+ All Categories
Home > Documents > EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a...

EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a...

Date post: 20-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
21
EFFICIENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES:1991-2002 A NON-PARAMETRIC FRONTIER APPROACH Prof. Dr. Recep Kök Dokuz Eylül University, Department of Economics, Buca-İzmir e-mail: [email protected] Doç. Dr. Ertuğrul Deliktaş Ege University, Department of Economics, Bornova-İzmir e-mail: [email protected] .edu.tr ABSTRACT This study based on panel data for 47 countries (25 transition countries and 22 OECD countries) examines efficiency convergence based on regression of average annual efficiency growth on initial levels of efficiency in transition economies during 1991-2002. Efficiency levels and average efficiency growth is calculated by Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) and then regression analysis is applied to estimate β –convergence. Efficiency change indices of trasition economies indicate that the poor transition economies are catching up the rich countries or the best-practice world production frontier. β -convergence also justifies this finding. Because the estimated convergence coefficient for transition economies, β, is (-0.0498) . Keywords: Convergence or catch-up, efficiency, transition economies, OECD countries, and data envelopment analysis. 1. Introduction By the end of 1991, the Soviet Union had disolved into independent states or economies and these economies are now called transition economies . The underlying economic reason of the transition from planned economies to market-based economies is the ever worsening economic efficiency in the planned period or communist regime. Therefore, the expectation was that economic efficiency would increase in market-based econmies and less productive economies would grow faster than more productive countries (Deliktaş and Balcilar 2002). This is an important subject to be tackled for economists and policy makers. In the other words, are less productive economies or transition economies catching up to their more productive or developed economies. Do initially less productive or less efficient economies have greater efficiency changes than the most efficient ones? These questions should be answered by looking at per capita growth performance or efficiency growth performance of economies. Three major strands of literature can be identified on the analysis of economic performance of nations. The first, and most typical, approach focuses on growth in real per capita income or real GDP per capita. This indicator can be considered as a proxy for the standard of living achieved in a country.
Transcript
Page 1: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

EFFICIENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES:1991-2002 A NON-PARAMETRIC FRONTIER APPROACH

Prof. Dr. Recep Kök

Dokuz Eylül University, Department of Economics, Buca-İzmir

e-mail: [email protected]

Doç. Dr. Ertuğrul Deliktaş

Ege University, Department of Economics, Bornova-İzmir

e-mail: [email protected]

ABSTRACT

This study based on panel data for 47 countries (25 transition countries and 22 OECD countries)

examines efficiency convergence based on regression of average annual efficiency growth on initial

levels of efficiency in transition economies during 1991-2002. Efficiency levels and average

efficiency growth is calculated by Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) and then regression analysis is

applied to estimate β –convergence. Efficiency change indices of trasition economies indicate that the

poor transition economies are catching up the rich countries or the best-practice world production

frontier. β -convergence also justifies this finding. Because the estimated convergence coefficient for

transition economies, β, is (-0.0498) .

Keywords: Convergence or catch-up, efficiency, transition economies, OECD countries, and data

envelopment analysis.

1. Introduction

By the end of 1991, the Soviet Union had disolved into independent states or economies and these

economies are now called transition economies . The underlying economic reason of the transition

from planned economies to market-based economies is the ever worsening economic efficiency in the

planned period or communist regime. Therefore, the expectation was that economic efficiency would

increase in market-based econmies and less productive economies would grow faster than more

productive countries (Deliktaş and Balcilar 2002). This is an important subject to be tackled for

economists and policy makers. In the other words, are less productive economies or transition

economies catching up to their more productive or developed economies. Do initially less productive

or less efficient economies have greater efficiency changes than the most efficient ones? These

questions should be answered by looking at per capita growth performance or efficiency growth

performance of economies.

Three major strands of literature can be identified on the analysis of economic performance of

nations. The first, and most typical, approach focuses on growth in real per capita income or real GDP

per capita. This indicator can be considered as a proxy for the standard of living achieved in a country.

Page 2: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

The second approach is to examine the extent of convergence achieved by the poor countries and

measure disparities in the global distribution of income. The third and recent approach, which is also

used in our paper, is to consider productive efficiency performance based on multi factor productivity

measures based on the concept of total factor productivity and its components, such as technical

efficiency change and technical change (Rao et al. 1998b). This third approach is also related to

convergence. Because change in technical efficiency level is an indicator of catching up or

convergence to the best-practice production frontier. This frontier is determined by both 25 transition

countries and 22 OECD countries in this study. Thus, convergence can be measured across transition

countries, and between transition countries and OECD countries.

The main aim of our study is to investigate the hypothesis of convergence or efficiency progress

based on the initial technical efficiency level and average annual efficiency change in 25 transition

countries for period 1991-2002 and secondly is to determine some probable sources of technical

efficiency progress, such as foreign aid, foreign direct investment, degrees of democratization and

political stability.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 identifies convergence and

literature on convergence. Section 3 includes efficiency and efficiency growth rates which are utilized

to estimate β- convergence in this study based on Malmquist total factor productivity index. Section 4

describes data that is used. Section 5 presents the basic methodology used, namely Data envelopment

analysis, (DEA) and regression analysis. Section 6 reports the results of the empirical analysis and

finally, section 7 presents conclusion of the study.

2. Convergence

Convergence is known as the tendency for two or more economies to become more similar in terms of

per capita income, growth rate or efficiency growth or such similar measure. Convergence may be

defined as catch-up by low efficiency economies to higher efficiency economies. Islam (2003)

identifies some of different ways in which convergence has been understood:

a) Convergence within an economy vs. convergence across economies;

b) Convergence in terms of growth rate vs. convergence in terms of income level;

c) Unconditional (absolute) convergence vs. Conditional convergence ;

d) β- convergence vs. σ- convergence ;

e) Global convergence vs. local or club-convergence;

f) Income convergence vs. total factor productivity (TFP) convergence;

g) Deterministic convergence vs. stochastic convergence.

In this study we preferred the way of β- convergence using the initial efficiency level and

efficiency change indices of transition economies. Convergence in terms of growth rate vs.

convergence in terms of income level requires what is called β- convergence. There exist β-

convergence in a cross-section of economies, if poor or low efficiency economies tend to grow faster

Page 3: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

than wealthy ones ore higher efficiency ones. Through the international diffusion of knowledge and

technology, low productivity and low-income countries have the opportunity to adopt the techniques

of the leader and hence catch-up with the higher productivity countries (Taskin, Zaim 1997).

Efficiency change is also an indicator of a country s performance in adapting the global technology,

and therefore represents the catch-up factor (Rao and Coelli 1998b).

β- convergence indicates that there should be a negative correlation between the initial income

level (efficiency level in our study) and the subsequent growth rate. The coefficient of the initial

efficiency level variable in these regressions (β) is supposed to pick up the negative correlation. That

is, the convergence is judged by the sign of coefficient of β. This follows from the assumption of

diminishing returns, which imply higher marginal productivity of capital is in a capital-poor country.

With similar savings, poorer countries will, therefore, grow faster (Islam 2003).

In neoclassical growth models as presented Solow (1956), a country’s per capita growth rate

tends to be inversely related to its starting level of output or income per person. If economies are

similar in respect to preferences and technology, then poor economies grow faster than the rich ones.

Thus there is a force that promotes convergence in levels of per capita product and income (Barro and

Sala-i- Martin 1992). However, Quah (1993a), Friedman (1994) emphasized that a negative (β) does

not necessarily imply a reduction in dispersion among countries. And the sign of (β) convergence

should be evaluated directly by looking at the dynamics of dispersion of income level or growth rates

across countries (σ- convergence, which is standard deviation of the cross-sectional distribution of

either income level or growth rate).

In the literature, there is extensive empirical evidence of β-convergence of per capita income or

productivity. Abromovitz (1986), Baumol (1986), and Maddison (1987) found evidence of

convergence in per capita income levels for a group of industrialized countries. Baumol and Wolf

(1988) detected similar results for a larger group of countries. Using cross-section regressions, Barro

(1991), Barro and Sala-i -Martin (1992), Mankiw et al. (1992) found convergence in levels of per

capita product and income. They argue that countries and regions are converging, or catching up, since

initially poor areas grow faster than their richer counterparts. On the other hand, Dowrick and Nguyen

(1989) studied TFP- convergence using a cross-section regression and their results support TFP-

convergence in a sample of fifteen for OECD countries (Islam 2003). Yigit and Kutan (2004) use a

stochastic endogenous growth model to investigate the impact of European Union integration on

convergence and productivity growth and their results support convergence.

Wolff (1991) and Dollar and Wolff (1994) examined TFP-convergence using time-series data in

order to get the TFP level indices across countries. TFP level indices obtained were used to check for

TFP-level convergence. For this, the subsequent TFP growth indices regressed on initial TFP levels.

Dougherty and Jorgenson (1996,1997) and Wolff, employing this methodology to the G-7 countries,

found evidence of TFP-convergence.

Alternatively, Fare et al. (1994) studied convergence by examining the changes in efficiency

obtained from the decomposition of the Malmquist productivity index in OECD countries for period

1979-1988. Bernard and Jones (1996) examined TFP-convergence in the manufacturing industry for

Page 4: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

14 OECD countries for period 1970-1987 and their major finding is that manufacturing shows little

evidence of multifactor productivity convergence. Taskin and Zaim (1997) found that the inverse

relationship between the mean efficiency change index and the initial per capita income level for a

group of high- and low- income countries for the period 1975-1990.

3. Efficiency and Efficiency Growth

Convergence requires the identification of the most productive countries in order to construct a

behavioral reference or benchmark or best practice frontier for the rest of economies. The distance that

separates it from the best practice frontier explains the relative performance of one economy. If that

distance becomes smaller over time it is said that there is a convergence. This is in contrast to the

traditional approach of measuring TFP growth for one economy exclusively on the basis of the

country’s past performance. Growth and convergence are closely related but not identical concepts so

are efficiency and productivity. Productivity is a ratio of the amount of outputs obtained to the amount

of inputs used, without regard to the efficiency of inputs utilization (Arcelus and Arocena 2000).

According to Farrel (1957), economic efficiency is divided into two parts: technical efficiency

and allocative efficiency. Technical efficiency reflects the ability of a firm to produce maximal output

from a given set of inputs at a certain time period while allocative efficiency reflects the ability of a

firm to use the inputs in optimal proportions, given their respective prices and the production

technology.

A decision-making unit or a firm exhibits production efficiency when it cannot produce more of

any output without decreasing some other output or increasing some other input. Efficiency is a

relative concept. Efficiency or performance of a firm must be compared with a standard or norm,

which indicates the firm is fully technically efficient. The full efficient firms determine the production

frontier. Efficiency levels of firms may increase, decrease or become constant over time.

Growth in efficiency change is an indicator of industry or country’s performance in adapting

technology (Rao and Coelli 1998) and it is also an indicator of the level of catch-up and convergence

among the countries (Deliktaş and Balcilar, forthcoming). Convergence may be broadly defined as the

tendency for two or more economies to become more similar, be they in terms of per capita incomes,

growth rates or total factor productivity growth (TFP growth). Total factor productivity growth is

decomposed into two factors: efficiency change and technical change.In the other words, the

predominance of efficiency change (or catch-up) as a source of TFP growth (Rao and Coelli 4/98).

Efficiency change, which is one of the main parts of TFP growth, can be identified by the Figure 1

illustrating the distance functions and Malmquist productivity index under the case of constant returns

to scale. ( Karadağ, et al , forthcoming).

Page 5: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Y

٠

(xt,yt)

٠ ٠

(xt+1,yt+1)

Rt

Rt+1

f e d c b a 0

X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index

Suppose one input is used to produce one output and there exist two technologies, namely, tR

and 1+tR or “the best production frontiers” in the periods (t) an (t+1) . The distance functions are

shown as , and in the

figure. Thus the efficiency change (EC) and technical change (TC) can be expressed as follows,

bayxD ttt 0/0),(0 = feyxD tt

t 0/0),( 111

0 =+++ ceyxD tt

t 0/0),( 110 =++

EC = ,00

00

ab

fe

(1)

TC = ,00

00 2/1

bd

cf

(2)

Following FÄRE et al., 1994, Malmquist index of productivity change between period t and t+1 is

defined as

,),(),(

),(),(

2/1

10

110

0

111

01,0

= +

+++++

+

ttt

ttt

ttt

ttt

tt

yxDyxD

yxDyxD

M (3)

where denotes the distance from the period t observation to the period t+1 technology. ),(10 ttt yxD +

Page 6: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Efficiency and technical changes are the two components of TFP change (see Fare et al.,

1994, for pioneering studies) as defined below:

Efficiency Change (EC) = ,),(

),(

0

111

0

ttt

ttt

yxDyxD ++

+

(4)

Technical Change (TC) = ,),(

),(),(

),(2/1

10

0

111

0

110

+

+++

++

ttt

ttt

ttt

ttt

yxDyxD

yxDyxD

(5)

Hence productivity change defined in equation 4 becomes

.1,0 TCECM tt ⋅=+ (6)

When there is an increase in the level of productivity from period t to t+1 then . 11,0 >+ttM

4.Data

Malmquist productivity index requires data on input and output quantities or shares for production.

Thus the input and output quantities or real values used in this study is based on data set related to the

each country. The data was mainly obtained from World Development Indicators 2004 (WDI)

published by the World Bank. The data covers the time period of 1991-2002 for 47 countries (25

transition and 22 OECD countries) and includes 564 observations in total.

Aggregate output (Q) is measured by real GDP (constant 1995 US dollars) for each country.

Inputs used in our model are labor (L) and, capital (K). Labor input is measured as the total labor

force. The capital stock for each country was cumulatively calculated from gross capital formation

(constant 1995 US dollars) by taking 1989 as the base year.

Following variables are considered as conditions that can explain efficiency growth among

transition economies. Indices of democratization and political stability taken from Kaufman et al.

(1999), foreign direct investment (percent of GDP), foreign aid (percent of GDP) economic

liberalization, the distance from Dusseldorf, time under communist regime, and human capital

(secondary school enrolment).

5. Methodology

In this study, we use the Malmquist index methods described in Fare et all (1994) to analyse

efficiency and efficiency change of transitional and OECD economies or in total.. Secondly, we

estimate β-convergence based on regression of base year efficiency level for transition economies on

the average efficiency change for transition economies for period 1991-2002.

Page 7: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Data envelopment analysis

Malmquist approach uses data envelopment analysis (DEA) methods to construct a pice-wise linear

production frontier over the data (input and output quantities of transition economies in our study) .

Efficiency measures are then calculated relative to this surface. The frontier surface is constructed by

the solution of a squence of linear programming problems. The linear programming problem must be

solved NT times in order to provide a value of φ for each country in the sample.

The DEA method was developed by Charnes et al., 1978, Lovell (1993), Ali and Seiford

(1993), Lovell (1994), Charnes et al., 1995, and Seiford, 1996, give the comprehensive review of this

method. Also, panel data applications of DEA method are widely used in the literature (see for

example, Milán and Aldaz, 2001; and Sıngh et al., 2000).

DEA can be either input-oriented or output-oriented. In the former case, the DEA methods

defines the frontier by seeking the maximum possible proportional reduction in input usage with a

given level of output for each economy. In the latter case, the DEA methods seeks the maximum

proportional increase in output production with a given set of inputs. These two approaches give the

same technical efficiency scores when constant returns to scale (CRS) technology is assumed,

however, they may give different efficiency scores when variable returns to scale (VRS) technology is

assumed. In this study we assume a CRS technolgy and output-oriented approach.

Malmquist TFP index might not correctly measure TFP changes when variable returns to scale

(VRS) assumed for the technology. Therefore it is important to impose constant returns to scale (CRS)

on any technology which is used to estimate distance functions regarding the calculation of Malmquist

TFP index (Karadağ et.al, forthcoming)1 .

The choice an appropriate orientation is not as curical as it is in the case of econometric

estimation. Given that linear programming dose not suffer from statistical problems as simultaneous

equation bias (Coelli et al. 1998).

We have preferred an output-orientation (Kök, Deliktaş 2004) because we believe that the

main challenge of transition or developping economies is to maximize output from given set of inputs,

rather than to decrease input usage.

1 There also exists some contrary argument on this subject. See BALK, 2001, for details.

Page 8: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

The output-oriented DEA model for the i-th country is as follows:

,max , φλφ

St. 0 ≥+− λφ Yyit ,

0 ≥− λXxit ,

0 ≥ λ , (7)

where,

yi is a Mx1 vector of output quantities for the i-th country;

xi is a Kx1 vector of input quantities for the-i-th country;

Y is a NxM matrix of output quantities for all N countries;

X is a NxK matrix of input quantities for all N countries;

λ is a Nx1 vector of weights; and

φ is a scalar and takes a value greater than one or equal to one. φ-1 is the proportional increase

in outputs that could be achieved by the i-th country with a given inputs. 1/φ defines technical

efficiency score, which varies between zero and one, with a value of one indicating any point on the

frontier.

Under CRS , it is obvious that the catching-up reflects the productivity change or change in the

components of TFP growth. The most productive country presents the highest ratio of average

productivity and it constitutes the reference for the rest. If the other countries increase their average

technical efficiency ratio more than the leader, they are considered to be “catching-up” to it (Arcelus

and Arocena 2000). For this, we follow standard methodology and regress each ecomoy’s annual

average efficiency growth indicies on the economiy’ initial efficiency level to estimate coefficient of

β- convergence. The classical definition of convergence refers to the log of real GDP per capita (Yigit

and Kutan 2004).

Regression

The form of the regression used in our study to estimate coefficient of β for each economy is given as

follows:

ii

T

tti

ti

Tεφββ

φφ

++=∑=

+1991

101

1

ln))(1(ln (8)

In our study, this equation is as follows:

Page 9: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

iiii IDEMFDIFAIDTEEFCHii

εβββββ +++++=− 432)1991(10)20021991( )ln()ln( (9)

where, (EFCH)i denotes the average technical efficiency change for period 1991-2002 for each

trantition economy. The subscript (i) represents the i-th country; N is equal to 25 accordingly. (TE)i

denotes the initial technical efficiency level of each economy, FAID stands for foreign aid (percent of

real GDP), FDI denotes foreign direct investment (percent of real GDP), IDEM is an index of

democratization (average of political process, civil society, independent media, and governance and

public administration ratings by the Freedom House, and IPS represents an index of political stability

foe each country (Deliktaş and Balcilar, forthcoming).

The other explanatory variables mentioned in section 4 have been found statistically

insignificant and been omitted from regression.

6. Empirical Results

The initial GDP per capita and efficiency level index, Malmquist productivity index or total factor

productivity change (tfpch) index, and its components, namely efficiency change (effch) index and

tecnological change (techch) index are given in Table 1 over the 1991-2002 period for the transition

economies. For each index, except for the initial efficiency level index3, a value greater one indicates

an average annual progress in the performance of the economy while a value less than one indicates

regress or detoriation in performance. The efficiency change index4 which is greater one also shows

catch-up or convergence of economy to the best-practice production frontier.

3 The initial efficiency level indices indicates that the best practice frontier is determined by Georgia, Slovenia, and Turkmenistan and other countries are inefficient in respcet to the full efficient countries in 1991. 4 The country-specific graphical behavior of efficiency change over time is given in appendix .

Page 10: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Table 1: Initial efficiency, initial GDP per capita, and annual average changes for transition

economies (1991-2002)

Initial efficiency level

Country

GDP per capita $ (1991) (1991 effch techch tfpch

Albania 620 0.346 1.097 0.784 0.861 Armenia 1337 0.231 1.054 0.839 0.885 Azerbaijan 983 0.482 1.012 0.813 0.822 Belarus 3021 0.356 1.019 0.843 0.859 Bulgaria 1597 0.433 1.018 0.847 0.863 Crotia 4268 0.908 0.993 0.833 0.828 Czech R. 4685 0.618 0.989 0.842 0.833 Estonia 4144 0.465 1.018 0.838 0.853 Georgia 1609 1.000 1.000 0.700 0.700 Hungary 4292 0.751 0.999 0.833 0.832 Kazakhstan 1780 0.304 1.073 0.836 0.897 Kyrgyzstan 1356 0.502 1.024 0.847 0.867 Latvia 3328 0.553 1.037 0.835 0.865 Lithuania 2806 0.824 0.990 0.845 0.837 Macedonia, FYR 2766 0.666 1.019 0.838 0.854 Moldova 1486 0.358 0.950 0.838 0.796 Poland 2772 0.617 1.015 0.837 0.850 Romania 1484 0.338 1.046 0.837 0.875 Russian F. 3472 0.376 1.055 0.869 0.917 Slovak R. 3464 0.567 1.014 0.832 0.844 Slovenia 8793 1.000 0.982 0.876 0.861 Tajikistan 1063 0.203 0.991 0.832 0.825 Turkmenistan 2329 1.000 1.000 0.824 0.800 Ukraina 1800 0.244 1.031 0.838 0.863

Uzbekistan 596 0.119 1.143 0.837 0.957

Mean 2634 0.530 1.022 0.831 0.849

Table 1 indicates that average annual technical efficiency change for 25 transition economies is 1.022

or 2.2% for period 1991-2002. In the same period, Uzbekistan has the greatest average growth rate of

technical change (14.3%). Secondly, Albania and Kazakhstan have average rates of growth of 9.7 and

7.3 percents in technical efficiency level, respectively. These countries are followed by Russia (5.5%),

Armenia (5.4%), Romania (6.6%), Latvia (3.7%), Ukraina (3.1%), Kyrgyzstan (2.4%), Macedonia

(1.9%), Bulgaria and Estonia (1.8%), Poland (1.5%), Slovak Republic (1.4%), and Azerbaijan 1.2%.

On the other hand, Moldova (-5.0%), Slovenia (11.8%), and Czech Republic (-1.1%) have

deterioration in performance while Georgia, Slovenia, and Turkmenistan have not experienced any

improvement and deterioration in performance over the period 1991-20025.

5 Although average annual technical efficiency growth rate for transition is greater one, average annaul total factor productivity growth rate is less than one. This is due to average annual tehnical regress in transition economies over the period 1991-2000.

Page 11: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

The average annual efficiency growth rates in the OFSU countries, the MEE countries, and

Baltic countries are 3.29, 1.93, and 1.50 percents, respectively6. It is seen that the OFSU countries

have higher annual efficiency growth than those of MEE and Baltic countries for period 1991-2002.

These findings indicate that the poor countries are catching up the rich countries. This argument can

also be supported by comparing transition economies to OECD countries. The average annual

efficiency change in 22 OECD countries has been measured as 0.991 for period 1991-20027 while that

of 25 transition countries is 1.022. These indices (appendix) clearly indicate that transition economies

or poor economies are converging the OECD countries.

On the other word, the results also show that the economies that have the lower initial efficiency

indices (or poor economies) have the highest technical efficiency growth rates or they catch-up the

best practice frontier at a faster rate than the economies that have the higher initial efficiency levels

(richer economies) This is a good indicator of convergence.

The robustness of convergence in transition economies is also justified by the significant negative

regression coefficient estimated by equation (9). The negative coefficient of the initial level of

technical efficiency level (TE), in equation 10, indicates β- convergence.

)1685.2()0125.3()4715.3()7295.4()3697.3(0094.00136.00011.0)ln(0498.03494.0)ln( IDEMFDIFAIDTEEFFCH +++−−=

−−

2R 603.0= , . (10) 115.10=− statisticF

We have regressed, in equation (10), each economy’s average annual efficiency change index

on the economy’s initial efficiency level index to produce estimate of β-convrgence. The equation

shows that the coefficient on the initial levels is negative and strongly significant (t values are in

parenteheses). It also shows that initially less efficient or poor countries are catching up to the most

efficient countries over period 1991-2002. The signs of the coefficients of FAID, FDI investment and

index of democratization have a positive impact on efficiency change. The coefficients of FAID, FDI,

and IDEM are also statistically significant at 5% level.

β- convergence can also be justified the regression of each economy’s average annual efficiency

change index on the each economy’s initial GDP per capita.

)1654.3()5367.3(ln0328.02826.0)ln(

−−= itaGDPpercapiEFFCH

270.02 =R , (11) 027.10=− statisticF

6 The OFSU countries are Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia,Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Russian Federation, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraina, Uzbekistan, and The MEE countries are Albania, Bulgartia, Crotia, Czech Republic, Hungary, Macedonia , Poland, Romania, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, 7 Fare et al. (1994) indicate that the average annual efficiency change index of 17 OECD countries is 0.998 over the period 1979-1988. Taskin and Zaim (1997) report that high income countries’ average annual efficiency change index is 0.999 over the period 1975-1990.

Page 12: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

The negative sign of coefficient of initial GDP per capita points out β- convergence in transition

economies for period 1991-2002. This is consistent with the result of equation (10).

7. Conclusion

We have investigated convergence based on regression of average efficiency growth on initial levels

of efficiency in 25 transition economies during 1991-2002. We have used DEA in order to measure

the efficiency levels and average annual efficiency growth. The efficiency change indices indicate that

the economies that have the lower initial efficiency levels have the highest technical efficiency growth

rates. The OFSU countries are converging the MEE countries and Baltic countries The transition

countries are also catching up the OECD countries.

The robustness of convergence is also justified by the cross section econometric regression as

finding a negative coefficient of the initial level of technical efficiency level (β- convergence) or of the

initial level of GDP per capita. The signs of coefficients of foreign direct investment, foreign aid and

index of democratization indicate that they have a positive impact on efficiency change. The positive

sign of democratization indicates that the establishment of democratic institutions will tend to

accelerate the rate of economic efficiency growth. The positive signs of foreign aid and foreign direct

investment point out the more foreign aid and more foreing direct investment are the more efficiency

growth in transition economies. The impact of foreign direct investment on transition economies is

consistent with the literature. It is estimated that foreign direct investment has a positive effect on

labor productivity and output in Turkish manufacturing industry and also the foreing firms creates

positive spillover effects on productivity of local firms (Kök and et al. Türkiye İktisat Kongresi,

2004). Yigit and Kutan (2004) also indicate that the FDI causes the high productivity gains in Poland

and Hungary and the presence of foreing firms creates positive spillover effects on productivity of

local firms in Hungary.

REFERENCES Abramowitz , M. (1986). “Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind”, Journal of Economic History 46,

385-406.

Ali, A.I. ve L.M. Seiford (1993). “The Mathemetical Programming Approach to Efficiency Analysis” in Fried

H.O., C.A.K. Lovell ve S.S. Schmidt (Eds), “The Measurement of Productivity Efficiency, Oxford Univ.

Press, New York, 120-159.

Arcelus, Francisco J, and Pablo Arocena (2000). “Convergence and productive efficiency in fourteen OECD

countries: A non- parametric frontier approach”, Int. J. Production 66, 105-117.

Balk B.M.(2001). “Scale efficiency and productivitiy change”, Journal of Productivity Analysis 15 (3), 159-83.

Barro R. J. (1991). “Economic Growth in A Cross Section of Countries”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106,

407-443.

Barro R.J. and Xavier Sala-i- M. (1992). “Convergence”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol.100, No 2, 223-251.

Baumol, W.J. (1986). “Productivity growth convergence and welfare: What the long-run data show”, American

Economic Review 76, 1072-1085.

Page 13: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Baumol W.J. and E.N. Wolf (1988). “Productivity growth, convergence and welfare: Reply”, American

Economic Review 78, 1155-1159.

B., Andrew B. and C. I. Jones, 1996. “Comparing Apples to Oranges: Productivity Convergence and

Measurement Across Industries and Countries”, The American Economic Review, Vol 86, No 5, 1217-

1258.

Coelli, Tim J., D. S. Prasada Rao and George E. Battase. (1998). An Introduction To Efficiency and Productivity

Analysis. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Charnes A., Cooper W.W., and Rhodes E. (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units, European

Journal of Operational Research 2, 429-44.

Charnes, A.; W.W. Cooper, A.Y. Lewin; and L.M. Seiford. (1995). Data Envelopment Analysis: Theory,

Methodology and Applications. Boston: Kluwer.

Deliktaş, E. and M. Balcılar, (2002).“A Comparative Analysis of Productivity Growth, Catch-Up and

Convergence in Transition Economies”, 6th METU International Conference in Economics, September

11-14, Ankara.

Deliktaş, E. and M. Balcılar, “A Comparative Analysis of Productivity Growth, Catch-Up and Convergence in

Transition Economies”, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade (forthcoming).

Dollar, D and E. Wolff (1994), Capital Intensity and TFP Convergence in Manufacturing, 1963-1985, in William

J. Baumol, Richard R. Nelson and Edward N. Wolf, eds.., Convergence of Productivity: Cross National

Studies and Historical Evidence, New York, Oxford University Press.

Dougherty and Jorgenson (1996), “International Comparison of Sources of Growth, American Economic Review

86, 25-29.

Dougherty C. and D.W. Jorgenson (1997), “There is No Silver Bullet: Investment and Growth in the G7”,

National Institute Economic Review 162, 57-74.

Dowrick S. and D. Nguyen (1989). “OECD comparative economic growth 1950-1985: Catch-up and

convergence”, The American Economic Review 79, 1010-1030.

Fare R., S. Grosskopf, M.Norris and Z. Zhang (1994), “Productivity Growth, Technical Progress, and Efficiency

Change in Industrialized Countries”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No 1, 66-83.

Farrel M.J. (1957).“The measurement of productive efficiency”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society”, Series

A, General 120 (3), 253-282.

Friedman M. (1994). “Do Old Fallacies Ever Die?, Journal of Economic Literature 30, 2129-2132.

I.Nazrul, 2003. “What Have We Learnt From the Convergence Debate?, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 17,

No 3, 309-358.

Kök, R.,E. Deliktaş, (2004). Endüstri İktisadında Verimlilik Ölçme ve Strateji Geliştirme Teknikleri,Dokuz

Eylül Üniversitesi, İİBF, Yayın K.No.15-8/1., İzmir.

Kök, R., E. Deliktaş, and M. Karaçuka, “Türkiye Cumhuriyetinin Yüzüncü Yılına Hazırlanırken: Temel

Dönüşümleri Açıklayan Analitik Yaklaşımlar ve Küreselleşmeden Beklentiler”, 2004 Türkiye İktisat

Kongresi (forthcoming).

Karadağ, M., A. Ö. Önder and E.Deliktaş. “Growth of Factor Productivity in the Turkish Manufacturing Industry

at Provincal Level”, Regional Studies (forthcoming).

Koopmans T.C. (1965). On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth, in the Economic Approach to

Development Planning.

Page 14: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Kaufmann, D.; A. Kraay; and P. Zoido-Lobatón. 1999. “Aggregating Governance Indicators.” World Bank

Policy Research Department Working Paper No. 2195, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Lovell, C.A.K. 1993. “Production Frontiers and Productive Efficiency.” In The Measurement of Productive

Efficiency, ed. H.O. Fried, C.A.K. Lovell, and S.S. Schmidt, pp. 3-76, New York: Oxford University

Press.

Maddison, A. (1987). “Growth and Slowdown in Advanced Capitalist Economies: Techniques of Quantitative

Assessment.” Journal of Economic Literature 25, no. 2: 649-698.

Mankiw N.G., D. Roomer, D.N. Weil (1992).“A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth”, Quarterly

Journal of Economics, Vol.107, No 2, 407-438.

Milán J. A. and N. Aldaz, (2001). “Efficiency and technical change in a panel DEA framework”, VII European

workshop on efficiency and productivity analysis.

Quah, D. (1993a). “Galton’s fallacy and test of the convergence hypothesis”, Scandinavian Journal of

Economics 95 (4), 427-443.

Rao, D.S. Prasada and Tim J.Coelli. 1998b. “A Cross-Country Analysis of GDP Growth Catch-up and

Convergence in Productivity and Inequality.” Working Paper, 5/98. CEPA.

Rao, D.S.P. and T.J. Coelli, (4/1998). “Catch-up and Convergence in Global Agricultural Productivity 1980-

1995”, Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis (CEPA) Working Papers.

Seiford L.M. (1996) Data envelopment analysis: The evolution of the state of the art (1978-1995), Journal of

Productivity Analysis 7, 99-138

Singh S., T.J. Coelli, and Fleming E. (2000). Performance of dairy plants in the cooperative and private sectors

in India, CEPA Working Papers 2/2000, Australia.

Solow , R. (1956). “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 65-

94.

Taskin, F. and O. Zaim, (1997). “Catching-up and innovation in high-and low-income countries”, Economics

Letters 54 , 93-100.

Yigit T:M. and A. Kutan (2004). “European Integration, Productivity Growth and Real Convergence”, William

Davidson Institute Working Paper Number 657, February.

Wolff, E. N. (1991). “Capital Formation and Productivity Convergence”, American Economic Review 81, 565-

579.

World Development Indicators 2004, Worldbank.

Page 15: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Appendix A

Table 2. Average annual changes in 47 countries over the 1991-2002 period Country effch techch pech sech tfpch

Albania 1.097 0.784 1.000 1.097 0.861

Armenia 1.054 0.839 1.051 1.003 0.885

Azerbaijan 1.012 0.813 1.005 1.007 0.822

Belarus 1.019 0.843 0.976 1.044 0.859

Bulgaria 1.018 0.847 0.993 1.025 0.863

Crotia 0.993 0.833 0.984 1.009 0.828

Czech 0.989 0.842 0.953 1.039 0.833

Estonia 1.018 0.838 1.000 1.018 0.853

Georgia 1.000 0.700 1.000 1.000 0.700

Hungary 0.999 0.833 0.976 1.023 0.832

Kazakhstan 1.073 0.836 1.040 1.032 0.897

Kyrgyzstan 1.024 0.847 0.989 1.035 0.867

Latvia 1.037 0.835 1.041 0.996 0.865

Lithuania 0.990 0.845 0.985 1.006 0.837

Macedonia 1.019 0.838 1.000 1.019 0.854

Moldova 0.950 0.838 0.943 1.008 0.796

Poland 1.015 0.837 0.988 1.028 0.850

Romania 1.046 0.837 1.020 1.026 0.875

Russian 1.055 0.869 0.991 1.065 0.917

Slovak 1.014 0.832 0.999 1.015 0.844

Slovenia 0.982 0.876 0.991 0.992 0.861

Tajikistan 0.991 0.832 0.977 1.014 0.825

Turkmenistan 0.971 0.824 1.000 0.971 0.824

Ukraina 1.031 0.838 0.965 1.068 0.863

Uzbekistan 1.143 0.837 1.120 1.021 0.957

Australia 0.990 0.985 1.005 0.985 0.975

Austria 1.000 0.963 1.002 0.998 0.963 Belgium 0.994 0.969 0.998 0.996 0.963 Canada 0.991 0.958 1.011 0.981 0.950 Denmark 1.000 0.973 1.001 0.999 0.973 Finland 1.013 0.976 1.014 0.999 0.988 France 0.993 0.974 1.000 0.993 0.967 Germany 0.990 0.969 0.996 0.993 0.959 Greece 0.994 0.953 1.002 0.992 0.948 Ireland 1.010 0.973 1.004 1.006 0.983 Italy 0.980 0.986 0.999 0.981 0.967 Japan 1.004 1.002 1.000 1.004 1.006 Netherland 1.000 0.972 1.007 0.993 0.972 New Zeland 0.991 0.957 0.990 1.001 0.948 Norway 1.020 0.958 1.012 1.007 0.977 Portugal 0.989 0.949 0.990 0.998 0.939 Spain 0.980 0.971 1.001 0.978 0.951 Sweden 0.993 0.986 1.003 0.990 0.979 Switzerland 1.000 0.978 1.000 1.000 0.978 Turkey 1.066 0.892 1.028 1.036 0.951 UK 0.989 0.957 1.007 0.982 0.947 USA 0.985 0.984 1.000 0.985 0.969

mean 1.011 0.895 1.001 1.009 0.905

Page 16: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Table 3. Average annual changes in transition countries over the 1991-2002 period

Country effch techch pech sech tfpch Albania 1.097 0.784 1.000 1.097 0.861 Armenia 1.054 0.839 1.051 1.003 0.885 Azerbaijan 1.012 0.813 1.005 1.007 0.822 Belarus 1.019 0.843 0.976 1.044 0.859 Bulgaria 1.018 0.847 0.993 1.025 0.863 Crotia 0.993 0.833 0.984 1.009 0.828 Czech 0.989 0.842 0.953 1.039 0.833 Estonia 1.018 0.838 1.000 1.018 0.853 Georgia 1.000 0.700 1.000 1.000 0.700 Hungary 0.999 0.833 0.976 1.023 0.832 Kazakhstan 1.073 0.836 1.040 1.032 0.897 Kyrgyzstan 1.024 0.847 0.989 1.035 0.867 Latvia 1.037 0.835 1.041 0.996 0.865 Lithuania 0.990 0.845 0.985 1.006 0.837 Macedonia 1.019 0.838 1.000 1.019 0.854 Moldova 0.950 0.838 0.943 1.008 0.796 Poland 1.015 0.837 0.988 1.028 0.850 Romania 1.046 0.837 1.020 1.026 0.875 Russian 1.055 0.869 0.991 1.065 0.917 Slovak 1.014 0.832 0.999 1.015 0.844 Slovenia 0.982 0.876 0.991 0.992 0.861 Tajikistan 0.991 0.832 0.977 1.014 0.825 Turkmenistan 0.971 0.824 1.000 0.971 0.824 Ukraina 1.031 0.838 0.965 1.068 0.863 Uzbekistan 1.143 0.837 1.120 1.021 0.957

Mean 1.022 0.831 1.000 1.022 0.849

Page 17: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Table 4. Average annual changes in OECD countries over the 1991-2002 period Country effch techch pech sech tfpch

Australia 0.989 0.981 1.002 0.987 0.970

Austria 1.000 0.963 1.000 1.000 0.963

Belgium 0.994 0.969 0.998 0.996 0.963

Canada 0.984 0.950 1.006 0.978 0.935

Denmark 1.000 0.973 0.999 1.001 0.973

Finland 1.013 0.976 1.009 1.004 0.988

France 0.993 0.974 1.000 0.993 0.967

Germany 0.990 0.969 0.996 0.994 0.959

Greece 0.979 0.949 0.983 0.996 0.930

Ireland 1.003 0.966 1.000 1.003 0.970

Italy 0.980 0.983 0.999 0.982 0.964

Japan 1.004 1.002 1.000 1.004 1.006

Netherland 1.000 0.972 1.007 0.993 0.972

New Zeland 0.981 0.949 1.008 0.973 0.931

Norway 1.020 0.958 1.006 1.014 0.977

Portugal 0.961 0.949 0.962 0.999 0.912

Spain 0.975 0.964 0.997 0.978 0.940

Sweden 0.993 0.984 1.001 0.992 0.977

Switzerland 1.000 0.978 1.000 1.000 0.978

Turkey 0.973 0.949 0.983 0.990 0.923

UK 0.979 0.950 1.003 0.976 0.930

USA 0.985 0.980 1.000 0.985 0.965

Mean 0.991 0.968 0.998 0.992 0.959

Page 18: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

Appendix B Country-based efficiency changes over the 1991-2002 period

year effch

1992 0.797

1993 1.086 1994 1.242 1995 1.138 1996 1.113 1997 1.149 1998 0.984 1999 0.958 2000 0.993 2001 1.052 2002 0.964

year effch

1992 0.807 1993 0.850 1994 1.046 1995 1.120 1996 1.071 1997 1.057 1998 0.973 1999 0.899 2000 0.961 2001 1.227 2002 0.956

year effch 1992 1.047 1993 0.995 1994 1.097 1995 1.057 1996 1.044 1997 1.045 1998 1.012 1999 1.009 2000 0.979 2001 0.979 2002 0.953

year effch

1992 0.670

1993 1.016 1994 0.837 1995 1.195 1996 1.080 1997 1.155 1998 0.964 1999 0.963 2000 1.006 2001 0.669 2002 1.071

Page 19: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

year effch

1992 1.131

1993 1.081 1994 1.123 1995 1.113 1996 1.045 1997 1.015 1998 0.986 1999 0.968 2000 0.917 2001 0.869 2002 0.959

year effch

1992 1.014

1993 1.086 1994 1.154 1995 1.207 1996 1.110 1997 0.998 1998 0.969 1999 0.963 2000 0.963 2001 1.084 2002 0.993

year effch

1992 0.909

1993 0.931 1994 1.001 1995 1.116 1996 1.089 1997 1.109 1998 1.046 1999 1.115 2000 1.052 2001 1.283 2002 1.007

year effch

1992 1.099

1993 0.961 1994 1.110 1995 1.091 1996 1.014 1997 1.021 1998 0.987 1999 0.981 2000 0.919 2001 1.021 2002 0.971

Page 20: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

year effch

1992 1.000

1993 1.000 1994 1.000 1995 1.000 1996 1.000 1997 1.000 1998 1.000 1999 1.000 2000 0.909 2001 0.959 2002 0.942

year effch

1992 0.981

1993 0.974 1994 0.932 1995 1.066 1996 0.967 1997 1.182 1998 1.091 1999 1.018 2000 1.073 2001 0.645 2002 1.083

year effch 1992 1.000 1993 1.000 1994 1.000 1995 1.000 1996 1.000 1997 1.000 1998 1.000 1999 1.000 2000 1.000 2001 1.000 2002 0.999

year effch

1992 1.014 1993 0.966 1994 0.906 1995 1.059 1996 1.041 1997 1.088 1998 1.054 1999 1.024 2000 1.037 2001 1.130 2002 1.036

Page 21: EFFICENCY CONVERGENCE IN TRANSITION ECONOMIES · Y ٠ (xt,yt) ٠٠ (xt+1,yt+1) Rt Rt+1 f e d c b a 0 X Figure 1. The Output Distance Functions and Malmquist Productivity Index Suppose

year effch

1992 1.380

1993 1.117 1994 1.135 1995 1.193 1996 1.126 1997 1.198 1998 1.041 1999 0.989 2000 1.039 2001 1.488 2002 0.965


Recommended