

3 Note that this formulation does not reference budget actually spent by year, but rather matches the assumption of even disbursement over

time. If that assumption is relaxed elsewhere, it needs to be relaxed here as well, but adjusting the formula to utilize the “Cumulative

Investment Fraction” discussed in section on sediment-related benefits over time.

Page 11: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Estimating changes in generation – increased yields4

The largest source of benefits comes from the increase in water yield flowing into Masinga reservoir, the

majority of which is assumed to flow through the Seven Forks cascade and generate electricity. To

estimate the change in generation, we can apply the standard physics-based equations based on change

in potential energy and efficiency of conversion to energy fed to the grid:

𝐸𝑔𝑒𝑛 = 𝜂𝑚𝑔ℎ

where η is the efficiency of energy conversion, reported by KenGen as between 90 and 93%. m is the

mass of one cubic meter of water (assumed to be 1000 kg, ignoring minor temperature and pressure

deviations), g is the gravitational acceleration (9.8 m/s/s), and h is the effective head (meters). This is

the formula we use to estimate power generation in the Seven Forks Cascade downstream of Masinga

dam.

For Masinga dam specifically, we were able to utilize data provided by KenGen5 describing efficiency as a

function of surface height (h), expressed as cubic meters of water required to produce a megawatt of

electricity. This greatly simplifies the calculation of increased generation to simple division:

𝐸𝑔𝑒𝑛 = 𝑉/𝛾(ℎ)

Where V is the volume and γ is the efficiency expressed in volume per unit energy. To choose γ, we must

identify a representative surface height (h). For this we simply used the average of daily surface heights

in Masinga for the 10 year period from 1 October 2001 to 30 September 2013. (KenGen provided data

for a slightly longer period, but we chose this interval rather than the entire dataset in order to avoid

bias from seasonality issues.) The average dam height and associated efficiency are 1051.505 meters

and the associated efficiency from the KenGen data of 9500.9 cubic meters per megawatt-hour, or .1053

kwh/m3.

However, if a significant fraction of the additional water yield is not used consumptively by irrigators or

other users within the Seven Forks cascade, then it will provide benefits at the downstream generating

stations as well.6 The total height of dams within the Seven Forks cascade, not counting Masinga, is

222.3 meters.

Dam Height (m)

Masinga 69.5

Kamburu 56

4 The calculations described here are mostly performed on the “Hydro – background calcs” sheet, as of v18.

5 Extracted from a report prepared by Soluziona consulting group.

6 In reality, this could be represented by a parameter representing the fraction of increased yields that actually generate electricity within the

Seven Forks cascade. The distribution of benefits to KenGen would be linearly sensitive to this parameter, though total benefits produced

would be less sensitive, as presumably abstracted water would be going to produce economic benefits, just in a different use. The error in

total benefits would be a function of the difference in value of water between hydropower and the competing use.

Page 12: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Gitaru 30

Kindaruma 24.3

Kiambere 112

total height = upper bound on head 291.8

total height = upper bound on head, not counting Masinga 222.3

Masinga average head to height ratio .626

Implied average head for remainder of cascade 139.2

We know, however, that the effective head is not equivalent to the dam height, but did not have the

same detailed data on the other dam surface heights as we did for Masinga. Therefore, we add a

parameter specifying average head as a function of surface height. For the reference case, we set this

equal to the same ratio as in Masinga reservoir.7 The total height of all the dams provides an upper

bound for this head.

We can use the physics-based equation based on potential energy to identify the kwh/m3 generated by

the rest of the cascade. Because the generation is linear in so many real (or implicit) parameters,

(efficiency, head, fraction of increased water yield traveling the whole cascade), in the model

implementation we capture this value as a single scalar expressing benefits as a multiple of generation

through Masinga dam (the “water yield benefits multiplier”). Under our reference case parameter

values, one cubic meter flowing the through Masinga dam will generate on average .105 kwh, and one

cubic meter flowing through the remainder of the cascade will generate .32 kwh. Therefore, for the

reference case, we multiply the Masinga generation by [(.105 + .32)/.105] = 4.06 to estimate generation

through the entire cascade. That is:

Long-run average annual value of water yield = water yield benefits multiplier × increased generation

at Masinga

Adjustments to this multiplier can capture any of the other uncertain parameters mentioned above as

part of sensitivity analysis. In the spreadsheet implementation of the model (as of v18), the increased

generation at Masinga is calculated as a product on the “Dashboard” sheet itself, using parameters

identified in background calculations.

Note that consumptive losses prior to and within the Seven Forks cascade would of course reduce this

benefit, however these would need to be consumptive losses of the increased water supply brought

about by the intervention. Also, note that (not accounting for changes in efficiency as a function of

head), the sensitivity to consumptive loss has a linear upper bound for impact. If 10% of the additional

water is lost between the priority watersheds and the lower portion of the Seven Forks Cascade,

generation is reduced by at most 10%, since it is unlikely all of the water will be lost to consumptive use

prior to flowing through Masinga reservoir – some will flow through at least some generating stations.

7 Given that Masinga reservoir is used to regulate the levels of the other dams, this may be a conservative estimate.

Page 13: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Avoided generation losses due to decreases in shutdown time

There are multiple smaller power plants upstream of Masinga that are likely to experience fewer

operational interruptions due to reduced sediment concentrations (for locations, see Figure 4 in the

main business case document). For example, on a visit to the 20MW Tana power station, we were told

operations must interrupted periodically to deal with sediment accumulation near the intake, and also

potentially sediment-related damage to turbine seals. Furthermore, each interruption removed

generators from service for about two weeks. If the frequency of interruptions is approximately

proportional to the sediment concentration, then this translates to fewer interruptions and lower

forgone generation. There is unfortunately very limited data to calibrate this relationship, but we were

told that two years may be considered a reference time period for needing to undertake such

maintenance. So as an example, halving sediment reduction would reduce interruptions to every four

years.

The avoided loss of generation associated with an individual shutdown event is simply:

GENloss = capacity × capacity factor × shutdown duration

At Tana for example, if we assume a capacity factor of .5, then two weeks offline translates to

20000 kw × .5 × (24 hours/day × 14 days) = 3336000 kwh

The undiscounted average annual benefit associated with a change in frequency of interruptions is:

(1

τ𝑜𝑙𝑑−

1

𝜏𝑛𝑒𝑤) × 𝐺𝐸𝑁𝑙𝑜𝑠𝑠

Where τ is the period of interruption (years between events). With the example of doubling the

frequency from 2 years to 4, one is essentially avoiding a service interruption every fourth year on

average.

Our nominal figures above were based on approximate benefits for Tana. Besides the assumption of

capacity factor, we make the assumption that scaling up by capacity is the best available approximation

for the benefits that would apply to the other power stations. As shown in the table below, this means

increasing the benefits by another 56% above those of Tana alone.

Power station Capacity (MW)

Mesco 0.38

Sagana (Falls) 1.5

Wanjii 7.4

Ndula 2

Tana 20

Total upstream of Masinga 31.28 Multiplier relative to Tana power station 1.564

Page 14: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Avoided dredging costs for small upstream dams

While do know that dredging occurs for a subset of the dams upstream of Masinga, we were unable to

acquire data on volume or frequency of that dredging. In general, the calculation would be similar as

that for avoided interruptions described above, where a given volume of dredging (or dredging event)

results in a periodic cost. Reduced sedimentation would either reduce the volume of dredging per

dredging event, or the frequency of dredging events.

Improved generation (or value capture) due to increased storage capacity

One of the primary benefits anticipated for KenGen was the preservation of reservoir storage volume.

While many dams (including Masinga) are designed with a finite useful life based on assumed

sedimentation rates, reducing sedimentation can extend the lifetime of the dam, reduce spillage events,

and allow for closer to optimal control of the water resource. Also, in the case of Masinga,

sedimentation is occurring faster than assumed during the design stage.

This analysis does not attempt valuing changes in the useful life of the dam, because the time to lose

even half the reservoir volume with or without the conservations interventions are both over 100 years,

which was deemed well beyond the relevant time horizon for this analysis – it would be difficult to make

assessments about the marginal value of hydro production for energy technologies 100 years in the

future.

However, in the near term, the impacts of sedimentation can still affect the bottom line for KenGen.

Masinga reservoir at the top of the Seven Forks Cascade – while the Masinga Power Station represents a

relatively small portion of the total generation, the storage capacity of the reservoir is used to balance

generation across the cascade. Capturing the marginal value of storage capacity on such an integrated

system would require detailed engineering information unavailable to us, as well as careful study of

inflow characteristics. We continue to examine alternative approaches to bound this benefit. One

avenue explored was to consider changes in spillage and associated lost generation capacity, assuming

the same historic inflow and outflow patterns. While this approach can be used to provide an upper

bound if the benefit stream is small, it cannot be used to establish the actual magnitude of the benefit

stream because it assumes no response by the dam operator, who would in fact take measures to

reduce losses, violating the assumption of managing to produce the same outflow as was done in the

past.

Potential negative value of preserved storage capacity

Conversely, there are potentially some benefits from sedimentation, which we identified as small: In

theory sedimentation could raise the effective head of the dam, by effectively displacing water upwards.

We checked the potential impact of this by assessing the marginal increase in volumetric generation

efficiency as a function of height (numerically estimating 𝑑[𝛾(ℎ)]/𝑑ℎ) assuming a linear response), and

multiplied it by the long-run change in surface height that might be expected under sediment

accumulation in the baseline case, with no change in flow: We find that the efficiency of generation

would lead to approximately 500,000 kwh extra per year all else equal. Even so, this amounts to an

annual loss of approximately 17600 USD, which is negligible. These calculations are detailed on the

“Hydro – background calcs” sheet.

Page 15: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Valuing the increase in generation is done at 3.06 Ksh/kwh based on the average generation cost.8 In

reality, the financial value to KenGen and the social value to Kenyans as a whole will depend on the time

and conditions of generation, as well as the details of the power-purchase agreements to which KenGen

is party. In the near term at least, it is quite likely that the value of increased generation is higher

especially during the dry season, when KenGen will rely on expensive fossil generation to cover low

hydropower production (though costs are largely passed through to consumers). However, this dynamic

of reliance on fossil fuel is likely to be reduced in the coming decades as increasingly large amounts of

geothermal come online and with increasing integration of the East African power pool. Also reducing

gains is that fact that the efficiency of hydro generation will presumably be lower in the dry season due

to the lower heads – though this efficiency difference is on the order of 10%, which is small compared to

the differences in marginal cost when moving from hydro to fossil fuel.

Nairobi City Water and Sewerage Company benefits

As described in the main business case document, reduced sediment concentrations to NCWSC have

multiple benefits, including:

Avoided flocculant costs

Avoided electricity costs

Avoided loss of revenue from saved process water

It is also likely that NCWSC’s operations will benefit from increased dry season baseflow, allowing

cheaper or improved reliability. In addition, the (future) costs associated with wet sludge disposal will be

lower (after NCWSC implements a wet-sludge disposal system), as wet sludge volume to be disposed is

approximately directly proportional to sediment concentration intake. Here we focus only on the

primary calculations of the three bulleted items above.

Avoided flocculant costs and avoided electricity costs

We group the explanation of these because they are both based on similar regressions of turbidity

against cost data for the Ngethu treatment plant. In each case, we were given access to historical

turbidity data, plant process volumes, and energy use or flocculant use.

For energy use, we estimated an equation of the form

𝐸𝐿𝐸𝐶 𝐶𝑂𝑆𝑇 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 log(𝑑𝑖𝑠𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑔𝑒) + 𝛽2𝑝𝑒𝑎𝑘𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏 + 𝛽3𝑠𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦

Where security is a dummy variable marking the date of transition to a new security system at the plant

which had a significant increase in continuous energy usage.9

The results of the above regression (which was chosen for fit based on several alternatives) was as

follows:

8 Kenya Electricity Generating Company Limited. 2014 Annual Report & Financial Statements

9 Personal communication with NCWSC.

Page 16: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Coefficients: Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(>|t|) Beta 0: (Intercept) 3008143.16 274108.37 10.974 3.80e-15 *** Beta 1: I(log(discharge_m3)) -145225.46 16815.48 -8.636 1.27e-11 *** Beta 2: peak_turb 105.25 25.66 4.101 0.000145 *** Beta 3: security 349007.77 50599.26 6.897 7.21e-09 *** --- Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1 Multiple R-squared: 0.8359, Adjusted R-squared: 0.8264 F-statistic: 88.28 on 3 and 52 DF, p-value: < 2.2e-16

The marginal effect on the peak_turb parameter identifies the change in monthly cost that would be

realized for a unit reduction in peak turbidity. We have data demonstrating that peak turbidity is highly

correlated with average monthly turbidity as measured at Ngethu, and also have shown that at the

monthly level, sediment concentration and turbidity are nearly directly proportional (see Chapter 4 of

the FutureWater appendix). Mean monthly sediment concentration reductions (averaged acrossed

simulated years) ranged from 55 to 58 percent (see Figure 11 of the business case report). Therefore,

while a more precise month by month estimate of the cost savings could be made by tracking the SWAT

outputs through the regression above, for simplicity and conservativism, we chose to estimate savings

based on average 50% reduction in peak turbidity. Based on this assumption, we calculate the

approximate long-run annual average savings as follows:

months per year × fraction reduction in sediment concentration × maximum average monthly

spending attributable to variation in electricity expenses

Maximum average monthly spending attributable to variation in electricity expenses is based on

multiplying the peak turbidity coefficient from the regression by the aggregate of NTU-months

contained in the peak turbidity column of the dataset.

A similar approach is taken to estimate flocculant savings.

𝐹𝐿𝑂𝐶 𝐶𝑂𝑆𝑇 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑠 + 𝛽2𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑠2 + 𝛽3𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏 + 𝛽4𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏2 + 𝛽5𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑠 ∗ 𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑏

Coefficients: Estimate Std. Error t value Pr(>|t|) Beta 0: (Intercept) 4.505e+06 8.389e+06 0.537 0.593 Beta 1: I(inflows) 7.138e-02 1.501e+00 0.048 0.962 Beta 2: I(inflows^2) 1.973e-08 6.738e-08 0.293 0.771 Beta 3: I(month_ave) 2.000e+05 1.229e+05 1.628 0.109 Beta 4: I(month_ave^2) 3.056e+01 1.180e+02 0.259 0.796 Beta 5: month_ave:inflows -1.118e-02 9.984e-03 -1.120 0.267 Multiple R-squared: 0.5179, Adjusted R-squared: 0.4797 F-statistic: 13.54 on 5 and 63 DF, p-value: 5.709e-09

Here, because the response is nonlinear in the monthly average turbidity, we actually do need to run the

changes in turbidity through the statistical cost function identified above. That is: Predict the cost by

month, under with-out project and with-project turbidities, where again a linear relationship is assumed

between sediment concentration and turbidity.

Page 17: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

Net revenue from saved process water

The largest source of benefit to NCWSC that we were able to calculate is that of saved process water

and the associated improvement in revenue capture. This benefit did not rely directly on changes in

sediment concentrations identified by SWAT, but were rather based on statements from NCWSC

employees that the change in sediment concentrations brought about by the Water Fund

implementations would allow them to reduce lost water from 5% to 3.5% – a major cause of this is the

need to use already-processed water to backflush sand filters – this is water that could otherwise be

delivered to NCWSC customers, providing a benefit to them, and improved revenue to NCWSC. The

benefits to NCWSC from this savings are calculated by multiplying the saved process water volume by an

adjustment to the volumetric tariff accounting for efficiency considerations. A “commercial efficiency”

(of 62%) accounts for the translation of revenue to financial benefit within NCWSC, while in the

reference case a further factor is used to reduce benefits by 25% based on any potential costs

associated with the increase in water delivery. We were unable to identify the precise source of the

commercial efficiency figure, and applied this extra scalar to be conservative. If the system is truly rife

with extra capacity to deliver this saved water, then potentially neither of these reductions in total

benefit would be necessary. Specifically, the formula used to calculate steady-state benefits is:

commercial efficiency × value per unit of process water saved × change in fraction of process water

used for backwash × annual water intake at Ngethu

The value of process water saved (to KenGen) was taken to be 14.025 KSh/m3 in the reference case

(allowing for further loss, relative to the tariff of 18.7 KSh/m3), with daily intake assumed to be the

conservative low value of 400,000 m3/day (multiplied by 365.25 days per year).

Scaling up for meeting demand

Our detailed cost accounting data was available primarily for the Ngethu treatment works, which are

currently the largest treatment works serving NCWSC. Unfortunately, even accounting for other existing

treatment works in the system, significant demand in Nairobi goes unmet. However, we assume that by

the time the full effect of the sediment retentions has occurred, additional infrastructure will be in place

to meet the existing unmet demand, and therefore scale-up the long-run cost savings benefits by the

demand shortfall. For the level of satisfied demand, we use 482000 m3/day, and a long-run demand of

650000 m3/day, which does not account for project demand from population growth, but is rather a

lower estimate for total demand.

Drinking water for those outside municipal water supply service As noted in the main body report (“Other co-benefits and stakeholders”), many residents of the Upper

Tana do not have access to treated water. We estimate that on the order of half a million residents

outside Nairobi will see improved water quality as well. According to 2009 census figures, there were

approximately 606,000 people within the catchment districts whose primary water source was raw

water from streams.10 This number is calculate on the “Raw water – census calcs” sheet, using data from

Table 8 of Volume II of the census (“Households by main Source of Water and District”). Household

10 The 2009 Kenya Population and Housing Census, Volume II.

Page 18: Ecosystem Services Assessment and Valuation of Proposed ......broader return-on-investment analysis. This document assumes the reader has read the primary business case report,2 and

counts are used to identify fractions of each household in each class of source drinking water, and then

multiplied by total population within the district. Assessment of whether a particular district was

relevant was based on visual inspection of the district locations relative to priority sub-watersheds.

There are reasons this number may be an under estimate or over estimate of the true number of people

affected, though chances are better it is an underestimate.11 However, the impact will also vary spatially,

with those upstream of many interventions not seeing as much change, while those far down will see

the impact diluted by sediment contributions from other sub-catchments that are not part of the

intervention.

11 The districts counted are not 100% contained within the priority watersheds, which biases the number upward. However, the population in

downstream districts is not counted at all. The figures also do not include those who listed “Pond/Dam” or “Lake” as their water source, even

though they will likely experience some increase in water quality as well.


Recommended