+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Effects on poverty and equity of the decline in collective tank …kajisa/papers/Tank and well...

Effects on poverty and equity of the decline in collective tank …kajisa/papers/Tank and well...

Date post: 16-Feb-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
52
1 Effects on poverty and equity of the decline in collective tank irrigation management in Tamil Nadu, India Kei Kajisa* International Rice Research Institute (IRRI) and Foundation for Advanced Studies on International Development (FASID) K. Palanisami Tamil Nadu Agricultural University Takeshi Sakurai Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries of Japan November, 2006 Abstract This paper investigates the factors influencing the decline in collective management of local commons and the impact of this decline on agricultural production and household consumption. The analysis is based on a village and household data set collected in 1999 in Tamil Nadu, India, where tank irrigation systems are managed collectively for rice cultivation by informal water users’ organizations. Our statistical analyses find that one major reason for the decline in collective tank irrigation management is the dissemination of private well irrigation systems. Once the decline has occurred, our analyses predict that the gap in rice yields between farmers who have access to private wells and those who must rely solely on tanks will widen, with only the latter group suffering lower yields. Our analyses also find that the same pattern holds for levels of income and consumption because the affected farmers cannot sufficiently compensate for the loss of their rice income by diversifying their income sources to agricultural labor or non-agricultural work. In this way, the decline in collective management results in greater inequality and poverty. JEL classifications: D31, D71, O33, Q25 Key words: common property, irrigation, income distribution, poverty, India. * Corresponding author: Address: IRRI DAPO Box 7777, Metro Manila, Philippines; E-mail: [email protected]
Transcript
  • 1

    Effects on poverty and equity of the decline in collective tank irrigation management in Tamil Nadu, India

    Kei Kajisa*

    International Rice Research Institute (IRRI) and Foundation for Advanced Studies on International Development (FASID)

    K. Palanisami Tamil Nadu Agricultural University

    Takeshi Sakurai Policy Research Institute, Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries of Japan

    November, 2006

    Abstract

    This paper investigates the factors influencing the decline in collective management of local commons and the impact of this decline on agricultural production and household consumption. The analysis is based on a village and household data set collected in 1999 in Tamil Nadu, India, where tank irrigation systems are managed collectively for rice cultivation by informal water users’ organizations. Our statistical analyses find that one major reason for the decline in collective tank irrigation management is the dissemination of private well irrigation systems. Once the decline has occurred, our analyses predict that the gap in rice yields between farmers who have access to private wells and those who must rely solely on tanks will widen, with only the latter group suffering lower yields. Our analyses also find that the same pattern holds for levels of income and consumption because the affected farmers cannot sufficiently compensate for the loss of their rice income by diversifying their income sources to agricultural labor or non-agricultural work. In this way, the decline in collective management results in greater inequality and poverty. JEL classifications: D31, D71, O33, Q25 Key words: common property, irrigation, income distribution, poverty, India. * Corresponding author: Address: IRRI DAPO Box 7777, Metro Manila, Philippines; E-mail: [email protected]

  • 2

    1. Introduction

    Tank irrigation management is at a crossroads. Tank irrigation systems

    collectively operated and managed by informal local bodies have been a dominant

    source of irrigation in southern India since time immemorial. However, the agricultural

    area under tank irrigation has been in retreat, especially since the 1990s, due to the

    decline in collective management. Concurrent with this is the rapid dissemination of

    private well irrigation systems. The percentage share of tank-irrigated agricultural area

    in southern India fell from 37 in the 1960s to 29 in the 1970s, 22 in the 1980s, and 18 in

    the 1990s. Meanwhile, the percentage share of private wells rose from 20 to 26 to 31

    and to 40 in the corresponding periods (Fertilizer Association of India, various issues).

    The shift in relative share reflects not only a preference for private wells when new

    systems are installed but also the actual replacement of tank systems by well systems.

    This process has been associated with significant increases in the average yield of rice, a

    staple crop in the area, and in the average income level of farmers.

    Despite such positive effects on average, there is concern that the diffusion of

    private wells is also associated with increased poverty and inequality. Access to water

    for irrigation from tanks is available to all farmers in the system command area in

    principle. Access to irrigation water from private wells, however, is limited to the

  • 3

    owners and to those who can buy from the owners. Private wells provide freedom in

    irrigation water control, and thus those who have access can increase their yields and

    income. When farmers who can access private wells exit from the collective

    management of their tank system — out of disinterest or loss of incentive — the quality

    of tank management declines and the tanks deteriorate. When this happens, farmers who

    are dependent solely on tanks suffer a reduction in rice yields, while farmers who have

    recourse to private wells can still achieve high yields. Whether this leads to a significant

    increase in poverty and inequality is an empirical question. If farmers with greater water

    availability due to access to private wells increase their demand for agricultural labor

    and then hire farmers without access to wells, the income of the farmers without access

    to wells may not decline significantly. Besides, farmers without access to wells may be

    able to diversify their income source to non-agricultural occupations. In this way,

    farmers without access to wells may be able to compensate to some extent for their

    income loss caused by the yield reduction. On the other hand, if opportunities to

    participate in agricultural labor and non-agricultural work are limited, the decline in

    collective management results in a reduction in income of farmers without access to

    wells to the extent that it increases poverty and inequality significantly.

    Numerous attempts have been made to examine the determinants of the decline

  • 4

    in collective management (Wade, 1988; Ostrom, 1990; Ostrom et al., 1994; Singh,

    1994; Baland and Platteau, 1996; Palanisami and Easter, 2000; Dayton-Johnson, 2000;

    Bardhan, 2000; Bardhan and Dayton-Johnson, 2001; Fujiie et al., 2005). However, few

    quantitative analyses have been made of the impact of the decline on the livelihoods of

    rural households.1 This paper aims to both investigate the determinants of the decline

    and examine whether this decline results in lower yields and income among farmers

    without access to private wells. As this was found to be true, this paper seeks to answer

    the question of whether a revitalization of tank management would reduce poverty and

    inequality. The analysis is based on a set of data collected from sample surveys at both

    the village and household levels in Tamil Nadu, India.

    The organization of this paper is as follows: the next section, Section 2, explains

    the characteristics of tanks and wells in Tamil Nadu and advances the hypotheses.

    Section 3 describes the study site and data collection. Sections 4 and 5 present the

    regression analyses on the determinants of collective management and on yield and

    income effects. Finally, Section 6 summarizes the discussion and presents policy

    implications.

    1 One exception is the benefit-cost analysis conducted by Kikuchi et al. (2001). Some significant descriptive studies are Jodha (1986), Singh (1994), Palanisami (2000), and Meinzen-Dick et al. (2002a).

  • 5

    2. Tanks and wells in Tamil Nadu

    The tank irrigation system

    The tank irrigation system consists of a water storage area, sluices, and water

    supply channels. The water storage area, or tank, is a small reservoir constructed across

    the slope of a valley to catch and store water. Water is controlled by sluices that are

    attached to the tank bank and is delivered to paddy fields through the channels.

    Traditionally, these tank systems are managed collectively by informal local bodies,

    called water users’ organizations (WUO), which mobilize community labor to perform

    the maintenance and management tasks. These tasks include (1) de-silting the water

    storage area, (2) cleaning the water supply channels, and (3) arranging water

    distribution among users. De-silting work for tanks with a minimum command area of

    40 hectares is supposed to be arranged and implemented by the Public Works

    Department (PWD) using state government funds. However, due to the limitation of

    such funds, de-silting work is occasionally done at the village level based on WUO

    initiatives. For command areas of less than 40 hectares, this work must be done by the

    village-level administration and the WUO. Channel cleaning and water distribution are

    arranged and implemented through collective action by the WUO, regardless of system

    size.

  • 6

    The tank irrigation system has the attributes of a common pool resource (CPR)

    in that the exclusion of farmers within the command area is difficult, but, if use exceeds

    supply capacity, the resource will become exhausted. Hence, in arranging collective

    action, the system is doomed to face two types of CPR management problems:

    provision and appropriation (Ostrom et al., 1994). The former problem arises in

    arranging the maintenance of the resource stock, while the latter occurs in arranging the

    distribution of output flow from the resource. In the context of tank management, the

    former corresponds to de-silting and cleaning arrangements, while the latter corresponds

    to water distribution arrangements.

    The central issue in CPR management of tank irrigation is the resolution of the

    provision problem because two technological features specific to the tank irrigation

    system make resolution difficult. First, tank irrigation technology is indivisible to some

    extent in terms of its supply capacity; hence, it is difficult to reduce the supply capacity

    precisely in accordance with a decline in the number of users. Therefore, as long as the

    tank irrigation system is used, it must maintain a certain supply capacity level and, for

    that purpose, a certain amount of labor input must be mobilized. Second, the

    maintenance work must be completed within a short period of time at the outset of the

    monsoon season. This means that all the participants in maintenance work must be

  • 7

    mobilized at once. However, this period corresponds to the preparation period of rice

    nurseries for those who are able to start preparation earlier with water from wells. For

    them, the opportunity cost of participation is high.2 Hence, when the number of private

    well users increases, it becomes difficult to mobilize a certain amount of labor input

    within a particularly short period of time. In this way, the cost of maintaining the tank

    system becomes too high to irrigate for the small number of remaining users. While

    Olson (1965) argues that a smaller group may facilitate the arrangement of collective

    management, due to the tank’s technological features, once the number of formal users

    declines, it becomes difficult to provide a sufficient level of tank maintenance work.

    Replacement of tank irrigation by private well irrigation

    Even when tanks are properly maintained, having access to private well

    irrigation systems substantially increases rice yields because those systems serve as a

    supplementary source of irrigation and thus improve water control, especially during the

    critical stages of rice cultivation (Palanisami, 2000). Hence, as long as the costs of

    private wells are relatively low, farmers are willing to incur the costs of installing

    private wells even if they can still obtain water from tanks.

    2 Non-participants are asked to contribute money for the maintenance. However, the collection of money is often incompletely implemented.

  • 8

    In the 1990s, the costs of installing and operating private wells declined

    dramatically because of changes in several exogenous conditions. First, the price of

    pumps declined significantly due to the development of the domestic pump industry.

    Figure 1 shows the decline in the relative price of electric motor pumps to paddy price

    throughout the 1990s in Tamil Nadu. Second, the introduction of the hydraulic drilling

    method in the 1980s reduced the cost of drilling by 30%. Because the nominal cost of

    drilling did not change much since then and the paddy price increased 135% in the

    1990s, the relative price of drilling to paddy price declined. Third, starting in 1989, the

    government policy of free electricity supply to farmers made the adoption of electric

    pumps more attractive. Fourth, policies to facilitate groundwater development, such as

    the provision of credit by agricultural cooperatives for pump and well investment,

    accelerated the process. These exogenous changes in the 1990s promoted the

    dissemination of private wells.

    One could argue that there is another reason: the deterioration of tank systems

    induced farmers to install private wells. We encountered such opinions during our field

    interviews and thus do not deny this direction of causality. At the same time, however, it

    is important to note that the sharp decline in the investment and operation costs of

    private well systems is also a strong driving force for the dissemination of private wells.

  • 9

    This paper examines some of the consequences of this phenomenon; specifically,

    it attempts to determine whether the diffusion of private well irrigation leads to a

    deterioration in tank management and tank quality, and ultimately to greater poverty and

    inequality. To understand how this process proceeds, we advance our hypotheses in the

    following subsection.

    Hypotheses

    The literature on collective action argues that if farmers have ready access to

    earning activities that are not reliant on local commons, their incentive to devote

    themselves to the collective management of such local commons will be reduced

    (Agrawal, 2001; Kikuchi, et al., 2001). Because of the tanks’ technological features

    explained previously, once such farmers exit from collective management, it becomes

    difficult to provide a sufficient level of tank maintenance activities. Thus, we

    hypothesize the following:

    Hypothesis 1

    As the number of farmers with access to private well irrigation systems grows, it

    becomes more difficult to provide a sufficient level of collective management of tank

  • 10

    irrigation systems.

    What will happen to farmers’ livelihoods if Hypothesis 1 holds? When tanks are

    well maintained, private wells are usually used for supplementary irrigation at the

    critical stages of rice cultivation. As explained before, by improving water control at

    these stages, the availability of well irrigation increases rice yields (Palanisami, 2000).

    Even if the tanks become less well maintained, yields for these farmers are protected

    because they have recourse to wells. The situation is quite different for farmers who

    cannot use private wells. While they do not suffer the complete loss of their rice harvest,

    they face lower yields because they are totally dependent on the insufficiently

    maintained tanks. This leads us to hypothesize the following:

    Hypothesis 2

    The yields of farmers who use only tank irrigation because they cannot access

    private wells are lower than the yields of farmers who can access wells. The decline in

    tank management results in much lower rice yields only among farmers without access

    to private wells.

  • 11

    Whether this leads to greater poverty and inequality is an empirical question.

    One income compensation strategy usually adopted by farmers without access to wells

    is to work as agricultural laborers for more productive farmers, who are usually farmers

    using private wells. If the labor demand increases appreciably with the greater water

    availability from private wells, the farmers without access may be able to compensate

    partially for their income loss caused by the yield decline. Another possible strategy is

    to diversify their income sources into non-agricultural activities. If these strategies are

    available for the farmers without access to wells, their incomes may not decline

    drastically. On the other hand, if these strategies are not available and their income is

    generated predominantly from their own rice plots that receive less and less water from

    the silted tanks, the lower yields will translate into lower income. Thus, our third

    hypothesis follows:

    Hypothesis 3

    Unless the farmers without access to private wells can sufficiently diversify

    their income sources to agricultural labor or non-agricultural work, the decline in tank

    irrigation management results in lower income for these farmers.

  • 12

    We test Hypothesis 1 in Section 4 and Hypotheses 2 and 3 in Section 5.

    3. Study site and data collection

    This study is based on our survey of 79 tank-irrigated villages randomly selected

    from four contiguous districts (Madurai, Ramnad, Virudunagar, and Sivaganga) in

    southern Tamil Nadu State, India. In these districts, rice is the dominant crop, irrigated

    mainly by tanks supplemented by wells. Other crops such as sorghum, millet, groundnut,

    cotton, chili, and sugarcane are cultivated with or without irrigation. In each village, we

    conducted a group interview to collect information on the management of tank irrigation

    as well as on village characteristics. When a village uses several tanks, we identified the

    most important one through the group interview and collected information on that

    particular tank. We also interviewed 450 rice-farming households, randomly selected

    with a sample of 5 or 6 households from each village. Due to the focus of this study, we

    excluded non-farmers from the sample. The authors collected the data in 1999. Normal

    rainfall was recorded at the study sites in the survey year. We observed no case wherein

    collective tank management was not conducted due simply to insufficient rainfall.

  • 13

    4. Determinants of collective management

    We test the first hypothesis postulated in Section 2 by means of a cross-section

    regression analysis based on sample village observations. For this purpose, we must

    specify the variables to measure the changes in the quality of collective management as

    well as the factors underlying the changes.

    Measuring collective management

    In order to measure the decline in collective management, we must evaluate the

    overall status of the collective actions devoted to tank management in the survey year as

    compared with the past. There are two approaches: (1) physical performance indicators,

    which measure the outcomes of collective action; and (2) more direct measures of

    cooperation, which evaluate the degree of cooperation.3 The former approach is not

    appropriate for our case due to difficulties in isolating the current status of irrigation

    from the influence of exogenous environmental conditions and from accumulated past

    successes or failures in collective management. Therefore, we use the latter approach,

    3 Examples of the former approach include Bardhan (2000), who uses the index of the quality of the maintenance of distributaries and channels, and Dayton-Johnson (2000), who uses the conditions of canals as the proxy for the existence of collective action. Bardhan (2000) also uses the latter approach when he uses the number of conflicts and the frequency of rule violations among beneficiaries. Another example of the latter approach is Fujiie et al. (2005), who measure cooperation in terms of the success or failure in organizing several water management–related activities.

  • 14

    although this approach also presents difficulties. Past studies generate a dichotomous

    variable because of the difficulty in objectively ranking the degree of cooperation. We

    were able to generate a dummy for each of the three tasks of collective management

    explained in Section 2. However, evaluating each separately will not necessarily provide

    useful information regarding the overall status because the activities may be mutually

    substitutable, that is, the lack of one activity does not necessarily indicate an overall

    decline (Fujiie et al., 2005). Moreover, the lack of de-silting and channel cleaning does

    not necessarily indicate that the management level declined in the survey year because

    such activities are carried out according to need.4 In order for the second approach to

    produce appropriate measurements, we must be able to measure the overall status in the

    survey year.

    The variable that we chose to implement in the second approach to measuring

    collective management is the dichotomous response of key village informants to the

    question of whether the informal water users’ organization (WUO) is active or inactive

    in the survey year; the dummy takes the value one if inactive. We consider this dummy

    variable to be an appropriate proxy for measuring tank management activity because,

    4 The need for channel cleaning varies across villages depending on the structure of the irrigation systems and their environment. Some villages require channel cleaning annually, while others may need it only biennially, or even less frequently. The need for de-silting work arises much less frequently, usually once or twice in ten years.

  • 15

    first, it evaluates the overall status of collective management, and, second, it evaluates

    the status in the survey year. Although this variable is somewhat arbitrary as it is based

    on subjective judgment, it is the best available proxy that we were able to identify,

    performing better in the regression analysis than other proxy variables.5

    Using this dummy as our measure, we classified the villages into those with and

    those without active collective management, and we found that the number of “inactive

    villages” (that is, without active collective management) is 31 (39%) and the number of

    “active villages” is 48 (61%).

    Determinants of collective management

    To test Hypothesis 1, the explanatory variable we use is the density of private

    wells in the tank command area. However, there may be reason for concern that the

    current number of private wells may be endogenously determined in the model in that

    5 This inactive WUO dummy has a high correlation (correlation coefficient 0.75) with a dummy that becomes one when channel cleaning had not been conducted in the last three years, indicating the consistency of villagers’ cleaning behavior and the subjective evaluation of the overall status. However, the channel cleaning dummy was not used because it failed to produce reasonable econometric results in the following section. The inactive WUO dummy is consistent also with water supply conditions. Among the inactive villages according to the classification of our variable, 48% of these villages claimed that the availability of tank water had worsened, whereas the corresponding percentage goes down to 29% in the active villages. Moreover, in the active villages, even in those that claimed that the situation had worsened, the majority claimed that the reason was bad rainfall rather than the poor management of irrigation facilities, whereas this was reversed in the inactive villages. The regression analysis with the dependent dummy of water availability did not produce reasonable results either. The low performance of these two alternative dummies stems from the shortcomings explained in the first paragraph of this section.

  • 16

    inactive management may cause farmers to switch to private wells. To circumvent this

    problem, we apply the instrumental variable (IV) method, using the relative cost of

    pump sets and the relative cost of well digging to paddy price as the identifying

    instruments.6 Note that if we obtain a significant coefficient of this well density

    variable, this simply indicates causality from private well dissemination to inactive

    management without denying a possible reverse causality. In other words, what we can

    confirm from our regression analyses is that although such a reverse causality possibly

    exists, the direction from private well dissemination to inactive management can also be

    a strong driving force behind failure in collective management.

    We also control the other determinants suggested by the literature on collective

    action. Relying on a synthesis by Agrawal (2001), and also on an empirical study of

    tank irrigation management in Tamil Nadu by Bardhan (2000), we divide the other

    factors into six categories: exit options, heterogeneity, group size, government

    interventions, destructive shocks, and weather.7 The descriptive statistics of the

    variables are presented in Appendix Table A1.

    6 The cost of pump set consists of the cost of pump with a particular horsepower and the cost of equipments typical in a survey village. The cost of digging is the cost required to dig a typical depth of well in a village. These costs vary across villages as the depth of well and the required pump set differ across villages, depending on geographical conditions and the locations of aquifer. 7 Agrawal’s (2001) synthesis relies on three major contributors in this area, that is, Wade (1988), Ostrom (1990), and Baland and Platteau (1996), supplemented by other studies.

  • 17

    To capture the accessibility to exit options, four variables are employed in our

    regression analysis: (1) the percentage of high-school graduates in a village, (2) the

    percentage of college graduates in a village, (3) male wage rate, and (4) agricultural area

    physically non-feasible for tank irrigation per agricultural household. All these variables

    are expected to have positive coefficients as they increase the attractiveness of activities

    other than rice cultivation.

    Among the variables of the second category, heterogeneity variables, we include

    the two variables that measure wealth heterogeneity: (1) the Gini coefficient and its

    squared term of animal holdings and (2) of tank-irrigable plot size. The squared terms

    are included to capture the inverted U-shape relationship between heterogeneity and

    inactive management (Bardhan, 2000; Dayton-Johnson and Bardhan, 2002).

    The third category, group size, is measured by the number of households having

    agricultural land in the tank command area. Along the theme of Olson (1965), the

    positive relationship between group size and inactive collective actions is expected.

    However, in the context of the tank management, a large group is less likely to suffer

    labor scarcity that would arise when a certain amount of labor input is required to

    maintain the indivisible tank technology. Hence, the effect of this variable is an

    empirical question, as empirically observed by Bardhan (2000).

  • 18

    Regarding the fourth category, government interventions, one relevant policy

    variable is the percentage length of the water supply channel lined by blocks and cement.

    This construction work is done by the Public Works Department (PWD) with funds

    from the government or from international aid programs. According to a specialist at

    Tamil Nadu Agricultural University, the selection of villages by the PWD was more or

    less at random. Channel lining reduces water loss in delivery and also eases cleaning,

    making tank irrigation more profitable with less labor. Hence, even if private well users

    exit from collective management, the introduction of this labor-saving technology

    makes management feasible by the remaining formal users. Thus, we postulate that tank

    management is less likely to be inactive when the channels are lined (negative

    coefficient). Another variable is a PWD tank dummy, which occurs if the PWD is

    supposed to perform tank de-silting. Although if this happens villagers may come to

    rely on the government even for those activities that are supposed to be the

    responsibility of the local water users’ organization, this may also enhance collective

    management by reducing the burden on the local organization; the direction of the effect

    is an empirical question.

    The fifth category, destructive shocks, includes (1) a dummy of at least one

    ethnic or religious conflict within a village in the last ten years and (2) the number of

  • 19

    droughts. As the literature argues, after experiencing such destructive shocks, collective

    management tends to disappear (positive coefficients of these variables) (Baland and

    Platteau, 1996; Sethi and Somanthan, 1996). The last category is weather and it is

    measured by block-level annual rainfall in the survey year.

    Regression results

    The results of the regression analyses are presented in Table 1. In addition to the

    probit model results, we report the linear probability model results, first, because the

    probit model cannot include one policy variable, the percentage of channel lining, due

    to the perfect prediction problem, and, second, because the linear model can provide

    diagnostic statistics that confirm the validity of our IV specification.8 The test statistics

    for the linear IV analysis presented in the lower part of Table 1 indicate that the current

    density is an endogenous variable (F test for endogeneity) but it is significantly

    predicted by the identifying instrumental variables (first-stage F test) that can be

    considered as exogenous to the model (χ2 test for over identification), providing

    confidence in the validity of the model specification (Wooldridge, 2002). The first-stage

    regression of the well density function (not reported here) indicates that the coefficient

    8 To circumvent the heteroskedasticity problem in the application of OLS to the dichotomous dependent variable, we report the robust standard errors in our OLS results.

  • 20

    of the relative price of pump sets is negative and highly significant, which is consistent

    with our observation of the dissemination of private wells with a reduction in pump

    costs. The qualitative results of our IV probit model are the same as those of our linear

    model. A key finding from these IV results is that the density of wells is statistically

    significant with a positive sign. Our supplementary analyses also find two supportive

    empirical results which are presented in Appendix. Hence, we conclude that the results

    support Hypothesis 1. This finding is consistent with Palanisami and Easter’s (2000)

    study on tank irrigation in other regions in Tamil Nadu.

    Turning to the other explanatory variables, the exit options are not statistically

    significant except for the male wage rate in the probit model. The educational variables

    become insignificant presumably because these variables capture not only educated

    people’s likelihood of exit (a positive coefficient) but also the effect of their leadership

    for collective management as local elites (a negative coefficient) (Meinzen-Dick et al.,

    2002b). Regarding wealth heterogeneity, the Gini of plot size and its squared term are

    strongly significant. Their signs are consistent with the inverted U-shape relationship in

    all four models, and thus are consistent with Bardhan’s (2000) empirical study.9 This

    result confirms the importance of socioeconomic factors for collective management. As

    9 For example, turning point value of Gini is 0.322 for linear IV or 0.314 for Probit IV which is 0.549 or 0.452 standard deviation higher than the mean value (=0.275).

  • 21

    for the two kinds of destructive shocks, the number of droughts is significantly positive.

    This result suggests that even in villages where collective management provides

    positive economic returns to the participants, this collective management may disappear

    due to shocks. Turning to the policy variable, as we have postulated, the percentage of

    channel lining in the linear probability models is highly significant with a negative sign.

    Thus, this policy could be an effective intervention tool for the revitalization of

    collective management.

    5. Impact on rice yields and income

    Binary comparison

    To develop an understanding of the impact of the decline in collective

    management, we compare rice yields, monthly income, monthly consumption value,

    and a subjective poverty assessment among 171 households in 31 inactive villages and

    279 households in 48 active villages. These data appear in Table 2. The difference in

    rice yields is clear: row (1) shows that rice yield in kg per hectare is lower in the

    inactive villages than in the active villages, and the difference is statistically significant.

    Note, however, that the difference is merely 7.6%, which seems rather small. The lower

    yield due to inactive management is likely largely compensated for by the existence of a

  • 22

    larger number of private well users in the inactive villages than in the active villages.

    Inequality measured by the Gini coefficient is higher among households in the inactive

    villages than in the active villages, indicating that yield variation is larger in the former

    than in the latter. Likewise, although the levels are very small, the average of the

    village-level Gini coefficients for the inactive villages is higher than that for the active

    villages, and the difference is statistically significant.

    A similar structure is observed in row (2) in the adult equivalent per capita

    monthly income: that is, lower income and higher inequality in the inactive villages.10

    Comparison of the poverty indexes shows that both the incidence of poverty and the

    poverty gap are higher in the inactive villages.11

    Comparison of the consumption value shows a slightly different picture, though

    the conclusions are essentially the same. The mean is lower in the inactive villages but

    the difference is not statistically significant, presumably because of the existence of

    consumption smoothing mechanisms to some extent. The magnitudes of the Gini are

    moderately higher for the inactive villages and significantly different from those of the 10 The weights used for computation of adult equivalent household size are 0.5 for a child of age below 5 years, 0.73 for a child aged 6-10, 0.83 for a child aged 11-14, 0.83 for a female above age 14, and 1.0 for males above age 14 (Rao, 1983). Household members living outside of the household because of work are excluded but members living outside because of educational pursuit are included as members of the household, on the assumption that students receive financial support from the household. 11 Use of the national poverty line of Rs. 324 monthly per capita for 1993-4, instead of US$ 1, does not change the qualitative results. The same applies to the comparison of the consumption value.

  • 23

    active villages.12 Moreover, poverty is more severe in the inactive villages in terms of

    both the ratio and the gap.13 These observations are consistent with the villagers’

    subjective assessment of their poverty conditions presented in row (4): a larger

    percentage of villagers in the inactive villages judged that they were in serious poverty

    than villagers in the active villages.

    In summary, the binary comparison suggests that inactive collective

    management is associated with greater poverty and inequality presumably because of

    insufficient income compensation from agricultural labor and non-agricultural work

    among farmers without access to private wells in the inactive villages. The regression

    analyses in the following subsection examine whether and to what extent this

    consequence is explained by inactive collective management and access to private wells,

    controlling for other covariates.

    Variables for regression analyses

    We estimate the regression functions explaining rice yield, agricultural labor

    income, non-agricultural income, total income, and consumption value. To test 12 The national-level Gini coefficient based on expenditure data in 1999-2000 was 32.5, which is very close to our Gini coefficients (all households in each category), indicating the appropriateness of our data (World Bank, 2004). 13 The national-level head count ratio of poverty and poverty gap are 34.7 and 8.2, respectively, in the 1999-2000 data (World Bank, 2004). Our figures show higher magnitudes, reflecting the high incidence of poverty in rural areas.

  • 24

    Hypotheses 2 and 3, we include the village-level inactive management dummy as one of

    the explanatory variables. To confirm that the decline in village-level collective

    management is exogenous to each individual in the villages, we apply the F-test for

    endogeneity and confirm that it is not necessary for this variable to be instrumented.14

    Also important is the household-level variable that measures inaccessibility to

    private wells. This is a dichotomous variable: non-well-owners who did not buy water

    from well-owners are classified into the no-access group (dummy=1), whereas owners

    and non-owners with water transaction records are classified into the access group

    (dummy=0). The differential impacts of no access to wells with and without collective

    management are captured by considering four different cases. Using the case of farmers

    having access to wells at an active village as the base (Access&Active), we construct

    three irrigation status dummies: (1) no access at an active village (No Access&Active),

    (2) no access at an inactive village (No Access&Inactive), and (3) access at an inactive

    village (Access&Inactive).

    14 The identifying instrumental variables used here are the village-level variable used in our analyses of the determinants of inactive collective management. These instruments are jointly significant in the first-stage F-test. The variable measuring inaccessibility to wells, which might be an endogenous variable, as we discuss later, is excluded from the model in order to keep all the variables other than the inactive collective management dummy exogenous. The F-values and the corresponding p-values on the residuals from the first-stage prediction of inactive collective management (F-test for endogeneity) are F=0.02 and p=0.88 for the rice yield regression, F=2.20 and p=0.14 for the consumption regression, and F=0.48 and p=0.50 for the income regression, indicating that the inactive management dummy is exogenous and use of the OLS model will not cause serious problems.

  • 25

    In Table 3, we summarize the expected signs on these irrigation status dummies.

    Note that the base (Access&Active) is the most irrigation-water-sufficient case. The

    coefficients of the dummies capture the differences from this base. Hence, in the rice

    yield function, if Hypothesis 2 holds, we observe negative coefficients on the first two

    dummies, No access&Active and No access&Inactive, at a larger magnitude for the

    second one. As long as private wells provide sufficient irrigation water, farmers achieve

    a high yield even in an inactive village; thus, the coefficient of the Access&Inactive

    dummy is expected to have no significant difference from the base. Turning to the

    agricultural labor income function, if income is supplemented by an increase in

    agricultural labor income, we should observe positive coefficients on the first two

    dummies at a larger magnitude for the second one. The same structure can be observed

    in the non-agricultural income function. However, since accessibility to non-agricultural

    occupations is largely determined by level of education rather than by irrigation status,

    we may not observe significant coefficients on the irrigation status dummies. Finally, if

    supplemental income is large enough, in the total income and consumption value

    functions, we should not observe any significant coefficients on the irrigation status

    dummies. On the other hand, if supplemental income is insufficient, we should observe

    negative coefficients again on the first two dummies at a larger magnitude for the

  • 26

    second one.

    To measure irrigation status, we must also control for the distance from the

    irrigation source to farmers’ fields because, in gravity irrigation systems like tank

    systems, this distance affects water availability. Moreover, the effect of distance may

    vary depending on the status of collective management and well access. In our

    explanatory variables, we include not only the distance from the tank but also the

    interaction of distance with our three irrigation status dummies.

    Consequently, our regression equations include six explanatory variables

    containing information on the status of accessibility to wells. Accessibility to wells,

    however, potentially entails endogeneity and measurement biases.15 These potential

    biases are controlled by the instrumental variable method.16

    The other determinants included in the rice yield regression are a set of

    household human and physical asset variables, socioeconomic characteristics, and

    15 There are two kinds of potential bias. First, under our definition of this dummy variable, the no-access group would include non-owner farmers who actually had access to well irrigation but chose not to use it because they had enough water from tanks or rainfall. These farmers presumably achieve yields and income as high as those of the farmers who use wells. The incorrect inclusion of them in the no-access group would result in an underestimation of the negative impact of non-access. Second, if high-income farmers selectively became well-owners, the impact of non-access would be overestimated. 16 The identifying instrumental variables that explain the six potentially endogenous variables include not only those that explain non-access to wells—such as the number of water sellers in a village, the number of water buyers in a village, the cost of well digging and its squared term, and the value of house building—but also the interactions of those variables with the inactive management dummy and with distance from the tank (Wooldridge, 2002).

  • 27

    village-level characteristics. The descriptive statistics are presented in Appendix Table

    A4. The household asset variables include (1) the proportion of working members with

    primary, secondary, and college-level schooling, respectively; (2) the average age of a

    working member and its squared term; (3) the size of the rice plot and its squared term;

    (4) the value of animal holdings per working member and its squared term; (5) the

    number of working members; and (6) a tractor owner dummy. The socioeconomic

    variable is the gender of the household head (male=1). Village-level differences are

    controlled by the male wage rate, block-level annual rainfall, the dummy measuring

    accessibility to the village by a vehicle, and the percentage of households wired for

    electricity. In the regressions other than the rice yield function, instead of rice plot size,

    we use (1) the size of tank-irrigable plots per working member and its squared term and

    (2) the size of tank-non-irrigable plots per working member and its squared term. Since

    the consumption value is affected by permanent household income instead of income

    for a particular year, average rainfall over the last ten years is used rather than annual

    rainfall.

    Regression results

    The regression results for yield, agricultural labor income, and non-agricultural

  • 28

    income are reported in Table 4, and the results for total income and consumption value

    in Table 5. In the functions in Table 4, endogeneity is not detected, thus we show the

    OLS results alone. Meanwhile, Table 5 shows both the OLS and IV results, since the

    F-tests indicate the possibility of endogeneity. In Table 5, the F-tests on the instruments

    in the first-stage regression are highly significant for all six endogenous variables,

    indicating high predictive power. The over-identification tests show the difficulty of

    rejection of the exogeneity of the instruments at the 5% significance level, adding

    confidence to the validity of our IV specifications.

    The results of the rice yield function in Table 4 show the expected signs and

    magnitudes for the No access&Active and No access&Inactive dummies. A key finding

    from this is that compared with the yields of farmers with access to wells in collective

    management active villages (base case), the yields of farmers without access to wells is

    337 kg lower even in the same active villages, confirming the importance of private

    wells as a supplementary irrigation source. Another key finding, this one related to

    inactive villages, is that in those villages, the yield gap between farmers with access and

    those without is becoming wider (863 kg).17 This is larger by far than the yield gap in

    17 Note that, unexpectedly, the coefficient of the Access&Inactive dummy is positive and significant (773.2 kg). Note also that the distance has a negative effect only among Access&Inactive farmers; at the average distance from the tank (0.545 km), this variable has a negative effect of 664 kg. Hence, the yield gap in inactive villages between the farmers without access to wells and those with access to wells is computed as 754.4+(773.2 – 664.6)=863 kg.

  • 29

    the active villages noted above. Based on this result, we conclude that Hypothesis 2

    holds. The results also indicate that all village characteristics are not significant. This

    feature holds for all the following regression functions except for the agricultural labor

    income function. Presumably, our key village variable, collective management status,

    representatively captures the village-level differences in our tank-irrigated villages, and

    thus its inclusion reduces the importance of the other village-level variables.

    The results for the agricultural labor income function in Table 4 also show the

    expected signs and magnitudes for the irrigation status dummies, indicating that lower

    income is compensated for by agricultural labor. However, the amount of compensation

    is not large in either case: Rs. 10.4 or Rs. 16.8 per person per month. In the

    non-agricultural income function, the insignificant coefficients for the first two

    dummies indicate that this income source is not available to either No access&Active

    farmers or No access&Inactive farmers as a supplemental income source. Rather,

    non-agricultural income is determined by the proportion of college-level graduates to

    the number of working members in a household. These results imply that opportunities

    for income diversification are limited, and thus we expect lower income and

    consumption among farmers without access to private wells in Table 5.

    As expected, the coefficients of No access&Active and No access&Inactive are

  • 30

    negative at larger magnitude for the second one. The IV results on total income indicate

    that in the active villages, the gap of total income between the farmers with and those

    without access to wells is Rs. 189.1, becoming wider (Rs. 269.5) in the inactive

    villages.18 The same qualitative pattern holds for the consumption value function,

    except for the insignificant coefficient of the distance variable. Given an average

    distance for all farmers of 0.4 km, the impact of distance is not large, and thus it is

    probably not captured as significant in the consumption value function.

    Counter-factual analysis

    The regression analyses indicate that farmers without access to wells suffer not

    only lower yields but also a lower income and consumption value when collective

    management declines. Although the negative coefficients are statistically significant, the

    magnitudes of the impacts may be marginal. Hence, one may raise a question as to

    whether the lower income caused by the decline in collective management is large

    18 Two remarks are necessary here. First, comparison of the OLS and IV results shows the OLS’s overestimation of the negative effects, implying that the root of the bias is in the rich farmers’ self-selection of being well-owners. Since income level is important to well ownership but yield, agricultural labor income, and non-agricultural income alone may not be, the three functions in Table 4 do not suffer an endogeneity problem. Second, the coefficients of Access&Inactive are no longer significant. Although the farmers with access to wells in the inactive villages achieve high yields, they grow rice intensively, with the use of wells as the primary source of irrigation. Sakurai and Palanisami (2001) show that the intensive use of wells does not necessarily result in high profit as it requires greater operation and maintenance costs than does tank management. Hence, no significant difference in profitability and thus in income is observed.

  • 31

    enough to result in greater poverty and inequality in the inactive villages. In other words,

    will the revitalization of collective management help alleviate poverty and inequality?

    Using the regression results and assuming active collective management in all the

    villages, we predict yield, total income, and consumption value. These descriptive

    statistics, including the Gini and the poverty indexes computed from the predicted

    values, are added to Table 2 as column (A-2) and are shown as Table 6.19 The last

    column in Table 6 shows the differences between the inactive villages under the

    counter-factual assumption and the actual active villages.

    The differences in the mean values are no longer significant for either variable.

    The Gini coefficients of income and consumption in the inactive villages have declined,

    resulting in insignificant differences in the comparison of village-level averages.

    Comparison of yields still indicates the existence of significant differences, yet the

    levels of the Gini coefficients themselves have become very small. The changes in the

    poverty indexes show that the poverty ratio and gap are reduced to the levels of the

    active villages. These results indicate that the negative impacts from the decline in

    collective management on farmers without access to wells are so large that the

    revitalization of collective management can contribute significantly to reductions in 19 For comparability with the figures in Table 2, the residuals from the actual data are added back to the counter-factual predicted value. Otherwise, the Gini, which measures a kind of variation, becomes incomparably small.

  • 32

    poverty and inequality.

    6. Conclusion and policy implications

    Using village- and household-level data collected in Tamil Nadu, India, we

    examined the factors underlying the decline in collective management of tank irrigation

    systems and the impact of that decline on rural livelihoods, especially in terms of

    poverty and inequality. A key conclusion of our regression analyses and counter-factual

    analysis is that the diffusion of private wells is one of the factors accelerating the

    decline in collective management, and that this decline leads to lower yields only

    among farmers without access to private wells. Our analyses also find that since these

    without-access farmers cannot sufficiently compensate for their lower income by

    diversifying income sources to agricultural labor or to non-agricultural work, lower

    yields translate into lower income. Farmers with access to private wells, by contrast, can

    continue to obtain high yields and high levels of income. As a result of this situation,

    poverty and inequality increase; thus, through this process, the decline in collective

    management carries social costs. According to our field observations in inactive villages,

    this consequence has yet to reach the point where without-access farmers sell their land

    to with-access farmers. The former usually leave their land fallow, relying on a

  • 33

    subsidized rice quota from public ration shops for their living.

    One of the major contributing factors to the decline is the exit behavior by some

    farmers who have gained alternative irrigation sources such as private wells. It is

    difficult to deter their exodus from collective management because they do not suffer

    the consequences of the deterioration in tank performance, unlike the remaining farmers.

    The number of exiting farmers will inevitably tend to increase in response to the

    development of small or medium-size irrigation technologies that are used by individual

    farmers. Unless less labor-intensive systems are introduced or some kind of support is

    given, it will be difficult to maintain collective tank management.

    One promising possibility suggested by our analysis is the use of lined channels

    with tank systems. This technology significantly reduces the labor required for

    maintenance work and also increases water availability by minimizing seepage.

    Although thus far construction of lined channels has been undertaken by the PWD, if

    the return on investment is assured, WUOs may decide to take over the task as a local

    public goods initiative. It will be important to conduct detailed cost-benefit analyses on

    the impact of channel lining and, if warranted, design appropriate support programs.

    Charging an appropriate fee for electricity would also help prevent a decline in

    collective management. Under the present practice of free electricity for agricultural

  • 34

    purposes, the number of electric pumps tends to be more than the social optimum,

    resulting in both overexploitation of groundwater and a decline in collective

    management. A revision of the present policy must be seriously considered.

    Collective management may still decline even with the policies mentioned

    above because some socioeconomic factors such as village-level heterogeneity and

    destructive shocks can also cause a decline. Hence, an alternative approach to reduce

    poverty and inequality is to implement policies that increase farmers’ prevention of

    irrigation water shortages. The development and introduction of a drought-tolerant rice

    variety is one possibility. Educational development also contributes by expanding

    farmers’ income sources to non-agricultural activities. More detailed policy implications

    could be derived through further analyses on the impacts of new rice technology and

    educational development on water-constrained poor farmers, which we leave for future

    research.

  • 35

    Acknowledgements

    This study was funded by Global Environment Research Fund through Ministry of

    Environment, Japan. The authors acknowledge useful comments from two anonymous

    referees, Yujiro Hayami, Keijiro Otsuka, and Daiji Kawaguchi as well as editorial

    assistance from Suzanne Akiyama and Paul Kandasamy.

  • 36

    Appendix Two supportive empirical results on the impact of well dissemination on collective management

    In order to confirm our claim, we conduct two regression analyses. First, we

    check the existence of the possible reverse causality from the decline in tank

    management to the installation of private wells. For this purpose, we run a

    household-level probit model explaining the determinants of private well ownership.

    The dependent variable is the dummy taking the value one if a household owns at least

    one private well. A key explanatory variable is the village-level status of collective

    management, which is exogenous to each individual household as we will show in the

    following section. Other important village-level variables include the relative cost of

    pump sets, the relative cost of well digging, and the percentage of households with

    electricity. Access to electricity is important as motor pumps are the most popular type

    in Tamil Nadu. Household-level characteristics such as wealth and education are also

    included. An important finding from the results reported in Appendix Table A2 is that

    the probability of well ownership increases significantly with cheaper pump prices,

    greater access to electricity, and larger physical and human capital, but not significantly

    with the status of collective management, indicating the relative unimportance of the

    reverse causality.

  • 37

    Second, if the causality is as we claim it is, we would observe an inverted

    U-shape relationship between the productivity of farmers who rely only on tanks and

    the density of wells in the tank command area. Since the private well users reduce the

    use of tank water, tank water availability and thus the productivity of the remaining tank

    users would increase initially until the tanks became seriously silted. Using a subsample

    of farmers relying only on tanks, we regress the rice yield per hectare on the density of

    private wells and its squared term as well as on the other relevant explanatory variables

    which are the household and village characteristics used for the yield regression in Table 4. The

    results in Appendix Table A3 are consistent with our postulate, indicating that yield

    increases until the density reaches 0.6 standard deviations higher than the mean value.

    With these two pieces of supportive evidence, we claim that the dissemination of private

    wells, which has been accelerated by the recent reduction in investment and operation

    costs, has a dominant impact on the decline in collective management.

  • 38

    References

    Agrawal, A., 2001. Common resources and institutional sustainability. In: Ostrom, E.,

    Dietz, T., Dolsak, N., Stern, P. C., Stonich, S., Weber E. U., (Eds.) The Drama of

    the Commons, National Academy Press, Washington, DC, pp. 41-85.

    Baland, J. M., Platteau, J. P., 1996. Halting degradation of natural resources: is there a

    role for rural communities? Oxford University Press, Oxford.

    Bardhan, P., 2000. Irrigation and cooperation: an empirical analysis of 48 irrigation

    communities in South India, Economic Development and Cultural Change.

    48(4), 847-65.

    Bardhan, P., Dayton-Johnson, J., 2001. Unequal irrigators: heterogeneity and commons

    management in large-scale multivariate research. In: Ostrom, E., Dietz, T.,

    Dolsak, N., Stern, P. C., Stonich, S., Weber E. U., (Eds.) The Drama of the

    Commons, National Academy Press, Washington, DC, pp. 87-112.

    Dayton-Johnson, J., 2000. Determinants of collective action on the local commons: a

    model with evidence from Mexico, J. of Development Econ. 62, 181-208.

    Dayton-Johnson, J. Bardhan, P., 2002. Inequality and conservation on the local

    commons: a theoretical exercise, The Economic J. 112, 577-602.

  • 39

    Director of Statistics, various issues. Season and Crop Report of Tamil Nadu, Director

    of Statistics, Government of Tamil Nadu, Tamil Nadu, India.

    Fertilizer Association of India, various issues. Fertilizer statistics, Fertilizer Association

    of India, New Delhi.

    Fujiie, M., Hayami, Y., Kikuchi, M., 2005. The conditions of collective action for local

    commons management: the case of irrigation in the Philippines, Agric. Econ.

    33(2), 179-189.

    Government of India, various issues. Economic Survey, Economic Division, Ministry of

    Finance, Government of India, New Delhi.

    Jodha, N. S., 1986. Common property resources and rural poor in dry regions of India.

    Economic and Political Weekly, 21, 1169-81.

    Kikuchi, M., Fujita, M., Hayami Y., 2001. State, community, and market in the

    deterioration of a national irrigation system in the Philippines. In: Aoki, M.,

    Hayami, Y. (Eds.) Communities and Markets in Economic Development, Oxford

    University Press, Oxford, pp. 265-294.

    Meinzen-Dick, R., Knox, A., Place, F., Swallow B., 2002a. Innovation in natural

    resource management, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

    Meinzen-Dick, R., Raju, K. V., and Gulati, A., 2002b. What affects organization and

  • 40

    collective action for managing resources? Evidence from canal irrigation

    systems in India, World Development. 30(4), 649-666.

    Olson, M., 1965. The logic of collective action, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

    Ostrom, E., 1990. Governing the commons, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., Walker J., 1994. Rules, games, and common-pool resources,

    University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.

    Palanisami, K., 2000. Tank irrigation: revival for prosperity, Asian Publishing Service,

    New Delhi.

    Palanisami, K., Easter, K. W., 2000. Tank irrigation in the 21st century-what next?

    Discovery Publishing House, New Delhi.

    Rao, V. K. R.V., 1983, Food, nutrition and poverty in India, Vikas Publishing House,

    New Delhi.

    Sakurai, T., Palanisami K., 2001. Tank irrigation management as a local common

    property: the case of Tamil Nadu, India. Agric. Econ. 25, 273-283.

    Sethi, R., Somanthan E., 1996. The evolution of social norms in common property

    resource use. Am. Economic Rev. 86(4), 766-88.

    Singh, K., 1994. Managing common pool resources: principles and case studies, Oxford

    University Press, Delhi.

  • 41

    Southern India Engineering Manufacturers’ Association, various issues, Recommended

    List Prices, Southern India Engineering Manufacturers’ Association,

    Coimbatore, India.

    Wade, R., 1988. Village republics: economic conditions for collective action in South

    India, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Wooldridge, J. M., 2002. Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, MIT

    Press, Cambridge.

    World Bank, 2004. World development indicators, World Bank, Washington, DC.

  • 42

    Table 1: Results of the regression analyses explaining the decline in collective management in villages

    Dep. Var.: collective management (inactive=1)

    Linear probability model Probit model OLS IV Probit IV probit Private well Density of well in tank command areaa (# / ha) 0.58 1.22 0.78 2.11 (1.30) (2.34)** (0.83) (2.24)** Exit options Percentage of secondary school graduates 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02

    (1.10) (1.47) (1.24) (1.43) Percentage of college graduates -0.01 -0.02 -0.04 -0.01

    (0.90) (1.10) (0.78) (0.25) Male wage rate (Rs./day) 0.01 0.01 0.04 0.03 (1.22) (1.37) (1.97)** (2.16)** Tank un-irrigable agric. area/Ag HH (ha) -0.00 -0.00 -0.03 -0.03

    (0.18) (0.23) (0.39) (0.52) Heterogeneity Gini coefficient of value of animal holdings 1.22 1.28 1.86 -0.81

    (0.93) (0.95) (0.32) (0.18) -0.20 -0.45 2.02 2.88 Gini coefficient of value of animal holdings squared

    (0.16) (0.35) (0.35) (0.56) Gini coefficient of tank-irrigable plot size 7.61 7.47 24.66 14.08

    (3.67)*** (3.40)*** (3.31)*** (2.10)** -12.02 -11.57 -39.79 -22.39 Gini coefficient of tank-irrigable plot size squared

    (3.25)*** (2.95)*** (3.02)*** (1.97)** Size

    -0.10 -0.13 -0.34 -0.33 Number of HH having agric. land in tank command area (100HH) (1.04) (1.33) (0.98) (1.13)

    Government intervention Channel lining (%) -0.02 -0.02

    (2.65)** (2.38)** Tank type (PWD =1) -0.14 -0.24 -0.26 -0.59

    (1.06) (1.79)* (0.59) (1.42) Destructive shocks

    0.17 0.15 1.09 0.71 Ethnic or religious conflict in the last 10 years (yes=1) (0.94) (0.78) (2.01)** (1.47)

    Number of droughts in the last 10 years 0.03 0.04 0.11 0.13 (1.71)* (2.25)** (1.96)* (2.62)** Rainfall Annual rainfall (mm) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 (0.87) (0.88) (0.89) (0.51) Constant -1.82 -1.91 -8.16 -4.99 (2.92)*** (2.98)*** (3.55)*** (2.52)** F-stat for endogeneity test (H0: no endogeneity) 3.44 [0.06] χ2-stat for endogeneity test (H0: no endogeneity) 13.69 [0.00] Joint significant test on instruments (First-stage F test) 3.26 [0.04] χ2 stat for over identification test 1.64 [0.20] F-stat (H0: all slope coeff=0) 7.35 [0.00] 7.65 [0.00] χ2-stat (H0: all slope coeff=0) 36.55 [0.00] 41.38 [0.00]

    Heteroskedasticity robust z-statistics in parentheses for probit and IV probit analysis. Heteroskedasticity robust t-statistics in parentheses for OLS and IV analyses. Numbers in brackets are p-values. * significant at 10% level; **significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level a Instrumented variable. Identifying instruments are the cost of well digging and the cost of pump set relative to rice price.

  • 43

    Table 2: Comparison of rice yield, total income, consumption value, and subjective poverty assessment of sample households between collective management inactive villages and active villages

    (A) (B)

    Households in

    inactive villages

    (villages: n=31)

    (HH: n=171)

    Households in

    active villages

    (villages: n=48)

    (HH: n=279)

    Difference

    (A)-(B)

    (|t-ratio|)

    (1) Rice yield (kg/hectare)

    Mean 3499 3786 -287 (2.59)***

    Std. dev. 1275 1049

    Gini (all households in each category) 20.7 15.4 5.3

    Gini (average of village-level Gini) 9.8 6.7 3.1 (2.60)***

    (2) Per capita monthly income (Rs./person) a

    Mean 332 395 -63 (1.77)*

    Std. dev. 370 363

    Gini (all households in each category) 53.9 45.8 8.1

    Gini (average of village-level Gini) 39.8 30.9 8.9 (1.98)**

    Head count ratio of poverty (P0) b 58.5 48.3 10.2

    Poverty gap (P1) b 33.7 21.6 12.1

    (3) Per capita monthly consumption value (Rs./person) a

    Mean 308 336 -28 (1.46)

    Std. dev. 194 202

    Gini (all households in each category) 34.1 31.8 2.3

    Gini (average of village-level Gini) 23.2 20.4 2.8 (1.67)*

    Head count ratio of poverty (P0) b 52.0 45.5 6.5

    Poverty gap (P1) b 19.8 14.2 5.6

    (4) Subjective poverty assessment Percentage of villages assessing that the current condition of poverty is serious

    61 29

    * significant at 10% level; **significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level. a The value is converted into a per capita base using the adult equivalent number of present household members. See footnote 9 for details of the conversion method. b International poverty line of US$ 1 per day adjusted for purchasing power parity is used.

  • 44

    Table 3: Irrigation status dummy, irrigation water condition, and expected sign and magnitude

    Irrigation status dummy

    Irrigation water condition Expected sign and magnitude in

    Rice yield function

    Agric. labor income function

    Non-agric. income function

    Total income/consumption function

    No Access&Active Less sufficient (water from tanks is still available) − + + / 0 − / 0

    No Access&Inactive Severe − − + + + + / 0 − − / 0

    Acess&Inactive Sufficient as long as private wells provide water 0 0 0 0

    Access&Active (base) Sufficient na na na na

    Note: − : negative and significant (double negative indicates larger magnitude) +: positive and significant (double positive indicates larger magnitude) 0: insignificant +/0: sign and significance depend on cases −/0: sign and significance depend on cases

  • 45

    Table 4: Results of the regression analyses of the determinants of rice yield, agricultural labor income, and non-agricultural income

    Dep. var. Rice yield Adult equivalent per cap. monthly agric. labor

    income

    Adult equivalent per cap. monthly non-agric.

    income OLS OLS OLS Variables related with irrigation status

    No access&Active -337.0 10.4 10.9 (1.70)* (2.92)*** (0.59) No access&Inactive -754.4 16.8 -7.6 (2.11)** (2.44)** (0.32) Access&Inactive 773.2 -5.0 91.9 (2.37)** (1.00) (1.96)* Distance from tank (km) 120.3 -1.6 -11.1 (0.67) (0.46) (0.58) No access&Active*Distance -296.5 -4.6 5.9 (1.14) (0.96) (0.21) No access&Inactive*Distance -155.2 -9.2 -28.8 (0.41) (1.47) (1.11) Access&Inactive*Distance -1219.4 -0.3 -105.9 (3.51)*** (0.06) (1.75)*Household characteristics Primary educ. proportion a 376.1 1.1 -26.5 (1.36) (0.17) (1.10) Secondary educ. proportion a 668.0 -8.4 -13.0 (2.59)** (1.14) (0.58) College educ. proportion a 1033.6 -25.3 521.5 (1.78)* (2.55)** (2.38)** Av. age b 11.1 0.2 2.4 (0.19) (0.11) (0.34) Av. age sq. b -0.3 -0.0 -0.0 (0.37) (0.33) (0.48) Rice plot size (ha) -502.9 (2.36)** Rice plot size sq. (ha) 81.5

    (1.58) Av. tank-irrigable plots c (ha) -47.2 -137.0

    (2.61)** (2.20)** Av. tank-irrigable plots sq. b 22.3 89.8 (1.81)* (2.76)*** Av. tank-un-irrigable plots b (ha) -4.8 -17.0 (1.19) (0.55) Av. tank-un-irrigable plots sq. b 0.5 1.8 (0.66) (0.33) Av. value of animal holdings b (000 Rs.) 60.9 0.3 0.9 (3.16)*** (0.69) (0.41) Av. value of animal holdings sq. b -1.3 -0.0 -0.1 (2.32)** (0.45) (1.21) No. of working members 43.6 -1.1 -3.7 (1.50) (1.20) (0.82) Owner of tractor (owner=1) 37.3 44.2 -33.3 (0.08) (1.92)* (2.07)** Male HH head (male=1) 366.6 10.9 11.0 (1.26) (3.24)** (0.67)Village characteristics Male daily wage rate (Rs./day) 10.6 0.1 0.0 (0.89) (0.29) (0.04) Annual rainfall (mm) -0.1 -0.0 -0.0 (0.86) (0.39) (1.05)

    Accessibility by vehicle (yes=1) -12.8 -2.2 -1.1 (0.11) (0.99) (0.12) Percentage of HH with electricity (%) -7.1 0.2 0.2 (1.62) (1.64)* (0.70)

    Constant 3274.1 7.8 64.0 (2.49)** (0.19) (0.42)

    F-stat for endogeneity test (H0: no endogeneity) 0.88 [0.51] 0.09 [0.99] 1.38 [0.22]F-stat (H0: all slope coeff=0) 6.35 [0.00] 2.86 [0.00] 2.91 [0.00]Village clustering robust t-statistics in parentheses. Numbers in brackets are p-values. * significant at 10% level; **significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level. a The proportion to the number of working members. b Divided by the number of working members.

  • 46

    Table 5: Results of the regression analyses of the determinants of total income and consumption value

    Dep. var. Adult equivalent per cap. monthly income

    Adult equivalent per cap. monthly consumption value

    OLS IV OLS IVVariables related to irrigation status

    No access&Active c -210.9 -189.9 -84.1 -75.1 (3.65)*** (3.40)*** (2.87)*** (2.54)** No access&Inactive c -286.8 -269.5 -124.6 -119.1 (3.79)*** (3.60)*** (3.05)*** (3.06)*** Access&Inactive c -5.8 17.3 83.9 101.7 (0.06) (0.16) (1.37) (1.57) Distance from tank (km) -125.4 -119.1 -46.1 -50.7 (2.00)** (1.70)* (1.32) (1.30) No access&Active*Distance c 37.3 33.7 15.2 26.4 (0.52) (0.36) (0.37) (0.49) No access&Inactive*Distance c 41.2 29.9 23.5 26.5 (0.53) (0.35) (0.52) (0.55) Access&Inactive*Distance c -55.7 -70.0 -95.6 -96.5 (0.55) (0.63) (1.49) (1.40)Household characteristics Primary educ. proportion a -34.7 -30.5 105.0 107.7 (0.50) (0.44) (2.44)** (2.50)** Secondary educ. proportion a -23.9 -23.0 61.4 60.6 (0.39) (0.37) (1.65) (1.59) College educ. proportion a 684.3 685.3 476.6 475.9 (2.32)** (2.32)** (3.57)*** (3.55)*** Av. age b 9.8 9.3 -0.9 -1.4 (0.72) (0.69) (0.10) (0.14) Av. age sq. b -0.2 -0.2 -0.0 -0.0 (1.24) (1.22) (0.15) (0.10)

    Av. tank-irrigable plots b (ha) 442.8 453.7 287.9 293.2 (2.96)*** (3.05)*** (3.65)*** (3.76)*** Av. tank-irrigable plots sq. b 0.2 -2.0 -76.7 -76.9 (0.00) (0.02) (1.39) (1.41) Av. tank-un-irrigable plots b (ha.) 440.7 440.5 74.3 71.9 (5.35)*** (5.32)*** (1.64) (1.61) Av. tank-un-irrigable plots sq. b -94.3 -94.8 -16.6 -16.6 (4.19)*** (4.22)*** (1.67)* (1.68)* Av. value of animal holdings b (000 Rs.) 6.3 6.3 -0.9 -0.9 (1.10) (1.09) (0.23) (0.25) Av. value of animal holdings sq. b -0.2 -0.2 0.1 0.1 (0.71) (0.72) (0.66) (0.65) No. of working members 20.6 21.2 1.9 2.2 (2.26)** (2.33)** (0.39) (0.43) Owner of tractor (owner=1) 155.8 151.4 -0.5 -2.9 (2.24)** (2.10)** (0.01) (0.05) Male HH head (male=1) 74.9 75.9 -14.1 -14.1 (0.76) (0.78) (0.24) (0.25)Village characteristics Male daily wage rate (Rs./day) -0.7 -0.7 1.7 1.7 (0.30) (0.30) (0.83) (0.83) Average rainfall for 10 years (mm) 0.0 0.0 (0.11) (0.06) Annual rainfall (mm) -0.0 -0.0 (0.65) (0.64)

    Accessibility by vehicle (yes=1) -11.7 -12.7 -12.4 -13.6 (0.53) (0.57) (0.81) (0.87) Percentage of HH with electricity (%) 0.6 0.6 -0.1 -0.1 (0.77) (0.76) (0.13) (0.19)

    Constant 180.1 170.7 238.4 246.1 (0.51) (0.50) (0.75) (0.77)

    F-stat for endogeneity test (H0: no endogeneity) 2.10 [0.05] 2.41 [0.03] Joint significance test on instruments (First-stage F test)

    [0.00] for all six end. vars.

    [0.00] for all six end. vars.

    χ2 stat for over identification test 18.0 [0.11] 20.1 [0.07] F-stat (H0: all slope coeff=0) 12.62 [0.00] 14.67 [0.00] 7.90 [0.00] 8.38 [0.00] Village clustering robust t-statistics in parentheses. Numbers in brackets are p-values. * significant at 10% level; **significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level. a The proportion to the number of working members. b Divided by the number of working members. c Instrumented variable. Identifying instruments are the number of water sellers in a village, the number of water buyers in a village, the cost of well digging and its squared term, and the value of house building as well as the interactions of these variables with the inactive management dummy and with distance from the tank.

  • 47

    Table 6: Comparison of rice yield, income, and consumption value between collective management inactive and active villages under the assumption of the revitalization of collective management in inactive villages

    (A-1) (A-2) (B)

    Households ininactive villages

    (villages: n=31)

    (HH: n=171)

    Predicted value

    if active

    Households in active villages

    (villages: n=48)

    (HH: n=279)

    Difference (A-2)-(B) (|t-ratio|)

    (1) Yield (kg/hectare)

    Mean 3499 3673 3786 -112.5 (1.05)

    Std. dev. 1275 1174 1049

    Gini (all households in each category) 20.7 18.0 15.4 2.6

    Gini (average of village-level Gini) 9.8 9.3 6.7 2.7 (2.63)***

    (2) Per capita monthly income (Rs./person) a

    Mean 332 400 395 5.2 (0.14)

    Std. dev. 370 360 363

    Gini (all households in each category) 53.9 43.0 45.8 -2.8

    Gini (average of village-level Gini) 39.8 25.9 30.9 -5.0 (0.09)

    Head count ratio of poverty (P0) b 58.5 48.0 48.3 -0.3

    Poverty gap (P1) b 33.7 17.8 21.6 -3.8

    (3) Per capita monthly consumption value

    Mean 308 325 336 -11 (0.58)

    Std. dev. 194 177 202

    Gini (all households in each category) 34.1 29.7 31.8 -2.1

    Gini (average of village-level Gini) 23.2 20.5 20.4 0.1 (0.05)

    Head count ratio of poverty (P0) b 52.0 47.4 45.5 1.9

    Poverty gap (P1) b 19.8 13.9 14.2 -0.3

    *** significant at 1% level. a The value is converted into a per capita base using the adult equivalent number of present household members. See footnote 9 for details of the conversion method. b International poverty line of US$ 1 per day adjusted for purchasing power parity is used.

  • 48

    Appendix Tables Table A1: Descriptive statistics for the regression analyses explaining the decline in

    active collective management in villages Mean Standard deviation

    Dependent variable

    Collective management (inactive=1) 0.41

    Explanatory variables

    Private well

    Density of wells in tank command area (#/ha) 0.102 0.145

    Exit options

    Percentage of high-school graduates (%) 17.77 12.64

    Percentage of college graduates (%) 3.83 4.11

    Male wage rate (Rs./day) 56.27 9.59

    Tank un-irrigable agric. area per agric. HH (ha) 2.91 2.70

    Heterogeneity

    Gini coefficient of value of animal holdings 0.461 0.165

    Gini coefficient of value of animal holdings squared 0.240 0.165

    Gini coefficient of tank-irrigable plot size 0.275 0.087

    Gini coefficient of tank-irrigable plot size squared 0.083 0.050

    Size

    Number of HH having agric. land in tank command area (100HH) 0.757 0.567

    Government intervention

    Channel lining (%) 2.29 8.16

    Tank type (PWD =1) 0.367 0.485

    Destructive shocks

    Ethnic or religious conflict in the last 10 years (yes=1) 0.114

    Number of droughts in the last 10 years 3.53 2.74

    Rainfall

    Annual rainfall (mm) 1019 381

    Identifying instrumental variables

    Relative cost of well digging (100 kg. of rice) 265.32 86.39

    Relative cost of pump set (100 kg. of rice) 62.80 19.29

  • 49

    Table A2: Results of the probit analysis explaining the determinants of private well ownership by individual farmers

    Dep var.: ownership of private well (owning at least one private well =1) Collective management (inactive=1) -0.221 (0.89) Tank-irrigable plot size (ha) 0.121 (2.56)*** Tank-unirrigable plot size (ha) -0.038 (2.00)*** Animal value (000 Rs.) 0.003 (0.81) Distance from tank (km) 0.000 (1.66)* No. of working members 0.048 (1.32) Average schooling (years) 0.077 (2.23)*** Owner of tractor (owner=1) 0.126 (1.68)* Male HH head (male=1) 0.518 (1.20) Average rainfall for 10 years (mm) -0.001 (0.77) Percentage of HH with electricity (%) 0.011 (1.83)* Cost of pump set relative to rice price -0.010 (2.09)*** Cost of digging relative to rice price 0.001 (1.05) Constant -2.517 (2.50)*** χ2-stat (H0: all slope coeff=0) 33.28 [0.00]

    Village clustering robust t-statistics in parentheses. Numbers in brackets are p-values. * significant at 10% level; **significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level.

  • 50

    Table A3: Results of the regression analysis explaining the relationship between rice yield and the density of wells in the tank command area among farmers relying only on tank systems

    Dep. var.: rice yield (kg/ha)

    Density of wells in tank command area Density of private wells in tank command area (#/ha) 20,277.5

    (4.56)*** Density of private wells in tank command area sq. -55,524.1

    (3.03)*** HH characteristics Distance from tank (km) 105.8

    (0.59) Primary educ. proportion a -123.8

    (0.42) Secondary educ. proportion a 394.1

    (1.66)* College educ. proportion a 1,754.8

    (2.17)** Av. age b 59.2

    (0.80) Av. age sq. b -0.8

    (0.84) No. of working members 40.7

    (1.39) Rice plot size (ha) -372.5

    (1.68)* Rice plot size sq. 57.4

    (1.21) Av. value of animal holdings b (000 Rs.) 93.3

    (3.65)*** Av. value of animal holdings sq. b -3.2

    (2.93)*** Owner of tractor (owner=1) -21.3

    (0.06) Male HH head (male=1) 367.0

    (1.37) Village characteristics Male daily wage rate (Rs./day) 13.6

    (1.01) Annual rainfall (mm) 0.1

    (0.15) Accessibility by vehicle (yes=1) -112.2

    (0.95) Percentage of HH with electricity (%) -7.7

    (1.78)* Constant 1,173.5 (0.65) F-stat (H0: all slope coeff=0) 7.73 [0.00]

    Village clustering robust t-statistics in parentheses. Numbers in brackets are p-values. * significant at 10% level; **significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level. a The proportion to the number of working members. b Divided by the number of working members.

  • 51

    Table A4: Descriptive statistics for the regression analyses of the determinants of yield, household consumption, and income

    Mean Standard deviation

    Dependent variables

    Yield (kg/hectare) 3676.8 1147.7

    Per capita monthly agric. labor income 13.9 36.0

    Per capita monthly non-agric. income 53.1 145.4

    Per capita monthly income (Rs.) 371.0 366.8

    Per capita monthly consumption (Rs.) 325.4 199.1

    Explanatory variables

    Variable related to collective management

    Inactive collective management (inactive=1) 0.38

    No access to well (no access=1) 0.72

    Distance from tank (km) 0.418 .464

    Household characteristics

    Primary educ. proportion 0.325 0.264

    Secondary educ. proportion 0.410 0.285

    College educ. proportion 0.024 0.086

    Average age 37.56 6.46

    Average age squared 1452.5 514.5

    No. of working members 4.13 1.99

    Rice plot size (ha) 0.927 0.710

    Rice plot size sq. 1.362 2.767

    Tank-irrigable plots per working member (ha) 0.295 0.270

    Tank-irrigable plots per working member sq. 0.160 0.358

    Tank-un-irrigable plots per working member (ha) 0.232 0.454

    Tank-un-irrigable plots per working member sq. 0.260 1.588

    Value of animal holdings per working member (000 Rs.) 3.995 5.184

    Value of animal holdings per working member sq. 42.77 132.81

    Owner of tractor (yes=1) 0.0267

    Male HH head (male=1) 0.971

    Village characteristics Male wage (Rs./day) 56.03 9.57

    Annual rainfall (mm) 1009.7 351.8

    Average rainfall for 10 years (mm) 832.2 129.0

    Accessibility by vehicle (yes=1) 1.942 0.910

    Percentage of HH with electricity in home (%) 68.13 22.49

  • 52

    Sources: Southern India Engineering Manufacturers’ Association, various issues, Recommended List Prices

    (Coimbatore, India: Southern India Engineering Manufacturers’ Association). Director of Statistics, various issues, Season and Crop Report of Tamil Nadu (Tamil Nadu, India: Director

    of Statistics, Government of Tamil Nadu). Note: Relative prices are not reported in the years that pump price data are not available.

    Figure 1: Relative price of electric motor pumps to paddy price(price of pump set/price of 1 kg of paddy)

    1000

    1500

    2000

    2500

    3000

    3500

    4000

    4500

    1990 1995 2000Year

    Kg o

    f pad

    dy 7.5 HP foropen well

    7.5 HP forbore well

    Figure 1: Relative price of electric motor pumps to paddy price(price of pump set/price of 1 kg of paddy)

    1000

    1500

    2000

    2500

    3000

    3500

    4000

    4500

    1990 1995 2000Year

    Kg o

    f pad

    dy 7.5 HP foropen well

    7.5 HP forbore well


Recommended