+ All Categories
Home > Documents > F3_Individual Income Taxation

F3_Individual Income Taxation

Date post: 14-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: multane
View: 225 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 43

Transcript
  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    1/43

    Chapter 3 Individual Income Taxation

    3.1 Introduction

    The individual income tax is the most important single tax in many countries. The basic

    principle of the individual income tax is that the taxpayers income from all sources should be

    combined into a single or global measure of income. Total income is then reduced by certain

    exemptions and deductions to arrive at income subject to tax. This is the base to which tax rate

    are applied when computing tax.

    A degree and coverage of exemptions and deductions vary from country to country. A

    degree of progressivity of tax rates also varies.

    Nevertheless the underlying principles of the tax system are common among countries and

    are worth reviewing.

    3.2 The Income-Based Principle

    Economists have argued that a comprehensive definition of income must be used that includes

    not only cash income but capital gains. A number of other adjustments have to be made to

    convert your cash income into the comprehensive income that, in principle, should form the

    basis of taxation.

    This comprehensive definition of income is referred to as the Hicksian concept or the

    Haig-Simons concept. This concept measures most accurately reflects ability to pay.

    (1)Cash basis: In practice, only cash-basis market transactions are taxed. The tax is thuslevied on a notion of income that is somewhat narrower than that which most economists

    would argue. Certain non-marketed (non-cash) economic activities are excluded,

    though identical activities in the market are subject to taxation (e.g. housewifes work at

    home (vis--vis a maids work), and own house (vis--vis rented house)).

    Some non-cash transactions are listed in the tax code but are difficult to enforce.

    Barter arrangements are subject to tax.

    Unrealized capital gains is also not included in the income tax bases. Capital gains

    are taxed only when the asset is sold (not on an accrual basis).

    (2)Equity-based adjustments: Individuals who have large medical expenses or casualtylosses are allowed to deduct a portion of those expenses from their income, presumably

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.1 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    2/43

    on the grounds that they are not in as good a position for paying taxes as someone with

    the same income without those expenses.

    (3)Incentive-based adjustments: The tax code is used to encourage certain activities byallowing tax credits or deductions for those expenditures. Incentives are provided for

    energy conservation, for investment, and for charitable contributions.

    (4)Special Treatment of Capital Income: The tax laws treat capital and wage incomeseparately. The difficulty of assessing the magnitude of the returns to capital plays some

    role, while attempts to encourage savings as a source of domestic investment and growth.

    The Progressivity Principle1

    Even the simplification of tax schedule prevails among countries, the premise remains that

    those with higher incomes not only should pay more but should pay a larger fraction of their

    income in taxes. In other words, progressivity is reflected in an increase not only in average

    rates but in marginal rates.

    Defining progressive and regressive is not easy and, unfortunately, ambiguities in definition

    sometimes confuse public debate. A natural way to define these words is in terms of the

    average tax rate, the ratio of taxes paid to income. If the average tax rate increases with

    income, the system is progressive; if it falls, the tax is regressive.

    Confusion arises because some people think of progressiveness in terms of the marginal tax

    rate the change in taxes paid with respect to a change in income. To illustrate the distinction,

    consider the following very simple income tax structure. Each individual computes her tax bill

    by subtracting $3,000 from income and paying an amount equal to 20 percent of the remainder.

    (If the difference is negative, the individual gets a subsidy equal to 20 percent of the figure.)

    Table 1 Tax Liabilities under a Hypothetical Tax System

    ($)

    Income Tax Liability Average Tax Rate Marginal Tax Rate2,000 -200 -0.10 0.23,000 0 0 0.25,000 400 0.08 0.2

    10,000 1,400 0.14 0.230,000 5,400 0.18 0.2

    Table 1 shows the amount of tax paid, the average tax rate, and the marginal tax rate for each of

    several income levels. The average rates increase with income. However, the marginal tax

    rate is constant at 0.2 because for each additional dollar earned, the individual pays an

    1 This Part draws heavily from Rosen (1999), pp.258-260.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.2 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    3/43

    additional 20 cents, regardless of income level. People could disagree about the

    progressiveness of this tax system and each be right according to their own definitions. It is

    therefore very important to make the definition clear when using the terms regressive andprogressive. In the remainder of this section, we assume they are defined in terms of average

    tax rates.

    The degree of progression

    Progression in the income tax schedule introduces disproportionality into the distribution of

    the tax burden and exerts a redistributive effect on the distribution of income. In order to

    explore these properties further, we need to be able to measure the degree of income tax

    progression along the income scale. Such measures are called measures of structural

    progression (sometimes, measures oflocal progression). There is more than one possibility, as

    we will see. Each such measure will induce a partial ordering on the set of all possible income

    tax schedules. We could not expect always to be able to rank a schedule

    unambiguously more, or less, structurally progressive than another schedule : we must

    allow that a schedule could display more progression in one income range and less in another.

    )(2 xt

    )(1 xt

    )(xt

    )(xm )(x

    Nevertheless, the policymaker and tax practitioner, and indeed the man in the street, would

    like to be able to say which of any two alternative income tax systems is the more progressive in

    its effects. Is the federal income tax in the USA more redistributive than the personal income

    tax in Germany? This sort of question will take us from measures of structural progression to

    measures ofeffective progression. Measuring effective progression is a matter of reducing a

    tax schedule and income distribution pair to a scalar index number. The same schedule

    could be more progressive in effect when applied to distribution A than to distribution B.

    Trends in effective progression for a given country over time, as well as differences between the

    income taxes of different countries, can be examined using such index numbers.

    Let us begin by defining as and a respectively the marginal and average rates of

    tax experienced by an income x :

    x

    xtxa

    )()( = and (1))(')( xtxm =

    Since

    x

    xaxmx )()()( =

    x

    txxt

    x

    xxtd )('

    d

    /)]([2

    = (2)

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.3 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    4/43

    for strict progression it is necessary and sufficient that

    xxax allfor)()>

    )(xm )(xa

    m( (3)

    The strict inequality rules out the possibility that the tax could be proportional to income in any

    interval: we may relax it if we wish. Measures of structural progression quantify, in various

    ways, the excess of the marginal rate over the average rate at income level x .

    We introduce two particularly important measures here.

    First, liability progression ) is defined at any income level(xLP x for which t as

    the elasticity of tax liability to pre-tax income:

    0)( >x

    1)(

    )(

    )(

    )('>=

    xa

    xm

    xt

    xxt)( ),( == exLP xxt (4)

    As we have already noted, for a strictly progressive income tax a 1 percent increase in pre-tax

    income x leads to an increase of more than 1 percent in tax liability. measures the

    actual percentage increase experienced. A change of tax schedule which, for some , casues

    an increase in connotes, in an obvious sense, an increase in progression at that income

    level . If the change in a strictly positive income tax involves an upward shift of the entire

    function , then the tax has become everywhere more liability progressive.

    )(xLP

    0x

    )( 0xLP

    0x

    )(xLP

    (xRPSecond, residual progression ) is defined at all income levels x as the elasticity of

    post-tax income to pre-tax income:

    1)(1

    )(1

    )

    )]( 0, Ul < 0, Uxx < 0 (12)

    and

    U as l) l x l( , 1 (13)

    (15) implies that each household will endeavour to avoid corner solutions with l=1 (no one

    wants to work all day long!!). The indifference curves of the utility function are illustrated

    bellows in which utility increases to the north west.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.14 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    15/43

    Figure 3 Preference

    I0I1

    I2

    l

    x

    To allow preferences and the budget constraint to be depicted on the same diagram, the

    utility function can be written

    U = U(x,l) = U(x, z/s) = u(x,z,s) (14)

    The indifference curves ofu(x,z,s), drawn (z,x)-space are dependent upon the ability level of

    the household since it takes a high-ability household less labor time to achieve any given level

    of income.

    In fact, the indifference curves are constructed from those in ( l,x)-space by multiplying by

    the relevant value ofs. This construction for the single indifference curve I0 and households of

    three different ability levels.

    Figure 4 Translation of indifference curves.

    x

    l

    I0

    x

    l

    I0(S1)

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.15 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    16/43

    Agent Monotonicity

    The utility function (14) satisfies agent monotonicity if uz/ ux , is a decreasing function ofs.

    Note that

    u

    uz

    xis the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and pre-tax

    income and that agent monotonicity requires

    ss

    s1. Agent

    monotonicity implies that any two indifference curves of households of different abilities only

    cross once. In other words, the indifference curve of an s-ability individual through the point

    (x,z)in consumption-labor space rotates strictly clockwise as s increases.

    Figure 5

    x

    1s=ss=s2

    z

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.16 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    17/43

    Mirrlees proved a theorem which shows, when the consumption function is a differentiable

    function of labor supply, agent monotonicity implies that gross income is an increasing functionof ability (in other words, if agent monotonicity holds and the implemented tax function has

    pre-tax income increasing with ability, then the second-order condition for utility maximization

    must hold). This is important as to identify ones ability by watching gross income.

    Self-selection

    Letx(s) andz(s) represent the consumption and income levels that the government intends a

    sehold of ability s to choose. The household of ability s will choose (x(s), z(s))provided

    In case of linear taxation, it does not need to consider the self-selection constraints since the

    can be determined as a function of the two parameters that describe

    e tax function; the lump-sum payment and the marginal rate of tax.

    tion, then the

    self-selection constraint is satisfied. The idea is to induce the more able group to reveal that

    th

    o derive the required minimization problem, let u(s)=u(x(s), z(s), s) represent the maximized

    (16)

    hou

    that this pair generates at least as much utility as any other choice. This condition must apply

    to all consumption-income pairs and to all households. Formally we can write,

    The self-selection constraint is satisfied if u(x(s), z(s), s) u(x(s), z(s), s) for all s ands.

    behavior of the household

    th

    In case of non-linear taxation, the self-selection constraints must be included. This is

    achieved by noting that the satisfaction of the self-selection constraint is equivalent to achieving

    the minimum of a certain minimization problem. If the sufficient conditions for the

    minimization are satisfied by the allocation resulting from the tax func

    ey have a high income, not the reverse.

    T

    level of utility for a consumer of ability s resulting from (10).

    0= u(s)-u(x(s), z(s), s) u(s)-u(x(s), z(s), s)

    so that s =s minimizes u(s)-u(x(s), z(s), s). Hence

    u(s)=us(x(s), z(s), s). (17)

    From the definition ofu(s) it follows that

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.17 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    18/43

    uxx(s) + uzz (18)

    Condit (17) or (18) is the necessary (the first order) condition for the self-selection

    The second-order condition for the self-selection constraint is found from the second

    (19)

    szz(s) + uss (20)

    .

    (21)

    (s) = 0

    is equivalent to (17).ion

    constraint to be satisfied.

    derivative ofu(s)-u(x, z, s) with respect to s to be

    u(s) - uss(x(s), z(s), s) 0

    Again using the definition ofu(s),

    u(s) usxx(s) + u

    which gives, by using (19)

    usxx(s) + uszz(s) 0

    Eliminatingx(s) using (18) provides the final condition

    u uu

    z s z ssz sxz s

    = ' ( ) ' ( )

    u ux x 0 (22)

    here s is the marginal rate of substitution introduced in the discussion of agent monotonicity.

    s

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    19/43

    3.7 The General Problem

    Using the individual demand and supply functions and integrating over the population, it is

    nd aggregate demand,X, where

    X x s s ds=

    ( ) ( )0 (24)

    The optimal tax function is then chosen to maximize social welfare, where social welfare is

    given by the Bergson-Samuelson function.

    W w u s s ds

    ( ( )) ( )0 (25)

    with W 0.

    There are two constraints upon the maximization of (25). The first is that the chosen

    allocation must be productively feasible such that,

    XF(Z) (26)

    where Fis the production function for the economy.

    This definition of productive feasibility can incorporate the government revenue requirement,

    expressed as a quantity of labor consumed by the government ZG, by noting that (26) can be

    written )

    Denoting the level of revenue required byR(ZG), the revenue constraint can be written

    [ ]s x s s ds ( ) ( ) ( ) (27)

    The second constraint is that it must satisfy the self-selection constraint which has already been

    possible to define total effective labor supplyZ, by

    Z z s s ds=

    ( ) ( )0 (23)

    a

    =

    X F Z Z F ZG =$ ( ) ( .

    R z

    0

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.19 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    20/43

    discussed.

    3.8 Linear taxation

    With linear taxation the marginal rate of tax is constant and there is an identical lump-sum tax or

    y for all househol

    The advantages of this restriction is that it en

    onvex so that optimal choices will be unique when preferences are strictly convex. In

    ibed by just two parameters: the marginal tax rate and the

    mp-sum subsidy.

    The linear tax structure corresponds to

    Under a linear tax system a household with ability s supplying l units of labor will pay tax of

    tslslT +=

    subsid ds.

    sures that the budge sets of all households are

    c

    addition, the tax system is descr

    lu

    proposals fornegative income tax schemes, in which

    all households below a given income level receive a subsidy from the tax system.

    amount,

    )( (28)

    t is the marginal rate of tax and

    egative.

    -t) by , the consumption function of the household is

    (29)

    Ea

    he first-order conditions can be reduced to

    where is a lump-sum subsidy if positive and a tax if

    n

    Denoting (1

    x =+sl.

    ch household chooses consumption and labor supply to maximize utility (3.2) subject to (29).

    T

    =U

    U

    sl

    x

    . (30)

    Labor suppl and functions cany and consumption dem be written as,

    l s

    x sl s

    =

    = +

    ( , , )

    ( , , )

    l

    (31)

    ubstituting (31) into the utility function, there determine the indirect utility function,S

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.20 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    21/43

    (UU ) ),,(), sVs,(),,,( lssl= =+ (32)

    with

    slUV

    UV

    xx ==

    ,

    (33)

    where V is equal to the marginal utility of income.

    The governments optimization problem is to choose the parameters of the tax system to

    maximize social welfare subject to raising the required revenue,R.

    (34)

    [ ]( , , ) ( ) (35)

    33) and defining the social marginal utility of income for a household of ability s by

    )()),,((max dsssVw 0,subject to

    +

    ( )10 sl = s s ds R

    Using (

    ),,()),,

    sVs (36) ((')( Vws =

    The necessary conditions for the choice of and respectively are

    ( )s ds H =

    00

    ( ) ( )

    zs ds

    1 (37)

    and

    =

    0 0()( zdssz

    )()1 dss

    (38)

    His th H s ds=

    ( )0 .

    z

    e population size,where

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.21 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    22/43

    Divide (38) by (37) and denote by a bar term of the formx/H.

    z s ds

    s ds

    z( )

    ( )

    0

    0

    0

    0

    z s ds

    zs ds

    ( ) ( )

    ( ) ( )

    1

    1 1

    =

    (39)

    on the left-han

    welfare-weighted average labor supply. From totally differentiating the government revenue

    onstraint whilst holdingR constant, it can be found that

    The term d side of (39) is now denoted z() and can be interpreted as the

    c

    +

    =0

    )()1( dssz

    zt

    0)()1(1 dss

    zRconst

    (40)

    (39) and (40),

    Hence from

    constRt

    =)(

    ince averaging over the p st give

    z (41)

    S opulation mu z z z( , )= , it follows from (41) that, holding

    revenue constant

    )(

    zzzzzz

    =+= (42)

    Therefore (40) can be written in the form

    RR constconst

    constR

    zt

    z

    =

    (43)

    ll that t= 1

    zz

    zz

    = )()1()(

    Reca

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.22 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    23/43

    const

    z

    zz

    t

    R

    =

    )((44)

    here the derivative is taken with revenue constant.

    Although the tax rule (44) only provides an implicit expression fort, it can be used to assess

    fects of various parametric changes.

    of s andz on increasing function

    increased on the high-s households so that equity was given less weight.

    3.

    y into account.

    he optimal structure of income taxation is characterized by applying Pontryagins maximum

    principle.

    The revenue function,

    ( )x s s ds) ( ' ) ( ' ) '= (45)

    he level of utility u(s), pre-tax incomez(s) and the tax payments of households of ability s are

    and the derivative of gross inco

    w

    the ef A reduction in the optimal tax would occur, with

    a decreasing function of s, if the welfare weights were

    9 Non-linear taxation

    With non-linear taxation, the self-selection constraint must be taken full

    T

    R s z ss

    s( ) ( '

    1

    2

    T

    me, ( )s z 'staken as the state variables is taken as the

    ontrol variable. The level of consumption can then be found by solving

    u

    c

    u s x s z s s( ( ), ( ), )=

    Adopting a utilitarian objective, the control variable is chosen to mazimize

    ( ) .

    u s s dss

    s( ) ( )

    1

    2

    (46)

    subject to

    ( ) )()()( ssxszR

    s (47)

    R s R s( ) ( )1 2 0= = (48)

    ( )

    u

    s

    u x s z s ss= ( ), ( ), (49)

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.23 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    24/43

    z

    s

    s= ( ) (50)

    ( )

    z

    ss

    = ( ) 0 (51)

    Introducing the adjoint variables (s), (s), (s) and(s), the Hamiltonian for the

    The revenue constraint is captured by (47) and (48). To simplify, it is assumed that zero

    revenue is to be collected. The rate of change in revenue (47) is derived directly from (48).

    The self-selection constraint is represented by (49)(51); the first-order condition is (49), the

    second-order condition are (50) and (51).

    optimization is

    ( ) ( )H u s s s z s x s s s u x s z s ss= + +( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ), ( ),

    v s s s s+ +( ) ( ) ( ) ( ). (52)

    an ns ared the necessary conditio

    H v= + =' ( ) 0 (53)

    ( )[ ] ( ) H z s x s sz

    u x s z s ss( ) ( ) ( ) ( ), ( ),

    z zv= + = ' (54)

    ( )[ ] ( )

    u u

    H

    us

    z s x s s u x s z s ss= +

    + = ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ), ( ),

    ' (55)

    R

    H= =' 0 (56)

    z

    s= 0,

    h transversality con

    0 (57)

    wit ditions are

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.24 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    25/43

    ( ) ( ) ,s s1 2= = ( ) ( )1 2v s v s0 0= = (58)

    To derive the form of these conditions that will be used below, note that from the identity( )s z s s, ( ),

    u x( ) it follows that

    x

    z

    u

    ux

    z

    = = (59)

    and

    x

    u ux=

    1. (60)

    In addition

    ( )u x s z s ss ( ), (

    zu

    x

    zu usx z x s

    ),= + = (61)

    and

    ( )

    x

    sxsx u

    u

    uu s xu

    sszsxu==

    ),(),((62)

    ( )Now denoting ( ) ( ) ' ( )s s s= , (53)(58) can be rewritten,

    =

    + ux s ( ) '1 0 (63)

    'usx + +

    =u ux x

    1 0 (64)

    z

    s= 0 0 (65)

    ( ) ( ) ,s s1 2= ( ) ( )s s0 0= =1 2 = (66)

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.25 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    26/43

    The interpretation of these neces

    (1) is zero for allself-selection constraint is not binding and pre-tax income is a stirictly increasing

    irst-order approach is identical to the second-order approach.

    (2) is not zero for all s. If is positive over [s0, s1], all households with abilitiesfalling in this interval earn the same pre

    These households are bunched at a single income level. Furthermore they must have the

    utility is increasing with lds since those with highers have to work

    less to obtain the co e.

    There are several thoretical results on optimal income tax.

    orem 1

    sary conditions is as follows.

    s. The second order condition for the satisfaction of the

    function of ability. The f

    -tax income.

    same level of consumption. Note that although pre-tax income and consumption are identical,

    s over the bunched househo

    mmon level of incom

    The (Mirrle

    If there exists an ability level ss 0 such that l(s0)=0, then l(s)=0 for any s

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    27/43

    Theorem 4 (Seade (1982))

    Let the upper bound on

    household of ability s2.roof

    ability s2 be finite. Then the marginal rate of tax must be 0 for a

    P

    les (1995, pp.151-

    short, since there is no household beyond ability s2 , there is no point to set the marginal rate

    ax positive at s2.

    Th

    See My 2).

    In

    of t

    eorem 5 (Seade (1977))

    For a population with bounded ability, any income tax schedule with a positive marginal

    rate at the top of the scale can be replaced by one that leaves all households better off,

    including them to earn more income but paying the same tax.

    Proof

    See Myles (1995, pp.153).

    Theorem 6 (Seade (1977))

    If there is no bunching at the lowest income, the optimal marginal rate for the household

    of lowest ability is zero.

    Proof

    Se m 4.

    been derived. arginal rate

    1. must be

    imal tax function cannot be progressive. In other

    ords, it may be optimal to force some households to choose to undertake no work. In this

    To generate numerical results, Mirrlees (1971) assumed that the social welfare function took

    e Myles (1995, pp.154). This is a Mirror image of Theore

    The above results of the optimal non-linear tax have The optimal m

    of taxation must be between 0 and At the highest and lowest abilities, the tax rate

    zero. The latter finding shows that the opt

    w

    case, it is the lowest ability households that will not work. Pre-tax income and consumption

    must both be increasing functions of ability.

    3.10 Numerical Results

    the form

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.27 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    28/43

    0,

    01

    0

    =

    =

    v

    v>ev

    w v

    (67)

    nt greater concern for equity, with v=0 representing the utilitarian

    case.

    The s the Cobb-Douglas,

    )(

    ,)(

    0=

    dssU

    dssU

    Higher values of v represe

    individual utility function wa

    U x l= + log log( )1 (68)

    og-normal,and the skill distribution is l

    ( )

    +=

    2

    )1(exp)(

    2s

    ss (69)

    ith a standard deviation (=0.39 from Lydall (1968)). An implicit assumption is that the

    able 3.1 Optimal Tax Schedule

    Consumption Average tax (%) Marginal tax (%)

    log1

    W

    skill distribution can be inferred directly from an observed income distribution.

    T

    Income

    (a)zG=0.013, v=0,=0.390.00 0.03 --- 230.05 0.07 -34 260.10 0.10 -5 240.20 0.18 9 210.30 0.26 13 190.40 0.34 14 18

    0.43 15 160.50

    (b)zG=0.003, v=1,=0.390.00 0.05 --- 30

    0.08 -66 340.12 -34 32

    0.34 16 2217 20

    0.050.100.20 0.19 7 280.30 0.26 13 250.400.50 0.41

    (c)zG=0.013, v=1,=10.00 0.10 ---0.10 0.15 -50

    5058

    0.25 0.20 20 600.50 0.30 40 591.00 0.52 48 571.50 0.73 51 542.00 0.97 51 523.00 1.47 51 49

    Source: Mirrlees (1971)

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.28 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    29/43

    The most important feature of the first two panel (a) and (b) in Table xx is the low marginal

    rates of tax, with the maximal rate being only 34%. There is also limited deviation in thesetes. The marginal rates become lower at high incomes but do not reach 0 because the skill

    verage rate of tax is negative for low incomes so that

    w-income consumers are receiving an income supplement from the government.

    eviation from 0.39 to 1.00). This raises the marginal tax rates but there remain fairly

    onstant across the income range. Kanbur and Tuomala (1994) find that an increased

    dispersion of skills raises the marginal tax rate at each income level and that it also has the

    ct of moving the maximum tax

    increasing over the majority of households.

    Atkinson (1975) considered the effect of changing the social welfare function to the extreme

    axi-min form,

    in{U} (70)

    From the above table, it can be seen that increased concern for equity, v going from 0 to 1,

    reased the optimal

    onsiderations such as maxi-min SWF lead to high marginal rates?. The result is given the

    ads to generally higher taxes. However they are again

    highest at low incomes and then decline. Absolute rate is lower than expected in all cases.

    Table 3.2 Optimal tax Schedule: Utilitarian vs. Maxi-min

    Utilitarian Maxi-min

    ra

    distribution is unbounded. The a

    lo

    The panel (c) of Table 3.1 show the effect of increasing the dispersion of skills (changing

    standard d

    c

    effe rate up the income range, so that the marginal tax rate is

    m

    w=m

    inc marginal tax rates. The natural question is can strong equity

    c

    below table. The maxi-min criterion le

    Level ofs Average rate (%) Marginal rate (%) Average rate (%) Marginal rate (%)Median 6 21 10 52Top decile 14 20 28 34Top percentile 16 17 28 26

    Source: Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980, Table 13-3, p.421)

    3.11 Numerical Results

    To generate numerical results, Mirrlees (1971) assumed that the social welfare function took

    the form

    6

    6 This part draws from Myles (1955) Chap 2, pp.156-9.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.29 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    30/43

    0,

    ,)(0

    =

    =

    v

    v>dssw (71)

    Higher values of v represent greater concern for equity, with v=0 representing the utilitarian

    case.

    y function was the Cobb-Douglas,

    )( =

    dss

    01 vU

    0 U

    ev

    The ind al utilitividu

    U x l= + log log( )1 (72)

    and the skill distribution is log-normal,

    ( )

    +=

    2

    )1log(exp

    1)(

    2s

    ss (73)

    With a standard deviation (=0.39 from Lydall (1968)). An implicit assumption is that the

    skill distribution can be inferred directly from an observed income distribution.

    Table 3 Optimal Tax Schedule

    Income Consumption Average tax (%) Marginal tax (%)

    (a)zG=0.013, v=0,=0.390.000.05 0.07

    0.03 --- 23-34 26

    0.10 0.10 -5 24

    0.40 0.34 14 180.50 0.43 15 16

    0.20 0.18 9 210.30 0.26 13 19

    (b)zG=0.003, v=1,=0.390.00 0.05 --- 300.05 0.08 -66 34

    0.10 0.12 -34 320.20 0.19 7 280.30 0.26 13 250.40 0.34 16 220.50 0.41 17 20

    (c)zG=0.013, v=1,=10.00 0.10 --- 50

    580.25 60

    4048

    1.50 0.73 51 540.97 51 521.47 51 49

    0.10 0.15 -50200.20

    0.300.501.00 0.52

    5957

    2.003.00

    Source: Mirrlees (1971)

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.30 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    31/43

    The most important feature of the first two panels (a) and (b) in Table 3 is the low marginal

    tes of tax, with the maximal rate being only 34%. There is also limited deviation in these

    n is unbounded. The average rate of tax is negative for low incomes so that

    w-income consumers are receiving an income supplement from the government.

    The panel (c) of Table 3 show the effect of increasing the dispersion of skills (changing

    dard deviation from 0.39 to 1.00

    constant across the income range. Kanbur and Tuomala (1994) find that an increased

    dispersion of skills raises the marginal tax rate at each income level and that it also has the

    ffect of moving the maximum tax rate up the income range, so that the marginal tax rate is

    inson (1975) considered the effect of changing the social welfare function to the extreme

    m

    =min{U}

    rom the above table, it can be seen that increased concern for equity, v going from 0 to 1,

    increased the optimal marginal tax rates. The natural question is can strong equity

    onsiderations such as maxi-min SWF l

    below table. The maxi-min criterion leads to generally higher taxes. However they are again

    ighest at low incomes and then decline. Absolute rate is lower than expected in all cases.

    Utilitarian Maxi-min

    rarates. The marginal rates become lower at high incomes but do not reach 0 because the skill

    distributio

    lo

    stan ). This raises the marginal tax rates but there remain fairly

    e

    increasing over the majority of households.

    Atk

    axi-min form,

    w (74)

    F

    c ead to high marginal rates?. The result is given the

    h

    Table 4 Optimal tax Schedule: Utilitarian vs. Maxi-min

    Level ofs Average rate (%) Marginal rate (%) Average rate (%) Marginal rate (%)Median (50%) 6 21 10 52Top deci 20 28

    17 28

    litz (1980, T 3-3, p.421)

    le (10%) 1416

    3426Top percentile (1%)

    Source: A on and Stigtkins able 1

    3.12 Vo over a Flat T

    Having tified the properties of the optimal tax structure, we now consider the tax system

    that emer om o his, we consider people voting over tax

    schedules me degree of redistribution. Bec it is difficult to model voting on

    nonlinear tax schemes given the high dimensionality of the problem, we will restrict attention to

    a linear tax structure as originally proposed by Romer (1975). We specify the model further

    sary complications and to simplify the analysis of

    ting ax

    iden

    ges fr the political process. T do t

    that have so ause

    with quasi-linear preferences to avoid unneces

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.31 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    32/43

    the voting equilibrium.

    , that individuals differ onl in their level of skill. We assume that skills

    are distributed in the population according to a cumulative distribution function )s that isknown to everyone, with mean skill

    Assume, as before y

    (Fs and median Individuals work a consume.

    They also vote on a linear tax scheme that pays a lu m benefit b to each individual

    financed proportional inco ax at rate t. dual utility function has the

    q

    ms

    m

    The indivi

    . nd

    psu

    by a me t

    uasi-linear form

    2

    2

    1,

    =

    s

    zx

    s

    zxu , (75)

    and the individual budget constraint is

    bztx += ]1[ . (76)

    It is easy to verify that in this simple model the optimal income choice of a consumer with skill

    level s is

    2]1[)( stsz = . (77)

    preferences imply that there is no income effect on labor supply (i.e., )(sz is

    independent of the lump-sum benefit b ). This simplifies the expression of the tax distortion

    induces taxpayers to work less and earn less income.

    rive

    e second equality. This constraint says that the lump-sum benefit paid to each individual

    termed the

    Dupuit-Laf and d n of le

    m uit-Laffer curve ell-shaped k a 2/1

    The quasi-linear

    and makes the analysis of the voting equilibrium easier. Less surprisingly a higher tax rate

    The lump-sum transfer b is constrained by the government budget balance condition

    )(]1[))(( 2sEttsztEb == , (78)

    where )(E is the mathematical expectation, and we used the optimal income choice to de

    th

    must be equal to the expected tax payment ))(( sztE . This expression is

    fer curve escribes tax revenue as a functio the tax rate. In this simp

    odel the Dup is b w a peaith t =t d no tax collected at the

    e 1= can now derive individ al preferences over tax schedules by

    s angement (indirect) utility can be written

    an

    nds 0=t and t . We u

    ubstituting (49) and (50) into (48). After re-arr

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.32 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    33/43

    22]1[1

    ),,( stbsbtv += .2

    (79)

    Taking the total differential of (52) gives

    dtstdbdv 2]1[ = . (80)

    so that along an indifference curve where 0=dv ,

    2]1[ stdt

    db= . (81)

    It can be seen from this that for given t, the indifference curve beco es steeper in ),( bt

    space as

    m

    s increases. This monotonicity is a consequence of the single-crossing property of

    the indifference curves. The single-crossing property is a sufficient condition for the Median

    ter Theorem to apply. It follows that there is only one tax policy that can result from

    jority voting: it is the policy preferred by the median voter (half the voters are poorer than the

    dian and prefer hig

    Letting mt he tax rate preferred by the median voter, then we have mt implicitly defined

    the solution to the first-order condition for maximizing the median voters utility. We

    into account the government budget constraint (51)

    obtain

    Vo

    ma

    y

    me her tax rates, and the other half are richer and prefer lower tax rates).

    be t

    b

    differentiate (52) with respect to t, taking

    to

    22 ]1[)(]2 stsEtv

    =

    . (82)

    etting this expression equal to zero for the median skill level ms yields the tax rate preferred

    by the median voter

    1[t

    S

    22 )(2 mm

    ssEt

    = , (8

    or, using the optimal income choice (50),

    22 )( mssE 3)

    m

    m

    zzE

    )(2

    )mzzE

    t

    =)(

    . (84

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.33 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    34/43

    This simple model predicts that the political

    f the median voter in the income distribution. The greater is income inequality as measured

    that the

    ses

    mpirical Fact in Japan

    ble 5 Individual Inhabitants

    Inhabitants Tax Income Tax

    equilibrium tax rate is determined by the position

    oby the distance between median and mean income, the higher the tax rate. If the median voter

    is relatively worse off, with income well below the mean income, then equilibrium

    redistribution is large. In practice, the income distribution has a median income below the

    mean income, so a majority of voters would favor redistribution through proportional income

    taxation. More general utility functions would also predict extent of this redistribution

    decrea with the elasticity of labor supply.

    E

    Ta and Income Tax

    Tax ecipient Municipal governments on 1st January National governmentR

    Tax government Individual lives in JapanPayer Individual lives in a municipal

    Tax ethod With holding AssessmentM

    Tax ase Last years income This years incomeB

    Income Deduction

    Basic deduction

    Spou

    Special spouse d

    Family deduction

    330,000

    330,000

    Basic deduction

    Family deduction

    380,000

    380,000

    se deduction

    eduction

    330,000max 330,000

    Spouse deduction

    Special spouse deduction

    380,000max 380,000

    MiniInc

    A couple with 2 children

    3,031,000,373,000

    A couple with 2 children

    Before a special tax deduction 3,616,000After special tax deduction 4,917,000

    mum Taxableome (1998) Before a special tax deductionAfter special tax deduction 4

    Taxable Income Tax Rates Taxable Income Tax RatesPrefectural Municipal Total

    Above 7,000,000 3% 12% 15% Below 18,000,000Below 30,000,000

    30%40%50%

    Below 2,000,000Below 7,000,000

    2%2%

    3%7%

    5%10%

    Below 3,300,000Below 9,000,000

    10%20%

    Above 30,000,000Tax Rate Capital Gain Income Capital Gain Income

    Below 40,000,000Below 80,000,000Above 80,000,000

    2%2%3%

    4%5.5%

    6%

    6%7.5%

    9%

    Below 40,000,000Below 80,000,000Above 80,000,000

    20%25%30%

    In 1999-2001 In 1998-2000

    Below 60,000,000Above 60,000,000

    2%2%

    4%5.5%

    6%7.5%

    Below 60,000,000Above 60,000,000

    20%25%

    Prefectural 1,000MunicipalPopulation above 0.5 millionPopulation between 0.5 millionPopulation below 50,000

    3,0002,5002,000

    Tax- Tax Incentives

    Housing Acquisition

    Research & Development

    Exemption

    - Adjustment for Double Taxation

    Dividends

    Foreign Tax

    - Adjustment for Double Taxation

    Dividends

    Foreign Tax

    Tax Revenue (1996) 90,17 trillion yen 189,649 trillion yen

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.34 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    35/43

    Ta Tax Rates Schedule

    1987 1988 1989 1995 1999

    ble 6 Historical Changes in Income

    1974 1984

    % % % % % million % million % million

    Tax R4045

    4550ate

    10

    212427303438424650

    60657075

    10.5

    1721253035

    50556065

    10.5

    2025303540

    5560

    10

    405060

    10

    4050

    (~3)

    (~2)(2~)

    10

    4050

    (~3.3)

    (~30)(30~)

    10

    37

    (~3.3)

    18)(18~)

    M mumInhabitants

    Tax Rate18% 18% 18% 16% 15% 15% 13%

    12141618

    1214

    1216

    2030

    2030

    (~6)(~1)

    2030

    (~9)(~18)

    2030

    (~9)(~

    55 70

    axi

    CombinedMaximum 93% 88% 78% 76% 65% 65% 50%Tax Rate

    NT

    umber ofax Brakets

    19(13)

    15(14)

    12(14)

    6(7)

    5(3)

    5(3)

    4(3)

    M

    inimumTaxableIncome

    1,707,000 2,357,000 2,615,000 2,619,000 3,198,000

    3,539,000(3,616,000

    after the 1998amendment)

    3,821,000

    Table 7 Change in Income Tax Payers

    Total

    of Declared EarnersApplicantsfor Refund

    SalaryEarners

    DeclaredEarners

    Business AgricultureSmall

    BusinessOthers

    1985 3,665 737 4,402 228 31 67 411 599

    1986 3,728 770 4,498 231 32 70 437 654

    ,538 235 25 70 441 699

    ,689 245 24 70 441 696

    1989 3,961 796 4,757 242 23 67 464 659

    25 67 513 663

    24 68 699

    1992 4,403 858 47 24 69 735

    4,473 22 781

    4,478 27 867

    4,484 5,286 213 19 510 864

    4,537 213 20 531 883

    1997 4,627 5,454 206 545 9

    ,551 2 557 ---

    1987 3,767 771 4

    1988 3,909 780 4

    1990 4,158 855 5,013 250

    1991 4,333 856 5,189 252 512

    5185,261 2

    1993 843 5,316 230 67 524

    1994 822 5,300 223 62 510

    1995 802 60

    1996 824 5,361 60

    827 16 60 09

    1998 4,703 848 5 10 20 61

    Source: Ministry of Finance.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.35 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    36/43

    Table 8 The 19 ome Bu R y

    (million yen)

    InAverageIncome

    Average Average

    xableInco

    Average

    Calculatedx

    A e Taxnt

    Gro

    IncomRa

    Effective

    Income TaxRate

    (-)

    96 Declared Inc Tax rden ate b Income Class

    come classIncome Ta

    Deduction

    me

    Ta

    verage Tax AveragDeduction Payme

    ss

    e Taxte

    100 748 2 18 2 8.9%546 202 0 0 .4%100 200 1,540 56 48 3.1% 8.8%200 300 2,476 1,016 103 88 3 8.7%300 500 3,870 2,074 2 197 5 9.5%500 1000 6,899 4,879 635 9.2% 13.0%1000+ 23,005 893 21,112 32 4,707 20.5% 22.3%

    TotalAverage

    5,864 8 759 12.9% 17.7%

    995 545 01,459 1 .5%1,796

    20330

    614

    .1%2,0 70

    4,7891,

    1,572 4,292 795

    Source: The 1996 Sample Su (Tax Bu

    Earners, Total Salary and Ta

    Number of Salary Earners (thousands) Total Salar Tax paid EffectiveTax Rate

    rvey of Declared Income Tax reau).

    Table 9 Number of Salary x in 1996

    y (100 million yen)

    Income Class of Tax Payers 00million yen)of Tax Payers (1

    Share Share Share ShareShare

    (%)- 100 3,228 7.2 479 1.2 23,993 1.2 2,789 0.1 213 0.2 7.6100 54,310 2.8 1,345 1.3 2.5200 4,818 10.7 3,419 8.7 72,423 3.5200 58 8.0 5,021 3.2300 6,818 15.2 6,230 15.9 173,522 8.4 1 ,778 4.9300 400 7,780 18 3.317.3 7,328 .7 272,122 13.2 25 13.06,351 8,471 8.2400 500 6,530 5 15.9 ,908 14 4 3.314. 6,244 292 .2 280,175 1 .2 9,222 9.0500 600 4,964 11.1 12. 272,721 ,861 8 3.44,802 3 13.2 263 13.4 8,898 .7600 700 3,273 7.3 3,215 8.2 211,900 ,179 7 7.2 3.610.2 208 10.6 ,429700 800 2,384 5.3 2,372 6.1 178,002 8.6 ,094 7 7. 4.4177 9.0 ,707 5

    800 900 1,604 3.6 1,604 4.1 135,837 6.6 ,837 7 7. 5.3135 6.9 ,168 0900 1000 1,004 2.2 1,004 2.6 95,168 4.6 ,168 6 6.0 6.495 4.8 ,1371000 1500 1,963 4.4 1,963 5.0 232,610 1.2 232,610 11.8 21,461 20.9 9.211500 2000 378 0.8 1.0 64,247 3.1 64,247 3.3 9,475 9.2 14.73782000 2500 87 0.2 0.2 20,098 1.0 20,098 1.0 3,956 3.8 19.7872500+ 64 0.1 0.2 23,254 1.1 23,254 1.2 6,294 6.1 27.164

    T 44,896 100.0 39,189 100.0 ,068,805 100.0 1,972,750 100.0 102,797 100.0 5.2otal 2

    Note: Employees on December 31, 1996.

    Source: The 1996 Tax Bur Private Sector Income Survey (Tax Bureau).

    Table 10 Tax asticity

    rect Tax (Income Tax) Total Tax

    eau

    El

    DiIndividual Corporate Indirect Tax Revenue

    1985 1.0 4 2 860 1.31 0.6 0.4 0.

    1986 1.8 6 3 879 1.74 1.6 1.8 1.

    1987 3.64 2.58 4.78 1.94 3.20

    1988 2.2 8 4 925 1.57 2.8 1.0 1.

    1989 1.6 2.736 0.58 0.77 1.44

    1990 1.36 2 16 1.06.69 0. 0.06

    1991 0.0 3 .10 0.032 0.06 1.4 0

    1992 6.18 6.09 7.77 1.09 4.50

    1993 4.14 2.14 17.71 4.71 1.86

    1994 4.75 5.50 8.25 8.25 5.57

    1995 1.10 2.00 6.50 1.55 1.20

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.36 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    37/43

    Figure 6 Before Tax Household Income Distribution in Japan

    Fraction

    j15000 1.8e+07

    0

    .428925

    Source : The National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure 1984, 1989 and 1994 (pooled)

    Note: Monthly average income during September through November.

    Figure 7 Before Tax Household Income Distribution in Japan (log normal transformation)

    Fraction

    j15000 1.8e+07

    0

    .125923

    Source : The National Survey of Family Income and Expenditure 1984, 1989 and 1994 (pooled)

    Note: Monthly average income during September through November.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.37 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    38/43

    Figure 8 After Tax Household Income Distribution in Japan

    Fraction

    ap2697 1.4e+06

    0

    .08466

    Source : The National Survey of F Incom d Ex e 1984, 1989 a 4 (po

    : Mon rage e d eptem throu mber.

    re 9 r T ou In e D ion ap no transformatio

    amily e an penditur nd 199 oled)

    Note thly ave incom uring S ber gh Nove

    Figu Afte ax H sehold com istribut in J an (log rmal n)

    Fraction

    ap2697 1.4e+06

    0

    .123219

    Source National Survey mily Income xpenditure 1984, 1989 and 1994 (pooled)

    Note: Monthly average incom ng Septemb ugh Novemb

    : The of Fa and E

    e duri er thro er.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.38 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    39/43

    Exercises

    1.

    [Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980), p.376]

    For the utility function vLX

    Ai

    in

    ii

    i

    =

    =

    11

    11

    1

    , where L units of labor, wage is w thus the

    budget co household is

    U

    nstraint for the == ywLXq ii . Show that the income termsyxi / ms are zero. Derive the optimal tax structure where i( ) and cross price ter are

    (positive) constants.

    2. Recently many countries adopt indirect taxation (e.g. VAT) and shift its weight from directtaxation (e.g. individual income). Could you justify this shift of tax reform?

    3. Stiglitz once argued that it can be shown, that if one has a well-designed income tax,adding differential commodity taxation is likely to add little, if anything. Would you

    agree with him? Or in what circumstances does the use of commodity taxation allow a

    higher level of social welfare to be achieved lwtbx ]1[ += in the presence of income

    1]

    Consider the bud lwtbx ]1[

    taxation?

    4. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.get constraint = + . Provide an interpretation of b. How

    How is the choice of fected by increases in b andt? effects.

    5. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.2]Assume that a consumer has preferences over consumption and leisure described by

    ]l=U , where

    does the average rate of atx change with income? Let utility be given by 2l=xU .

    l af Explain these

    x1[x is consumption and l is labor. For a given wage rate w , which

    her labor supply: an income tax at constant rate t or a lump-sum taxleads to a hig T that

    raises the same revenue as the income tax?

    6. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.3]Let the utilit ly function be = )log(xU . Find the level of labor supply if the wage rate,

    w, is equal to 10. the effect of the introduction of an overtime premium that raises

    w o s in excess of that worked at the wage of 10?7. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.4]

    Assu )1log()log( l

    What is

    r hourto 12 f

    =Ume that utility is x . Calculate the labor supply function.

    Explain the form of this function by calculating the income and substitution effects of a

    6]

    Show that a tax function is average-rate progressive (the average rate of tax rises with

    AR

    wage increase.

    8. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.TMRTincome) if > .

    9.

    [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.7]

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.39 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    40/43

    Which is better: a uniform tax on consumption or a uniform tax on income?

    10. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.8]Consider the utilit

    2

    l=xU .a. For 10=U , plot the indifference curve with l on the horizontal axis andy function x on the

    vertical axis.

    Now define ls= . For 5.0b. z =s , 1, and 2 plot the indifference curves for 10=U withz on the horizontal axis andx on the vertical.

    c. Plot the indiff curves for 5.0erence =s 1, and 2 thro e 20=x , 2=ugh th point z .d. any point (x zProve that at , ) the indifference curve of a high-skill consumer is flatter

    than that of a low-skill.

    11. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.9]Consider an economy with two co 11 =nsumers who have skill levels s and 22 =s and

    22/110 l= xU . Let the governm come tax function that

    4= , 5

    utility function

    leads to the allocation

    ent employ an in

    x =z for the consumer of skill 1=s and 9=x , 8z for

    e compatibility constraint that each

    consumer must prefer his allocation to that of the other.

    high-skill to the low-skill consumer.

    i. Calculate the effect on each consumers utility.ii. Show that the sum of utilities increases.iii. Show that the incentive compatibility constraint is still satisfied.iv. Use parts i through iii to prove that the initial allocation is not optimal for a utilitarian

    social welfare function.

    12. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.11]Assume that skill is uniformly distributed between 0 and 1 and that total population size is

    normalized at 1. If utility is gi )1 l

    =

    the consumer of skill 2=s .

    a. Show that this allocation satisfies the incentivb. Keeping incomes fixed, consider a transfer of 0.01 units of consumption from the

    ven by log()log( = xU

    al values ofb andtwhe

    and the budget constraint is

    ls , find the optim n zero revenue is to be raised. Isthe optimal tax system progressive?

    13. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.13]12 s> . Denote

    at to the high-skill consumer by

    2x , 2z .

    a.

    tbx )1( +=

    Consider an economy with two consumers of skill levels 1s and 2s , s

    the allocation to the low-skill consumer by 1x , 1z and th

    For the utility function szxuU = )( show that incentive compatibility requires that

    )]1 .()([ 21 xuxuz +2z =

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.40 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    41/43

    b. For the utilitarian social welfare function2

    22 )( s

    zxu , express W as

    )( hx , derive the

    itution for th

    alloc

    14. (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.15]revenue is to

    ]1,0[

    1

    11)( s

    zxuW +=

    a function of 1x and 2x alone.c. Assuming log)( hxu = optimal values of 1x and 2x and hence of 1z d. Calculate the marginal rate of subst e two consumers at the optimal

    ation. Comment on your results.

    [Hindriks and Myles

    and 2z .

    Suppose two types of consumers with skill levels 10 and 20. There is an equal number of

    consumers of both types. If the social welfare function is utilitarian and no

    be raised, find the optimal allocation under a nonlinear income tax for the utility function

    l= )log(xU . Contrast this to the optimal allocation if skill was publicly observable.

    15. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.16]Tax revenue is given by )()( ttBtR = , where t is the tax rate and )(tB is the tax

    base. Suppose htat the tax elasticity of the tax base ist

    t

    =

    1with

    1,

    2

    1 .

    ng tax rate?a. What is the revenue-maximizib. Graph tax revenue as a function of the tax rate both for 2/1= and 1= . Discus

    = 1 lU

    s

    the implications of this Dupuit-Laffer curve.

    16. [Hindriks and Myles (2006) Chapter 15, Exercises 15.17]Consider an economy populated by a large number of workers with utility function

    1] , where[x x is disposable i come, l is the fraction of time worked

    ( 10 l ), and

    n

    is a preference parameter (with 10 B is

    yment.

    gh-skill person have higher

    that the condition for job market

    g

    the unconditional benefit pa

    a. Find the optimal labor supply for someone with ability w . Will the high-skill personwork more than the low-skill person? Will the hi

    disposable income than the low-skill person? Show

    participation ist

    w

    >1

    [[ B ]]1 .

    ds are only used to fin e the benefitb. If tax procee Banc , what is the governments budgetconstraint?

    c. Suppose that the mean skill in the population is w and that the lowest skill is afraction of the mean skill. If the government wants to redistribute all tax1

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    42/43

    ),( Bt satisfy?

    d. Find the optimal tax rate if the government seeks to maximize the disposable income ofbject to evethe lowest skill worker su ryone working.

    Lectures on Public Finance Part2_Chap3, 2012 version P.42 of 43

  • 7/27/2019 F3_Individual Income Taxation

    43/43

    xation with General Equilibrium Effects on Wages,

    blic Economicstiglitz

    ublic Economics, 6, 55-75.

    iversity Press.ics, McGraw Hill

    Boa

    Crem

    Devereux, M.P. (19

    gressivity: A nt,Na (1),Hillm bridge University Press.Hin omics, T Press.Kanbur, S.M.R. and M. Tuomala (1994) Inherent, Inequality and the Optimal Graduation of

    f Economics, 96, 275-82.

    iversity Press.

    r Developing Countries, Oxford

    RomTax,Journal of Public Economics, 7, pp.163-8.

    Rosen, H.S. (1999) PSeade, J. (1977) On the Shape of Optimal Tax Schedule, Journal of Public Economics, 7,

    203-36Sea e

    Stern, N. n the Specificat dels of

    Tuo x and Redistribution, Oxford University Press.

    References

    Allen, F. (1982) Optimal Linear Income Ta

    Journal of Pu , 6, 123-62.Atkinson, A. and S , J. (1976) The design of tax structure: direct vs. indirect taxes,

    Journal of PAtkinson, A. and Stiglitz, J. (1980)Lectures on Public Economics, London: McGraw Hill.Atkinson, A.B. (1975) Maxi-min and Optimal Income Taxation, Cahiers du Sminaire

    dconomtrie, 16.Atkinson, A.B. (1995), Public Economics in Action, Oxford UnAtkinson, A.B. and J.E. Stiglitz (1980),Lectures on Public Econom

    dway, R., Marchand, M. and Pestieau, P. (1994) Toward a Theory of The Direct-IndirectTax Mix,Journal of Public Economics, 55, 271-288.

    er,H. and Gahvari,F.(1995) Uncertainty, Optimal Taxation and The Direct versus Indirect

    Tax Controversy, Economic Journal, 105,1165-1179.96) The Economics of Tax Policy, Oxford University Press.Feenberg,Formby, J.P., Smith W.J. and Sykes, D. (1986) Intersecting Tax Concentration Curves and the

    Measurement of Tax Pro Comme tional Tax Journal, 39 pp.115-18.an, A.L. (2003) Public Finance and Public Policy, Cam

    driks J. and G.D. Myles (2006)Intermediate Public Econ he MIT

    Marginal Tax Rates, Scandinavian Journal oMirrlees, J.A. (1971) An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation,Review of

    Economic Studies, 38, 175-208.Myles, G.D. (1995) Public Economics, Cambridge Un

    Newbery, D. and N. Stern (1987) The Theory of Taxation foUniversity Press.

    er T. (1975) Individual Welfare, Majority Voting and the Properties of a Linear Income

    ublic Finance, 5th ed., New York: McGraw-Hill.

    .de, J. (1987) On the Sign of the Optimum Marginal Incom Tax, Review of Economic

    Studies, 49, 637-43.H. (1976) O ion of mo Optimum Income Taxation,Journal of

    Public Economics, 17, 135-44.mala, M. (1990) Optimal Income Ta


Recommended