+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December...

Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December...

Date post: 08-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
23
REM WORKING PAPER SERIES Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078 Lisboa, Portugal ISSN 2184-108X Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of REM. Short, up to two paragraphs can be cited provided that full credit is given to the authors.
Transcript
Page 1: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

REM WORKING PAPER SERIES

Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry

Rui Faustino

REM Working Paper 0107-2019

December 2019

REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20,

1249-078 Lisboa, Portugal

ISSN 2184-108X

Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of REM. Short, up to two paragraphs can be cited provided that full credit is given to the authors.

Page 2: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry∗

Rui Faustino†

Update: November, 2019

Abstract

During economic expansions the net product creation and average product quality increase as firms in-

troduce new products with higher quality. The introduction of new products with higher quality produces

a quality bias in price level measures. In this paper I develop a firm-entry model with endogenous quality

of consumer goods. Following a TFP shock, the price level increases not only due to a larger number of

varieties but also due to a higher average quality. Simultaneously, the channel of endogenous quality acts

as a propagation mechanism to other variables in the economy, amplifying their response to shocks. This

channel can also be either contractionary or shut down, depending on how consumers derive utility from

quality.

Keywords: Firm-entry, business cycle, quality, prices.

JEL codes: E32, E20, L11

1 Introduction

Empirical evidence suggests that net product creation is linked to improvements in the quality of goods

and heavily procyclical, as replacement of outdated goods by new ones is accelerated during booms - Broda

and Weinstein (2010). Furthermore, net product creation is mainly determined by firm entry rather than

firm exit. Simultaneously, an extensive literature has been produced on general equilibrium models with

endogenous firm entry1, capable of explaining the dynamics of product creation. However, these models do

not account for the dynamics in quality and its role as propagation mechanism to the rest of economy, mainly

markups and prices2.∗I would like to thank to Luís Costa, the participants of 13th Lisbon Macro Club for the useful comments and suggestions.†ISEG - School of Economics & Management, Universidade de Lisboa; UECE – Research Unit on Complexity and Economics.

Email: [email protected] and Floetotto (2008), Colciago and Etro (2010) and Bilbiie et al. (2012) are the main examples of these type of

models.2Two exceptions are the models in Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2012) and Jaimovich et al. (2019). Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe

(2012) develop a model with exogenously-determined quality and analyze the importance of quality bias in the setting of inflationtargets. Jaimovich et al. (2019) study the trading down in consumption during recessions using a general equilibrium model withendogenous quality.

1

Page 3: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

In this study, I address this shortcoming by introducing endogenous quality into an otherwise standard

endogenous firm-entry model. Following a productivity shock, the model generates a positive response of

firm creation and average quality level, leading to an increase in the price level. This is consistent, not only

with the empirical evidence for net product creation, but also with the findings in Bils (2009) and Broda and

Weinstein (2010) of the role of quality improvements in price level dynamics.

In these studies, the authors find that quality improvements account for a significant part of inflation and

since statistical authorities do not adjust fully the impact of quality in prices, the inflation rate is consistently

overestimated (i.e. quality bias). Likewise as price level is partially determined by quality in the model, the

changes in the unadjusted price level are significantly higher than when one accounts for the quality bias.

Since the framework is the standard firm-entry model, the model with endogenous quality maintains its

features, such as the procyclical behavior of firm entry and countercyclical response of markups. However,

with endogenous quality the model adds one more propagation channel to productivity shocks and the

response of the main variables is amplified. Prices and markups, as well as consumption and output, are

now determined by the interaction between the number of firms (varieties) and average quality level.

The effect on other variables crucially depends on marginal utility of quality to consumers. When the

marginal utility is constant, the channel of transmission of changes in quality to the rest of the economy is

broken and the model produces the same results as in Hamano and Zanetti (2018). In that case, the markup

is only endogenously determined by the number of firms in the economy that in turn is unaffected by the

changes in quality. Therefore, with this specification, changes in quality of goods only have a direct impact

(in the same proportion) on prices and profits.

When the marginal utility is increasing, the average quality level is both negatively determined and has

a negative effect on the other variables in the economy such as labor, investment and output. Following a

productivity shock, as it becomes cheaper to produce consumer goods, the investment in quality by firms

decreases. The negative response of quality produces a positive feedback effect on economy and amplifying

the responses of output, labor and investment.

In contrast, when there is decreasing marginal utility, a positive exogenous shock in the quality of goods

produced leads to a positive response of the consumption, output, labor, markup, firm entry, and prices.

Since a TFP shock has a positive effect on quality, the response is amplified by the positive feedback loop

generated within the model. Therefore, the model produces a larger response of consumption and prices

than in the firm-entry model without endogenous quality.

Since there is no benchmark value to the parameter regulating the marginal utility of quality, I apply the

IRF-matching method to the model, in order to find the value of the parameter most consistent with US data.

I find that the value of parameter that guarantees the impulse-response functions (IRFs) for the model closest

to the ones obtained for the estimated vector autoregression (VAR) is the one implying decreasing marginal

utility. This value is consistent with the hypothesis considered in the main case.

2

Page 4: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

In the benchmark specification of the model, It is assumed that quality enters firms’ decisions in the

same form as intermediate inputs or labor – in each period, quality incorporated in consumer goods is equal

to that acquired by firms. This specification is similar to the one used in Jaimovich et al. (2019), where the

authors study the food and drinks service industries.

However, for manufactured goods, the quality of the product does not depend only on the quality of

the inputs. Rather, it depends on the design, technology and innovation which do not disappear with the

manufacturing process, but can become obsolete and require frequent updates. This is translated into the

model by considering the quality as stock, like physical capital. Under the new specification the effect of

quality on other variables is mitigated, as it fluctuates less as a stock. As a result, the model produces IRFs

and second moments closer to the standard firm-entry model.

The remainder of the paper is organized in three sections. In section 2 I present the firm-entry model

and discuss the results obtained under different specifications. Section 3 presents an alternative specification

of quality incorporation at firm level. Section 4 concludes.

2 Model

2.1 Households

Consider a representative household that derives utility fromconsumption at and disutility from supplying

labor lt . Its objective is to maximize expected discounted utility given by

Eo

∞∑t=0

βtU(at, lt ), (1)

where at is the composite consumption index given by

at =

[N∑i=1

(ci,t (xθi,t )

) ε−1ε

] εε−1

, (2)

where ct and xt are the quantity and the quality of each variety consumed, respectively, ε > 1 is the elasticity

of substitution between varieties and θ is the elasticity of quality in the consumption aggregator. The

consumer have the following budget constraint:

vt (Nt + NEt )st+1 + atQt = (πt + vt )Nt st + wt lt, (3)

where v is the value of each firm, π represents the individual firm’s profits, N is the number of firms, NE

stands for the number of newly-created firms, s the share of equity detained by the household and q is the

price of consumer goods adjusted by quality.

The first-order condition for the maximization problem are:

3

Page 5: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

−Ul,t

Ua,t=

wt

Qt, (4)

vt = βEt

[Ua,t+1

Ua,t

Qt

Qt+1(vt+1 + πt+1)

], (5)

where 4 is the Frisch labor supply and 5 is the Euler equation for share holdings.

For any given level of consumption ct , the demand of each differentiated variety of goods i = 1, ...,N in

period t must solve the dual problem of minimizing total expendituresN∑i=1

pi,tci,t , subject to the aggregation

constraint in 2. The optimal level of demand ci,t for i = 1, ...,N is given by

ci,t =(Qi,t

Qt

)−εat x

ε(θ−1)−θi,t , (6)

with the nominal quality-adjusted price index, Qt , defined as

Qt =

[N∑i=1

(qi,t

)1−ε di

] 11−ε

, (7)

qi,t =pi,txi,t

. (8)

2.2 Market Structure

In each period, representative household allocate its expenditure E XPt across varieties according to the

demand equation in 6 that can be rewritten as

ci,t =(Qi,t

Qt

)−εE XPt xθ−1

t xε(θ−1)−αi,t , (9)

where E XPt =N∑i=1

pi,tci,t = ctPt = atQt x1−θt . The inverse demand function is then given by

pi,t =c− 1ε

i,t E XPt

N∑i=1(xi,tci,t )

ε−1ε

xα−1ε

t xθ−θ/εi,t . (10)

In each period, the firms seeks to maximize its profits by choosing the quantities of consumer goods to

produce as the strategic variables3:

πi,t (ci,t ) =[pi,t − λi,t

]ci,t − px

t xi,t, (11)

3It is assumed that firm compete over quantities (Cournot) since it leads to a price schedule depending on ε and N . This happensbecause quality (x) is multiplicative in the demand function. Nevertheless, the results for Cournot competition are fairly similar tothe obtained with Bertrand - see Etro and Colciago (2010).

4

Page 6: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

where λi,t is themarginal cost and pxt is the price of intermediate quality goods. In ourmodel, the intermediate

quality goods are produced in a separated sector and acquired by firms producing consumer goods to boost

the quality of their products. The demand for quality goods by the producing firms is determined by the

effect of xi,t in demand for their consumer goods ci,t . By substituting equation 10 in 11 and maximizing

profits in order of ci,t we obtain

ε − 1ε

E XPt xθ−1ε

t xθ− θεi,t

©­­­­«c− 1ε

i,t

N∑i=1(xi,tci,t )

ε−1ε

−c− ε−1

ε

i,t xi,tN∑i=1(xi,tci,t )

2ε−1ε

ª®®®®¬= λt . (12)

By imposing the symmetry in the Cournot equilibrium we obtain the optimal output of each firm:

ct =ε − 1ε

Nt − 1N2t

E XPt

λtxθ−1t . (13)

Substituting the quantities obtained in the inverse price pt =EXPt

ctNtwe obtain:

pt = µtλt, (14)

where the price markup, µt , depends endogenously on Nt and xt and it is defined as:

µt (ε,Nt, xt ) =ε

ε − 1Nt

Nt − 1x1−θt . (15)

As they choose quantities, firms also choose the level of quality that maximizes their profits. From the

first-order condition we obtain:

pxt = ct xθ−2

t

Ntθ(ε − 1) − ε − θNtε

. (16)

In the symmetric equilibrium, Qt = qtN1

1−εt so that the variety effect is given by

qt = N1ε−1t . (17)

2.3 Firms

In this model it is assumed that the production of each variety of consumer goods only requires labor

input lci,t and is given by

ci,t = pt zt lci,t, (18)

where zt is the aggregate technology, which follows a first-order autoregressive process:

ln(zt ) = ρz ln(zt−1) + uzt , (19)

5

Page 7: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

where uzt ∼ N(0, σz) is the exogenous innovation in technology. This gives us the marginal cost λt = wt

zt.

The profits of each firm are given by

πt = (1 −1µt)

ctNt. (20)

As in most of firm-entry models, the number of firms is governed by the law of motion

Nt+1 = (1 − δ)(Nt + NEt ), (21)

where the δ ∈ [1,0] is the exit rate of firms. The creation of new firms is given by

NEt =

zt letφe

, (22)

where let is the labor allocated to firm creation and where φe is the fixed cost of entering the market. Firms

will enter the market until the marginal cost of creating a new firm equals the value of the firm. Therefore,

the firm-entry condition is given by

vt = φewt

zt(23)

with wt

Atdefined as the marginal cost of creating new firms.

The market in quality sector operates under perfect competition, meaning that the price paid by firms in

the consumer goods sector is the same to what would cost if they produced it themselves. The production

function of quality goods is given by

xi,t = it lxi,t, (24)

where lxi,t is the labor input in the production of quality goods and it is the aggregate technology, which

follows a first-order autoregressive process:

ln(ut ) = ρu ln(ut−1) + uit, (25)

where uit ∼ N(0, σi) is the exogenous innovation in technology. The price schedule of quality goods is given

by

pxt =

wt

it. (26)

The model is closed by imposing the labor market clearing condition:

lt = lct + let + lxt . (27)

6

Page 8: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

2.4 Calibration and results

For this model, I use the following utility functional form

U(at, lt ) =a1−σt − 11 − σ

− ψl1+χt

1 + χ,

where χ and σ are equal to 1, and the parameter ν is positive and calibrated so, in steady-state, the labor

supply is equal to 1. Since my model is build over the framework of Bilbiie et al. (2012), I follow their

calibration. The discount factor β is set to 0.99, while the exit rate of firms, δ is set to 0.0253. In our

calibration, the elasticity of substitution between varieties is higher than in Bilbiie et al. (2012) and equal to

ε = 5.3. The fixed cost of entry φE is equal to 1. The persistence parameters of productivity and preference

shocks are set to 0.95. The model is solved by first-order perturbation method.

Figure 1: Impulse-response functions to a one percent productivity shock in the firm-entry model with θ = 0.75, 1and 1.5

0 5 10 15 200

2

4Real Output

0 5 10 15 200

1

2 Real Consumption

0 5 10 15 200

2

4

Real Investment

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

Labor

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0Wage Rate

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

Number of Firms

0 5 10 15 20

−0.2

0.0

0.2

Price Mar up

0 5 10 15 20−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

Price Level

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

Aggregate Profits

0 5 10 15 20−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0Quality

0 5 10 15 200

1

2Quality Cost

0 5 10 15 200.00

0.05

0.10

Quality-Adjusted Price

θ=0.75 θ=1 θ=1.5

7

Page 9: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

In our model, as in Bilbiie et al. (2012), consumption, output, investment and the wage rate are measured

in nominal terms. To obtain these variables in real terms, one has simply to divide them by pt . In Bilbiie

et al. (2012), real consumption is given by ct/pt , real wage by wt/pt and real investment, since there is no

physical capital, is equal to the total value of new firms created and thus given by netvt/pt . Here, I have to

go further than Bilbiie et al. (2012) and I have thus to add the impact of quality in the real output which is

given by yt = ct xt/pt + netvt/pt .

Figure 1 displays the IRFs to productivity a one percent shock for three different scenarios of endogenous

quality. First we have the scenario where the elasticity of quality is lower than one (θ = 0.75), i.e. quality

has decreasing marginal utility. In the second scenario, quality exhibits constant marginal utility (θ = 1).

Finally, in the third, the elasticity is higher than one (θ = 1.5), i.e. increasing marginal utility over quality.

For the main macro variables such as the output, consumption, investment (measure by netvt/pt ), labor

and wage rate, the IRFs from the model are similar, regardless of the value of θ one chooses. On the other

hand, the variables related to prices, quality and competition behave differently across the parameter values.

When we consider θ = 1, the price markup is only determined by the number of firms. As new firms

enter the market, the markup decreases and the variety effect, measured by the relative price, increases. The

consumer substitutes quality (x) for quantity (c), which is now relatively cheaper. As a result, the aggregate

profits have an initial positive response, as firms spend less in quality goods. Since the price level has a more

positive evolution than quality, the adjusted price, measured by p/x, increases.

For θ > 1, the decrease in quality as a result of the increase in consumption is more pronounced.

Therefore, the price markup displays an initial positive response due to the decrease in quality offsets the

negative impact of firm entry. The profits are higher since firms spend even less in quality goods and the

number of firms increases more as the value of firms is higher due to higher profits.

In contrast, when we consider θ < 1, the model produces a comovement between consumption and

quality. Due to the positive effect of quality, the markup responds less negatively than in the firm-entry-only

case.

Nevertheless, the most important result is the two distinct responses of the price levels - unadjusted and

quality-adjusted. As the firms react to the TFP shock by increasing the quality incorporated in their products,

the (unadjusted) price level increases with it. In fact, this effect accounts for almost the entire variation in

price level as shown by small response of the quality-adjusted price level (0.05% at its peak compared to 1%

peak in raw price level).

Alternatively, we can consider a TFP shock in quality goods (Figure 2).

8

Page 10: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Figure 2: Impulse-response functions to a one percent quality shock in the firm-entry model with θ = 0.75, 1 and 1.5

0 5 10 15 20

0

1

2Real Output

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

Rea Consumption

0 5 10 15 20

0

2

Rea Investment

0 5 10 15 20−0.4

−0.2

0.0

0.2Labor

0 5 10 15 20

0.00

0.25

0.50

Wage Rate

0 5 10 15 20

−0.2

0.0

Number of Firms

0 5 10 15 20

−0.50

−0.25

0.00

Price Markup

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

Price Leve

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

Aggregate Profits

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

Qua ity

0 5 10 15 20

0.0

0.5

1.0Qua ity Cost

0 5 10 15 20

−0.05

0.00

Qua ity-Adjusted Price

θ=0.75 θ=1 θ=1.5

For θ = 1, the response of the variables in consumer goods sector to a quality shock is null. Investment,

labor, firm entry, wage rate, and price markup remain constant as the θ = 1 cancels the transmission

mechanism to this part of the economy. Real consumption, profits, and price level increase in direct

proportion to the increment in quality. As a result, the quality-adjusted price remains unchanged.

On other hand, for θ > 1, the increase in quality has a recessionary effect on the economy, leading to a

decrease in firm creation and, by definition, in investment. Due to a reduction in firm creation, the aggregate

demand for labor also decreases. The increase in real wage rate is determined by the joint effect of the

decrease in the markup and the increase in labor productivity in the quality sector.

As it can be seen in Figures 1 and 2, the model calibrated with decreasing marginal utility in quality

consumption produces the IRFs most consistent with empirical evidence. In Figure 3, I compare the model

with decreasing marginal utility on quality and the model without endogenous quality.

9

Page 11: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Figure 3: Impulse-response functions to a one percent TFP shock in firm-entry model with and without endogenousquality

0 5 10 15 200

1

2

3

4Output

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0Consumption

Firm Entry Firm Entry plus Quality Without Quality Adjustment

0 5 10 15 200

2

4

Investment

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5Labor

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Wage Rate

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5Firms

0 5 10 15 20

−0.15

−0.10

−0.05

0.00Price Mar up

0 5 10 15 20

0.0

0.5

1.0

Price Level

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

Aggregate Profits

In comparison with the firm-entry model, the model with endogenous quality is able to produce a larger

and hump-shaped response in consumption, even when one does not adjust real consumption by the increase

in quality (ct/pt ). However, the response of investment is weaker than the one observed in firm-entry-only

model, leading to a lower response of aggregate output.

When the effect quality on price level is removed, the response of the price level is smaller (solid line) and

closer to the one obtained for from firm-entry-only (blue doted). Additionally, the IRF of real consumption,

adjusted by the improvement in quality, is amplified, leading to a greater response of aggregate output. This

is consistent with the findings from Broda and Weinstein (2010), which state that, with a correction of the

quality bias present in the deflators, the variance observed in the data for the real variables would be larger.

The response of investment is very similar in both cases since the pt is not very large in any of the models.

10

Page 12: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

2.5 IRF-matching and second moments

In Figure 3 I assumed that the marginal utility from quality goods specified in the consumption aggregator

is decreasing and θ = 0.75. However, up to this point we do not know what is the true value of this

parameter.To accomplish this, we resort to the methodology presented in Hall et al. (2012).

I consider a recursive VAR xt f pt ≡ [TFPt HOURSt GDPt PCEt µt Πt ], where TFPt is total-

factor productivity, HOURSt is the indicator for total working hours in non-farm business, GDPt the real

Gross Domestic Product, PCEt the real personal consumption expenditure, µt is the average price markup

andΠt are the corporate profits4. I use quarterly data for the period 1960:I to 2017:IV. In the VAR estimation

I use four lags5, one constant, one trend, and all variables are in logarithms. Having the impulse-response

functions IRe for the VAR, I denote a vector of parameters Θ = [ρ, θ] and compute the impulse-response

functions IRm(Θ) for the model. The estimated parameter vector Θ is the one that minimizes the distance

between IRe and IRm(Θ) according to the following equation

Θ = argminΘ[IRe − IRm(Θ)]′W[IRe − IRm(Θ)],

where W is the weighting matrix, corresponding to the inverse of the variance-covariance matrix of IRe.

The IRF-matching is runned on the firm-entry model with endogenous quality and I estimate the values

for θ and ρ. From the IRF-matching between the VAR and the firm-entry model, I estimated the value of θ

to be equal 0.869, while ρ is equal to 0.916. This results, allows us to focus onwards on the results obtained

for case where θ < 1.

Figure 4 presents the response of both the estimated VAR and the theoretical calibrated model. We can

observe that the response of real consumption6 from the model matches almost exactly the response from

VAR, while the responses of output and hours match the sign but not the profile. On the other hand, the IRFs

from estimated VAR and calibrated model for markup and profits display the same profile but they are less

negative in the estimated VAR.

To further assess the fitness of the model to the data, I compare the second moments observed in the

US data and the results from the models with and without endogenous quality in Table 1. To allow the

comparability with the results obtained by Bilbiie et al. (2012), I define χ = 1/4, l = 1, ρa = 0.979 and

variance of uat equal to 0.00722. The second moments for variables of consumption, output and investment

are calculated in real terms.4The estimation of TFP and the price markup as well as the data sources used in our calculations are presented in Appendix B.5Since I am working with quarterly data, the rule of thumb in the VAR specification is four lags.6As for the second moments, I assume that real consumption and real output in the data do not take fully into account quality

changes so I only correct them by using the price level pt .

11

Page 13: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Figure 4: Impulse-response functions to a one percent productivity shock for estimated VAR and the calibrated model

As stated previously, to obtain the data-consistent variables in firm-entry models, the real consumption,

investment and output need to be corrected by the price level. Up to this point, I corrected even further, by

adjusting it also by the quality level. However, since statistical authorities do not take fully into the changes

in quality of the products7 and to increase the comparability with second moments for the firm-entry-only

model, the nominal variables are only corrected using the price level pt .

When observing the standard deviation of the models (σ(X)), one notices that, besides real consumption

and real wage, the model with endogenous quality displays a lower standard deviation. In relative terms

(σ(X)/σ(Y )), investment and labor present significantly lower volatility in comparison with the baseline

model. In fact, the standard deviation of labor is moment where the model with quality performs worse in

comparison with data.

7See Broda and Weinstein (2010).

12

Page 14: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Table 1: Second moments of main macroeconomic variables from US data for 1960:I-2017:IV, firm-entry model andendogenous quality model

Data Firm Entry Firm Entry + Quality

σ(X) σ(X)σ(Y) AC r(X,Y ) σ(X) σ(X)

σ(Y) AC r(X,Y ) σ(X) σ(X)σ(Y) AC r(X,Y )

Y 1.46 1.00 0.86 1.00 1.54 1.00 0.69 1.00 1.04 1.00 0.68 1.00C 1.20 0.82 0.87 0.87 0.77 0.50 0.77 0.94 0.99 0.95 0.78 0.99I 6.59 4.51 0.82 0.90 5.76 3.74 0.66 0.97 3.48 3.35 0.21 0.60L 1.81 1.24 0.92 0.86 0.90 0.58 0.66 0.97 0.14 0.13 0.47 0.95W 0.70 0.48 0.92 0.32 0.96 0.62 0.75 0.98 0.99 0.95 0.74 0.99µ 0.74 0.51 0.55 -0.12 0.06 0.04 0.95 -0.16 0.06 0.06 0.87 -0.73Π 7.96 5.45 0.80 0.59 0.74 0.48 0.76 0.96 0.55 0.53 0.20 0.56

As for the other macro variables, the presence of endogenous quality allows the model to match the

second moments closely observed for consumption and improve the results obtained for both the markup

and aggregate profits.

Table A.2 in the appendix presents the second moments for the model with θ equal to 1 and 1.5. As the

value of θ increases, the model produces lower standard deviations. For some variables, such as investment,

labor and profits, the persistence of shocks, measured by the autocorrelation, also decreases. At the same

time, the increase in θ produces a price markup more negatively correlated with the output.

The second moments obtained for the different values of θ suggest that a model with a θ < 1 produces

results that are more consistent with the data.

3 Quality as a stock

Up to this point, it was assumed that the quality of each variety of consumption goods was equal to the

output of quality sector, meaning that the quality of goods consumed can have significant fluctuation between

periods. This can be plausible for services industries - e.g. food services - where quality depends directly on

the inputs used, but not so much for consumer goods - e.g. gadgets - where most of the quality depends on

technology and design behind the product. In consumer goods, the increase in quality is mostly determined

by innovation, where new improvements add to the pre-existing quality.

Here, we consider that the quality of each variety is a stock that evolves according to the following law

of motion

xi,t+1 = (1 − δx)xi,t + invi,t, (28)

where invi,t is the improvement in x, equal to the output of quality sector, and δx is the depreciation rate of

13

Page 15: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

quality. The profits of firms in the consumer goods sector are now given by

πi,t (ci,t ) =[pi,t − λi,t

]ci,t − px

t invi,t, (29)

and the first-order condition for the demand of quality goods is:

pxt − (1 − δx)px

t+1 = ct xθ−2t

Ntθ(ε − 1) − ε − θNtε

. (30)

As there are no reference values for δx , I consider a δx = 0.1, meaning that a given variety becomes

obsolete within 2.5 years. This value of depreciation, that is higher than δ = 0.253 considered for the exit

rate of the firms, is low enough to guarantee dynamics different from the main model, while high enough to

avoid the low volatility generated by the stock of quality goods. Figure 5 presents the IRFs from the model

for different values of θ.

Figure 5: Impulse-response functions to a one percent TFP shock for quality-as-stock model

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

Real Output

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

Real Consumption

0 5 10 15 200

1

2

3Real Investment

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

Labor

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

Wage Rate

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4Number of Firms

0 5 10 15 20

−0.75

−0.50

−0.25

0.00Price Mar up

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.1

0.2

Price Level

0 5 10 15 20

−1.0

−0.5

0.0

0.5Aggregate Profits

0 5 10 15 20

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15Quality

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.5

1.0

Quality Cost

0 5 10 15 200.00

0.05

Quality-Adjusted Price

θ=0.75 θ=1 θ=1.5

The impulse responses obtained from the model with stock of quality are similar to the ones from our

main model, with the exception for the impulse responses for values of θ higher than one. For these values,

14

Page 16: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

the model generates IRFs of investment, labor and firm entry below the ones observed in our main model. At

the same time, the aggregate profits now exhibit a negative response to TFP shocks because quality responds

positively leading to lower markup and higher costs. As the markup is lower for a longer period, the real

wage response is also more persistent.

Figure 6: Impulse-response functions to a productivity shock for estimated VAR and the calibrated model with qualityas a stock

For θ < 1, the only difference is that the response of aggregate profits, which is now positive, determined

by a lower cost imposed by the increase in quality. With the new quality specification, the model produces

impulse responses that match closely the ones observed for the model with only firm entry - see Figure

C.8. Since the quality of goods specified as stock exhibits lower volatility through the business cycle, its

effect on other variables is mitigated. As a result, the model with low δx generates IRFs closer to the ones

for firm-entry-only, while with high δx the IRFs are closer to the ones in benchmark model of endogenous

quality.

As in the previous section, one can estimate the "true" value of the parameter θ in the model with quality

15

Page 17: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

as a stock using the IRF-matching method. In this case, the value that minimizes the distance of IRFs of

the model to the ones from the VAR is 0.646 (and ρ = 0.92). The lower value of θ is explained by the

relatively lower effect of quality as a stock, which requires values of θ further away from 1. Figure 6 presents

the IRFs for the estimated VAR and the calibrated model. In comparison with the results obtained for the

benchmark model, presented in Figure 4, the calibrated quality-as-stock model generates IRF of labor closer

to the ones obtained for the estimated VAR. However, this result is obtained at the cost of a less accurate IRF

of consumption and profits, where the benchmark model performs significantly better. Likewise, second

moments of investment and labor obtained for the model with θ = 0.75 are also more in line with the

ones generate by US data, while producing variables of consumption and profits less correlated with output.

(Table C.4).

4 Conclusion

In recent years, a considerable amount of literature on dynamics of product creation and destruction, as

well as its effects on prices, was produced. Simultaneously, the literature on general equilibrium models

addressed the dynamics of product creation and destruction through the introduction of endogenous firm

entry. In these models prices and markups dynamics through the business cycle are fully determined through

the number of varieties (i.e. firms) in the economy. However, as found in Bils (2009) and Broda and

Weinstein (2010), quality changes account for a significant part of price dynamics.

To address this gap in general equilibrium models literature, a mechanism of endogenous quality in

consumption was introduced in a standard firm-entry model. With endogenous quality, the model is able to

replicate the response of product quality and prices observed in data8, while maintaining all the desirable

properties of the firm-entry models.

The way in which quality of each variety is introduced in aggregate consumption allows for its marginal

utility to be defined as either decreasing, constant or increasing. As such, the value assumed for the parameter

regulating the marginal utility generated by quality determines the effect of quality on the markup, prices,

profits, and entry decisions of firms. When the marginal utility obtained from quality of goods consumed is

constant (θ = 1), the transmission of quality to other variables is shut down and changes in quality only have

an effect on the unadjusted price level (higher quality, higher prices), profits (higher prices, higher profits)

and composite consumption (due to higher quality of goods consumed). For increasing marginal utility,

positive changes in quality have a negative impact on the economy as firms trade away the quantity produced

for the increased quality in their products. The reduction in the quantities of goods consumed leads to a

reduction in labor demand, investment, and the markup.

However, when quality is considered to provide decreasing marginal utility (θ < 1)9, the response of

8See Bils (2009) and Broda and Weinstein (2010), as stated above.9This is the case where the model matches best with data – see subsection 2.5.

16

Page 18: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

quality to a TFP shock is positive, leading to a feedback loop that is only partly offset by the response of the

average price markup. When compared with the canonical firm-entry model, the introduction of endogenous

quality amplifies the IRF for consumption and output, and produces a less negative response for the price

markup due to the positive effect of quality. With the inclusion of endogenous quality, the firm entry model

improves its second moments for real consumption and aggregate profits.

Moreover, firms in consumer goods markets respond by increasing the quality incorporated in their

goods and, with it, the prices charged to consumers. With endogenous quality, the firm-entry model has

two different sources of price changes – quality and variety. In fact, this effect of quality accounts most of

variation in price level after a TFP shock, which is consistent with the findings in Bils (2009).

Finally, in contrast with the benchmark model, where quality consumed by households is equal to the

amount defined by firms every period, I considered an alternative specification where the quality goods can

be accumulated by firms through a law of motion similar to the one of capital accumulation10.

While the definition of quality as a flow is appropriate when one considers the services industries, where

the quality crucially depends on the inputs used in each period, the quality-as-stock approach is closer to

what is observed in the production of goods, where the quality of each product depends on the investment

from firms in R&D and equipment. This type of investment does not disappear with the production of the

goods but rather become obsolete over time.

With quality defined as a stock, its effect on the economy is weakened since the volatility of stocks is

smaller. Nevertheless, the model holds the same properties and still outperforms the standard firm-entry

model.

References

Afonso, A. and Costa, L. F. (2013). Market power and fiscal policy in OECD countries. Applied Economics, 45(32):4545–4555.Bilbiie, F. O., Ghironi, F., and Melitz, M. J. (2012). Endogenous Entry, Product Variety, and Business Cycles. Journal of Political

Economy, 120(2):304–345.Bils, M. (2009). Do Higher Prices for New Goods Reflect Quality Growth or Inflation?*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,

124(2):637–675.Broda, C. and Weinstein, D. E. (2010). Product Creation and Destruction: Evidence and Price Implications. American Economic

Review, 100(3):691–723.Colciago, A. and Etro, F. (2010). Real business cycles with Cournot competition and endogenous entry. Journal of Macroeconomics,

32(4):1101 – 1117.Etro, F. and Colciago, A. (2010). Endogenous Market Structures and the Business Cycle. The Economic Journal, 120(549):1201–

1233.Hall, A. R., Inoue, A., Nason, J. M., and Rossi, B. (2012). Information criteria for impulse response function matching estimation

of DSGE models. Journal of Econometrics, 170(2):499 – 518. Thirtieth Anniversary of Generalized Method of Moments.

10See section 3.

17

Page 19: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Hamano, M. and Zanetti, F. (2018). On Quality and Variety Bias in Aggregate Prices. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,50(6):1343–1363.

Jaimovich, N. and Floetotto, M. (2008). Firm dynamics, markup variations, and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics,55(7):1238 – 1252.

Jaimovich, N., Rebelo, S., and Wong, A. (2019). Trading down and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 102:96 –121. Carnegie-Rochester-NYUConferenceSeries on Public Policy“AConference Honoring the Contributions ofCharles Plosserto Economics”Held at the University of RochesterSimon Business SchoolApril 20-21, 2018.

Schmitt-Grohé, S. and Uribe, M. (2012). On quality bias and inflation targets. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(4):393 – 400.

18

Page 20: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

A Main Model

Figure A.7: Impulse-response functions to three types of shocks for the main model

0 5 10 15 200

2

4

6Real Output

0 5 10 15 200

1

2

3

Real Consumpt on

0 5 10 15 200.0

2.5

5.0

7.5

Real Investment

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

Labor

0 5 10 15 20

0.0

0.5

1.0Wage Rate

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

Number of F rms

0 5 10 15 20.0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2Pr ce Markup

0 5 10 15 20

0

1

2

Pr ce Level

0 5 10 15 200

1

2

Aggregate Prof ts

0 5 10 15 20

0

1

2

Qual t−

0 5 10 15 20

0

1

2

Qual t− Cost

0 5 10 15 200.000

0.025

0.050

0.075

Qual t−-Adjusted Price

Productivity Shock Quality Shock Aggregate Shock

19

Page 21: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Table A.2: Second moments of main macroeconomic variables from US data for 1960:I-2017:IV, model with θ = 1and model with θ = 1.5

Data θ = 1 θ = 1.5

σ(X) σ(X)σ(Y) AC r(X,Y ) σ(X) σ(X)

σ(Y) AC r(X,Y ) σ(X) σ(X)σ(Y) AC r(X,Y )

Y 1.46 1.00 0.86 1.00 1.02 1.00 0.69 1.00 1.01 1.00 0.73 1.00

C 1.20 0.82 0.87 0.87 0.99 0.97 0.77 0.99 1.01 1.00 0.77 1.00

I 6.59 4.51 0.82 0.90 2.96 2.90 0.22 0.61 2.10 2.08 0.10 0.52

L 1.81 1.24 0.92 0.86 0.11 0.11 0.33 0.83 0.05 0.05 0.21 0.75

W 0.70 0.48 0.92 0.32 1.01 0.99 0.76 0.99 1.03 1.02 0.78 1.00

µ 0.74 0.51 0.55 -0.12 0.10 0.10 0.84 -0.65 0.14 0.14 0.77 -0.68

Π 7.96 5.45 0.80 0.59 0.70 0.68 0.23 0.41 0.87 0.86 0.14 0.20

B US Data and Markup estimation

As stated in subsection 2.5, I follow Afonso and Costa (2013) in our average markup’s estimation. In

their paper, the short-run markup is a function of labor share and defined as

µt =1 − αt

st

11 − φt

, (B.31)

where st is the labor share, αt is the long-run capital share and φt is the measure of increasing returns

φt =µ∗ − 1µ∗

K∗αtt L∗1−αt

t

Kαtt L1−αt

t

, (B.32)

where µ∗ is steady-state average markup and K∗t and L∗t are the steady-state level of capital and labor input,

respectively. Substituting A.27 into markup equation we obtain

µt =1 − αt

st

µ∗

µ∗ − (µ∗ − 1)xt, (B.33)

where xt =HP(K

αtt L

1−αtt )

Kαtt L

1−αtt

. Both αt and the long-run values of output are obtained through the Hodrick-

Prescott filter. The steady-state markups is same as in Afonso and Costa (2013) and is equal to 1.203.

The TFP series used in the VAR were estimated through the following equation

∆TFPt = ∆(Yht Lt ) − αtKt − (1 − αt )Lt, (B.34)

where Yht Lt is the real output of Nonfarm Business Sector. Table B.3 presents the data sources for the series

used in our estimations.

20

Page 22: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Table B.3: Data sources 1960:I-2017:IV

Variable Series Code Source

Y Real Gross Domestic Product GDPC1 FRED

C Real Personal Consumption Expenditures PCEC96 FRED

L Nonfarm Business Sector: Hours of All Persons HOANBS FRED

Yh Nonfarm Business Sector: Real Output Per Hour of All Persons OPHNFB FRED

K Net Capital Stock OKND AMECO

s Compensation of Employes/Gross Domestic Product COE/GDP FRED

W Nonfarm Business Sector: Real Compensation Per Hour COMPRNFB FRED

π Corporate Profits with IVA and CCAdj CPROFIT FRED

C Quality as stock

Table C.4: Second moments of main macroeconomic variables from US data for 1960:I-2017:IV, for firm-entry modeland firm-entry with quality as stock

Data Firm Entry Firm Entry + Quality

σ(X) σ(X)σ(Y) AC r(X,Y ) σ(X) σ(X)

σ(Y) AC r(X,Y ) σ(X) σ(X)σ(Y) AC r(X,Y )

Y 1.46 1.00 0.86 1.00 1.54 1.00 0.69 1.00 1.29 1.00 0.80 1.00

C 1.20 0.82 0.87 0.87 0.77 0.50 0.77 0.94 0.82 0.64 0.76 0.96

I 6.59 4.51 0.82 0.90 5.76 3.74 0.66 0.97 5.40 4.19 0.85 0.95

L 1.81 1.24 0.92 0.86 0.90 0.58 0.66 0.97 0.74 0.57 0.74 0.90

W 0.70 0.48 0.92 0.32 1.00 0.65 0.76 0.95 0.94 0.73 0.73 0.98

µ 0.74 0.51 0.55 -0.12 0.06 0.04 0.95 -0.16 0.10 0.08 0.95 0.11

Π 7.96 5.45 0.80 0.59 0.74 0.48 0.76 0.96 1.64 1.27 0.50 0.06

21

Page 23: Endogenous Quality and Firm Entry Rui Faustino · Rui Faustino REM Working Paper 0107-2019 December 2019 REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics Rua Miguel Lúpi 20, 1249-078

Figure C.8: Impulse-response functions to a one percent TFP shock for firm-entry model and quality-as-stock model

0 5 10 15 200.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

1.25Output

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

Consumption

Firm Entry Firm Entry plus Quality Without Quality Ad ustment

0 5 10 15 200

1

2

3

Investment

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5Labor

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0Wage Rate

0 5 10 15 200.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5Firms

0 5 10 15 20

−0.20

−0.15

−0.10

−0.05

0.00Price Markup

0 5 10 15 200.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

Price Level

0 5 10 15 20−0.4

−0.2

0.0

0.2

0.4

Aggregate Profits

22


Recommended