+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial...

Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial...

Date post: 06-Mar-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
53
1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University of Leeds 1 Abstract This paper argues that analyses of inequality based on existing theories of distribution do not adequately account for growing wealth disparities. This is because the division into capitalists and workers traditionally envisaged in the Post Keynesian wage share models has been altered by financialisation, making these categories more heterogeneous. Financial deregulation and securitisation have contributed to the falling wage share of national income. The rich accumulate high-yielding assets while the middle/low-income groups suffer from high leverage due to unsustainable debt accumulation. Rising indebtedness, linked to stagnating wage growth and validated by the growing demand for asset-backed securities among financial investors, has led to massive wealth disparities. Recent contributions to the stock flow consistent modelling literature incorporate some wealth considerations into the Post Keynesian stock flow consistent models by distinguishing between rentiers, non-managerial and managerial workers as well as by allowing for indebtedness of non-supervisory workers and consumption emulation. This paper aims to complement these contributions by focusing on how financialisation has altered the structures of householdsǯ balance sheets, and affected their stability. In particular, the implications of these changes for income distribution are examined in a stock flow consistent model of a US economy with three classes of households and a complex financial sector. The simulation results reveal that balance sheet heterogeneity among households has an important impact on inequality levels. WORK IN PROGRESS DO NOT QUOTE OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT PERMISSION November 2016 Note The author wishes to thank Yannis Dafermos, Gary Dymski, Giuseppe Fontana, Antoine Godin, Marc Lavoie, Maria Nikolaidi, Ozlem Onaran, Cem Oyvat and Peter Phelps for comments on an earlier draft of the paper. 1 Contact e-mail: [email protected]
Transcript
Page 1: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

1

Financial sector development and inequality – theoretical model for USA

Hanna Szymborska

University of Leeds1

Abstract

This paper argues that analyses of inequality based on existing theories of

distribution do not adequately account for growing wealth disparities. This is

because the division into capitalists and workers traditionally envisaged in the

Post Keynesian wage share models has been altered by financialisation, making

these categories more heterogeneous. Financial deregulation and securitisation

have contributed to the falling wage share of national income. The rich

accumulate high-yielding assets while the middle/low-income groups suffer

from high leverage due to unsustainable debt accumulation. Rising indebtedness,

linked to stagnating wage growth and validated by the growing demand for

asset-backed securities among financial investors, has led to massive wealth

disparities. Recent contributions to the stock flow consistent modelling literature

incorporate some wealth considerations into the Post Keynesian stock flow

consistent models by distinguishing between rentiers, non-managerial and

managerial workers as well as by allowing for indebtedness of non-supervisory

workers and consumption emulation. This paper aims to complement these

contributions by focusing on how financialisation has altered the structures of households balance sheets, and affected their stability. In particular, the

implications of these changes for income distribution are examined in a stock

flow consistent model of a US economy with three classes of households and a

complex financial sector. The simulation results reveal that balance sheet

heterogeneity among households has an important impact on inequality levels.

WORK IN PROGRESS – DO NOT QUOTE OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT

PERMISSION

November 2016

Note

The author wishes to thank Yannis Dafermos, Gary Dymski, Giuseppe Fontana, Antoine

Godin, Marc Lavoie, Maria Nikolaidi, Ozlem Onaran, Cem Oyvat and Peter Phelps for

comments on an earlier draft of the paper.

1 Contact e-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

1

Table of Contents

I. Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 2 II. Theories of inequality – an assessment ................................................................. 10 III. Wealth and inequality in stock-flow consistent models .................................. 14 IV. Model specification ........................................................................................................ 15

The household sector .............................................................................................................................. 19

Firms .............................................................................................................................................................. 27

Commercial banks .................................................................................................................................... 28

SPVs/underwriters .................................................................................................................................. 29

Institutional investors ............................................................................................................................ 29

Simulations ................................................................................................................................................. 30

V. Results ................................................................................................................................. 31 VI. Sensitivity analysis ......................................................................................................... 39 VII. Conclusion and future work ....................................................................................... 44 References ....................................................................................................................................... 47

List of Figures

Figure 1. Percentage change in homeownership rate by percentile............................ 4

Figure 2. The top 1% income share, USA 1980-2013 ........................................................ 5

Figure 3. Mean and median net worth, USA 1983-2013................................................... 6

Figure 4. Financial fragility measures by percentile, USA 2010 .................................... 7

Figure 5. Median net worth annual growth rate by decile, USA 1989-2013 ............ 8

Figure 6. Household portfolio composition, USA 2014 ..................................................... 9

Figure 7. Change in the top 10%-bottom 40% and the top 10%-middle 50%

median income ratios, USA 1992-2013 ................................................................................ 22

Figure 8. Simulation results – full model ............................................................................. 33

Figure 9. Simulation results – pure capitalists specification .................................... 36

Figure 10. Simulation results – pure capitalist specification, no rentier debt ... 37

Figure 11. Simulation results – reduced specification without securitisation ..... 38

List of Tables

Table 1. Annual growth rates of average hourly wages, USA 1979-2012............... 12

Table 2. Stock-flow consistent model - balance sheet matrix...................................... 17

Table 3. Stock-flow consistent model - transaction flow matrix ................................ 18

Table 4. Government transfers as a percentage of pre-tax income, USA 2011 ..... 23

Page 3: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

2

I. Introduction

The main goal of this paper is to examine the dynamics of income and wealth

inequality in high-income countries and the implications for the stability of

household financial positions across the distribution in the light of financial

sector transformation since 1980s. A theoretical stock flow consistent model is

proposed, aiming to explain the concentration of income and wealth at the top of

the distribution and the diffusion of financial fragility to the rest of the society.

The innovation of the model lies in its interpretation of inequality as balance

sheet structure disparities, based on a reinterpretation of the working and

rentier class and a new conceptualisation of the middle class in Post Keynesian

analysis. Three-class specification of the household sector is developed,

accounting for indebtedness, financial fragility and wage inequality – processes

strongly associated with the impact of financial sector transformation on

inequality.

Financial sector transformation, often described by the umbrella term financialisation , is an extremely complex process occurring at a variety of dimensions. It finds its roots in the persistently high inflation and high interest

rates in the late 1960s, which induced non-financial companies to turn to

financial markets rather than banks for funding investment. This realigned firms objectives away from long-term investment towards short-term profitability,

making them more involved in financial activities (such as issuing shares), which

raised the importance of financial over real profits and contributed to the

growing share of the financial, insurance and real estate sector (FIRE) in the

economy at the expense of manufacturing (Palley 2007:18).

The processes of financialisation gained steam in the 1980s under policies

promoting market liberalisation and retrenchment of the state from public

service provision associated with the leadership of Reagan in USA and Thatcher

in UK (Sawyer 2013:13). Firstly, labour market liberalisation and the associated

rolling back of minimum wage, unemployment protection and union-oriented

policies resulted in gradually declining wage income growth. Simultaneously,

provision of pensions, housing and public goods such as education and

Page 4: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

3

healthcare was increasingly delegated from the state to the private sector. With

stagnant wages and diminishing state provision, households found themselves in

need of additional financing through borrowing.

Rising credit demand was paralleled by the massive proliferation of

financial instruments and the development of structured finance. The

aforementioned turn of non-financial companies towards financial markets

resulting from high borrowing costs in 1960s and 70s led financial

intermediaries to seek revenue in the household sector and through innovation

of new financial products (Dymski 2009:157). An increasing volume of financial

obligations — primarily consumer debt and mortgages — was transformed into

securities in a process labelled securitisation, forming collateralised debt

obligations (CDOs), which combined financial instruments of varying risk and

return characteristics (Pollin/Heintz 2013:113). The establishment of credit

default swaps (CDS) and derivatives on existing products allowed investors to

bet against the default of any financial instrument, leading to the transformation

of traditional lending relations based on intermediation towards an originate and redistribute" model, where default risk became originated" by creditors and then spread across the financial system through securitisation. The actors of this

new lending model were not only registered banks, transformed into highly consolidated megabanks as a result of intense merger activity, but also non-

bank intermediaries, which played a role similar to that of formal banks but were outside central bank s jurisdiction in obtaining liquidity ibid.:115). This whole

process was validated by increasing financial deregulation measures such as the

Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act in 1999 in USA, which allowed commercial banks to

engage in financial investment activities.

The combination of demand factors (stagnant earnings, privatisation of

public services) and supply factors (securitisation, deregulation) led households

in high-income economies to become more involved in financial markets,

although to a varying extent in different countries depending on the degree of

liberalisation and deregulation introduced. On the supply side, financial

intermediaries were eager to include more households in their services partly to

compensate for diminishing deposits from non-financial firms (banks) and partly

Page 5: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

4

to generate more underlying assets for CDOs so as to keep pace with the rapidly

growing demand for securitised instruments among financial investors (bank

and non-bank intermediaries) (cf. Goda/Lysandrou 2013). In the process, many

non-bank intermediaries took advantage of lax financial regulation and engaged in predatory lending practices by offering subprime" mortgages at extremely harsh conditions to social groups previously excluded from access to credit, such

as the young, women and racial minorities (cf. Dymski et al. 2013). Those

subprime mortgages formed a lion share of securitised assets demanded by

investors. In result, growth in homeownership rates among households at the

bottom of the distribution spiked (Fig.1). Securitisation and tranching of

subprime loans and other instruments into CDOs created an unequal hierarchy

of monetary claims, giving priority to the interests of senior (and wealthy)

financial investors and diminishing possibilities of debt renegotiation and

forgiveness in case of financial distress for the low-income borrowers (cf. Mian

and Sufi 2013). In the wake of the crisis, this resulted in a wave of foreclosures,

evictions and unsustainable indebtedness for the subprime borrowers,

spreading the burden of the crisis unequally between different race and gender

groups (cf. Young 2010).

Figure 1. Percentage change in homeownership rate by percentile,

USA 1989-2007 (source: Survey of Consumer Finances)

These mutually validating processes associated with financial sector

transformation set in motion institutional forces exerting direct impact on the

dynamics of income and wealth distribution in advanced countries. Data show

that various measures of inequality have dramatically increased in high-income

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Pe

rce

nt

Page 6: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

5

countries. In USA, where the trends are the most extreme, Gini coefficient for

income rose from 0.48 in 1982 to 0.57 in 2006 (Wolff 2014:27). Furthermore,

the share of national income held by the richest 1% (excluding capital gains) in

USA increased by 131% between 1980 and 2012, peaking at 18.3% in 2007

(Alvaredo et al., fig.2).

Figure 2. The top 1% income share, USA 1980-2013 (source: Alvaredo et al.)

The growth in inequality at the top tail of the distribution was driven by

financial sector, with financial services sector employees accounting for 15%-

27% of the top 0.1% of the income distribution in USA (and non-financial sector

top executives representing only around 6%, cf. Kaplan/Rauh 2009).

Simultaneously, due to wage growth lagging behind productivity growth, the

share of worker compensation in GDP declined steadily from 62% in 1980 to

56% in 2013 in USA (AMECO Database), suggesting redistribution of national

income towards profits, specifically financial profits (Krippner 2005).

In terms of wealth, the rise in wealth Gini in USA has been less dynamic

than that of income but its level has been persistently higher, reaching 0.87 in

2010 (Wolff 2014). Deepening wealth inequality is further highlighted by the

Pe

rce

nt

0

5

10

15

20

25

Top 1% income share

Top 1% income share inc. capital gains

Page 7: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

6

growing gap between mean and median net worth (defined as marketable assets

less current debt) — in USA, the mean-median ratio increased from 3.9 in 1983

to 7 in 2013 (Survey of Consumer Finances, fig.3). Similarly to income, finance

has been strongly associated with rising wealth inequality. Almost a third of

wealth of the Forbes 400 listed rich derives from finance, compared with around

10% from manufacturing or technology (Foster/Holleman 2010).

Figure 3. Mean and median net worth (left axis) and the mean-median ratio

(right axis), USA 1983-2013 (source: Survey of Consumer Finances)

These worrying trends in inequality were only briefly reversed during the

2007 recession. The top 1% income share in USA declined from 18.3% in 2007 to

16.7% in 2009, but it quickly recovered to 18.9% in 2012. Importantly, fall in the

top 1% share of national income was redistributed within the top quintile, as the

share of the top 10% decreased by far less than the top 1% share between

2007-2011 (Dufour/Orhangazi 2016:165). Real wages were temporarily on the

rise and despite growing unemployment, low and middle income households

suffered smaller income losses than the top 1%. The latter saw they capital

income diminished in result of falling asset and property prices

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

1983 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013

Median Net Worth Mean Net Worth Mean-Median Ratio

00

0s,

20

13

US

D

Page 8: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

7

3,5

60,6

18,9 21

127

41,2

71,5

134,5

51,3

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

Debt / equity ratio Debt / income ratio Principal residencedebt / house value

Top 1%

All HHs

Middle 3

quintiles

(Dufour/Orhangazi 2016:165). The overall Gini coefficient for income fell from

0.57 to 0.55 (Wolff 2014:27). Nevertheless, there are reasons to believe that the

relative income gains for the working class are likely to be short lived as positive

growth of real wages in recent years has been driven primarily by low inflation

(caused mainly by falling commodity prices, which are known to be highly

volatile) rather than rising nominal wages (Gould 2016).

In contrast, while falling asset prices slightly diminished the stocks of

wealth of the rich, the Gini coefficient for wealth increased by 0.035 Gini points

in the post-crisis period (Wolff 2014:32). In fact, while median net wealth fell by

21.2% from 2007 to 2010, mean net wealth saw only 6.5% decline, suggesting an

uneven burden of the crisis across the society (ibid.:24). The increase in wealth

inequality during the crisis was due to different degrees of leverage across the

population (ibid.:32). The ratios of debt to assets and income were unsustainable

for the middle and bottom part of the distribution and amplified the asset price

losses (Fig.4). Consequently, wealth gains experienced by these income groups in

the 1990s and early 2000s relied primarily on asset price inflation and

increasing indebtedness, turning to be illusory as the recession unfolded (Fig.5).

Figure 4. Financial fragility measures by percentile, USA 2010 (source: Wolff 2014)

Pe

rce

nt

Page 9: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

8

Figure 5. Median net worth average annual growth rate by decile,

USA 1989-2013 (source: Survey of Consumer Finances)

The key argument of this paper is that these differences in the dynamics

of wealth and inequality are related to balance sheet composition of households

along the distribution (Fig.6). Middle- and low-income households rely more

heavily on primary residence and high homeownership rates (67% share of total

assets compared to 31% for all households) and greater relative indebtedness

(debt-equity and debt-income ratio at 72% and 135% respectively compared to

21% and 127% for the whole sample, see fig.5) driven by mortgage debt, making

their balance sheets more vulnerable to financial shocks (ibid.:22). As was

mentioned before, asset price movements and housing market collapse shortly

before the Great Recession generated a massive drop in median wealth, while

mean net worth suffered less and grew at a faster rate than the median in the

whole period, indicating deepening inequality. The fact that top quintiles

directed most of their wealth into financial assets meant that annual rates of

return were comparatively higher for these wealth groups (ibid.:30-31).

Crucially, these dynamics of household balance sheet structures were directly

related to the political economy of securitisation and household indebtedness

outlined above. Consequently, a powerful case of the impact of financialisation

Pe

rce

nt

-1,78

0,46

-7,84

0,74

3,66

-4,83

2,45

4,23

-1,63

-10,0

-8,0

-6,0

-4,0

-2,0

0,0

2,0

4,0

6,0

1989-2013 1989-2007 2007-2013

Bottom 40% 40th-90th percentile Top 10%

Page 10: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

9

on inequality emerges from wealth distribution, household balance sheet

structures and leverage.

Figure 6. Household portfolio composition, USA 2014 (source: Wolff 2014)

Overall, the above analysis of the data reveals that in the context of

financial sector transformation an important aspect of inequality emerges from

the distribution of wealth. The growing need for borrowing arising from

retrenchment of the state and labour market liberalisation policies was matched

by rising demand of wealthy financial investors for securitised assets derived

from loans to households. This led to an emergence of a new class of

homeowners forming the new middle class. Their wealth gains were driven by

the real and financial housing bubble and were largely eroded during the Great

Recession. Coupled with stagnating incomes, the new home owning middle class

lost out the most due to financial sector transformation. It is argued below that

the existing theoretical approaches to inequality do not fully account for this

heterogeneity of wealth among households its impact on inequality. The

proposed theoretical model aims to incorporate these considerations.

9,4

66,6

31,3

5,5

5,9

6,2

7,8

14,2

15,3

25,4

3,1

15,7

50,3

8,9

29,8

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%

Top 1%

Middle 3 quintiles

All HHs

Principal residence

Liquid assets

Pension accounts

Corporate stock, financial assets, trusts and funds

Unincorp. business equity, other real estate

Other

Page 11: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

10

II. Theories of inequality – an assessment

Although aspects of wealth have been increasingly incorporated into

distributional theories, heterogeneity of households financial positions has not

been taken into full consideration explicitly.

Theory putting the largest emphasis on the importance of wealth for

inequality is found in the seminal work of Piketty (2014). The main premise of his Capital in the Twenty-First Century is that inequality is driven by accumulation of persistently higher returns to wealth (r) relative to the growth

of income (g) (historically averaging at 5% and 1% respectively). Compounding

of the returns to wealth overtime generates higher income flows for the wealth

holders and their inheritors (identified with the top 0.1-1%) than for the rest of

the society. Higher capital income in turn allows for greater saving, facilitating

further wealth generation and perpetuating inequality. In other work

(Piketty/Zucman 2014) it is emphasised that due to its high concentration and

the aforementioned accumulation dynamics, inequality of wealth is more

important for the overall structure of inequality in the 21st century than in the

post-war era. Importantly, saving and consumption propensities are not enough

to predict wealth-income levels in advanced countries (higher wealth-income

ratios suggesting large economic power of asset holders and deepening

inequality). This is because capital gains (often driven by housing wealth) are

found to account for around 40% of increase in national wealth to income ratios

between 1970 and 2010 (Piketty/Zucman 2014:1288). Piketty s insight regarding the interplay between income and wealth dynamics and its impact on inequality is particularly relevant in the age of

financialisation. As highlighted in the introduction, financial innovation and

securitisation influenced inequality by generating differential rates of return and

degrees of volatility across the distribution. Large wealth holdings of the rich

allowed them to invest in high-yielding financial instruments (often requiring

large initial payments, which can only be afforded at high levels of net worth),

generating sizeable capital income. Moreover, they were able to use their

economic power to secure higher wages, particularly when employed in financial

sector.

Page 12: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

11

Despite the importance of its general conclusions, Piketty s Capital in the Twenty-First century suffers from several drawbacks. The most relevant criticisms for our analysis concern the weakness of Piketty s theoretical explanation and insufficient emphasis on household debt in contributing to

inequality.

While his empirical work is to be applauded, theoretical explanation for

inequality based on r greater than g relies on the expectation that these trends observed in the past would continue into the future (Pressman 2016:159).

Hence, Piketty does not provide any explicit theoretical explanation why returns

to wealth should always exceed the growth of income. Consequently, despite the

relevance of his conclusions, there is no formal link between inequality and

financial sector transformation in Piketty s framework. The alternative body of theoretical literature identified with the Post

Keynesian functional distribution explicitly takes into account the link between

financialisation and distribution. It focuses on the macroeconomic impact of

increasingly unequal functional distribution of national income between two

factors of production – capital and labour – which are associated with higher

propensity to save and consume respectively (cf. Kalecki 1971). The distributive

force of financialisation is seen as the maximisation of shareholder value,

proxied by a higher rentier (i.e. capitalist) income share, related to the

increasingly short-term orientation in firm operations and preference for

financial rather than real investment, which increased the corporate governance

power towards shareholders (cf. Hein 2009, 2015; Hein/Van Treeck 2010; Palley

2012, 2013; Van Treeck 2009). These models often draw from Bhaduri/Marglin

(1990) argument that the macroeconomic effects of income transfers between

wage and profit earners hinge on whether the economy is wage- or profit-led.

Onaran et al. (2011) establish that the majority of advanced economies are

wage-led, which in the Bhaduri/Marglin framework signifies that lower wage

share resulting from financial sector transformation has a negative impact on

aggregate demand and growth by undercutting effective investment demand

because resources are taken away from those who are more likely to spend them

to those who are more likely to hoard them.

Page 13: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

12

However, what this theoretical approach has not yet done is to examine

how the transformation in the nature of financial intermediation has

complexified the division of society into two distinct categories. Both groups of workers and capitalists have become heterogeneous, which complicates their

analytical usefulness. In the course of financialisation workers became the

recipients of capital income through homeownership and private pension

schemes, while capitalists became the recipients of the highest wages in the

economy. In fact, the top 10% of earners were the only income group with

above-average income growth between 1979-2012 (Bivens et al. 2014), with the

top 5% of wage earners experiencing a wage increase during the Great Recession

(Table 1). Clearly, not only are there large disparities in the aggregate

characteristics of households within each category but also the boundaries

between the two have become less clear.

Table 1. Average annual growth rates of average hourly wages, USA 1979-2012

(own calculation based on Bivens et al. 2014)

Moreover, Keynesian models are traditionally focused on investment as

the variable most important for macroeconomic growth, treating savings and

consumption as residual and passive (Setterfield/Kim 2013:2). However, since

1980s consumption has become much more volatile and thus more important as

an independent source of aggregate demand. This is largely due to development

of financial sectors and massive expansion of credit to households, leading

household spending to become increasingly disconnected from income.

1979-2012 1979-2007 2007-2012

All households +0.7% +0.8% +0.02%

0th-40th percentile –0.14% +0.05% –1.2%

40th-80th percentile +0.13% +0.3% –0.6%

80th-95th percentile +0.8% +1.02% –0.3%

Top 5% +2.9% +3.4% +0.4%

Page 14: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

13

Similar drawback can be identified in Piketty. This is because his

argument relies on comparing average growth rates of wealth and income.

However, there is a substantial variability in income and wealth trends across

the distribution, which is particularly important when it comes to understanding

the impact of financialisation on inequality. As suggested in the introduction, the

top 10% experienced the most rapid and above average wage income and net

wealth growth over the past decades. In contrast, income and wealth gains to the

middle and lower class were illusory as they were underpinned by a housing

price bubble and large household debt holdings relative to income and assets.

Consequently, differential degrees of leverage across the population turned to be

an important driver of inequality, particularly during the 2007 recession. It is not

only the access to financial resources but also the stability of that access

overtime across the population that has implications for inequality. For instance,

financial investors owning a diversified portfolio of securitised assets with

return guaranteed by the seniorage of their claims (due to tranching) are better

able to bear financial losses associated with risky financial instruments than

households whose portfolios are based on housing equity withdrawal (HEW). In

the latter case, price deflation of collateralised assets prevents further

withdrawal of equity to cover outstanding loan repayments, generating higher volatility of household s balance sheet position relative to the former case. Since

interest rates differ for the bottom/middle and high-income households, there is a disproportionate impact of borrowing on financial stability of households balance sheets (Pressman/Scott 2009). When interest payments are considered,

smaller portion of income is available of consumption and hence inequality is

deepened.

Examination of household balance sheets structures remains relevant

after the Great Recession. Scott/Pressman (2015) show that households have

not deleveraged their massive debt levels after the 2008 crisis. Using data from

US Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) they show that the decrease in total

median monthly debt payments and debt payments to income ratio has been

illusory and reflected low interest rates rather than real reduction in debt. In

fact, mortgage debt levels have not fallen much since the recession. Moreover,

the share of households filing for bankruptcy has been rising since 2010. Because

Page 15: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

14

households have not deleveraged properly after the Great Recession, there have

been no increases in consumption and saving allowing for more equitable

growth of the economy.

Consequently, there is a gap in the existing literature on inequality. On the

one hand, Piketty s insight on the interplay between wealth and income is not fully developed on a theoretical level. On the other hand, the Post Keynesian

theoretical literature does not take into sufficiently explore the role of wealth

distribution, household balance sheet structures and leverage for overall

inequality dynamics. This provides an opportunity to complement the existing

literature with a theoretical model incorporating wealth into the analysis of

inequality. We propose a three-class theoretical model aiming to explain the

observed trends in inequality, accounting for disparate wage growth, unequal

returns to wealth and leverage across the population and the role played by the

middle class.

III. Wealth and inequality in stock-flow consistent models

To maintain dialogue with the existing literature on financialisation and

distribution described above, we adopt the method well established among the

Post Keynesians, namely the stock flow consistent modelling (thereby SFCM).

Originating in Copeland (1949) and the works of Tobin and Godley in 1980s, the

framework has recently been formalised by Godley/Lavoie (2007). It is a

macroeconomic tool integrating stocks and flows across real and financial

sectors in the economy in a consistent fashion, relying on the quadruple-entry

system, which necessitates that every inflow has a corresponding outflow in the

system (Caverzasi/Godin 2013).

A number of recent contributions in the SFCM literature take into account

some aspects of household wealth into the analyses of growth and

macroeconomic stability (Zezza 2008; Caversazi/Godin 2013; Setterfield/Kim

2013; Nikolaidi 2015; Sawyer/Passarella Veronese 2015;

Dafermos/Papatheodorou 2015). Most commonly, it is by allowing for

borrowing by workers, whose debt becomes financial assets of the rentiers via

banks. Wealth of rentiers is usually divided into equities and deposits and

Page 16: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

15

allocation between these two components depends on the relative rates of

return. We argue, however, that current analyses do not adequately capture the

impact of financialisation on balance sheet structures of different households

and hence inequality. The models do not consider the importance of the middle

class in this context as the standard two-class division of households into

workers and capitalists prevails.

With the exception of Dafermos/Papatheodorou (2015), most of the

SFCMs reviewed above do not explain income distribution endogenously. This is

because they are ultimately concerned with macroeconomic growth and

stability. Consequently, analysis of household balance sheets based on the

division of society in two classes of workers and capitalists encounters the same

difficulties as described in the previous section, namely that they do not

sufficiently account for the heterogeneity of wealth among different households.

Apart from Sawyer/Passarella Veronese (2015) borrowing is restricted to

workers, while in most high-income countries it is the rich who are indebted the

most both in terms of value and participation (Survey of Consumer Finances).

Furthermore, few of the studies reviewed above take into account changes

within the financial sector brought about by financialisation – Nikolaidi (2015)

and Sawyer/Passarella Veronese (2015) constitute one of the few analyses

incorporating a sophisticated financial sector. Consequently, the proposed model

attempts to fill the emergent gap in the literature, providing an analysis of

endogenous inequality determination in an economy with a complex financial

sector. Emphasis is put on balance sheet structures within the household sector

and, in particular, different levels of leverage across the population.

IV. Model specification

The aim of the model presented in this paper is to account for household wealth

dynamics in explaining inequality in a financialised economy, using the

benchmark exercise developed by Dafermos/Papatheodorou (2015). The model

setup is simulated and the evolution of various inequality measures is examined

for the personal distribution of income and wealth, with functional income

distribution treated as given. The US economy is taken as an example. The

Page 17: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

16

methodology of SFCM yields itself to consideration of the reinforcing dynamics

between stocks of wealth and flows of income a la Piketty. Tables 2 and 3

present the balance sheet and transaction flow matrices respectively for the

sectors in our economy. The model considers a closed economy with no

government consisting of 5 sectors: a three-tier household sector, firms,

commercial banks, special purpose vehicles (SPVs) and underwriters, as well as

institutional investors. This distinction within the financial sector aims to

capture the increased complexity of financial institutions in the course of

financialisation. Specifically, it allows for introduction of securitisation into the

model dynamics, which is argued to have had an impact on inequality by

generating uneven returns and risk for households along the distribution (see

introduction). m

Page 18: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

17

Table 2. Balance sheet matrix

Households

Firms Commercial

banks SPVs/underwriters

Institutional investors

Sum Working class Middle class Rentier class

Deposits +Mw +Mm +Mr –Mw–Mm–Mr 0

Loans –Lw –Lm –Lr +Lw+LmNS+Lr +LmS 0

Capital +K +K

Houses +phHm +phHr +phHU +phH

Equity +E –E 0

MBS –MBS +MBS 0

Institutional investors shares +SH –SH 0

Net worth Vw Vm Vr Vf Vb Vs VI V

Page 19: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

18

Table 3. Transaction flow matrix

Households Firms Commercial banks SPVs/underwriters Institutional investors

Sum Working class

Middle class

Rentier class Current Capital Current Capital Current Capital Current Capital

Consumption –Cw –Cm –Cr +Cw+Cm+Cr 0

Investment +I –I 0

Wages +Ww +Wm +Wr –W 0

Firm profits +DP –TP +RP 0

Bank profits +FB –FB 0

Financial profits

+FI –FI 0

SPVs profits –COUPAY +COUPAY 0

Interest on deposits

+rm*Mw +rm*Mm +rm*Mr –rm*M 0

Interest on loans

–rw*Lw –rlm*Lm –rl*Lr +rw*Lw+rlm*Lr

+rl*LmNS +rlm*LmS 0

Rent on housing

–R +R 0 Δ Deposits –ΔMw –ΔMm –ΔMr +ΔM 0 Δ Loans +ΔLw +ΔLm +ΔLr –ΔLw–ΔLr –ΔLmNS

–ΔLmS 0 Δ Capital +ΔK –ΔK 0 Δ (ouses –ph*Δ(m –ph*Δ(r +ph*Δ(m +ph*Δ(r

0 Δ Equities –pe*ΔE +pe*ΔE 0 Δ MBS +ΔMBS –ΔMBS 0 Δ )nst. inv. shares

–ΔS( +ΔS( 0 Δ Net worth ΔVw ΔVm ΔVr 0 ΔVf 0 ΔVb 0 ΔVs 0 ΔVI ΔV

Page 20: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

19

The household sector

In contrast to the existing Post Keynesian approaches to distribution, social

groups in our analysis are defined not by the type of employment or ownership

of the means of production but by their balance sheet characteristics. As argued

previously, this is a more suitable method to understanding inequality in the age

of financial sector transformation and massive indebtedness of the society.

Moreover, it links with the theory developed by Piketty, which highlights the

importance of wealth in contributing to overall inequality.

The working class

The working class includes non-supervisory production/ blue collar workers. )n line with the Kaleckian approach, this group has the highest propensity to

consume. Critically, they are the most leveraged group. It is identified with the

bottom 40% of US population, which experience net wealth losses over the past

three decades (see fig.5 above).

One of the phenomena associated with financial sector transformation

has been the massive extension of credit to those previously excluded from

access to it based on their low incomes and low or non-existent wealth. As was argued before, this credit expansion wasn t accidental as household loans, primarily mortgages and consumer credit, constituted the basis for asset-backed

securities. Consequently, there were strong incentives in the financial sector to

generate as many household loans as possible to satisfy the growing demands of

financial investors for securitised instruments. For these reasons, analysis of the

household sector in the model accounting for financial sector transformation

calls for consideration of credit among the lowest income groups. In the present

model, the working class households are seen as subprime borrowers. We

assume that they do not carry enough wealth and income that would allow them

to take out mortgages and hence that all working class households rent houses.

Consequently, it is assumed that credit to the working class households consists

of unsecured short-term consumer credit and payday loans. This has been

particularly relevant in recent years as unsecured debt and payday borrowing

have been on the rise after the crisis (cf. The Pew Charitable Trust 2012; PWC

2015).

Page 21: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

20

Working class households rely primarily on wage income (Bivens et al.

2014:6). In our model, real disposable income of the working class consists of

wages and interest earned on deposits, less interest paid on loans and house

rental payments to rentiers. Households consume part c1 of their disposable

income as well as proportion c3 of their wealth, and store the remaining savings

as bank deposits. We assume that the propensity to consume of this income

group is the highest among all households. Furthermore, at this stage of the

model we assume constant propensity to consume out of wealth c3 across all

household groups.

Assuming simple adaptive expectations, borrowing by the working class

is determined by their past consumption level, adjusted by parameter β. β captures household borrowing norms as well as lending norms in the financial

sector (Setterfield/Kim 2013:10). In this way, we are able to indirectly account

for borrowing constraints for workers, reflecting commercial banks attitude towards creditworthiness of borrowers. We can think of β as high during the housing bubble, when lending norms were lax due to the perceived minimisation

of credit risk by securitisation. In times of recessions, β can be thought of as low as lenders are more concerned about creditworthiness and lending norms are

strict. Because workers are constrained in their access to credit, their demand

for loans also includes the debt burden ratio, capturing the repayment capacity

of past loans.

Net wealth of the working class is accumulated entirely in deposits, less

loans. Rental payments on housing are defined as a proportion � of the value of

houses owned by rentiers. � depends positively on the change in rentier demand

for housing. At this stage of the analysis it is not endogenously explained why

households in each group chose to rent or own their house, although the earlier

discussion in this paper explains how financial innovation had the middle class

households turn into homeowners and low-income households rely on

unsecured debt.

Because differential degrees of leverage and unequal ability to cope with

financial fragility along the distribution are important contributors to inequality

Page 22: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

21

in a financialised economy (as discussed above), one of the most innovative tasks

of our model is to examine the exact dynamics of household leverage and

inequality. Since measurement of financial distress is a complex task (cf.

DeVaney/Lytton 1995, Boushey/Weller 2008, Ampudia et al. 2014), we include

three different measures of leverage to account for financial fragility in the most

complete way possible at the present stage given our choice of SFCM as

modelling technique. Firstly, the ratio of debt to assets is provided, capturing the

value of loans relative to the value of gross wealth. Secondly, debt to disposable

income ratio constitutes a measure of the stock of loans to the flow of disposable

income in each period. Finally, debt servicing to income ratio shows how much of

gross income is directed towards debt repayments in each period. We assume

that for the working class all of these measures are relatively high.

The middle class

Definition of the middle class is complex. In monetary terms it is defined,

according to the relative size of income, as the middle 60% of the population,

with incomes ranging from 75% to 125% of median income as the standard,

although some studies have extended the upper limit to as much as 300% of

median income (this is because with 125% as the cut-off a disproportionately

large portion of the population in certain countries falls into the upper class

category, cf. Pressman 2007). Atkinson/Brandolini (2011) develop a wealth

criterion to qualify the income definition of the middle class. Based on various

studies, the rich can be classified as having net wealth at least 30 times larger

than mean income. As for the lower cut-off point, members of the middle class

should have enough real and financial assets to be clear from the risk of falling

into poverty for a certain period of time, e.g. 6 months, if income suddenly falls.

Atkinson/Brandolini argue that asset-poor individuals may need to be excluded

from the middle class even if their income exceeds the poverty threshold.

In contrast, definition of the middle class in the present model is centred

on the stylised facts on balance sheet composition and income trends found in

the income and wealth data for USA. Middle class is defined as a group whose

balance sheets depend on housing. Their wealth was rising in the 1990s and

2000s due to increasing house prices, allowing them to refinance their

Page 23: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

22

mortgages by taking on more credit and engage in home equity withdrawal, a

strategy which was only feasible in house price bubble. When the price trends

reversed during 2006 and 2007, these households saw their wealth gains largely

wipe out. For these reason, the middle class is assumed to have high leverage

ratios.

Separation of this group from the working class is important as the

evidence shows that in USA inequality growth has been the most striking

between the middle and upper parts of the population rather than between the

top and the bottom (cf. Wolff 2014). Because of the differential rates of return on

wealth of the upper and middle income groups as well as stagnant income for the

latter, the ratio of median income held by the top 10% to median income of

households in 40th to 90th percentile increased by an average 1.5% a year

between 1989 and 2013, compared to 0.9% growth in the ratio of the top 10% to

bottom 40% median income (Figure 7). This difference in the inequality trends

between the middle and bottom population groups is also related to higher

government support and greater contribution of social security to income of the

latter (Table 4).

Figure 7. Change in the top 10%-bottom 40% and the top 10%-middle 50%

median income ratios, USA 1992-2013 (source: Survey of Consumer Finances)

-6%

-3%

0%

3%

6%

9% T10/B40

T10/M50

T10/B40AverageT10/M50Average

Page 24: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

23

Table 4. Government transfers as a percentage of pre-tax income, USA 2011

(source: Congressional Budget Office)

Note: Government transfers include local, state and federal level in-kind benefits and cash payments from social insurance and government assistance programs.

This definition of the middle class encompasses the portion of the

population between the 40th and the 90th percentile and thus includes the

median household. The lower cut-off has been chosen as households below the

40th percentile saw negative wage and net worth growth between 1989-2013

(see table 1 and fig.5). In contrast, the upper cut-off has been chosen as only

households above the 90th percentile experienced above average income growth

(Bivens et al. 2014).

Because the middle class is assumed to account for 50% of population in

our analysis, issues associated with heterogeneity of this group need to be

acknowledged. Currently, the middle class in our model includes both subprime

mortgage borrowers, whose incomes resemble more the income of the working

class, and the middle-managers in the 80th-90th percentile, whose incomes and

wealth are closer to the rentier households.

We argue that heterogeneity issues cannot be avoided in analysing the

household sector. Three class division adopted here is superior to the two-class

conceptualisation of households in the literature because it allows for a more

intricate examination of household balance sheets, leverage and incomes in the

age of financialisation, which altered the traditionally envisaged economic

relationships. There is a possibility of extending the division of households even

further, which has been done by Dafermos/Papatheodorou (2015). Such detailed

division is not necessary in the present model for two reasons. Firstly, it would

introduce a considerable degree of complexity to an already elaborate model of

Bottom quintile 36.9%

Second quintile 34.6%

Middle quintile 24.8%

Fourth quintile 14.4%

Highest quintile 4.4%

Page 25: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

24

heterogeneous households and financial institutions. Secondly, in an aggregate

model that SFCM is, it would be difficult to meaningfully break down the social

classes into upper/lower groups and introduce a drastically different picture of

balance sheets than already provided in the three class model. This is because at

the aggregate level the most important distinctions between the different types

of debt and wealth accumulation possibilities are already made.

Real disposable income of the middle class consists of wage income and

interest earned on deposits less interest payments on loans. A fraction of

disposable income and wealth is consumed. Residual income is saved as

deposits, including realised capital gains on housing.

Borrowing of the middle class depends on their target consumption and

their debt burden. Target consumption incorporates past consumption (due to

simple adaptive expectations) and relative consumption concerns, which depend

on rentier consumption adjusted by an emulation parameter η. η is exogenously

defined as the Ravina emulation parameter (Ravina 2007). Consumption

emulation has recently emerged as a potentially important driver of borrowing

(cf. Cynamon/Fazzari 2008, Pressman/Scott 2009), leading to lower levels of

consumption than income inequality (cf. Krueger/Perri 2006). However, while in

existing SFCM studies emulation is applied to low-income workers (see above

and Kapeller/Schuetz 2015; Detzer 2016), we restrict relative consumption to

the middle class. This approach is more reflective of reality as emulation motives

are more likely to be relevant among the more affluent households belonging to

the middle class, who can afford necessities such as owning their house. In

contrast, working class households are more concerned with maintaining their

living standards in the light of rising living costs (rent payments). Their demand

for loans is thus more likely to be driven by necessitous borrowing concerns (cf.

Pollin 1988) rather than their desire to follow the celebrity lifestyle of the rich. It

would be possible to introduce emulation of the middle class consumption by the

working class, in line with the expenditure cascades theory where each group

emulates consumption of the one just above it in the distribution (Frank et al.

2014). However, we believe that in the age of financial sector transformation,

due to falling median incomes and increases in the prices of housing, rising

Page 26: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

25

demand of low-income households for unsecured credit such as payday loans is

motivated primarily by sustaining a constant standard of living rather than

achievement of social status.

Net wealth of the middle class is composed of deposits and housing, less

loans. We therefore assume that middle class households are owner-occupiers of their houses and hence that they don t rent out their property) and that loans to

the middle class consist exclusively mortgages. Demand for houses by the middle

class depends positively on their income and change in the provision of

mortgages and negatively on their consumption and debt-to-income ratio,

adjusted by the price of housing. As in the case of the working class, different

measures of financial fragility for the middle class are presented, including the

debt-to-asset ratio, debt-to-income ratio and the debt-service-to-income ratio.

Rentier class

Households in this group are defined as the top 10% of the population. In

contrast to the other household groups, they saw income growth equal or above

the average since 1980s (Bivens et al. 2014). Moreover, their balance sheets are

relying primarily on financial wealth rather than housing or wages, which

differentiates this group from the middle and the working class respectively (see

fig.6).

Existing studies accounting for distributional heterogeneity often adopt

social classification from the times of Marx and treat the rich as pure rentiers,

deriving their income purely from capital ownership. This is also envisaged by

Piketty – as wealth becomes inherited and compounding returns to wealth

exceed income growth overtime, the rich abandon work as they are able to live

off the returns to their wealth. While this was true in the pre-Fordist era and

seems like a plausible scenario for the future in light of the deepening wealth concentration, it doesn t describe the realities seen since the post-war period.

Data for USA show that inheritance accounts for a small portion of existing

wealth for the rich (Keister/Lee 2014:20). In turn, much of the income of the top

10% derives not only from large returns to capital but also from extremely high

salaries, particularly for financial sector executives (cf. Kaplan/Rauh 2010). To

Page 27: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

26

account for growing wage inequality we can describe the rentier class in our

model as working rentiers . This complements the traditional Post Keynesian

view of the capitalist class as owners of capital earning no wage income.

Importantly, the rentier class engages in work not because of necessity (as is in

the case of the working and the middle class) but because institutional

conditions made employment an alternative investment strategy for the rich along the ownership of capital, as they are able to use their financial power to

influence their earnings.

Furthermore, in contrast to the majority of SFCM studies including debt,

we allow for indebtedness of the rich. This is because the analysis of household

survey data reveals that the top decile undertakes sizeable debt and constitutes

the most indebted income group in terms of both participation and the amount

of debt. Consequently, in our model it is assumed that rentiers borrow from

banks to consume and invest in excess of their wage and capital income. Rentier

borrowing depends positively on their wealth, which serves as a collateral. What

is different about indebtedness of the rich is their leverage. In contrast to other

income groups, debt of the top decile constitutes a small portion of their assets. Rentiers disposable income consists of wages, interest on deposits, part

of the profits of firms, commercial banks and institutional investors, return on

equity, institutional investors shares as well as housing rent payments by the

working class households, less interest paid on loans. As other household groups,

rentiers consume a fraction of their income and wealth. In line with Kalecki,

rentiers are assumed to have the lowest propensity to consume among all

household groups. Deposits of rentiers consist of residual saving as well as

realised capital gains on housing and equity.

Borrowing of rentiers depends on their past consumption and debt

burden ratio and does not include relative consumption concerns. It should be

mentioned, however, that since growth in the national income share of the top

10% is driven by the top 1%, and the growth of the top 1% share is driven by the

top 0.1% (cf. Piketty 2014), relative consumption motives are bound to be

especially strong among the richest 10%, who engage in luxury goods consumption and aim to attain the highest status and the associated celebrity

Page 28: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

27

lifestyle . (owever, high aggregation of SFCM and the elaborate character of the

current model prevent us from modelling the precise consumption behaviour of

different income groups within the top 10%.

It is assumed that the allocation of rentiers wealth between houses, equities, institutional investors shares and deposits (treated as a buffer stock)

follows a Tobinesque portfolio principle and depends on the relative rates of

return offered on these assets (Caverzasi/Godin 2015:16). Business equity

accounts for an important part of wealth for the richest 10% and thus rentiers in

our model are assumed to own all firm equity. Return on housing considered by

the rentiers is given by the ratio of rent payments by the working class and

capital gains on housing to the value of housing in the previous period.

Firms

To rein in the complexity arising from the three class composition of the

household sector, firm analysis remains simple. Profits are residual and the

profit share is determined as a mark-up over unit labour costs. It is assumed that

firms invest in housing and produce a single capital good on demand so that

capital inventories are not taken into account. Furthermore, we assume that

firms retain part of their profits and distribute the rest to rentiers.

Output of the modelled economy is given by consumption spending of

households as well as investment in productive capital and housing. Wage bill

follows from a bargaining process and is defined according to an exogenously

given wage share of output. Wage rates of the working and the middle class

depend on the share of each group (Nw and Nm respectively) in total population.

Importantly, wages paid to rentiers are linked to a variable remuneration dependent on firms profits. The rentier wage premium is given by a premium

mw > 1 over the workers wage rate, the profit sharing element ℎ and exogenous

parameter ∈ , reflecting the relative importance of profit remuneration in

the wage rate determination (Dafermos/Papatheodorou 2015:13).

Investment is defined simply as the growth rate of capital stock. A fraction x

of investment spending is financed by equity issue.

Page 29: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

28

Apart from productive capital, firms invest in housing, which depends on

the difference between housing demanded by rentiers and the middle class and

the available housing supply in the previous period. In every period, a stock of

houses remains unsold, depending on the change in the supply and demand for

housing among the middle class (note that the Tobinesque portfolio equation

implies that all houses demanded by rentiers are sold). Change in the price of

housing is given by the difference between the change in the demand for housing

by rentiers and the middle class and the change in supply of housing by firms.

Commercial banks

Since the aim of our model is to account for inequality determination in the age

of financialisation, commercial banks are envisaged as active profit-seeking

entities rather than passive intermediaries between debtors and creditors.

Profits of commercial banks are generated by charging higher interest rates on

loans than offered on deposits. A constant interest rate on deposits is assumed

for all households, defined as an exogenous premium �1 over a given central

bank interest rate. The interest rate on loans is set by charging an exogenous

premium �2 over the deposit rate. Commercial bank profits are thus derived as a

sum of interest payments on non-securitised mortgages of the middle class,

consumer loans of the working class and loans to rentiers, less interest payments

on deposits to households. All profits are transferred to rentier households, who

are the owners of all financial institutions.

Commercial banks accept deposits from the household sector. However,

each household group faces a different rate of interest depending on the

perception of their creditworthiness by banks. Interest on loans to the working

class is higher than the rate charged to the middle class and rentiers. This risk

premium depends on exogenous parameters 0 and 1, capturing institutional

conditions in financial markets, the debt to income ratio of the working class, and

their debt service ratio.

Importantly, part of mortgages taken out by the middle class are

securitised and sold to underwriters and their SPVs. The share of securitised

loans depends on an exogenous parameter s0 (capturing institutional conditions

Page 30: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

29

such as the degree of financial regulation) and the target yield on mortgage-

based securities (MBS) (given by the past yield under the assumption of simple

adaptive expectations), adjusted by parameter s1.

Middle class loans are subject to a mortgage rate, defined as a spread over

the commercial bank lending rate. The mortgage spread depends positively on

parameter 0, the debt service ratio and the debt to income ratio of the middle

class adjusted by parameter 2, and negatively on the rate of return on MBS

adjusted by parameter 3.

SPVs/underwriters

The main role of the sector of SPVs and underwriters is to transform securitised

mortgages bought from commercial banks into mortgage-backed securities

(MBS). It is assumed that SPVs/underwriters pay no administrative fees to banks

for this transaction.

It is assumed that all MBS are sold to institutional investors without any

fee in the form of coupon payments at a coupon rate determined by an

exogenous spread over the mortgage rate. Consequently, the SPVs/underwriters

sector accumulates no profits. Importantly, MBS issued are assumed to be of the single pass-through type rather than consisting of various pooled MBS cf. Nikolaidi 2015:4).

Institutional investors

The institutional investors sector includes entities such as pension funds, mutual

funds, hedge funds, insurance companies, and investment banks (cf. Davis 2003).

They earn revenue from holding MBS and finance their operations by issuing

shares, which are purchased by rentiers. For simplicity, a constant price of

shares equal to $1 is assumed. Demand for MBS follows the portfolio principle,

where the return on MBS depends on the yield and capital gains on MBS.

Institutional investors accumulate profits equal to the coupon payments

from SPVs/underwriters, which are entirely distributed to rentiers. Return on institutional investors shares is given as the ratio of their profits to shares demanded by rentiers in the previous period.

Page 31: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

30

Simulations

The model is calibrated to the US economy. The main objective of the simulation

exercise is to examine the impact of the proposed model on inequality patters.

Specifically, we analyse how changes in household balance sheet composition

and leverage affect quantitative measures of income inequality such as the Gini

index, the Atkinson index (with inequality aversion parameter �=2) and the

squared coefficient of variation. While the Gini and Atkinson indices range

between 0 and 1, squared coefficient of variation ranges from 0 to infinity. In all

indices, higher value indicates higher inequality level. This follows the

benchmark exercise outlined in Dafermos/Papatheodorou (2015) where the

choice of these three inequality measures is motivated by their different

sensitivity to inequality in different moments of the distribution (the middle, the

bottom and the top of the distribution respectively).

In addition, we calculate the Theil T index to capture wealth inequality.

This is because the other measures of income inequality incorporated in our

model cannot be readily adapted to the distribution of wealth due to possible

negative net worth values (cf. Cowell 2009:72). Theil T index is a generalised

entropy measure of inequality, ranging between 0 and infinity, higher value

corresponding to a higher inequality level (World Bank 2005). To compare the

distributions of income and wealth in our model, we also compute the Theil T

index for income.

It is expected that the balance sheet heterogeneity should produce more

acute long-run polarisation of income. This is because the inclusion of wealth in

the model creates forces which pull the upper class even further away from the

rest of the distribution, drowning the middle and working class in debt.

Consideration of the different types of debt, which is reflected in our distinction

between the working and the middle class, could also explain the middle class

meltdown in countries like USA and should reproduce the illusion of short-run

prosperity for the middle class in the run up to the crisis.

Firstly, a full model, which is outlined above, is simulated for 100 periods.

For clarity, simulation results are presented from period 20 onwards to allow for

Page 32: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

31

adjustment of the system to a steady state. The steady state is defined as a

situation where all variables in the economy grow at the same rate, given by the

exogenous growth rate of capital gk. Results for the income Gini coefficient, the

Atkinson index and the squared coefficient of variation as well as for the Theil T

index for income and wealth are presented. Additionally, we report the three

measures of leverage for each household group.

Secondly, we compare the above results of the full model with reduced

form specification without the novel features introduced in our model, namely

rentier wage, rentier debt and securitisation.

V. Results

Simulations of the model produce a consistent result of increasing inequality

according to all measures. The Gini index in the model tends towards 0.6, which

is close to the actual 2006 value recorded in USA (see introduction). The

Atkinson index tends towards 0.45 and the squared coefficient variation towards

1.25 (Fig.8, panel A). Furthermore, model results show that wealth inequality is

higher than income inequality, which reproduces the stylised fact outlined in the

introduction (panel B in fig.8). This is measured using Theil T indices for both

income and wealth to maintain comparability.

Interesting results follow from simulating various financial fragility

measures. Looking at the debt-to-asset ratio, the working class is the most

leveraged, with the ratio stabilising at 0.5 (panel D in fig.8). The ratio for the

middle and the rentier class reaches 0.4, with rentiers being slightly less

leveraged than the middle class. This is because of the presence of housing on the

asset side of the middle class balance sheet. However, although the ratio for

rentiers reaches similar values as the middle class, rentiers do not face the

negative consequences of large debt holdings as the middle and the working

class due to high returns to their assets and diverse income sources. This is best

highlighted by examination of the debt service to income ratio (panel C, fig.8).

This measure shows clearly that debt is the most burdensome for the working

class, as debt repayments in each period correspond to 8.7% of their income.

Similarly, despite lower debt-to-asset ratio of the middle class, their debt

repayment ratio of 0.077 puts them closer to the working class in terms of their

Page 33: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

32

balance sheet fragility. Conversely, due to multiple income sources and large

high-yielding asset holdings rentiers debt service corresponds to only 3.8% of

their income in each period.

In contrast, an opposite picture emerges from the debt-to-income ratio

analysis (panel E, fig.8). By this measure, the working class is leveraged the least,

with the ratio reaching 0.87. The ratio for the middle class stabilises at 1.3 and

for rentiers at 1.4. This order is surprising and does not corresponds to the debt-

to-income ratios found in the household survey data. Hence, while our model

reproduces the empirical fact that debt of rentiers is large, it either understates

the demand for loans by the working and the middle class or it overstates their

income. This may be either because the part of the wage share accruing to the

working and the middle class is overstated in our model compared to the real

world or because the impact of securitisation on household indebtedness does

not generate enough supply and demand for debt among the lower and middle

income groups. Both of these explanations are related to the aggregate nature of

the SFCM method and the inability to decompose the imposed aggregated

structures. Consequently, in the context of our model it is important to examine

household financial fragility holistically, as each of the commonly used measures provides different information on households capacity to handle financial distress.

Page 34: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

33

Figure 8. Simulation results – full model

De

bt

serv

ice

to

in

com

e r

ati

o

Working class Middle class Rentier class

(A)

(B) (C)

(D) (E)

Gini index Atkinson index Squared coefficient of variation

Working class Middle class Rentier class

Working class Middle class Rentier class

Theil wealth Theil income

Page 35: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

34

Secondly, we present the simulation results of a reduced form model to

highlight the importance of the novel features presented in our model for

analysing inequality. Figure 9 reports the simulation results of the model with a pure capitalist class, i.e. it is assumed in line with the existing literature that

rentiers earn only capital income and no wages. In this case, the overall trends in

the indicators reported in the full model are replicated. However, all measures of

inequality are understated. The Gini index for income is lower at 0.5, the

Atkinson index decreases to 0.37 and the squared coefficient of variation falls to

0.8 (panel A, fig.9). Similarly, the reported Theil T indices are lower, with values

of 0.024 and 0.013 for wealth and income respectively (panel B). The leverage

indicators remain largely unchanged, although the debt-to-asset ratio of the

rentier class increases slightly to 0.4 (panel D).

Similar results follow from a reduced form specification without neither

wage nor debt holdings for rentiers (fig.10). The Gini index and the Atkinson

index decrease to 0.5 and 0.38 respectively, while the squared coefficient of

variation falls to 0.85 (panel A). The values for the Theil indices for wealth and

income decrease to 0.028 and 0.016 respectively (panel B). Since no rentier debt

is considered, leverage ratios are only reported for the working and the middle

class. The values for both groups remain similar to the full specification, although

the debt service to income ratio for the middle class decreases slightly to 0.074

(panel C).

Finally, we present results from a reduced specification without

securitisation (fig.11). In this case, mortgages are not securitised and commercial

banks are the only financial institutions in the model. The asset side of rentiers balance sheet is reduced as they do not earn profits of institutional investors nor

do they purchase shares of securitised assets. Similarly to previous reduced

specification results, inequality measures are lower than in the full model. The

Gini index settles at 0.54, the Atkinson index falls to 0.41 and the squared

coefficient of variation falls to 0.99 (panel A, fig.11). The Theil T indices for

wealth and income stabilise at 0.026 and 0.013 respectively (panel B). In terms

of leverage measures, the debt service to income ratio falls slightly to 0.083 for

the working class (panel C).

Page 36: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

35

The comparison of the reduced specification results with the full model

shows clearly that heterogeneity of household balance sheets along the

distribution matters for inequality. Firstly, it is striking that factors commonly

omitted in the theoretical literature, such as rentier debt and rentier wage, have

an important impact on inequality measures, as is shown by the higher values of

all inequality indicators in the full model than in the reduced specifications.

Secondly, the results reveal that in light of household balance sheet

heterogeneity leverage of different income groups needs to be analysed

holistically. This is because each measure of financial fragility captures a

different aspect of indebtedness and thus does not represent the true capacity of

households to handle financial distress when analysed by itself. Consequently,

the results of our model strongly show that the theory of inequality in 21st

century in the context of financial sector transformation needs to take into

account different balance sheet positions of households and the associated

implications for financial distress.

Page 37: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

36

Figure 9. Simulation results – pure capitalists specification (A)

(B) (C)

(D) (E)

Theil wealth Theil income Working class

Middle class Rentier class

Working class Middle class Rentier class

Working class Middle class Rentier class

Gini index Atkinson index Squared coefficient of variation

Page 38: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

37

Figure 10. Simulation results – pure capitalist specification with no rentier debt

Gini index Atkinson index

(A)

(B) (C)

(D) (E)

Working class Middle class

Working class Middle class

Working class Middle class

Theil wealth Theil income

Gini index Atkinson index Squared coefficient of variation

Page 39: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

38

Figure 11. Simulation results – reduced specification without securitisation

(A)

(B) (C)

(D)

Theil wealth Theil income

Working class Middle class Rentier class

Working class Middle class Rentier class

Working class Middle class Rentier class

(E)

Gini index Atkinson index Squared coefficient of variation

Page 40: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

39

VI. Sensitivity analysis

In order to test the robustness of our finding that greater household balance

heterogeneity contributes to inequality, a range of sensitivity test is performed to

examine the volatility of the proposed model to specific parameter values. 12

parameters are identified as crucial to model results, reflecting the underlying

assumptions about economic behaviour. Two types of sensitivity analysis are

conducted – a univariate test, where the full model scenario is re-run changing

only one parameter at a time while leaving the others constant, and a

multivariate test, where variation in full model result is assessed by changing all

parameter values simultaneously. The model outcome is then seen as robust if

the values of key variables do not change significantly despite substantial

variation in parameter calibration.

Univariate sensitivity test

The choice of the sensitivity test values is motivated by changes in the actual

economic environment in the US after the 2007 crisis. All parameter values are

subsequently shocked in period 50.

One of the key distributional variables in our model is the central bank

interest rate rcb, as it constitutes the baseline for the interest rates on loans and

deposits set by commercial banks. In the sensitivity analysis, central bank

interests rate is shocked to increase from 0.25% to 0.5%. This corresponds to the

actual change in the interest rate level adopted by the Fed at its December 2015

meeting. Thus, apart from assessing the robustness of the model result, this

exercise also allows us to examine the impact of monetary policy on inequality

levels in the modelled economy.

Another parameter relevant for the interest rate level is 0, reflecting

institutional conditions in the lending market. Higher level of 0 indicates stricter

lending standards among the intermediaries, contributing to a larger transfer of

income from low- and middle-income households to rentiers via the banking

sector. In the sensitivity analysis, the value of 0 is increased from 0.03 to 0.04.

Page 41: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

40

Furthermore, the exogenously given share of wages is important for

distribution as it determines the portion of national income going to wage

payments. The wage share parameter sw is decreased from 57% to 50%,

additionally allowing us to analyse the impact of falling wage share on inequality

levels.

Another parameter crucial to the model dynamics is s0, which captures

the institutional conditions in financial markets in the equation defining the

share of securitised mortgages. The greater the proportion of securitised

mortgages the higher the transfer of the middle class wealth to rentiers via

securitisation. To examine volatility of the model outcome to the value of this

parameter, s0 is decreased from 0.6 to 0.4, reflecting slowdown in the mortgage

securitisation market after the crisis.

Further parameter influencing the distribution of income in our model is

the firm profit retention rate sf. Higher value of this parameter is likely to prevail

in recessionary periods as firms are more credit constrained. The value of sf

increases to 0.5, which corresponds to the actual post-crisis value.

Additionally, the sensitivity analysis assesses model robustness by

decreasing the rentier portfolio equation parameter λ30 from 0.33 to 0.25.

Importantly, due to the adding-up constraint requiring λ10, λ20 and λ30 to sum up

to unity (cf. Godley/Lavoie 2007), fall in λ30 necessitates a simultaneous rise in

one of the remaining two values. It is assumed that λ10 increases to 0.5. Rise in

the value of λ10 indicates greater preference for firm equities among rentiers and

hence smaller demand for securitised assets among institutional investors.

Choice of these parameters is once again motivated by the fall in demand for

mortgage-backed securities after the 2007 crisis.

In addition to the above parameters directly affecting the distribution of

income and wealth in our model we consider five parameters important for the

overall model dynamics. Firstly, we test model sensitivity to parameter β,

capturing household borrowing and lending norms. The value of β is decreased

from 0.1 to 0.05, reflecting more stringent lending conditions after the 2007

crisis. Secondly, propensity to consume out of wealth c3 is increased from 0.1 to

0.2, maintaining the assumption that each household group consumes the same

Page 42: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

41

proportion of its wealth. Thirdly, parameters h1 and h3 are decreased from 0.5 to

0.1, indicating a slowdown of housing supply by firms and a brake on the house

price growth respectively. Finally, parameter �10 in the institutional investors portfolio equation is decreased from 0.3 to 0.1, suggesting fallings demand of

institutional investors for MBS.

Overall, the univariate sensitivity analysis shows that our model results

are robust to changes in most of the key parameters. When the values of rcb, s0

and �10 are shocked in period 50, the model outcome exhibits no variation from

the baseline full model specification. Similarly, following a shock to the values of

h1, h3, 0, λ20 and λ30 model results do not change their long-term steady state

values, experiencing only very slight variations in the short-run.

However, the model outcome is sensitive to the values of parameters sw, sf,

β and c3. Fall in the wage share sw leads to higher steady-state levels of inequality,

with largest increases in the squared coefficient of variation for income (value of

1.6) and the Theil T index for wealth (0.033). The Gini index, the Atkinson index

and the Theil T index for income rise to 0.7, 0.53 and 0.02 respectively. Leverage

measures increase for the working and the middle class in the short run,

returning to their pre-shock levels in the long run. Conversely, leverage

indicators for rentiers decrease slightly following the shock, retaining their

original value in the long run.

In contrast, fall in the value of sf is associated with lower levels of

inequality but similar leverage levels in the model. Squared coefficient of

variation decreases the most to 0.73, with smaller fall in the Gini coefficient to

0.46 and the Theil T index for income to 0.01. The Atkinson index decreases to

0.4 and the Theil T index for wealth settles at 0.024. This occurs as the lower

level of distributed profits reduces the rentier income. Thus the decrease in

inequality is driven by redistribution at the top. The long run values of leverage

measures remain close to the baseline specification, with the middle class debt-

service to income ratio falling from 7.7% to 7.3%.

Furthermore, fall in parameter β has little influence on the levels of

inequality but it does result in lower values of the leverage measures. The debt

service to income ratio decreases to 0.051, 0.05 and 0.025 for the working, the

Page 43: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

42

middle and the rentier class respectively. The debt to asset ratio falls to 0.43,

0.31 and 0.29 respectively for the working, the middle and the rentier class. The

debt to income ratio settles at a lower level of 0.66, 0.91 and 0.93 for the working

class, the middle class and rentiers.

Finally, following the change in c3 all reported inequality and leverage

measures experience an initial decrease, followed by a rise and a subsequent fall.

The Gini index, Atkinson index and the squared coefficient of variation settle at a

slightly higher level of 0.63, 0.46 and 1.3 respectively. Similarly, the Theil T

indices for income and wealth rise to 0.017 and 0.029 respectively. The debt

service to income ratio increased only for rentiers, rising from 3.8% to 3.9%. The

debt to asset ratio increases from 0.5 to 0.64 for the working class as well as

from 0.4 to 0.57 and 0.55 for the middle and rentier class respectively. Finally,

debt to income ratio rises across households, from 0.87 to 0.89 for the working

class, from 1.3 to 1.38 for the middle class and from 1.4 to 1.45 for rentiers.

Multivariate sensitivity test

Having examined the sensitivity of the model result to changes in individual

parameters, we proceed to analyse its variation to changes in all chosen

parameters simultaneously. Since at the present stage of the analysis the choice

of sensitivity values for different parameters is not random, one multivariate

scenario corresponding to the post-crisis conditions in USA is considered,

maintaining consistency across parameter changes.

Introducing shocks to parameter values in period 50, the model is able to

reproduce the overall trends in economic dynamics experienced by USA after the

2007 crisis. Firstly, the change in parameter values is associated with a recession

in the model as following an initial acceleration from 2.5% to 16.5%, the steady

state growth rate of output falls to –6.5% and gradually returns to its pre-shock

level after around 20 periods.

Secondly, three out of four income inequality measures indicate falling

income inequality in the periods following the shock, settling at a lower steady

state level after approximately 10 periods. Squared coefficient of variation

experiences the largest fall from 1.25 to 0.88. The Gini index decreases by a

Page 44: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

43

smaller amount, from 0.6 to 0.49. Similarly, the Theil T index for income falls

from 0.016 to 0.01. In contrast, after the shock the Atkinson index for income

increases from 0.45 to 0.49. This suggest that changes in inequality occurring in

USA after the crisis have been different for various income groups. Sensitivity of

the squared coefficient of variation and the Gini index to changes at the top and

in the middle of the distribution respectively indicates that the fall in income

inequality post-2007 has been driven by its decrease among the top income

group, and less so by the middle. Conversely, sensitivity of the Atkinson index to

changes at the bottom of the distribution suggests that income inequality has

increased as the lowest income groups experienced a larger fall in incomes than

the rest. Furthermore, the model reproduces the fact that, unlike income, wealth

inequality as measured by the Theil T index increased after the crisis from 0.026

to 0.028, peaking at 0.033 in the period immediately after the shock.

Thirdly, among the leverage measures, debt service to income ratio and

debt to income ratio indicate overall deleveraging of households, while debt to

asset ratio indicates rising financial distress across household groups.

Specifically, the debt service to income ratio falls the most for the working class,

settling at a lower level of 5.2% after an initial increase from 8.5% to 15%. The

new steady state level of this ratio is significantly lower that the 8.7% result in

the baseline full model specification. The trend in the debt service to income

ratio is similar for the middle class, albeit of smaller magnitude. After a peak of

10% after the shock, the ratio settles at 5.3%, down from 7.7% in the baseline.

Similarly, the ratio for rentiers falls to 3%, after an initial increase to 5%, which

is also lower than the baseline result of 3.8%.

Furthermore, the debt to income ratio dips slightly, peaks and

subsequently falls across all household groups. This variation is the highest for

the rentiers, with the ratio rising to 1.75 before settling at a new value 0.98,

lower compared to the baseline result 1.4. The debt to income ratio for the

middle class peaks at 1.45 and subsequently decreases to 0.89 (1.3 in the full

model specification). Similarly, the ratio for the working class rises to 0.9 before

falling to 0.65, down from 0.87 in the baseline specification. Consequently, the

multivariate sensitivity analysis preserves the counterintuitive result regarding

Page 45: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

44

the order of magnitude of the debt to income ratio for different household

groups encountered in the full model simulation.

In contrast, the debt to asset ratio increases across all household groups

relative to the baseline simulation result. Following the shock, the ratio initially

peaks at approximately 0.6 for all households, before settling at a new level equal

to 0.55, 0.47 and 0.45 for the working, middle and rentier class respectively.

These values are higher than the baseline result of 0.5 for the working class and

0.4 for the middle and rentier class. Higher values of the debt to asset ratio

suggest that following a simultaneous variation of all key parameter values, loans

are falling less rapidly than the value of assets across all households.

Overall, the sensitivity analysis shows that the model results presented in

the previous section are robust to changes in most of the key parameters,

particularly in the long run. Sensitivity of the model outcome to changes in the

wage share and the profit retention ratio as well as household lending norms and

the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth suggest that not only income

but also wealth channels are important for inequality determination. The

proposed model setout, putting emphasis on balance sheet heterogeneity of

different household groups and a more active financial sector does well in

explaining trends in inequality in USA before and after the 2007 crisis.

VII. Conclusion and future work

Summary

The model outline presented here constitutes a first attempt of the author to

develop a theoretical model of inequality in the age of financialisation. SFCM is

adopted to account for the interactions between the financial and real sector and

their impact on the distribution of income and wealth in a financialised economy.

Unlike the existing functional distribution literature, in the current model

inequality is understood in terms of differential balance sheet and net wealth

structures among various income groups in the society. It is argued that this is a

more suitable approach to analysing inequality in times of financial sector transformation as the traditionally envisaged groups of workers and capitalists in the Post Keynesian literature became more heterogeneous since

Page 46: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

45

1980s. While low- and middle-income households became actively involved in

financial markets through securitisation, the rich captured an increasing share of

income and economic power due to high returns to their wealth in result of

financial innovation and deregulation as well as high incomes received in the

financial sector. Thus, the innovation of our model is to reinterpret the groups of

workers and rentiers as well as to reconceptualise the middle class and its role in

inequality trends since 1980s.

The main distributional channels in our model emerge through credit

provision to the working and the middle class (firstly, because the interest

payments by the latter are ultimately received by the rentiers, and secondly,

because loans to the working and middle class are transformed into derivative

instruments held by rentiers); the housing sector (directly through rent

payments by the working class households to rentiers and indirectly through

interest payments on mortgages); and inequality is also reflected in the relative

consumption undertaken by the middle class.

Future work

At this early stage, the model is necessarily simplistic. In the near future, I aim to

extend the model so as to account for important processes influencing

distribution in the age of financial sector transformation, which could not be

considered at present due to their novelty and complexity.

The most innovative aspect which will be considered in the model is the

addition of more complex microeconomic behaviour using agent-based

modelling (ABM) techniques (cf. Gaffeo et al. 2007, Delli Gatti et al. 2011, Caiani

et al. 2016). The present SFCM representation is too aggregate to study changes

in the shape of the wealth and income distribution in detail. This is because its

macroeconomic character imposes a top-down structure of behaviour in the

model. This macroeconomic rigour is certainly important as shown by

Dafermos/Papatheodorou (2015) since aggregate mechanisms provide

important feedback mechanisms into the distribution of income, which could

give misleading outlook on the dynamics of inequality overtime if omitted.

However, it may not be a suitable starting point for the analysis of inequality

based on understanding what determines portfolio decisions of households and

Page 47: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

46

hence their balance sheet structures in the times of financialisation. Agent-based

dynamics could inform what drives household behaviour when interacting with

different social groups, employers and the financial sector. It could also help to

correct the puzzle regarding the opposite than expected order of the debt-to-

income ratios in the present model.

Furthermore, I will analyse the influence of specific balance sheet

structures on income shares of different household groups. Decomposition

technique could be adopted to reveal which aspect of balance sheet inequality

has the biggest impact on distribution. This issue remains ambiguous in the

literature. While the Post Keynesian theories of inequality reviewed earlier

suggest that it is debt which exacerbates the distribution of income away from

workers, empirical studies often find that it is the asset side of the balance sheets

that contributes more to inequality (cf. Fredriksen 2012). Similar conclusion can

be drawn from Piketty, according to whom high capital income from assets held

by the top 1% drives economic inequality. The unique setout of our model would

be capable of testing these competing claims.

Further extension to the present model will concern the inclusion of

social transfers. This is particularly important in the recent years, as due to

stagnating incomes and worsening working conditions (due to globalisation,

privatisation and labour market liberalisation), many especially low income

households (corresponding to the working class in our model) rely increasingly

on social security in their income. Furthermore, it would shed light on how

different taxation policies influence inequality.

Page 48: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

47

References

Alvaredo, F., Atkinson, A.B., Piketty, T. and Saez, E., The World Top Incomes

Database, http://topincomes.g-mond.parisschoolofeconomics.eu;

AMECO Database, European Commission. Available at:

http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ameco/user/serie/SelectSerie.cfm [Accessed:

3/08/2015]; Ampudia M., van Vlokhoven, (., and Zochowski, D. Financial fragility of euro area households , Working paper , European Central Bank; Atkinson, A.B. and Brandolini, A. On the identification of the middle class , EC)NEQ Working Paper -217, Bivens, J., Gould, E., Mishel, L. and Shierholz, (. Raising America s Pay. Why )t s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge , Economics Policy )nstitute Briefing

Paper #378; Bhaduri, A., and Marglin, S. Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for contesting political ideologies , Cambridge Journal of Economics, , pp. 375-393; Boushey, (., and Weller, C. (as Growing )nequality Contributed to Rising (ousehold Economic Distress? , Review of Political Economy, 20(1), pp. 1-22;

Caiani, A., Godin, A., Caverzasi, E., Gallegati, M., Kinsella, S., Stiglitz, J.E. (2016) Agent based-stock flow consistent macroeconomics: Towards a benchmark model , Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 69, pp. 375-408; Caverzasi, E. and Godin, A. Stock-flow Consistent Modeling through the

Ages , The Levy Economics )nstitute Working Paper No. ; Caverzasi, E. and Godin, A. Financialization and the sub-prime crisis: a

Stock-Flow Consistent model , Working paper; Congressional Budget Office (2014), The Distribution of Household Income and

Federal Taxes, 2011. Available at: https://www.cbo.gov/publication/49440

Copeland, M. A. ( Social Accounting for Money Flows , The Accounting

Review, 24(3), pp. 254–264;

Page 49: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

48

Cynamon, B.Z. and Fazzari, S.M. (ousehold Debt in the Consumer Age: Source of Growth—Risk of Collapse , Capitalism and Society, 3(2), pp. 1-30;

Dafermos, Y. and Papatheodorou, C. Linking functional with personal income distribution: a stock-flow consistent approach , )nternational Review of Applied Economics, 29(6), pp. 1-29; Davis, E.P. )nstitutional )nvestors, Financial Market Efficiency, and Financial Stability , E)B Papers, , pp. -107;

Delli Gatti D., Desiderio, S., Gaffeo, E., Cirillo, P. and Gallegati, M. (eds) (2011)

Macroeconomics from the Bottom-up, Milan: Springer; Detzer, D. Financialisation, Debt and )nequality – Scenarios Based on a Stock Flow Consistent Model , )MK Working Paper No. / ; DeVaney, S.A. and Lytton, R.(. (ousehold insolvency: A review of household debt repayment, delinquency, and bankruptcy , Financial Services Review,

4(2), pp. 137-156;

Dos Santos, C.(. and Macedo e Silva, A.C. Revisiting and Connecting Marglin-Bhaduri and Minsky: An SFC Look at Financialization and Profit-led Growth , The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper No. 567;

Duesenberry, J.S. (1949) Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumption

Behaviour, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press;

Dufour, M. and Orhangazi, O. Growth and distribution after the – US financial crisis: who shouldered the burden of the crisis? , Review of Keynesian

Economics, 4(2), pp. 151-174; Dymski, G.A. Racial Exclusion and the Political Economy of the Subprime Crisis , Historical Materialism, 17, pp.149-179; Dymski, G.A., (ernandez, J. and Mohanty, L. Race, Gender, Power, and the US Subprime Mortgage and Foreclosure Crisis: A Meso Analysis", Feminist Economics,

19(3), pp.124-151;

Foster, J.B. and Holleman, (. The Financial Power Elite , The Monthly

Review, 62(1);

Page 50: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

49

Frank, R.(., Levine, A.S. and Dijk, O. Expenditure Cascades ; Review of

Behavioral Economics, 1(1–2), pp 55-73; Fredriksen, K.B. Less )ncome )nequality and More Growth — Are they

Compatible? Part 6. The Distribution of Wealth , OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 929;

Gaffeo, E., Catalano, M., Clementi, F., Delli Gatti, D., Gallegati, M. and Russo, A. Reflections on modern macroeconomics: Can we travel along a safer road? , Physica A, 382, pp. 89-97;

Goda, T., and Lysandrou, P. The Contribution of Wealth Concentration to the Subprime Crisis: A Quantitative Estimation , C)BS Working Paper No. ; Godley, W. and Lavoie, M. (2007) Monetary Economics. An Integrated Approach to

Credit, Money, Income, Production and Wealth, 1st Edition, Basingstoke: Palgrave

Macmillan;

Gould, E. (2016) Wage inequality continued its 35-year rise in 2015 , Economic Policy Institute Briefing Paper #421; (ein, E. Financialisation in a comparative static, stock-flow consistent

Post-Kaleckian distribution and growth model , Macroeconomic Policy )nstitute )MK Studies 21/2008; (ein, E. Finance-dominated capitalism and re-distribution of income: a Kaleckian perspective , Cambridge Journal of Economics, , pp. 907-934; (ein, E. and Van Treeck, T. Financialisation and Rising Shareholder Power in Kaleckian/Post-Kaleckian Models of Distribution and Growth , Review of Political Economy, 22(2), pp. 205-233;

Kalecki, M. (1971) Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy,

Cambridge: CUP; Kapeller, J. and Schuetz, B. Conspicuous Consumption, )nequality and Debt: The Nature of Consumption-driven Profit-led regimes , Metroeconomica, 66:1, pp.

51-70;

Page 51: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

50

Kaplan, S.N. and Rauh, J. (2010) Wall Street and Main Street: What Contributes to the Rise in the (ighest )ncomes? , The Review of Financial Studies, , pp. -

1050;

Keister, L.A. and Lee, (.Y. The One Percent: Top Incomes and Wealth in

Sociological Research , Social Currents, 1(1), pp. 13-24; Krippner, G. The financialization of the American economy , Socio-

Economic Review, 3, pp.173-208; Krueger, D. and Perri, F. Does )ncome )nequality Lead to Consumption )nequality? Evidence and Theory , Review of Economic Studies, 73, pp. 163-193;

Minsky, H.P. (1986) Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, Yale: Yale University Press; Nikolaidi, M. Securitisation, wage stagnation and financial fragility: a stock-flow consistent perspective , Greenwich Papers in Political Economy; Onaran, O., Stockhammer, E. and Grafl, L. Financialisation, income distribution and aggregate demand in the USA , Cambridge Journal of Economics, , pp. 637-661; Palley, T.). Financialization: What )t )s and Why )t Matters , The Levy

Economics Institute Working Paper No. 525; Palley, T.). Wealth and wealth distribution in the neo-Kaleckian growth model , Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, , pp. -474; Palley, T.). Enriching the neo-Kaleckian growth model: Nonlinearities, political economy, and financial factors , PER) Working Paper No. ; Pew Charitable Trust Payday Lending in America: Who Borrows, Where They Borrow, and Why , Report; Pew Research Center The American Middle Class )s Losing Ground ,

Report;

Piketty, T. (2014) Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Harvard: HUP;

Piketty, T. and Zucman, G. Capital is back: wealth-income ratios in rich

countries 1700– , The Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp. 1255-1310;

Page 52: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

51

Pollin, R. and (eintz, J, Study of U.S. Financial System", FESSUD Studies in Financial Systems No. 10;

Pressman, S. (2007) The Decline of the Middle Class: An )nternational Perspective , Journal of Economic Issues, 41(1), pp. 181-200;

Pressman, S. (2016) Understanding Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century,

Abingdon: Routledge;

Pressman, S. and Scott, R. Consumer Debt and the Measurement of Poverty and )nequality in the US , Review of Social Economy, 67(2), pp. 127-148;

PWC , Precious Plastic. How Britons fell back in love with borrowing , Report; Ravina, E. (abit formation and keeping up with the Joneses: evidence from micro data . Available at:

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=928248 Sawyer, M. What is Financialisation? , International Journal of Political

Economy, 42(4), pp. 5-18; Sawyer, M. and Passarella Veronese, M. The Monetary Circuit in the age of Financialisation , University of Leeds Working Paper;

Scott, R. and Pressman, S. )nadequate (ousehold Deleveraging: )ncome, Debt and Social Provisioning , Journal of Economic Issues, 49(2), pp. 483-492; Setterfield, M. and Kim, Y.K. Debt Servicing, Aggregate Consumption, and Growth , Trinity College Department of Economics Working Paper -16;

Survey of Consumer Finances, 1989-2013, Federal Reserve. Available at:

http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/scf/scfindex.htm Van Treeck, T. A synthetic stock-flow consistent macroeconomic model of financialisation , Cambridge Journal of Economics, , pp. -493;

Veblen, T. (1899) The Theory of the Leisure Class, New York: Macmillan; Wolff, E.N. (ousehold wealth trends in the United States, 1983- , Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(1), pp. 21-43. World Bank )nequality Measures , Chapter , Poverty Manual;

Page 53: Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model … · 2016. 11. 16. · 1 Financial sector development and inequality theoretical model for USA Hanna Szymborska University

52

Young, B. The Gendered Dimension of Money, Finance and the Subprime Crisis . )n: Bauhardt, C. and Caglar, G. eds) Gender and Economics. Feministische Kritik

der politischen Oekonomie, Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften; Zezza, G. U.S. growth, the housing market, and the distribution of income , Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, , pp. -401.


Recommended